An economic history of the Tour de France, 1903–2015
Jean-François Mignot
The Tour de France is a three-week bicycle race held in July on the roads of France and
neighboring countries. It is the most popular and prestigious bicycle race in the world
and it is also the most profitable race for organizers, sponsors and riders. How did the
Tour become so popular? Why is it still commercially successful and considered as a
high-quality product Andreff
reflect?
? And which economic trends does this success
To answer these questions, it is necessary to go back to the origins of the Tour de
France and trace the main steps of its history. The Tour de France was created in 1903,
and since then it has been held every year except during world wars (1915–1918 and
1940–1946). As many spectators know, the Tour has a diversified geography (Bačík and
Klobučník 2013), a long sporting history (Chany and Cazeneuve 2003; McGann and
McGann 2006, 2008) and a rich cultural history (Dauncey and Hare 2003; Thompson
2006; Reed 2015). However, despite some studies on the economic aspects of the Tour
de France (Calvet 1981; Reed 2003), the economic motivations behind the race are less
well known. This chapter presents the economic history of the Tour de France since the
early 20th century (Mignot 2014), focusing on the changes that affected the three most
important economic agents of the race: (1) the organizers, (2) the riders and (3) the
spectators.
<a>4.1 Who organizes the Tour? The Tour de France as a private company
When modern bicycles were invented, in the 1880s, they immediately started selling,
first among the upper classes but progressively more and more among the bulk of the
population (Gaboriau 1995). As early as the mid-1900s in France there were around five
1
bicycles per 100 inhabitants (INSEE 1952). It is in this context that the Tour de France
was organized for the first time. Who created the Tour, and why? Who owns it? How do
the organizers make a profit?
The Tour de France was created in 1903 by the French sports newspaper L’Auto.
Indeed, from the late 19th century, Western European sports journals started organizing
bicycle races to report on them and increase their circulation. The journal paid for the
race’s logistics and prize money in order to sell more papers and to be able to charge
more for advertisements. However, in the 1900s, the Tour de France was not just a race
among many others: it was one of the first if not the first stage race, i.e. a road race run
over several one-day stages, and it was by far the longest and the most heroic of all races.
The first edition of the Tour included six stages over three weeks, totaling an impressive
2,428 kilometers. The first Tour was so successful that L’Auto’s main competitor, Le Vélo,
died out in 1904.
Since 1903, the owner of the Tour has always been a profit-seeking media group
(McKay 2011a). From 1903 to 1940, the Tour was owned by the founding newspaper
L’Auto. After the Second World War, from 1947 to 1965, the race was owned by the
newspapers L’Équipe and Le Parisien libéré (through La Société du Parc des Princes).
And since 1965, the Tour has been owned by firms from the group which became the
Amaury Sport Organisation (ASO), a French sports event organizer and the most
powerful actor in present-day professional road cycling. As researchers noted, neither
the teams nor the riders, obviously essential ingredients of a cycling race, nor the
national and international cycling federations, as regulatory bodies, are able to challenge
this dominant position of ASO at this moment Van Reeth and Lagae
, p.
.
To make a profit without charging spectators for being on the sides of the road,
the organizers initially relied mostly on increases in the circulation of their journal and
2
the concomitant advertising revenue. And indeed, from the 1900s to the 1930s, the Tour
usually made L’Auto’s sales double in July, compared to the other months of the year.
However, organizers soon found additional ways to make the race profitable. First, from
the interwar years on, they auctioned off the race’s route to the highest bidding host
cities (and local newspapers), predominantly in France but also in other countries (for
more on the economic relationship between the Tour and host cities, see Viollet 2007
and Reed 2015). Second, they sold advertising space on the race. Local firms or cycling
clubs have always been willing to offer race prizes in order to advertise for their activity.
)t is only since
, however, that the Tour includes a publicity caravan, i.e. vehicles
which precede riders by a few minutes and distribute goodies to spectators. Today,
companies pay between €200,000 and €500,000 a year to be part of the caravan, and
during the 21 days of racing, they give away about 14 million product samples Lagae
2015, p. 96). In addition, the Tour has had various sponsors since the interwar years,
and today it has four main sponsors and several official partners, which further increase
its advertising revenues. Third, since the 1960s, Tour organizers also sell television
broadcast rights. These are the Tour de France’s three main turnover sources.
Although the Tour probably was often in deficit from the late 1930s until the mid-
1970s (Reed 2003; Viollet 2007), it has always been profitable since at least the 1990s
Andreff
. )n the
its profits were around €
s, while ASO’s yearly revenues hovered around €
million McKay
million,
a . (owever, as long-term data on the
profits of the Tour are not publicly available, I focus on the Tour’s turnover since the
1950s (Figure 4.1).
<SETTER: insert Figure 4.1 here>
<caption>Figure 4.1 <em> Tour de France revenues, 1950–2013 (in 2013
dollars)</caption>
3
100%
100 000 000
75%
50%
10 000 000
25%
1 000 000
0%
1950
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
2010
Turnout (left axis)
Television rights, in % of turnout (right axis)
<source>Source: Mignot 2014.</source>
From the early 1950s to the late 1970s, the turnover of the Tour doubled. During this
period, cycling was one of the most popular sports in Europe, which made cities and
sponsors willing to pay to have their image associated with the Tour de France. The
Tour’s turnover was composed of host cities’ contributions around
–40% of the total
turnover) and, above all, revenues from advertising and sponsoring (60–70% of the total
turnover). This period may also be seen as the period of some of the greatest champions
of all time: Italian campionissimo Fausto Coppi, French champion Jacques Anquetil and
Belgian legend Eddy Merckx.
It is only since the early 1980s that the turnover of the Tour skyrocketed:
between the early 1980s and the late 2000s it multiplied by 20 (Figure 4.1, left axis).
This major transformation is partly due to the direct increase in television rights: while
in the early 1980s they represented less than 10% of the total turnover, they now
represent more than two-thirds of it (Figure 4.1, right axis). Television broadcasting also
enriched the Tour de France indirectly, by making cities and sponsors willing to pay
more and more to gain access to a wider, globalized audience. Nowadays, the Tour’s
turnover is mainly composed of television broadcasting rights (70% of the total
4
turnover , while advertising and sponsoring
% and cities’ contributions
far less important contributors to the Tour’s revenues.
% are
Why has there been such a huge increase in television rights since the 1980s,
while half of French households had a television set as early as 1965? Technological
advances enabled television channels to broadcast longer, better-quality and live images
of bicycle races. This increased the audience, which increased channels’ willingness to
pay to broadcast the Tour. More importantly still, as European television markets were
liberalized in the 1980s, several channels started to compete with each other to
broadcast the Tour. Until then, the Tour de France had to compete against other sports
events to be broadcast on the (unique) French national television channel. From the
1980s, the Tour de France gained market power against the (now multiple) television
channels and it was able to extract more and more money from them (Bolotny and
Bourg 2009).
<a>4.2 Who rides the Tour? The riders as professionals
Cycling never was an amateur sport: it became professional as early as the late
nineteenth century, which makes it one of the very first sports practiced for commercial
purposes. Indeed, bicycle and tire companies were willing to sponsor riders, i.e. to give
them some food, accommodation, health care and equipment to help them win races and
thereby advertise their products. By contrast, bicycle companies rarely organized races,
because the public would have suspected them of manipulating the race in order to
advertise their brand (Calvet 1981). It is in this context that a few sons of peasants or
workers became riders. How did they make a living? How has their labor income
evolved over time? When and why did riders group into teams?
From the late nineteenth century to the Second World War, most sponsors gave
riders only a bicycle and tires, and riders’ income stemmed entirely from race prize
5
money. This is why the prize money was so crucial in determining whether riders would
participate in the Tour or not. In 1913, after French champion Octave Lapize quit the
Tour, he explained:
<quotation>The Tour is not a good deal for me! In the team I am the only one fighting to
make money and some of my teammates are demanding more money than they should.
If I win the Tour, which is easier said than done, I will hardly earn 7,000 francs. Track
contracts [i.e., money given by velodromes to have riders participate in track races] will
earn me much more. (Chany and Cazeneuve 2003, p. 163)</quotation>
Riders earned an income that was both relatively low and totally dependent on their
individual performance, which induced riders to find (often secret) ways to insure
against the very high volatility of their earnings. For instance, in 1903, Hippolyte
Aucouturier sacrificed his chances for Emile Georget in exchange for money and the
stage win in Marseilles. In 1911, a rider who could not hope to win much anymore,
Maurice Brocco, sold his services to the highest bidder – for which he was excluded.
Riders’ wages probably were at their lowest immediately after the First World War,
when the few remaining bicycle companies cartelized the demand for riders and
restricted their wages.
It is only since the 1950s that most sponsors have given riders a fixed annual
wage. (owever, from the
s to the
s, the larger part of riders’ labor income was
not made up of their fixed wage or their variable share of the prize money: most of their
income stemmed from criteriums, i.e. short one-day road races which paid riders to
participate and to meet their fans, and sometimes to let some predetermined rider win
(McKay 2011b). This is why in the late 1940s il campionissimo Fausto Coppi conditioned
his participation in the Tour on his being guaranteed post-Tour track contracts.
Although riders’ wages and prize winnings suffered a decline from the mid-1950s to the
6
mid-
s, their overall labor incomes did not decrease because criteriums’ appearance
fees increased substantially.
Until the 1980s, riders originated very much from peasant and working-class
origins and from the countryside, which means cycling was, to some extent, a means of
upward social mobility for a few riders. And the Tour organizers insisted on this aspect
to encourage such dreams in its followers. For instance, as early as 1925, L’Auto
published a series and participated in the making of a (silent, multi-episode) movie
entitled Le roi de la pédale, featuring a working-class boy climbing the social ladder
thanks to the Tour (Bauer and Froissart 2015). On retirement, some riders opened a bar,
a restaurant or a bicycle shop, but only a very few of them could reasonably be
considered as rich (Thompson 2006, pp. 141–179).
Since the 1980s, as most criteriums disappeared, the increase in television
audiences improved sponsors’ willingness to pay riders higher wages. This is why riders’
fixed annual wages have increased. Actually, this is especially the case for those few
cyclists with the highest marginal productivity in terms of media coverage – cycling’s
superstars Rosen
for more on riders’ salaries, see Van Reeth
a, pp. 66–71).
)n addition, the increase in television broadcast rights improved Tour organizers’
willingness to increase the Tour’s prize money in order to attract the world’s best riders.
Currently, the Tour de France is a race between 22 teams of nine riders each, i.e.
198 riders. The rider who completes the stages of the race in the shortest time wins the
general classification leader’s yellow jersey, which wins the highest cash prize and was
created in 1919 after the color of L’Auto’s pages. There also exist other prizes such as the
King of the Mountains classification’s polka dot jersey for climbers, since
the points classification’s green jersey for sprinters, since 1953). To increase
and
competition, the Tour also includes other prizes such as stage-win cash prizes, and a
7
fighting-spirit prize for the rider who attacks the most, etc. All these cash prizes are
shared among team members.
Historically, the total prize pool of the Tour de France increased mainly when the
Tour budget increased (Figure 4.2, left axis). From 1930 onward, the creation of the
publicity caravan increased the Tour’s budget substantially, which led the organizers to
increase the total prize money in order to attract the world’s best riders. (owever, the
total prize pool remained relatively low until the 1980s. In 1965, Jacques Anquetil
deliberately chose not to participate in the Tour because the public was tired of his alltoo-frequent and predictable victories. (e said: )f ) win the Tour de France a sixth time
my criterium contracts will not get more rewarding. However if I do not win they will
definitely become less rewarding. Don’t count on me! Chany and Cazeneuve
, p.
501).
From the 1980s, increasing television broadcast rights made the Tour budget
skyrocket, which once again led the organizers to increase the total prize money to keep
on attracting the world’s best riders. While the total prize money was less than
US$1,000,000 in the mid-1980s, in the mid-1990s it was more than US$3,000,000.
<SETTER: insert Figure 4.2 here>
<caption>Figure 4.2 Tour de France Prize Money, 1903–2013 (in 2013 dollars)</caption>
8
5 000 000
30%
4 000 000
20%
3 000 000
2 000 000
10%
1 000 000
0
1900
0%
1925
1950
1975
2000
Total prize pool (left axis)
Winner's share of the total prize pool (right axis)
<source>Source:<em>ASO and Augendre 2015.</source>
Given the total size of the prize money, Tour de France organizers have always
structured the prize pool to give riders an incentive to fight, rather than share the money
without effort. As contest theory shows, amplifying the difference between each rank’s
cash prize and the next makes it in the riders’ interest to compete more intensely for
victory (Tullock 1980). This is why the distribution of the prize money shows clear
winner-takes-all aspects: since the
s, around
% of the prize money goes to a
single rider, the winner (Figure 4.2, right axis). During the 1980s and 1990s, the share of
the prize pool given to the winner went from less than 5% to around 20%. This may be
because when riders’ fixed wages increase, the additional prize money which is
necessary to lead riders to fight for victory is greater.
From 1903 to 1929, the Tour organizer allowed the participation of individual
riders and, progressively, riders grouped into teams which were sponsored by bicycle
constructors or tire companies such as Peugeot, Alcyon and Automoto. However, from
1930 to 1961 (and in 1967–1968), the organizer replaced sponsored teams with
national teams, because sponsors were accused of fixing the race or colluding to share
the prize pool. For instance, the Alcyon team, which won the Tour in 1927, 1928 and
9
again in 1929, is suspected of having bribed competitors to ensure it would win. Since
1962, all participants are members of a sponsored team, and teams are sponsored not
only by cycling-related companies (Gitane, Renault, BMC, etc.) but by companies from a
diverse array of industries (Lagae 2015), as testified by some winning teams since the
1990s: Banesto, US Postal Service, Discovery Channel, Sky, Astana, etc. Since the 1960s,
the Tour de France has developed a whole discourse on sport’s values to attract
sponsors whose products are not related to cycling any more.
<a>4.3 Who watches the Tour? Spectators as demanders of a show
Since the late nineteenth century, the economic model of the Tour de France has
remained the same: the public is willing to watch advertisements (on the road, in the
newspaper or on television) in order to be able to follow the developments of the race,
and this is why the Tour exists in the first place. However, the Tour de France also
reflects long-term economic changes. It is the increase in incomes and the advent of
leisure time, including reading newspapers and riding a bicycle, which created a demand
for a bicycle race like the Tour de France. And since its creation the Tour also reflects the
advent of the mass media and the globalization of sport. Nowadays, the Tour is one of
the world’s largest sports events, with
–15 million spectators on the roads per year
and over 20 million TV viewers worldwide per racing day (Andreff 2015).
The media that have been broadcasting the Tour since its creation have had a
clear impact on the Tour’s economic value for organizers, sponsors and riders, but also
on the content of the race and its cultural impact. When the newspaper L’Auto founded
the Tour de France to increase its circulation, it instituted rules which made the race an
epic race which would attract readers. The public wanted to read about the giants of
the road defying mountains (first covered in 1910), rain, mud and snow in endless
stages. This is why, according to the rules, riders were not supposed to group into teams,
10
they had to repair their bicycle without any help and until 1937 they were not allowed
to use derailleur gears.
Then, from the late 1920s, the Tour de France started to be broadcast on the
radio (and in cinema newsreels). People interested in the Tour could now hear the
voices of champions and, above all, follow the developments of the race almost
instantaneously. The Tour adapted to this new context by shortening stages to make
them more exciting and better suited to radio listeners who were especially interested
in following stage finishes live. In addition, L’Auto allied with other economic actors to
promote the Tour de France by creating Tour-related cultural objects (Thompson 2006;
Bauer and Froissart 2015).
Since the 1950s, the Tour has been broadcast on television. The Tour was first
filmed with fixed cameras and broadcast with a delay of one day; it is only since the
1970s that it has been broadcast live, with mobile cameras and on color television sets.
Once again, the Tour adapted to this new context by shortening stages further and
organizing them around peak television viewing times, i.e. around the end of the
afternoon (Van Reeth 2015b). Thus, Tour organizers have modified the sport content of
the race to better suit demand and their own economic interest.
The television broadcast of the Tour has had another consequence: it has
probably contributed to the decrease in the number of people watching the race on the
roads (Figure 4.3). While in the 1900s only about 2% of the French population followed
the Tour, in the 1960s approximately one-third did. However, since then, this proportion
has decreased. Television offers such a great show that the need to see the riders for
real is less than it was.
<caption>Figure 4.3 <em> Proportion of the French population on the Tour de France
roads, 1903–2003</caption>
11
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
1900
1925
1950
1975
2000
<source>Source:<em>Viollet 2007.</source>
Although there were international exchanges among cycling’s actors as early as the
nineteenth century (Knuts and Delheye 2014), it is only since the Second World War
that the Tour has deliberately tried to attract fans from foreign countries. Its aim is to
increase its audience, and thus increase the television broadcast rights it can garner
from abroad. This is why the Tour has been crossing into more and more countries in
addition to France: Italy and Spain (1949), the Netherlands (1954), Belgium (1958),
Germany (1965), Switzerland (1982), Luxembourg (1989), Ireland (1998), England
(2007), etc. This is also why the Tour has been inviting more and more teams with
foreign riders. The proportion of participants who are not French has exceeded 25%
since the 1910s, has been more than 50% since the 1930s and has been more than 75%
since the 1980s. And the nationalities of (elite and non-elite) riders, cycling teams and
team riders have become even more diversified since the 1990s (Van Reeth 2015c), now
including Colombian, American and Eastern European riders. The Tour is now broadcast
in almost 200 countries worldwide, and is a partly international sporting event, even
though Africa and to some extent Asia are still massively under-represented among both
riders and television spectators of the Tour de France.
12
<a>4.4 Reasons behind the success of the Tour
The enduring success of the Tour may be explained partly by the quality of the show.
)ndeed, in the long term, riders’ performance has clearly improved, while at least in
certain respects the element of uncertainty in terms of the outcome of the race has
improved too.
As the winners’ mean speed illustrates, riders’ speeds have increased (Figure 4.4,
left axis). This reflects major long-term improvements in riders’ equipment, road quality,
bicycle weight, brake quality, etc. Just as Joseph Schumpeter noted that good brakes
make cars go faster, better brakes enabled racers to increase their speed without taking
too many risks. The long-term increase in riders’ speed also reflects riders’ better
physical preparation, diet and training. The improvement of performance is also partly
due to a more efficient organization (i.e., better incentives) inside teams, as recent
research on the determinants of performance suggests (Torgler 2007; Prinz and Wicker
2012; Rogge et al. 2013). The increase in performance inequality amongst Tour riders
since the 1970s has been shown to be due entirely to an increase in performance
inequalities within – not between – teams (Candelon and Dupuy 2015), which means
that domestiques increasingly sacrifice their own chances to help their team leader
perform better and then share his prizes.
<caption>Figure 4.4 <em> Performance and competitive balance in the Tour de France,
1903–2014</caption>
13
50
180
40
120
30
60
20
1900
0
1925
1950
1975
2000
Winner's mean speed, in km/h (left axis)
Time gap between winner and 2nd finisher, in minutes (right axis)
<source>Source:<em>Mignot 2014.</source>
Racers’ performances have also probably been impacted by performance-enhancing
drugs (Brewer 2002; Woodland 2003; Brissonneau et al. 2008). Since the late 19th
century, riders have been using – in chronological order – strychnine, nitroglycerine,
amphetamines, anabolic steroids, corticosteroids, growth hormones, beta-2-agonists,
blood doping and (several generations of) EPO, and blood doping again (Vandeweghe
2015). The 1960s’ doping practices triggered tragedies such as Roger Rivière’s serious
accident (19
and Tom Simpson’s death on the climb of the Mont Ventoux
which is why anti-doping tests started being used in the second half of the 1960s.
,
However, in 1966, the new anti-doping urine tests were immediately welcomed in with
a riders’ strike. Since the 1990s, the use of EPO generated several doping scandals, most
notably the Festina Affair
and Lance Armstrong’s most sophisticated,
professionalized and successful doping program that sport has ever seen U.S. AntiDoping Agency 2012). As game-theoretical analyses indicate, athletes who have to
choose between doping and not doping find themselves in a prisoner’s dilemma:
although each athlete would prefer that no one (rather than everyone) dopes, each also
prefers to dope whether others dope or not (Eber 2009).
14
Even more than purely performance, the competitive balance of the Tour is a major
determinant of the quality of the show. As race organizers know, no one would want to
watch a race the outcome of which is known in advance. For instance, when in 1934
Tour organizers introduced the King of the Mountains classification, they also
introduced the first individual time trial so that both climbers and riders who are strong
on the flat may win the overall competition. And when in 1952 the campionissimo Fausto
Coppi dominated the race as early as the tenth stage, organizers doubled the secondplace cash prize so that riders could fight for second if not first place.
To the extent that the time gap between the winner and second finisher is a good
indicator of overall competitive balance, organizers have succeeded in increasing the
uncertainty of the race (Figure 4.4, right axis). In this respect, the most competitive
edition of the race was the legendary 1989 Tour, in which Greg LeMond beat Laurent
Fignon by eight seconds. However, additional indicators of (static or dynamic)
competitive balance, including indicators taking into account the relative strengths of
teams, not just individual racers, should be computed to re-examine this observation.
Indeed, although it is very difficult to predict the name of the winner from one year to
the next, shortly after the Tour’s start it is usually pretty easy to predict from which
team(s) and among which riders the winner will come (Andreff 2015, p. 246).
Part of the success of the Tour de France is also due to the fact that it refers to
symbols that generate strong emotions among the French public – it is one of France’s
realms of memory Vigarello
. For instance, the
Tour offered
,
francs
at the 1,789th kilometer to celebrate the 200th anniversary of the French Revolution.
The 1994 Tour also went through the places where the Normandy landings liberated
France from Nazi rule 50 years before. From a more global perspective, the success of
the Tour de France is also partly due to the fact that it shows beautiful pictures of the
15
French countryside and Paris. It is precisely to produce such telegenic pictures that the
Tour introduced a prologue (1967) and the arrival at the Champs-Élysées (1975).
<a>4.5 Conclusion
The Tour de France became popular from its creation in 1903. Back then, it was a
symbol of speed, mass consumption and modernity. However, why did the Tour de
France stay popular, and how has it been able to survive the competition from other
sporting events for more than a century? The major reason is probably that the Tour
succeeded in adapting to new types of demand. As sports newspapers declined, the Tour
was able to profit from the advent of the radio in the interwar years, and from the
advent of television from the 1950s. When bicycle and tire companies stopped
sponsoring the Tour and cycling teams in the 1950s, the Tour was able to attract more
diversified companies. And as sport globalized in the 1980s, the Tour was able to garner
interest from cycling fans beyond France and Europe. Thus, the history of the Tour de
France is not just part of the history of professional road cycling (Mignot 2015). Much
more generally, it is part of – and in many ways reflects – European economic history.
<a>References
Amaury Sport Organisation and Jacques Augendre (2015), Le Tour de France. Guide
historique. Available at http://netstorage.lequipe.fr/ASO/cyclisme/letour/2015/histoire/Historique-VERSION_INTEGRALE-fr.pdf (accessed 1 November
2015).
Andreff, Wladimir (2015), The Tour de France: A Success Story in Spite of Competitive
Imbalance and Doping, in Daam Van Reeth and Daniel Larson eds. The Economics of
Professional Road Cycling (Springer: New York), 233–255.
Bačík, Vladimir and Michal Klobučník (2013), History of Tour de France from the
Geographical Point of View, Sport Science Review 22, 255–277.
16
Bauer, Thomas and Tony Froissart (2015), Cycling, Mass Media and Business:
Serialization of Le Roi de la pédale (1925) by Paul Cartoux and Henri Decoin, The
International Journal of the History of Sport 32(11/12), 1456–1471.
Bolotny, Frédéric and Jean-François Bourg (2009), The Demand for Media Coverage, in
Wladimir Andreff and Stefan Szymanski eds. Handbook on the Economics of Sport
(Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA, USA), 112–133.
Brewer, Benjamin D. (2002), Commercialization in Professional Cycling, 1950–2001:
Institutional Transformations and the Rationalization of "Doping," Sociology of Sport
Journal 19(3), 276–301.
Brissonneau, Christophe, Olivier Aubel and Fabien Ohl (2008), L’épreuve du dopage.
Sociologie du cyclisme professionnel (Presses universitaires de France: Paris).
Calvet, J. (1981) Le Mythe des Géants de la Route (Presses universitaires de Grenoble:
Grenoble).
Candelon, Bertrand and Arnaud Dupuy (2015), Hierarchical Organization and
Performance Inequality: Evidence from Professional Cycling, International Economic
Review 56(4), 1207–1236.
Chany, Pierre and Thierry Cazeneuve (2003), La Fabuleuse Histoire du Tour de France
(Minerva: Geneva).
Dauncey, Hugh and Geoff Hare (2003), The Tour de France, 1903–2003. A Century of
Sporting Structures, Meanings and Values (Frank Cass: London).
Eber, Nicolas (2009), Doping, in Wladimir Andreff and Stefan Szymanski eds. Handbook
on the Economics of Sport (Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA,
USA), 773–778.
Gaboriau, Philippe (1995), Le Tour de France et le Vélo. Histoire sociale d’une épopée
contemporaine L’(armattan: Paris).
17
INSEE (1952), Annuaire statistique de la France 1951 (PUF: Paris).
Knuts, Stijn and Pascal Delheye P. (2014), Borderless Sport? Imagining and Organising
Bicycle Racing in Belgium, 1869–1914: Between Transnational Dynamics and
National Aspirations, European Review of History 21(3), 379–404.
Lagae, Wim (2015), Peculiarities of Sponsorship in Professional Road Cycling, in Daam
Van Reeth and Daniel Larson eds. The Economics of Professional Road Cycling
(Springer: New York), 83–98.
McGann, Carol and Bill McGann (2006), The Story of the Tour de France Vol. 1 (Dog Ear
Publishing: Indianapolis, IN).
McGann, Carol and Bill McGann (2008), The Story of the Tour de France Vol. 2 (Dog Ear
Publishing: Indianapolis, IN).
McKay, F. (2011a), The Man Who Sold the Tour, in Cyclismas. Available at
http://www.cyclismas.com/biscuits/the-man-who-sold-the-tou/ (accessed 1
November 2015).
McKay, F. (2011b), The Shadow of the Tour: The Post-Tour Critérium Circuit, in Podium
Cafe. Available at http://www.podiumcafe.com/2011/8/16/2365901/the-shadowof-the-tour-the-post-tour-criterium-circuit (accessed 1 November 2015).
Mignot, Jean-François (2014), Histoire du Tour de France (La Découverte: Paris).
Mignot, Jean-François (2015), The History of Professional Road Cycling, in Daam Van
Reeth and Daniel Larson eds. The Economics of Professional Road Cycling (Springer:
New York), 7–31.
Prinz, Joachim and Pamela, Wicker (2012), Team and Individual Performance in the
Tour de France, Team Performance Management 18, 418–432.
18
Reed, Eric (2003), The Economics of the Tour, 1930–2003, in Hugh Dauncey and Geoff
Hare eds. The Tour de France, 1903–2003. A Century of Sporting Structures, Meanings
and Values (Frank Cass: London), 103–127.
Reed, Eric (2015), Selling the Yellow Jersey. The Tour de France in the Global Era
(University of Chicago Press: Chicago, IL).
Rogge, Nicky, Daam Van Reeth and Tom Van Puyenbroeck (2013), Performance
Evaluation of Tour de France Cycling Teams Using Data Envelopment Analysis,
International Journal of Sport Finance 8, 236–257.
Rosen, Sherwin (1981), The Economics of Superstars, American Economic Review 71(5),
845–858.
Thompson, Christopher (2006), The Tour de France: A Cultural History (University of
California Press: Berkeley, CA).
Torgler, Benno (2007), "La Grande Boucle." Determinants of Success at the Tour de
France, Journal of Sports Economics 8(3), 317–331.
Tullock, Gordon (1980), Efficient Rent Seeking, in James Buchanan, Robert Tollison and
Gordon Tullock eds. Toward a Theory of Rent Seeking Society (Texas A&M University
Press: College Station, TX), 97–112.
U.S. Anti-Doping Agency (2012), Report on Proceedings Under the World Anti-Doping
Code and the USADA Protocol. United States Anti-Doping Agency, Claimant, v. Lance
Armstrong, Respondent. Reasoned Decision of the United States Anti-Doping Agency
on Disqualification and Ineligibility. Available at
https://d3epuodzu3wuis.cloudfront.net/ReasonedDecision.pdf (accessed 1
November 2015).
19
Vandeweghe, Hans (2015), Doping in Cycling: Past and Present, in Daam Van Reeth and
Daniel Larson eds. The Economics of Professional Road Cycling (Springer: New York),
285–311.
Van Reeth, Daam (2015a), The Finances of Professional Cycling Teams, in Daam Van
Reeth and Daniel Larson eds. The Economics of Professional Road Cycling (Springer:
New York), 55–82.
Van Reeth, Daam (2015b), TV Viewing of Road Cycling Races, in Daam Van Reeth and
Daniel Larson eds. The Economics of Professional Road Cycling (Springer: New York),
99–128.
Van Reeth, Daam (2015c), Globalization in Professional Road Cycling, in Daam Van
Reeth and Daniel Larson eds. The Economics of Professional Road Cycling (Springer:
New York), 165–205.
Van Reeth, Daam and Wim Lagae (2015), The Future of Professional Road Cycling, in
Daam Van Reeth and Daniel Larson eds. The Economics of Professional Road Cycling
(Springer: New York), 313–341.
Vigarello, Georges (1997), The Tour de France, in Pierre Nora and Lawrence Kritzman
eds. Realms of Memory: The Construction of the French Past, Vol. 2: Traditions
(Columbia University Press: New York), 469–500.
Viollet, Sandrine (2007), Le Tour de France Cycliste, 1903–2005 (L’(armattan: Paris).
Woodland, Les (2003), The Crooked Path to Victory: Drugs and Cheating in Professional
Bicycle Racing (Cycle Publishing: San Francisco, CA).
20