www.giga-hamburg.de/workingpapers
October 2016
No 293
Luis Leandro Schenoni
Regional Power Transitions:
Lessons from the Southern Cone
___________________________
GIGA Research Programme:
Power and Ideas
GIGA Working Papers serve to disseminate the research results of work in progress prior to publicaton to encourage the exchange of ideas and academic debate.
Inclusion of a paper in the Working Papers series does not constitute publication and should not limit publication in any other venue. Copyright remains with the authors.
GIGA Working Papers
293/2016
Edited by the
GIGA German Institute of Global and Area Studies
Leibniz-Institut für Globale und Regionale Studien
The GIGA Working Papers series serves to disseminate the research results of work in
progress prior to publication in order to encourage the exchange of ideas and academic
debate. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. Inclusion of a paper in the GIGA Working Papers series
does not constitute publication and should not limit publication in any other venue. Copyright remains with the authors.
GIGA Research Programme “Power and Ideas”
Copyright for this issue: © Luis Leandro Schenoni
WP Coordination and English-language Copyediting: Melissa Nelson
Editorial Assistance and Production: Silvia Bücke
All GIGA Working Papers are available online and free of charge on the website
<www.giga-hamburg.de/workingpapers>.
For any requests please contact: <workingpapers@giga-hamburg.de>
The GIGA German Institute of Global and Area Studies cannot be held responsible for
errors or any consequences arising from the use of information contained in this Working
Paper; the views and opinions expressed are solely those of the author or authors and do
not necessarily reflect those of the Institute.
GIGA German Institute of Global and Area Studies
Leibniz-Institut für Globale und Regionale Studien
Neuer Jungfernstieg 21
20354 Hamburg
Germany
<info@giga-hamburg.de>
<www.giga-hamburg.de>
GIGA Working Papers
293/2016
Regional Power Transitions:
Lessons from the Southern Cone
Abstract
Approximately four decades ago, the Southern Cone witnessed the beginning of a transition from a bipolar balance of power between Argentina and Brazil to unipolarity under
Brazilian primacy. While such processes are expected to generate conflict, this particular
transition was cooperative, leaving an interesting IR puzzle unresolved: Why did Argentina stop counterbalancing Brazil and opt for accommodation instead? Building on power
transition theory, I use process tracing to show that key cooperative turns in this bilateral
relationship – during the late 1970s and early 1990s – were possible only after social coalitions were redefined in Argentina. My conclusions suggest that cooperation between Argentina and Brazil was not a product of democracy but rather a consequence of structural
changes, at both the international and the domestic level.
Keywords: Brazil, Argentina, Southern Cone, power transition
Luis Leandro Schenoni
is a PhD student in political science (international relations) at the University of Notre
Dame. He was a visiting research fellow at the GIGA in 2014 and 2015 and is now a fellow
at the Kellogg Institute for International Studies.
<lschenon@nd.edu>
293/2016
GIGA Working Papers
Regional Power Transitions:
Lessons from the Southern Cone
Luis Leandro Schenoni
Article Outline
1 Introduction
2 A Deductive Approach to Peaceful Power Transitions
3 In the Midst of the Transition: No Longer Balance but Not Yet Hegemony
4 From Conflict to Cooperation: The Late 1970s
5 The Consolidation of Brazilian Primacy: The Early 1990s
6 A Process-Tracing Analysis of Alternative Hypotheses
7 Conclusion
Bibliography
Databases
1 Introduction
The structure of international politics in the Southern Cone has changed considerably over
time.1 While today’s scenario is one of Brazilian unipolarity, four decades ago the region exhibited a two-centuries-old bipolarity between Argentina and Brazil (Martín 2006; Lima 2013;
Schenoni 2015; Flemes and Wehner 2015). Although regional power transitions are expected
to result in conflict (Lemke 2002; cf. Waltz 1979; Organski and Kugler 1980; Gilpin 1981), during Brazil’s shift to a position of regional primacy Argentina gave up competition, agreeing
1
The final version of this paper is forthcoming with Foreign Policy Analysis. An earlier version was presented at
workshops at Sciences Po, Paris, on 24 April 2014, and the German Institute for Global and Area Studies,
Hamburg, on 23 March 2015. The author would like to thank Jorge Battaglino, Olivier Dabène, Michael Desch,
Andrés Malamud, Detlef Nolte, and Sebastian Rosato, for their insightful comments at different stages of this
research.
GIGA Working Papers
293/2016
5
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
to a series of compromises regarding nuclear capabilities, defence technology, and trade. The
result was highly unusual: an increase in bilateral cooperation in the midst of a power transition. Given that IR alchemists concerned with the rise of China are seeking the formula for
peaceful power transitions as the philosopher’s stone of our age, this result is what renders
this case interesting.
What allowed for the peaceful Brazilian rise in the Southern Cone? Building on previous
IR literature on Argentina–Brazil cooperation (see Resende-Santos 2002; Malamud 2005;
Oelsner 2005; Darnton 2012; Gómez-Mera 2013), I tackle this question by considering the
domestic variables that deterred Argentina from prolonging competition in the economic,
nuclear, and military realms; discouraged it from forming alliances with third countries; and
dissuaded it from going to war with Brazil. This strategy of accommodation,2 I will argue,
was evident in two critical junctures – the resolution of the Itaipú dispute (1977–1980) and
the creation of Mercosur (1990–1994) – during which Argentine presidents successfully dismantled pro-conflict coalitions in the domestic realm. Following these critical junctures, a
cooperative relationship that has lasted until today was cemented.
Although this paper may be framed within neoclassical realism (Rose 1998),3 it differs
from this research programme in two important respects. On the methodological side, neoclassical realist analyses have worked on hypotheses derived inductively from particular
case studies, leading to explanations that fit those cases but are difficult to generalise (Geddes
1990). On the theoretical side, neoclassical realism claims that accommodation is an anomaly
and that the balance of power will always be restored (Legro and Moravcsik 1999), which is
implausible in the case of the power gap that separates Brazil and Argentina today. I address
these shortcomings in Section 2 by proposing a deductive approach to identifying those variables that explain accommodation. I argue that we can deduce from theories of power distribution4 that a change in social coalitions is a necessary condition for a peaceful power transition.
In Section 3, I analyse Argentine–Brazilian relations in relation to power transition theory
as a passage from a bipolar balance of power to Brazilian unipolarity. In sections 4 and 5, I
examine the two critical junctures where Argentina drastically revised its foreign policy
strategy toward Brazil: the resolution of the Itaipú crisis (1977–1980) and the establishment of
2
I would like to thank Michael Desch for proposing the use of this concept. In previous drafts and in other articles I have used the term underbalancing instead of accommodation to highlight the incentives to restore the
previous balance that Argentina had in a scenario of early regional unipolarity (Schweller 2006). However,
underbalance was so protracted in this particular case that the idea of accommodation more accurately captures the long-term nature of the Argentine response to the Brazilian rise.
3
Arguably the main research programme concerned with the causes of underbalancing in unipolar contexts (cf.
Wohlforth 1999; Schweller 2006) and how domestic variables may intercede to prevent foreign policy outcomes induced by the international structure.
4
I will use the phrase “theories of power distribution” to refer to those realist theories that predict conflict or cooperation based fundamentally on power distribution. In principle, this is the case for balance of power theory
(Waltz 1979), hegemonic stability theory (Gilpin 1981), and power transition theory (Organzki and Kugler 1980).
293/2016
GIGA Working Papers
6
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
the Southern Common Market, hereafter Mercosur – (1990–1994). In Section 6 the aforementioned hypothesis and other possible explanations for the Argentine accommodation at these
critical junctures are compared with historical evidence using process tracing (Mahoney
2012; Beach and Pedersen 2013). The conclusions close the paper.
2 A Deductive Approach to Peaceful Power Transitions
Prominent realist theories based on power distribution would have predicted intense competition between Argentina and Brazil in the 1970s (cf. Mello 1996). On the one hand, balance of
power theory (Waltz 1979) expects subsystems to be stable when two or more powers balance each other and would have predicted conflict following the rise of a single major regional power such as Brazil. On the other hand, hegemonic stability theory (Gilpin 1981) and
power transition theory (Organski 1958; Organski and Kugler 1980) expect subsystems to be
stable when a single power bears uncontested primacy and would have predicted that power
parity – what Argentina and Brazil experienced in the 1970s – would cause conflict. From
both points of view, the distribution of regional power should have led to a conflictive outcome, something that never happened.5
Since Argentina and Brazil had started to cooperate intensely by the late 1970s, most
scholars have addressed this puzzle by simply abandoning the realist frame and searching
for alternative explanations. I argue in this section that the answer lies in the assumptions of
these power distribution theories. Those who expected the rise of Brazil to disturb the regional balance and produce conflict6 assumed that domestic actors who had vested interests
in the bilateral competition – industrialists, the military, and the state bureaucracy – would
continue to be as powerful in Argentina as they were in Brazil. Conversely, those who ex-
5
It has been argued that these theories have not been developed to explain regional subsystems. However, important efforts have been made to show that power transition theory should and can explain regional outcomes (Lemke 2002). Prominent theorists have called for these theories to be tested at the subsystemic level.
After acknowledging that “A general theory of international politics is necessarily based on the great powers,”
Waltz immediately continues by saying that “The theory once written also applies to lesser states that interact
insofar as their interaction is insulated from the intervention of the great powers of a system” (Waltz 1979: 73).
The Southern Cone was a case of such insulation. The effects of great power politics on Argentine and Brazilian foreign policy were relatively constant during the late 1970s and early 1990s. Both countries were constantly
under US hegemony. Systemic incentives show little country specific variation – that is, the way the international system influenced Brazil was relatively similar to the way it influenced Argentina. Moreover, the Argentina–Brazil interaction was rarely affected by the direct intervention of a great power that may have inclined the playing field in favour of one or the other.
6
For Waltzian realists, stability depends on the maintenance of relative parity, which is characterised by (i) uncertainty about the results of an eventual war, (ii) self-reliance in the control of resources, capital and markets,
(iii) little differentiation in the production of value-added goods, and (iv) scarce development of international
regimes (cf. Waltz 1979; Grieco 1993).
GIGA Working Papers
293/2016
7
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
pected stability – rather than conflict – under the scenario of Brazilian primacy7 assumed
changes in coalitional patterns to be a given.8 In other words, these theories seem contradictory because they make different assumptions about domestic coalitions. The main theoretical insight of this paper is to treat these coalitions as a variable.
Balance of power theory postulates that the two leading states in a bipolar structure are
always functionally equivalent and that “competitors become like one another as their competition continues” (Waltz 1979: 173). This implies not only a mirrored display of strategies
but also a similar configuration of domestic actors – such as the state bureaucracy, the local
bourgeoisie, and the military. These influence the decision-making process in similar ways,
leading to analogous foreign policy outcomes. Conversely, in hegemonic stability and power
transition theories, states involved in hegemonic relations are supposed to be very different
with regard to their roles (Butt 2013: 579). To comply with its distinctive functions – that is,
provide public goods to the system – the hegemon exhibits a far more competitive local
bourgeoisie, a more active state bureaucracy, and a more capable military (Wallernstein 1974;
Rogowski 1989). While a coalition of these actors is always at the core of the hegemon’s decision-making process, in subordinate states these actors are typically absent.9
Table 1 summarises the set of assumptions that need to be true for the predictions of theories based on power distribution to be true as well. The grey areas are of special interest for my
argument. In a system of small power differentials, balance is based on the countries having
similar social coalitions. Conversely, for a system of large power differentials to be stable, only
7
More specifically, for Gilpin and Organski, systems are likely to be stable when a single hegemon (i) has
enough military power to systematically defeat any potential contester, (ii) controls the access to raw materials, natural resources, capital, and markets, (iii) has competitive advantages in the production of value-added
goods, and (iv) generates accepted international regimes reflecting the status quo (cf. Gilpin 1981; Keohane
1984; Kindleberger 1973; Krasner 1976).
8
In this sense, this article intends to bridge Waltzian and Gilpinian traditions (Wohlforth 2011). These two theoretical branches of realism developed separately, but many IR theorists implicitly accept that hegemonic or
“suzerain” systems interact with balance of power systems (cf. Wright 1948). Robert Keohane (1984) argued
for a peaceful transition from American hegemony towards a multipolar world, and, more recently, John
Ikenberry (2011) has applied the same logic to the relations between China and the United States. Regional hierarchies can also coexist with international balances. John Mearsheimer (2001) conceives of the existence of an
American regional hegemony in the Western Hemisphere compatible with offshore balancing behaviour. But
in such a world of “multiple hierarchies” (Lemke 2002), both approaches would have predicted conflict in the
case of the power transition between Argentina and Brazil, somewhere between the 1950s and the 1990s.
9
With regard to the Southern Cone, social scientists have long argued that the differences in social coalitions
are a central feature of hegemonic systems. Dependency theory has stressed that “the overcoming of the centreperiphery structure requires a programme of import substitution industrialisation (ISI) and the active participation of the state in the promotion of industrial development” (Briceño Ruiz 2012: 196), which is another way
of saying that the coalition of a competitive local bourgeoisie and a capable state bureaucracy is usually limited to the hegemon. For such scholars, the formation of this coalition – sometimes called a developmentalist
coalition – has been considered a key objective for attaining some autonomy in international relations (cf.
Jaguaribe 1985; Puig 1980).
293/2016
GIGA Working Papers
8
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
the hegemon should present a coalition of the local bourgeoisie, the state bureaucracy, and the
military. In other words, large power differentials are based on differences in social coalitions.10
Table 1. Assumptions and Expectations of Power Distribution Theories
HEGEMONIC STABILITY
BALANCE OF POWER STABILITY
CAPABILITY DISTRIBUTION
Large power differential
Small power differential
SYSTEMIC ASSUMPTIONS
The hegemon has enough military power to
systematically defeat any potential contester.
The hegemon controls access to raw materials,
resources, capital, and markets.
The hegemon has competitive advantages in the
production of value-added goods and services.
The hegemon builds legitimacy through international
regimes that reflect its primacy.
Relative military parity and uncertainty about the results
of an eventual war
Self-reliance in the control of resources, capital, and markets
Little differentiation in the production of value-added
goods and services
International regimes including the poles are weak and
limited.
BEHAVIOURAL ASSUMPTIONS
Functional differentiation
Functional equivalence
DOMESTIC ASSUMPTIONS
Only the hegemon has a competitive and outwardsoriented local bourgeoisie.
Only the hegemon has a capable outwards-oriented
state bureaucracy.
Relative equivalence with respect to the competitiveness
of the local bourgeoisie
Relative equivalence in the capabilities and tasks of the
state bureaucracy
Only the hegemon has a professionalised outwardsoriented military.
Coalitional difference
Relative equivalence with regard to the professionalisation
and capabilities of the military
Coalitional similitude
PREDICTION
Hierarchies are more stable and parities increase the
probability of war.
Balances are more stable and imbalances increase the
probability of war.
My argument is based on two simple propositions: First, stability
event that the power differential is low
tion that we call balance
the power differential is high
call hegemony
⟹
⟹
can be attained in the
and there is coalitional similitude
. Second, stability
, a situa-
can be attained in the event that
and there is coalitional difference
, a situation that we
. In accordance with modus tollens, we know that conflict
must be the product of two possible configurations:
⟹
a large
10 Some examples can illustrate how the stability of these two ideal types depends on these assumptions holding. If among two countries in a hegemonic system the behaviour of the subordinate one violates these assumptions – e.g. trying to produce value-added goods that compete with the hegemon’s, developing military
capabilities that threaten the hegemon, etc. – it would be reasonable to expect conflict, even in the presence of
a large power differential. The other way around, an imbalance may not be conflictive from a Waltzian perspective if increasing power differentials are accompanied by a change in other systemic or domestic assumptions of the theory. For instance, neorealists have proposed that increasing power differentials do not lead to
conflict in countries that do not behave as if the difference existed (cf. Walt 1987). Similarly, imbalances could
happen peacefully if the local bourgeoisie, the state bureaucracy, and the military are relatively weakened in
the declining state as the power differential increases.
GIGA Working Papers
293/2016
9
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
power differential with coalitional similitude or a small power differential with coalitional
differentiation. Therefore, the absence of conflict in a context of changing power distribution
must be accompanied by a change in social coalitions.11 Ergo, the change from a small to a
large power differential has to be accompanied by a change from similar to different coalitional patterns among countries.
Deductive logic leads to my central hypothesis: When the local bourgeoisie, the state bureaucracy, and the military in the declining country – Argentina – are weakened, the power
transition should not lead to conflict since the domestic interests affected by the rising country – Brazil – are no longer influential foreign policy decision makers. In other words, peaceful power transitions should be preceded by the disarticulation of the coalition between the
local bourgeoisie and the state bureaucracy within the declining state.
This theoretical account seems to fit not only the Southern Cone’s experience but also
other peaceful power transitions at the systemic level such as that between Great Britain and
the United States, where the dismantling of deep-rooted coalitions was of central importance
for peace (Friedberg 1988; see Snyder 1991). External shocks may play a role in inducing coalitional change – as was the case in both the UK and, as I will show, Argentina – but even if
we disregard what causes coalitional change, it nevertheless appears to be a necessary condition for a peaceful power transition.
Figure 1. Power Transition from Balance to Hegemony
11 We can infer this from what in logic is called the Destructive Dilemma:
,
litional patterns lead to conflict
tional patterns lead to conflict
⇒
⇒
. In other words, if great power differentials in contexts of similar coa⇒
and small power differentials in contexts of different coali-
⇒
, and we see no conflict
, it follows that we had similar
coalitional patterns when the power differential was small and different coalitional patterns when the power
differential was large
293/2016
.
GIGA Working Papers
10
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
The plain thin grey line divides the figure into two areas. The lower area represents the assumptions of balance of power theory, while the upper area displays the assumptions of
hegemonic stability theory. The dashed line also divides Figure 1 into two areas, which represent the probability of conflict. Each numbered circle represents an ideal type of bilateral relation: the balance of power ideal (circle 1), the hegemonic stability ideal (circle 3), the hegemonic war or “conflictive power transition” ideal (circle 4), and, finally, the accommodation
or “cooperative power transition” ideal (circle 2).12 The latter is possible when social coalitions are restructured before changes in relative power lead to conflict. In the following sections the power transition that took place between Argentina and Brazil is analysed through
these lenses.
3 In the Midst of the Transition: No Longer Balance but Not Yet Hegemony
Thirty years ago, when the Latin American subsystem became unipolar, the rivalry between
Argentina and Brazil involved much more than football (Martín 2006; Lima 2013; Schenoni
2015; Flemes and Wehner 2015). Most historical analyses of Argentina–Brazil bilateral relations consider GDP to be the main indicator that Brazilian ascendency began in the middle of
the twentieth century (Fausto and Devoto 2004; Rapoport and Madrid 2011), following at
least 50 years of Argentine economic primacy in the Southern Cone.13
12 Circle 1 represents the ideal of bilateral balance. The two countries are very similar in terms of their domestic
coalitions and they are not very different in terms of their national capabilities. However, an increase in domestic capabilities by either of them would rapidly lead to the dotted line, and therefore to conflict. Here, both
actors have incentives to balance.
In contrast, circle 3 represents the ideal of bilateral hegemony – e.g. of ‘B’ over ‘A’ – where the two countries
are different in terms of their domestic coalitions (‘B’ has a much stronger state and national industrial bourgeoisie) and the hegemon exhibits a much higher CINC, accounting for its systemic pre-eminence. Here, incentives exist for ‘A’ to bandwagon.
Circle 4 represents a situation where two states, being very similar in their domestic coalitions, exhibit a considerable difference in systemic power and thus go to war – the Waltzian conflict hypothesis – or, on the contrary, being distant in terms of power relations suddenly exhibit competing coalitions that, in time, may defy
hegemonic stability – the Gilpinian conflict hypothesis, also shared by power transition theory.
Finally, circle 2 represents an interesting case, not purely understandable using these theories. It is the ideal of
a transitional bilateral relation, going from balance to hegemony or vice versa. In this case, there are no clear
incentives to balance or bandwagon, because the domestic coalitions are already very different before great
disparities in power capabilities arise. It is in this situation where underbalancing – or peaceful power transitions – may take place. In the next section it will be argued that Argentina–Brazil bilateral relations resembled
this ideal type for more than 30 years.
13 Even if Brazil is almost three times greater than its southern neighbour in size, with 8,514,215 km² to 2,791,810
km², and has always been more populous – the relation was already 2.8 to 1 in the 1950s and is now 4.9 to 1 –
its pre-eminence was not that obvious considering the productivity of its territory and population. In 1951
Brazil’s GDP was equivalent to that of Argentina. However, many indicators continued to relativise the case
for Brazilian ascendancy. Argentina’s GDP per capita was more than double that of its neighbour by the 1950s
GIGA Working Papers
293/2016
11
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
The Composite Index of National Capabilities (Singer et al. 1972)14 suggests that Brazil
started its rise in the 1950s and had triple Argentina’s power by the 1980s, thus making the
South American subsystem unipolar (Schweller 2004; Martin 2006).
Figure 2. Argentinean and Brazilian National Capabilities, 1900–2007
30
25
20
15
Argentina
Brazil
10
5
1900
1905
1910
1915
1920
1925
1930
1935
1940
1945
1950
1955
1960
1965
1970
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
0
Source: CINC 2015 (Singer et al. 1972).
The existence of a subjective balance can also be identified in the behaviour of relevant political actors on both sides of the border.15 Confrontational behaviour and discourse reached a
climax during the 1970s. By then, many Argentine businessmen, bureaucrats, and military
elites – who used to think of Brazil as an underdeveloped American satellite in the region –
were seriously concerned about the geopolitical ambitions of Argentina’s rising neighbour
(Moniz Bandeira 2011: 124-126).16
– it is still 1.5 times higher. This was also the case for development indicators such as life expectancy or literacy (UNDP 2015), and for infrastructure indicators such as railroad mileage, highways, telephones and commercial vehicles per capita (Banks and Wilson 2015). Although the gap has decreased in many of these areas,
particularly human development indicators, the differences continue to demonstrate Argentine pre-eminence.
14 The CINC is based on six indicators of international power which are considered relevant for a neorealist definition of the concept: energy consumption, iron and steel production, military expenditure, military personnel, total population, and urban population.
15 This history of rivalry is so internalised that, even in the twenty-first century, many actors in both countries
still interpret the bilateral relationship in the terms of the historical balance of power (Russell and Tokatlian
2003).
16 A paradigmatic case is that of Mário Travassos, a leading geopolitical analyst whose book Projeção Continental
do Brasil (Travassos 1935) unequivocally articulated how Brazil’s long-term strategic interests in South Ameri293/2016
GIGA Working Papers
12
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
In fact, it was during these years that the increase in Brazil’s energy consumption, triggered by a long period of impressive economic growth known as “the Brazilian miracle”
(1968–1973), led to the construction of the Itaipú hydroelectric dam near the Argentine border. The project was interpreted by Argentina as affecting its control of the Paraná River flow
and its strategic position in an eventual conflict. Between 1974 and 1979 – and for the first
time in more than a century – the military resolution of the dispute became a possible scenario
for both countries (Moniz Bandeira 2004: 385), thereby constituting a clear example of the
tensions expected when power transitions take place. However, against all odds, Argentine
foreign policy towards Brazil changed radically during the late 1970s – and then again in the
early 1990s – thus ultimately allowing the Southern Cone to transition smoothly to unipolarity.
However, the fact that Brazil accumulated more than three times Argentina’s power did
not make it hegemonic in the commercial, financial, productive, military, or ideological
realms (see Wilkinson 1999). This point is important, since some scholars have referred to
Brazil in these terms (Lima 1990; Burges 2008).17 First, Brazil is not yet a hegemon in military
terms. Even though Brazilian military expenditures are six times those of Argentina (SIPRI
2014), Brazil has a larger payroll of military personnel, roughly four times the Argentine
troops, just 2.3 times its combat planes, two times its tanks, and only 1.5 times its battle ships
(The Military Balance 2015). In this situation, potential regional alliances and technological
parity make it difficult to guess the result of a hypothetical conflict.
Second, Brazilian hegemony would imply preferential access to the Argentine market
and considerable competitive advantages. Mercosur – the only institution intended to restrict
third-party access to the Argentine market – has an average common external tariff of 13 per
cent, which is too low to discourage third-party imports (Porta 2008). Since the inception of
this imperfect customs union, Argentina has never imported more than 31 per cent of total
imports from nor exported more than 25 per cent of its total exports to Brazil (CEPAL 2015;
SECEX 2015; MECON 2015).18
Third, Brazil cannot be hegemonic in the financial realm until the real becomes an important reserve or trade currency or Brazil becomes the primary debt holder and source of
ca clashed with Argentina’s in the Plata Basin (Colacrai 2002). Another work that intensified the Argentine
concern with Brazilian ambitions was Golbery do Couto e Silva’s Geopolítica do Brasil (Couto e Silva 1966).
17 Hegemony is a systemic concept. Therefore, it may be confusing to talk about “bilateral hegemony.” In a strict
sense, Brazil can only be hegemonic with regard to a region and not with regard to just one neighbour. However, as we know that Argentina has historically been the second-largest country in the region, it is assumed
that if Brazil is not hegemonic in relation to Argentina, then it is not a regional hegemon and vice versa. Additionally, it should be noted that this article does not interpret hegemony in a Gramscian sense (cf. Cox 1983) as
Sean Burges does.
18 Despite the fact that it did not provide control over the Argentinean market, it must be said that Mercosur set
the conditions for a relatively more developed value-added production in Brazil (Crespo Armengol 2004: 134138) – even if this was far from the hegemonic ideal type. However, the peso devaluation of 2002, Mercosur’s
stagnation (Malamud 2012), and Brazil’s “re-primarisation” have been preventing the continuation of that
trend for years now.
GIGA Working Papers
293/2016
13
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
FDI for Argentina. Although it is true that Brazilian FDI in Argentina has increased substantially since the 2001 crisis, it is still exceeded by American, European, and Chilean FDI
(MECON 2015).19
Fourth, if Brazil was a hegemon, this should be reflected in international regimes – that
is, sets of rules governing specific issue areas – reflecting that primacy. The regimes in the
Southern Cone are far from reflecting the preferences of Itamaraty. Sometimes they are even
meant to contain Brazil.20
To summarise, Brazil cannot yet be said to be a hegemon (Schenoni 2015) in the way the
United States is in the Americas, even though it had achieved unipolar primacy in the Southern
Cone by the 1980s and its relative power has been continuously increasing since then.21
4 From Conflict to Cooperation: The Late 1970s
Transitions from authoritarian rule beginning in the 1980s encouraged an extended democratic peace hypothesis, which suggests that regime change nullified the effect of balance of
power competition between Argentina and Brazil. Other liberal approaches hold that new
international regimes and an increase in commercial exchange in the 1980s further affected
cost-benefit assessments, making balance of power too expensive. In fact, it is a combination
19 Brazil has become the only South American country that invests more than it receives from abroad – six times
the Argentine FDI (Schenoni 2015) – but in the economic realm Argentina–Brazil relations do not follow the
hegemonic paradigm. Instead, they show some asymmetries regarding size, market share, specialisation pattern, and regulations (Bouzas and Kosacoff 2010).
20 International organisations such as the Alianza Bolivariana para las Américas (ALBA), the Comunidad Andina
de Naciones (CAN), or the recent Alianza del Pacífico exclude Brazil (Flemes and Wehner 2015). Others, such
as the Organization of American States (OAS) or the Asociación Latinoamericana de Integración (ALADI) are
a remnant from a time when Brazil did not bear South American primacy and therefore do not reflect its strategic interests (Nolte et al. 2013). But even some institutions which were actively promoted by Itamaraty and
could be said to reflect Brazilian strategic conceptions – such as Mercosur, the Comunidad de Estados de
América Latina y el Caribe (CELAC), or the Unión Sudamericana de Naciones (UNASUR) – do not reflect Brazilian primacy in their design. The decision-making procedures in some of these institutions could have reflected the difference in size between Brazil and its neighbours, as is the case within in the Council of the European Union, with the quota system in the IMF, or with the veto power in the UN Security Council. Nonetheless, the institutions in the Southern Cone are all based on a strict “one country, one vote” principle, which allows for regional contestation by second-tier states (Nolte and Wehner 2014).
21 Last but not least, Brazil is not a hegemon because of the United States’ weight in the Western Hemisphere. In
almost every aforementioned dimension, the distance between the United States and Brazil is greater than the
distance between Brazil and Argentina. This affects our subsystemic analysis in two ways. Firstly, it shows
that, beyond the logic of their bilateral relations, Argentina and Brazil are further constrained by their relationship with the United States. Secondly, it opens up the possibility of forming an alliance with the United
States against any rising country that would threaten regional stability (Huntington 1999). Although these effects do not affect this article’s conclusions, they must be taken into account to further relativise the idea of
Brazilian hegemony in South America at the current time.
293/2016
GIGA Working Papers
14
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
of these explanations that constitutes the official history of the “friendship” between Argentina and Brazil (cf. Oelsner 2005; Rapoport and Madrid 2011).22
However, a process-tracing approach to this matter asks us to identify the precise moment when the cooperative turn took place and to analyse the contextual conditions and
immediate causes of this particular change in bilateral relations (Mahoney 2012; Beach and
Pedersen 2013). In this sense, it is indisputable that an initial critical juncture – that is, an initial radical change in the two countries’ foreign policy behaviour toward each other – had already taken place under authoritarian rule. “The mid-1980s agreements, significant as they
were, did not begin cooperation de novo. While a new set of factors prompted both sides in
the mid-1980s to erect more elaborate, deeper structures, institutionalized cooperation was
built on the foundations established in 1979–80” (Resende-Santos 2002: 89; cf. Solingen 1994;
Darnton 2012).
The end of the Itaipú crisis was closely followed by a series of treaties that consolidated a
friendly relationship between both countries long before the democratic transitions. From
1977 to 1978, five meetings between the foreign ministers of Argentina, Brazil, and Paraguay
took place. These negotiations ended with the signing of the Acuerdo Multilateral de Corpus-Itaipú, also known as the Tripartite Agreement, which formally settled the dispute on
17 October 1979. In 1980, de facto presidents Figueiredo and Videla visited each other. These
meetings ended in 11 protocols regarding mutual cooperation in the development of missile,
aeronautic, and nuclear technology. Although no agreements were made on other issues, the
talks also included commerce and cooperative defence in the South Atlantic (Escudé and
Cisneros 2000). Considering the broad range of issues discussed during these meetings and
the level of compromise reached, it is obvious that the advances made between 1977 and
1980 constituted the most important critical juncture in the bilateral relationship. The democratisation of Argentina (1983) and Brazil (1985) were significantly less meaningful events. In
the words of a prominent authority, “the initial rapprochement occurred much earlier, under
the military regimes in 1979–1980” (Darnton 2012: 120).
What changed between 1977 and 1980, then, that allowed for a cooperative turn in Argentina–Brazil relations? The answer appears to be both systemic and domestic. On the one
hand, Buenos Aires had to face international pressure on a second front starting in 1977, after
a court of arbitration granted disputed territory near the Beagle Channel to Chile, putting
both countries on the verge of war (Garrett 1985). On the other hand, a radical coalitional
22 Democratic transitions did bring a series of compromises. In 1985, José Sarney became president of Brazil –
Argentina had already achieved democracy in 1983 – and met Alfonsín in Foz de Iguazú. They discussed security in the South Atlantic, giving support to the Contadora Group, which was managing the Central American conflict at the time, and even signed the Iguazú Declaration on Nuclear Policies, fostering scientific and
military cooperation. More importantly, one year later, Argentina and Brazil signed the Programa de Integración y Cooperación Económica (PICE), often considered the first step toward Mercosur and the moment
Argentina and Brazil decided to undertake serious economic commitments toward each other on a long-term
basis. However, democratisation does not explain the turn to cooperative behavior.
GIGA Working Papers
293/2016
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
15
change took place in Argentina, sidelining economic and political actors who had previously
impeded cooperation with Brazil.
During 1977 – the most violent year in terms of the state’s repression of leftist movements –
Videla initiated a market-oriented reform “in an alliance with rural sectors and financial capital” (Fausto and Devoto 2004: 387). The local industrial bourgeoisie was deeply affected, and
state capacities – along with a highly trained developmentalist bureaucracy – were severely
damaged by an overvalued currency, high interest rates, and a significant decline in public
expenditure (see Figure 3).23
Figure 3.
Public Expenditure in Argentina and Brazil
Source: Banks and Wilson (2012).
Note: In current US dollars (billion).
Although Brazil later had to undertake some liberal reforms, it did not suffer from a turn
from state interventionism to neo-liberalism, as Argentina did, but rather experienced a sequence of autonomy, control, and relative privatisation during the 1980s (Tavares de Almeida 1999). The importance Brazil gave to the national bourgeoisie and state-owned enterprises as the axis of its development strategy was still evident at the end of the decade (Barros
de Castro 1994; Peixoto 2011) and was explicitly introduced into the 1988 constitution, limiting
neo-liberal governments’ room to manoeuvre in the 1990s. This is reflected in the enduring
influence not only of the national bourgeoisie, but also of the developmentalist military and
bureaucrats.
23 This was not the result of mere neo-liberal ideas; it was the consequence of the historical competition between
the industrialist and agro-financial patrias in Argentina, each of which had always promoted different development models (O’Donnell 2004). Interestingly, only the victorious model could benefit from a more cooperative relationship with a rising Brazil and decompress bilateral tensions.
293/2016
GIGA Working Papers
16
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
The neo-liberal reforms undertaken by the military had left Argentina’s industry much
more vulnerable and its state much less capable. By the mid-1980s the state-owned enterprises’
share of Argentina’s GDP was 2.7 per cent, while in Brazil they accounted for 7.6 per cent of a
much higher GDP (Pang 2002: 133). The results for industrial protection in the two countries
are also impressive. By the winter of 1990 – one year before the signing of the Mercosur Treaty – the average import tariff in Argentina was 11.7 per cent, compared with 25.4 per cent in
Brazil. Although Brazil undertook an economic reform plan under Sarney from 1988 to 1990,
it was limited to special import arrangements and the elimination of tariff redundancy, and it
scarcely affected protection levels (Berlinski 2004). In fact, Brazil did not undergo true market
reforms until the 1990s.
The novel coalition between the military, neo-liberal technocrats, the financial and agricultural sectors, and foreign capital (cf. O’Donnell 1973) in Argentina had much to gain from
a peaceful settlement of the Itaipú crisis and the re-establishment of cooperative relations
with Brazil:
Starting from a realist assessment of the enormous power gap between Argentina and
Brazil, the president and the economic diplomacy [intergovernmental agencies of the
Ministry of Economy], as well as big financial and agricultural capital linked to transnational networks, coincided in favouring subregional cooperation and extended markets instead of old-fashioned conflict hypotheses […], [whereas] nationalist and developmentalist sectors on the Argentine and Brazilian sides had their reservations about it
[the Tripartite Agreement]. On the Argentine side, led by General Juan Gugliamelli, it
was argued that these developments turned Argentina into a “minor partner” of Brazil,
a country that would reach the status of a great power in the Plata Basin by the year 2000.
For Gugliamelli, this result was inevitable if Matínez de Hoz’s liberal economic policies
were to continue, given the existing gap between the Brazilian industrial potential and
the agro-export bias of the Argentine economy. (Escudé and Cisneros 2000: 312)24
This paragraph summarises the logic of the coalitional change that took place in Argentina,
and which made it possible for Brazil to achieve regional pre-eminence in the form of the
current unipolar order. From 1977 on, the further strengthening of this new coalition and the
concentration of foreign policymaking in hands of the Argentine military – with the diplomats and other developmentalist bureaucrats excluded (Russell 1988) – made it possible for
these two countries to maintain cooperative relations while the power gap between them increased.
Following these changes in the economic realm, the next step towards subsystemic unipolarity was the Malvinas/Falklands War in 1982.25 With the Itaipú crisis resolved, Argentina
24 Translated by the author.
25 The Malvinas/Falklands War is also an example of how Argentina–Brazil bilateral relations had improved
from 1977 to 1982. Brazil transferred small arms and several planes and even disclosed technological military
GIGA Working Papers
293/2016
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
17
had renounced its industrial primacy, but it remained a powerful military player. Therefore,
the resolution of the Brazilian conflict hypothesis could have contributed to the dynamics
that almost led to war with Chile and altered the strategic balance in the South Atlantic.
However, the Falklands/Malvinas defeat eliminated Argentina’s military competitiveness in
the Southern Cone. Successive democratic governments in Casa Rosada would continue to
downgrade defence budgets as a way to control the military.
Figure 4. Military Expenditure in Argentina and Brazil
Sources: CINC 2015 (Singer et al. 1972) and SIPRI 2015, in current US dollars (billion).
5 The Consolidation of Brazilian Primacy: The Early 1990s
After the significant turn in bilateral relations that took place from 1977 to 1980, democracy
facilitated the deepening and institutionalisation of the compromises initiated under the authoritarian regimes (Resende-Santos 2002: 89). Yet further negotiations were timid.26 If there
was a second moment when Argentina unambiguously accepted the advancement of “integration” with Brazil, it was during the presidency of Carlos Menem. On 6 July 1990, he and
improvements to Argentina during the conflict (Moniz Bandeira 2011: 223). Furthermore, Brazil denied the
use of its territory for any British operations, backed Argentina’s sovereignty claim, and represented its
neighbour in London.
26 Even the first democratic administrations, which had sought the aforementioned improvements in bilateral
relations, did not promote many compromises after the Programa de Integración y Cooperación entre la Argentina y Brasil (PICAB) was agreed in July 1986. The implementation of the programme only began in 1988,
since the further downgrading of tariffs was seen as potentially damaging for the Argentine industrial sector.
293/2016
GIGA Working Papers
18
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
Fernando Collor de Mello signed the Buenos Aires Act, which put an end to a decade of hesitant sectorial negotiations and promoted the creation of a common market.27 The Asunción
Treaty followed in March 1991, giving a name and an institutional structure to Mercosur and
establishing a schedule for progressive, linear, and automatic tariff reductions, which now
also included Paraguay and Uruguay. In 1994 the Ouro Preto Treaty further institutionalised
the free trade agreement – with the exception of some products, such as sugar and materials
for auto manufacturing – and transformed Mercosur into a customs union by establishing a
common foreign tariff. The 1990–1994 period must therefore be viewed as a moment of unusual cooperative behaviour (Onuki 2006).
The dynamics of domestic politics in Argentina during those same years support the hypothesis that changing coalitions constrained balancing behaviour. Mercosur talks were
made possible after a tremendous hyperinflation crisis that led neo-liberals back to economic
policymaking under Menem’s administration starting in July 1989. By October 1990, the Argentine state had already sold its state-owned monopolies in five sectors – highways, trains,
telephones, commercial aviation, and oil – and had announced the privatisation of water and
electricity, both of which were in the hands of the private sector by 1993 (Palermo and Novaro
1996: 171). These services went mostly to foreign investors; only steel production was sold to
Argentine investors from the company Techint.
Through a series of harsh negotiations with trade unions, Menem also managed to reduce
public employment, deregulate the labour market, and decentralise healthcare and education
(Etchemendy 2001: 681-682). The state reform was accompanied by commercial measures that
also damaged the competitiveness of the remaining industrial activities and fostered transformations that favoured the agricultural and financial sectors. Moreover, the legal establishment of a fixed parity between the peso and the US dollar – through the Convertibility Law –
prevented Argentina from devaluing its currency, further damaging the local industrial bourgeoisie. In summary, during this period “Argentina suffered one of the most comprehensive
market reforms among developing countries. In less than five years this country witnessed
the fundamental restructuring of state–society relations” (Etchemendy 2001: 675).
Brazil also had its share of neo-liberalism during the 1990s,28 but Mercosur was far from being only the project of a neo-liberal coalition, as it was in Argentina. In Brasilia, pragmatic developmentalists conceived of Mercosur as a way to protect the local bourgeoisie from the hemispheric trade policies sponsored by Washington (Onuki 2006; Saraiva 2012: 91; Poggio Teixeira
27 In fact, they changed the PICAB’s formula, which agreed to “gradually remove asymmetries,” to an ambitious
commitment to “Establish a common market between Argentina and Brazil that should be definitely confirmed by 31 December 1994” (Buenos Aires Act, Art. 1).
28 As Fabiano Santos and Maria Regina Soares de Lima put it: “During the Sarney administration, the dispute
between developmentalists and economists who were critical of the previous model of industrialization prevented major changes in the status quo. However, from the Collor administration onward, the decision to
pursue trade liberalization through more or less radical measures became a state policy” (Lima and Santos
1998: 17).
GIGA Working Papers
293/2016
19
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
2014: 113-118).29 Moreover, while the local bourgeoisie was excluded from the process of liberalisation in Argentina (Etchemendy 2001), the Brazilian state became more permeable to the
demands of Brazilian business people during the 1990s (Oliveira and Pfeifer 2006: 391). As a
result, market reforms in Brazil were better regulated, quicker, and less comprehensive.30
Furthermore, this first neo-liberal wave in Brazil ended rapidly. When Collor de Mello attempted to continue unilaterally fostering state reform and economic liberalisation through
presidential decrees – medidas provisórias – a coalition of the local bourgeoisie and the developmentalist bureaucracy, represented by established political parties, called for his impeachment. This led to Collor’s resignation in October 1992 (Skidmore 1999: 221). The political crisis froze the reforms until Fernando Henrique Cardoso, once a leftist activist and
scholar, became president in 1995. He enacted some temperate reforms during his first
term.31 In the words of a renowned Brazilian historian:
29 “[…] [while] for Argentina the strengthening of Mercosur indicated an approximation to the United States
and a possible entrance to the North American Free Trade Agreement; for Brazil – on the contrary – integration with neighbouring countries represented an opportunity to legitimate its leadership position in South
America, besides consolidating a distinct regional space, independent from the United States’ orientation”
(Onuki 2006: 307).
30 When Collor launched the National Programme for Destatisation (PND) in April 1990 – three months after
assuming the presidency – 188 federal enterprises were to be privatised. By 1992 the Brazilian PND had privatised only 18 of them, in the steel, fertilisers and petrochemicals sectors (Fausto and Devoto 2004: 488). In
these cases, the majority of shares ended up in hands of Brazilian investors or other clubes de investimento involving workers themselves (Di Tella 1995: 158).
Despite Collor’s will, privatisation had to comply with a restricted regulatory framework: “A foreign investor
was limited to 35% of the total shareholding of any public company […] The investment should remain in the
country at least six years. Another 35% of the shares were reserved for Brazilian individual investors, each investor could retain up to 5%, and finally 30% of the remaining stock should be reserved for employees of the
destatised public company. The law still reflected economic nationalism with a strong dose of xenophobia […]
Unlike Mexico or Argentina, Brazil established strict regulations on how foreign investors could participate”
(cf. Pang 2002: 135).
Additionally, major state enterprises were strengthened while purchasing smaller ones. The so-called “privatisation” process in Brazil ended with an increase in the state-owned enterprises’ share of the GDP to 8 per cent –
while it decreased to 1.3 per cent in Argentina – by 1995 (Pang 2002: 133-136).
31 Cardoso created a National Council for Destatisation, which continued to privatise the huge mining company
Vale do Rio Doce, along with trains, computer systems, banks, energy, and telecommunication companies.
This second cycle of large privatisations ended with that of Petrobras in 1997. However, destatisation was far
from the Argentine style. BNDES gave large and flexible loans to the Brazilian bourgeoisie to purchase a major
portion of the shares in almost every enterprise (Boschi 2011). In some cases, such as Petrobras, the state remained the majority shareholder.
Moreover, Cardoso could not implement many other reforms. Congress rejected tax reform, labour reform,
and social security reform (Peixoto 2011). Brazil did not tie the real to the US dollar, instead keeping a “dirty”
floating exchange rate. Brazilian integration into international markets was progressive and controlled. While
Argentina was trading 4.2 times its average of the past decade by 1995–1998, Brazil expanded its foreign trade
by only 2.5 times during those years (Petrecolla 2004: 20).
293/2016
GIGA Working Papers
20
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
Even if neo-liberalism impregnated the intelligence of the Brazilian elite in the 1990s, it
did not become the exclusive tendency in determining the international relations of
Brazil, as was the case in Argentina. Public opinion distrusted Fernando Collor’s discourse and never forgave the failure of his shock monetarism. This inspired the substitution government of Itamar Franco (1992–1994), which stopped the neo-liberal impetus
by promoting development and valorising national production. Afterward, Cardoso’s
reservations reflected the heterogeneity of Brazilian society. (Cervo 2006: 14)32
Figure 5 summarises the logic behind Argentina’s failure to balance Brazil, following the
scheme proposed in Figure 1. It shows that Brazil’s increased power capabilities made it impossible for Argentina to maintain the former coalition of local bourgeoisie and state bureaucracy without this leading to conflict. By disempowering these societal actors, Argentina secured peace through accommodation.
Figure 5. Yearly Snapshots of the Power Transition
Sources: CINC 2015 (Singer et al. 1972) and Index of Economic Freedom (Fraser Institute 2015).
Note: As in Figure 1, each circle represents the state of bilateral relations during a certain year. Capabilities distance – values in – is the difference between Argentina and Brazil in terms of their CINC; as the circles go
upward, the power differential grows bigger. Coalitional similitude – values in – is calculated as the difference in economic openness, as measured by the Fraser Institute’s Index of Economic Freedom, between
Argentina and Brazil. From 1975 to 2001 Argentina became relatively more open than Brazil, therefore pushing the circles to the left. This indicates that the developmentalist coalition was stronger in Brazil during
that period.
Finally, Brazil devalued the real in January 1999, ending a brief second cycle of reforms and seriously damaging Argentina’s trade balance.
32 Translated by the author.
GIGA Working Papers
293/2016
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
21
6 A Process‐Tracing Analysis of Alternative Hypotheses
The previous sections offered an account of the changes in bilateral relations and domestic
social coalitions that took place during the periods 1977–1980 and 1990–1994, allowing for a
peaceful power transition in the Southern Cone. However, more than one speculative explanation of these changes has been given in the past and I test all of these more thoroughly in
this section.
My main hypothesis – derived deductively from realist theory in Section 2 and offered as
an analytic narrative (cf. Bates et al. 1998) in sections 3, 4, and 5 – is that changes in coalitions
within Argentina, the weakening of the local bourgeoisie and the state bureaucracy, explain
the peaceful power transition. This hypothesis (H1) has at least two observational implications: First, if a change in social coalitions is taking place, the government has to insulate decision-making from previously influential actors. Second, once decision-making processes
are insulated, the government has to enact economic policies that overtly damage those actors.33 Therefore, H1 requires the insulation of the decision-making process – for example, the
concentration of power in the hands of Argentine president – and a subsequent change in
economic policy that supersedes previous policy frontiers – for example, neo-liberal
measures that affect the developmentalist coalition – and precedes important negotiations
and agreements.
Some competing hypotheses are laid out in the literature: “Institutional liberalism” (H2)
proposes that the establishment of international regimes precedes cooperative foreign policy
turns. “Commercial liberalism” (H3) argues that transnational economic interchange drives
cooperative behaviour. And “republican liberalism” (H4) highlights the importance of domestic regime type (cf. Keohane 1990). “Ideational liberalism” (H5) also stresses that a
change in “social values or identities” (Moravcsik 1997: 515) may explain cooperation. The
latter is also associated with constructivism (H6), which argues that changes in ideas – as evidenced in policy speeches (Onuf 2001) – are the most immediate cause of actual changes in
foreign policy. Last but not least, extra-regional factors (H7) – for example, changes in the
foreign policy of the United States, the end of the Cold War, etc. – may impact the bilateral
relationship.
33 Presented this way, H1 acknowledges the bulk of the foreign policy analysis literature on social actors. Most
of the time, “states represent some subset of domestic society, on the bases of whose interests state officials define state preferences and act purposively in world politics” (Moravcsik 1997: 518), but in certain critical junctures, the state can insulate decision-making from societal pressures, moving previously rigid “policy frontiers” (Golob 2003: 363-368) and using international agreements to restructure social coalitions (cf. Gourevitch
1978; Putnam 1988).
293/2016
GIGA Working Papers
22
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
Table 2. Process‐Tracing Analysis of Critical Junctures Leading to Cooperation
Itaipú (1977–1980)
Social coalitions (H1)
Institutions (H2)
Commerce (H3)
Democracy (H4)
Social ideas (H5)
Political discourse (H6)
Global context (H7)
Hoop
✓
Smoking gun
✓
✓
✓
✓
Mercosur (1990–1994)
Hoop
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
Smoking gun
✓
✓
Note: “Hoop” tests evaluate if the conditions were present, while “smoking-gun” tests evaluate if the condition
was evident immediately prior to cooperative turns within these critical junctures.
Table 2 summarises the results of a process-tracing analysis of these hypotheses. “Hoop
tests”34 are intended to show whether the conditions predicted by each hypothesis were present in 1977–1980 and 1990–1994, while “smoking-gun tests”35 evaluate whether such conditions were evident immediately prior to major agreements (Mahoney 2012: 576-579). The results, based on historical accounts and primary sources, support the hypothesis that changes
in coalitions (H1) – as evidenced by the concentration of power in the hands of the chief executive and radical changes in economic policy that affected developmentalist actors – were
necessary conditions for cooperation between Argentina and Brazil. They also suggest that
external shocks initiating from the systemic level (H7) helped to induce such coalitional
changes and are therefore necessary to explain the peaceful power transition. Although space
constraints permit me from going into too much detail, I will briefly describe the mechanics
and results of this process-tracing analysis.
The 1977–1980 critical juncture provides the most decisive evidence in favour of H1. Declassified documents from the Argentine Ministry of Foreign Affairs show that Ambassador
Oscar Camilión began intense negotiations with the Brazilian government in May 1977
(MRECIC 2015), precisely one month before Martínez de Hoz announced his most important
neo-liberal policy: a financial reform that liberalised interest and exchange rates, and practically eliminated all subsidies to credit. This was the most damaging policy setback that the
34 A hoop test specifically asks about the occurrence of certain conditions or mechanisms that should be present
at a precise historical moment for a hypothesis to be true. Passing the hoop test is a necessary condition for the
hypothesis to be true. In other words, if a hypothesis does not pass though the hoop, then it should be discarded. For example, the democratic peace hypothesis does not jump the hoop for 1977–1980 since both Argentina and Brazil were strong authoritarian regimes at that time.
35 A smoking-gun test does not test the mere possibility that a certain hypothesis is true as the hoop test does.
Smoking-gun tests are intended to confirm a particular hypothesis by finding very clear evidence – like a
smoking gun in the hands of a suspect – that there is a causal relation between events. One way to pass this
test is by proving temporal precedence and close temporal proximity between an alleged cause and the effect.
For example, as will be shown, the fact that the Convertibility Law was sent to Congress the same day Menem
attended the summit in Asunción that gave birth to Mercosur provides clear smoking-gun evidence in favor
of H1.
GIGA Working Papers
293/2016
23
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
Argentine industrial bourgeoisie had suffered since the 1930s (Canitrot 1980) and also
demonstrates the overwhelming power that President Videla had obtained by then.
The timing of the 1979 Tripartite Agreement also offers some smoking-gun evidence. The
day it was signed – October 19 – the Argentine National Institute of Statistics announced an
unemployment rate of 1.5 per cent, the lowest ever registered in Argentina (La Nación, October 19, 1979). The spring of 1979 represented the apex of Videla’s power. The last demonstrations against the government took place that April. Journalists, lawyers, judges, and religious
hierarchies by then all supported the “authoritarian peace” (Novaro, 2010: 173). Not even
Admiral Emilio Massera – Videla’s nemesis inside the junta during his first two years in
power – questioned the president’s authority.36 This situation allowed Videla to impose the
Tripartite Agreement on the developmentalist and nationalist opposition, sign further accords in 1980, and continue to apply neo-liberal policies until March 1981.
An analysis of the 1977–1980 juncture not only offers support for H1, but also, most remarkably, shows that all other hypotheses beside H7 have little basis. Bilateral trade (H3)
was at a historical low in 1976, with a total volume of USD 760 million, and would only increase considerably by 1980, to USD 1,847 million, probably as a consequence of the aforementioned agreements (Camilión 1987: 11). There were still almost no important bilateral institutions (H2) that could have had any agency or acted as a neutral sphere within which bilateral cooperation could be enhanced. Even Pan-American institutions were blocked due to
Washington’s stance vis-à-vis authoritarian regimes.
It would be problematic to assert that social values or ideas led to a push for cooperation
(H5) in a context where the level of radicalisation was high and nationalist sentiments were
mobilised repeatedly and consistently until after the Malvinas/Falklands War (cf. Mainwaring & Pérez-Liñán 2013). Obviously, democracy (H4) was far from a reality.
H6 and H7 are the only alternative hypotheses that pass the hoop test for the first critical
juncture. The official economic discourse in Buenos Aires had acquired a neo-liberal tone
starting in 1976, and the international environment had changed due to Carter’s human rights
policy and Argentina’s conflict with Chile. However, H7 is the only hypothesis besides H1 for
which there is smoking-gun evidence. In February 1977 Carter announced a considerable reduction of foreign aid to Argentina, and in July the EXIM bank refused an important loan,
blocking the purchase of police equipment (Selden 1999: 130). On 2 May 1977, Queen Elisabeth II also presented her arbitration favouring Chile in the Beagle Channel dispute, which
led to increased pressure on Argentina from Santiago as well. Therefore, in the first critical
36 Admiral Isaac Francisco Rojas was the only influential politician who publicly expressed his concern about the
treaty, in a letter to Videla, stating that the Tripartite Agreement had “[…] highly prejudicial connotations for
Argentina, not only political, but economic, and military […] now they [Brazil] will dominate the Parana River,
upstream and downstream Itaipú, like a lock, whose key will be in their hands […]” (La Nación, October 17,
1979).
293/2016
GIGA Working Papers
24
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
juncture, both coalitional change and a change in the global context appear to have been present and to have constituted the necessary conditions for Argentina–Brazil cooperation.
The 1990–1994 critical juncture is far more complex and confusing, since all the hypotheses pass the hoop test. However, the concentration of power with President Menem and economic reforms closely preceded changes in foreign policy, providing smoking-gun evidence
in support of H1 that is lacking for every other hypothesis – perhaps with the exception of H7.
So far, few scholars have identified power concentration in the hands of the president as
a determinant of the Act of Buenos Aires of 6 July 1990 and the Asunción Treaty of 26 March
1991 (cf. Malamud 2005). A close analysis of what happened during the winter of 1990 is
consistent with this hypothesis. Menem took office in a context of economic and social unrest
that jeopardised his presidency in 1989 (Novaro 2009: 356); it was only in April 1990 that he
managed to discipline his own party, bring about the privatisation of several state-owned enterprises, reduce public employment by 14 per cent, and apply a drastic cut of 25 per cent to
the government bureaucracy (Pucciarelli 2011: 40). These measures had restored economic
stability by July 1990 and allowed Menem to meet Collor with an approval rate of 80 per
cent, having overpowered the developmentalist veto (Clarín, July 08, 1990). The July 1990
juncture is, however, not conclusive, since the international context (H7) had also changed
dramatically as a result of President Bush’s announcement of the Enterprise for the Americas
Initiative in June of the same year (Gomez-Mera 2013).
Still, the signing of the Asunción Treaty one year later provides conclusive smoking-gun
evidence in favour of H1. Little had changed in the domestic or international contexts when
President Menem travelled to Asunción, except that it was the same day that he sent the
Convertibility Act – ostensibly the most damaging policy undertaken against Argentine industrials since Martínez de Hoz’s financial reform – to the Argentine Congress (La Nación,
March 25, 1991). The temporal coincidence in this case is stunning. We can see both the
smoke and the bullet coming out of the gun; the most important policy setback for the developmentalist coalition was sent to Congress a few hours before the most important bilateral
agreement with Brazil was signed.
Thus, in looking back at the early 1990s, it seems clear that Mercosur, the most important
bilateral cooperative initiative ever agreed between Argentina and Brazil, occurred simultaneously to coalitional change under the first Menem administration. The concomitance of
these two policies – which, amazingly, has never been highlighted before – provides conclusive smoking-gun evidence supporting H1. Therefore, to summarise, this second critical
juncture points again to H1 and H7 as the necessary conditions for Argentine–Brazilian cooperation and the occurrence of a peaceful power transition in the Southern Cone.
GIGA Working Papers
293/2016
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
25
7 Conclusion
In this article I have addressed the puzzle of peaceful power transitions and the phenomenon
of accommodation, looking for an answer both in the theory and the specific regional example
of the Southern Cone from the 1970s to the 1990s.
In Section 2, I surveyed the theories of power distribution and identified the invariable
nature of domestic coalitions as a key underlying assumption of this literature. Departing
from this finding, I demonstrated deductively that power transitions might not be conflictive
if they are accompanied by a change in the domestic social coalitions in one of the countries
involved. By following this strategy, I avoided the problems of inductive theorisation, therefore providing some grounds for generalisation and further testing.
The analytical narrative based on the case study of the Southern Cone shows that the two
critical junctures in the history of Argentina–Brazil rapprochement, 1977–1980 and 1990–
1994, coincided with coalitional changes in Argentina. This hypothesis and other alternative
explanations have been tested using process tracing to search for the contextual (hoop tests)
and simultaneous (smoking-gun tests) presence of other explanatory variables. These tests
suggest that historical accounts that highlight constructivist or liberal variables, which today
constitute the mainstream history of these two countries’ friendship, are fundamentally mistaken. Cooperative ideas, shared identities, democracy, commerce, and international institutions should be seen not as a cause but rather as epiphenomena of improving bilateral relations. Cooperation was seemingly possible only when certain domestic actors – namely, the
state bureaucracy and the local industrial bourgeoisie, and later the military – were excluded
from foreign policymaking in Argentina.
Through the process tracing, I also detected the importance of international pressures
that were not theorised but were nevertheless to be expected given the subsystemic nature of
the Argentina–Brazil dyad. The coalitional changes in Argentina and the cooperative turns in
its bilateral relationship with Brazil appear to have been contemporaneous with important
external shocks. The pressures arising from the Beagle Channel dispute with Chile and the
US human rights policy help to explain the radical changes undertaken in Argentina by 1977.
The pressure arising from Washington’s Enterprise of the Americas in 1990 also appears to
have hastened neo-liberal reform and the development of Mercosur.
These lessons from the Southern Cone are not automatically transferable to other cases of
power transition. Particularly because of its subsystemic nature, this case offers only partial
insights regarding the dilemma posed by the rise of China. In the Southern Cone, the United
States pressed for peace and market reform during the power transition, whereas there may
be no third party capable of inducing coalitional change in either China or the United States.
However, illuminating the critical role of these social coalitions during regional power transitions is a valuable first step in considering how to engineer them for the purposes of peace,
even at the systemic level.
293/2016
GIGA Working Papers
26
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
Bibliography
Amorim, Celso (2010) “A Política Externa Brasileira no governo do Presidente Lula (20032010): uma visão geral,” in: Revista Brasileira de Política Internacional, 53, 1, 214-240.
Barros de Castro, António (1994) “Renegade Development: Rise and Demise of State-led Development in Brazil,” in: Smith, William et al. (eds.) Democracy, Markets and Structural Re‐
forms in Latin America, Miami: Transaction Publishers, 183-214.
Bates, Robert; Avner Greif and Margaret Levi (1998) Analytic Narratives, New York: Princeton
University Press.
Battaglino, Jorge (2012) “Defence in a Post-Hegemonic Regional Agenda: The Case of the
South American Defence Council,” in: Riggirozzi, Pia and Diana Tussie (eds.) The Rise of
Post‐Hegemonic Regionalism. The Case of Latin America, New York: Springer, 81-100.
Battaglino, Jorge (2013) “The Politics of Defense Revival in Argentina,” in: Defense and Security
Analysis, 29, 1, 3-15.
Beach, Derek and Rasmun Pedersen (2013) Process Tracing Methods: Foundations and Guidelines,
Detroit: University of Michigan Press.
Berlinski, Julio (2004) Los impactos de la política comercial: Argentina y Brasil (1988‐1997), Buenos
Aires: Instituto Di Tella – Siglo XXI.
Boschi, Renato (2011) “State Developmentalism: Continuity and Uncertainty,” in: Font, Mauricio and Laura Randall (eds.) The Brazilian State: Debate and Agenda, New York: Lexington
Books.
Bouzas, Roberto and Bernardo Kosacoff (2010) “Cambio y continuidad en las relaciones económicas de la Argentina con Brasil,” in: Ágora Internacional, 4, 10, 31-40.
Briceño Ruiz, José (2012) “Raúl Prebisch e a contribuição latino-americana para a teoria das
relações internacionais,” in: Costa Lima, Marcos; Rafael Villa, Rossana Rocha Reis and
Marcelo de Almeida Medeiros (eds.), Teóricos das relações internacionais, São Paulo:
HUCITEC, 177-219.
Butt, Ahsan (2013) “Anarchy and Hierarchy in International Relations: Examining South
Americaʹs War-Prone Decade (1932–1941),” in: International Organization, 67, 3, 575-607.
Camilión, Oscar (1987) “Integración Argentina-Brasil, realidades y proyecciones” in: Intergra‐
ción Latinoamericana, 2, 2, 1-18.
Canitrot, Alfredo (1980) “Un ensayo sobre el programa económico del gobierno argentino
desde 1976” in: Desarrollo Económico, 16, 76, 453-475.
Cervo, Amado (2006) “Ação internacional do Brasil em um mundo em transformação: conceitos, objetivos e resultados (1990-2005),” in: Henrique Altemani and Carlos Anônio Lessa
(org.) Relações Internacionais do Brasil: Temas e Agendas, Vol. 1, São Paulo: Saraiva, 7-34.
GIGA Working Papers
293/2016
27
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
Colacrai, Miriam (1992) “Perspectivas teóricas en la bibliografía de política exterior argentina,” in: Russell, Roberto (ed.) Enfoques teóricos y metodológicos para el estudio de la política ex‐
terior, Buenos Aires: Grupo Editor Latinoamericano, 19-51.
Couto e Silva, Golbery (1967) Geopolítica do Brasil, Rio de Janeiro: Livraria José Olympio.
Cox, Robert (1983) “Gramsci, Hegemony and International Relations: An Essay in Method,”
in: Millennium, 12, 162–75.
Crespo Armengol, Eugenia (2004) “La evolución comercial y productiva del MERCOSUR: un
análisis estadístico,” in: Kosacoff, Bernardo (ed.) Evaluación del desempeño y aportes para un
rediseño del Mercosur. Una perspectiva desde los sectores productivos argentinos, Buenos Aires:
CEPAL, 131-224.
Darnton, Christopher (2012) “A False Start on the Road to MERCOSUR: Reinterpreting Rapprochement Failure between Argentina and Brazil, 1972,” in: Latin American Research Re‐
view, 47, 2, 120-141.
Di Tella, Torcuato (1995) “El sistema político brasileño en perspectiva argentina,” in: De La
Balze, Felipe (ed.) Argentina y Brasil enfrentando el siglo XXI, Buenos Aires: CARI.
Escudé, Carlos and Andrés Cisneros (2000) Historia General de las Relaciones Exteriores de la Re‐
pública Argentina, Vol. XIII, Buenos Aires: Grupo Editor Latinoamericano.
Etchemendy, Sebastián (2001) “Construir coaliciones reformistas: la política de las compensaciones en el camino argentino hacia la liberalización económica,” in: Desarrollo Económi‐
co, 40, 160, 679-696.
Fausto, Boris, and Fernando Devoto (2004) Brasil e Argentina. Um ensaio de história comparada
(1850‐2002), São Paulo: Espacio Editora 34.
Flemes, Daniel and Leslie Wehner (2015) “Drivers of Strategic Contestation: the Case of South
America,” in: International Politics, 52, 2, 163-177.
Friedberg, Aaron (1988) The Weary Titan: Britain and the Experience of Relative Decline 1895‐1905,
Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Garrett, James (1985) “The Beagle Channel Dispute: Confrontation and Negotiation in the
Southern Cone,” in: Journal of Interamerican Studies and World Affairs, 27, 3, 81-109.
Geddes, Barbara (1990) “How the Cases You Choose Affect the Answers You Get: Selection
Bias in Comparative Politics,” in: Political Analysis 2, 1, 131-150.
Gilpin, Robert (1981) War and Change in International Politics, Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
Golob, Stephanie (2003) “Beyond the Policy Frontier: Canada, Mexico and the Ideological Origins of NAFTA,” in: World Politics, 55, 3, 361-398.
Gómez-Mera, Laura (2013) Power and Regionalism in Latin America: the Politics of MERCOSUR,
South Bend: University of Notre Dame Press.
293/2016
GIGA Working Papers
28
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
Gourevitch, Peter (1978) “The Second Image Reversed: The International Sources of Domestic
Politics,” in: International Organization, 32, 4: 881-912.
Grieco, Joseph (1993) “Understanding the Problem of International Cooperation: The Limits
of Neoliberal Institutionalism and the Future of Realist Theory,” in: Baldwin, David (ed.)
Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate, New York: Columbia University
Press.
Grugel, Jean and Pia Riggirozzi (2007) “The Return of the State in Argentina,” in: International
Affairs, 83, 1, 87-107.
Guillermo O’Donnell (2004) “Estado y Alianzas en Argentina, 1956-1976,” in: Contrapuntos,
Paidós: Buenos Aires.
Huntington, Samuel (1999) “The Lonely Superpower (US Military and Cultural Hegemony
Resented by other Oowers),” in: Foreign Affairs, 78, 2, 35-49.
Ikenberry, John (2011) Liberal Leviathan: The Orgins, Crisis, and Transformation of the American
World Order, Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Jaguaribe, Hélio (1985) El nuevo escenario internacional, Autonomía periférica y hegemonía del cen‐
tro, México: Fondo de Cultura Económica.
Keohane, Robert (1984) After Hegemony, Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Kindleberger, Charles (1973) The World in Depression, 1929‐1939, Berkeley: University of California Press.
Krasner, Stephen (1976) “State Power and the Structure of International Trade,” in: World Poli‐
tics, 28, 3, 317-347.
Legro, Jeffrey and Andrew Moravcsik (1999) “Is Anybody Still a Realist?,” in: International Se‐
curity, 24, 2, 5-55.
Lemke, Douglas (2002) Regions of War and Peace, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Lima, Maria Regina Soares (2013) “Realações interamericanas: a nova agenda Sul-Americana
e o Brasil,” in: Lua Nova, 90, 167-201.
Lima, Maria Regina Soares and Fabiano Santos (1998) “Brazilian Congress and Foreign Trade
Policy,” paper presented at the Latin American Studies Association annual meeting, Chicago,
24-26 September.
Mahoney, James (2012) “The Logic of Process Tracing Tests in the Social Sciences,” in: Socio‐
logical Methods and Research, 41, 4, 570–597.
Mainwaring, Scott & Aníbal Pérez-Liñán (2013) Democracies and Dictatorships in Latin America:
Emergence, Survival, and Fall, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Malamud, Andrés (2005) “Presidential Diplomacy and the Institutional Underpinnings of
Mercosur: An Empirical Examination,” in: Latin American Research Review, 40, 1, 138-164.
GIGA Working Papers
293/2016
29
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
Malamud, Andrés (2012) “Sovereignty in Back, Integration out: Latin American Travails with
Regionalism,” in: Roy, Joaquín (ed.) The State of the Union(s): Comparative Regional Integra‐
tion and the EU Model, Miami: EU Center of Excellence, 177-190.
Malamud, Andrés and Júlio Rodriguez (2014) “Straddling the Region and the World: Brazilʹs
Dual Foreign Policy Comes of Age,” in: Herzog, Mark and Philip Robins (eds.) The Role,
Position and Agency of Cusp States in International Relations, London: Routledge, 111-128.
Martín, Félix (2006) Militarist Peace in South America: Conditions for War and Peace, New York:
Palgrave.
Mearsheimer, John (2001) The Tragedy of Great Power Politics, New York: Norton.
Mello, Leonel (1996) Argentina e Brasil: a Balança de Poder no Cone Sul, São Paulo: Annablume.
Moniz Bandeira, Luiz (2004) Argentina, Brasil y Estados Unidos: De la Triple Alianza al Mercosur,
Buenos Aires: Grupo Editorial Norma.
Moniz Bandeira, Luiz (2011) Brasil‐Estados Unidos: a rivalidade emergente, Rio de Janeiro: Civilização Brasileira.
Moravcsik, Andrew (1997) “Taking Preferences Seriously: A Liberal Theory of International
Politics,” in: International Organization, 51, 4, 5513-553.
Nolte, Detlef and Leslie Wehner (2012) “UNASUR and Regional Security in South America,”
in: Wegner, Andreas and Stephen Aris (eds.) Regional Organizations and Security: Concep‐
tions and Practices, London: Routledge.
Nolte, Detlef, Brigitte Weiffen and Leslie Wehner (2013) “Overlapping Regional Security Institutions in South America: The Case of OAS and UNASUR,” in: International Area Studies
Review, 16, 4, 370-389.
Novaro, Marcos (2009) Argentina en el fin de siglo: democracia, mercado y nación, Buenos Aires:
Paidós.
Novaro, Marcos (2010) Historia de la Argentina 1955‐2010, Buenos Aires: Siglo XXI.
O’Donnell, Guillermo (1973) Modernization and Bureaucratic‐Authoritarianism: Studies in South
American Politics, Berkeley: University of California Press.
Oelsner, Andrea (2005) International Relations in Latin America: Peace and Security in the Southern
Cone, New York: Routledge.
Oliveira, Amâncio and Alberto Pfeifer (2006) “O empresariado e a política exterior do Brasil”
in: Henrique Altemani and Carlos Anônio Lessa (org.) Relações Internacionais do Brasil: Te‐
mas e Agendas, Vol. 2, São Paulo: Saraiva, 389-427.
Onuf, Nicholas (2001) “Speaking of Policy,” in: Kubalkova, Armonk (ed.) Foreign Policy in a
Constructed World, New York: M.E. Sharpe, 77-95.
293/2016
GIGA Working Papers
30
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
Onuki, Janina (2006) “O Brasil e a construção do Mercosul,” in: Altemani, Henrique Altemani
and Carlos Anônio Lessa (org.) Relações Internacionais do Brasil: Temas e Agendas, Vol. 1,
São Paulo: Saraiva, 299-320.
Organski, Abramo (1958) World Politics, New York: Knopf.
Organski, Abramo and Jacek Kugler (1980) The War Ledger, Chicago: University of Chicago
Press.
Palermo, Vicente and Marcos Novaro (1996) Política y poder en el gobierno de Menem, Buenos
Aires: Norma.
Pang, Eul-Soo (2002) The International Political Economy of Transformation in Argentina, Brazil
and Chile since 1960, New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Peixoto, João Paulo (2011) “The Brazilian state since Vargas,” in: Font, Mauricio and Laura
Randall (eds.) The Brazilian State: Debate and Agenda, New York: Lexington Books, 11-36.
Petrecolla, Alberto (2004) “Devaluaciones y alianzas. Brasil y Argentina en 1999 y 2002,” in:
Petrecolla, Alberto; Pablo Neumeyer and Federico Sturzenegger (eds.) La Nueva Economía
de la Integración Americana, Buenos Aires: La Crujía.
Poggio Teixeira, Gustavo (2014) Brazil, the United States, and the South American Subsystem: Re‐
gional Politics and the Absent Empire, New York: Lexington Books.
Porta, Fernando (2008) “La integración sudamericana en perspectiva: problemas y dilemas,” in:
Serie colección documentos de proyectos, Santiago: CEPAL-Chile.
Pucciarelli, Alfredo (2011) Los años de Menem: la construcción del orden neoliberal, Buenos Aires:
Siglo XXI.
Puig, Juan Carlos (1980) Doctrinas internacionales y autonomía latinoamericana, Caracas: Instituto
de Altos Estudios de América Latina.
Putnam, Robert (1988) “Diplomacy and Domestic Politics: The Logic of Two‐Level Games,”
in: International Organization, 42, 3, 427‐460.
Rapoport, Mario and Eduardo Madrid (2011) Argentina‐Brasil de rivales a aliados, Buenos Aires:
Capital Intelectual.
Resende-Santos, João (2002) “The Origins of Security Cooperation in the Southern Cone,” in:
Latin American Politics and Society, 44, 4, 89-126.
Rogowski, Donald (1989) Commerce and Coalitions: How Trade Affects Domestic Political Align‐
ments, Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Rose, Giddeon (1998) “Neoclassical Realism and Theories of Foreign Policy,” in: World Politics,
51, 1, 144-172.
Russell, Roberto (1988) “Argentina y la política exterior del régimen autoritario (1976-1983):
una evaluación preliminar,” in: Rubén Perina and Roberto Russell (eds.), Argentina en el
mundo (1973‐1987), Buenos Aires: Grupo Editor Latinoamericano.
GIGA Working Papers
293/2016
31
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
Russell, Roberto and Juan Tokatlian (2003) El lugar de Brasil en la política exterior argentina,
Buenos Aires: Fondo de Cultura Económica.
Saraiva, Miriam (2012) “Procesos de integración deAmérica del Sur y el papel de Brasil: los
casos del Mercosur y la Unasur,” in: Revista CIDOB d’afers internacionals, 97, 87-100.
Schenoni, Luis (2015) “The Brazilian Rise and the Elusive South American Balance,” GIGA Workingpapers, 269, 1-23, online: <www.giga-hamburg.de/workingpapers>.
Schweller, Randall (2006) Unanswered Threats: Political Constraints on the Balance of Power,
Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Schweller, Randall and Xiaoyu Pu (2011) “After Unipolarity,” in: International Security, 36, 1,
41-72.
Selden, Zachary (1999) Economic Sanctions as Instruments of Foreign Policy, Westport: Praeger.
Singer, David, Stuart Bremer and John Stuckey (1972) “Capability Distribution, Uncertainty,
and Major Power War, 1820-1965,” in Russett, Bruce (ed.) Peace, War, and Numbers, Beverly Hills: Sage, 19-48.
Skidmore, Thomas (1999) Brazil: Five Centuries of Change, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Snyder, Jack (1991) Myths of Empire: Domestic Politics and International Ambition. Ithaca:
Cornell University Press.
Solingen, Etel (1994) “The Political Economy of Nuclear Restraint,” in: International Security, 19,
2, 126-69.
Tavares de Almeida, María Herminia (1999) “Negociando a Reforma: a Privatização de Empresas Públicas no Brasil,” in: Dados, 42, 3, 421-451.
Wallerstein, Immanuel (1974) The Modern World‐System, New York: Academic Press.
Walt, Stephen (1987) The Origins of Alliances, Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Waltz, Kenneth (1979) Theory of International Politics, New York: McGraw Hill.
Wilkinson, David (1999) “Unipolarity without Hegemony,” in: International Studies Review, 1,
2, 141-172.
Wohlforth, William (1999) “The Stability of a Unipolar World,” in: International Security, 24, 1,
5-41.
Wohlforth, William (2011) “Gilpinian Realism and International Relations,” in: International
Relations, 25, 4, 449-511.
Wright, Martin (1948) Power Politics, New York: Holmes and Meir.
293/2016
GIGA Working Papers
32
Luis Leandro Schenoni: Regional Power Transitions: Lessons from the Southern Cone
Databases
Banks, Arthur and Kenneth Wilson (2015) Cross‐National Time‐Series Data Archive, Databanks
International: Jerusalem.
IISS (2015) The Military Balance, online: <www.iiss.org/en/publications>.
UNDP (2015) UNDP Human Development Report, online: <http://hdr.undp.org/en/data>.
CINC (2015) Composite Index of National Capabilities, Correlates of War, online: <www.correlate
sofwar.org>.
SIPRI (2015) Stockholm International Peace Research Institute, online:< www.sipri.org/databases>.
CEPAL (2015) Comisión Económica para América Latina, online:< www.eclac.cl/estadisticas/>.
SECEX (2015) Secretaria de Comércio Exterior do Brasil, online: <www.stn.fazenda.gov.br/
estatistica>.
MECON (2015) Ministerio de Economía de Argentina, online: www.indec.mecon.ar/>.
MRECIC (2015) Ministerio de Relaciones Exteriores, Comercio Internacional y Culto de Argentina,
online:< http://desclasificacion.cancilleria.gov.ar>.
Fraser Institute (2015) Index of Economic Freedom, online: <www.freetheworld.com/
countrydata>.
GIGA Working Papers
293/2016
Recent Issues
No 292 Jasmin Lorch and Betina Bunk: Gender Politics, Authoritarian Regime Resilience, and the
Role of Civil Society in Algeria and Mozambique, October 2016
No 291 María Cecilia Roa García: Agua, democratización ambiental y fronteras extractivas en
Colombia, September 2016
No 290 Marina Dodlova, Anna Giolbas, and Jann Lay: Non-Contributory Social Transfer
Programmes in Developing Countries: A New Data Set and Research Agenda, August 2016
No 289 Felix Haaß, Sabine Kurtenbach, and Julia Strasheim: Fleeing the Peace? Determinants of
Outward Migration after Civil War, August 2016
No 288 Stephan Rosiny: Brutalisation as a Survival Strategy: How the “Islamic State” Is Prolonging
Its Doomsday Batle, July 2016
No 287 Julia Strasheim: Domestic Explanations for War and Peace in Ukraine, June 2016
No 286 Maria Josua: If You Can’t Include Them, Exclude Them: Countering the Arab Uprisings in
Algeria and Jordan, May 2016
No 285 Cornelis W. Haasnoot: Does Size Mater? The Productivity of Government: Expenditures
and the Size of States: Evidence from India, May 2016
No 284 Hanspeter Mates: Die regionalen Ambitionen Marokkos in Westafrika: Strategie ‒
Aktivitäten ‒ Erfolgsbilanz [Morocco’s Regional Ambitions in West Africa: Strategies,
Activities, Track Record], April 2016
No 283 Georg Strüver: International Alignment between Interests and Ideology: The Case of
China’s Partnership Diplomacy, March 2016
No 282 David Kuehn: Institutionalising Civilian Control of the Military in New Democracies:
Theory and Evidence from South Korea, February 2016
No 281 Alexander Stroh: The Consequences of Appointment Policies for Court Legitimacy in
Benin: A Network Analysis Approach, February 2016
No 280 Abbas Busafwan and Stephan Rosiny: Power-Sharing in Bahrain: A Still-Absent Debate,
November 2015
No 279 Rustum Mahmoud and Stephan Rosiny: Opposition Visions for Preserving Syria’s EthnicSectarian Mosaic, October 2015
All GIGA Working Papers are available free of charge at <www.giga-hamburg.de/workingpapers>.
For any requests please contact: <workingpapers@giga-hamburg.de>.
WP Coordinator: Melissa Nelson
GIGA German Institute of Global and Area Studies / Leibniz-Institut für Globale und Regionale Studien
Neuer Jungfernstieg 21 • 20354 Hamburg • Germany
E-mail: <info@giga-hamburg.de> • Website: <www.giga-hamburg.de>