Circuitism – its monetary theory and model of the money circuit
by Joseph Huber
Source: https://sovereignmoney.eu/circuitism, as of March 2015
Introduction ............................................................................................. 2
Monetary theory ...................................................................................... 3
Neglect of the dysfunctions of banks´ primary credit creation ................ 4
Ambiguity regarding the interplay between banks and central bank ..... 5
Token money, paper money, and credit .................................................. 6
Wrong identification of token money and credit money ........................ 7
The rhetoric about endogenous and exogenous money ......................... 7
Incomplete picture of credit creation ................................................... 10
The model of the money circuit ............................................................. 12
Old-industrial logic of capital vs labour ................................................. 13
Banks and nonbank financial institutions ............................................. 14
The real-bills doctrine of Circuitism ...................................................... 14
Is there a necessary sequence in money circulation? .......................... 15
Classical bias regarding the 'secondary' economic status of the
state ....................................................................................................... 19
Lost in the circuit ................................................................................... 20
Circuitist literature referred to .............................................................. 22
2
Introduction
The literature of Circuitism deals with two different subjects.1 One subject
is monetary theory, i.e. the functioning of the present-day money and
banking system. The other subject focuses on the circulation of money. The
Circuitist model examines how money originates in the banking sector by
being credited to firms, circulates from the firms to wage earners, and
flows back via the firms to the banking sector whereupon the money is
extinguished.
Circuitism distances itself from neoclassical economics as well as from
orthodox Keynesianism. Notwithstanding, Graziani makes positive
reference to Keynes (but 'mostly the Treatise on Money, much less the
General Theory'2) as well as to Kalecki and later representatives of
Postkeynesianism (Moore, Minsky, Kregel, Davidson). He also
acknowledges earlier contributions by the Swedish and German schools,
e.g. Wicksell, Schumpeter and Hahn.
Circuitism is seen as a Postkeynesian theory, or an offspring of
Postkeynesianism. This certainly applies to the monetary theory. The
model of the money circuit, however, as will become apparent in the
second part of this paper, looks rather like a new classical and Neomarxist
construction of the money-mediated economic process dominated by
banking capitalism. For the rest, the analytical perspective tends to be
supply-side (from the firms' point of view) rather than Keynesian demandside.
Under the angle of New Currency Theory as pursued on this website, there
is agreement as well as partial disagreement with the monetary theory of
Circuitism. With regard to the model of the money circuit, it appears as if
that 'circuit' were just another case of over-simplified model-building.
1
Except Augusto Graziani, who is the main reference here, further important Circuitists
include Bernard Schmitt, Alain Parguez, Alvaro Cencini, Frédéric Poulon and Giuseppe
Fontana.
2
Graziani 2003 23.
3
Monetary theory
Under descriptive aspects the monetary theory of Circuitism reflects the
state of knowledge of Postkeynesianism in recent decades. It builds on the
notion of endogenous credit money in the form of deposits. Bank credit
creates deposits, while the reverse, deposits serving to fund bank credit,
does not hold true, except for formally independent investment units of
banks such as investment trusts; these, however, are nonbank financial
institutions.3 Modern fiat money has no coverage by other monetary items.
It is pure purchasing power in general and regular use.4
Circuitism has developed an explicit understanding of what it means to
have a monetarised and financialised economy, in contrast to a mere
barter economy, as is characteristic of neoclassical theories of market
equilibria, that operates on 'exogenous' money and finances itself on the
basis of recycled savings only. The money, or capital respectively, that prefinances production and trade, however, is basically created as primary
bank credit. Its existence, according to Circuitism, alters the structure and
inner workings of the economy. In general, as Graziani says,
'money is never neutral' and 'is, at the economic level, a source of profits
and, at the social level, a source of power.' – 'Since access to money and
credit is a key factor in a wage economy, producers of money and credit …
enjoy a privileged position and are admitted as such to a share of total
product.'5
According to Circuitist teaching, modern economies depend on how credit
and money are managed. Likewise, the levels of employment and income
are thought not to be determined by relative prices, but by the conditions
of credit funding that are jointly decided upon by banks and firms, with the
banks holding the whip hand. This stresses the Circuitists' view of 'the
power of banks' and the overriding position of the banking industry as a
pivotal player in the economy.6
Graziani states on various occasions that central banks, as core institutions
of the monetary system, must not be merged with 'the government' into
one and the same category, i.e. the public sector, as opposed to the private
and foreign sectors. Lumping together government and central bank
creates confusion about monetary and fiscal functions and is bound to
result in unreal ideas about the creation and circulation of money.
3
Graziani 1990 8-10, 16, 29; Graziani 2003 11, 23-29, 82.
Fontana 2000 42.
5
Graziani 1990 29, 2003 26.
6
Graziani 2003 58-62; 1990 8, 11–29.
4
4
According to Circuitists, government has no role in creating money today,
as 'the monetary base is being created by the banking system, and not as
being the consequence of a government deficit'.7 Whether this still is the
case indirectly, remains open to question. The relevant aspect here is
Graziani arguing in favour of a separation of monetary and fiscal functions,
not to say separation of state powers between the government and the
central bank. This is contrary to Keynes-inspired models of public-private
sector balances, and the idea that government debt equals the creation of
sovereign currency. This idea is to be found in the approach to sector
balances by Godley/Lavoie, and more pointedly so in Modern Money
Theory (MMT), another strand of Postkeynesian origin whose monetary
theory otherwise overlaps with Circuitism in a number of aspects.8
Neglect of the dysfunctions of banks' primary credit creation
Despite the Circuitists' emphasis on the power of banks, and recognition of
the bias towards privileged financial-capital revenue, there is, as is the case
in Keynesianism in general, no criticism of the banking industry's systemic
position as a monetary power. Circuitist theory seems to content itself with
the description of the money and banking system, while being reluctant to
evaluate the situation and give policy advice. Even if it could be read into
some text passages that Circuitists may want to curb the power of banks,
they have not, to my knowledge, contemplated reshaping the monetary
and banking system.9
Still more remarkably from a New Currency point of view, Circuitists see no
fault in fractional reserve banking and do not attribute financial instability
and recurrent banking and financial crises to the regime of bank money
such as it stands today. This is certainly typical for standard textbook
economics and Keynesianism, but also for most scholars of
Postkeynesianism, through to Circuitism and MMT. Quantities of money
and GDP-disproportionate overshooting of pro-active primary credit and
thus money creation are not an issue. This is a rare case of collective
neglect of an issue – the quantity theory of money – that used to be a
common topic for centuries. With special regard to Circuitism this also
7
Graziani 1990 29, 7, 11.
Godley, Wynne / Lavoie, Marc 2007: Monetary Economics, London: palgrave/ macmillan.
- Wray, Randall 2012: Modern Money Theory, Palgrave/Macmillan. - Tcherneva, Pavlina
2006: Chartalism and the tax-driven approach, in: Arestis, Philip / Sawyer, Malcolm (eds.),
A Handbook of Alternative Monetary Economics, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 69–86.
9
In his journal article from 1990, p. 18, Graziani once mentions 'the possibility for the
central bank to create money in order to finance the government deficit. Central-bank
money thus created is no longer debt of commercial banks, but debt of the government
towards the central bank.'
8
5
results from its version of the Banking-School's real bills doctrine as
discussed below.
Ambiguity regarding the interplay between banks and central bank
In various passages Graziani is unclear, as Keynes was, as to whether banks
or central banks have the lead in creating money. In both Keynes and
Circuitism there seems to be a prevailing belief in the effectiveness of
central-bank reserve positions and base rates for controlling, or at least
influencing, the rate and pace of banks' credit creation. Graziani even
seems to refer to the multiplier model (rightly given up in much of
Postkeynesianism) when he explains that the Circuitist theory 'stresses the
fact that the credit potential of the banking system depends on the
monetary base, the reserve ratio'.10
On the other hand, Graziani endorses the banks' ability for pro-active
primary credit creation, explicitly referring to Keynes's statement in the
Treatise on Money that 'there is no limit to the amount of bank-money
which the banks can safely create, provided that they move forward in
step.' And, it has to be added, as long as central banks always
accommodate the banks' demand for reserves.
On balance, Circuitism remains unclear about the question of who has the
pro-active lead in creating money; unlike the accommodationist view of
Postkeynesianism, to which there is no doubt that the banking industry has
the lead in creating credit and deposits, while the central bank of a
currency area reactively accommodates the banks' demand for fractional
re-financing in the form of reserves and residual cash.11 In consequence,
primary bank credit determines the entire money supply. The creation of
bank money certainly depends to a degree on the demand for money from
firms, government and households. This, however, does not alter the
position of the banks as the pivotal actors in the money supply chain, in
that they decide selectively on whether, how much, for what and for whom
they create primary credit, thus bank money.
10
Graziani 1990 16.
Moore, Basil 1988: Horizontalists and Verticalists: The Macroeconomics of Credit Money,
Cambridge University Press. - Palley, Thomas 1993: Competing Views of the Money
Supply, New School for Social Research, New York, Dept. of Economics, July 1993,
http://www.thomaspalley.com/ docs/articles/macro_theory/monetary_supply.pdf.
11
6
Token money, paper money, and credit
There is another ambiguity when Graziani says that a monetary economy
'must be using a token money, which is nowadays paper currency.' –
'Nowadays, money is paper money introduced into the market by means of
bank credit'.12
This can be misunderstood. Bank credit creates deposits (bank money-onaccount), not banknotes (paper money). As far as customers demand
payout of deposits in cash, the banks need to obtain the coins and
banknotes from the central bank, whereby the monopoly of coining rests
with the national treasuries, while the central banks have the monopoly on
banknotes since the 19th century. In contrast to bank money, the banks
have to finance paper money and coins to 100%, not just fractionally.
Moreover, Graziani's 'nowadays' is now a long time ago. Depending on the
country, paper money came into use in Europe around 1700 and became
the predominant form of token money from about 1800 to the middle of
the 20th century. However, throughout that time it never existed in its own
right (except for a few short periods as colonial bills, continental dollars
and Greenbacks in the history of the US).13 Paper money was not
constitutive for the monetary system, but rested on traditional silver and
gold currency, or a central national reserve of gold bullion under the gold
standard from 1844 to 1971, since then just on primary central-bank credit
(= central-bank money = reserves).
At the source, modern money is non-cash money-on-account in a bank or
central-bank account. Physical cash, as long as it remains in use, is
exchanged out of and back into the basically non-cash money supply. For
the time being this also holds true for e-cash. Whether e-cash, while
physical cash is vanishing, will become another privileged domain of the
banking industry that is ever more detaching itself from central banks and
legal tender, or whether e-cash as legal tender will serve to restore the
sovereign monetary prerogatives of the currency, money and seigniorage,
this is being decided today in the further course of contemporary history.14
12
Graziani 1990 10, 2003 11.
Cf. Zarlenga, Stephen 2002: : The Lost Science of Money, Valatie, NY: American
Monetary Institute, chapters 14–17; Hixson, William F. 1993: Triumph of the Bankers,
Westport, CT: Praeger, chapters 7, 8, 11 – 19.
14
Cf. sovereignmoney.eu/monetary-reform-step-by-step.
13
7
Wrong identification of token money and credit money
A fundamental reason for not seeing problems with fractional reserve
banking seems to be that most economic teachings today―neoclassical as
well as of Keynesian descent―identify token money with credit money,
and take this as the unquestioned natural state of affairs. For once, though,
Graziani makes a distinction between money and credit (as any Currency
scholar will do), in that he declares money to be more than credit:
'something different from a regular commodity and something more than a
mere promise of payment; ... money has to be accepted as a means of final
settlement of the transaction, otherwise it would be credit and not
money.'15
The observation that credit creates a mutual obligation to pay, whereas the
transfer of money discharges an obligation to pay, captures an important
aspect of the matter.
Beyond that passage, however, and much like Postkeynesianism and MMT,
Graziani falls back to an absolute identification of money with credit, that
is, token money with credit money, as an alleged historical fact and
necessity from the archaic beginnings of civilisation. This ignores about
2,500 years of coin currencies where the rulers of a realm – the premodern State, in a sense – enjoyed the genuine seigniorage from minting
coins and spending these into circulation free of debt; which of course can
be done in much the same way and more easily with modern money-onaccount and mobile e-cash. Credit money certainly is token money, but
token money is not necessarily credit money.
The rhetoric about endogenous and exogenous money
Postkeynesianism has developed the notion of endogenous and exogenous
money, and holds the view that money (credit) in the modern economy is
endogenous.16 This can basically be endorsed, and yet may be misleading
in a specific sense.
The distinction can be traced back to a narrative created by Adam Smith
and lateron also Carl Menger in the 1870s (neoclassical Austrian School).
According to this narrative, money is imagined to have emerged as a
15
Graziani 1990 11–12, 2003 61–62.
Cf. Rochon, Louis-Philippe 1999: Credit, Money and Production. An Alternative PostKeynesian Approach, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, p.15, 17, 155, 163, pp.166. - Keene, Steve
2011: Debunking Economics, London/New York: Zed Books, pp.358. - Moore, Basil 1988:
Horizontalists and Verticalists: The Macroeconomics of Credit Money, Cambridge
University Press.
16
8
spontaneous creation in archaic barter and early market processes,
originally as commodity money (livestock, grain, salt, silver), then coins
made of silver, copper and gold, and more recently also as credit-based
paper money originated by individual market participants. At the time of
Smith and Menger, this idea was directed against money creation by
alleged 'outsiders' to the economy, in particular political or religious
authorities.
What is really known about archaic and traditional societies, however,
provides evidence to the contrary. In the archaic beginnings, money was
developed as a unit of account for documenting and clearing claims and
obligations (debt, tributes). This took place in the extended householdeconomies of the worldly and religious rulers of the time and the related
chains of provision. When coins were introduced much later, 2,700 years
ago, coining was under the control of those rulers from the beginning.17
The sequence of commodity monies > precious-metal coins > credit-based
paper money is probably correct, not however the postulate of
'spontaneous' barter and market economies including the 'spontaneous'
creation of money. Rather, the economy developed around the courts and
temples of the rulers of a realm, under their control, including control of
the monetary and financing practices at subsequent stages of
development.
Seen in the light of historical knowledge and contemporary facts, it is not
any economic agent who can create 'endogenous' credit or money. Today,
only banks and national central banks, that is, monetary institutions, create
money. (Treasury coins now count for less than 1 per cent of the money
supply). Private currencies, such as not-for-profit complementary
currencies or speculative bitcoins, and other private means of payment
beyond bank money do exist, but are not used as a general and regular
means of payment. Unlike bank money they are not official money, i.e. de
facto authorised money in addition to legal tender. Also payment in kind,
or the transfer of bills of exchange, debentures or other financial assets in
lieu of payment in official money are special cases representing
exemptions to the rule. With the development of electronic payment
systems run by the central banks, payment in official money is the rule
more than ever before.
17
Cf. the contributions of Henry, Hudson, Gardiner and Ingham in Wray, L. Randall (ed.)
2004: Credit and State Theories of Money, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. - Graeber, David
2011: Debt. The first 5,000 years, New York: Melville House Publishing.
9
In neoclassical and Keynesian mainstream economics from about the
1920s, the narrative of 'money from outside vs inside the economy' was
specified – or say, re-interpreted – so as to label legal tender from the
national central bank or the treasury as 'exogenous', whereas bank money
is deemed 'endogenous'. This is reflected in the two-tier model of the
banking system, which, more precisely, is a double-circuit money system
comprising the public circulation based on bank money, and the interbank
circulation based on central-bank money (reserves).
The split between the two also expresses the prevailing situation of
incomplete chartalism.18 This means there are nation-state currencies,
while the money supply consists of state money and private bank money in
parallel, with the bank money over time having come to dominate the
entire system. The situation has not been questioned since the interwar
period. There may be some controversy on whether money creation is led
by the supply side or the demand side. But only Postkeynesianism,
Circuitism and the New Currency perspective of the monetary reform
movement have posed the question of the extent to which 'the power of
banks' dominates the system and determines the creation of money.
The Postkeynesian notion of endogenous vs exogenous money is
nonetheless fallacious. Banks and central banks both create credit money
in basically the same way. Both of them do it on demand. The banks,
however, apply selective supply policies of their own, including proprietary
trading beyond customer demand. The central banks today, by contrast,
deliver as much money as the banks are demanding. Presently, central
banks no longer intend to exert control over the quantity of money. If bank
money is seen as endogenous in the economy, so too must central-bank
money. If central-bank money is seen as exogenous to the economy, so too
must bank money.
Considering the status of bank money as endogenous and that of centralbank money as exogenous is purely arbitrary. It represents ideological
labelling which makes banks appear as 'insiders' of the economy, whereas
the central bank appears to be an alien outside agency, similar to the way
in which many economists see the role of government. This still goes back
18
Chartal theories of money see the money system and the money itself as a creature of
the law. The lasting existence of money depends on being backed up by the state. Major
references are the British Currency School of the 1830–40s, the State Theory of Money by
Fr. Knapp (1905), and, soon thereafter, the writings by A. Mitchell-Innes. The latter
authors, however, advocated incomplete chartalism, where the money is not necessarily
state money, but can also be private money, in particular credit money created by the
banking sector.
10
to the bourgeois ideology of the market economy as an 'extra-territorial'
Robinson island beyond the state and society, based on private law with no
role for public or state law. Amid all the justified criticism of the feudal
state and mercantilism of the 17th to the 19th centuries, the fundamental
and indispensable role of the state in modern societies, including the
money system and creating a legal framework for the economy and
finances, was not properly understood; which often enough is still the case
today.
Speaking of 'exogenous' money would only make sense if an amount of
money would be given, somewhere from an elusive 'economic outside',
prior to the economic process without dynamically changing with the
demand for and the supply of money. Exogenous money in this sense,
however, does not exist in a modern economy. If something that comes
close to an exogenous money supply did ever exist, it was the silver and
gold of traditional coin currencies, and―in concept, not in reality―national
gold hoards under the old-industrial gold standard. Present-day fiat money,
however, is always endogenous. In consequence, the distinction between
exogenous and endogenous money is prejudiced and confusing.
A distinction analogous to endogenous vs exogenous and of the same
meaning is the one between outside money (issued by the central bank
and, maybe, the treasury) and inside money (issued by the banking
industry).19 The difference between the two wordings seems to be that
'outside money' is considered the more reliable, higher ranking asset in
contrast to bank money, because 'outside money' comes from the central
bank as the ultimate source of money and is also backed by the
government, whereas banks in crisis are backed by no one―except their
central bank and government. As a specification this is certainly correct.
The terminology of inside vs outside nonetheless reproduces the
ideological dictum according to which the banking industry is seen 'inside
the markets' whereas the central banks are shunt off to an unreal, in fact
non-existent position 'outside' the money and capital markets.
Incomplete picture of credit creation
The Circuitist view of the creation of bank money is incomplete in two
ways. Firstly, there is too narrow a focus on bank loans; secondly, bank
19
Lagos, Ricardo 2006: Inside and Outside Money, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis,
Research Department Staff Report 374, May 2006. - Roch, Cullen 2012: Understanding
Inside Money and Outside Money, Pragmatic Capitalism, www.pragcap.com/understanding-inside-money-and-outside-money.
11
loans in the Circuitist model just flow to firms. The latter aspect is dealt
with in the next chapter.
With regard to the first aspect, the Circuitist view misses the fact that
banks create primary credit not only by way of making loans and granting
overdraft, but equally by purchasing securities or real estate, and even by
paying for salaries, services, equipment and materials. A payment from a
bank to nonbanks creates deposits, while payments from nonbanks to a
bank delete deposits.
In this respect, Graziani held a traditional view: 'A bank cannot buy
commodities by means of its own credit (if it did so, it would require
commodities from the market without giving anything in return).'20 But of
course, yes, banks can. They actually have to, because, since banks do not
pay for salaries etc. in cash, they pay by crediting accounts, and when
banks credit accounts they create primary bank credit and deposits.
However, when banks receive payments from proprietary transactions in
bank money, this creates an entry in the earnings account, while the
deposits are deleted at the payer's bank and cease to exist.
More generally speaking, whenever a bank credits a giro account - held by
nonbanks, nonbank financial intermediaries, or other banks apart from
their central-bank account - new bank money is created, irrespective of the
purpose of the transaction. Whenever payments are made to a bank from
a giro account held by these actors, bank money is deleted.
How many excess reserves (payment reserves) a respective bank will
ultimately obtain in the process, or will have to pay on balance, depends on
the entirety of outgoing and incoming payments in both proprietary and
customer transactions. In actual fact, the base of reserves involved in the
process will be just a fraction of bank-money turnover at almost any point
in time, even more so, the bigger a bank is (or a banking union with a
central clearing unit).
Graziani obscures the matter further when saying that
'banks need to make use of interest payments made by firms in order to
pay wages and salaries to their employees, buy commodities on the market,
and possibly pay interest on deposits.'21
Interest payments to a bank, however, cannot 'be used' by that bank for
making subsequent payments. Banks certainly need to keep up a certain
balance of incoming and outgoing reserves (in order to avoid costly
20
21
Graziani 1990 15.
Graziani 1990 27.
12
liquidity shortages). It does not make a difference, however, where the
reserves come from, from proprietary or customer transactions, and
whether a bank has enough reserves available when a payment has to be
carried out, or whether the reserves have to be taken up upon payment or
afterwards from the central bank or in the interbank market. In any case,
banks do not need to have received a particular amount in interest
payments in order to be able to pay salaries or purchase securities.
There is, however, an important difference between two kinds of
transactions. One is bank purchases of securities, foreign exchange,
derivatives, real estate, gold, commodities, and long-term equipment. The
other is expenditure on salaries, services and materials. The difference
between the two is that the former types of transactions (securities, etc.)
can be booked as an asset on the balance sheet, whereas the latter
transactions (salaries, bonuses, services, operational costs) have to be
booked as an expenditure à fonds perdu in the profit-and-loss account,
with no additional asset as counterpart, thus one-sidedly debiting the
equity. The final profit or loss of a bank, a surplus or deficit in its equity
account, depends on the balance of its earnings and expenditures as well
as on gains or losses in the value of its assets.
The model of the money circuit
The Circuitist model of money circulation consists of a four-step sequence
from money creation to its deletion: banks credit firms > firms pay
employees > employees buy what firms produce > firms pay back the credit
to the banks.22 According to Graziani, 'Circuit theory tries to consider the
whole life cycle of money, starting with its creation by means of bank loans
and ending with its destruction when these loans are repaid.'23
In actual fact, however, the Circuitist model does not satisfy the claim of
representing 'the whole life cycle of money'. Beyond the bank-firmrelationship, the model does not make a distinction between realeconomic and financial transactions; it does not systematically differentiate
between banks and financial intermediaries; it reproduces the oldindustrial concept of production and consumption; equally, it reproduces
the old-industrial concept of capital and labour; it blinds out the
interdependencies with foreign economies; equally, it blinds out the
fundamental economic role of the state; it thereby also reproduces the
22
23
Graziani 2003 26–31; Parguez/Seccareccia 2000.
Graziani 2003 21.
13
lopsided idea of 'primary' allocation and distribution by the private
economy, and 'secondary' redistribution by the government.
Old-industrial logic of capital vs labour
What firms sell to and buy from other firms is blanked out in the model on
the grounds that this affects payments among firms, i.e. trade within the
same 'sector', where expenditures and earnings are netting out. The model
thus considers banks, firms and wage earners as the three sectors of the
economy, in methodological analogy to other Keynesian sector-account
mechanics (which, though, are based on different types of sectors, i.e. a
private, public, and foreign sector). According to the three sectors of the
Circuitist model, 'real output gets divided into real wages, industrial profits,
and financial profits'.24
Circuitismus defines the economy as a wage economy. This is not the only
aspect under which the model is reminiscent of 19th century theories of
division of labour (forerunners of today's life-cycle and chain analyses) and,
in particular, theories of labour value according to which all value added
can be retraced to labour employed, which is to say, wages paid. In
Marxism this also includes wages foregone to the workers due to
appropriation by the capitalist entrepreneurs and bankers.
The model thus reproduces the old-industrial logic of capital and labour.
This certainly continues to be a defining component, and yet it is too
simplistic in order to capture realities in a sufficiently differentiated way.
For example, earned income must not be reduced to dependent wage
labour, while it continues to be inappropriate to merge income earned by
self-employed and small and medium-sized businesses with 'industrial
capital'.
Equally, real-economic and financial investment is absolutely fundamental
to modern economies, as Circuitism recognises by its definition of what a
'money economy' is. It thus is flawed to give capital revenues as such a
negative connotation. Even if it does not apply to the lower classes, many
dependent employees today have, to a degree, savings and other invested
funds and thus benefit from capital revenue. Moreover, in today's
individualised society, 'non-active' individuals represent about half of the
population. They have to be supplied with money, but can no longer simply
be treated as the family appendage of the wage earners and recipients of
capital income.
24
Graziani 1990 27.
14
Banks and nonbank financial institutions
In Circuitism – and not only there – the term 'bank' is not used consistently.
In many passages 'bank' properly means a commercial monetary
institutions that creates primary credit and deposits, refinances itself at the
central bank if need be, and participates in the electronic payment system
of the central bank. In other passages, however, the term 'bank' is also
used for nonbank financial intermediaries that help to on-lend or to invest
already existing bank money. Sometimes 'bank' is used as a generic term
for both types of financial firms.
The difference between banks and intermediaries is that only banks are
monetary institutions that create and delete bank money (deposits),
whereby they do not on-lend or invest existing deposits. Financial
intermediaries, by contrast, are not able to create deposits. They are no
monetary institutions. They operate as managers and investors of already
existing deposits.
The difference between banks as monetary institutions and nonbank
financial intermediaries must not be blurred. When loans or bonds are
redeemed to a nonbank creditor, the money involved is not deleted, but
continues to circulate. At the same time, the banks continue to create
additional credit (deposits) if this is in their individual business interest.
Over time this can lead to problematic effects, as discussed at the end of
this paper.
The real-bills doctrine of Circuitism
The Circuitist model comes with its implicit version of the real bills
doctrine. This was a central Banking-School position in the historical
controversy with the Currency School. The doctrine maintains that banks
will always create an optimum quantity of money, neither an inflationary
overshoot nor a deflationary shortage of the money supply, and will thus
always operate on the safe side as long as they create money for funding
'real bills', i.e. credit against bills of exchange or other securities issued by
reputable enterprises, sound business, etc. Moreover, if banks do so, they
should do it over the short rather than the long term. In the face of the
realities of banking and entrepreneurship, this is just glossing things over,
including a good measure of pretence of knowledge. In the end, as things
naturally turn out, firms and banks often have not had enough knowledge,
or things may change in an unforeseen way, so that initial expectations
ascribed to projects and 'real bills' become unreal. What is more, many
bankers, investors and adventurers, particularly in the upswing and climax
15
of business and financial cycles, cannot stop themselves from leveraging up
the stakes.
Such market dynamics and related risk behaviour are no issue in Circuitism,
as the existence of a huge non-GDP-related financial economy is nonexistent in the Circuitist model. Instead, primary and secondary credit are
assumed to fund real-economic expenditure of firms only. In this respect,
the Circuitists' understanding of the financial economy is under-developed.
In particular, it fails to see the difference between GDP-related and non
GDP-related transactions – a flaw which again is typical not only for
Circuitism. The growth of non GDP-related finance has been particularly
important since around 1980, but it already existed in the beginnings of
Circuitism.
In the Circuitist model, firms and banks are supposed to make appropriate
predictions regarding business perspectives, the demand for what firms
intend to supply, future prices, the work force, etc. Firms are supposed to
know how much money they will need, and they negotiate the credit
conditions with the banks for funding the firms' planned activities. The
firms' demand for money thus is supposed to have a 'real' and reliable
foundation, and banks accordingly cannot fail in serving that demand – in
fact another real bills doctrine, all the more, as banks in the last decades
have created primary credit predominantly for financial investment,
including real-estate bubbles, and sovereign-bond bubbles by financing
governments far beyond reasonable levels of indebtedness.
Is there a necessary sequence in money circulation?
The Circuitist model states a specific sequence in the circulation of money.
Developing some such sequence, as an alternative to older classical and
neoclassical positions, was among Keynes's research desiderata. Among
those older models was the distinction between basic industries, or capitalgoods industries, and consumer-goods industries (economic sections I and
II in Marxist economics), as well as the Austrian-School five- to seven-step
production model that is underlying its capital theory.25
The centrepiece of the Circuitist model is bank credit to firms.
Fontana: 'Money ... is mainly the flow of bank deposits demanded by firms
to finance the production of goods and services'.26
Graziani: 'Negotiations between banks and firms on the money market
determine the amount of credit actually granted and the rate of interest
25
Cf. Jesús Huerta de Soto 2009: Money, Bank Credit, and Economic Cycles, Ludwig von
Mises Institute, Auburn, Alabama, Chapter 5, 265–396.
26
Fontana 2000 42.
16
charged to firms. ... The model is money market first, labour market second,
the first determining the conditions for the latter. ... The total amount of
money is a debt of the firms to the banking sector and a credit of wageearners to the same sector'.27
Credit to other actor groups, such as consumer credit, mortgages, or
sovereign bonds, is considered to be of secondary importance, in fact
maintaining that everything is determined by the gravitational circuit
between capital and labour, i.e. between financing banks and producing
firms on the one hand, and consuming wage earners on the other.
This is overly reductionist. The Circuitist model does not correspond to the
empirical pattern of present-day credit and money creation. The 'circuit'
between capital and labour represents just one component in a wider
picture. Close to 60% of bank lending today is allotted to mortgages. The
rest is spread over government debt, student loans (in the US), consumer
credit (overdraft, car, credit-card and home-equity-line credit) as well as
lending to firms.28 The latter, of course, is part of the banking business, but
is in no way predominant and applies to small and medium-sized
enterprises rather than big companies. Industrial corporations no longer
depend on bank credit to a major extent. They tap the secondary credit
market, i.e. on-lending of already existing bank money, for example, by
way of issuing corporate bonds, shares, or taking up money from
investment funds. Moreover, large multinationals now run banks of their
own (which is a questionable development in terms of separation of
monetary, fiscal, financial and real-economic functions).
In recent decades, furthermore, liquid bank money (i.e. money circulating
by way of primary and secondary credit, as represented in European M1)
has grown several times the nominal GDP that represents the economic
product at current prices (including consumer price inflation). This is to say
that the lion's share of credit went into financial non-GDP transactions, into
self-referential and quite often purely speculative financial portfolio
trading. The disproportionate growth of such non-GDP transactions creates
bubbles so that even mortgages and sovereign bonds, normally considered
as conservative investments, can turn into high-risk exposures.
According to classical and neoclassical views, credit should first flow into
capital expenditure, especially into private investment in productive
capacities, not immediately into consumption, and less so into government
27
Graziani 1990 12.
Jordà, Òscar / Schularick, Moritz / Taylor, Alan M. 2014: The Great Mortgaging: Housing
Finance, Crises, and Business Cycles, NBER Working Papers, No. 20501, Sep 2014, National
th
Bureau of Economic Research. – Economist, March 28 , 2015, 16.
28
17
expenditure, both of which are supposed to result in inflation. In the
beginning of industrialisation, with productive capacities at a low level of
development, and potential consumptive demand still unsatisfied for the
most part, the idea of 'investment in productive capacities first,
consumption second' made some sense.
Programs of government expenditure since the 1930s, in particular
Keynesian demand-side policies after WWII, established a complementary
alternative to the classical attitude. In the context of a structurally
entrenched lack of effective demand, additional government expenditure
and increased wages were ascribed a positive role of their own, because
this prevents deflationary depression and, as long as capacities are
underused, does not entail an important risk of inflation. One reason is that
productive capacities today are much higher and connected through global
markets. This means that supply chains are flexibly adaptive. Increased
demand for goods and services triggers a swift increase in supply rather
than inflation, the more so as long as the cost level in new industrial and
developing countries is much lower than in developed countries.
This is not to justify the abuse of Keynesian demand-side policies by
permanent deficit spending as a bad political all-seasons habit detached
from the real business cycle, resulting in all-too high levels of government
expenditure and debt. In many cases, moreover, state interventionism
actually contributes to reinforcing rather than overcoming problems of
structural entrenchment.
Circuitism does not contribute to analysing such questions. Its narrow
focus on 'banks financing firms' in fact leaves a somewhat dated
impression. Classical, Marxist and neoclassical economists until the 1920s
used to think in these terms, including R. Hilferding's and R. Luxemburg's
notion of financial capitalism as banking capitalism. During the century
since, the arena of actors and the complexity of the financial and real
economy have considerably evolved. Focussing questions of money and
finance too narrowly on the firm now represents an old-industrial bias of
economics that may have had a point from around 1800 until about the
1960s. One consequence of this has been building the industrial welfare
state too narrowly upon the relationship between employers and wage
labour. Over time this has become another fiscal and financial-market
problem without lastingly solving respective social problems.
A positive aspect in the model is that Circuitists reject a special focus on
investment in real-economic capacities. They rather refer to 'the monetary
18
cost of output in general', i.e. capital expenditure with a broad meaning,
including wages.29
Notwithstanding, the firms in the Circuitist model still stand for the
production of consumer supplies, the wage earners for the effective
demand which absorbs the consumer goods and household-related
services supplied. Again, this is just one part of the whole picture. It
reproduces, however, the concept of a linear vertical production chain of
an economy entirely aimed at 'final' private consumption. This is reflected
in today's national accounts and the Circuitist model which describes the
economy as a reduced linear circle from the creation of bank money for
financing the production of goods by firms, which includes paying wages,
to wage-earning consumers buying consumer items and household-related
services, so that firms are able to pay back the credit, plus interest, to the
banks. This may be handy, and, as is known, Henry Ford thought this way a
hundred years ago. Today, it does not sufficiently reflect the multifaceted
realities of the economy, less so the financial economy and the total
picture of the circulation of money.
The real-economic supply-side channel is of course an important one, but
there is a wider picture – supply-side and demand-side impulses; by firms,
private households and public units; life cycles of technologies,
products/services and markets as well as vertical and horizontal chains of
provision; including the arbitrariness of classifying steps therein as
'productive/investive' or 'consumptive'; the existence of a GDP-related and
non-GDP money circulation. All this suggests the development of a more
complex understanding of what money circulation actually encompasses.
It follows from this that there is no 'natural' sequence in the circulation of
money. Instead, there can be various ways of channelling new money into
circulation, and many ways in the further circulation of the money. There is
no such thing as a strictly necessary sequence regarding the creation,
circulation and deletion of money. Respective doctrines can safely be
dropped. The important thing is that enough money for GDP-related
purposes can be obtained by financial institutions, firms, private
households and public bodies whenever they need it.
The above criticism of the circuitist model is certainly of a relative nature.
Even if outmoded to a degree, the model maintains a core of truth which is
certainly more adequate than, for example, the Postkeynesian model of
29
Graziani 1990 14.
19
sector balances which confuses its sectoral book-keeping model of the
economy with an analysis of monetary and financial dynamics.
Classical bias regarding the 'secondary' economic status of the state
The Circuitist model reproduces the classical view regarding allocation
through enterprises, followed by primary distribution between capital and
labour, and secondary redistribution by way of taxes through the state.30
This too has been taken as the natural state of affairs up to the present
day, not only in Circuitismus. It is a common feature in almost all
approaches to economic modelling. Economic models often start from a
version without the state (and no foreign economy), and then proceed to
less-simplified versions including the state (and possibly a foreign
economy). What nevertheless remains is the coding of the 'economic base'
as primary/productive/ entrepreneurial/competitive, and the 'state
superstructure' as secondary/unproductive/bureaucratic/powerdominated/monopolist, or in the same vein.
Once more the real picture is different, and a rather mixed one on both
fronts. In modern corporate economies, private-sector companies tend to
be heavily bureaucratised; most markets – not only labour, but also goods
and services as well as certain segments in finance – are power-dominated
and oligopolistic; factor allocation is often inefficient.
Regarding the relationship between the 'economic base' and the 'state
superstructure' one cannot really say in the ongoing process which is the
chicken and which is the egg. With the government sector representing
35–60% of GDP, and with much of the additions to the money supply
created due to government demand for additional money, the
government's economic status is anything but secondary. In actual and
historical fact, the state represents the institutional, legal and
infrastructural base of the economy which includes private as much as
public firms, institutes, organisations and households. Seen like this, the
state would appear as the 'primary basis' rather than a secondary
redistributive 'superstructure' (which is not advocated here). Marx and
Engels' utopia of communism was somewhat grotesque when they
expected the dwindling-away of the state (an element of early 19th century
social romanticism, at the time present in liberalism as much as lateron in
both anarchism and socialism).
30
Also cf. Parguez/Seccareccia 2000 pp.425.
20
Government expenditure is certainly not always optimal, but so too is
private capital expenditure. Labelling government expenditure per se as
'unproductive' and private capital expenditure as 'productive' is ideological
humbug. Government expenditure feeds mass purchasing power more
effectively than capital expenditure does by itself. Government provides
necessary administrative and judicial functions, also and specifically for the
economy. Government provides general infrastructures and a wide range
of public services, including health and education, the biggest sectors of
the economy. How much of this is to be classified as consumptive or
investive, and how much contributes to 'reproducing' or 'producing' human
capital, is a highly arbitrary and futile question, comparable to the flawed
19th century theories of productive and unproductive labour. In the
transition from traditional to modern societies, all of these questions are
backward-looking to pre- and old-industrial stages of development.
Lost in the circuit
The model of the money circuit raises yet another old issue, that is, the
'loss' of a certain quantity of money in circulation, because money owners
may retain some part of their money rather than spending it or lending it
to others who spend it.
Graziani: 'If wage earners decide to keep part of their savings in the form of
liquid balances … firms will get back from the markets less money than they
have initially injected in it … there has been a loss in the circuit.31
Fontana: 'Circuitists have explained that for any given production process
an increase in money holdings by wage earners is exactly the same as a loss
of liquidity, and hence an equivalent increase in bank debts by firms.'32
In a way this is right, but reminiscent of the notion of hoarding of money in
traditional economies with coin currencies. Graziani actually uses the term
hoarding for that part of savings that are not on-lent or invested by wage
earners on the secondary credit market.33 The subject was treated in
Keynes as the problem of liquidity preference.
Much in this context, however, rather than holding liquidity, is about
avoiding liquidity and debt, or reducing them, respectively. Banks
systematically avoid holding more liquidity than is necessary in order to
make current payments. The actual question here is whether banks—as
primary credit creators—are prepared to lend or invest, supposing there
are potential debtors who appear to be creditworthy and are prepared to
go into debt. Avoidance of currently not necessitated liquidity also applies
31
Graziani 1990 13.
Fontana 2000 43.
33
Graziani 2003 32.
32
21
to nonbank financial intermediaries, real-economic firms and public
households in a similar way.
Private households, too, do not hoard large quantities of cash under the
mattress, and normally there is not much idle money in current bank
accounts either. Rather, money which is currently not needed is parked as
a savings or time deposit in M2/M3, about 10–20% of income in advanced
countries.
What is actually relevant with regard to the thesis of a 'loss in the circuit' is
the fact that M2/M3-positions are non-liquid, even though they can be
liquidated within a couple of weeks or months. (If there are M2-positions
which can be liquidated any time, these are mis-classified positions which
actually belong in M1). M2/M3-positions in fact represent a reduction in
liquid money M1. M2/M3-positions, contrary to popular belief, do not
serve to fund loans or investment. Credits in a savings or time account with
a bank represent inactivated, non-circulating bank money.
It would nevertheless be inadequate to interpret M2/M3-items as 'hoarded
currency'. Rather, M2/M3 is part of the equity of those households,
beneficial to the entire economy, particularly in a life-time or other longrange perspective. With endogenous money, the banking industry—or
whoever else exercises the privileged prerogative of creating money—can
fill any supposed gap in M1.
Liquidity preference is certainly real. It causes a need for maturity
transformation, or tolerated maturity mismatch, respectively. Equally,
liquidity preference represents pro-cyclical behaviour. It waxes and wanes
in the rhythm of economic and financial cycles. However, it does not cause
cycles and crises by itself. Should there really be a 'Circuitist' problem with
regard to absorbing what the firms have produced, this has not necessarily
to do with liquidity preference and liquidity shortage. Nor is it, under
present-day conditions, a fundamental problem when firms have to
borrow additional money in order to finance current business. The central
role ascribed to liquidity preference in Keynesian and Postkeynesian
economics is overdone.
As an alternative to M2/M3-savings, money can be invested in sovereign
and corporate bonds, stocks, and funds of various types. This represents
secondary credit which keeps the bank money circulating in M1, thus
preventing it from being 'lost' in the circuit. The question remains,
nonetheless, whether the money is lost to the real economy. The
secondarily on-lent or invested part of the money supply can serve to fund
real expenditure of firms, government and consumers (as is the case, for
example, with IPOs of bonds and stocks). But the money may also go into
22
non-GDP transactions (such as after-IPO trading of securities as well as
mergers and acquisitions, hostile takeovers, or speculative investment in
foreign exchange, real estate, commodities and derivatives).
In a way, the 'loss' in the money circuit and the supposed liquidity gap
resulting from it, is an analogy to another question that has haunted
theologists and social philosophers for centuries, i.e. the interest gap, the
question of how, with a given money supply, to pay interest on top of
repaying the principal. Circuitism is preoccupied with its version of a
liquidity gap, while not looking into the question of an interest gap.
Discussing the latter might anyway be going too far here. But I would like
to remark that problems such as the Circuitist liquidity gap, or the
Anarchosyndicalist interest gap, represent methodological artefacts
resulting from the reductionist nature of the respective model
considerations.
Is it not simply the case that in a monetarised and financialised economy,
all kinds of expenditure, or income respectively, must initially and
perpetually be funded to a considerable extent? And that with endogenous
money there is basically no reason why this should not be ensured? Things
would be different with exogenous money, but that is not part of our
reality. Whether things may somewhat be different in a post-growth
economy remains to be seen.
Circuitist literature referred to
Fontana, Giuseppe 2000: Post Keynesians and Circuitists on Money and
Uncertainty, Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, Fall 2000, Vol.23,
No.1, 27–48.
Graziani, Augusto 2003: The Monetary Theory of Production, Cambridge
University Press.
Graziani, Augusto 1990: The Theory of the Monetary Circuit, Économies et
Sociétés, No.7, 1990, 7–36.
Parguez, Alain / Seccareccia, Mario 2000: The credit theory of money -The
monetary circuit approach, in J. Smithin (ed), What is Money?,
London/New York: Routledge, 101–123.