Unit 1
Concepts of Managerial Economics
Learning Outcome
After going through this unit, you will be able to:
•
Explain succinctly the meaning and definition of managerial economics
•
Elucidate on the characteristics and scope of managerial economics
•
Describe the techniques of managerial economics
•
Explain the application of managerial economics in various aspects of decision
making
•
Explicate the application of managerial economics in marginal analysis and
optimisation
Time Required to Complete the unit
1.
1st Reading: It will need 3 Hrs for reading a unit
2.
2nd Reading with understanding: It will need 4 Hrs for reading and understanding a
unit
3.
Self Assessment: It will need 3 Hrs for reading and understanding a unit
4.
Assignment: It will need 2 Hrs for completing an assignment
5.
Revision and Further Reading: It is a continuous process
Content Map
1.1
Introduction
1.2
Concept of Managerial Economics
1.2.1 Meaning of Managerial Economics
1.2.2 Definitions of Managerial Economics
Managerial Economics
1
1.2.3 Characteristics of Managerial Economics
1.2.4 Scope of Managerial Economics
1.2.5 Why Managers Need to Know Economics?
1.3
Techniques of Managerial Economics
1.4
Managerial Economics - Its application in Marginal Analysis and Optimisation
1.4.1
Application of Managerial Economics
1.4.2
Tools of Decision Science and Managerial Economics
1.5
Summary
1.6
Self Assessment Test
1.7
Further Reading
2
Managerial Economics
1.1 Introduction
Managerial decisions are an important cog in the working wheel of an organisation.
The success or failure of a business is contingent upon the decisions taken by managers.
Increasing complexity in the business world has spewed forth greater challenges for
managers. Today, no business decision is bereft of influences from areas other than the
economy. Decisions pertinent to production and marketing of goods are shaped with a view
of the world both inside as well as outside the economy. Rapid changes in technology,
greater focus on innovation in products as well as processes that command influence over
marketing and sales techniques have contributed to the escalating complexity in the
business environment. This complex environment is coupled with a global market where
input and product prices are have a propensity to fluctuate and remain volatile. These
factors work in tandem to increase the difficulty in precisely evaluating and determining the
outcome of a business decision. Such evanescent environments give rise to a pressing need
for sound economic analysis prior to making decisions. Managerial economics is a discipline
that is designed to facilitate a solid foundation of economic understanding for business
managers and enable them to make informed and analysed managerial decisions, which are
in keeping with the transient and complex business environment.
1.2 Concept of Managerial Economics
The discipline of managerial economics deals with aspects of economics and tools of
analysis, which are employed by business enterprises for decision-making. Business and
industrial enterprises have to undertake varied decisions that entail managerial issues and
decisions. Decision-making can be delineated as a process where a particular course of
action is chosen from a number of alternatives. This demands an unclouded perception of
the technical and environmental conditions, which are integral to decision making. The
decision maker must possess a thorough knowledge of aspects of economic theory and its
tools of analysis. The basic concepts of decision-making theory have been culled from
microeconomic theory and have been furnished with new tools of analysis. Statistical
methods, for example, are pivotal in estimating current and future demand for products.
The methods of operations research and programming proffer scientific criteria for
maximising profit, minimising cost and determining a viable combination of products.
Managerial Economics
3
Decision-making theory and game theory, which recognise the conditions of uncertainty and
imperfect knowledge under which business managers operate, have contributed to
systematic methods of assessing investment opportunities.
Almost any business decision can be analysed with managerial economics
techniques. However, the most frequent applications of these techniques are as follows:
•
Risk analysis: Various models are used to quantify risk and asymmetric information and
to employ them in decision rules to manage risk.
•
Production analysis: Microeconomic techniques are used to analyse production
efficiency, optimum factor allocation, costs and economies of scale. They are also
utilised to estimate the firm's cost function.
•
Pricing analysis: Microeconomic techniques are employed to examine various pricing
decisions. This involves transfer pricing, joint product pricing, price discrimination, price
elasticity estimations and choice of the optimal pricing method.
•
Capital budgeting: Investment theory is used to scrutinise a firm's capital purchasing
decisions.
1.2.1 MEANING OF MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS
Managerial economics, used synonymously with business economics, is a branch of
economics that deals with the application of microeconomic analysis to decision-making
techniques of businesses and management units. It acts as the via media between economic
theory and pragmatic economics. Managerial economics bridges the gap between 'theoria'
and 'pracis'. The tenets of managerial economics have been derived from quantitative
techniques such as regression analysis, correlation and Lagrangian calculus (linear). An
omniscient and unifying theme found in managerial economics is the attempt to achieve
optimal results from business decisions, while taking into account the firm's objectives,
constraints imposed by scarcity and so on. A paradigm of such optmisation is the use of
operations research and programming.
Managerial economics is thereby a study of application of managerial skills in
economics. It helps in anticipating, determining and resolving potential problems or
obstacles. These problems may pertain to costs, prices, forecasting future market, human
4
Managerial Economics
resource management, profits and so on.
1.2.2 DEFINITIONS OF MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS
McGutgan and Moyer:
“Managerial economics is the application of economic
theory and methodology to decision-making problems
faced by both public and private institutions”.
McNair and Meriam:
“Managerial economics consists of the use of economic
modes of thought to analyse business situations”.
Spencer and Siegelman:
Managerial economics is “the integration of economic
theory with business practice for the purpose of
facilitating decision-making and forward planning by
management”.
Haynes, Mote and Paul:
“Managerial economics refers to those aspects of
economics and its tools of analysis most relevant to the
firm’s
decision-making
process”.
By
definition,
therefore, its scope does not extend to macroeconomic theory and the economics of public policy, an
understanding of which is also essential for the
manager.
Managerial economics studies the application of the principles, techniques and
concepts of economics to managerial problems of business and industrial enterprises. The
term is used interchangeably with business economics, microeconomics, economics of
enterprise, applied economics, managerial analysis and so on. Managerial economics lies at
the junction of economics and business management and traverses the hiatus between the
two disciplines.
Managerial Economics
5
Fig. 1.1: Relation between Economics Business Management and Managerial Economics
1.2.3 CHARACTERISTICS OF MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS
1. Microeconomics: It studies the problems and principles of an individual business firm or
an individual industry. It aids the management in forecasting and evaluating the trends
of the market.
2. Normative economics: It is concerned with varied corrective measures that a
management undertakes under various circumstances. It deals with goal determination,
goal development and achievement of these goals. Future planning, policy-making,
decision-making and optimal utilisation of available resources, come under the banner of
managerial economics.
3. Pragmatic: Managerial economics is pragmatic. In pure micro-economic theory, analysis
is performed, based on certain exceptions, which are far from reality. However, in
managerial economics, managerial issues are resolved daily and difficult issues of
economic theory are kept at bay.
4. Uses theory of firm: Managerial economics employs economic concepts and principles,
which are known as the theory of Firm or 'Economics of the Firm'. Thus, its scope is
narrower than that of pure economic theory.
5. Takes the help of macroeconomics: Managerial economics incorporates certain aspects
of macroeconomic theory. These are essential to comprehending the circumstances and
environments that envelop the working conditions of an individual firm or an industry.
Knowledge of macroeconomic issues such as business cycles, taxation policies, industrial
policy of the government, price and distribution policies, wage policies and antimonopoly policies and so on, is integral to the successful functioning of a business
6
Managerial Economics
enterprise.
6. Aims at helping the management: Managerial economics aims at supporting the
management in taking corrective decisions and charting plans and policies for future.
7. A scientific art: Science is a system of rules and principles engendered for attaining given
ends. Scientific methods have been credited as the optimal path to achieving one's goals.
Managerial economics has been is also called a scientific art because it helps the
management in the best and efficient utilisation of scarce economic resources. It
considers production costs, demand, price, profit, risk etc. It assists the management in
singling out the most feasible alternative. Managerial economics facilitates good and
result oriented decisions under conditions of uncertainty.
8. Prescriptive rather than descriptive: Managerial economics is a normative and applied
discipline. It suggests the application of economic principles with regard to policy
formulation, decision-making and future planning. It not only describes the goals of an
organisation but also prescribes the means of achieving these goals.
1.2.4 SCOPE OF MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS
The scope of managerial economics includes following subjects:
1. Theory of demand
2. Theory of production
3. Theory of exchange or price theory
4. Theory of profit
5. Theory of capital and investment
6. Environmental issues, which are enumerated as follows:
1. Theory of Demand: According to Spencer and Siegelman, “A business firm is an
economic organisation which transforms productivity sources into goods that are to be
sold in a market”.
a. Demand analysis: Analysis of demand is undertaken to forecast demand, which is a
fundamental component in managerial decision-making. Demand forecasting is of
Managerial Economics
7
importance because an estimate of future sales is a primer for preparing production
schedule and employing productive resources. Demand analysis helps the
management in identifying factors that influence the demand for the products of a
firm. Thus, demand analysis and forecasting is of prime importance to business
planning.
b. Demand theory: Demand theory relates to the study of consumer behaviour. It
addresses questions such as what incites a consumer to buy a particular product, at
what price does he/she purchase the product, why do consumers cease consuming a
commodity and so on. It also seeks to determine the effect of the income, habit and
taste of consumers on the demand of a commodity and analyses other factors that
influence this demand.
2. Theory of Production: Production and cost analysis is central for the unhampered
functioning of the production process and for project planning. Production is an
economic activity that makes goods available for consumption. Production is also
defined as a sum of all economic activities besides consumption. It is the process of
creating goods or services by utilising various available resources. Achieving a certain
profit requires the production of a certain amount of goods. To obtain such production
levels, some costs have to be incurred. At this point, the management is faced with the
task of determining an optimal level of production where the average cost of production
would be minimum. Production function shows the relationship between the quantity of
a good/service produced (output) and the factors or resources (inputs) used. The inputs
employed for producing these goods and services are called factors of production.
a. Variable factor of production: The input level of a variable factor of production can
be varied in the short run. Raw material inputs are deemed as variable factors.
Unskilled labour is also considered in the category of variable factors.
b. Fixed factor of production: The input level of a fixed factor cannot be varied in the
short run. Capital falls under the category of a fixed factor. Capital alludes to
resources such as buildings, machinery etc.
Production theory facilitates in determining the size of firm and the level of
production. It elucidates the relationship between average and marginal costs and
8
Managerial Economics
production. It highlights how a change in production can bring about a parallel change in
average and marginal costs. Production theory also deals with other issues such as
conditions leading to increase or decrease in costs, changes in total production when one
factor of production is varied and others are kept constant, substitution of one factor with
another while keeping all increased simultaneously and methods of achieving optimum
production.
3. Theory of Exchange or Price Theory: Theory of Exchange is popularly known as Price
Theory. Price determination under different types of market conditions comes under the
wingspan of this theory. It helps in determining the level to which an advertisement can
be used to boost market sales of a firm. Price theory is pivotal in determining the price
policy of a firm. Pricing is an important area in managerial economics. The accuracy of
pricing decisions is vital in shaping the success of an enterprise. Price policy impresses
upon the demand of products. It involves the determination of prices under different
market conditions, pricing methods, pricing policies, differential pricing, product line
pricing and price forecasting.
4. Theory of profit: Every business and industrial enterprise aims at maximising profit.
Profit is the difference between total revenue and total economic cost. Profitability of an
organisation is greatly influenced by the following factors:
•
Demand of the product
•
Prices of the factors of production
•
Nature and degree of competition in the market
•
Price behaviour under changing conditions
Hence, profit planning and profit management are important requisites for
improving profit earning efficiency of the firm. Profit management involves the use of most
efficient technique for predicting the future. The probability of risks should be minimised as
far as possible.
5. Theory of Capital and Investment: Theory of Capital and Investment evinces the
following important issues:
•
Selection of a viable investment project
• Efficient allocation of capital
Managerial Economics
9
•
Assessment of the efficiency of capital
•
Minimising the possibility of under capitalisation or overcapitalisation. Capital is the
building block of a business. Like other factors of production, it is also scarce and
expensive. It should be allocated in most efficient manner.
6. Environmental issues: Managerial economics also encompasses some aspects of
macroeconomics. These relate to social and political environment in which a business
and industrial firm has to operate. This is governed by the following factors:
•
The type of economic system of the country
•
Business cycles
•
Industrial policy of the country
•
Trade and fiscal policy of the country
•
Taxation policy of the country
•
Price and labour policy
•
General trends in economy concerning the production, employment, income, prices,
saving and investment etc.
•
General trends in the working of financial institutions in the country
•
General trends in foreign trade of the country
•
Social factors like value system of the society
•
General attitude and significance of social organisations like trade unions, producers’
unions and consumers’ cooperative societies etc.
•
Social structure and class character of various social groups
•
Political system of the country
The management of a firm cannot exercise control over these factors. Therefore, it
should fashion the plans, policies and programmes of the firm according to these factors in
order to offset their adverse effects on the firm.
1.2.5 WHY MANAGERS NEED TO KNOW ECONOMICS
The contribution of economics towards the performance of managerial duties and
responsibilities is of prime importance. The contribution and importance of economics to
the managerial profession is akin to the contribution of biology to the medical profession
and physics to engineering. It has been observed that managers equipped with a working
knowledge of economics surpass their otherwise equally qualified peers, who lack
10
Managerial Economics
knowledge of economics. Managers are responsible for achieving the objective of the firm to
the maximum possible extent with the limited resources placed at their disposal. It is
important to note that maximisation of objective has to be achieved by utilising limited
resources. In the event of resources being unlimited, like air or sunshine, the problem of
economic utilisation of resources or resource management would not have arisen.
Resources like finance, workforce and material are limited. However, in the absence of
unlimited resources, it is the responsibility of the management to optimise the use of these
resources.
•
How economics contributes to managerial functions
Though economics is variously defined, it is essentially the study of logic, tools and
techniques, to make optimum use of the available resources to achieve the given ends.
Economics affords analytical tools and techniques that managers require to accomplish the
goals of the organisation they manage. Therefore, a working knowledge of economics, not
necessarily a formal degree, is indispensable for managers. Managers are fundamentally
practicing economists.
While executing his duties, a manager has to take several decisions, which conform
to the objectives of the firm. Many business decisions fall prey to conditions of uncertainty
and risk. Uncertainty and risk arise chiefly due to volatile market forces, changing business
environment, emerging competitors with highly competitive products, government policy,
external influences on the domestic market and social and political changes in the country.
The intricacy of the modern business world weaves complexity in to the decision making
process of a business. However, the degree of uncertainty and risk can be greatly condensed
if market conditions are calculated with a high degree of reliability. Envisaging a business
environment in the future does not suffice. Appropriate business decisions and formulation
of a business strategy in conformity with the goals of the firm hold similar importance.
Pertinent business decisions require an unambiguous understanding of the technical
and environmental conditions under which business decisions are taken. Application of
economic theories to explain and analyse technical conditions and business environment,
contributes greatly to the rational decision-making process. Economic theories have many
pronged applications in the analysis of practical problems of business. Keeping in view the
escalating complexity of business environment, the efficacy of economic theory as a tool of
analysis and its contribution to the process of decision-making has been widely recognised.
•
Contributions of economic theory to business economics
According to Baumol, there are three main contributions of economic theory to
business economics.
1. The practice of building analytical models, which assist in recognising the structure of
Managerial Economics
11
managerial problems and eliminating minor details, which might obstruct decisionmaking has been derived from economic theory. Analytical models help in eradicating
peripheral problems and help the management in retaining focus on core issues.
2. Economic theory comprises a founding pillar of business analysis- ‘a set of analytical
methods’, which may not be applied directly to specific business problems, but they do
enhance the analytical capabilities of the business analyst.
3. Economic theories offer an unequivocal perspective on the various concepts used in
business analysis, which enables the manager to swerve from conceptual pitfalls.
•
Importance of managerial economics
Business and industrial enterprises aim at earning maximum proceeds. In order to
achieve this objective, a managerial executive has to take recourse in decision-making,
which is the process of selecting a specified course of action from a number of alternatives.
A sound decision requires fair knowledge of the aspects of economic theory and the tools of
economic analysis, which are directly involved in the process of decision-making. Since
managerial economics is concerned with such aspects and tools of analysis, it is pertinent to
the decision-making process.
Spencer and Siegelman have described the importance of managerial economics in a
business and industrial enterprise as follows:
1. Accommodating traditional theoretical concepts to the actual business behaviour and
conditions: Managerial economics amalgamates tools, techniques, models and theories
of traditional economics with actual business practices and with the environment in
which a firm has to operate. According to Edwin Mansfield, “Managerial Economics
attempts to bridge the gap between purely analytical problems that intrigue many
economic theories and the problems of policies that management must face”.
2. Estimating economic relationships: Managerial economics estimates economic
relationships between different business factors such as income, elasticity of demand,
cost volume, profit analysis etc.
3. Predicting
relevant
economic
quantities:
Managerial
economics
assists
the
management in predicting various economic quantities such as cost, profit, demand,
capital, production, price etc. As a business manager has to function in an environment
of uncertainty, it is imperative to anticipate the future working environment in terms of
the said quantities.
4. Understanding significant external forces: The management has to identify all the
important factors that influence a firm. These factors can broadly be divided into two
categories. Managerial economics plays an important role by assisting management in
understanding these factors.
12
Managerial Economics
•
External factors: A firm cannot exercise any control over these factors. The plans,
policies and programmes of the firm should be formulated in the light of these
factors. Significant external factors impinging on the decision-making process of a
firm are economic system of the country, business cycles, fluctuations in national
income and national production, industrial policy of the government, trade and fiscal
policy of the government, taxation policy, licensing policy, trends in foreign trade of
the country, general industrial relation in the country and so on.
•
Internal factors: These factors fall under the control of a firm. These factors are
associated with business operation. Knowledge of these factors aids the
management in making sound business decisions.
5. Basis of business policies: Managerial economics is the founding principle of business
policies. Business policies are prepared based on studies and findings of managerial
economics, which cautions the management against potential upheavals in national as
well as international economy.
Thus, managerial economics is helpful to the management in its decision-making
process.
Study Notes
Assessment
Answer the followings in detail:
1. What do you understand by Managerial Economics? Give Definition and meaning of
Managerial Economics.
2. What are the characteristics and scope of Managerial Economics?
Managerial Economics
13
Discussion
What is the relation between Economics, Business Management and Managerial
Economics? Discuss.
1.3 Techniques of Managerial Economics
Managerial economics draws on a wide variety of economic concepts, tools and
techniques in the decision-making process. These concepts can be categorised as follows: (1)
the theory of the firm, which explains how businesses make a variety of decisions; (2) the
theory of consumer behavior, which describes the consumer's decision-making process and
(3) the theory of market structure and pricing, which describes the structure and
characteristics of different market forms under which business firms operate.
1. Theory of the firm: A firm can be considered an amalgamation of people, physical and
financial resources and a variety of information. Firms exist because they perform useful
functions in society by producing and distributing goods and services. In the process of
accomplishing this, they employ society's scarce resources, provide employment and pay
taxes. If economic activities of society can be simply put into two categories- production
and consumption- firms are considered the most basic economic entities on the
production side, while consumers form the basic economic entities on the consumption
side. The behaviour of firms is usually analysed in the context of an economic model,
which is an idealised version of a real-world firm. The basic economic model of a
business enterprise is called the theory of the firm.
2. Theory of consumer behaviour: The role of consumers in an economy is of vital
importance since consumers spend most of their incomes on goods and services
produced by firms. Consumers consume what firms produce. Thus, study of the theory
of consumer behaviour is accorded importance. It is desirous to know the ultimate
objective of a consumer. Economists have an optimisation model for consumers, which
is analogous to that applied to firms or producers. While it is assumed that firms attempt
at maximising profits, similarly there is an assumption that consumers attempt at
14
Managerial Economics
maximising their utility or satisfaction. While more goods and services provide greater
utility to a consumer, however, consumers, like firms, are subject to constraints. Their
consumption and choices are limited by a number of factors, including the amount of
disposable income (the residual income after income taxes are paid for). A consumer's
choice to consume is described by economists within a theoretical framework usually
termed the theory of demand.
3. Theories associated with different market structures: A firms profit maximising output
decisions take into account the market structure under which they are operate. There
are four kinds of market organisations: perfect competition, monopolistic competition,
oligopoly and monopoly.
All the above theories are analysed with the help a vast and varied quantitative tools and
techniques.
Study Notes
Assessment
What are the tools and techniques of Managerial Economics?
Managerial Economics
15
Discussion
Discuss Theory of Consumer Behaviour in detail.
1.4 Managerial Economics - Its application in Marginal Analysis
and Optimisation
1.4.1 APPLICATION OF MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS
Tools of managerial economics can be used to achieve virtually all the goals of a
business organisation in an efficient manner. Typical managerial decision-making may
involve one of the following issues:
•
Decisions pertaining to the price of a product and the quantity of the commodity to be
produced
•
Decisions
regarding
manufacturing
product/part/component
or
outsourcing
to/purchasing from another manufacturer
•
Choosing the production technique to be employed in the production of a given product
•
Decisions relating to the level of inventory of a product or raw material a firm will
maintain
•
Decisions regarding the medium of advertising and the intensity of the advertising
campaign
•
Decisions pertinent to employment and training
•
Decisions regarding further business investment and the modes of financing the
investment
It should be noted that the application of managerial economics is not restricted to
profit-seeking business organisations. Tools of managerial economics can be applied equally
well to decision problems of nonprofit organisations. Mark Hirschey and James L. Pappas
cite the example of a nonprofit hospital making use of the managerial economics techniques
for optimisation of resource use. While a nonprofit hospital is not like a typical firm seeking
to maximise its profits, a hospital does strive to provide its patients the best medical care
possible given its limited staff (doctors, nurses and support staff), equipment, space and
other resources. The hospital administrator can employ concepts and tools of managerial
economics to determine the optimal allocation of the limited resources available to the
hospital. In addition to nonprofit business organisations, government agencies and other
16
Managerial Economics
nonprofit organisations (such as cooperatives, schools and museums) can exploit the
techniques of managerial decision making to achieve goals in the most efficient manner.
While managerial economics aids in making optimal decisions, one should be aware
that it only describes the predictable economic consequences of a managerial decision. For
example, tools of managerial economics can explain the effects of imposing automobile
import quotas on the availability of domestic cars, prices charged for automobiles and the
extent of competition in the auto industry. Analysis of managerial economics reveals that
fewer cars will be available, prices of automobiles will increase and the extent of
competition will be reduced. However, managerial economics does not address whether
imposing automobile import quotas is a good government policy. This question
encompasses broader political considerations involving what economists call value
judgments.
1.4.2 TOOLS OF DECISION SCIENCE AND MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS
Managerial decision-making draws on economic concepts as well as tools and
techniques of analysis provided by decision sciences. The major categories of these tools
and techniques are optimisation, statistical estimation, forecasting, numerical analysis and
game theory. Most of these methodologies are technical. The first three are briefly
explained below to illustrate how tools of decision sciences are used in managerial decisionmaking.
1. Optimisation: Optimisation techniques are probably the most crucial to managerial
decision making. Given that alternative courses of action are available, the manager
attempts to produce the most optimal decision, consistent with stated managerial
objectives. Thus, an optimisation problem can be stated as maximising an objective
(called the objective function by mathematicians) subject to specified constraints. In
determining the output level consistent with the maximum profit, the firm maximises
profits, constrained by cost and capacity considerations. While a manager does not
resolve the optimisation problem, he or she may make use of the results of
mathematical analysis. In the profit maximisation example, the profit maximising
condition requires that the firm select the production level at which marginal revenue
equals marginal cost. This condition is obtained from an optimisation model/technique.
The techniques of optimisation employed depend on the problem a manager is trying to
solve.
Managerial Economics
17
2. Statistical estimation: A number of statistical techniques are used to estimate economic
variables of interest to a manager. In some cases, statistical estimation techniques
employed are simple. In other cases, they are much more complex and advanced. Thus,
a manager may want to know the average price received by his competitors in the
industry, as well as the standard deviation (a measure of variation across units) of the
product price under consideration. In this case, the simple statistical concepts of mean
(average) and standard deviation are used.
Estimating a relationship among variables requires a more advanced statistical
technique. For example, a firm may desire to estimate its cost function i.e. the relationship
between cost concept and the level of output. A firm may also wish to the demand function
of its product that is the relationship between the demand for its product and factors that
influence it. The estimates of costs and demand are usually based on data supplied by the
firm. The statistical estimation technique employed is called regression analysis and is used
to engender a mathematical model showing how a set of variables are related. This
mathematical relationship can also be used to generate forecasts.
An example from the automobile industry is befitting for illustrating the forecasting method
that employs simple regression analysis. Let us assume that a statistician has data on sales of
American-made automobiles in the United States for the last 25 years. He or she has also
determined that the sale of automobiles is related to the real disposable income of
individuals. The statistician also has available the time series data (for the last 25 years) on
real disposable income. Assume that the relationship between the time series on sales of
American-made automobiles and the real disposable income of consumers is actually linear
and it can thus be represented by a straight line. A rigorous mathematical technique is used
to locate the straight line that most accurately represents the relationship between the time
series on auto sales and disposable income.
3. Forecasting: It is a method or a technique to predict many future aspects of a business or
any other operation. For example, a retailing firm that has been in business for the last
25 years may be interested in forecasting the likely sales volume for the coming year.
Numerous forecasting techniques can be used to accomplish this goal. A forecasting
technique, for example, can provide such a projection based on the experience of the
firm during the last 25 years; that is, this forecasting technique bases the future forecast
on the past data.
18
Managerial Economics
While the term 'forecasting' may appear technical, planning for the future is a critical
aspect of managing any organisation or a business. The long-term success of any
organisation has close association with the propensity of the management of the
organisation to foresee its future and develop appropriate strategies to deal with the likely
future scenarios. Intuition, good judgment and knowledge of economic conditions enables
the manager to 'feel' or perhaps anticipate the likelihood in the future. It is not easy,
however, to metamorphose a feeling about the future outcome into concrete data for
instance, as a projection for next year's sales volume. Forecasting methods can help predict
many future aspects of a business operation, such as forthcoming years' sales volume
projections.
Suppose a forecast expert has been asked to provide quarterly estimates of the sales
volume for a particular product for the next four quarters. How should he attempt at
preparing the quarterly sales volume forecasts? Reviewing the actual sales data for the
product in question for past periods will give a good start. Suppose that the forecaster has
access to actual sales data for each quarter during the 25-year period the firm has been in
business. Employing this historical data, the forecaster can identify the general trend of
sales. He or she can also determine whether there is a pattern or trend, such as an increase
or decrease in sales volume over time. An in depth review of the data may unearth some
type of seasonal pattern, such as, peak sales occurring around the holiday season. Thus, by
reviewing historical data, there is a high probability that the forecaster develops a good
understanding of the pattern of sales in the past periods. Understanding such patterns can
result in better forecasts of future sales of the product. In addition, if the forecaster is able
to identify the factors that influence sales, historical data on these factors (variables) can
also be used to generate forecasts of future sales.
There are many forecasting techniques available to the person assisting the business
in planning its sales. Take for example a forecasting method in which a statistician
forecasting future values of a variable of business interest—sales, for example, examines the
cause-and-effect relationships of this variable with other relevant variables. The other
pertinent variable may be the level of consumer confidence, changes in consumers'
disposable incomes, the interest rate at which consumers can finance their excess spending
through borrowing and the state of the economy represented by the percentage of the
labour force unemployed. This category of forecasting technique utilises time series data on
many relevant variables to forecast the volume of sales in the future. Under this forecasting
Managerial Economics
19
technique, a regression equation is estimated to generate future forecasts (based on the
past relationship among variables).
Study Notes
Assessment
1. Explain how Managerial Economics is applied in Marginal Analysis?
2. Explain Optimization.
Discussion
Discuss Forecasting as a tool
OF DECISION SCIENCE AND MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS.
1.5 Summary
Managerial Economics: The discipline of managerial economics deals with aspects of
economics and tools of analysis, which are employed by business enterprises for decision
making. Business and industrial enterprises have to undertake varied decisions that entail
managerial issues and decisions. Decision-making can be delineated as a process where a
particular course of action is chosen from a number of alternatives. This demands an
20
Managerial Economics
unclouded perception of the technical and environmental conditions, which are integral to
decision making. The decision maker must possess a thorough knowledge of aspects of
economic theory and its tools of analysis, which are integral to decision making. The basic
concepts have been culled from microeconomic theory and have been furnished with new
tools of analysis.
Characteristics of Managerial Economics: Following are the characteristics of managerial
economics:
•
Microeconomics
•
Normative economics
•
Pragmatic
•
Uses theory of firm
•
Takes the help of macroeconomics
•
Aims at helping the management
•
A scientific art
•
Prescriptive rather than descriptive
Scope of managerial economics: The scope of managerial economics includes
following subjects: 1) Theory of Demand 2) Theory of Production 3) Theory of Exchange or
Price Theory 4) Theory of Profit 5) Theory of Capital and Investment 6) Environmental Issues
Importance of managerial economics: Spencer and Siegelman have described the
importance of managerial economics in a business and industrial enterprise as follows:
•
Reconciling traditional theoretical concepts to the actual business behaviour and
conditions
•
Estimating economic relationships
•
Predicting relevant economic quantities
•
Understanding significant external forces
•
Basis of business policies
Techniques of managerial economics: Managerial economics uses a wide variety of
economic concepts, tools and techniques in the decision-making process. These concepts
can be enlisted as follows:
•
The theory of the firm, which elucidates how businesses make a variety of decisions
Managerial Economics
21
•
The theory of consumer behaviour, which describes decision making by consumers
•
The theory of market structure and pricing, which opens a window into the structure and
characteristics of different market forms under which business firms operate
1.6 Self Assessment Test
Broad Questions
1. Explain concept and techniques of managerial economics.
2. How is Managerial Economics applied in analysis and decision-making?
3. Why managers need to know economics? Explain the importance of managerial
economics.
Short Notes
a. Meaning and definition of managerial economics
b. Application of managerial economics
c. Theories of managerial economics
d. Characteristics of managerial economics
e. Optimisation and forecasting in managerial economics
1.7 Further Reading
1. A Modern Micro Economics, Koutsoyiannis, Macmillan, 1991
2. Business Economics, Adhikary M, Excel Books, 2000
3. Economics Theory and Operations Analysis, Baumol W. J., Ed. 3, Prentice Hall Inc, 1996
4. Managerial Economics, Chopra O P., Tata McGraw Hill, 1985
5. Managerial Economics, Keat Paul G & Philips K Y Young, Prentice Hall, 1996
6. Economics Organisation and Management, Milgrom P and Roberts J, Prentice Hall Inc,
1992
7. Managerial Economics, Maheshwari Yogesh, Sultanchand & Sons, 2009
8. Managerial Economics, Varshney R L., Sultanchand & Sons, 2007
9. Managerial Economics, Suma Damodaran, Oxford, 2006
22
Managerial Economics
Assignment
•
What are the principles of managerial economics? How far are these principles followed
in present managerial economic scenarios?
•
Why is demand estimation and forecast important for managerial decision- making?
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
Managerial Economics
23
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
Managerial Economics
24
Unit 2
Theory of Demand
Learning Outcome
After going through this unit, you will be able to:
•
Explain meaning and concept of demand
•
Elucidate on Law of Demand and Elasticity of Demand
•
Identify Demand Functions
•
List Determinant factors of Elasticity of Demand
•
Carry out Demand Forecasting
Time Required to Complete the unit
1.
1st Reading: It will need 3 Hrs for reading a unit
2.
2nd Reading with understanding: It will need 4 Hrs for reading and understanding a
unit
3.
Self Assessment: It will need 3 Hrs for reading and understanding a unit
4.
Assignment: It will need 2 Hrs for completing an assignment
5.
Revision and Further Reading: It is a continuous process
Content Map
2.1
Introduction
2.2
Theory of Demand
2.2.1 Essentials of Demand
2.2.2 Law of Demand
2.3
Demand Function
Managerial Economics
25
2.4
Elasticity of Demand
2.4.1 Price Elasticity of Demand
2.4.2 Point and Arc Elasticity of Demand
2.4.3 Nature of Demand Curves and Elasticity
2.4.4 Slope of the Demand Curve and Price Elasticity
2.4.5 Price Elasticity and Marginal revenue
2.4.6 Price Elasticity and Consumption Expenditure
2.4.7 Cross-Elasticity of Demand
2.4.8 Income Elasticity of Demand
2.5
Determinants of Demand
2.6
Demand Forecasting
2.6.1 Demand Forecast and Sales Forecast
2.6.2 Components of Demand Forecasting System
2.6.3 Objectives of Demand Forecast
2.6.4 Importance of Demand Forecast
2.6.5 Methods of Demand Forecast
2.6.6 Some demand forecasting methods
2.6.7 Methods of Estimation
2.7
Summary
2.8
Self Assessment Test
2.9
Further Reading
26
Managerial Economics
2.1 Introduction
Demand theory evinces the relationship between the demand for goods and
services. Demand theory is the building block of the demand curve- a curve that establishes
a relationship between consumer demand and the amount of goods available. Demand is
shaped by the availability of goods, as the quantity of goods increases in the market the
demand and the equilibrium price for those goods decreases as a result.
Demand theory is one of the core theories of microeconomics and consumer
behaviour. It attempts at answering questions regarding the magnitude of demand for a
product or service based on its importance to human wants. It also attempts to assess how
demand is impacted by changes in prices and income levels and consumers
preferences/utility. Based on the perceived utility of goods and services to consumers,
companies are able to adjust the supply available and the prices charged.
In economics, demand has a specific meaning distinct from its ordinary usage. In
common language we treat ‘demand’ and ‘desire’ as synonymously. This is incongruent from
its use in economics. In economics, demand refers to effective demand which implies three
things:
•
Desire for a commodity
•
Sufficient money to purchase the commodity, rather the ability to pay
•
Willingness to spend money to acquire that commodity
This substantiates that a want or a desire does not develop into a demand unless it is
supported by the ability and the willingness to acquire it. For instance, a person may desire
to own a scooter but unless he has the required amount of money with him and the
willingness to spend that amount on the purchase of a scooter, his desire shall not become a
demand. The following should also be noted about demand:
•
Demand always alludes to demand at price. The term ‘demand’ has no meaning
unless it is related to price. For instance, the statement, 'the weekly demand for
potatoes in city X is 10,000 kilograms' has no meaning unless we specify the price at
which this quantity is demanded.
• Demand always implies demand per unit of time. Therefore, it is vital to specify the
Managerial Economics
27
period for which the commodity is demanded. For instance, the statement that
demand for potatoes in city X at Rs. 8 per kilogram is 10,000 kilograms again has no
meaning, unless we state the period for which the quantity is being demanded. A
complete statement would therefore be as follows: 'The weekly demand for
potatoes in city X at Rs. 8 per kilogram is 10,000 kilograms'. It is necessary to specify
the period and the price because demand for a commodity will be different at
different prices of that commodity and for different periods of time. Thus, we can
define demand as follows:
“The demand for a commodity at a given price is the amount of it which will be
bought per unit of time at that price”.
2.2 Theory of Demand
2.2.1 ESSENTIALS OF DEMAND
1. An Effective Need: Effective need entails that there should be a need supported by the
capacity and readiness to shell out. Hence, there are three basics of an effective need:
a. The individual should have a need to acquire a specific product.
b. He should have sufficient funds to pay for that product.
c. He should be willing to part with these resources for that commodity.
2. A Specific Price: A proclamation concerning the demand of a product without
mentioning its price is worthless. For example, to state that the demand of cars is 10,000
is worthless, unless expressed that the demand of cars is 10,000 at a price of Rs. 4,
00,000 each.
3. A Specific Time: Demand must be assigned specific time. For example, it is an
incomplete proclamation to state that the demand of air conditioners is 4,000 at the
price of Rs. 12,800 each. The statement should be altered to say that the demand of air
conditioners during summer is 4,000 at the price of Rs. 12,800 each.
4. A Specific Place: The demand must relate to a specific market as well. For example,
every year in the town of Dehradun, the demand for school bags is 4,000 at a price of Rs.
200.
Hence, the demand of a product is an effective need, which demonstrates the
quantity of a product that will be bought at a specific price in a specific market at some
28
Managerial Economics
stage in a specific period. Nevertheless, the significance of a specific market or place is
not as significant as the price and time period for which demand is being measured.
2.2.2 LAW OF DEMAND
We have considered various factors that fashion the demand for a commodity. As
explained the first and the most important factor that determines the demand of a
commodity is its price. If all other factors (noted above) remain constant, it may be said that
as the price of a commodity increases, its demand decreases and as the price of a
commodity decreases its demand increases. This is a general behaviour observed in a
market. This gives us the law of demand:
“The demand for a commodity increases with a fall in its price and decreases with a rise in its
price, other things remaining the same”.
The law of demand thus merely states that the price and demand of a commodity are
inversely related, provided all other things remain unchanged or as economists put it ceteris
paribus.
•
Assumptions of the Law of Demand
The above statement of the law of demand, demonstrates that that this law operates
only when all other things remain constant. These are then the assumptions of the law of
demand. We can state the assumptions of the law of demand as follows:
1. Income level should remain constant: The law of demand operates only when the
income level of the buyer remains constant. If the income rises while the price of the
commodity does not fall, it is quite likely that the demand may increase. Therefore,
stability in income is an essential condition for the operation of the law of demand.
2. Tastes of the buyer should not alter: Any alteration that takes place in the taste of the
consumers will in all probability thwart the working of the law of demand. It often
happens that when tastes or fashions change people revise their preferences. As a
consequence, the demand for the commodity which goes down the preference scale of
the consumers declines even though its price does not change.
3. Prices of other goods should remain constant: Changes in the prices of other goods
often impinge on the demand for a particular commodity. If prices of commodities for
which demand is inelastic rise, the demand for a commodity other than these in all
probability will decline even though there may not be any change in its price. Therefore,
for the law of demand to operate it is imperative that prices of other goods do not
change.
Managerial Economics
29
4. No new substitutes for the commodity: If some new substitutes for a commodity
appear in the market, its demand generally declines. This is quite natural, because with
the availability of new substitutes some buyers will be attracted towards new products
and the demand for the older product will fall even though price remains unchanged.
Hence, the law of demand operates only when the market for a commodity is not
threatened by new substitutes.
5. Price rise in future should not be expected: If the buyers of a commodity expect that its
price will rise in future they raise its demand in response to an initial price rise. This
behaviour of buyers violates the law of demand. Therefore, for the operation of the law
of demand it is necessary that there must not be any expectations of price rise in the
future.
6. Advertising expenditure should remain the same: If the advertising expenditure of a
firm increases, the consumers may be tempted to buy more of its product. Therefore,
the advertising expenditure on the good under consideration is taken to be constant.
Desire of a person to purchase a commodity is not his demand. He must possess
adequate resources and must be willing to spend his resources to buy the commodity.
Besides, the quantity demanded has always a reference to ‘a price’ and ‘a unity of time’. The
quantity demanded referred to ‘per unit of time’ makes it a flow concept. There may be
some problems in applying this flow concept to the demand for durable consumer goods like
house, car, refrigerators, etc. However, this apparent difficulty may be resolved by
considering the total service of a durable good is not consumed at one point of time and its
utility is not exhausted in a single use. The service of a durable good is consumed over time.
At a time, only a part of its service is consumed. Therefore, the demand for the services of
durable consumer goods may also be visualised as a demand per unit of time. However, this
problem does not arise when the concept of demand is applied to total demand for a
consumer durable. Thus, the demand for consumer goods also is a flow concept.
•
Demand Schedule
The law of demand can be illustrated through a demand schedule. A demand
schedule is a series of quantities, which consumers would like to buy per unit of time at
different prices. To illustrate the law of demand, an imaginary demand schedule for tea is
given in Table 2.1. It shows seven alternative prices and the corresponding quantities
(number of cups of tea) demand per day. Each price has a unique quantity demanded,
associated with it. As the price per cup of tea decreases, daily demand for tea increases, in
accordance with the law of demand.
30
Managerial Economics
Table 2.1: Demand Schedule for Tea
Price per Cup of Tea (Rs.)
No. of Cups of Tea Demand Symbols representing per
per Consumer per Day
Price-Quantity Combination
8
2
A
7
3
B
6
4
C
5
5
D
4
6
E
3
7
F
2
8
G
•
Demand Curve
The law of demand can also be presented through a curve called demand curve.
Demand curve is a locus of points showing various alterative price-quantity combinations. It
shows the quantities of a commodity that consumers or users would buy at difference prices
per unit of time under the assumptions of the law of demand. An individual demand curve
for tea as given in Fig. 2.1 can be obtained by plotting the data give in Table 2.1.
Managerial Economics
31
In Fig. 2.1, the curve from point A to point G passing through points B, C, D and F is
the demand curve DD’. Each point on the demand curve DD’ shows a unique price-quantity
combination. The combinations read in alphabetical order should decreasing price of tea
and increasing number of cups of tea demanded per day. Price quantity combinations in
reverse order of alphabets illustrate increasing price of tea per cup and decreasing number
of cups of tea per day consumed by an individual. The whole demand curve shows a
functional relationship between the alternative price of a commodity and its corresponding
quantities, which a consumer would like to buy during a specific period of item—per day,
per week, per month, per season, or per year. The demand curve shows an inverse
relationship between price and quantity demanded. This inverse relationship between price
and quantity demanded results in the demand curve sloping downward to the right.
•
Why does the demand curve slope downwards
As Fig. 2.1 shows, demand curve slopes downward to the right. The downward slope
of the demand curve reads the law of demand i.e. the quantity of a commodity demanded
per unit of time increases as its price falls and vice versa.
The reasons behind the law of demand i.e. inverse relationship between price and
quantity demanded are following:
Substitution Effect: When the price of a commodity falls it becomes relatively cheaper if
price of all other related goods, particularly of substitutes, remain constant. In other
words, substitute goods become relatively costlier. Since consumers substitute cheaper
goods for costlier ones, demand for the relatively cheaper commodity increases. The
increase in demand on account of this factor is known as substitution effect.
Income Effect: As a result of fall in the price of a commodity, the real income of its
consumer increase at least in terms of this commodity. In other words, his/her
purchasing power increases since he is required to pay less for the same quantity. The
increase in real income (or purchasing power) encourages demand for the commodity
with reduced price. The increase in demand on account of increase in real income is
known as income effect. It should however be noted that the income effect is negative in
case of inferior goods. In case, price of an inferior good accounting for a considerable
proportion of the total consumption expenditure falls substantially, consumers’ real
income increases: they become relatively richer. Consequently, they substitute the
superior good for the inferior ones, i.e., they reduce the consumption of inferior goods.
Thus, the income effect on the demand for inferior goods becomes negative.
32
Managerial Economics
Diminishing Marginal Utility: Diminishing marginal utility as well is to be held
responsible for the rise in demand for a product when its price declines. When an
individual purchases a product, he swaps his money revenue with the product in order to
increase his satisfaction. He continues to purchase goods and services as long as the
marginal utility of money (MUm) is lesser than the marginal utility of the commodity
(MUC). Given the price of a commodity, he modifies his purchase so that MUC = MUm.
This plan works well under both Marshallian assumption of constant MUm as well as
Hicksian assumption of diminishing MUm. When price falls, (MUm = Pc) < MUC. Thus,
equilibrium state is upset. To get back his equilibrium state, i.e., MUm = PC, = MUC, he
buys more quantities of the commodity. For, when the supply of a commodity rises, its
MU falls and once again MUm = MUC. For this reason, demand for a product rises when
its price falls.
•
Exceptions to the Law of Demand
The law of demand does not apply to the following cases:
Apprehensions about the future price: When consumers anticipate a constant rise in
the price of a long-lasting commodity, they purchase more of it despite the price rise.
They do so with the intention of avoiding the blow of still higher prices in the future.
Likewise, when consumers expect a substantial fall in the price in the future, they delay
their purchases and hold on for the price to decrease to the anticipated level instead of
purchasing the commodity as soon as its price decreases. These kinds of choices made by
the consumers are in contradiction of the law of demand.
Status goods: The law does not concern the commodities which function as a ‘status
symbol’, add to the social status or exhibit prosperity and opulence e.g. gold, precious
stones, rare paintings and antiques, etc. Rich people mostly purchase such goods as they
are very costly.
Giffen goods: An exception to this law is the typical case of Giffen goods named after Sir
Robert Giffen (1837-1910). 'Giffen goods' does not represent any particular commodity.
It could be any low-grade commodity which is cheap as compared to its superior
alternatives, consumed generally by the lower income group families as an important
consumer good. If price of such goods rises (price of its alternative remaining stable), its
demand escalates instead of falling. E.g. the minimum consumption of food grains by a
lower income group family per month is 30 kgs consisting of 20 kgs of bajra (a low-grade
good) at the rate of Rs 10 per kg and 10 kgs of wheat (a high quality good) at Rs. 20 per
kg. They have a fixed expenditure of Rs. 400 on these items. However, if the price of
Managerial Economics
33
bajra rises to Rs. 12 per kg the family will be compelled to decrease the consumption of
wheat by 5 kgs and add to that of bajra by the same quantity so as to meet its minimum
consumption requisite within Rs. 400 per month. No doubt, the family's demand for
bajra rises from 20 to 25 kgs when its price rises.
•
The Market Demand Curve
The quantity of a commodity which an individual is willing to buy at a particular price
of the commodity during a specific time period, given his money income, his taste and prices
of substitutes and complements, is known as individual demand for a commodity. The total
quantity which all the consumers of a commodity are willing to buy at a given price per time
unit, other things remaining the same, is known as market demand for the commodity. In
other words, the market demand for a commodity is the sum of individual demands by all
the consumers (or buyers) of the commodity, per time unit and at a given price, other
factors remaining the same. For instance, suppose there are three consumers (viz., A, B, C)
of a commodity X and their individual demand at different prices is of X as given in Table 2.2.
The last column presents the market demand i.e. the aggregate of individual demand by
three consumers at different prices.
Table 2.2: Price and Quantity Demanded
Price
of Quantity of X demanded by
Commodity
Market Demand
X
A
B
C
10
4
2
0
6
8
8
4
0
12
6
12
6
2
20
4
16
8
4
28
2
20
10
6
36
0
24
12
8
44
(Price per unit)
Graphically, market demand curve is the horizontal summation of individual demand
curves. The individual demand schedules plotted graphically and summed up horizontally
gives the market demand curve as shown in Fig. 2.2.
34
Managerial Economics
The individual demands for commodity X are given by DA, DB and Dc, respectively. The
horizontal summation of these individual demand curves results into the market demand
curve (DM) for the commodity X. The curve DM represents the market demand curve for
commodity X when there are only three consumers of the commodity.
Fig. 2.2: Derivation of market demand
Study Notes
Assessment
1.
What are the essentials of a Demand?
2.
Explain Law of Demand, in detail.
Managerial Economics
35
Discussion
Why does the demand curve slope downwards? Discuss.
2.3 Demand Function
The functional relationship between the demand for a commodity and its various
determinants may be expressed mathematically in terms of a demand function, thus:
Dx = f (Px, Py, M, T, A, U) where,
Dx = Quantity demanded for commodity X.
f = functional relation.
Px = The price of commodity X.
Py = The price of substitutes and complementary goods.
M = The money income of the consumer.
T = The taste of the consumer.
A = The advertisement effects.
U = Unknown variables or influences.
The above-stated demand function is a complicated one. Again, factors like tastes
and unknown influences are not quantifiable. Economists, therefore, adopt a very simple
statement of demand function, assuming all other variables, except price, to be constant.
Thus, an over-simplified and the most commonly stated demand function is: Dx = f (Px),
which connotes that the demand for commodity X is the function of its price. The traditional
demand theory deals with this demand function specifically.
It must be noted that by demand function, economists mean the entire functional
relationship i.e. the whole range of price-quantity relationship and not just the quantity
demanded at a given price per unit of time. In other words, the statement, 'the quantity
demanded is a function of price' implies that for every price there is a corresponding
quantity demanded.
To put it differently, demand for a commodity means the entire demand schedule,
which shows the varying amounts of goods purchased at alternative prices at a given time.
36
Managerial Economics
Shift in Demand Curve
When demand curve changes its position retaining its shape (though not necessarily),
the change is known as shift in demand curve.
Fig 2.3: Shift in Demand Curves
Let’s suppose that the demand curve D2 in Fig. 2.3 is the original demand curve for
commodity X. As shown in the figure, at price OP2 consumer buys OQ2 units of X, other
factors remaining constant. If any of the other factors (e.g., consumer’s income) changes, it
will change the consumer’s ability and willingness to buy commodity X. For example, if
consumer’s disposable income decreases, say, due to increase in income tax, he may be able
to buy only OQ1 units of X instead of OQ2 at price OP2 (This is true for the whole range of
price of X) the consumers would be able to buy less of commodity X at all other prices. This
will cause a downward shift in demand curve from D2 to D1. Similarly, increase in disposable
income of the consumer due to reduction in taxes may cause an upward shift from D2 to D3.
Such changes in the position of the demand curve are known as shifts in demand curve.
Reasons for Shift in Demand Curve
Shifts in a price-demand curve may take place owing to the change in one or more of
other determinants of demand. Consider, for example, the decrease in demand for
commodity X by Q1Q2 in Fig 2.3. Given the price OP1, the demand for X might have fallen
from OQ2 to OQ1 (i.e., by Q1Q2) for any of the following reasons:
•
Fall in the consumer’s income so that he can buy only OQ1 of X at price OP2—
it is income effect.
•
Price of X’s substitute falls so that the consumers find it beneficial to substitute Q1Q2 of X
Managerial Economics
37
with its substitute—it is substitution effect.
•
Advertisement made by the producer of the substitute, changes consumer’s taste or
preference against commodity X so much that they replace Q1Q2 of X with its substitute,
again a substitution effect.
•
Price of complement of X increases so much that they can now afford only OQX of X
•
Also for such reasons as commodity X is going out of fashion; its quality has deteriorated;
consumer’s technology has so changed that only OQ1 of X can be used and due to
change in season if commodity X has only seasonal use.
Study Notes
Assessment
Explain, why there is shift in demand curve?
Discussion
Give the functional relationship between the demand for a commodity and its various
determinants, in mathematical terms of a demand function.
38
Managerial Economics
2.4 Elasticity of Demand
While the law of demand establishes a relationship between price and quantity
demanded for a product, it does not tell us exactly as how strong or weak the relationship
happens to be. This relation, as already discussed, is inverse baring some rare exceptions.
However, a manager needs an exact measure of this relationship for appropriate business
decisions. Elasticity of demand is a measure, which comes to the rescue of a manager here.
It measures the responsiveness of demand to changes in prices as well as changes in income.
A manager can determine almost exactly how the demand for his product would change
when he changes his price or when his rivals alter prices of their products. He can also
determine how the demand for his product would change if incomes of his consumers go up
or down. Elasticity of demand concept and its measurements are therefore very important
tools of managerial decision making.
From decision-making point of view, however, the knowledge of only the nature of
relationships is not sufficient. What is more important is the extent of relationship or the
degree of responsiveness of demand to changes in its determinants. The responsiveness of
demand for a good to the change in its determinants is called the elasticity of demand. The
concept of elasticity of demand was introduced into the economic theory by Alfred Marshall.
The elasticity concept plays an important role in various business decisions and government
policies. In this unit, we will discuss the following kinds of demand elasticity.
•
Price Elasticity: Elasticity of demand for a commodity with respect to change in its price.
•
Cross Elasticity: Elasticity of demand for a commodity with respect to change in the price
of its substitutes.
•
Income Elasticity: Elasticity of demand with respect to change in consumer’s income.
•
Price Expectation Elasticity of Demand: Elasticity of demand with respect to consumer’s
expectations regarding future price of the commodity.
2.4.1 PRICE ELASTICITY OF DEMAND
The price elasticity of demand is delineated as the degree of responsiveness or
sensitiveness of demand for a commodity to the changes in its price. More precisely,
elasticity of demand is the percentage change in the quantity demanded of a commodity as
a result of a certain percentage change in its price. A formal definition of price elasticity of
demand (e) is given below:
Managerial Economics
39
The measure of price elasticity (e) is called co-efficient of price elasticity. The
measure of price elasticity is converted into a more general formula for calculating
coefficient of price elasticity given as
-------------------------------------------eq. I
Where QO = original quantity demanded, PO = original price,
demanded and
Q = change in quantity
P = change in price.
Note that a minus sign (-) is generally inserted in the formula before the fraction with
a view to making elasticity coefficient a non-negative value.
2.4.2 POINT AND ARC ELASTICITY OF DEMAND
The elasticity of demand is conventionally measured either at a finite point or
between any two finite points, on the demand curve. The elasticity measured on a finite
point of a demand curve is called point elasticity and the elasticity measured between any
two finite points is called arc elasticity. Let us now look into the methods of measuring point
and arc elasticity and their relative usefulness.
(A) POINT ELASTICITY
The point elasticity of demand is defined as the proportionate change in quantity
demanded in response to a very small proportionate change in price. The concept of point
elasticity is useful where change in price and the consequent change in quantity demanded
are very small.
The point elasticity may be symbolically expressed as
---------------------------------------------eq. II
Measuring Point Elasticity on a Linear Demand Curve
40
Managerial Economics
To illustrate the measurement of point elasticity of a linear demand curve, let us
suppose that a linear demand curve is given by MN in Fig. 2.4 and that we want to measure
elasticity at point P.
Fig. 2.4: Point Elasticity of a Linear Demand Curve
Let us now substitute the values from Fig. 2.4 in eq. II. As it is obvious from the
figure, P = PQ and Q = OQ. What we need now is to find the values for δQ and δP. These
values can be obtained by assuming a very small decrease in the price. However, it will be
difficult to depict these changes in the figure as and hence Q –O. There is however an easier
way to find the value for δQ/δP. In derivative given the slope of the demand curve MN. The
slope of demand curve MN, at point P is geometrically given by QN/PQ. That is, may be
proved as follows. If we draw a horizontal line from P and to the vertical -.here will be three
triangles.
Since at point P, P=PQ and Q=OQ, substituting these values in eq. II, (ignoring
the minus sign), we get
Geometrically,
MON,
MRP and
PQN (Fig. 3.1) in which
MON and
PQN are right angles.
Therefore, the other corresponding angles of the triangles will always be equal and hence,
MON, MRP and PQN are similar triangles.
Managerial Economics
41
According to geometrical properties of similar triangles, the ratio of any two sides of
similar triangle is always equal to the ratio of corresponding sides of the other sides.
Therefore, in
PQN and
MRP,
………………………………… eq. III
Hence, RP=OQ, by substituting OQ for RP in eq. III, we get
In proportionality rule, therefore,
It may thus be concluded that price elasticity at point P (Fig 2.4) is given by
Measuring Point Elasticity on a Non-linear Demand Curve
Let us now elucidate the method of measuring point elasticity on a non-linear
demand curve. Suppose we want to measure the elasticity of demand curve DD’ at point P
in, let us draw a line (MN) tangent to the demand curve DD’ at point P. Since demand curve
DD’ and the line MN pass through the same point (P) the slope of demand curve and that of
the line at this point is the same. Therefore, the elasticity of demand curve DD’ at point P
will be equal to the elasticity of demand line, MN, at point P. Elasticity of the line, MN, at
point P can be measured (ignoring ‘minus’ sign) as
Fig 2.5: Point Elasticity of Demand
42
Managerial Economics
Given the graphical measurement of point elasticity, it is obvious that the elasticity at
a point of a demand curve is the ratio between the lower and the upper segments of a linear
demand curve from the point chosen for measuring point elasticity. That is,
Geometrically, QN/OQ=PN/PM. (For proof, see the proceeding section).
Fig 2.6: Point Elasticity on a non-linear Demand Curve
It follows that at mid-point of a linear demand curve, e = 1, as shown at point P in Fig.
2.6, because both lower and upper segments are equal (i.e., PN = PM) at any other point to
the left of point P, e > I and at any point to the right of point.
Price Elasticity at Terminal Points
The price elasticity at terminal point N equals 0 i.e. at point N, e = 0. At terminal
point M, however, price-elasticity is undefined, though most texts show that at terminal
point M, e = ∞. According to William J. Baumol, a Nobel Prize winner, price elasticity at
upper terminal point of the demand curve is undefined. It is undefined because measuring
elasticity at terminal point (M) involves division of zero and division by-zero is undefined. In
his own words, “Here the elasticity is not even defined because an attempt to evaluate the
Managerial Economics
43
fraction p/x at that point forces us to commit the sign of dividing by zero. The reader who
has forgotten why division by zero is immoral may recall that division is the reverse
operation of multiplication. Hence, in seeking the quotient c = a/b we look for a number, c,
which when multiplied by b gives us the number a, i.e., for which cb = a. But if a is not zero,
say a = 5 and b is zero, there is no such number because there is no c such that c x 0 = 5”.
(B) MEASURING ARC ELASTICITY
The concept of point elasticity is pertinent where change in price and the resulting
change in quantity are infinite or small. However, where change in price and the consequent
hunger in demand is substantial, the concept of arc elasticity is the relevant concept. Arc
elasticity is a measure of the average of responsiveness of the quantity demanded to a
substantial change in the price. In other words, the measure of price elasticity of demand
between two finite points on a demand curve is known as arc activity. For example, the
measure of elasticity between points J and K (Fig. 2.7) is: the measure of arc elasticity. The
movement from point J to K along the demand curve D) shows a fall in price from Rs 25 to Rs
10 so that AP = 25 - 10 = 15. The consequent increase in demand, AQ = 30 - 50 = - 20. The arc
elasticity between point J and K and (moving from J to K) can be obtained by substituting
these values in the elasticity formula.
………..eq. I
It means that a one percent decrease in price of commodity X results in a 1.11
percent increase in demand for it.
Fig 2.7: Measuring Arc Elasticity
44
Managerial Economics
Problems in Using Arc Elasticity
The use of arc elasticity in economic analysis entails a good deal of chariness because
it is capable of being misinterpreted. Arc elasticity coefficients differ between the same two
finite points on a demand curve if direction of change in price is reversed. Arc elasticity for a
decrease in price will be different from that for the same increase in price between the same
to points on a demand curve. For example, the price elasticity between points J and K —
moving from J to K — is equal to 1.11. This is the elasticity for decrease in price from Rs 25 to
Rs 10. But a reverse movement on the demand curve, i.e., from point K to J implies an
increase in price from Rs 10 to Rs 25 which will give a different elasticity coefficient. In case
of movement from point K to J, P = 10,
P = 10 - 25 = - 15, Q = 50 and
Q = 50 - 30 = 20.
Substituting these values in the elasticity formula, we get
The measure of arc elasticity co-efficient in equation I for the reverse movement in
price is obviously different from the one given in equation II. Therefore, while measuring the
arc elasticity, the direction of price change should be carefully noted, otherwise it may yield
misleading conclusions.
A method suggested to resolve this problem is to use the average of upper
and lower values of P and Q in fraction, P/Q, so that the formula is
Substituting the values from this example, we get
This method has its own drawbacks as the elasticity co-efficient calculated through
this formula, refers to the elasticity of demand at mid-point between points J and K (Fig.
2.7). Elasticity co-efficient (0.58) is not applicable for the whole range of price-quantity
combinations at different points between J and K on the demand curve (Fig. 2.7). It gives
only mean of the elasticity between the two points. It is important to note that elasticity
between the mid-point and the upper point J or lower point K will be different. Thus, this
Managerial Economics
45
method does not give one measure of elasticity.
2.4.3 NATURE OF DEMAND CURVES AND ELASTICITY
Generally, elasticity of a demand curve throughout its length is not the same (Fig.
2.8). It varies between 0 and ∞, or in other words,
In some cases, however, the elasticity remains the same throughout the length of the
demand curve. Such demand curves can be placed in the following categories: (i) perfectly
inelastic (e = 0); (ii) unitary elastic (e = 1); and (iii) perfectly elastic (e = ∞). These three types
of demand curves are illustrated in Fig. 2.8 (a), (b) and (c), respectively.
Fig 2.8: Constant Elasticity Demand Curve
2.4.4 SLOPE OF THE DEMAND CURVE AND PRICE ELASTICITY
The elasticity of a demand curve is often judged by its appearance: the flatter the
demand curve, the greater the elasticity and vice versa. But this conclusion is misleading
because two demand curves with different slopes may have the same elasticity at a given
price. In fact, what appearance of a demand curve reveals is its slope, not the elasticity. The
slope of the demand curve is the marginal relationship between change in price (
change in quantity demanded ( Q). The slope of demand curve is expressed as
is the reciprocal of the slope
P) and
P/ Q. It
Q/ P which appears in the elasticity formula, not the slope
itself.
We will show below: (i) that demand curves having different slopes may have the
same elasticity at a given price and (ii) that demand curves having the same slope may have
different elasticity at a given price.
46
Managerial Economics
(A) ELASTICITY OF DEMAND CURVES HAVING DIFFERENT SLOPES
Let us first illustrate that two demand curves with different slops may have the same
elasticity at a given price. In Fig. 2.9, demand curves AB and AD have different slopes. It may
be proved as follows:
Fig 2.9: Demand Curves having different slopes
Slope of the demand curve AB=OA/OB and
Slope of the demand curve AD=OA/OD
Note that in these ratios, numerator OA is common to both the fractions, but in case
of denominators OB<OD.
Obviously, the slopes of the two demand curves are different. Let us now show, that
at a given price, both the demand curves have the same elasticity. As shown in Fig. at a given
price OP, the relevant points for measuring the elasticity are Q and R on the demand curves
AB and AD, respectively. Recall that the elasticity at a point on a linear demand curve is
obtained as
Managerial Economics
47
Thus, at point Q on demand curve AB, ep=QB/QA and at point R on AD, ep=RD/RA
Thus, at point Q on demand curve AB, e = QB/QA and at point R on AD, ep = RD/RA. It
can be geometrically proved that the two elasticity are equal, i.e., QB=RD
Let us first consider
AOB. If we draw a horizontal line from point Q to intersect the
vertical axis at point P and an ordinate from Q to M at the horizontal axis, we have three
triangles—
AOB,
APQ and
QMB. Note that
AOB,
APQ and
QMB are right-
angles. Therefore, all the three triangles are right-angled triangles. As noted above, the
ratios of their two corresponding sides of similar right-angle triangles are always equal.
Considering only the relevant triangles,
APQ and
QMB, we have
Since MQ = OP, by substituting OP for QM in ratio BQ/MQ, we get
We can similarly prove that
Thus it is proved, that at price OP,
It is thus proved that two demand curves with different slopes have the same
elasticity at a given price.
48
Managerial Economics
(B) ELASTICITY OF PARALLEL DEMAND CURVES
Fig 2.10: Price Elasticity of two parallel demand curves
Now, we will compare the price elasticity at two parallel demand curves at a given
price. This has been illustrated in Fig 2.10 where two demand curves AB and CD are given
which are parallel to each other. The two demand curves which are parallel to each other
imply that they have the same slope. Now, we can prove that at price OP price elasticity of
demand on the two demand curves AB and CD is different. Now, draw a perpendicular from
point R to the point P on Y-axis. Thus, at price OP the corresponding points on the two
demand curves are Q and R respectively.
The elasticity of demand on the demand curve AB at point Q will be equal to QB/QA
and at point R on the demand curve CD it is equal to RD/RC.
Because it is right-angled triangle OAB, PQ is parallel to QB:
Hence, price elasticity at point Q on the demand curve
At point R on the demand curve CD, price elasticity is equal to RD/RC. Because in the
right angled triangle OCD, PR is parallel to OD.
Hence, on point R on the demand curve CD, price elasticity =OP/PC
On seeing the diagram it will be clear that at point Q the price elasticity OP/PA and at
point R the price elasticity OP/PC are not equal to each other. Because PC is greater than PA,
Managerial Economics
49
It is therefore; clear that at point R on the demand curve CD the price elasticity is less
than that at point Q on the demand curve AB, when the two demand curves being parallel to
each other have the same slope. It also follows that as the demand curve shifts to the right
the price elasticity of demand at a given price goes on declining. Thus, as has been just seen,
price elasticity at price OP on the demand curve CD is less than that on the demand curve
AB.
2.4.5 PRICE ELASTICITY AND MARGINAL REVENUE
In this section, we look at one of the most important uses of the price elasticity of
demand, used especially in business decision-making. It pertains to the relationship between
price elasticity and the marginal change in the total revenue of the firm planning to change
the price of its product. The relationship between price elasticity and the marginal revenue
(MR) can be derived as follows.
Let us suppose that a given output, Q, is being sold at a price P, so that the total
revenue, TR, equals P times Q, i.e.
TR = P X Q ……………….Eq. I
Since P and Q in eq. I are inversely related, a question arises, whether a change in P
will increase or decrease or leave the TR unaffected. It depends on whether MR is greater
than or less than or equal to zero, i.e., whether
MR > 0, MR < 0, or MR = 0
The marginal revenue, (MR) can be obtained by differentiating TR = PQ with respect
to P as shown below.
50
Managerial Economics
1. Price elasticity and total revenue
Given the relationship between marginal revenue and price elasticity of demand in
Eq. II, the decision-makers can easily know whether or not it is advantageous to change the
price. Given Eq. II, if e = 1, MR = 0. Therefore, change in price will not cause any change in
TR. If e < 1, MR < 0 and, therefore, TR decreases when price decreases and TR increases
when price increases. And, if e > 1, MR > 0, then TR increases if price decreases and TR
increases when price increases.
The effect of change in price on TR for different price-elasticity co-efficient is
summarised in the table mentioned below:
Table 2.3: Elasticity, Price change and change in TR
Elasticity Demand
Nature of Price
Change in TR
Change
in
efficient
ep = 0
Managerial Economics
Perfectly inelastic
Increase
Increases
Decrease
Decreases
51
co-
ep < 1
ep = 1
Inelastic
Unitary elastic
Increase
Increases
Decrease
Decreases
Increase
No change in TR
Decrease
ep > 1
ep = ∞
Elastic
Infinitely elastic
Increase
Decrease
Decrease
Increases
Increase
Decrease
Decrease to zero
Increase infinitely
As the table shows, when e = 0, the demand is said to be perfectly inelastic. Perfect
inelasticity of demand implies no change in quantity demanded when price is changed.
Therefore, a rise in price will increase the total revenue and vice versa. In case of an inelastic
demand (i.e., e < I), quantity demanded increases less than the proportionate decrease in
price and hence the total revenue falls when price falls. Total revenue increases when price
increases because quantity demanded decreases less than proportionately. If demand for a
product is unit-elastic (e = 1) quantity demanded increases (or decreases) in the proportion
of decrease (or increase) in the price. Therefore, the total revenue remains unaffected. If
demand for a commodity has e > 1, change in quantity demanded is greater than the
proportionate change in price. Therefore, the total revenue increases when price falls and
vice versa. The case of an infinitely elastic demand is rare. Such a demand line simply implies
that a consumer has the opportunity of buying any quantity of a commodity and the seller
can sell any quantity of the commodity, at a given price: it is the case of a commodity being
bought and sold in a perfectly competitive market.
2.4.6 PRICE ELASTICITY AND CONSUMPTION EXPENDITURE
Another important relationship which is often referred to in economic analysis is the
relationship between price elasticity and consumption expenditure. From the law of
demand, we know that quantity demanded of a commodity increases when its price falls.
But, what happens to the total expenditure on that commodity: does it fall or increase?
The relationship between price-elasticity and total consumption expenditure may be
derived as follows. Suppose that the total expenditure, Ex on a commodity X, at a given price,
52
Managerial Economics
P, all other prices remaining the same, is given by
EX = QX ∙ PX……………Eq. III
By differentiating Eq. III with respect to PX, we get marginal expenditure (ME), as
……………….. Eq. IV
The relationship between, total expenditure and price elasticity of demand has
summed up in the following table:
Table 2.4: Elasticity and Consumption Expenditure
Elasticity
Price change
(ece)
ece < 1
Managerial Economics
Marginal Expenditure Total Consumer
Expenditure
Rise
ME < 1
Decreases
Fall
ME > 1
Increases
53
ece = 1
ece > 1
Rise
ME = 1
Constant
Fall
ME = 1
Constant
Rise
ME < 1
Increases
Fall
ME > 1
Decreases
As shown in Table 2.4, when ece > 1, e.g., demand is elastic, an increase in price
causes more than proportionate decrease in quantity demanded. Hence, total expenditure
decreases. And, if price decreases quantity demanded increases more than proportionately.
As a result, total expenditure increases.
When ece = 1, a rise (or fall) in price causes a proportionate fall (or rise) in quantity
demanded leaving total expenditure unchanged.
When ece < 1, i.e., when demand is inelastic, a rise in price causes a rise in the total
expenditure because demand decreases less than proportionately and a fall in price reduces
it as quantity demanded increases less than proportionately.
2.4.7 CROSS-ELASTICITY OF DEMAND
The cross-elasticity is the measure of responsiveness of demand for a commodity to
the changes in the price of its substitutes and complementary goods. For instance, crosselasticity of demand for tea (T) is the percentage change in its quantity demanded with
respect to the change in the price of its substitute, coffee (C). The formula for measuring
cross-elasticity of demand for tea (et,c) with respect to price of coffee (Pc)
The cross elasticity of demand for coffee (QC) with respect to price of tea (Pt)
is
………… Eq. V
For example, suppose that price of coffee (Pe) increases from Rs 10 to Rs 15, per 10
54
Managerial Economics
grams and as a result demand for tea increases from 20 tons to 30 tons per week, price of
tea remaining constant. By substituting these values in Eq. V, we get cross-elasticity of
demand for tea with respect to price of coffee, as
It is important to note that cross-elasticity between any two substitute goods is
always positive.
The same formula is used to calculate the cross-elasticity of demand for a good in
reaction to the change in the price of its complementary goods. Electricity to electrical
gadgets, petrol to automobile, butter to bread, sugar and milk to tea and coffee, are the
examples of complementary goods. Notice that the demand for complementary goods has
negative cross-elasticity e.g. rise in the price of a good reduces the demand for its
complementary goods.
A significant characteristic of cross-elasticity is that if cross-elasticity between two
goods is positive, the two may be regarded as substitutes for each other. Moreover, the
greater the cross-elasticity, the closer the substitute. Likewise, if cross-elasticity of demand
for two related goods is negative, the two may be regarded as complementary of each
other: the higher the negative cross-elasticity, the higher the degree of complementarily.
2.4.8 INCOME ELASTICITY OF DEMAND
Aside from the price of a product and its substitutes, another vital element of
demand for a product is consumer’s income. As noticed previously, the relationship
between demand for regular and luxury goods and consumer’s income is of positive nature,
not like the negative price-demand relationship. I.e, the demand for regular goods and
services rises with the rise in consumer’s income and vice versa. The reaction of demand to
the change in consumer’s income is known as income elasticity of demand.
Income elasticity of demand for a product, say X (i.e., ex ) is defined as
Managerial Economics
55
Where X = quantity of X demanded; Y = disposable income;
demanded of X; and
X = change in quantity
Y = change in income.
Unlike price elasticity of demand (which is negative except in case of Giffen goods),
income elasticity of demand is positive because of a positive relationship between income
and demand for a product. There is an exception to this rule. Income elasticity of demand
for an inferior good is negative, because of negative income-effect. The demand for inferior
goods reduces with the rise in consumer’s income and vice versa. When income is more,
consumers change over to the consumption of superior commodities. I.e. they replace
inferior goods for superior ones. For instance, when income increases, people would rather
purchase more of rice and wheat and less of inferior food grains like bajara, ragi and use
more of taxi and less of bus service and so on.
NATURE OF COMMODITY AND INCOME ELASTICITY
For all regular goods, income elasticity is positive although the degree of elasticity
fluctuates as per the nature of commodities. Consumer goods are usually categorised under
three classes, viz. necessities (essential consumer goods), comforts and luxuries. The
universal structure of income elasticity for goods of various categories or a rise in income
and their effect on sales are provided in Table 2.5. The income elasticity of demand for
different categories of goods may still show discrepancies from house to house and from
time to time, as per the options, taste and preference of the consumers, degree of their
consumption and income and their receptiveness to ‘demonstration effect’. The other
aspect which could bring about a deviation from the universal structure of income elasticity
is the frequency of rise in income. Income rises often and repeatedly, income-elasticity as
provided in Table 2.5 follows the universal structure.
A few significant uses of income elasticity are as follows:
First, the concept of income elasticity can be used to approximately calculate the
potential demand only if the rate of rise in income and income elasticity of demand for the
commodities are identified. The information of income elasticity can hence be useful in
predicting demand, when changes in personal incomes are anticipated, other things
remaining the same.
56
Managerial Economics
Table 2.5: Income Elasticity of different consumer goods
Commodities
Coefficient of income elasticity
Impact on expenditure
Necessities
Less than unitary (ey < 1)
Less than proportionate change in
income
Comforts
Almost equal to unity (ey = 1 )
Almost
proportionate change in
income
Luxuries
Greater than unity (ey > 1)
More than proportionate increase in
income
Second, the concept of income elasticity could furthermore be used to describe the
‘regular’ and ‘inferior’ goods. The goods whose income elasticity is positive for all levels of
income are termed as ‘regular goods’. On the other hand, the goods for which income
elasticity is negative, further than a particular level of income, are termed as ‘inferior goods’
Study Notes
Assessment
Write notes on the following:
1.
Elasticity of Demand
2.
Arc Elasticity of Demand
3.
Price Elasticity and Marginal Revenue
Managerial Economics
57
4.
Price Elasticity and Consumption Expenditure
5.
Nature of Demand Curves and Elasticity
6.
Cross elasticity and income elasticity.
Discussion
Discuss the problems in using Arc Elasticity.
2.5 Determinants of Demand
Price elasticity of demand fluctuates from commodity to commodity. While the
demand of some commodities is highly elastic, the demand for others is highly inelastic. In
this section, we will describe the main determinants of the price elasticity of demand.
1.
Availability of Substitutes
One of the most significant determinants of elasticity of demand for a commodity is
the availability of its substitutes. Closer the substitute, greater is the elasticity of demand for
the commodity. For instance, coffee and tea could be regarded as close substitutes for one
another. Thus, if price of one of these goods rises, its demand reduces more than the
proportionate rise in its price as consumers switch over to the relatively lower-priced
substitute. Moreover, broader the choice of the substitutes, greater is the elasticity. E.g.
soaps, washing powder, toothpastes, shampoos, etc. are available in several brands; each
brand is a close substitute for the other. Thus, the price-elasticity of demand for each brand
will be to a large extent greater than the general commodity. In contrast, sugar and salt do
not have their close substitute and for this reason their price-elasticity is lower.
2. Nature of Commodity
The nature of a commodity as well has an effect on the price elasticity of its demand.
Commodities can be categorised as luxuries, comforts and necessities, on the basis of their
nature. Demand for luxury goods (e.g., luxury cars, decorative items, etc.) are more elastic
than the demand for other types of goods as consumption of luxury goods can be set aside
or delayed when their prices increase. In contrast, consumption of essential goods, (e.g.,
sugar, clothes, vegetables, etc.) cannot be delayed and for this reason their demand is
inelastic. Demand for comforts is usually more elastic than that for necessities and less
Managerial Economics
58
elastic than the demand for luxuries. Commodities may also be categorised as durable goods
and perishable or non-durable goods. Demand for durable goods is more elastic than that
for non-durable goods, as when the prices of the former rises, people either get the old one
fixed rather than substituting it or buy ‘second hand’ goods.
3. Proportion of Income Spent on a Commodity
Another aspect that has an impact on the elasticity of demand for a commodity is the
proportion of income, which consumers use up on a specific commodity. If proportion of
income spent on a commodity is extremely little, its demand will be less elastic and vice
versa. Characteristic examples of such commodities are sugar, matches, books, washing
powder etc., which use a very tiny proportion of the consumer’s income. Demand for these
goods is usually inelastic as a rise in the price of such goods does not largely have an effect
on the consumer’s consumption pattern and the overall purchasing power. Thus, people
continue to buy approximately the same quantity even at the time their price rises.
4. Time Factor
Price-elasticity of demand relies moreover on the time which consumers take to
amend to a new price: longer the time taken, greater is the elasticity. As each year passes,
consumers are capable of altering their spending pattern to price changes. For instance, if
the price of bikes falls, demand may not rise instantaneously unless people acquire surplus
buying capacity. In the end nevertheless people can alter their spending pattern so that they
can purchase a car at a (new) lower price.
5. Range of Alternative Uses of a Commodity
Broader the range of alternative uses of a commodity, higher the price elasticity of its
demand intended for the fall in price however less elastic for the increase in price. As the
price of a versatile commodity falls, people broaden their consumption to its other uses.
Thus, the demand for such a commodity usually rises more than the proportionate fall in its
price. E.g., milk can be consumed as it is, it could be transformed into curd, cheese, ghee and
buttermilk. The demand for milk will thus be extremely elastic for fall in their price. Likewise,
electricity can be utilised for lighting, cooking, heating, as well as for industrial purposes.
Thus, demand for electricity is extremely price elastic for fall in its price. For this reason,
nevertheless, demand for such goods is inelastic for the increase in their price.
6. The Proportion of Market Supplied
Price elasticity of market demand furthermore relies on the proportion of the market
supplied at the determined price. If less than half of the market is supplied at the
Managerial Economics
59
determined price, elasticity of demand will be higher if more than half of the market is
supplied. i.e. demand curve is more elastic at the upper half than at the lower half.
Study Notes
Assessment
What are the factors, which determine the demand of a commodity? Explain.
Discussion
Discuss how availability of Substitute goods determines the demand of a good.
2.6 Demand Forecasting
Demand forecasting entails forecasting and estimating the quantity of a product or
service that consumers will purchase in future. It tries to evaluate the magnitude and
significance of forces that will affect future operating conditions in an enterprise. Demand
forecasting involves use of various formal and informal forecast techniques such as informed
guesses, use of historical sales data or current field data gathered from representative
markets. Demand forecasting may be used in making pricing decisions, in assessing future
capacity requirements, or in making decisions on whether to enter a new market. Thus,
demand forecasting is estimation of future demand. According to Cardiff and Still, “Demand
forecasting is an estimate of sales during a specified future period based on a proposed
Managerial Economics
60
marketing plan and a set of particular uncontrollable and competitive forces". As such,
demand forecasting is a projection of firm’s expected future demands.
2.6.1 DEMAND FORECAST AND SALES FORECAST
Due to the dynamic and complex nature of marketing phenomenon, demand
forecasting has become an important and regular business exercise. It is essential for profit
maximisation and the survival and expansion of a business. However, before selecting any
vendor a retailer should well understand the requirement and the importance of demand
forecasting. In management circles, demand forecasting and sales forecasting are used
interchangeably. Sales forecasts are first approximations in production and forward
planning. These provide a platform upon which plans could be prepared and amendments
may be made. According to American Marketing Association, “Sales forecast is an estimate
of sales in monetary or physical units for a specified future period under a proposed
business plan or programmer or under an assumed set of ‘economic and other environment
forces, planning premises, outside business/ antiquate which the forecast or-estimate is
made”.
2.6.2 COMPONENTS OF DEMAND FORECASTING SYSTEM
•
Market research operations to procure relevant and reliable information about the
trends in market.
•
A data processing and analysing system to estimate and evaluate the sales performance
in various markets.
•
Proper co-ordination of steps (i) and (ii) above
•
Placing the findings before the top management for making final decisions.
2.6.3 OBJECTIVES OF DEMAND FORECAST
1. Short Term Objectives
a. Drafting of Production Policy: Demand forecasts facilitate in drafting appropriate
production policy so that there may not be any space between future demand and
supply of a product. This can in addition ensure:
•
Routine Supply of Materials: Demand forecasting assists in figuring out the
preferred volume of production. The essential prerequisite of raw materials in
future can be calculated on the basis of such forecasts. This guarantees regular
and continuous supply of the materials in addition to managing the amount of
supply at the economic level.
Managerial Economics
61
•
Best Possible Use of Machines: Demand forecasting in addition expedites cutting
down inactive capacity because only the necessary amount of machines and
equipments are set up to meet future demands.
•
Regular Availability of Labour: As soon as demand forecasts are made, supplies
of the necessary amount of skilled and unskilled workers can be organised well
beforehand to meet the future production plans.
b. Drafting of Price Policy: Demand forecasts facilitate the management to prepare a
few suitable pricing systems, so that the level of price does not rise and fall to a great
extent during depression or inflation.
c. Appropriate Management of Sales: Demand forecasts are made area wise and after
that the sales targets for different regions are set in view of that. This abets the
calculation of sales performances.
d. Organising Funds: On the basis of demand forecast, an individual can find out the
monetary requirements of the organisation in order to bring about the desired
output. This can make it possible to cut down on the expenditure of acquiring funds.
2. Long Term Goals: If the demand forecast period is more than a year, in that case it is
termed as long term forecast. The following are the key goals of such forecasts:
a. To settle on the production capacity: Long term decisions are entwined with
capacity variations by adding or discarding capacity in the form of capital assets manufacturing plants, new technology implementation etc. Size of the organisation
should such that output matches with the sales requirements. Organisations that are
extremely small or large in size might not be in the financial interest of the company.
Inadequate capability can hasten declining delivery performance, needless rise in
work-in-process and disturb sales personnel and those in the production unit.
Nevertheless, surplus capacity can be expensive and pointless. The incompetence to
appropriately deal with capacity can be an obstacle to attaining the best possible
performance. By examining the demand pattern for the product as well as the
forecasts for the future, the company can prepare for a company's output of the
desired capacity.
b. Labour Requirements: Spending on labour is one of the most vital elements of cost
of production. Dependable and correct demand forecasts can facilitate the
management to evaluate suitable labour requirements. This can ensure finest labour
supply and uninterrupted production procedures.
62
Managerial Economics
c. Production Planning: Long term production planning can aid the management in
organising long term finances on practical terms and conditions.
The study of long term sales is accorded greater importance as compared with shortterm sales. Long term sales forecast facilitates the management to take a few policy
decisions of huge importance and any mistake carried out in this could be extremely
different or costly to be corrected.
Therefore, the complete success of an organisation usually is contingent upon the
quality and authenticity of sales forecasting methods.
2.6.4 IMPORTANCE OF DEMAND FORECAST
1. Management Decisions: An effective demand forecast facilitates the management to
take appropriate steps in factors that are pertinent to decision making such as plant
capacity, raw-material requisites, space and building requirements and availability of
labour and capital. Manufacturing schedules can be drafted in compliance with the
demand requisites; in this manner cutting down on the inventory, production and other
related costs.
2. Evaluation: Demand forecasting furthermore smoothes the process of evaluating the
efficiency of the sales department.
3. Quality and Quantity Controls: Demand forecasting is an essential and valuable
instrument in the control of the management of an organisation to provide finished
goods of correct quality and quantity at the correct time with the least amount of
expenditure.
4. Financial Estimates: As per the sales level as well as production functions, the financial
requirements of an organisation can be calculated using various techniques of demand
forecasting. In addition, it needs a little time to acquire revenue on practical terms. Sales
forecasts will, as a result, make it possible for arranging adequate resources on practical
terms and in advance as well.
5. Avoiding Surplus and Inadequate Production: Demand forecasting is necessary for the
old and new organisations. It is somewhat essential if an organisation is engaged in large
scale production of goods and the development period is extremely time-consuming in
the course of production. In such situations, an estimate regarding the future demand is
essential to avoid inadequate and surplus production.
6. Recommendations for the future: Demand forecast for a specific commodity
furthermore provides recommendations for demand forecast of associated industries.
Managerial Economics
63
E.g. the demand forecast for the vehicle industry aids the tyre industry in calculating the
demand for two wheelers, three wheelers and four wheelers.
7. Significance for the government: At the macro-level, demand forecasting is valuable to
the government as it aids in determining targets of imports as well as exports for various
products and preparing for the international business.
2.6.5 METHODS OF DEMAND FORECAST
No demand forecasting method is 100% precise. Collective forecasts develop
precision and decrease the probability of huge mistakes.
1. Methods that relay on Qualitative Assessment:
Forecasting demand based on expert opinion. Some of the types in this method are:
•
Unaided judgment
•
Prediction market
•
Delphi technique
•
Game theory
•
Judgmental bootstrapping
•
Simulated interaction
•
Intentions and expectations surveys
•
Conjoint analysis
2. Methods that rely on quantitative data:
64
•
Discrete event simulation
•
Extrapolation
•
Quantitative analogies
•
Rule-based forecasting
•
Neural networks
•
Data mining
•
Causal models
•
Segmentation
Managerial Economics
2.6.6 SOME DEMAND FORECASTING METHODS
A. QUALITATIVE ASSESSMENT
1. Prediction markets: These are speculative markets fashioned with the intention of
making predictions. Assets that are produced possess an ultimate cash worth bound to a
specific event (e.g. who will win the next election) or situation (e.g., total sales next
quarter). The present market prices can then be described as forecasts of the likelihood
of the event or the estimated value of the situation. Prediction markets are as a result
planned as betting exchanges, without any kind of compromise for the bookmaker.
People who buy low and sell high are rewarded for improving the market prediction,
while those who buy high and sell low are punished for degrading the market prediction.
Evidence so far suggests that prediction markets are at least as accurate as other
institutions predicting the same events with a similar pool of participants.
Many prediction markets are open to the public. Betfair is the world's biggest
prediction exchange, with around $28 billion traded in 2007. Intrade is a for-profit company
with a large variety of contracts not including sports. The Iowa Electronic Markets is an
academic market examining elections where positions are limited to $500. Trade Sports are
prediction markets for sporting events.
2. Delphi method: This is a systematic, interactive forecasting method which relies on a
panel of experts. The experts answer questionnaires in two or more rounds. After each
round, a facilitator provides an anonymous summary of the experts’ forecasts from the
previous round as well as the reasons they provided for their judgments. Thus, experts
are encouraged to revise their earlier answers in light of the replies of other members of
their panel. It is believed that during this process the range of the answers will decrease
and the group will converge towards the 'correct' answer. Finally, the process is stopped
after a pre-defined stop criterion (e.g. number of rounds, achievement of consensus,
stability of results) and the mean or median scores of the final rounds determine the
results.
3. Game theory: Game theory is a branch of applied mathematics that is used in the social
sciences, most notably in economics, as well as in biology (particularly evolutionary
biology and ecology), engineering, political science, international relations, computer
science and philosophy. Game theory attempts at mathematically capturing behaviour in
strategic situations or games in which an individual's success in making choices depends
on the choices of others. While initially developed to analyse competitions in which one
individual does better at another's expense (zero sum games), it has been expanded to
Managerial Economics
65
treat a wide class of interactions, which are classified according to several criteria.
Today, "game theory is a sort of umbrella or 'unified field' theory for the rational side of
social science, where 'social' is interpreted broadly, to include human as well as nonhuman players (computers, animals, plants)" (Aumann 1987).
Traditional applications of game theory aim at finding equilibrium in these games. In
equilibrium, each player of the game has adopted a strategy that they are unlikely to
change. Many equilibrium concepts have been developed (most famously the Nash
equilibrium) in an endeavor to capture this idea. These equilibrium concepts are differently
motivated depending on the field of application, although they often overlap or coincide.
This methodology is not without criticism and debates continue over the appropriateness of
particular equilibrium concepts, the appropriateness of equilibrium altogether and the
usefulness of mathematical models more generally.
Although, some developments occurred before it, the field of game theory came into
being with Émile Borel's researches in his 1938 book Applications aux Jeux des Hazard and
was followed by the 1944 book Theory of Games and Economic Behavior by John von
Neumann and Oskar Morgenstern. This theory was developed extensively in the 1950s by
many scholars. Game theory was later explicitly applied to biology in the 1970s, although
similar developments go back at least as far as the 1930s. Game theory has been widely
recognised as an important tool in many fields. Eight game theorists have won the Nobel
Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences and John Maynard Smith was awarded the Crafoord
Prize for his application of game theory to biology.
The games studied in game theory are well-defined mathematical objects. A game
consists of a set of players, a set of moves (or strategies) available to those players and a
specification of payoffs for each combination of strategies. Most cooperative games are
presented in the characteristic function form, while the extensive and the normal forms are
used to define non-cooperative games.
QUANTITATIVE DATA
1. Discrete-event simulation: The operation of a system is represented as a chronological
sequence of events. Each event occurs at an instant in time and marks a change of state
in the system. For example, if an elevator is simulated, an event could be "level 6 button
pressed", with the resulting system state of "lift moving" and eventually (unless one
chooses to simulate the failure of the lift) "lift at level 6".
A common exercise in learning how to build discrete-event simulations is to model a
queue, such as customers arriving at a bank to be served by a teller. In this example, the
66
Managerial Economics
system entities are CUSTOMER-QUEUE and TELLERS. The system events are CUSTOMERARRIVAL and CUSTOMER-DEPARTURE. (The event of TELLER-BEGINS-SERVICE can be part of
the logic of the arrival and departure events.) The system states, which are changed by these
events, are NUMBER-OF-CUSTOMERS-IN-THE-QUEUE (an integer from 0 to n) and TELLERSTATUS (busy or idle). The random variables that need to be characterised to model this
system stochastically are CUSTOMER-INTERARRIVAL-TIME and TELLER-SERVICE-TIME.
2. Rule based forecasting: Rule-based forecasting (RBF) is a proficient method that
incorporates judgment as well as statistical techniques to merge forecasts. It involves
condition-action statements (rules) where conditions are based on the aspects of the
past progress and upon knowledge of that specific area. These rules give in to the load
suitable to the forecasting condition as described by the circumstances. In fact, RBF uses
structured judgment as well as statistical analysis to modify predictive techniques to the
condition. Practical outcomes on several sets of the past progress indicate that RBF
generates forecasts that are more precise than those generated by the conventional
predictive techniques or by an equal-load amalgamation of predictions.
3. Data mining: Data mining is the process of extracting patterns from data. Data mining is
seen as an increasingly important tool by modern business to transform data into an
informational advantage. It is currently used in a wide range of profiling practices, such
as marketing, surveillance and scientific discovery.
Data mining commonly involves four classes of tasks:
•
Clustering - is the task of discovering groups and structures in the data that are in some
way or another "similar", without using known structures in the data.
•
Classification - is the task of generalising known structure to apply to new data. For
example, an email program might attempt to classify an email as legitimate or spam.
Common algorithms include decision tree learning, nearest neighbor, naive Bayesian
classification, neural networks and support vector machines.
•
Regression - Attempts to find a function which models the data with the least error.
•
Association rule learning - Searches for relationships between variables. For example a
supermarket might gather data on customer purchasing habits. Using association rule
learning, the supermarket can determine which products are frequently bought together
and use this information for marketing purposes. This is sometimes referred to as
market basket analysis.
Managerial Economics
67
2.6.7 METHODS OF ESTIMATION
1. Regression analysis: Regression analysis is the statistical technique that identifies the
relationship between two or more quantitative variables: a dependent variable whose
value is to be predicted and an independent or explanatory variable (or variables), about
which knowledge is available. The technique is used to find the equation that represents
the relationship between the variables. A simple regression analysis can show that the
relation between an independent variable X and a dependent variable Y is linear, using
the simple linear regression equation Y= a + bX (where a and b are constants). Multiple
regression will provide an equation that predicts one variable from two or more
independent variables, Y= a + bX1+ cX2+ dX3.
The steps in regression analysis are:
a. Construction of the causal model: The construction of an explanatory model is a
crucial step in the regression analysis. It must be defined with reference to the action
theory of the intervention. It is likely that several kinds of variable exist. In some
cases, they may be specially created, for example to take account of the fact that an
individual has benefited from support or not (a dummy variable, taking values 0 or
1). A variable may also represent an observable characteristic (having a job or not) or
an unobservable one (probability of having a job). The model may presume that a
particular variable evolves in a linear, logarithmic, exponential or other way. All the
explanatory models are constructed on the basis of a model, such as the following,
for linear regression:
Y = β0 + β1X1 + β2X2 + …. + β kXk + ε, where
Y is the change that the programme is mainly supposed to produce (e.g. employment
of trainees)
X1-k are independent variables likely to explain the change.
β0-k are constants and
ε is the error term
Phenomena of co-linearity weaken the explanatory power. For example, when
questioning women about unemployment, if they have experienced periods of previous
unemployment which are systematically longer than those of men, it will not be possible to
separate the influence of the two explanatory factors: gender and duration of previous
unemployment.
68
Managerial Economics
b. Construction of a sample: To apply multiple regression, a large sample is usually
required (ideally between 2,000 to 15,000 individuals). Note that for time series data,
much less is needed.
c. Data collection: Reliable data must be collected, either from a monitoring system,
from a questionnaire survey or from a combination of both.
d. Calculation of coefficients: Coefficients can be calculated relatively easily, using
statistical software that is both affordable and accessible to PC users.
e. Test of the model: The model aims to explain as much of the variability of the
observed changes as possible. To check how useful a linear regression equation is,
tests can be performed on the square of the correlation coefficient r. This tells us
what percentage of the variability in the y variable can be explained by the x variable.
A correlation coefficient of 0.9 would show that 81% of the variability in Y is captured
by the variables X1-k used in the equation. The part that remains unexplained
represents the residue (ε). Thus, the smaller the residue better is the quality of the
model and its adjustment. The analysis of residues is a very important step: it is at
this stage that one sees the degree to which the model has been adapted to the
phenomena one wants to explain. It is the residue analysis that also enables one to
tell whether the tool has made it possible to estimate the effects in a plausible way
or not. If significant anomalies are detected, the regression model should not be
used to estimate effects and the original causal model should be re-examined, to see
if further predictive variables can be introduced.
2. Time series analysis: An analysis of the relationship between variables over a period of
time. Time-series analysis is useful in assessing how an economic or other variable
changes over time. For example, one may conduct a time-series analysis on a stock, sales
volumes, interest rates and quality measurements etc.
Methods for time series analyses may be divided into two classes: frequency-domain
methods (spectral analysis and recently wavelet analysis) and time-domain methods
(auto-correlation and cross-correlation).
a. Frequency domain: Frequency domain is a term used to describe the domain for
analysis of mathematical functions or signals with respect to frequency, rather than
time. A time-domain graph shows how a signal changes over time. Whereas a
frequency-domain graph shows how much of the signal lies within each given
frequency band over a range of frequencies. A frequency-domain representation can
also include information on the phase shift that must be applied to each sinusoid in
Managerial Economics
69
order to be able to recombine the frequency components to recover the original
time signal.
b. Time domain: Time domain is a term used to describe the analysis of mathematical
functions, or physical signals, with respect to time. In the time domain, the signal or
function's value is known for all real numbers, for the case of continuous time, or at
various separate instants in the case of discrete time. An oscilloscope is a tool
commonly used to visualise real-world signals in the time domain.
3. Utility analysis: A subset of consumer demand theory that analysis consumer behavior
and market demand using total utility and marginal utility. The key principle of utility
analysis is the law of diminishing marginal utility, which offers an explanation for the law
of demand and the negative slope of the demand curve. The main focus of utility analysis
is on the fulfillment of wants and needs acquired by the utilization of goods. It
additionally facilitates in getting the knowledge of market demand as well as the law of
demand. The law of demand by way of utility analysis states that consumers buy goods
that fulfill their wants and needs, i.e., create utility. Those goods that create more utility
are more important to consumers and therefore buyers are prepared to pay a higher
price. The main aspect to the law of demand is that the utility created falls when the
quantity consumed rises. As such, the demand price that buyers are prepared to pay falls
when the quantity demanded rises.
The law of diminishing marginal utility asserts that marginal utility or the
extra utility acquired from consuming a good, falls as the quantity consumed rises.
Basically, each extra good consumed is less fulfilling as compared to the previous one.
This law is mostly significant for awareness into market demand as well as the law of
demand.
a. Cardinal utility: A measure of utility, or satisfaction derived from the consumption of
goods and services that can be measured using an absolute scale. Cardinal utility
exists if the utility derived from consumption is measurable in the same way that
other physical characteristics--height and weight--are measured using a scale that is
comparable between people. There is little or no evidence to suggest that such
measurement is possible and is not even needed for modern consumer demand
theory and indifference curve analysis. Cardinal utility, however, is often employed
as a convenient teaching device for discussing such concepts as marginal utility and
utility maximisation.
70
Managerial Economics
b. Ordinal utility: A method of analysing utility, or satisfaction derived from the
consumption of goods and services, based on a relative ranking of the goods and
services consumed. With ordinal utility, goods are only ranked only in terms of more
or less preferred, there is no attempt to determine how much more one good is
preferred to another. Ordinal utility is the underlying assumption used in the analysis
of indifference curves and should be compared with cardinal utility, which
(hypothetically) measures utility using a quantitative scale.
Study Notes
Assessment
Write notes on the following:
1. Objectives of Demand Forecast
2. Importance of Demand Forecast
3. Methods of Demand Forecast
4. Regression analysis
5. Cardinal utility
6.
Ordinal utility
Managerial Economics
71
Discussion
Discuss Delphi method and Game theory in detail.
2.7 Summary
Demand: "The demand for a commodity at a given price is the amount of it which
will be bought per unit of time at that price”.
Law of Demand: “The demand for a commodity increases with a fall in its price and
decreases with a rise in its price, other things remaining the same”. The Law of demand thus
merely states that the price and demand of a commodity are inversely related, provided all
other things remain unchanged or as economists put it ceteris paribus.
Assumptions to the Law of Demand: We can state the assumptions of the law of
demand as follows: (1) Income level should remain constant, (2) Tastes of the buyer should
not change, (3) Prices of other goods should remain constant, (4) No new substitutes for the
commodity, (5) Price rise in future should not be expected and (6) Advertising expenditure
should remain the same.
Why Demand Curve Slopes Downwards: The reasons behind the law of demand, i.e.,
inverse relationship between price and quantity demanded are following: (i) substitution
effect, (ii) income effect, (iii) diminishing marginal utility.
Market Demand: The total quantity which all the consumers of a commodity are
willing to buy at a given price per time unit, other things remaining the same, is known as
market demand for the commodity. In other words, the market demand for a commodity is
the sum of individual demands by all the consumers (or buyers) of the commodity, per time
unit and at a given price, other factors remaining the same.
Individual demand: The individual demand means the quantity of a product that an
individual can buy given its price. It implies that the individual has the ability and willingness
to pay.
Demand Function: Demand function is a mathematical expression of the law of
demand in quantitative terms. A demand function may produce a linear or curvilinear
demand curve depending on the nature of relationship between the price and quantity
demanded. The functional relationship between the demand for a commodity and its
72
Managerial Economics
various determinants may be expressed mathematically as:
Dx = f (Px, Py, M, T, A, U) where, Dx = Quantity demanded for commodity X, f =
functional relation, Px = The price of commodity X, Py = The price of substitutes and
complementary goods, M = The money income of the consumer, T = The taste of the
consumer, A = The advertisement effects, U = Unknown variables or influences
Elasticity of Demand: The concept of elasticity of demand can be defined as the
degree of responsiveness of demand to given change in price of the commodity.
Methods of Measurement of Elasticity of Demand: By using three different
methods, elasticity of demand is measured.
•
Ratio Method
•
Expenditure Method
•
Point Method
Demand Forecasting: According to Cardiff and Still, “Demand forecasting is an
estimate of sales during a specified future period based on a proposed marketing plan and a
set of particular uncontrollable and competitive forces’’.
Objectives of Demand Forecast: Following are the objectives of demand forecasting:
•
Formulation of production policy
•
Price policy formulation
•
Proper control of sales
•
Arrangement of finance
•
To decide about the production capacity
•
Labour requirements
•
Production planning
GAME THEORY
Game theory is a branch of applied mathematics that is used in the social sciences,
most notably in economics, as well as in biology (particularly evolutionary biology and
ecology), engineering, political science, international relations, computer science and
philosophy. It attempts to capture behaviour mathematically in strategic situations or games
in which an individual's success in making choices depends on the choices of others.
While initially developed to analyse competitions in which one individual does better
at another's expense (zero sum games), it has been expanded to include a wide class of
interactions, which are classified according to several criteria.
Managerial Economics
73
2.8 Self Assessment Test
Broad Questions
1. State the law of demand and show it through a demand schedule and a demand curve.
What are the exceptions to the law of demand?
2. Explain the concepts of arc and point elasticity of the demand curve for a commodity.
What is the problem in using the arc elasticity? How can this problem be resolved? How
is the point elasticity on curvilinear demand curve measured?
3. Prove the following:
a. Two parallel straight-line demand curves have different price elasticity at the same
price.
b. Two intersecting straight-line demand curves have different elasticity at the point of
intersection.
Short Questions
a. Demand Forecasting
b. Law of Demand
c. Increase and decrease in demand
d. Importance of Demand Forecasting
e. Methods of measuring Elasticity of Demand
f. Demand Forecast and Sales Forecast
g. Prediction markets
h. Delphi method
i.
Game theory
j.
Regression analysis
k. Time series analysis
l.
Cardinal utility
m. Ordinal utility
74
Managerial Economics
Numerical Questions:
1. Derive a demand curve from the demand function Q = 50 - 10P.
2. From the demand function Q = 600/P, show that the total expenditure on the
commodity remains unchanged as price falls. Estimate elasticity of demand along the
demand curve at P = Rs 4 and P = Rs 2.
3. Suppose a demand schedule is given as follows:
Pri
ce (Rs)
1
00
Qu
antity
8
0
1
00
6
0
2
00
4
0
3
00
0
5
6
0
4
00
2
00
00
a. Work out the elasticity for the fall in price from Rs 80 to Rs 60.
b. Calculate the elasticity for the increase in the price from Rs 60 to Rs 80.
Why is the elasticity coefficient in (a) different form that in (b)?
2.9
Further Reading
1. Business Economics, Adhikary, M,., Excel Books, New Delhi, 2000
2. Economics Theory and Operations Analysis, Baumol, W J., 3rd ed., Prentice Hall Inc, 1996
3. Managerial Economics, Chopra, O P., Tata McGraw Hill, New Delhi, 1985
4. Managerial Economics, Keat, Paul G and Philips K Y Young, Prentice Hall, New Jersey,
1996
5. A Modern Micro Economics, Koutsoyiannis, Macmillan, 1991
6. Economics Organisation and Management, Milgrom, P and Roberts J, Prentice Hall Inc,
Englewood Clitts, New Jersey, 1992
7. Managerial Economics, Maheshwari, Yogesh, Sultanchand and Sons, 2009
8. Managerial Economics, Varshney, R L., Sultanchand and Sons, 2007
Managerial Economics
75
Assignment
1. Which of the following statements are right or wrong?
a. When percentage change in price is greater than the percentage change in quantity
demanded, e > 1
b. The coefficient of the price-elasticity of a demand curve between any two points
remains the same irrespective of whether price falls or rises.
c. The slope of a demand curve gives the measure of its elasticity.
d. The slope of demand curve multiplied by P/Q measures the elasticity of demand.
e. Two parallel straight-line demand curves have the same elasticity at a given price.
f. Two intersecting straight-line demand curves have the same elasticity at the point of
their intersection.
g. Two straight line demand curves originating at the same point on the price axis have
the same elasticity at a given price,
h. When income increases, the expenditure on essential goods increases more than
proportionately
i.
The demand for a product increases when price of its substitute increases,
j.
The greater the cross elasticity, the closer the substitute,
k. The price elasticity of the supply of a commodity is always negative.
l.
The income elasticity of the demand for luxury goods is always positive,
m. If price elasticity is less than one and price rises, the total expenditure decreases,
n. If price elasticity is equal to one, the total revenue increases with the increase in
price
[Ans. Right Statements—(g), (i), (j), (k)]
2. Which of the following gives the measures of price elasticity of demand?
a. The ratio of change in demand to the change in price
b. The ratio of change in price to the change in demand
c. The ratio of % change in demand to % change in price
d. None of the above
76
Managerial Economics
3. Which of the following gives the measure of price elasticity of demand?
a. (AQ/AP)(P/Q)
b. (AP/AQHP/Q)
c. (AQ/AP) (Q/P)
4. Price of a commodity falls and its demand increases so that elasticity is estimated to be
1.25. Suppose price increases back to its old level. Will price elasticity be (a) the same (b)
less than 1.25 (c) higher than 1.25?
5. At a given price, two parallel demand curves have
a. The same point elasticity
b. Different point elasticity
6. Two intersecting demand curves have at the point of their intersection (a) the same
elasticity (b) a different elasticity
7. A less-than-zero income elasticity indicates that with an increase in income,
consumption of a product
(a) Turns negative (b) increase
(b) Decrease (d) remains constant?
[Ans. 2. (a), 3. (c), 4. (b), 5. (b), 6. (b), 7. (c)]
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
Managerial Economics
77
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
Managerial Economics
78
Unit 3
Production and Cost Functions
Learning Outcome
After going through this unit, you will be able to:
•
Discuss Production Function
•
Outline Concepts of Cost Functions
•
Summarise Concept of isoquants and isocosts
•
Explain concepts of Economies and Diseconomies of scale
•
Describe Short and Long run Production Function
•
Compare Short and Long run Cost Function
Time Required to Complete the unit
1.
1st Reading: It will need 3 Hrs for reading a unit
2.
2nd Reading with understanding: It will need 4 Hrs for reading and understanding a
unit
3.
Self Assessment: It will need 3 Hrs for reading and understanding a unit
4.
Assignment: It will need 2 Hrs for completing an assignment
5.
Revision and Further Reading: It is a continuous process
Content Map
3.1
Introduction
3.2
Production Function
3.2.1
Uses of Production Function
3.2.2
Types of Production Function
3.2.3
Short run and Long run Production Function
Managerial Economics
79
3.3
Cost Function
3.3.1 Short run Cost Function
3.3.2 Relation between AC and MC
3.3.3 Long run Cost Function
3.4
Production ISOQUANT
3.4.1
Isoquants
3.4.2
Types of Isoquants
3.4.3
Properties of Isoquants
3.5
ISOCOST
3.6
Economies of Scale
3.6.1
Concept of Economies of Scale
3.6.2
Laws of Returns to Scale
3.6.3
Economies and Diseconomies of Scale
3.7
Summary
3.8
Self Assessment Test
3.9
Further Reading
80
Managerial Economics
3.1 Introduction
Production functions and cost functions are the cornerstones of business and
managerial economics. A production function is a mathematical relationship that captures
the essential features of the technology by means of which an organisation metamorphoses
resources such as land, labour and capital into goods or services such as steel or cement. It is
the economist’s distillation of the salient information contained in the engineer’s blueprints.
Mathematically, let Y denote the quantity of a single output produced by the quantities of
inputs denoted (x1,..., xn). Then the production function f(x1,...,xn) describes how a given
output can be produced by an infinite combinations of inputs (x1,.., xn), given the technology
in use. Several important features of the structure of the technology are captured by the
shape of the production function. Relationships among inputs include the degree of
substitutability or complementarily among pairs of inputs, as well as the ability to aggregate
groups of inputs into a shorter list of input aggregates. Relationships between output and
the inputs include economies of scale and the technical efficiency with which inputs are
utilised to produce a given output.
Each of these features has implications for the shape of the cost function, which is
intimately related to the production function. A cost function is also a mathematical
relationship, one that relates the expenses an organisation incurs on the quantity of output
it produces and to the unit prices it pays. Mathematically, let E denote the expense an
organisation incurs in the production of output quantity Y when it pays unit prices (p1,..., pn)
for the inputs it employs. Then the cost function C(y, p1, ..., pn) describes the minimum
expenditure required to produce output quantity Y when input unit prices are (p1,..., pn),
given the technology in use and so E≥C(y, p1,...,pn). A cost function is an increasing function
of (y, p1,..., pn), but the degrees to which minimum cost increases with an increase in the
quantity of output produced or in any input price depends on the features describing the
structure of production technology. For example, scale economies enable output to expand
faster than input usage. In other words, proportionate increase in output is larger than the
proportionate increase in inputs. Such a situation is also denoted as elasticity of production
in relation to inputs being grater than one scale economies thus create an incentive for
large-scale production and by analogous reasoning scale diseconomies create a
technological deterrent to large-scale production. For another example, if a pair of inputs is
a close substitute and the unit price of one of the inputs increases, the resulting increase in
cost is less than if the two inputs were poor substitutes or complements. Finally, if wastage
in the organisation causes actual output to fall short of maximum possible output or if inputs
are misallocated in light of their respective unit prices, then actual cost exceeds minimum
Managerial Economics
81
cost; both technical and allocative inefficiency are costly.
As these examples suggest, under fairly general conditions the shape of the cost
function is a mirror image of the shape of the production function. Thus, the cost function
and the production function generally afford equivalent information concerning the
structure of production technology. This equivalence relationship between production
functions and cost functions is known as ‘duality’ and it states that one of the two functions
has certain features if and only if, the other has certain features. Such a duality relationship
has a number of important implications. Since the production function and the cost function
are based on different data, duality enables us to employ either function as the basis of an
economic analysis of production, without fear of obtaining conflicting inferences. The
theoretical properties of associated output supply and input demand equations may be
inferred from either the theoretical properties of the production function or, more easily, for
those of the dual cost function.
Empirical analysis aimed at investigating the nature of scale economies, the degree
of input substitutability or complementarily, or the extent and nature of productive
inefficiency can be conducted using a production function or again more easily using a cost
function.
If the time period under consideration is sufficiently short, then the assumption of a
given technology is valid. The longer-term effects of technological progress or the
adaptation of existing superior technology can be introduced into the analysis. Technical
progress increases the maximum output that can be obtained from a given collection of
inputs and so in the presence of unchanging unit prices of the inputs technical progress
reduces the minimum cost that must be incurred to produce a given quantity of output. This
phenomenon is merely an extension to the time dimension of the duality relationship that
links production functions and cost functions. Of particular empirical interest are the
magnitude of technical progress and its cost-reducing effects and the possible labour-saving
bias of technological progress and its employment effects that are transmitted from the
production function, to the cost function and then to the labour demand function.
3.2 Production Function
Synonymous to the demand theory that pivots around the concept of the demand
function, the theory of production revolves around the concept of the production function.
A production function can be an equation, table or graph presenting the maximum amount
of a commodity that a firm can produce from a given set of inputs during a period of time.
82
Managerial Economics
The concept of production function portrays the ways in which the factors of
production are combined by a firm to produce different levels of output. More specifically, it
shows the maximum volume of physical output available from a given set of inputs or the
minimum set of inputs necessary to produce any given level of output.
The production function comprises an engineering or technical relation, because the
relation between inputs and outputs is a technical one. The production function is
determined by a given state of technology. When the technology improves the production
function changes, because the new production function can yield greater output from the
given inputs or smaller inputs will be enough to produce a given level of output. Further, the
production function incorporates the idea of efficiency. Thus, production function is not any
relation between inputs and outputs, but a relation in which a given set of inputs produces a
maximum output. Therefore, the production function includes all the technically efficient
methods of producing an output.
A method or process of production is a combination of inputs required for the
production of output. A method of production is technically efficient to any other method if
it uses less of at least one factor and no more of the other factors as compared with another
method.
Example: Technically Efficient Method of Production
Let us suppose that commodity X is produced by two methods by using labour and
capital:
Factor inputs
Method A
Method B
Labour
3
4
Capital
4
4
In the above example, method B is inefficient compared to method A because
method B uses more of labour and same amount of capital as compared to method A. A
profit maximising firm will not be interested in improvident or inefficient methods of
production. If method A uses less of one factor and more of the other factor as compared
with any other method C, then method A and C are not directly comparable. For example,
let us suppose that a commodity is produced by two methods:
Managerial Economics
83
Factor inputs
Method A
Method C
Labour
3
2
Capital
4
5
In the above example, both methods A and C are technically efficient and are
included in the production function, which one of them would be chosen depends on the
prices of factors. The choice of any particular technique from a set of technically efficient
techniques (or methods) is an economic one, based on prices and not a technical one.
In a production function, the dependent variable is the output and the independent
variables are the inputs. Thus, the production function can be expressed as
Q = ƒ (N,L,K,E,T)
Where, Q = Quantity Produced, N = Natural resources, L = Labour, K = Capital, E =
Entrepreneur or organizer and T = Technology.
For simplicity, only the inputs of labour and capital are considered independent
variables in a production function. Normally, land does not enter the production function
explicitly because of the implicit assumption that land does not impose any restriction on
production. However, labour and capital enter production explicitly. A simple specification
of a production function is
Q = ƒ (L, K)
Where Q, as above, is the output, L and K are the quantities of labour and capital and
ƒ shows the functional relation between the inputs and output. The production function is
based on an implicit assumption that the technology is given. This is because an
improvement in technical knowledge will lead to larger output from the use of same
quantity of inputs.
3.2.1 USES OF PRODUCTION FUNCTION
The production function can have various uses. It can be used to compute the leastcost factor combination for a given output or the maximum output combination for a given
cost. Knowledge of production function may be helpful in deciding on the value of
employing a variable factor in the production process. As long as the marginal revenue
productivity of a variable factor exceeds its price, it will be profitable to increase its use.
When the marginal revenue productivity of the factor becomes equal to its price the
additional employment of the factor should be stopped. Since, the production function
shows the returns to scale it will help in the decision making. If the returns to scale are
84
Managerial Economics
diminishing, it is not worthwhile to increase production. The opposite will be true if the
returns to scale are increasing.
3.2.2 TYPES OF PRODUCTION FUNCTION
Production function is of two different forms:
•
The fixed proportion production function
•
The variable proportion production function
These can be explained as follows:
1. Fixed Proportion Production Function
A fixed proportion production function is one in which the technology requires a
fixed combination of inputs, say capital and labour, to produce a given level of output. There
is only one way in which the factors may be combined to produce a given level of output
efficiently. In this type of production, there is no possibility of substitution between the
factors of production.
The fixed proportion production function is illustrated by isoquants which are ‘L’
shaped or ‘right angle’ shaped. This is shown in Fig. 3.1 below.
Fig. 3.1: Fixed Proportion Production Function
Let us suppose that at point A, the output is one unit. The isoquant Q1 passing
through the point A1 shows that one unit of output is produced by using 2 units of capital
and 3 units of labour. In other words, the capital-labour ratio is 2:3. In this case with 2 units
of capital, any increase in labour beyond 3 units will not increase output and, therefore,
labour beyond 3 units is redundant. Similarly, with 3 units of labour, any increase in capital
beyond 2 units is redundant. The kink point shows the most efficient combination of factors.
The capital labour ratio must be maintained for any level of output. The output can be
doubled by doubling the quantity of inputs, that is, two units of output can be produced by 4
Managerial Economics
85
units of capital and 6 units of labour.
labou Thus isoquant Q2 passes through thee point A2. The line
OA describes a production
n process,
proces that is, a way of combining inputss to obt
obtain certain
output. The slope of the linee shows the capital-labour ratio.
The fixed proportion
on production
pr
function is characterised by constant
onstant returns to
scale, that is, a proportionate
ate incre
increase in inputs leads to a proportionate increase in outputs.
This type of production function provides the basis for the input - output analysis in
economics. Thus, this typee of isoquant
iso
is also called input-output isoquant
quant o
or “leontiff”
isoquant after Leontiff who invented
invente the input-output analysis.
2. Variable Proportions Production
oduction Function
The variable proportion
rtion pro
production function is the most familiar productio
roduction function.
In this case, a given level of outpu
output can be produced by several alternative
ive comb
combinations of
factors of production, say capital and
a labour. It is assumed that the factors
rs can be combined
in infinite number of ways.
ays. The common level of output obtained from alternative
combinations of capital and
d labour is given by an isoquant Q in Fig. 3.2, given
ven belo
below:
Fig. 3.2: Variable
Va
Proportions Production Function
The isoquant
nt Q is the locus of efficient points of factorr combinations
comb
to
produce a given level of output. The isoquant is continuous, smooth and con
convex to the
origin. It assumes continuous
ous sub
substitutability of capital and labour over
er a cer
certain range,
beyond which factors cannot
ot substitute
subst
each other.
Since the variable
ariable proportions
p
production function is the most co
common we
discuss below in detail thee isoqua
isoquant representing the variable the proportions
ortions production
function.
86
Manageri
rial Economics
3.2.3 SHORT RUN AND LONG RUN PRODUCTION FUNCTION
The discussion of production up to now has ignored the time needed to build
production facilities. There is a need to take into consideration the time factor in the
discussion on the production. Thus, in this section we consider the behaviour of production
in the short-run and long-run.
The short run is a phase in which the organisation can alter manufacturing by
changing variable factors such as supplies and labour but cannot change fixed factors such
as capital. The long run is a phase adequately long so that all factors together with capital
can be altered.
The factors which can be increased in the short run are called variable factors, since
they can be easily changed in a short period of time. Hence, the level of production can be
increased within the limits of existing plant capacity during the short run. Thus, the short run
production function proves that in the short run the output can be increased by changing
the variable factors, keeping the fixed factors constant. In other words, in the short run the
output is produced with a given scale of production, that is, with a given size of plant. The
behaviour of production in the short-run where the output can be increased by increasing
one variable factor keeping other factors fixed is called law of variable proportions.
The size of plant can be varied in the long run and, therefore, the scale of production
can be varied in the long run. The long run analysis of the laws of production is referred to as
laws of returns to scale.
Study Notes
Managerial Economics
87
Assessment
1.
Explain Production Function.
2.
What are the uses and types of Production Function?
3.
Explain short and long run production function.
Discussion
Discuss which is the technically efficient method of production out of the two given in the table
below, and why?
Factor inputs
Method A
Method B
Labour
5
4
Capital
4
4
3.3 Cost Function
Cost function is a derived function. It is derived from the production function, which
describes the efficient method of production at any given time. The production function
specifies the technical relationships between inputs and the level of output. Thus, cost will
vary with the changes in the level of output, nature of production function, or factor prices.
Thus, symbolically, we may write the cost function as
C = ƒ(X, T, Pf)
Where, C = Total cost, X = Output, T = Technology, Pf = Prices of factors.
Total cost is evidently, an increasing function of output, C = ƒ (X), ceterius paribus.
The clause 'ceteris paribus' implies that 'all other factors which determine costs are
constant'. If these factors change, they will affect the cost. The technology is itself
determined by the physical quantities of the factor inputs, the quality of the factor inputs,
the efficiency of the entrepreneur, both in organising the physical side of the production and
in making the correct economic choice of techniques. Thus, any change in these
88
Managerial Economics
determinants will shift the production function and hence will shift the cost curve. For
instance, the introduction of a better method of organising production or the application of
an educational programme to the existing labour will shift the production function upwards
and hence will shift down the cost curve. Similarly, the improvement of raw material, or the
improvement in the use of the same raw materials will lead to a downward shift of the cost
function.
Since no output is possible without an input, an increase in factor prices, ceteris
paribus, will lead to an increase in the cost. The factor prices depend on the demand and
supply of factors in the economy.
Of all the determinants of cost, the cost-output relationship is considered as the
most important one. Thus, in economic analysis the cost function is analysed with respect to
output. This is because the cost-output relationship is subject to faster and more frequent
changes. The relationship between cost and output is analysed with respect to short-run and
long-run.
3.3.1 SHORT RUN COST FUNCTION
In the short-run the firm cannot change or modify overhead factors such as plant,
equipment and scale of its organisation. In the short-run output can be increased or
decreased by changing the variable inputs like labour, raw material, etc. Thus, the short-run
costs of production are segmented into fixed and variable costs. On the other hand, in the
long-run all factors can be adjusted. Hence, in the long run all costs are variable and none
are fixed.
1) Total Cost: Fixed and Variable
The total cost (TC) of the firm is a function of output (q). It will increase with the
increase in output, that is, it varies directly with the output. In symbols, it can be written as
TC = ƒ(q)
Since the output is produced by fixed and variable factors, the total cost can
be divided into two components: total fixed cost (TFC) and total variable cost (TVC).
TC = TFC + TVC
•
Fixed Cost
Fixed costs are those which are independent of output. They must be paid even if the
firm produces no output. They will not change even if output changes. They remain fixed
whether output is large or small. Fixed costs are also called 'overhead costs', 'sunk costs' or
Managerial Economics
89
'supplementary costs'. They comprise payments such as rent, interest, insurance,
depreciation charges, maintenance costs, property taxes, administrative expense like
manager’s salary and so on. In the short period, the total amount of these fixed costs will
not increase or decrease when the volume of the firms output rises or falls (See Table 3.3).
•
Variable Cost
Variable costs are those which are incurred on the employment of variable factors of
production. They vary with the level of output. They increase with the rise in output and
decrease with the fall in output. By definition, variable costs remain zero when output is
zero. They include payments for wages, raw materials, fuel, power, transport and the like.
Marshall called these variable costs as “Prime Costs” of production.
The relation between total variable cost and output may not be linear, that is,
variable cost may not increase by the same amount for every unit increase in output. This is
shown in the table mentioned below:
Table 3.1: A Schedule of a Firm's Total Cost
Output (q)
(1)
Total Fixed Total
Total
Cost (TFC)
(TC)
(2)
Variable
Cost (TVC)
Cost
(4)
(3)
90
0
100
0
100
1
100
25
125
2
100
40
140
3
100
50
150
4
100
70
170
5
100
100
200
6
100
145
145
7
100
205
305
8
100
285
385
Managerial Economics
9
100
385
485
10
100
515
615
Table 3.1 shows a simplified
simplifie cost schedule showing the relation betwee
between costs for
each different levels output.
t. We ca
can observe the following relations:
•
The column (2) shows that
hat TFC remains fixed at all levels output.
•
The column (3) shows that TVC varies with the output and it is zero when th
the output is
nil. It can also be observed
rved from
fro the column (3) that TVC does not change
hange in the same
proportion. In the beginning,, as the output increases, TVC increases att a decre
decreasing rate,
but after a point it increases
eases at an increasing rate. This is due to the operation
peration of the law
of variable proportions.
•
The column (4) shows that tot
total costs are equal to fixed plus variable
le costs
costs. TC varies
with the change in output
ut in the same proportion as the TVC.
The above costs and
d output
outpu relations are also shown in Fig 3.3. Byy plottin
plotting the cost
data of Table 3.1, graphically
lly and joining
jo
the plotted points by smooth curves,
rves, we can obtain
total fixed, total variable and
d total cost
c curves.
Fig. 3.3: Total Cost Curves
It can be seen from Fig 3.3
3. that since total fixed cost remains constant,
stant, TFC
T curve is
parallel to the X-axis. The TVC
VC curve
curv begins at zero and then rises gradually
lly in the beginning
and eventually, becomes steeper
teeper aas the output rises. The TC curve is obtained
ained by adding up
vertically TFC and TVC curves.
ves. The shape of the TC curve is exactly the same
ame as tthat of TVC
curve because the same vertical
rtical distance
dis
separates TC and TVC curves.
Managerial Economics
91
2) Unit Costs
There are four different
rent kinds
kin of unit costs, viz. average total cost (or as us
usually called
average cost), average fixed
d cost, aaverage variable cost and marginal cost.
•
Average Total Cost (ATC)
One of the most important
portant cost concepts is average total cost. When
hen com
compared with
price or average revenue it will allow
allo a business to determine whether orr not it is making a
profit. Average total cost is total cost
co divided by the number of units produced
uced i.e.
Since, the total costt is the sum
s
of total fixed cost and total variable
le cost, tthe average
total cost is also the sum of average
averag fixed cost (AFC) and average variable
le cost (A
(AVC). Thus,
Average Total Cost (ATC) = Average Fixed Cost (AFC) + Average Variable Cost
ost (AVC
(AVC).
•
Average Fixed Cost (AFC)
By dividing total fixed
ed cost b
by output we get average fixed cost.
Since, the same
ame amount
am
of fixed cost is shared equally between
tween tthe various,
units of output; AFC falls continuou
ontinuously as output rises.
•
Average Variable Cost (AVC)
Average variable cost
st is total
tota variable cost divided by output. Thus,
The average variable
le cost will generally fall as the output risess from zzero to the
normal capacity level of output due
d to the operation of increasing returns.
turns. B
Beyond the
normal capacity output, anyy increa
increase in output will increase AVC quite sharply
arply on account of
the operation of diminishingg returns.
return
•
Marginal Cost (MC)
Marginal cost is the extra or
o additional cost of producing one extraa unit of output. In
economics the term ‘marginal’
inal’ whether
wh
applied to utility, cost, production,
n, consumption
consu
or
92
Manageri
rial Economics
whatever means ‘incremental’
al’ or ‘extra’.
‘
Thus, marginal cost is the totall cost of n units of
output minus the total cost of n--1 units. In symbols:
Since, fixed costs do
o not change
ch
with outputs, MC is independentt of fixe
fixed cost. On
the other hand, variable costs
osts vary with output in the short-run and therefore,
refore, MC can be
calculated from total variable
ble cost. Hence, marginal cost is the addition to
o the tot
total variable
cost for producing an additional
tional unit
un of output. In other words, marginal cost is eequal to the
change in TVC.
•
Computation of AC, AFC,
C, AVC and
a MC
The computation off AC, AFC,
AFC AVC and MC and their relationships are illust
illustrated by a
hypothetical example and it is show
shown in Table 3.2
Table 3.2: A Schedule of Short
hort Run Costs
Quantity
Q
Total
Total
Tota
Total
Marginal
Average
Average
Average
verage
Fixed
Variable
Cos
Cost
Cost
Total
Fixed
Variable
ariable
Cost
Cost
Cost
Cost
Cost
TFC
TVC
TC = MC
ATC
= AFC
= AVC
VC
TFC +
TC/q or TFC / q
TVC
ATC
=
AVC
+
=
TFC
FC / q
AFC
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
0
100
0
100
--
--
--
--
1
100
25
125
25
125
100
25
2
100
40
140
15
70
50
20
3
100
50
150
10
50
33.3
16.7
4
100
70
170
20
42.5
25
17.5
5
100
100
200
30
40
20
20
Managerial Economics
93
6
100
145
145
45
40.8
16.6
24.2
7
100
205
305
60
43.6
14.3
29.3
8
100
285
385
80
48.1
12.5
35.6
9
100
385
485
100
53.9
11.1
42.8
10
100
515
615
130
61.5
10
51.5
Column (7) shows that AFC declines continuously as output increases. We can
observe from column (8) that AVC falls initially, reaches a minimum and eventually rises with
the increase in output. From column (6) we can see that ATC too falls initially, reaches the
minimum and then rises as output increases. It can also be seen that ATC is the sum of AFC
and AVC. Column (5) shows that MC too behaves in the same way as AVC and ATC.
•
Relationship between AC, AFC, AVC and MC Curves
The relationship between AC, AFC, AVC and MC is explained graphically by drawing
respective cost curves in Fig. 3.4. The behaviour of cost curves is explained below.
Fig. 3.4: Marginal and Average Cost Curves
Since, AFC is falling steadily as output increases, the AFC curve is also falling steadily
from left to right. In mathematical terms, AFC curve approaches both axes, that is, it gets
very near to but never touches either axis. Since we are dividing the constant fixed cost by
different levels of output, AFC curve is a rectangular hyperbola. This implies that if we
multiply AFC at any point on the AFC curve with the corresponding quantity of output, we
will always get the same total fixed cost. This property of the AFC curve shows that TFC is
constant throughout.
94
Managerial Economics
The AVC curve falls initially, reaches a minimum and then rises as output increases. It
falls slowly as the firm’s output rises from zero to the normal capacity level. Once normal
capacity output is reached AVC curve rises sharply with the increase in output. This is owing
to the fact that the use of more and more of the variable factors, say labour, will lead to
overcrowding and also to problems of organisation. Further, as the existing fixed factors are
used more intensively machines will breakdown more frequently. All these lead to sharp
increase in AVC.
If AFC and AVC curves are added together we obtain ATC curve or, as usually called,
average cost (AC) curve. In the beginning as output rises ATC curve falls because of the
predominance of falling AFC curve. At higher levels of output AVC curve rises quite sharply
and therefore, ATC curve rises after a point. The continuous fall in average fixed costs will be
too small to offset it. Thus AC curve is ‘U’ shaped.
MC curve is also ‘U’ shaped as in Fig. 3.4. Marginal cost curve falls initially, then
reaches a minimum point and finally rises. The shape of the MC curve is determined by the
law of variable proportions, that is, by the behaviour of the marginal product of the variable
factor. MC curve intersects AC and AVC curves at their minimum. This is due to the
important relationship between marginal and average costs.
The relationship between AVC, ATC and MC can be summarised as follows:
•
AVC, ATC and MC fall first, then reach a minimum and finally rise as output increases.
•
The rate of change in MC is greater than that in AVC and therefore the MC is lowest at an
output lower than the output at which AVC is lowest.
•
The ATC falls for a longer range of output than the AVC and therefore the minimum ATC
is at a larger output than the minimum AVC.
•
MC = AVC, when AVC is lowest.
•
MC = ATC, when ATC is minimum.
3.3.2 RELATION BETWEEN AC AND MC
The relationship between AC and MC are the following:
•
If MC is below AC, then AC must be falling. This is because, if MC is below AC, then the
last unit produced costs less than the AC of all the earlier units produced. If the last unit
costs less than the earlier ones, then the new AC must be less than the old AC. Hence, AC
must be falling.
Managerial Economics
95
•
If MC is above AC, then the cost of the last unit produced will be higher than the AC of
the earlier units. Hence, the new AC must be higher than old AC. Therefore, when MC is
above AC, AC must be rising.
•
If MC is equal to AC, the last unit costs exactly the same as the AC of all earlier units.
Hence the new AC is equal to old AC. Thus, the AC curve is flat when AC equals MC.
The above mentioned relationship between AC and MC can be seen clearly with the
help of figure 3.5
Fig. 3.5: Relation between AC and MC
To the left of the lowest point of the AC curve, MC is below AC, so the AC curve is
falling. Even if MC is rising, AC will continue to fall as long as the rising MC is less than AC. To
the right of the minimum point of the AC curve, MC is above AC, so the AC curve is rising. At
the point where MC equals AC, the AC curve is flat. Hence the rising MC curve cuts the AC
curve at its lowest point.
The relationship between AC and MC can be easily understood by an example of a
cricket player’s batting averages. Let us assume that a cricket player’s batting average is 40.
If in his next innings he scores less than 40, let us assume 30, then his average score will fall
because his marginal score is less than his average score. Instead, if he scores more than 40,
say 50, in his next innings, then his average score will increase because his marginal score is
greater than his previous average score. On the other hand, assuming the average score is
40, if the batsman scores 40 in his next innings then his average score will remain the same
and his marginal and average scores will be equal.
This relationship between average and marginal cost can easily be recalled with the
aid of Fig. 3.6. It can be seen from the figure that so long as MC is below AC, average cost
falls, that is, MC pulls AC downwards. When MC is above AC, the average cost rises, that is,
MC pulls AC upwards. When MC equals AC, the average cost remains constant, that is, MC
pulls AC horizontally. The arrows show the direction of these pulls.
96
Managerial Economics
Fig.
Fig 3.6: Average and marginal cost
It is to be noted that
at a risin
rising MC curve also cuts AVC curve at itss lowest point. The
reason for this is exactly the
e same as
a that we have given above to explain why MC cuts AC at
its minimum point.
3.3.3 LONG RUN COST FUNCTION
ca amend its size and organisation to
o volatil
volatile demand
In the long-run a firm can
conditions. In other words,, in the long-run
l
the firm can adjust its scale off operati
operations or size
of plant to produce any required
uired ou
output in the most efficient way. Thus, in
n the lon
long run fixed
factors can be altered. Manageme
nagement can be restructured to run a firm of a diff
different size.
Capital can also be used differently.
different In short, all factors are variable in the lon
long run and
therefore the scale of operations
ations can
ca be altered.
Thus, in the long-run
un all costs
co are variable (i.e. the firm faces no
o fixed ccosts). The
length of time of the long-run
run depends
dep
on the industry. In some service industri
industries, such as
dry-cleaning, the period off the long-run
lon
may be only a few months or weeks. For capital
intensive industries, such as elect
lectricity-generating plant, the construction
on of a new plant
may take many years and hence
ence long-run
lon
may be many years. The length of time o
of the longrun depends upon the time required
require for the firm to be able to vary all inputs.
The long-run is often presented
pres
as the planning sphere as the organi
organisation can
construct the plant that cuts
uts dow
down the expenditure of producing any estimate
estimated level of
output. Once the plant hass been constructed, the organisation operatess in the short-run.
Therefore, the organisation plans for
fo the long-run and operates in the short-run.
run.
LONG RUN AVERAGE COST CURVE
In the long run, a firm can have a large number of alternative plant ssizes. For a
certain level of output, a plant
lant of a particular size will be most suited.
Corresponding to each
ach scale or size of the plant there will be an average
verage cost curve.
Hence, the long run is a series
ries of alternative
a
short run average cost curves,
es, assoc
associated with
different plants, out of which
ich a choice
cho is to be made by the firm for its actual
tual ope
operation. The
Managerial Economics
97
long run average cost curvee is derived
deriv from a number of short run averagee cost (S
(SAC) curves.
This is explained in Fig 3.7.
Fig 3.7: Long run Average Cost Curve
The above figure is drawn on
o the assumption that there are three plants an
and they are
depicted by the short run average cost curves SAC1, SAC2, SAC3. A given plant is best suited
for a particular level of output.
tput. It can
c be seen from Fig. 3.7 that output OLL can be produced
at a lower cost with the plant SAC
SA 1, than with the plant SAC2. The cost of producing OL
output on plant SAC1, is ALL and it is less than the cost of producing the same output
o
with
plant SAC2. The difference in cost is equal to AB. If the firm wants to produce
oduce O
ON output it
can produce it either by plant
ant SAC1, or plant SAC2. But it would be advantageous
ageous ffor the firm
to use the plant SAC2 for ON
N level of output because the larger output OM
M can b
be obtained
at the lowest average cost from this
th plant. Thus, output larger than ON but
ut less th
than OQ can
be produced at a lower average
erage cost
co with plant SAC2. For output larger than
an OQ,
OQ the firm will
have to employ plant SAC3. For ins
instance, output OP can be produced at average cost of PE
with plant SAC3.
It is clear from the above analysis
an
that in the long run the firm has a choice regarding
the employment of a plant
nt and it
i will employ that plant which yields possible minimum
average cost for producingg a given
give output. Thus long-run average costt curve d
depicts the
lowest possible average cost
st for producing
pr
various levels of output. Assuming
ming tha
that there are
only three plants as in Fig. 3.7,, then
the LAC curve is the thick wave like portions
ions of SSAC curves,
i.e., FACDEG. The dotted portions
ortions of these SAC curves are of no importance
nce in th
the long-run
because the firm would prefer
efer to change
c
the size of the plant rather than operate on them.
If we assume that the
he size of
o the plant can be varied by infinitely small gra
gradations so
that there are numerous SAC
AC curves
curve corresponding to infinite number of plants, th
the long run
average cost curves will be
e smooth
smoo one as in Fig. 3.8. Since, we are assuming
ssuming an infinite
number of SAC curves, every
ry point on the LAC curve will be a tangency point
oint with some SAC
Manageri
rial Economics
98
curve. Hence, the LAC curve
rve is the
t
locus of the points of the lowest
st average
avera cost of
producing various levels of output.
Fig 3.8:
3 Long run Smooth Envelope Curve
It should be noted that, w
with one exception, the LAC curve is not tang
tangent to the
minimum points of the short
rt run average
a
cost curves. This exception occurs
urs at th
the optimum
level of output. In Fig. 3.8, this occurs
occ
at the output OM at which the lowest
west po
point of SAC3
coincides with the minimum
um point
poin on the LAC curve at point R. The plant SSAC3 which
produces the optimum output
tput OM at the minimum cost RM is the optimum
ptimum plant. For
outputs less than OM the lowest long
lo run costs occur on the falling portions
ions of SAC
S curves.
In Fig. 3.8, LAC curve is tangent
angent to falling portions of SAC1 and SAC2 at poin
points S and T
respectively, but points of S and T are not the minimum points of SAC1 and SA
SAC2. On the
other hand, for outputs greater
reater than
th OM, the lowest long run average costs oc
occur on the
rising portions of short run average cost curves.
Study Notes
Managerial Economics
99
Assessment
What is cost function?
Explain short and long run cost function.
Discussion
Discuss Relationship between AC, AFC, AVC and MC Curves.
3.4 Production Isoquant
3.4.1 ISOQUANTS
An isoquant shows all those combinations of factors which produce the same level of
output. An isoquant is also known as equal product curve or iso-product curve.
3.4.2 TYPES OF ISOQUANTS
The isoquant may have various shapes depending on the degree of substitutability of
factors:
1. Linear Isoquant: In this case, the isoquant would be straight lines as in Fig. 3.9 This type
assumes perfect substitutability of factors of production. In this case, labour and capital
are perfect substitutes, that is, the rate at which labour can be substituted for capital in
production is constant.
Fig. 3.9: Linear Isoquant
100
Managerial Economics
This isoquant evinces that a given commodity may be produced by using only capital
or only labour or by an infinite combination of labour and capital. At point A on the isoquant
the level of output can be produced with capital alone (i.e. without labour). Similarly, point B
indicates that the same level of output can be produced with labour alone (i.e. without any
capital). This is unrealistic because capital and labour are not perfectly substitutable.
2. Right Angled Isoquant: This assumes zero substitutability of the factors of production.
There is only one method of producing any one commodity. In this case, the isoquant
takes the form of a right angle as in Fig. 3.10.
Fig. 3.10: Right Angled Isoquant
In this case, labour and capital are perfect complements, that is, labour and capital
must be used in fixed proportion shown by point C. The output can be increased only by
increasing both the quantity of labour and capital in the same proportion depicted at the
point C.
This isoquant is called input-output isoquant or Leontief isoquant after Leontief, who
invented the input-output analysis.
3. Kinked Isoquant: This isoquant assumes only limited substitutability of capital and
labour. There are only a few processes for producing any one commodity.
This is shown in Fig. 3.11 where A1, A2, A3 and A4 show the production process and Q
is the kinked isoquant. In this case, the O substitutability of factors is possible only at the
kinks.
Managerial Economics
101
Fig. 3.11: Kinked Isoquant
This is more realistic type of isoquant because engineers, managers and production
executives consider the production process as a discrete rather than continuous process.
4. Smooth Convex Isoquant: This type of isoquant assumes continuous substitutability of
capital and labour over a certain range, beyond which the factors cannot substitute each
other. This is shown in Fig 3.12.
Fig. 3.12: Smooth Convex Isoquant
The traditional economic theory has adopted this isoquant for analysis since it is
uncomplicated. Further, this is an approximation to the more realistic form of a kinked
isoquant because as the number of process become infinite, the isoquant becomes a
smooth curve. Therefore, the properties of this isoquant are explained in detail below.
DERIVATION OF SMOOTH CONVEX ISOQUANT
It is assumed that each of the different combinations of labour and capital shown in
Table 3.3 produces the same level of output, that is, 20 units. The combinations are such
that if one factor is increased the other factor is decreased and vice versa. All these
combinations are technically efficient.
102
Managerial Economics
Table 3.3: Various Combinations of Labour and Capital to Produce 20 Units of Output
Factor Combination
Labour
Capital
A
1
15
B
2
11
C
3
8
D
4
6
If we plot all these combinations and join them we obtain a curve Q. This is shown in
Fig 3.13.
Fig. 3.13: Isoquant or Equal Product Curve
The curve Q is the isoquant or equal product curve. It shows all those combinations
of labour and capital which, with a given technology, produce 20 units of output. Thus, an
isoquant is the locus of all those sublimations of labour and capital, which yield the same
level of output. In other words, an isoquant includes all the technically efficient methods of
producing a given level of output.
Isoquant Map
We can label isoquants in physical units of output without any difficulty. Since, each
isoquant represents a specified level of output it is possible to say by how much the output
is greater or lesser on one isoquant than on other. This is explained by an isoquant map
shown in Fig. 3.14
Managerial Economics
103
Fig. 3.14: Isoquant Map
It shows that the output is 20 units, 40 units and 60 units on isoquants Q1, Q2 and Q3
respectively. Thus, on isoquant Q2 the output is 20 units more than on isoquant Q1; and on
isoquant Q3 the output is 40 units more than on isoquant Q1. So, an isoquant map facilitates
not only measurement of the physical quantities of output but also comparison the size of
output between the various isoquants. In theory, an isoquant map contains an infinite
number of isoquants. This is because the response of output to infinite changes in factors is
assumed to be continuous.
3.4.3 PROPERTIES OF ISOQUANTS
The important properties of isoquants are the following:
1. Isoquants slope downwards to the right: It means that, in order to keep the output
constant; when the amount of one factor is increased the quantity of other factor must
be reduced.
An upward sloping isoquant demonstrates that a given product can be produced with
less of both the factors of production. An entrepreneur, who is maximising profits, would
not use any combinations of factors shown on an upward sloping portion of an isoquant.
Therefore, the points on the upward sloping portion of an isoquant cannot represent an
equilibrium position. Similarly, a horizontal or vertical range of an isoquant cannot also
represent a possible position of equilibrium. In this case, the same output could be obtained
at a reduced cost by reducing the amount of one of the factors. Thus, isoquants slope
downwards to the right as in fig 3.15.
104
Managerial Economics
Fig. 3.15: Isoquant sloping downwards
2. Isoquants are convex to the origin: The slope, at any point of an isoquant, is negative. Its
numerical value measures the marginal rate of technical substitution between labour
and capital. It equals the ratio of the marginal product of labour to the marginal product
of capital. Thus, the slope of an isoquant is
Where
K is the change in capital,
L is the change in labour, MRTSLK is the marginal
rate of technical substitution of labour for capital, MPL is the marginal product of labour and
MPK is the marginal product of capital.
The convexity of isoquant means that as we move down the curve less and less of
capital is given up for an additional unit of labour so as to keep constant the level of output.
This can be observed from the Fig. 3.16.
Fig. 3.16: Convex Isoquant
It can be seen from the figure above that as we increase labour at a constant rate the
amount of capital given up ( K) for an additional unit of labour goes on falling. Thus, the
convexity of the isoquant shows that the marginal rate of technical substitution of labour for
capital is diminishing.
Managerial Economics
105
If the isoquant is concave to the origin it would mean that the marginal rate of
technical substitution is increasing. This behaviour is elucidated in Fig. 3.17
Fig 3.17: Concave Isoquant
It is apparent from the Fig. 3.17 that as the labour is increased at a constant rate the
amount of capital given up ( K) goes on increasing. Such behaviour is irrational and
therefore, isoquants are not concave to the origin.
3. Isoquants do not intersect: By definition isoquants, like indifference curves, can never
cut each other. If they cut each other it would be a logical contradiction.
4. Isoquants cannot touch either axis: If an isoquant touches any axis, as in Fig. 3.18 it
would mean that the output can be produced with the help of one factor. It is unrealistic
because output cannot be produced only by labour or capital alone.
Fig 3.18: Isoquant touching axis
106
Managerial Economics
Study Notes
Assessment
Write short notes on:
1. Types of Isoquants
2. Production Isoquants
3. Properties of Isoquants
Discussion
Discuss derivation of smooth convex isoquant.
3.5 ISOCOST
In economics, an isocost line represents all combinations of inputs which cost the
same total amount. Although, similar to the budget constraint in consumer theory, the use
of the isocost line pertains to cost-minimisation in production, as opposed to utilitymaximisation. For the two production inputs, labour and capital, with fixed unit costs of the
inputs, the equation of the isocost line is
Where w represents the wage rate of labour, r represents the interest rate of capital,
K is the amount or units of capital used, L is the amount of labour used and C is the total cost
Managerial Economics
107
of acquiring these inputs.
The absolute value of the slope of the isocost line, with capital plotted vertically and
labour plotted horizontally, equals the ratio of the prices of inputs of labour and capital. The
isocost line is combined with the isoquant map to determine the optimal production. This
optimality is arrived at a point where an isoquant and the isocost curves are tangent to each
other. It ensures that the firm attains the highest level of possible output with a given
isocost line. Consequently, the output is produced at with least cost or most efficiently. This
tangency can also be interpreted as one where the slopes of the isoquant and the isocost
are equal. This entails that tangency ensures that the marginal productivities of the two
inputs are proportional to the ratios of the prices of the two inputs. Specifically, the point of
tangency between an isoquant and an isocost line gives the lowest-cost combination of
inputs that can produce the level of output associated with that.
•
Least Cost Factor Combination: Producers Equilibrium or Optimal Combination of
Inputs
The analysis of production function has shown that alternative combinations of
factors of production, which are technically efficient, can be used to produce a given level of
output. Of these, the firm will have to choose that combination of factors which will cost it
the least. In this way the firm can maximise its profits. The choice of any particular method
from a set of technically efficient methods is an economic one and it is based on the prices
of factors of production at a particular time.
The firm can maximise its profits either by maximising the level of output for a given
cost or by minimising the cost of producing a given output. In either case, the factors will
have to be employed in optimal combination at which the cost of production will be
minimum.
There are two ways to determine the least cost combination of factors to produce a
given output. That is,
•
Finding the total cost of factor combinations
•
Geometrical method
1. Finding the Total cost of Factor Combinations
Here we try to find the total cost of each factor combination and choose the one
which has the least cost. The cost of each factor combination is found by multiplying the
price of each factor by its quantity and then summing it for all inputs. This is illustrated in
Table 3.4.
108
Managerial Economics
Table 3.4: Choosing the Lowest Cost of Production Technique
Techniqu
Capital
Labour
Capital Cost Labour
Cost Total Cost
e
(units)
(units)
Rs.
Rs.
Rs.
1
2
3
4
5
6
A
6
10
500X6=3000
400X10=4000
7000
B
2
14
500X2=1000
400X14=5600
6600
It is assumed that 100 pairs of shoes are produced per week and the price of capital
and the wage of labour are Rs. 500 and Rs. 400 per week respectively. In order to simplify
the analysis, we assume that there are only two technically efficient methods of producing
shoes and they are labelled A and B.
The table 3.4 demonstrates that the total cost of producing 100 pairs of shoes is Rs.
7000 per week using technique A and Rs. 6600 per week using technique B. The firm will
choose technique B, which is an economically efficient (or lowest cost) production technique
at the factor prices assumed in the above example.
If either of the factor prices alters the equilibrium proportion of the factors will also
change so as to use less of those factors that display a price rise. Therefore, we will have a
new optimal combination of factors. This can again be found out by calculating the cost of
different factor combinations with the new factor prices and choosing the one that costs the
least.
2.
Geometrical method
The second and a more general way to determine the least cost combination of
factors is geometrical in essence. It is done with the help of isoquant map and isocost line. In
order to determine the least cost factor combination or the maximum output for a given
cost, we have to superimpose the isoquant map on the isocost line. This is explained below.
a)
Isoquant Map
An isoquant map shows all the possible combinations of labour and capital that can
produce different levels of output. The isoquant closer to the origin denotes a lower level of
output. The slope of an isoquant is
Managerial Economics
109
The isocost line shows
ws vario
various combinations of labour and capital that the firm could
buy for a given amount of money at
a the given factor prices. This is explained
ed in Fig
Fig. 3.19
Fig. 3.19: Iso-cost Line
In the figure, the line AB is the isocost line. It depicts that the firm ca
can hire OA
amount of capital or OB amount
ount of labour or some combinations of labour
ur and capital
ca
along
the AB line. Thus, isocost line is the
t locus of all those combinations of labour and capital
which, given the prices of labour and
a capital, could be bought for a given amount of money.
The slope of the isocost linee is equal
equ to the ratio of the factor prices, that is, the sslope of isocost line.
Similar iso-cost liness can be drawn for different sums of money. If the m
money to be
spent on the factors increase,
ase, the isocost line will shift to the right and itt denote
denotes that with
the given factor prices, the firm could
co
buy more of the factors. Thus, we can
an have a family of
isocost lines AB, A1B1 and A2B2 as in Fig 3.19. They are all parallel to one another
nother b
because the
factor prices are assumed to be th
the same in all cases. The iso-cost lines closer to the origin
show a lower total cost outlay.
b)
Slope of Isocost Line
Given the monetaryy resources,
resour
if the factor prices change the slope
lope of iisocost line
will change. This is shown in Fig 3.20.
3.
110
Manageri
rial Economics
Fig. 3.20: Slope of Iso-cost Line
Let us assume thatt with a given amount of money and the prices
ices of llabour and
capital, the iso-cost line is AC in Fig 3.20. If the price of labour falls the firm
rm could hire more
than OC amount of labour for the same
s
amount of money. If we assume that the firm could
hire only OC, amount of labour
bour then
the the slope of isocost line changes to AC1. On the other
hand, if the price of labourr rises, the
t firm could hire less than OC amount
nt of lab
labour. If we
assume that the firm could
d hire only
o
OC2 amount of labour then the slope
pe of iso-cost line
changes to AC2.
ine depends
depe
upon 2 factors: (i) prices of factorss of pro
production (ii)
Thus, the iso-cost line
the amount of money which
ch the firm
fi can spend on the factors. A changee in the amount of
money will shift the isocost
st lines as in Fig. 3.20 but the slope of iso-cost
cost lines
line remains
constant. A change in factorr prices, for example labour will change the slope
pe of iso-cost
iso
lines
as in Fig. 3.20.
The producer can bee in equilibrium
equi
either by minimising the cost off produc
producing a given
output or by maximising the
e level of
o output for a given cost. These both cases are explained
below:
•
Optimal Input Combination
bination for Minimising Cost
In this case, the firm has to produce the given output with the minimum
nimum ccost. This is
explained in Fig 3.21.
The single isoquant
ant Q denotes the desired level of outputt to be produced.
There is a family of isocost lines AB
AB, A1B1 and A2B2. The isocost lines are parallel
arallel b
because the
factor prices are assumed to be constant
co
and therefore, all the iso-cost lines
ines have the same
slope.
Managerial Economics
111
Fig. 3.21: Minimising Cost
The firm minimises its cost at the point ‘e’ where the isoquant Q is tangent to the
isocost line AB. The optimal combination of factors is OK and OL. The optimal combination
takes place at the point ‘e’ where the given output can be produced at the least cost. Points
below 'e' are desirable but are not attainable for output Q. Points above 'e' are on higher
iso-cost lines and they show higher costs. Hence, the point 'e' is the least cost point and it is
the lowest cost combination of factors for producing the output Q. It is produced by OK
amount of capital and OL amount of labour. At the point of tangency, that is, at point 'e', the
slope of isocost line is equal to the slope of the isoquant. This is the first condition for the
equilibrium. The second condition is that the isoquant should be convex to the origin at the
point of equilibrium. Thus at the point 'e' the ratio of marginal product of two factors is
equal to the ratio of their factor prices.
•
Optimal Input Combination For Maximisation of Output
The equilibrium conditions of the firm are identical to the above situation that is, the
iso-cost line should be tangent to the highest possible isoquant and the isoquant must be
convex. However, the present problem is conceptually different. In this case the firm has to
maximise its output for a given cost. This is explained in the fig. 3.22:
Fig. 3.22: Maximisation of Output
112
Managerial Economics
The firm’s cost constraint is given by the iso-cost line AB. The maximum level of
output that the firm can produce is Q2 because the point ‘e’ lies on the isoquant Q2. The
point ‘e’ is the equilibrium point because at this point the iso-cost line AB is tangent to the
isoquant Q2. Other points on the isocost line that is S and T, lie on a lower isoquant Q1. Points
to the right of ‘e’ indicate higher levels of output which are desirable, but are not attainable
due to the cost constraint. Hence, Q2 is the maximum output possible for the given cost. The
optimal combination of factors is OK1 and OL1.
The above analysis shows that the optimal combination of inputs needed for a firm
to minimise the cost of producing a given level of output or to maximise the output for a
given cost outlay is given at the tangency point of an isoquant and is cost line.
The above analysis is based on constant factor prices. If the factor prices change, the
firm will choose another factor combination that will minimise the cost of production for the
given output or maximise the level of output for a given cost.
Study Notes
Assessment
1.
What is Iso-cost?
2.
Explain Least Cost Factor Combination.
Discussion
Discuss Geometrical Method in detail.
Managerial Economics
113
3.6 Economies of Scale
3.6.1 CONCEPT OF ECONOMIES OF SCALE
Economies of scale allude to the cost advantages that a business obtains due to
expansion. 'Economies of scale' is a long run concept and refers to reductions in unit cost as
the size of a facility and the usage levels of inputs increases. Diseconomies of scale are the
opposite. The common sources of economies of scale are labour (division of labour)
purchasing (bulk buying of materials through long-term contracts), managerial (increasing
the specialisation of managers), financial (obtaining low interest loans when borrowing from
banks and having access to a greater range of financial instruments), marketing (spreading
the cost of advertising over a greater range of output in media markets) and technological
(taking advantage of returns to scale in the production function). Each of these factors
reduces the long run average costs (LRAC) of production by shifting the short-run average
total cost (SRATC) curve down and to the right. Economies of scale are also derived partially
from learning by doing.
Before explaining economies and diseconomies of scale, let us have a look at laws of
returns to scale, in brief.
3.6.2 LAWS OF RETURNS TO SCALE
Laws of returns to scale refer to the long-run analysis of the laws of production. In
the long run, output can be increased by varying all factors. Thus, in this section we study
the changes in output as a result of changes in all factors. In other words, we study the
behaviour of output in response to changes in the scale. When all factors are increased in
the same proportion an increase in scale occurs.
Scale refers to quantity of all factors which are employed in optimal combinations for
specified outputs. The term ‘returns to scale’ refers to the degree by which output changes
as a result of a given change in the quantity of all inputs used in production. We have three
types of returns to scale: constant, increasing and decreasing. If output increases by the
same proportion as the increase in inputs we have constant returns to scale. If output
increases more than proportionally with the increase in inputs, we have increasing returns
to scale. If output increases less than proportionally with the increase in inputs we have
decreasing returns to scale. Thus, returns to scale may be constant, increasing or decreasing
depending upon whether output increases in the same, greater or lower rate in response to
a proportionate increase in all inputs. Returns to scale can be expressed as a movement
along the scale line or expansion path which we have seen in the previous section. The three
114
Managerial Economics
types of returns to scale aree explained
explain below.
1.
Constant Returns to
o Scale
If output increases in the same
sa
proportion as the increase in inputs,
ts, returns
retur to scale
are said to be constant. Thus,
hus, doubling
dou
of all factor inputs causes doubling
ling of the
t level of
output; trippling of inputs causes trippling
tr
of output and so on. The case of constant
consta returns
to scale is sometimes called
d linear homogenous production function. Thiss is illust
illustrated with
the help of isoquants in Fig. 3.23
3 where the line OE is the scale line. The scale lin
line indicates
the increase in scale. It can be observed
obse
from Fig. 3.23 that the distance between
etween successive
isoquants is equal, that is,
s, Oa = ab = bc. It means that if both labour
ur and capital are
increased in a given proportion
tion the output expands in the same proportion.
Fig 3.2
23: Constant returns to Scale: Oa=ab=bc
2.
Increasing returns to scale
When the output increases
increase at a greater proportion than the increase in inputs,
returns to scale are said to
o be increasing.
inc
It is explained in Fig. 3.24. When
hen the returns to
scale are increasing, the distance
istance between
b
successive isoquants becomes less and less, that
is, Oa >ab >bc. It means that
at equal
equa increases in output are obtained by smaller
maller and
a smaller
increments in inputs. In other
er words,
word by doubling inputs the output is moree than d
doubled.
Fig. 3.2
24: Increasing returns to scale: Oa>ab>bc
Managerial Economics
115
Increasing returns to scale arise on account of indivisibilities off some factors. As
output is increased the indivisibl
isible factors are better utilised and therefore,
erefore, increasing
returns to scale arise. In other
ther words,
wo
the returns to scale are increasing due to economies
of scale.
3.
Decreasing returns to scale
When the output increases
increase in a smaller proportion than the increase
crease in all inputs
returns to scale are said to be decreasing.
decr
It is explained in Fig. 3.24.
Fig. 3.2
25: Decreasing returns to scale: Oa<ab<bc
It can be seen from
m Fig. 3
3.24 that the distance between successive
ssive iso
isoquants are
increasing, that is, Oa < ab < bc. It signifies that equal increments in output
ut are o
obtained by
larger and larger increasess in inpu
inputs. In other words, if the inputs are doubled,
oubled, output will
increase by less than twicee its original
orig
level. The decreasing returns to scale
cale are caused by
diseconomies of large scale
e production.
produc
The returns to scalee can be measured in terms of the coefficient of outpu
output elasticity
(QE).
If QE = 1, we have constant returns to scale, if QE > 1, we have increasing
creasing returns to
scale and if QE < 1, we havee decreasing
decrea
returns to scale.
According to economic
omic theory,
the
as the size of a firm increases, the firm will face
successively increasing returns,
urns, followed
fol
by constant returns and then decreasing
creasing returns to
scale. This is due to indivisibility
ibility of some factors. An input is said to be indivisible
ivisible when it is
available in a ‘lumpy’ form, which cannot be divided into smaller units. Therefore
herefore, as output
is increased indivisible factors
ctors ar
are better utilised and therefore, increasing
easing rreturns are
obtained. If the inputs are perfectly divisible we cannot have varying returns
rns to sc
scale, that is,
116
Manageri
rial Economics
returns to scale will be constant always. Thus, the existence of varying returns to scale is
owing to the fact that inputs are not perfectly divisible. According to Chamberlin, the
indivisibility thesis does not afford a complete explanation for the existence of increasing
returns to scale. Even if all inputs are perfectly divisible the efficiency of the firm still
depends upon its size. According to him, the existence of larger quantity of inputs allows for
improved division of labour which, in turn, results in increasing returns to scale. Thus, as the
size of the firm expands it is possible to employ superior and more efficient inputs which
cause increasing returns to scale. On the other hand, decreasing returns to scale arise on
account of the increasing difficulties involved in coordinating the multiplicity of complex
activities of the firm. As the size of the firm increases the multiple activities of the firm
become more and more complex.
The increasing and decreasing returns to scale describe the behaviour of long run
average cost. The long-run average costs decrease as output rises due to increasing returns
to scale (or economies of scale). The economies of scale refer to the situation in which
output grows proportionately faster than inputs. For example, output more than doubles
with a doubling of inputs. If the input prices remain constant, this leads to lower cost per
unit. On the other hand, the long run average costs increase as output rises due to
decreasing returns to scale, (or diseconomies of scale). In this case, output grows at a
proportionately lower rate than the inputs. With the prices of inputs remaining constant,
this leads to higher costs per unit. This leads to rising LAC (Long-run Average Cost) curve. The
LAC becomes lowest at the output at which the forces for increasing returns to scale are just
balanced by the forces for decreasing returns to scale.
3.6.3 ECONOMIES AND DISECONOMIES OF SCALE
Economies and diseconomies of scale are of two types- internal and external.
Internal economies and diseconomies are those which a firm reaps as a result of its own
expansion. On the other hand, external economies and diseconomies are those which a firm
accrues as a result of the growth of industry as a whole. They are external because they
accrue to the firms from outside.
The internal economies and diseconomies of scale affect the shape of the long run
average cost curve. Internal economies of scale cause the long run average cost to fall, while
internal diseconomies of scale causes the long run average cost to rise as output increases.
On the other hand, external economies and diseconomies of scale affect the position of both
the short run and long run average cost curves. External economies shift down the cost
curve, while external diseconomies shift up the cost curve.
Managerial Economics
117
1. Internal Economies of Scale
Internal economies of scale are the advantages of large scale production. They are
enjoyed by the firm when it increases its scale of production. They accrue to the firm from
their own actions. They affect the shape of the long-run average cost curve. They are
responsible for increasing returns to scale. According to many economists, internal
economies arise due to indivisibility of some factors. As the output increases the large
indivisible factors can be used more efficiently and, therefore, the firm experiences
increasing returns to scale. The internal economies of scale are classified into two, as shown
in the chart below:
Fig. 3.26: Chart representing Internal Economics of Scale
A) REAL ECONOMIES OF SCALE
Real economies are delineated as those which are associated with a reduction in the
physical quantity of inputs such as raw materials, varying types of labour and various types
of capital. They are mostly associated with indivisibilities or lumpiness of units of factors of
production. The important kinds of real economies are:
1.
Production economies
2.
Marketing economies
3.
Managerial economies
4.
Transport and storage economies
1. Production Economies: Production economies arise from the use of factors of
production in the form of (i) labour economies (ii) technical economies and (iii) inventory
economies
118
Managerial Economics
•
Labour Economies: As the size of output increases the firm enjoys labour economies
due to (a) specialisation, (b) time-saving, (c) automation of the production process
and (d) ‘cumulative volume' economies. As the size of production increases the firm
merits from the advantages of division of labour and specialisation of labour which
enhance the productivity of the various types of labour. The advantages of division of
labour is emphasised by Adam Smith in his book, The Wealth of Nations published in
1776. Division of labour also condenses the time lost in changing from one type of
work to another. Division of labour promotes invention of tools and machines which,
in turn, leads to mechanisation of the production process. This assists the labour in
working faster and therefore, increases the labour productivity. Further, large scale
production helps the technical personnel to acquire considerable experience from
the ‘cumulative effect’. This ‘cumulative volume’ experience leads to higher
productivity. Hence, as the size of output increases the unit cost falls.
•
Technical Economies: The important technical economies result from the use of
specialised capital equipment, which comes into effect only when the output is
produced on a large scale. Technical economies also arise from the indivisibilities,
which are the characteristics of the modern techniques of production. In other
words, as the scale of production increases the firm reaps the advantages of
mechanisation of using mass production methods. This will reduce the unit cost of
production.
•
Inventory Economies: The role of inventories is to aid the firm in meeting random
changes in the input and the output sides of the operations of the firm. The purpose
of inventories is to smooth out the supply of inputs and the supply of outputs.
Inventories on spare parts, raw materials and finished products increase with the
scale of production, but they do not increase proportionately with the increase in the
size of output. Therefore, as the size of output amplifies the firm can hold smaller
percentage of inventories to meet random changes.
2. Marketing Economies: They are allied with the selling of the product of the firm. They
arise from advertising economies. Since, advertising expenses increase less than
proportionately with the increase in output, the advertising costs per unit of output falls
as the output increases. Similarly, other sales promotion expenditures like samples,
salesmen force etc. also increase less than proportionately with the output. Further, a
large firm can have special arrangements with exclusive dealers to maintain a good
service department for the product of the firm. Hence, the average selling costs fall with
the increase in the size of the firm.
Managerial Economics
119
3. Managerial Economies: Large scale production makes possible the division of
managerial functions. Thus, there exists a production manager, a sales manager, a
finance manager, a personnel manager and so on in a large firm. However, all or most of
the managerial decisions are taken by a single manager in a small firm. This division of
managerial functions increases their efficiency. The decentralisation of managerial
decision making also increases the efficiency of management. Large firms are also in a
position to introduce mechanisation of managerial functions through the use of telex
machines, computers and so on. Hence, as output increases the managerial costs per
unit of output continue to decline.
4. Transport and Storage Economies: As the output increases, the unit cost of
transportation of raw materials, intermediate products and finished products fall. This is
because a large firm may be able to reduce transport costs by having their own
transportation means or by using larger vehicles. Similarly, as the size of the firm
increases the storage costs will also fall.
B) PECUNIARY ECONOMIES
Pecuniary economies (i.e. monetary economies) are those economies accrued by the
firm from paying lower prices for the factors used in production and distribution of the
product due to bulk buying by the firm. They add to the firm on account of discounts it can
obtain due to its large scale production. They reduce the money costs of the factors for a
particular firm.
The pecuniary economies are realised by a firm in the following ways:
•
The firm will be able to get raw materials at lower prices due to bulk buying.
•
A large firm can get funds at lower cost, that is, at a lower rate of interest due to its
reputation in the money market.
•
The large firm may be given lower advertising rates if they advertise at large.
•
Transport rates may be also low if the amount of commodities transported is large.
2. Internal Diseconomies of Scale
Internal economies of scale exist only up to a certain size of the plant. This size of
plant is known as the optimum plant size because with this size of plant all possible
economies of scale will be fully exploited. If the size of the plant increases beyond this
optimum size there arise diseconomies of scale (i.e. decreasing returns to scale) especially
from managerial diseconomies. It is argued that technical diseconomies can be avoided by
duplicating the optimum technical size of the plant.
120
Managerial Economics
The most important cause for diseconomies of scale is the diminishing returns to
management. As the output grows beyond certain level the top management becomes
overburdened, it becomes less efficient as coordinator and ultimate decision maker. Thus,
increase in the size of the plant beyond a certain large size makes the managerial structure
more complicated and reduces the overall efficiency of the management.
Another cause for diseconomies of scale may be the exhaustible natural resources.
E.g., increasing the fishing fleet may not cause an increase in catching of the fish.
3. External Economies
The external economies arise outside the firm as a result of improvement in the
industrial environment in which the firm operates. They are external to the firm, but internal
to the industry to which the firms belong. They may be realised from the actions of other
firms in the same industry or in another industry. Their effect is to cause a change in the
prices of factors employed by the firm. They cause a shift in the short-run and long-run cost
curves of the firm.
The important external economies are the following:
•
Cheapening of Materials and Equipments: Expansion of an industry increases the
demand for various kinds of materials and capital equipments. This will lead to large
scale production of materials and equipments. Large scale production will reduce their
cost of production and therefore, their prices. Hence, the firms using them will get them
at lower prices.
•
Growth of Technical Know-how: Expansion of an industry may lead to the discovery of
new technical know-how. As a result of this the firms may be able to use improved and
better machinery which will increase the productivity of the firms and therefore, reduce
the cost of production.
•
Development of Skilled Labour: As the industry grows the training facilities for labour
will increase. This helps the development of skilled labour, which will increase the
productivity of workers in the firms.
•
Growth of Subsidiary and Ancillary Industries: Expansion of an industry may facilitate
the growth of subsidiary and ancillary industries to produce tools, equipments, machines
etc. and to provide them to the main industry at the lower prices. Likewise, firms may
also come up to transform the waste of the industry into some useful products. This
tends to reduce the cost of production.
Managerial Economics
121
•
Development of Transportation and Marketing Facilitates: The expansion of an industry
may expedite the development of transportation and marketing facilities which will
reduce the cost of transportation.
•
Development of Information Services: External economies also arise from the
interchange of technical information between firms. With the expansion of an industry
the firms may give the information about the technical knowledge through the
publication of trade and technical journals. The firms may also set up jointly research
institutes to develop new improved techniques.
4. External Diseconomies
The expansion of an industry is likely to generate external diseconomies which raise
the cost of production. An increase in the size of industry may raise the prices of some
factors like raw materials and capital goods which are in short supply. Expansion of an
industry may also elevate the wages of skilled labour, which are in short supply. It may also
create transport bottlenecks. As the size of an industry expands lakes, rivers and seas may
be polluted by firms. This will create external diseconomies to some other firms or
industries, for example, the fishing industry. Pollution of this sort will also create health
hazards to the people in the adjoining areas. Expansion of an industry may also pollute the
air from the smoke of factories or fumes of vehicles. This too will have similar diseconomies.
Thus, several external diseconomies may be generated by the expansion of the size
of an industry (or industries) and they will raise the costs of the individual firms.
Study Notes
122
Managerial Economics
Assessment
Write notes on the following:
1. Concept of Economies of Scale
2. Internal Economies of Scale
3. Internal Diseconomies of Scale
4. External Economies of Scale
5.
External Diseconomies of Scale
Discussion
Discuss Laws of Returns to scale in detail.
3.7 Summary
Production Function: A production function specifies the output of a firm, an
industry or an entire economy for all possible combinations of inputs. This function is an
assumed technological relationship, based on the current state of engineering knowledge
and technical feasibility of substituting inputs.
TYPES OF PRODUCTION FUNCTION
Production function is of two different forms:
•
The fixed proportion production function
•
The variable proportion production function
These can be explained as follows:
1. Fixed Proportion Production Function
A fixed proportion production function is one in which the technology requires a
fixed combination of inputs, say capital and labour, to produce a given level of output. There
is only one way in which the factors may be combined to produce a given level of output
efficiently. In this type of production, there is no possibility of substitution between the
Managerial Economics
123
factors of production.
The fixed proportion production function is characterised by constant returns to
scale, that is, a proportionate increase in inputs leads to a proportionate increase in outputs.
This type of production function provides the basis for the input - output analysis in
economics. Thus, this type of isoquant is also called input-output isoquant or “leontiff”
isoquant after Leontiff who invented the input-output analysis.
2. Variable Proportions Production Function
The variable proportion production function is the most familiar production function.
In this case, a given level of output can be produced by several alternative combinations of
factors of production, say capital and labour. It is assumed that the factors can be combined
in infinite number of ways.
Cost Function: The term cost function is a financial term used by economists and
mangers within businesses to understand how costs behave. The cost function shows how a
cost changes as the levels of an activity relating to that cost changes.
Cost function is a derived function. It is derived from the production function, which
describes the efficient method of production at any one time. In other words, the
production function specifies the technical relationships between inputs and the level of
output. Thus, cost will vary with the changes in the level of output, nature of production
function, or factor prices. Thus, symbolically, we may write the cost function as
C = ƒ(X, T, Pf)
Where, C = Total cost, X = Output, T = Technology, Pf = Prices of factors.
Isoquants: An isoquant is the locus of points showing how a given output can be
produced with different combinations of inputs. An isoquant shows the extent to which the
firm in question has the ability to substitute between the two different inputs in order to
produce the same level of output.
Types of Isoquants
1. Linear isoquant
2. Right angled isoquant
3. Kinked isoquant
4. Smooth convex isoquant
124
Managerial Economics
Isocost: An isocost line shows all possible combinations of inputs which cost the
same total amount. Although similar to the budget constraint in consumer theory, the use of
the isocost line pertains to cost-minimisation in production, as opposed to utilitymaximisation.
Economics of Scale: Economies of scale, refers to the cost advantages that a business
obtains due to expansion. There are factors that cause a producer’s average cost per unit to
fall as the scale of output is increased. "Economies of scale" is a long run concept and refers
to reductions in unit cost as the size of a facility and the usage levels of other inputs
increase.
3.8 Self Assessment Test
Broad Questions
1. What is production function? Discuss the fixed proportions and variable proportions
production functions.
2. Explain the concept of isoquant. What are the properties of isoquants?
3. The firm can maximise its profits by choosing the least cost combination of factors.
Discuss.
4. The firm can maximise its profits by employing the factors in optimal combinations at
which the cost of production will be minimum. Explain.
5. Discuss diagrammatically the laws of returns to scale.
Short Notes
a. Production function
b. Isoquant
c. Isocost line
d. Expansion path
e. Economies of scope
f. Internal economies of scale
Managerial Economics
125
3.9 Further Reading
1. Business Economics, Adhikary, M,., Excel Books, New Delhi, 2000
2. Economics Theory and Operations Analysis, Baumol, W J., 3rd ed., Prentice Hall Inc, 1996
3. Managerial Economics, Chopra, O P., Tata McGraw Hill, New Delhi, 1985
4. Managerial Economics, Keat, Paul G and Philips K Y Young, Prentice Hall, New Jersey,
1996
5. A Modern Micro Economics, Koutsoyiannis, Macmillan, 1991
6. Economics Organisation and Management, Milgrom, P and Roberts J, Prentice Hall
Inc,Englewood Clitts, New Jersey, 1992
7. Managerial Economics, Maheshwari, Yogesh, Sultanchand and Sons, 2009
8. Managerial Economics, Varshney, R L., Sultanchand and Sons, 2007
126
Managerial Economics
Assignment
Quote examples, how can production and cost functions be used in daily life?
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
Managerial Economics
127
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
Managerial Economics
128
Unit 4
Theory of Firm
Learning Outcome
After going through this unit, you will be able to:
•
Discuss various theories of firm
•
Describe transaction cost theory
•
Outline Managerial and Behavioural Theories
•
Describe Williamson's approach
•
Distinguish Profit and Sales Maximisation
•
Define Team Production
Time Required to Complete the unit
1.
1st Reading: It will need 3 Hrs for reading a unit
2.
2nd Reading with understanding: It will need 4 Hrs for reading and understanding a
unit
3.
Self Assessment: It will need 3 Hrs for reading and understanding a unit
4.
Assignment: It will need 2 Hrs for completing an assignment
5.
Revision and Further Reading: It is a continuous process
Content Map
4.1
Introduction
4.2
Theory of Firm
4.3
Various Theories of Firm
4.3.1
Transaction Cost Theory
Managerial Economics
129
4.3.2
Managerial and Behavioural Theories
4.3.3
Profit Maximisation
4.3.4
Sales Maximisation
4.3.5
Team Production
4.3.6
Williamson's Approach
4.3.7
Simon Satisfying Behaviour Model
4.3.8
Other Models
4.4
Summary
4.5
Self Assessment Test
4.6
Further Reading
130
Managerial Economics
4.1 Introduction
Microeconomics, especially the theory of the firm, assumed importance and
attracted considerable attention in the early twentieth century. This shift ensued after the
growing realisation that perfect competition assumption of the classical economists was not
a ground reality. This realisation resulted in a spate of efforts to analyse and understand the
behaviour of individual firms. In perfect competition, all firms are assumed to be price takers
and therefore studies into the behaviour of individual firms were not called for. Since, the
reality was far different, the urgency to study the behaviour of firms of all sizes was obvious.
Naturally theory of the firm, rather how firms, big and small, behave under different
circumstances began to attract wide attention, especially in the aftermath of World War I.
The need for a revised theory of the firm was emphasised by empirical studies
undertaken by Berle and Means, which made it clear that ownership of a typical American
corporation is spread over a wide number of shareholders, leaving control in the hands of
managers who own very little equity themselves. Hall and Hitch found that executives made
decisions by rule of thumb rather than in accordance to marginal analyses. Firms exist as an
alternative system to the market mechanism when it is more efficient to produce in a nonprice environment. For example, in a labour market, it might be very difficult or costly for
firms or organisation to engage in production when they have to hire and fire their workers
depending on demand/supply conditions. It might also be costly for employees to shift
companies everyday looking for better alternatives. Thus, firms engage in a long-term
contract with their employees to minimise the cost.
Klein (1983) asserts that “Economists now recognise that such a sharp distinction
[between intra- and inter-firm transactions] does not exist and that it is useful to consider
also transactions occurring within the firm as representing market (contractual)
relationships”. The costs involved in such transactions that are within a firm or even
between the firms are transaction costs.
According to Putterman, this is an exaggeration—most economists accept a
distinction between the two forms, but also that the two merge into each other; the extent
of a firm is not simply defined by its capital stock. Richardson for example, notes that a rigid
distinction fails because of the existence of intermediate forms between firm and market
such as inter-firm co-operation.
Ultimately, whether the firm constitutes a domain of bureaucratic direction that is
shielded from market forces or simply “a legal fiction”, “a nexus for a set of contracting
relationships among individuals” (Jensen and Meckling) is “a function of the completeness of
Managerial Economics
131
markets and the ability of market forces to penetrate intra-firm relationships”.
4.2 Theory of Firm
Theory of the firm is related to comprehending how firms come into being, what are
their objectives, how they behave and improve their performance and how they establish
their credentials and standing in society or an economy and so on. The theory of the firm
aims at answering the following questions:
•
Existence – why do firms emerge and exist, why are not all transactions in the economy
mediated over the market?
•
Which of their transactions are performed internally and which are negotiated in the
market?
•
Organisation – why are firms structured in such a specific way? What is the interplay of
formal and informal relationships?
•
Heterogeneity of firm actions/performances – what drives different actions and
performances of firms?
Study Notes
Assessment
Write a note on the history of Theory of Firms.
Discussion
Discuss the aims of theory of Firm.
132
Managerial Economics
4.3 Various theories of Firm
4.3.1 TRANSACTION COST THEORY
Fig. 4.1: Transaction Cost Theory
The above model reveals institutions and market as a possible form of organisation
to coordinate economic transactions. When the external transaction costs are higher than
the internal transaction costs, the company will grow. If the external transaction costs are
lower than the internal transaction costs the company will be downsized by outsourcing. For
example, Ronald Coase set out his transaction cost theory of the firm in 1937, making it one
of the first (neo-classical) attempts to define the firm theoretically in relation to the market.
Coase sets out to define a firm in a manner which is both realistic and compatible with the
idea of substitution at the margin, so instruments of conventional economic analysis apply.
He notes that a firm’s interactions with the market may not be under its control (for
instance because of sales taxes), but its internal allocation of resources is: “Within a firm,
market transactions are eliminated and in place of the complicated market structure with
exchange transactions is substituted the entrepreneur who directs production”. He asks why
alternative methods of production (such as the price mechanism and economic planning),
could not either achieve all production, so that either firms use internal prices for all their
production, or one big firm runs the entire economy.
Coase begins from the standpoint that markets could in theory carry out all
production and that what needs to be explained is the existence of the firm, with its
"distinguishing mark … [of] the supersession of the price mechanism". Coase identifies some
Managerial Economics
133
reasons why firms might arise and dismisses each as unimportant:
•
If some people prefer to work under direction and are prepared to pay for the privilege
(but this is unlikely)
•
If some people prefer to direct others and are prepared to pay for this (but generally
people are paid more to direct others)
•
If purchasers prefer goods produced by firms
Coase contends that the central reason to establish a firm is to evade some
transaction costs of using the price mechanism. These include discovering relevant prices
(which can be reduced but not eliminated by purchasing this information through
specialists), as well as the costs of negotiating and writing enforceable contracts for each
transaction (which can be large if there is uncertainty). Moreover, contracts in an uncertain
world will necessarily be incomplete and have to be frequently re-negotiated. The costs of
haggling about division of surplus, particularly if there is asymmetric information and asset
specificity, may be considerable.
If a firm operated internally under the market system, many contracts would be
required (for instance, even for procuring a pen or delivering a presentation). In contrast, a
real firm has very few (though much more complex) contracts, such as defining a manager's
power of direction over employees, in exchange for which the employee is paid. These kinds
of contracts are drawn up in situations of uncertainty, in particular for relationships which
last long periods. Such a situation runs counter to neo-classical economic theory. The neoclassical market is instantaneous, forbidding the development of extended agent-principal
(employee-manager) relationships, of planning and of trust. Coase concludes that “a firm is
likely therefore to emerge in those cases where a very short-term contract would be
unsatisfactory”. and that “it seems improbable that a firm would emerge without the
existence of uncertainty”.
He notes that government measures relating to the market (sales taxes, rationing,
price controls) tend to increase the size of firms, since firms internally would not be subject
to such transaction costs. Thus, Coase defines the firm as "the system of relationships which
comes into existence when the direction of resources is dependent on the entrepreneur".
We can therefore think of a firm as getting larger or smaller based on whether the
entrepreneur organises more or fewer transactions.
However, what determines the size of the firm; why does the entrepreneur organise
the transactions he does, why no more or less? Since, the reason for the firm's being is to
have lower costs than the market, the upper limit on the firm's size is shaped by costs
Managerial Economics
134
mounting to the point where internalising an additional transaction equals the cost of
making that transaction in the market. (At the lower limit, the firm’s costs exceed the
market’s costs and it does not come into existence.) In practice, diminishing returns to
management, augments cost of organising a large firm, particularly in large firms with many
different plants and differing internal transactions (such as a conglomerate) or if the relevant
prices change recurrently.
Coase concludes that the size of the firm is reliant on the costs of using the price
mechanism and on the costs of organisation of other entrepreneurs. These two factors
collectively determine how many products a firm produces and how much of each product
they produce.
4.3.2 MANAGERIAL AND BEHAVIOURAL THEORIES
It was only in the 1960s that the neo-classical theory of the firm was disputed by
alternatives such as managerial and behavioural theories. Managerial theories of the firm, as
developed by William Baumol (1959 and 1962), Robin Marris (1964) and Oliver E. Williamson
(1966), suggest that managers would seek to maximise their own utility and consider the
implications of this for firm behaviour in contrast to the profit-maximising case. Baumol
suggested that managers’ interests are best served by maximising sales after achieving a
minimum level of profit which satisfies shareholders. More recently this has developed into
‘principal-agent’ analysis (e.g. Spence and Zeckhauser and Ross (1973) on problems of
contracting with asymmetric information) which models a widely applicable case where a
principal (a shareholder or firm for example) cannot infer how an agent (a manager or
supplier, say) is behaving. This may arise either because the agent has greater expertise or
knowledge than the principal or because the principal cannot directly observe the agent’s
actions; it is asymmetric information which transforms into a problem of moral hazard. This
means that to an extent, managers can pursue their own interests. Traditional managerial
models typically assume that managers, instead of maximising profit, maximise a simple
objective utility function (this may include salary, perks, security, power, prestige) subject to
an arbitrarily given profit constraint (profit satisfying).
4.3.3 PROFIT MAXIMISATION
The profit maximisation theory states that firms (companies or corporations) will
establish factories where they see the potential to achieve the highest total profit. The
company will select a location based upon comparative advantage (where the product can
be produced the cheapest). The theory draws from the characteristics of the location site:
land price, labour costs, transportation costs and access, environmental restrictions, worker
Managerial Economics
135
unions, population etc. The company will then elect the best location for the factory to
maximise profits. This is anathema to the idea of social responsibility because firms will
place their factory to achieve profit maximisation. They are nonchalant to environment
conservation, fair wage policies and exploit the country. The only objective is to earn more
profits. In economics, profit maximisation is the process by which a firm determines the
price and output level that returns the greatest profit. There are several approaches to this
problem. The total revenue–total cost method relies on the fact that profit equals revenue
minus cost. Equating marginal revenue and marginal cost is a better and convenient method
for arriving at profit maximising output. It allows firms to check whether they are really
maximising profits at a given level of output by comparing additional costs and revenues
generated by the production of an additional unit of output. If this cost of producing an
additional unit is less than the addition it makes to total revenue, the firm must expand as it
would increase total profit. This expansion must continue till MR and MC are equal. Profits
are maximised when this equality is achieved provided the marginal cost at this level of
output envelops the average cost of the firm. In case MC turns out to be higher than the
marginal revenue at the point of investigation, the firm must contract by reducing its output
to a level where MC equals MR. This method is particularly useful to very large
organisations, with multiple divisions and where computation of total revenue and total cost
may be a difficult and complex task.
a)
Total cost-total revenue method
Fig. 4.2: Profit Maximisation - The Totals Approach
To obtain the profit maximising output quantity, we start by recognising that profit is
equal to total revenue (TR) minus total cost (TC). Given a table of costs and revenues at each
quantity, we can either compute equations or plot the data directly on a graph. Finding the
profit-maximising output is as simple as finding the output at which profit reaches its
136
Managerial Economics
maximum. That is represented
ted by o
output Q in the diagram.
There are two graphical
hical ways
wa of determining that Q is optimal. Firstly, we
w see that
the profit curve is at its maximum
aximum at this point (A). Secondly, we see that
at at th
the point (B)
that the tangent on the total
tal cost curve (TC) is parallel to the total revenue
nue curve
curv (TR), the
surplus of revenue net of costs
osts (B, C) is the greatest. Because total revenuee minus total costs
is equal to profit, the line segment
egment C, B is equal in length to the line segment A,, Q
Q.
Computing the price, at which
whi the product should be sold, requiress knowle
knowledge of the
firm's demand curve. Optimum
imum price
p
to sell the product is the price at which
whic quantity
demanded equals profit-maximissing output.
b)
Marginal cost-marginal
inal revenue
reve
method
Fig. 4.3: Profit
Prof Maximisation - The Marginal Approach
An alternative argument
ment says
sa that for each unit sold, marginal profit (M
(Mπ) equals
marginal revenue (MR) minus
nus marginal
marg
cost (MC). Then, if marginal revenue
nue is gr
greater than
marginal cost, marginal profit
ofit is positive,
po
and if marginal revenue is less than ma
marginal cost,
marginal profit is negative.. When marginal
m
revenue equals marginal cost,
t, marginal
margin profit is
zero. Since total profit increases
reases when
w
marginal profit is positive and total
al profit decreases
when marginal profit is negative,
gative, it must reach a maximum where marginal
al profit is zero - or
where marginal cost equals
ls margi
marginal revenue. If there are two points where this
t
occurs,
maximum profit is achieved
d where the producer was collected positive profit u
up until the
intersection of MR and MC (where zero profit is collected), but would nott continu
continue to after,
as opposed to vice versa, which
hich represents
re
a profit minimum. In calculus terms, tthe correct
intersection of MC and MR will occur
occu when:
Managerial Economics
137
The intersection of MR and MC is shown in the next diagram as point A. If the
industry is perfectly competitive (as is assumed in the diagram), the firm faces a demand
curve (D) that is identical to its Marginal revenue curve (MR), and this is a horizontal line at a
price determined by industry supply and demand. Average total costs are represented by
curve ATC. Total economic profit are represented by area P,A,B,C. The optimum quantity (Q)
is the same as the optimum quantity (Q) in the first diagram.
If the firm is operating in a non-competitive market, minor changes would have to be
made to the diagrams. For example, the Marginal Revenue would have a negative gradient,
due to the overall market demand curve. In a non-competitive environment, more
complicated profit maximization solutions involve the use of game theory.
c)
Maximising revenue method
In some cases, a firm's demand and cost conditions are such that marginal profits are
greater than zero for all levels of production. In this case, the Mπ = 0 rule has to be modified
and the firm should maximise revenue. In other words, the profit maximising quantity and
price can be determined by setting marginal revenue equal to zero. Marginal revenue equals
zero when the marginal revenue curve has reached its maximum value. An example would
be a scheduled airline flight. The marginal costs of flying the route are negligible. The airline
would maximise profits by filling all the seats. The airline would determine the p-max
conditions by maximising revenues.
Numerical Example
A promoter decides to rent an arena for concert. The arena seats 20,000. The rental
fee is 10,000. (This is a fixed cost.) The arena owner gets concessions and parking and pays
all other expenses related to the concert. The promoter has properly estimated the demand
for concert seats to be Q = 40,000 - 2000P, where Q is the quantity of seats and P is the price
per seat. What is the profit maximising ticket price?
As the promoter’s marginal costs are zero, the promoter maximises profits by
charging a ticket price that will maximise revenue. Total revenue equals price, P, times
quantity. Total revenue is expressed as a function of quantity, so we need to work with the
inverse demand curve:
P (Q) = 20 − Q / 2000
This gives total revenue as a function of quantity, TR (Q) = P (Q) x Q, or
TR (Q) = 20Q − Q2 / 2000
Total revenue reaches its maximum value when marginal revenue is zero. Marginal
138
Managerial Economics
revenue is the first derivative of the total revenue function: MR (Q)=TR'(Q). So
MR (Q) = 20 − Q / 1000
Setting MR (Q) = 0 we get
0 = 20 − Q / 1000
Q = 20,000
Recall that price is a function of quantity sold (the inverse demand curve. So to sell
this quantity, the ticket price must be
P (20000) = 20 − 20,000 / 2,000 = 10
It may seem more natural to view the decision as price setting rather than quantity
setting. Generally, this is not a more natural mathematical formulation of profit
maximisation because costs are usually a function of quantity (not of price). In this particular
example, however, the promoter’s marginal costs are zero. This means the promoter
maximises profits simply by charging a ticket price that will maximise revenue. In this
particular case, we characterise total revenue as a function of price:
TR2 (P) = (40,000 − 2000P)P = 40,000P − 2000 (P) 2
Total revenue reaches its maximum value when marginal revenue is zero. Marginal
revenue is the first derivative of the total revenue function. So
MR2 (P) = 40,000 − 4000P
Setting MR2 = 0 we get,
0 = 40,000 − 4000P
P = 10
Profit = TR2 (P) -TC
Profit = [40,000P - 2000(P) 2] - 10,000
Profit = [40,000(10) - 2000(10)2] - 10,000
Profit = 400,000 - 200,000 - 10,000
Profit = 190,000
What, if the promoter had charged 12 per ticket?
Q = 40,000 - 2000P.
Q = 40,000 - 2000(12)
Managerial Economics
139
Q = 40,000 - 24,000 = 16,000 (tickets sold)
Profits at 12:
Q = 16,000(12) = 192,000 - 10,000 = 182,000
d)
Changes in fixed costs and profit maximisation
A firm maximises profit by operating where marginal revenue equals marginal costs.
A change in fixed costs has no effect on the profit maximising output or price. The firm
merely treats short term fixed costs as sunk costs and continues to operate as before. This
can be confirmed graphically. Using the diagram, illustrating the total cost total revenue
method, the firm maximises profits at the point where the slope of the total cost line and
total revenue line are equal. A change in total cost would cause the total cost curve to shift
up by the amount of the change. There would be no effect on the total revenue curve or the
shape of the total cost curve. Consequently, the profit maximising point would remain the
same. This point can also be illustrated using the diagram for the marginal revenue marginal
cost method. A change in fixed cost would have no effect on the position or shape of these
curves.
•
What if the arena owner in the example above triples the fee for the next concert but all
other factors are the same. What price should the promoter now charge for tickets in
light of the fee increase?
The same price of Rs. 10
The fee is a fixed cost, which the promoter should consider a sunk cost and simply
ignore it in calculating his profit maximising price. The only effect is that the promoter’s
profit will be reduced by Rs. 20, 000.
e)
Markup pricing
In addition to using the above methods to determine a firm’s optimal level of output,
a firm can also set price to maximise profit. The optimal markup rules are:
(P - MC)/P = 1/ -Ep
Or
P = (Ep/(1 + Ep)) MC
Where MC equals marginal costs and Ep equals price elasticity of demand. Ep is a
negative number. Therefore, -Ep is a positive number.
The rule here is that the size of the markup is inversely related to the price elasticity
of demand for a good.
140
Managerial Economics
f)
MPL, MRPL and profit maximisation
The general rule is that firm maximises profit by producing that quantity of output
where marginal revenue equals marginal costs. The profit maximisation issue can also be
approached from the input side. That is, what is the profit maximising usage of the variable
input? To maximise profits, the firm should increase usage "up to the point where the
input’s marginal revenue product equals its marginal costs". So mathematically the profit
maximising rule is MRPL = MCL. The marginal revenue product is the change in total revenue
per unit change in the variable input- assuming input as labour. That is, MRPL = ∆TR/∆L.
MRPL is the product of marginal revenue and the marginal product of labour or MRPL = MR x
MPL.
•
Derivation:
MR = ∆TR/∆Q
MPL = ∆Q/∆L
MRPL = MR x MPL = (∆TR/∆Q) x (∆Q/∆L) = ∆TR/∆L
4.3.4 SALES MAXIMISATION
The notion that business firms (especially those operating in the real world) are
primarily goaded by the aspiration to achieve the greatest possible level of sales, rather than
profit maximisation needs due consideration. On an everyday basis, most real world firms
probably do try to maximise sales rather than profit. For firms operating in relatively
competitive markets, facing relatively fixed prices and relatively constant average cost, then
increasing sales is bound to increase profits as well.
Sales maximisation theory is an alternative theory to profit maximisation. W.J.
Baumol (Economic Theory and Operations Analysis, 1965) is generally recognised as having
first suggested that firms often seek to maximise the money value of their sales, i.e. their
sales revenue, subject to a constraint that their profits do not fall short of some minimum
level which is just on the borderline of acceptability. In other words, so long as profits are at
a satisfactory level, management will devote its energy and efforts to the expansion of sales.
Such a goal may be explained perhaps by the businessman's desire to maintain his
competitive position, which is partly reliant on the sheer size of his enterprise. This goal may
also rise out of management's vested interest since the management's salaries may be
related more closely to the size of the firm's operation than to its profits, or it may simply be
a matter of prestige. It is also Baumol's view that short-run revenue maximisation may be
consistent with long-run profit maximisation and revenue maximisation can be regarded as a
Managerial Economics
141
long-run goal in many oligopolistic firms. Baumol also reasons that high sales attract
customers to popular products.
4.3.5 TEAM PRODUCTION
Armen Alchian and Harold Demsetz's analysis of team production is an amplification
and clarification of earlier work by Coase. According to them, the firm develops because
extra output is provided by team production. However, its success is conditioned according
to the propensity to manage the team. This takes in to account metering problems (it is
costly to measure the marginal outputs of the cooperating inputs for reward purposes) and
attendant shirking (the moral hazard problem), which can be overcome by estimating
marginal productivity by observing specifying input behaviour. Therefore such monitoring is
essential. However, this kind of monitoring can only be encouraged effectively if the monitor
is the recipient of the activity’s residual income (otherwise the monitor would have to be
monitored, ad infinitum). Thus, for Alchian and Demsetz, the firm, is an entity which brings
together a team which is more productive working together than at arm’s length through
the market, because of informational problems associated with monitoring of effort. In
effect, therefore, this is a ‘principal-agent’ theory. Since it is asymmetric information within
the firm, which Alchian and Demsetz emphasise, it must be overcome. In Barzel’s (1982)
theory of the firm, drawing on Jensen and Meckling (1976), the firm emerges as a means of
centralising monitoring and thereby avoiding costly redundancy in that function.
The weakness in Alchian and Demsetz’s argument, according to Williamson, is that
their concept of team production has quite a narrow range of application, as it assumes
outputs cannot be related to individual inputs. In practice, this may have limited applicability
(small work group activities, the largest perhaps a symphony orchestra), since most outputs
within a firm (such as manufacturing and secretarial work) are separable, so that individual
inputs can be rewarded on the basis of outputs. Hence, team production cannot offer the
explanation of why firms (in particular, large multi-plant and multi-product firms) exist.
4.3.6 WILLIAMSON'S APPROACH
For Oliver E. Williamson, the existence of firms derives from ‘asset specificity’ in
production, where assets are specific to each other such that their value is much less in a
second-best use. This leads to problems if the assets are owned by different firms (such as
purchaser and supplier). The reason behind it is that it will lead to protracted bargaining
concerning the gains from trade because both agents are likely to become locked in a
position where they are no longer competing with a (possibly large) number of agents in the
entire market and the incentives are no longer there to represent their positions honestly:
142
Managerial Economics
large-number bargaining is transformed into small-number bargaining.
If the transaction is a recurring or lengthy one, a continual power struggle takes place
concerning the gains from trade, further increasing transaction costs. Thus, re-negotiation
may be necessary. Moreover, there are liable to be situations where a purchaser may
require a particular, firm-specific investment of a supplier, which would be profitable for
both. However, after the investment has been made it becomes a sunk cost and the
purchaser can endeavour to re-negotiate the contract such that the supplier may make a
loss on the investment (this is the hold-up problem, which occurs when either party
asymmetrically incurs substantial costs or benefits before being paid for or paying for them).
In this kind of a situation, the most efficient approach to overcome continual conflict of
interest between two agents (or coalitions of agents) may be the removal of one of them
from the equation by takeover or merger. Asset specificity can also apply to some extent to
both physical and human capital so that the hold-up problem can also occur with labour (e.g.
labour can threaten a strike because of the lack of good alternative human capital but
equally the firm can threaten to fire).
Probably, the best constraint on such opportunism is reputation (rather than the law,
because of the difficulty of negotiating, writing and enforcement of contracts). If a
reputation for opportunism significantly damages an agent’s dealings in the future, this
alters the incentives to be opportunistic.
Williamson opines that the limit on the size of the firm is partly an outcome of costs
of delegation (as a firm’s size increases its hierarchical bureaucracy does too) and partly the
result of the large firm’s increasing inability to replicate high-powered incentives of residual
income of an owner-entrepreneur. To a certain extent this can be attributed to the nature of
large firms to ensure that its existence is more secure and less dependent on the actions of
any one individual (increasing the incentives to shirk) and because intervention rights from
the centre characteristic of a firm tend to be accompanied by some form of income
insurance to compensate for the lesser responsibility, thereby diluting incentives. Milgrom
and Roberts (1990) show that increased cost of management is a result of employee's
tendency to provide false information beneficial to themselves, which increases the cost of
filtering information. This grows worse with firm size and more layers in the hierarchy.
Empirical analyses of transaction costs have rarely attempted to measure and operationalise
transaction costs. Research that attempts to measure transaction costs is the most critical
limit to efforts to potential falsification and validation of transaction cost economics.
Managerial Economics
143
4.3.7 SIMON SATISFYING BEHAVIOUR MODEL
The behavioural approach, as developed in particular by Richard Cyert and James G.
March of the Carnegie School, places emphasis on explaining how decisions are taken within
the firm and goes well beyond neo-classical economics. This approach utilises the work of
Herbert Simon on behaviour in situations of uncertainty conducted in the 1950s. He argues
that “people possess limited cognitive ability and so can exercise only ‘bounded rationality’
when making decisions in complex, uncertain situations”. Thus, individuals and groups tend
to ‘satisfy’—that is, to attempt to attain realistic goals, rather than maximise a utility or
profit function. Cyert and March argued that the firm cannot be regarded as a monolith,
because different individuals and groups within it have their own aspirations and conflicting
interests and that firm behaviour is the weighted outcome of these conflicts. Organisational
mechanisms (such as ‘satisfying’ and sequential decision-taking) exist to maintain conflict at
levels that are not unacceptably detrimental. Compared to ideal state of productive
efficiency, there is organisational slack (Leibenstein’s X-inefficiency).
For Cyert and March, the firm is best viewed as a coalition of individuals or groups of
individuals. Individuals or groups of individuals are seen as being likely to have goals,
whereas organisations do not. There is the likelihood that there may be competing goal
conflict between individuals or groups that make up the coalition. A simple resolution of this
potential conflict can be achieved as follows: The assumption that there is a supreme
authority that is willing and able to force conformity in the behaviour of these individuals or
groups to some higher level goal or the assumption of a happy coincidence of consensus is
rejected from the outset. Rather Cyert and March argue that organisational goals are
formed through a bargaining process involving the members of the coalition. The form,
which this bargaining takes, is normally over the distribution of what are referred to as 'side
payments'. Side payments are inducements in the form of policy commitments or simply
payments. The distinction between these two forms of 'side payments' might not be
important. This is because commitments to pay money can be reduced to policy
commitments.
The pattern of policy commitments that result from the bargaining process can be
seen to be a specification of the goals of the organisation. However, it is likely that because
of the way in which agreement is reached, organisational objectives that emerge are
imperfectly rationalised and expressed either in the form of 'aspiration levels' or in nonoperational form. These organisational goals change in two ways as the bargaining process,
which is continuous, proceeds: aspiration levels with respect to existing goals i.e. the levels
of achievement regarded as acceptable by coalition members, will be modified in the light of
144
Managerial Economics
the levels actually achieved and new goals will be introduced as the attention focus of
coalition members alters. The organisation copes with irrationalised conflicting goals partly
because some of the objectives are expressed in non-operational form, since at any one
time some of the objectives will assume a non-active form but mainly because objectives are
considered sequentially and not simultaneously. Sequential, rather than simultaneous
consideration is one of the central characteristics of the theory. Closely allied to the
hypothesised ability of the organisation to survive in the face of conflicting goals is the
concept of 'organisational slack' i.e. the notion that due to ignorance and market
imperfections, the payment made to coalition members will normally be in excess of that
needed to keep them within the coalition. The existence of organisational slack enables the
organisation to survive adverse changes in the external environment without disintegrating.
Decisions taken within the organisation are explicitly made dependent on the
information available to and the expectations formed by the decision takers within the
organisation. Emphasis is placed upon the fact that the expectations, formed on the basis of
any given information and indeed the type of information gathered, will not be independent
of the subjective situation and interests of the individuals or groups involved. The theory
argues that change is typically only considered when a problem arises, although it is
recognised that if a solution comes to hand, a search for an appropriate problem may be
induced. Once a problem has arisen, usually in relation to the non achievement of one of the
organisational goals or sub-goals, 'search activity' is triggered off to discover possible
solutions; that is, information is sought. Here, at this point, the concept of sequential as
opposed to simultaneous consideration becomes relevant. The alternatives thrown up by
search activity are considered in turn as they arise and the first alternative that enables the
aspiration level with respect to the goal in question to be achieved is accepted. Hence, the
procedure of decision making has been described as 'satisfying' rather than maximising; it is
designed to satisfy multiple, changing, acceptable-level goals, not to maximise a consistently
specified objective function. This is not to say that the firm's behaviour is 'irrational'. Given
the problems of information gathering and processing and the desire to reduce uncertainty,
some sort of satisfying procedure may be the best possible in practice. For this reason, the
approach outlined here has been nominated as 'qualified' or 'bounded' rationality.
The result of this analysis is that the firm is seen as an adaptive organisation. Changes
in the environment raise problems and the organisation reacts to these problems according
to certain established routines, known as 'standard operating procedures', which have been
evolved in the course of a long-run adaptive process. The theory has been developed
deliberately for the analysis of short-run behaviour and consequently little attention has
Managerial Economics
145
been paid to the exploration of the long-run adaptive process.
THE SIGNIFICANCE OF THE BEHAVIOURAL APPROACH
The significance of the behavioural approach is difficult to assess. It provides useful
insights into some aspects of business behaviour. Cyert and March have claimed
considerable short-run predictive success with their theory and have suggested that this is
due to the realism of their assumptions about the internal workings of the firms in question.
However several problems are yet to be resolved. In order to predict any specific firm's
behaviour, detailed knowledge of the goals and standard operating procedures of that
specific firm is required. Since operating procedures in particular are by their nature highly
particularised, there is little scope for generalisation. Changes in goals and standard
operating procedures occur in response to fairly immediate problems, within an essentially
short-run framework. Of course, the changes are made in accordance with higher level rules,
but these somehow just emerge from a long-run adaptive process that is not explored and
they are presumably still very firm specific. Although not explored, it is clear that the longrun adaptive process is not to be regarded as tending towards long-run 'rationality', since in
an uncertain and unstable environment; it has been argued short run adaptation is the key.
There may, nevertheless, be interest in the relationship between the short-run and the long
run and it has yet to be demonstrated that the behavioural approach can be adapted in this
direction. Associated with the short-run orientation of the behavioural approach is its
concept of the firm as essentially passive. The stress on the process of short-run response to
environmental stimuli, with longer-run considerations of survival conditions and strategic
planning explicitly excluded is overwhelming. Yet, as argued earlier in this chapter, the
characteristics of the large dominant firm suggest the need for a concept of the firm as an
active entity, consciously seeking to influence its environment in ways that are favourable to
the achievement of its objectives. By focusing the way in which stimuli from an exogenous
environment call forth responses from an isolated individual firm, attention is firmly directed
away from the properties of the system as a whole. The environment exists somehow 'out
there' and its properties are placed beyond the scope of the inquiry.
It is, of course, possible to recognise the force of the observation that large firms are
complex organisations and yet to avoid recourse to behaviour. If a firm's organisational
characteristics have no implications for its behaviour or more probably have implications
that can be taken into account without adopting a behaviourist approach, a holistic concept
of the firm can be retained. Thus, although organisational characteristics such as the
relationship between shareholders and managers may need to be analysed in order to
determine what the firm's objective is, once this has been done, the firm can be viewed as a
146
Managerial Economics
unit acting consistently in pursuit of a clearly specified objective. Similarly, internal
administrative processes can be regarded as a separate area of study, in the same way that
technical processes of production or marketing are regarded as separate areas of study and
can be abstracted from the theory of the firm. Of course, the study of internal
administration may lead to conclusions with relevance for a theory of the firm, such as that
there exists an absolute size or a rate of growth above which the administrative efficiency of
the firm declines. Once established, these conclusions can be regarded as part of the initial
set of assumptions required for the construction of any theory.
The main contribution of the behavioural approach for the development of an
understanding of business behaviour is to highlight the role played by uncertainty (not risk),
the view that the behaviour of the firm can best be understood as viewing it as a continuing
process and the rejection of micro equilibrium.
4.3.8 OTHER MODELS
Efficiency wage models like that of Shapiro and Stiglitz (1984) suggest wage rents as
an addition to monitoring, since this gives employees an incentive not to shirk their
responsibilities, given a certain probability of detection and the consequence of being fired.
Williamson, Wachter and Harris (1975) suggest promotion incentives within the firm as an
alternative to morale-damaging monitoring, where promotion is based on objectively
measurable performance. (The difference between these two approaches may be that the
former is applicable to a blue-collar environment, the latter to a white-collar one).
Leibenstein (1966) sees a firm’s norms or conventions, dependent on its history of
management initiatives, labour relations and other factors, as determining the firm’s
‘culture’ of effort, thus affecting the firm’s productivity and hence size.
George Akerlof (1982) develops a gift exchange model of reciprocity, in which
employers offer wages unrelated to variations in output and above the market level and
workers develop concern for each other’s welfare, such that all put in effort above the
minimum required but the more able workers are not rewarded for their extra productivity;
again, size here depends not on rationality or efficiency but on social factors. Therefore, the
limit to the firm’s size is given where costs rise to the point where the market can undertake
some transactions more efficiently than the firm.
Managerial Economics
147
Study Notes
Assessment
Write short notes on the following:
1. Transaction Cost Theory
2. Williamson's Approach
3.
Simon Satisfying Behaviour Model
Discussion
Discuss the difference between PROFIT MAXIMISATION AND SALES MAXIMISATION THEORIES.
4.4 Summary
Theory of Firm: The theory of the firm consists of a number of economic theories,
which describe the nature of the firm, its objectives, its existence, its behaviour and its
relationship with the market.
Transaction Cost Theory: Ronald Coase set out his transaction cost theory of the firm
in 1937, making it one of the first (neo-classical) attempts to define the firm theoretically in
relation to the market.
148
Coase concludes by saying that the size of the firm is dependent on the cost of using
Managerial Economics
the price mechanism and on the cost of organisation of other entrepreneurs. These two
factors together determine how many products a firm produces and how much of each.
Managerial and Behavioural Theories: Managerial theories of the firm, as developed
by William Baumol (1959 and 1962), Robin Marris (1964) and Oliver E. Williamson (1966),
suggest that managers would seek to maximise their own utility and consider the
implications of this for firm behaviour in contrast to the profit-maximising case. (Baumol
suggested that managers’ interests are best served by maximising sales after achieving a
minimum level of profit, which satisfies shareholders.)
Profit Maximisation Theory: The profit maximisation theory states that companies
or corporations will locate firms/ factories where they can achieve the highest total profit.
The company will select a location based upon comparative advantage (where the product
can be produced the cheapest). In economics, profit maximisation is the process by which a
firm determines the price and output level that returns the greatest profit.
Sales Maximisation Theory: W.J. Baumol (Economic Theory and Operations Analysis,
1965) is generally recognised as having first suggested that firms often seek to maximise the
money value of their sales i.e. their sales revenue, subject to a constraint that their profits
do not fall short of some minimum level which is just on the borderline of acceptability.
Team Production: Armen Alchian and Harold Demsetz's analysis of team production
is an extension and clarification of earlier work by Coase. Thus, according to them, the firm
emerges because extra output is provided by team production but that the success of this
depends on being able to manage the team so that metering problems (it is costly to
measure the marginal outputs of the co-operating inputs for reward purposes) and
attendant shirking (the moral hazard problem) can be overcome, by estimating marginal
productivity by observing or specifying input behaviour.
Williamson's Approach: For Oliver E. Williamson, the existence of firms derives from
‘asset specificity’ in production, where assets are specific to each other such that their value
is much less in a second-best use.
Simon's Satisfying Behavioural Model: Herbert Simon’s work in the 1950s
concerning behaviour in situations of uncertainty, which argued that “people possess limited
cognitive ability and so can exercise only ‘bounded rationality’ when making decisions in
complex, uncertain situations”.
Managerial Economics
149
4.5 Self Assessment Test
Broad Questions
1. Explain Simon's Satisfying Behavioural Model. What is the significance of behavioural
approach?
2. What are the various theories of Firm?
Short Notes
a. Profit maximisation
b. Transaction Cost Theory
c. Team production
d. Williamson's approach
e. Sales maximisation
4.6 Further Reading
1. A Modern Micro Economics, Koutsoyiannis, Macmillan, 1991
2. Business Economics, Adhikary, M,., Excel Books, New Delhi, 2000
3. Economics Organisation and Management, Milgrom, P and Roberts J, Prentice Hall Inc,
Englewood Clitts, New Jersey, 1992
4. Economics Theory and Operations Analysis, Baumol, W J., 3rd ed., Prentice Hall Inc, 1996
5. Managerial Economics, Chopra, O P., Tata McGraw Hill, New Delhi, 1985
6. Managerial Economics, Keat, Paul G and Philips K Y Young, Prentice Hall, New Jersey,
1996
7. Managerial Economics, Maheshwari, Yogesh, Sultanchand and Sons, 2009
8. Managerial Economics, Varshney, R L., Sultanchand and Sons, 2007
150
Managerial Economics
Assignment
According to you, which approach should be preferred, "profit maximisation or sales
maximisation"? You can also suggest any other theory, which you feel should be followed.
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
Managerial Economics
151
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
Managerial Economics
152
Unit 5
Market Structure
Learning Outcome
After going through this unit, you will be able to:
•
Outline Classification of Market
•
Discuss Meaning and characteristics of Perfect Competition.
•
Interpret basics of Monopoly
•
Identify Monopolistic Competition
•
Outline basics of Oligopoly
•
Contrast price determination in various market situations
Time Required to Complete the unit
1.
1st Reading: It will need 3 Hrs for reading a unit
2.
2nd Reading with understanding: It will need 4 Hrs for reading and understanding a
unit
3.
Self Assessment: It will need 3 Hrs for reading and understanding a unit
4.
Assignment: It will need 2 Hrs for completing an assignment
5.
Revision and Further Reading: It is a continuous process
Content Map
5.1
Introduction
5.2
Types of Market Structures formed by the Nature of Competition
5.3
Perfect Competition
5.3.1
Definition of Perfect Competition
5.3.2
Characteristics of Perfect Competition
Managerial Economics
153
5.3.3
5.4
5.5
Price under Perfect Competition
Monopoly
5.4.1
Definition of Monopoly
5.4.2
Characteristics of Monopoly
5.4.3
Types of Monopoly
5.4.4
Sources of Monopoly
5.4.5
Price under Monopoly
Monopolistic Competition
5.5.1
Features of Monopolistic Competition
5.5.2
Assumptions of Monopolistic Competition
5.5.3 Price determination under Monopolistic Competition
5.5.4 Defects or Wastes of Monopolistic Competition
5.6
Oligopoly
5.6.1 Definition of Oligopoly
5.6.2
Characteristics of Oligopoly
5.6.3
Price-Output Determination under Oligopoly
5.7
Summary
5.8
Self Assessment Test
5.9
Further Reading
154
Managerial Economics
5.1 Introduction
Market economy pricing is conditioned by market structure. There are distinct forms
of market structures. Perfect competition is accorded great importance as a market
structure. As a theoretical mode, classical and neoclassical economists assume conditions of
perfect competition.
The market is an assemblage of conditions in which buyers and sellers come in
contact for the purpose of exchange. Market situations vary in their structure. Different
market structures channel the behaviour of buyers and sellers (firms). Further, different
prices and trade volumes are fashioned by different market structures. Again, all kinds of
markets are not equally efficient in the exploitation of resources and consumers’ welfare
also varies accordingly. Hence, the aspects of pricing process should be analysed in relation
to different types of market.
5.2 Types of Market Structures formed by the Nature of
Competition
Traditionally, the nature of competition is assayed to be the fundamental criterion
for distinguishing different types of market structures.
The degrees of competition may vary among the sellers as well as the buyers in
different market situations.
•
The nature of competition among the sellers is viewed on the basis of two major aspects:
The number of firms in the market
•
The characteristics of products, such as whether the products are homogeneous or
differentiated
Individual seller’s control over the market supply and his hand on price
determination basically depends upon these two factors.
Based on selling or supply, the following types of market structures are commonly
distinguished:
•
Perfect competition
•
Monopoly
•
Oligopoly
•
Monopolistic competition
Managerial Economics
155
Perfect competition and monopoly are two extremes of market situations. Other
forms of market such as oligopoly and monopolistic competition fall in between these two
extremes. Oligopoly and monopolistic competition are the market situations characterised
by imperfect competition.
Study Notes
Assessment
1. Define Market.
2. What is Market Structure?
3. What are the types of Market structures on the basis of competition.
Discussion
Discuss Types of Market Structures Formed by the criterion other than nature of competition.
5.3 Perfect Competition
5.3.1 DEFINITION OF PERFECT COMPETITION
1. Prof. Marshall
“The more nearly perfect a market is, the stronger is the
tendency for the same price to be paid for the same thing at
the same time in all parts of the market”.
2. Prof. Benham
156
“A market is said to be perfect when all the potential sellers
Managerial Economics
and buyers are promptly aware of the price at which
transactions take place and all of the offers made by other
sellers and buyers and when any buyer can purchase from any
seller and vice-versa”.
Thus, perfect competition is a market situation where a
colossal amount of buyers as well as sellers possessing
complete knowledge of the market come together to afford
the similar products. In perfect competition, an equilibrium
price exists in the market and firms are free to take part in and
to exit the market.
5.3.2 CHARACTERISTICS OF PERFECT COMPETITION
Following are the characteristics of perfect competition market:
•
Large Number of Buyers and Sellers: As there are a large number of buyers and sellers,
no individual buyer or seller can influence the price of product, which is determined by
collective effect of all the buyers and sellers.
•
Homogenous Product: As the product of all the firms is homogenous or identical, all the
firms sell their product at the market price. No firm can charge any price more than the
price prevailing in the market.
•
Free Entry and Exit of Firms: All the firms are free to join or leave industry. There is no
restriction on their entry and exit. Hence, if the industry is accruing profits, new firms will
enter into the market. Contrarily, if the industry is suffering loss, many firms will leave
the market.
•
Perfect Knowledge of Market Conditions: Since all the buyers and sellers hold perfect
knowledge of all the market conditions, there is free movement of buyers and sellers.
Advertisement and selling methods do not have an effect on consumer behaviour.
•
Perfect Mobility of the Factors of Production: As all the factors of production are
perfectly mobile, factors of production are free to shift to any organisation where they
are not being paid a fair price.
•
Independence of Decision Making: All buyers and sellers are fully independent. None of
them is committed to anyone. Hence, the buyers are free to purchase the required
commodity from any seller and sellers are free to sell their commodity to any buyer or
buyers. The price of a commodity at a particular time tends to be equal all over the
market which all the firms have to follow.
Managerial Economics
157
•
Absence of Selling and Transportation Costs. It is assumed that selling and
transportation costs have no role to play in the determination of price.
5.3.3 PRICE UNDER PERFECT COMPETITION
We can analyse the equilibrium of a firm under Perfect Competition in both the
short-run as well as in the long run.
A. SHORT RUN EQUILIBRIUM OF A FIRM UNDER PERFECT COMPETITION
Under short period, the firm can face four different situations depending on
whether:
•
AR > AC
Supernormal Profits
•
AR = AC
Normal profits
•
AR < AC
Losses
•
AR < AC < AVC
a)
Shut down point
Supernormal Equilibrium: E is the point of stable equilibrium as MC = MR and
the MC cuts the MR from below.
Fig. 5.1: Supernormal Equilibrium
This is point the firm produces OM amount of the output. To produce this output,
the firm incurs an average cost of MF, while it earns average revenue of ME. Since at
equilibrium ME > MF, the firm makes a profit of FE per unit of output sold. Again, since the
total revenue earned when OM is sold is OPEM and the total cost incurred to produce the
same output is ORFM, the total profit earned at that level of output is RPEF.
158
Managerial Economics
b)
Normal Profits: With the condition of MC = MR and the MC cuts the MR from
below, if E is the point of stable equilibrium, output of the firm is OM. produce this output,
the firm incurs an average cost ME, while it earns average revenue, which is also equal to
ME. Thus, we see that the firm just makes a normal profit – i.e., its AR = AC. Since the total
revenue earned and the total cost incurred at output OM is OPEM, the firm earns a normal
profit.
Fig 5.2: Normal profit equilibrium
c)
Losses: At the point of equilibrium i.e. E where MR = MC, the firm produces
OM amount of the output. To produce this output, the firm incurs an average cost of PF,
while it earns average revenue, which is equal to ME. Since at equilibrium MF > ME, (AR<AC)
the firm incurs a loss of EF per unit of output produced. Again, since the total revenue
earned when OM output is sold is only OPEM, while the total cost incurred at output OM is
ORFM, the firm incurs a total loss of PRFE. This is actually the situation of the firm
minimising its losses.
Fig. 5.3: Losses
Managerial Economics
159
In-spite of incurring loss, the firm could continue its functioning since its Average
Variable Cost is being covered. At output OM, the firm covers its AVC, which is equal to MG.
Hence, as long as the firm is recovering at least its AVC, it would be possible for this firm to
continue functioning.
Shut Down Point: With MR = MC, the firm attains equilibrium at point E
d)
where, it produces OM amount of the output. To produce this output, the firm incurs an
average cost of MF, while it earns average revenue ME. At equilibrium MF > ME, the firm
incurs a loss of EF per unit of output produced. Since the total revenue earned is only OPEM,
while the total cost incurred is ORFM, the firm incurs a total loss of PRFE. The loss incurred is
too much for this firm to continue, as this firms’ AVC curve is also above its AR = MR curves –
i.e. it is unable to cover even its AVC. In the above situation, at output OM, the firm’s AVC, is
equal to MG, which is greater than the AR = ME. Hence, this firm is not even recovering its
daily or running expenses, so it should shut down.
SHUT DOWN POINT i.e. AR < AVC < AC
Y
MC
AC
AVC
R
F
ME – MF = - EF
AR < AVC < AC
ME < MG < MF
G
P
SHUT DOWN POINT
AR <AVC < AC
ME < MG < MF
AR – AC = Av. Profit
AR = MR
TR
-
TC
OPEM - ORFM
= Total Profit
= PRFE
E
Fig. 5.4: Shut down point
B. LONG RUN EQUILIBRIUM OF A FIRM UNDER PERFECT COMPETITION
In the long run, due to the assumption of free entry and exit of the firms, it is not
possible for the firms to make super-normal profits nor is it possible for them to incur losses.
Hence, due to the size of the industry increasing or decreasing in the long run, firms can only
earn normal profits in this time period.
The possibility of only normal profits can be explained as under.
160
Managerial Economics
Y
Y
S1
D
S
P
R
S2
MC
P’
AC AR’=MR’
I
E1
C
E
P
P”
E
E”
AR=MR
AR’’=MR’’
Fig. 5.5: Long Run Equilibrium under Perfect Competition
Suppose that the firm is earning a super-normal profit in the long run, since the
industry’s price (OP) (i.e. the firm’s AR’ = MR’ = OP’) is greater than its AC. In this situation,
new firms would find this area of production to be attractive and hence they would enter
this industry in large numbers. With the number of firms increasing, the supply in the
industry also rises. As the supply rises, the price will start lowering. This will go on until the
supply curve becomes S1 to S. This leads to fall in price from P' to P. The firm’s AR=MR curve
becomes tangential to the firms LAC at point E and so from the situation of earning supernormal profits the profit’s size has been reduced to normal profit.
Suppose that the firm is incurring losses in the long run since the industry’s price (OP)
(i.e. the firm’s AR’’ = MR’’ = OP”) is lower than its AC. In this situation, some of the firms that
are unable to recover even their AVC will shut down and leave the industry. With the
number of firms decreasing, the supply in the industry also falls. As the supply keeps falling,
the price will start rising. Thus, price rises from P" to P. This will go on until the supply curve
becomes S2 to S. The firm’s AR=MR curve becomes tangential to the firms LAC and so from
the situation of incurring losses, the firm’s revenues have improved so as to convert losses
into normal profits.
Hence, we can conclude that in the long run, a firm under perfect Competition can
only earn normal profits and not earn super-normal profits or incur losses.
Study Notes
Managerial Economics
161
Assessment
What is Perfect Competition? What are the characteristics of Perfect Competition?
Discussion
Discuss price under perfect completion in short and long run.
5.4 Monopoly
The term ‘Monopoly’ has been derived from Greek term ‘Monopolies’ which means a
single seller. Thus, monopoly is a market condition in which there is a single seller of a
particular commodity who is called monopolist and has complete control over the supply of
his product.
5.4.1 DEFINITION OF MONOPOLY
1. Prof. Thomas
“Broadly, the term Monopoly is used to cover any effective price
control, whether of supply or demand of services or goods;
narrowly it is used to mean a combination of manufacturers or
merchants to control the supply price of commodities or services”.
2. Prof. Chamberlain
“Monopoly refers to the control over supply”.
3. Prof. Robert Triffin
“Monopoly is a market situation in which the firm is independent
of price changes in the product of each and every other firm".
He is called a monopolist. He is the only producer in the industry. There are no close
substitutes for his product. Thus, when there is only one seller of a commodity and there is
162
Managerial Economics
no competition at all, the situation is one of pure monopoly.
A monopolist firm is itself an industry, for the distinction between a firm and an
industry disappears under monopoly.
In technical language, pure monopoly is a single firm-industry where the crosselasticity of demand between its product and the products of the other industries is zero.
Professor E.H. Chamberlin points out that the essence of monopoly is control over
supply.
Pure monopoly rarely exists in reality. It is merely a theoretical concept, because
even if there were no close substitutes, some kind of competition would always be there,
such as a choice between decorating a house or buying a car. However, even though pure
monopolies are a rare phenomenon in developed countries, they are found in developing
countries like India in the form of State monopolies, e.g. the Mahanagar Telephone Nigam
Ltd. (MTNL) and the Post and Telegraph Department of the Government of India.
5.4.2 CHARACTERISTICS OF MONOPOLY
From the above discussion, let us summarise the main characteristics of monopoly as
under:
•
There is a single producer of a commodity.
•
There is absence of competition.
•
There are no close substitutes for a monopoly product.
•
Cross-elasticity of demand for a monopoly product is zero in the case of pure monopoly
and very low in the case of simple monopoly.
•
The monopolistic firm has control over supply of its commodity.
•
There is no distinction between firm and industry under monopoly.
•
Cases of pure monopolies are not found in developed countries. However, such cases of
pure monopolies are found in developing countries.
•
A monopolist will prevent entry of new firms in the long run.
5.4.3 TYPES OF MONOPOLY
•
Natural Monopoly: Natural monopoly is due to natural factors. For example, a particular
raw material is concentrated at a particular place and this gives rise to monopoly
exploitation of such material, e.g. monopoly of diamond mines in South Africa.
Managerial Economics
163
Bangladesh has monopoly of raw jute.
•
Public Utility Monopoly: Governmental authorities seize complete control and
management of some utilities to protect social interests. For example, posts and
telegraph, telephones, electric power, railway transport, provision of water, are
monopolies of the government and local authorities. There may be private monopolies
of public utility services.
•
Fiscal Monopoly: To prevent exploitation of employees and consumers, government
nationalises certain industries and acquires fiscal monopoly power over them. E.g. Fiscal
monopoly of tobacco in France, Life insurance and general insurance monopoly in India
•
Legal Monopoly: Some monopolies are engendered and protected under certain laws.
Inventors of new processes, articles or devices obtain monopoly powers for such
inventions under patent, trade mark and copyright laws. There are many examples of
legal monopoly of medicines. As Professor F.W. Taussing observes in his Principles of
Economics, copyrights and patents are the simplest cases of absolute monopoly by law.
However, as Professor E.H. Chamberlin points out, such cases would fall more under
monopolistic competition than under monopoly.
•
Voluntary Monopoly through Combinations: To eliminate competition and thereby
secure higher prices, firms producing a particular product may come together and make
monopoly agreements. These are known as industrial combinations. When all the firms
merge into one organisation, such a monopoly takes the form of a trust. The Associated
Cement Companies (A.C.C.) in India is an example of this kind of trust. Where the firms
maintain their individual identity and yet enter into monopoly agreements such
combinations are known as trade associations, pools, cartels and holding companies. A
pool is deemed a loose combination to maintain a particular higher price level of a
commodity. A cartel is based on agreements to restrict output to get high prices e.g. the
Sugar Syndicate in Maharashtra. A holding company secures monopolistic control over a
number of firms by holding a majority of shares in them.
5.4.4 SOURCES OF MONOPOLY
•
Legal Sanction: A monopoly as stated above may be the result of a government sanction.
The government of a country may legally permit a private monopoly or monopoly in the
public sector for myriad reasons. National security (e.g. manufacture of defense
equipments), social equity (post office, water supply, electricity supply, telephones) or
economic considerations (public utility services or essential goods to be produced on a
large scale by a single firm for reducing the cost and price e.g. monopoly of transport
Managerial Economics
164
services) are paradigms of such monopolies. Monopolies may be created to avoid wastes
due to duplication of services e.g. public utilities.
•
Control Over Supply of Inputs: Secondly, a monopoly situation may arise due to control
over the supply of an essential input - raw materials, skilled labour, technology useddenying access to these inputs to any potential firm e.g. government monopoly of
Railways in India. Rail tracks are not used by private rail companies. Monopolies may be
protected through a protectionist policy of the government by putting tariffs on foreign
goods.
•
Merger for Large-scale Production: Thirdly, monopoly undertaking may be a
consequence of the necessity to produce on a large scale to reduce costs. Existing small
firms may merge into a big firm or may not survive in the long period. It is only when
there is single firm in such a situation that costs are greatly reduced due to the
economies of large-scale production.
•
Rival Firms Eliminated: Fourthly, pressure tactics and unfair means by a giant firm may
lead to elimination of rival firms from the industry to secure sole position of a giant firm.
In India, many such examples were revealed in the Monopoly Inquiry Commission’s
report.
5.4.5 PRICE UNDER MONOPOLY
The aim of the monopolist is to maximise profit therefore; he will produce that level
of output and charge that price that gives him maximum profits. He will be in equilibrium at
that price and output at which his profits are the maximum. In other words, he will be in
equilibrium position at that level of output at which marginal revenue equals marginal cost.
In order to achieve equilibrium, the monopolist should satisfy two conditions:
•
Marginal cost should be equal to marginal revenue.
•
The marginal cost curve should cut marginal revenue curve from below.
A. Short run equilibrium of a firm under monopoly
The short run equilibrium of the monopolist is shown below in figure 5.6.
Managerial Economics
165
Fig. 5.6: Abnormal Profit under Monopoly
AR is the average revenue curve, MR is the marginal revenue curve, AC is the average
cost curve and MC is the marginal cost curve. Up to OQ, level of output marginal revenue is
greater than marginal cost but beyond OQ the marginal revenue is less than marginal cost.
Therefore, the monopolist will be in equilibrium where MC=MR. Thus, a monopolist is in
equilibrium at OQ level of output and at OP price. He earns abnormal profit equal to PRST.
However, it is not always possible for a monopolist to earn super normal profits. If
the demand and cost situations are not favourable, the monopolist may incur short run
losses.
Fig. 5.7: Loss under Monopoly
Though the monopolist is a price maker, due to weak demand and high costs, he
suffers a loss equal to PABC as shown above in figure 5.7.
B. Long run Equilibrium of a Firm under Monopoly
In the long run, the firm has the time to adjust his plant size or to use the existing
plant so as to maximise profit. The long run equilibrium of the monopolist is shown in figure
5.8.
166
Managerial Economics
Fig. 5.8: Long run equilibrium of a firm under monopoly
The monopolist is in equilibrium at OL output where LMC cuts MR curve. He will
charge OP price and earn an abnormal profit equal to TPQH.
Study Notes
Assessment
1.
Explain Monopoly Market structure.
2.
Explain features and types of Monopoly.
Discussion
Discuss Pricing under Monopoly.
Managerial Economics
167
5.5 Monopolistic Competition
In the real world, market is neither perfectly competitive nor a monopoly. The great
majority of imperfectly competitive producers in the real world produce goods, which are
neither completely different nor completely same. They produce goods, which are
analogous to those produced by their rivals. This means that the goods produced in the
market are close substitutes. It follows that such producers must be concerned about the
way in which the action of these rivals affects their own profits. This kind of market is known
as ‘monopolistic competition’ or group equilibrium. Here there is competition, which is
keen, though not perfect, between firms manufacturing very similar products, for example
market for toothpaste, cosmetics, watches, etc.
5.5.1 FEATURES OF MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION
Following are the features of a monopolistic competitive market:
•
Large number of firm: Monopolistic competition is characterised by large number of
firms producing close substitutes but not identical product. Each firm must control a
small yet significant portion of the market share such that by substantially extending or
restricting its own sales, it is not able to affect the sales of any other individual seller.
This condition is the same as in perfect market.
•
There is product differentiation: No seller has full control over the market supply. Each
seller produces very close substitute products. The product is neither identical nor
markedly different. Since every seller produces slightly differentiated product, each
seller has minor control over the price. Unlike perfect market conditions, the firm is a
price – maker to some extent. That is, a firm can change the price slightly, though not
much. The control over price will depend on the degree of product differentiation.
•
Absence of Inter-dependence: Existence of a large number of firms insures the condition
too large and too small. Thus, the individual firm’s supply is small constituent of total
supply. Therefore, individual firm has limited control over price level. Similarly, each firm
can decide, its price or output policies independently through price discrimination, any
action by one firm may not invite reaction from rival firms.
•
Selling cost: Competitive advertisement is an essential feature of monopolistic
competition. Selling cost becomes an integral part of the marketing of firms when
product is differentiated. It is necessary to tell the buyers about the superiority of the
product and induce the customer to buy the products.
168
Managerial Economics
•
Free entry and exit: Under
nder monopolistic
mo
competition, new firms can enter
ter or existing
firms can exit. There are
e no res
restrictions on entry or exit. Moreover entry
try is ea
easy because
of the small size of firms.
s. Existence
Existe
of supernormal profit attracts entry and existence of
loss, business firms to quit
uit the market.
m
5.5.2 ASSUMPTIONS OF MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION
•
There are a significant number of sellers as well as buyers in the ‘group’.
•
Products of the sellers are separated,
sepa
however they are close substitutes
tes of one
on another.
•
There is free entry as well as exit of the organisation in the group.
•
The objective of the firm is to maximise profits, both in the short run as we
well as in the
long run.
5.5.3 PRICE DETERMINATION UNDER MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION
A) SHORT-TERM EQUILIBRIU
UILIBRIUM OF A FIRM
Short-term implies to the period
pe
where a firm is not able to regulate the supply of its
product as per the demand. Owing
Owin to this reason, a firm is not able to accomp
accomplish much
taking into account its profit situation
situati in the short-run. Thus, in the short-run,
run, there
ther could be
three contingencies concerning profit
pro (i) Abnormal profit, (ii) Normal or Zero
ro profit
profit, (iii) Loss.
1. Abnormal Profit. In short-run
run an organisation could be capable of acquiring
cquiring abnormal
profit only as soon as the demand
dem
of the organisation's product is extremel
xtremely high and
there is no close substitute
itute to its product. Under these circumstances,
s, the organisation
can establish a high price
ice for iits product and can acquire abnormal profit. TThis can be
achievable only in the short-run,
short
as no new organisation can become invol
nvolved in the
market in the short-run.. It can b
be explained with the help of figure 5.9.
Fig. 5.9:: Supernormal
Supe
Profit under Monopolistic Market
Managerial Economics
169
In the figure above, 'E' is the point of equilibrium of firm because at this point
marginal cost and marginal revenue of the firm are equal. At this point ‘OP’ is the
equilibrium price, OQ is the equilibrium quantity of production and sale, PC is the profit per
unit. In this situation, the firm is earning abnormal profit equal to the area PBTC.
2. Normal Profit or Zero Profit: If the demand of the organisation's product is not
extremely high, the organisation could acquire only normal profit once average revenue
is a little more than the average cost or zero profit as soon as average revenue and
average cost are equal. These situations can be explained with the help of figure 5.10.
Fig. 5.10: (A) Normal Profit and (B) Zero Profit under Monopolistic Competition
In the figure 5.10 (A) above, 'E' is the point of equilibrium of firm because at this
point marginal cost and marginal revenue of the firm are equal. At this point, ‘OQ’ is the
equilibrium quantity, ‘OA’ is the price per unit and ‘OD’ is the cost per unit. Here, average
revenue is slightly more than average cost; in this case, the firm accrues profit equal to the
area of ‘ABCD’.
In the figure 5.10 (B) above, 'E' is the point of equilibrium of firm because at this
marginal cost and marginal revenue of the firm are equal. At this point, ‘OQ’ is the
equilibrium quantity, ‘OP is the price per unit and ‘OP’ is also the cost per unit. Here,
average revenue and average cost are equal. Therefore, the firm is not making any profit or
loss.
3. Loss: In short-run, a firm may have to suffer loss when demand of the product of firm is
so weak that the firm has to sell its product at a price less than its cost, in this case,
average revenue of the firm is less than its average cost. It can be illustrated with the
help of figure 5.11 given below:
170
Managerial Economics
Fig.. 5.11: Loss under Monopolistic Market
In the figure 5.11 above, average revenue of the firm is less than its avera
average cost. ‘E’
is the point of equilibrium.. At this point, ‘OQ’ is the equilibrium quantity,
y, ‘OD’ iis the price
per unit and ‘OA’ is the cost pe
per unit. Here, price per unit is less than
han cost per unit.
Therefore, the firm is suffering
ng a loss
los equal to the area ABCD.
B) LONG-TERM EQUILIBRIU
UILIBRIUM OF A FIRM
Long-term is the period
eriod where an organisation could regulate the supply of its
product as per its demand.
d. It is the period where new organisations can furthermore
become involved in the market. In this situation, an organisation at all times
es acquires
acqui normal
profit, as in case an organisati
rganisation is acquiring abnormal profit in short-term,
short
new
organisations will become involved in the market. It will add to the supply
ply of the product
and consequently the price
e of the product will decline. This series of new organisations
getting involved in the market
ket will carry on till the organisation is in the position
osition o
of acquiring
normal profit only. In contrast,, if an organisation is suffering a loss in the short-run,
short
several
organisations will leave the industry.
industr In this situation, supply of the product
uct will decline and
price of the product will rise to the
th level of average cost or a little moree than the average
cost. Consequently, the organisatio
ganisation will acquire normal profit. Nevertheless,, foll
following two
conditions should be fulfilled for the
th equilibrium of an organisation in the long-run
run.
•
Marginal cost as well as marginal
margin revenue of all the organisations should
ld be eq
equal.
•
Average cost as well as average revenue of all the organisations should be equ
equal.
It can be explained with the help of the following figure
Managerial Economics
171
Fig. 5.12: Long run Equilibrium under Monopolistic Market
In the figure 5.12 mentioned above, ‘E’ is the point of equilibrium. At this point, MC =
MR. At this point, ‘OM’ is the equilibrium quantity, ‘OP’ is the equilibrium price and ‘QM’ is
the average cost. At this point, average cost and average revenue are equal. It satisfies the
conditions of normal profit. In this situation, the firm is accruing normal profit equal to the
area of PQRS.
5.5.4 DEFECTS OR WASTES OF MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION
EXCESS CAPACITY
It implies the amount of output by which the long run output of the firm under
monopolistic competition falls short of the Ideal output. This is considered as wastage in
monopolistic competition.
The excess capacity under imperfect competition emerges because of downward
sloping demand curve. It can be tangent only at the falling part of LAC. This means the
greater the elasticity of this downward sloping demand curve, lesser will be excess capacity.
A firm under monopolistic competition in long run equilibrium produces an output,
which is less than what is deemed socially optimum or ideal output. Society’s productive
resources are fully utilised when they produce the output at minimum long run average
cost. However, firm under monopolistic competition operates at the output on the falling
portion of LAC; which implies it is not operating at minimum LAC point. However, under
perfect competition the firm in long period operates at minimum LAC i.e. Ideal output or
socially optimum output.
•
Unemployment: Under imperfect competition, the production capacity of the firm is not
used fully. This implies that there is underutilisation of capacity. This leads to
unemployment.
•
Exploitation: Under imperfect competition the output is restricted, so that price is kept
172
Managerial Economics
higher than the marginal cost (AR>MC). The excess of the price on MC represents real
extra burden on the community i.e. exploitation. Under perfect competition this
exploitation is not possible as price is equal to AC and MC (AR=MC=AC)
•
Advertisement: Expenditure on competition advertisement is regarded as a waste of
competition. It is the result of imperfect competition because under perfect competition
there is no need for such advertisement due to homogenous products. However, under
imperfect competition product is differentiated and therefore advertisement becomes
necessary in order to earn larger share in the market.
•
Cross Transport: The existence of cross transport is another factor contributing to waste
of imperfect competition. A firm in India may be a selling a commodity in India while the
same product produced in India may be sold abroad. This is also the result of absence of
perfect competition and presence of product differentiates.
•
Specialisation: Another waste of imperfect competition is the failure of each firm in
India to specialise in the production of those commodities for which it is best suited.
•
Standardisation: Under imperfect competition, standardisation which helps in reducing
cost is not possible. No produce can take the rich producing particular design on larger.
Study Notes
Assessment
1.
Explain Monopolistic Market structure in detail.
2.
What are the defects and wastages of Monopolistic Market structure.
Managerial Economics
173
Discussion
Discuss Pricing under Monopolistic Competition.
5.6 Oligopoly
The type of market condition, which is most appropriate in the today's economy, is
oligopoly. It is characterised by mutual interdependence among a few sellers who control
the total market supply. Oligopoly, therefore, occurs when there are only a few sellers. It
differs from both monopoly and perfect competition and from monopolist competition.
Oligopoly is a market where a small group of producers, have significant control over major
portion of the market demand, with or without differentiated product.
5.6.1 DEFINITION OF OLIGOPOLY
Mrs. John Robinson-
“Oligopoly is market situation in between monopoly and
perfect competition in which the number of sellers is more
than one but is not so large that the market price is not
influenced by any one of them”.
Prof. George J. Stigler-
“Oligopoly is a market situation in which a firm determines its
marketing policies on the basis of expected behaviour of close
competitors”.
Prof. Stoneur and Hague-
“Oligopoly is different from monopoly on one hand in which
there is a single seller, on the other hand, it differs from
perfect competition and monopolistic competition also in
which there is a large number of sellers. In other words, while
describing the concept of oligopoly, we include the concept of
a small group of firms".
Prof. Left Witch-
“Oligopoly is a market situation in which there are a small
number of sellers and the activities of every seller are
important for others”.
Thus, oligopoly is a market situation in which a few firms producing an identical
product or the products, which are close substitutes to each other, compete with each
other.
174
Managerial Economics
5.6.2 CHARACTERISTICS OF OLIGOPOLY
Oligopoly can be characterized as follows:
•
Small Number of Sellers: There are more than one sellers of a product however; the
number is not so huge in order to generate perfect competition of monopolistic
competition.
•
Interdependence of Sellers: All the sellers are dependent on each other. They are not
free to establish their own marketing and price policies. Activities of one seller have an
effect on others.
•
Homogenous product: The product of all the sellers is identical or a close substitute to
each other.
•
Uniformity of Price: All the sellers adopt a uniform price policy due to the uniformity of
their product.
•
Price Rigidity: As the activities of all sellers are inter-reliant, the sellers prefer not to
change the price of their product too often. For that reason, the market price happens to
be steady.
•
Entry and Exit of Firms: The entry as well as exit of organisations is relatively difficult
because of non-availability of raw materials, labour, etc.
•
Inconsistency in Firms: All the organisations operating in a market are not precisely
similar to each other. One organisation could be huge and another organisation could be
tiny.
•
Uncertainty of Demand Curve: Demand curve is extremely erratic. An organisation
cannot predict its demand curve without difficulty because it is extremely difficult to
predict whether or not the competitors will change their policies of the organisations. It
is moreover extremely difficult to predict the level of such changes. For this reason, the
demand curve of an oligopoly organisation is constantly erratic.
5.6.3 PRICE-OUTPUT DETERMINATION UNDER OLIGOPOLY
(Kinky Demand Curve) Short Period
The kinked demand curve was first employed by Prof. Paul M. Sweezy to explain
price rigidity under oligopoly. In an oligopoly market, the firm knows that if it increases
price, other firms will not follow; but if price is reduced, other firms will follow the price
reduction. In some respect, the price output analysis in oligopoly is simple. Since each seller
wants to avoid uncertainty, every oligopolistic firm will adhere to the point of kink, where it
Managerial Economics
175
is safe and where it can anticipate the reaction of its rivals. However, the firm will neither
increase nor decrease price.
Y
R
E P
V
&
C
O
S
T
MC2
E
MR
MC1
AR
X
O
M
OUTPUT
Fig. 5.13: Kinked Demand Curve
This is an important consequence of the existence of the kink in the demand curve of
the firm. Because, of the vertical section in MR, i.e. uncertainty range, without affecting the
price or level of output. Under these circumstances, equality between MC and MR will not
determine the point of equilibrium. The profits will, however, be determined as in any other
market, by the difference between AR and AC. With a given marginal cost of production, OP
is more likely to be the profit-maximising price. The length of the discontinuity portion in the
MR depends on the relative elasticity of demand at point E of AR. The greater the elasticity
of demand of the portion of AR above point E and the lower the elasticity of demand of the
portion of AR below point discontinuity portion of MR, the bigger will be the discontinuity
portion of MR. Figure 5.16 shows that the price is fixed at OP and output is OM.
Study Notes
176
Managerial Economics
Assessment
1. Define Oligopoly
2. What are the features of Oligopoly
3. Explain types of Oligopoly.
Discussion
Give practical examples of Oligopoly Market situation.
5.7 Summary
Market economy pricing is conditioned by the market structure. There are many
different market structures. Perfect competition is accorded great importance as a market
structure by the classical and neoclassical economists.
Types of market structures formed by the nature of competition:
•
Traditionally, the nature of competition is adopted as the fundamental criterion for
distinguishing different types of market structures.
•
The degrees of competition may vary among the sellers as well as the buyers in different
market situations. The nature of competition among the sellers is viewed based on two
major aspects: The number of firms in the market and the characteristics of products,
such as whether the products are homogeneous or differentiated.
An individual seller’s control over the market supply and his hand on price
determination basically depends upon these two factors.
On the selling side or supply side of the market, the following types of market
structures are commonly distinguished:
•
Perfect competition
•
Monopoly
•
Oligopoly
• Monopolistic competition.
Managerial Economics
177
Perfect competition and monopoly are the two extremes of the market situations.
Other forms of market such as oligopoly and monopolistic competition fall in between these
two extremes. Oligopoly and monopolistic competition are the market situations
characterized by imperfect competition.
PERFECT COMPETITION
Perfect Competition is a market situation where a large number of buyers as well as
sellers come together to provide the similar product. They possess complete knowledge of
the market, the equilibrium price everywhere in the market. The firms are free to take part
in and to exit the market.
MONOPOLY
The term ‘monopoly’ has been derived from Greek term ‘monopolies’, which means
a single seller. Thus, monopoly is a market condition in which there is a single seller called
monopolist of a particular commodity and has complete control over the supply of his
product.
Pure monopoly rarely exists. It is merely a theoretical concept because even if there
were no close substitutes, some kind of competition would always be there, such as a choice
between decorating a house or buying a car. However, even though pure monopolies are a
rare phenomenon in developed countries, they are found in developing countries like India
in the form of State monopolies e.g. the Mahanagar Telephone Nigam Ltd. (MTNL) and the
Post and Telegraph Department of the Government of India.
MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION
In the real world, market is neither perfectly competitive nor a monopoly. The great
majority of imperfectly competitive producers in the real world produce goods, which are
neither completely different nor completely same. They produce the goods, which are
similar to those produced by their rivals. This implies that the goods produced in the market
are close substitutes. It follows that such producers must always be concerned about the
manner in which the action of these rivals affects their own profits. This kind of market is
known as ‘monopolistic competition’ or group equilibrium. Here there is competition, which
is keen, though not perfect, between firms producing very similar products, for example
market for toothpaste, cosmetics, watches etc.
OLIGOPOLY
The type of market condition, which is realistic in present day economy, is oligopoly.
It is characterised by mutual interdependence among a few sellers who control the total
178
Managerial Economics
market supply. Oligopoly, therefore, occurs when there are only a few sellers. It differs from
both the monopoly and perfect competition and also from monopolist competition.
Oligopoly is a market where a small group of producers, have significant control over major
portion of the market demand, with or without differentiated product.
5.8 Self Assessment Test
Broad Questions:
1. What are the characteristics of perfect competition? What is the relative position of a
firm in a perfectly competitive industry? How does it choose its price and output?
2. Under what market conditions is a firm a price-taker. What would happen to a firm if it
becomes price-maker?
3. Write a note on “The Relationship between average revenue and marginal n under (i)
perfect competition and (ii) monopoly”.
4. For a profit maximising monopoly, price is greater than marginal cost and it n so over a
large range of output. Why does then a monopolist not produce when MC = MR?
5. A monopoly firm may earn normal or abnormal profits or may even incur in the shortrun. Do you agree with this statement? Give reasons for your answer.
Short Notes
a. Importance of AR, AC, MR and MC in determining firm equilibrium under perfect
competition.
b. Oligopoly and Price determination under Oligopoly
c. Differentiate between Monopoly and Monopolistic Competition
d. Price determination under Perfect competition for Long as well as short run.
e. Monopoly and types of Monopoly
5.9 Further Reading
1. A Modern Micro Economics, Koutsoyiannis, Macmillan, 1991
2. Business Economics, Adhikary, M,., Excel Books, New Delhi, 2000
3. Economics Theory and Operations Analysis, Baumol, W J., 3rd ed., Prentice Hall Inc, 1996
4. Economics Organisation and Management, Milgrom, P and Roberts J, Prentice Hall Inc,
Englewood Clitts, New Jersey, 1992
Managerial Economics
179
5. Managerial Economics, Chopra, O P., Tata McGraw Hill, New Delhi, 1985
6. Managerial Economics, Keat, Paul G and Philips K Y Young, Prentice Hall, New Jersey,
1996
7. Managerial Economics, Maheshwari, Yogesh, Sultanchand and Sons, 2009
8. Managerial Economics, Varshney, R L. Sultanchand and Sons, 2007
180
Managerial Economics
Assignment
Give two examples of each: Perfect Market, Monopoly, Monopolistic and Oligopoly Market
practiced in your area.
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
Managerial Economics
181
Glossary
Absolute advantage
A country has an absolute advantage if its output per
unit of input of all goods and services produced is
higher than that of another country.
Aggregate demand
is the sum of all demand in an economy. This can be
computed by adding the expenditure on consumer
goods and services, investment and not exports (total
exports minus total imports).
Aggregate supply
is the total value of the goods and services produced in
a country, plus the value of imported goods less the
value of exports.
Average total cost
is the sum of all the production costs divided by the
number of units produced.
Balance of Payment
is the summation of imports and exports made
between one country and the other countries with
which it carries out trade.
Balance of trade
The difference in value over a period between a
country's imports and exports
Barter system
System where there is an exchange of goods without
involving money
Break even
A term used to describe a point at which revenue
equals cost. (Fixed and variable)
Budget
It is a summary of intended expenditures along with
proposals for how to meet them. A budget can provide
guidelines for managing future investments and
expenses.
Budget deficit
The amount by which government spending exceeds
government revenues during a specified period of time
usually a year
Capital budget
It is a plan of proposed capital outlays and the means of
financing them for the current fiscal period. It is usually
a part of the current budget. If a capital program is in
182
Managerial Economics
operation, it will be the first year thereof. A capital
program is sometimes referred to as a capital budget.
Capital Budgeting
To make investment decisions that will maximise the
value of the firm
Capital
It refers to wealth in the form of money or property
owned by a person or business and human resources of
economic value. Capital is the contribution to
productive activity made by investment is physical
capital (machinery, factories, tools and equipments)
and human capital (eg general education, health).
Capital is one of the three main factors of production;
other two are labour and natural resources.
Cartel
An organisation of producers seeking to limit or
eliminate competition among its members, most often
by agreeing to restrict output to keep prices higher
than would occur under competitive conditions. Cartels
are inherently unstable because of the potential for
producers to defect from the agreement and capture
larger markets by selling at lower prices.
Centrally planned economy
A planned economic system in which the production,
pricing and distribution of goods and services are
determined by the government rather than market
forces is referred to as a planned economy or a 'non
market economy'. Former Soviet Union, China and
most other communist nations are examples of
centrally planed economy
Classical economics
The economics of Adam Smith, David Ricardo, Thomas
Malthus and later followers such as John Stuart Mill
The theory concentrated on the functioning of a market
economy, spelling out a rudimentary explanation of
consumer and producer behaviour in particular
markets and postulating that in the long term the
economy would tend to operate at full employment
Managerial Economics
183
because
increases
in
supply
would
create
corresponding increases in demand.
Closed economy
A closed economy is one in which there are no foreign
trade transactions or any other form of economic
contacts with the rest of the world.
Cost benefit analysis
A technique that assesses projects through a
comparison between their costs and benefits, including
social costs and benefits for an entire region or country.
Depending on the project objectives and its the
expected outputs, three types of CBA are generally
recognised: financial; economic; and social. Generally,
cost-benefit analyses are comparative, i.e. they are
used to compare alternative proposals. Cost-benefit
analysis compares the costs and benefits of the
situation with and without the project; the costs and
benefits are considered over the life of the project.
Cost-Volume-Profit-Analysis
It is the volume of output, which equates TR and TC.
Cross elasticity of demand
The change in the quantity demanded of one product
or service affecting the change in demand for another
product or service. E.g. percentage change in the
quantity demanded of a good divided by the
percentage change in the price of another good (a
substitute or complement)
Deflation
Deflation is a reduction in the level of national income
and output, usually accompanied by a fall in the general
price level.
Duopoly
A market structure in which two producers of a
commodity compete with each other
Econometrics
The application of statistical and mathematical
methods in the field of economics to test and quantify
economic theories and the solutions to economic
problems
Economic Cost
184
Explicit Cost + Implicit Cost
Managerial Economics
Economic development
The process of improving the quality of human life
through increasing per capita income, reducing poverty
and enhancing individual economic opportunities
It is also sometimes defined to include better
education, improved health and nutrition, conservation
of natural resources, a cleaner environment and a
richer cultural life.
Economic growth
An increase in the nation's capacity to produce goods
and services
Economic infrastructure
The underlying amount of physical and financial capital
embodied in roads, railways, waterways, airways and
other forms of transportation and communication plus
water supplies, financial institutions, electricity and
public services such as health and education. The level
of infrastructural development in a country is a crucial
factor determining the pace and diversity of economic
development.
Economic integration
The merging to various degrees of the economies and
economic policies of two or more countries in a given
region
Economic policy
A statement of objectives and the methods of achieving
these objectives (policy instruments) by government,
political party, business concern etc
Some examples of government economic objectives are
maintaining full employment, achieving a high rate of
economic growth, reducing income inequalities and
regional development inequalities and maintaining
price stability. Policy instruments include fiscal policy,
monetary and financial policy and legislative controls
(e.g., price and wage control, rent control).
Economic Profit
Total Revenue-Economic Cost
Economics of Scope
It occurs when the joint production cost is less than the
cost of producing multiple outputs separately.
Managerial Economics
185
Economics
The art of applying economic theory in business and
administrative decision making
Elasticity of demand
The degree to which consumer demand for a product
or service responds to a change in price, wage or other
independent variable
When there is no perceptible response, demand is said
to be inelastic.
Excess capacity
Volume or capacity over and above the required
amount, to meet peak planned or expected demand
Excess demand
Situation in which the quantity demanded at a given
price exceeds the quantity supplied- Opposite: excess
supply
Expected Value of Profit
It is the values of the profits weighed by the underlying
probability distribution.
Fixed costs
A cost incurred in the general operations of the
business that is not directly attributable to the costs of
producing goods and services. These 'fixed' or 'indirect'
costs of doing business will be incurred whether or not
any sales are made during the period, thus the
designation 'fixed', as opposed to 'variable'.
Gross domestic product (GDP)
Gross Domestic Product: The total of goods and
services produced by a nation over a given period,
usually 1 year
Gross Domestic Product measures the total output
from all the resources located in a country, wherever
the owners of the resources live.
Gross national product (GNP)
It is the value of all final goods and services produced
within a nation in a given year, and income earned by
its citizens abroad, minus income earned by foreigners
from domestic production. The fact book, following
current practice, uses GDP rather than GNP to measure
national production. However, the user must realise
186
Managerial Economics
that in certain countries net remittances from citizens
working abroad may be important to national well
being. GNP equals GDP plus net property income from
abroad.
Human capital Productive investments: Investments embodied in human persons. These
include skills, abilities, ideals and health resulting from
expenditures
on
education,
on-the-job
training
programs and medical care.
Imperfect competition
A market situation or structure in which producers have
some degree of control over the price of their product
e.g. monopoly and oligopoly
Imperfect market
A market where the theoretical assumptions of perfect
competition are violated by the existence of, for
example, a small number of buyers and sellers, barriers
to entry, non-homogeneity of products and incomplete
information
The three imperfect markets commonly analysed in
economic
theory
are
monopoly,
oligopoly
and
monopolistic competition.
Income inequality
The existence of disproportionate distribution of total
national income among households whereby the share
going to rich persons in a country is far greater than
that going to poorer persons (a situation common to
most LDCs). This is largely due to differences in income
derived from ownership of property and to a lesser
extent the result of differences in earned income.
Inequality of personal incomes can be reduced by
progressive income taxes and wealth taxes. This is
measured by the Gini coefficient.
Inflation
Percentage increase in the prices of goods and services
Internal Rate of Return
It is the discount rate, which equates the present value
of the expected cash flow to the initial cost of
investment.
Managerial Economics
187
International commodity agreement Formal agreement by sellers of a common
internationally traded commodity (coffee, sugar) to
coordinate supply to maintain price stability
International poverty line
An arbitrary international real income measure, usually
expressed in constant dollars (e.g., $270), used as a
basis for estimating the proportion of the world's
population that exists at bare levels of subsistence
Learning Curve
When knowledge gained, experience is used to improve
production techniques, which results in a decline in the
long-run average cost.
Long-run Cost
It is when the time is long enough to change all inputs
therefore all costs are variable.
Macroeconomics
The
branch
of
economics
that
considers
the
relationships among broad economic aggregates such
as
national
income,
total
volumes
of
saving,
investment, consumption expenditure, employment
and money supply. It is also concerned with
determinants of the magnitudes of these aggregates
and their rates of change over time.
Market economy
A free private-enterprise economy governed by
consumer sovereignty, a price system and the forces of
supply and demand
Market failure
A phenomenon that results from the existence of
market imperfections (e.g., monopoly power, lack of
factor mobility, significant externalities, lack of
knowledge) that weaken the functioning of a freemarket economy--it fails to realize its theoretical
beneficial results. Market failure often provides the
justification for government interference with the
working of the free market.
Market mechanism
The system whereby prices of stocks and shares,
commodities or services freely rise or fall, when the
buyer's demand rises or falls or the seller's supply of
them decreases or increases
188
Managerial Economics
Market prices
Prices established by demand and supply in a freemarket economy
Market-friendly approach
World Bank notion that successful development policy
requires governments to create an environment in
which markets can operate efficiently and to intervene
selectively in the economy in areas where the market is
inefficient (e.g., social and economic infrastructure,
investment coordination, economic 'safety net')
Microeconomics
The branch of economics concerned with individual
decision units--firms and households--and the way in
which their decisions interact to determine relative
prices of goods and factors of production and how
much of these will be bought and sold. The market is
the central concept in microeconomics.
Mixed economic systems
Economic systems that is a mixture of both capitalist
and socialist economies
Most developing countries have mixed systems. Their
essential feature is the coexistence of substantial
private and public activity within a single economy.
Monopoly
A market situation in which a product that does not
have close substitutes is being produced and sold by a
single seller.
Open economy
It is an economy that encourages foreign trade and has
extensive financial and nonfinancial contacts with the
rest of the world in areas such as education, culture
and technology.
Opportunity Cost
It is often known as implicit cost or non-cash cost. It is
the fore-gone cost associated with current next best
use of an asset.
The implied cost of not doing something that could
have led to higher returns.
Perfect competition
A market situation characterized by the existence of
very many buyers and sellers of homogeneous goods or
Managerial Economics
189
services with perfect knowledge and free entry so that
no single buyer or seller can influence the price of the
good or service
Political economy
The attempt to merge economic analysis with practical
politics- to view economic activity in its political context
Much of classical economics was political economy and
today
political
economy
is
increasingly
being
recognised as necessary for any realistic examination of
development problems.
Price elasticity of demand
The responsiveness of the quantity of a commodity
demanded to a change in its price, expressed as the
percentage change in quantity demanded divided by
the percentage change in price
Price elasticity of supply
The responsiveness of the quantity of a commodity
supplied to a change in its price, expressed as the
percentage change in quantity supplied divided by the
percentage change in price
Price
It is the monetary or real value of a resource,
commodity or service. The role of prices in a market
economy is to ration or allocate resources in
accordance with supply and demand; relative prices
should reflect the relative scarcity of different
resources, goods or services.
Revenue expenditure
This is expenditure on recurring items, including the
running of services and financing capital spending that
is paid for by borrowing. This is meant for normal
running of governments' maintenance expenditures,
interest payments, subsidies, transfers etc. It is current
expenditure, which does not result in the creation of
assets. Grants given to State governments or other
parties are also treated as revenue expenditure even if
some of the grants may be meant for creating assets.
Subsidy:
190
Financial
assistance
(often
from
the
Managerial Economics
government) to a specific group of producers or
consumers
Revenue receipts
Additions to assets that do not incur an obligation that
must be met at some future date and do not represent
exchanges of property for money Assets must be
available for expenditures. These include proceeds of
taxes and duties levied by the government, interest and
dividend on investments made by the government, fees
and other receipts for services rendered by the
government.
Short -run Cost
It is when the time is not enough to change all inputs;
therefore, costs are classified into fixed and variable
costs
Sunk Cost
The cost that does not change or vary across decision
alternatives
The Value of the Firm
The PV of the expected future net cash flows
discounted by the appropriate discount rate
Managerial Economics
191