October 2006
Volume 5 No.1
www.U4.no
April 2008 - No. 12
U4BRIEF
Political finance:
state control and civil society monitoring
Modern politics face the challenge of reconciling
the presence of money in politics with the risks it
poses to democratic values and good governance.
This U4 Brief describes the nature of common
risks and challenges, and looks at avenues for
mitigating the corruption-related problems with
political funding.
As election day approached, Mayor Sullivan asked Paul
for a significant contribution to support his re-election
campaign. He had done so last time. And Paul’s business
with the city had surged during Sullivan’s administration.
Sullivan promised Paul’s company would be rewarded
for the support. Paul had no doubt about that. In
fact, when facing problems with the administration in
the past (for not abiding by the quality standards he
had committed to in the contract he was awarded) a
phone call to Sullivan’s office sufficed to smooth out the
problems. But this time Paul was doubtful about the
elections. There was a realistic chance for the opposition
to win. Therefore, he decided to support the opposition
candidate, in addition to Sullivan. If cut off from the
government contracts, his company could not survive.
Since the sitting mayor would dislike double-crossing,
Paul insisted with Sullivan’s opponents to keep his
donation off the books.
The street where Jane grew up had lacked water and
electricity for as long as she could remember. While the
city administration never really cared, in election years
this scenario changed completely. Candidates regularly
had streets paved and promised more improvements once
elected. But that never occurred. The paving, however,
did not last much longer than a year, and the situation
would be the same the next election. Candidates also
had pharmacists hand out medicine or physicians treat
patients for free. If individuals or the private sector
financed this, jobs and contracts would be provided
after the election in compensation. And candidates who
themselves had invested part of their own assets to win
the election had miraculously become richer, forging a
political career from one office to the next.
These two cases, albeit fictitious, are illustrative of common
real practices related to political finance. However, political
finance is a necessary feature of political competition and
must not cause damage to democracy. Modern democracies
require resources to finance campaigns and party
organisations. To keep the system functioning, political
parties ideally resort to the engagement of party activists
and sympathisers. However, modern politics require a high
degree of professionalism in management. Many services
cannot be delivered by voluntary engagement. To cover the
costs of running modern party organisations, recruiting and
training new political leaders, and reaching out to voters in
election campaigns, parties and candidates typically resort
to considerable amounts of monetary and non-monetary
resources.1 Without these, free and informed competition
would not be sustainable.
Risks stemming from money in politics
While money is required to foster political competition, its
role in politics can undermine the tenets of democracy. Depending on where money comes from, how it is distributed
and what it is spent on, it can turn from a blessing into a
curse. Money can distort the electoral process as a result
of the source and distribution of funds, the management of
resources and expenses, as well as the motivation linked to
donations.
Risk no. 1: Distorting competition between
candidates
Where resources are unfairly distributed between candidates, the electoral contest may be distorted. Incumbent candidates may abuse state resources to fund their campaigns.
1 Political finance comes in a variety of partly overlapping
currencies – the three most notable include government resources
(unlawfully used to promote the re-election), financial support
from private donors, and, as the third and most recent currency,
political communication through media.
AntiCorruption
Resource
Centre
www.U4.no
Bruno Wilhelm Speck
Universidade Estadual
de Campinas, Brazil
Download this Brief from
U4.no/themes/political-corruption
This distorts political competition or ultimately blocks the
process of democratic alternation of leadership. Candidates
representing powerful economic interests may conduct sophisticated campaigns while their competitors who stand
for less well-off constituencies are cut off from communication with voters. Resources for electoral competition may
be pocketed by candidates, or campaign finance can be used
as a channel for money laundering.
Risk no. 2: Diminishing the role of citizens
Political finance might also be looked at from the citizens’
perspective. Campaign funds may be used for improper purposes like vote buying, thereby anaesthetising the critical
role of voters. Both corporate donations and state resources
can also crowd out the role citizens play in the political system. Individual citizens’ campaign contributions, as an expression of political participation, can hardly compete with
the substantial amounts of funding that private companies
are able to provide. The political class might also be able
to extract generous state funding for elections and parties
without the knowledge and consent of the citizenry.
Risk no. 3: Mining integrity of representation
Political finance also has an impact on policy making once
candidates take office. Private donors may require privileged treatment in return for donations. This could range
from tax exemptions and other donor-friendly measures,
to preferential treatment in public contracting processes. In
countries where foreign contributions are allowed or occur
de facto, political finance can have a distorting impact on
foreign policy. As such, political finance potentially affects
the direction and quality of public policies and whether
these respond to broader collective or rather specific private interests. If money becomes a primary channel for buying influence, poor communities will find themselves at the
loosing end. The direct impact of political finance on the
behaviour of officeholders is of course often difficult to assess. But the suspicion of undue influence has an impact on
the credibility of the system of representative democracy as
damaging as a proven causal relationship.
on fiscal responsibility.3 In addition, many countries with
a presidential regime have limited consecutive re-election of
the government in power.4 All these measures have not fully
eliminated the abuse of state resources, which continues to
distort elections in many countries. To some extent, the
advantage of officeholders is considered inevitable and
private campaign contributions are considered a necessary
means to counterbalance any such advantage. In fact,
in countries dominated by government parties, private
donations are often the only way to allow smaller parties
to gain presence.
Regulating private money
The role of private money, considered often as a prerequisite
for – as well as a risk to – democracy, has been addressed
by different regulatory tools, including bans and limits on
private finance, exclusion of undesirable sources, levelling
the amount of private donations and/or limiting the connection between candidates and donors. Similarly, some countries have set ceilings on the overall amount of campaign
costs, which immediately helps level the playing field, and
has collateral effects on other aspects of campaign finance.
In countries where some kind of regulation concerning the
role of private resources is in place, these regulations vary
from timid to more ambitious. At the same time, the ability
of state control to effectively force parties and donors into
abiding by these rules varies widely. A main challenge of reforming political finance regimes is to develop sound regulations to minimise the above-mentioned stemming from private donations. When moving from scenario A to D (graph
1), many countries get trapped in ineffective regulations due
to a lack of effective oversight (scenario B, e.g. Argentina).
Another risk is a deadlock of poor regulation due to lack of
Graph 1: Regulating political finance and performance of
state oversight
How have regulations addressed these
risks in the past?
Countries with a long democratic tradition have established
different sets of regulations. These are typically designed
to prevent the abuse of government resources to remain
in office and the damage to democracy caused by large
private donations, while ensuring fairness in how the media
influences political competition, and building independent
control agencies.
Abuse of state resources
Abuse of state resources has been tackled by prohibiting
the unilateral use of these, by building an independent
civil service and, more recently, by introducing specific
regulations constraining the spending leeway of governments
during election campaigns. The latter includes specific
rules on public procurement, employment of civil servants,
government advertising in election years,2 and general rules
2 See e.g. the New Zealand Auditor-General’s report on
Government and Parliamentary Publicity and Advertising, June
2005. Similar concerns have been brought forward in Australia.
In Canada, the civil society organisation Democracy Watch has
raised the issue and requests regulation: http://www.dwatch.ca
3 The following countries have introduced fiscal responsibility
laws: New Zealand, Sweden, Bulgaria, Estonia, Poland, United
Kingdom, Euro Area, Argentina, Chile, Peru, Brazil, Colombia,
Ecuador, India, and Venezuela (Kopits, 2007).
4 In a few countries (Mexico, Costa Rica) this rule extends to
the Legislature.
political will to reform (scenario C, e.g. Brazil). Both unrestrained influence of money on politics and a rule representing a mere facade cause political cynicism among citizens.
Public subsidies
Public subsidies and regulations guaranteeing free access to
services have been a widely cultivated approach for supporting parties in organising political competition and limiting
dependence on private funds. However, in most counties
the amount of public resources has not been able to effectively replace the role of private money. And even countries
spending considerable amounts of public resources to fund
parties and campaigns have not been spared from scandals.
The Flick Scandal in Germany and the Seat Scandal in Spain
unveiled that high public subsidies could at best mitigate,
but not ban, the risk of influencing political decisions by
political donations.
The media’s role in political competition
The regulation of media has been at the heart of many
reforms, focusing on the different roles of media as a
channel of information and a carrier of campaign ads.
While some countries trust freedom and pluralism to
produce a balanced role of media in political competition,
others opt for regulation, establishing rules for a balanced
approach in election campaigns. Regulation of its role in
political competition ranges from guaranteeing access to
advertising for political proselytism, levelling the playing
field by regulating the space and price for ads, to providing
free radio and TV time. Since TV ads are one of the most
expensive items of modern election campaigns, free airtime
as a form of indirect public subsidy has played an important
role in reducing the costs of, and the pressure to fundraise
for, political campaigns.5
State agencies controlling political finance
Finally, countries have regulatory state control bodies, often
autonomous agencies, vested with the power to investigate
and impose sanctions. Controlling political finance is a relatively recent practice, and even in established democracies,
after a century of political finance regulation, the role of
independent and effective state oversight has received recognition only in recent decades.6 While many independent
regulatory agencies were installed to guarantee free and fair
elections by managing the electoral process,7 new agencies
now often receive the additional task of monitoring the financial background of elections. Independence, technical
preparation for the job, sufficient resource allocation, as
well as ample legal investigative and sanctioning capacity
are prerequisites for achieving this task.
5 Countries that provide significant free airtime during elections
in combination with a ban on paid advertising are Brazil, Chile,
Mexico and Colombia.
6 In the United States, the Federal Election Commission was
introduced only in 1975.
7 In Central American countries like Guatemala and Panama,
the process of redemocratisation started with the building of
independent electoral agencies.
State control and social oversight
While political finance regulations have till now very much
focused on the regulatory capacity of laws and state oversight
bodies, social oversight has recently gained growing relevance.
In many countries, social control has developed into an
institution by its own right in recent decades. The efforts
of civil society organisations (CSO) and the press to engage
in the issue bear on different origins. First, organisations
involved in electoral observation have enlarged their scope
of attention. Recognising that campaign finance is a vital
aspect for assessing whether elections are free and fair,
international and national election observers have dedicated
more attention to this. Still, the focus is basically on the
impact on the electoral process, neglecting the aspect of
political finance between elections. In addition, organisations
dedicated to corruption control have discovered that many
corrupt deals originate from campaign finance schemes.
The central question for these organisations ought to be the
post electoral favours triggered by donations. However, in
practice, electoral and post-electoral risks linked to political
finance are intertwined.
What do civil society organisations do? The scope of civil
society organisations’ work in the area of political finance
has been documented recently.8 Examples of activities include voter education activities, whereby voters are alerted
to the long-term costs of vote buying and other forms of manipulating the electorate. An additional category of activities
focuses on informing voters about candidates and parties in
general, and if possible, political finance. In countries where
official data is scarce, CSOs resort to collecting this data
themselves. In other countries, they analyse, translate and
disseminate data on candidates in general and on election
finance.
Apart from informing voters, a handful of CSOs work with
parties, donors and state agencies. In Peru and Colombia,
CSOs have engaged in training political parties to abide by
political finance laws. In Brazil and Chile, non-governmental
actors have developed special projects informing corporate
donors about their rights and duties in campaign finance.
International initiatives have also called on companies to apply transparency standards regardless of the national law.
There are also efforts to convince candidates to voluntarily
disclose information on campaign finance.
Two fields of additional monitoring efforts concern the role
of media in elections and the use of government resources.
Media monitoring, either focusing on political advertising
or on balanced journalism, can reveal important aspects
of resource allocation, while equally shedding light on the
question of media neutrality.
Regarding abuse of government resources, this has always
been part of election monitoring efforts, focusing on the use
of official vehicles and mobilisation of servants in election
campaigns. However, recently, the focus of such observation
has been broadened to include monitoring the use of government advertising for political purposes.
8 Transparency International: Corruption fighters’ tool kit. Civil
society experiences and emerging strategies, Berlin, 2002; Open
Society Justice Initiative: Monitoring Election Campaign Finance.
A Handbook for NGOs. New York, 2005.
The relationship between state control and social
control has complementarities, but also competition and asynchronies. Complementarities prevail
where civil society organisations report misbehaviour, thus providing input to state control agencies, given the limited capacity of state agencies to
monitor extensively what happens on the ground.
This channel of information is vital where peer
review between parties comes to a halt due to a
pact of mutual protection among political contenders. Contrariwise, social oversight depends
on state control agencies. For social control to
happen efficiently, data on political finance needs
to be disclosed to the public. Depending on the
law and on how state control agencies implement
these rules, CSOs themselves can enhance their
role by ensuring that this information reaches the
public.
State control
Role
Guarantee compliance
with the law
Criteria
Law and regulations
Social oversight
Empower citizens to
support or reject parties
Oversee state control
Standards of behaviour
accepted by society
Investigative and sanction Uncover and denounce
misbehaviour
unacceptable political
finance links
Powers
Depending on reporting
of misbehaviour
Poor performance
Weakness
Depending on disclosure
Lacking awareness of
political finance
Political, civil, criminal
Protest and withdraw
sanctions
support
Hard
to
prove
causal
link
Corrupt links beReasonable doubt suffices
tween donations and
for withdrawal of politifavours
cal support
Sanctions
Reform debate
A key role of state agencies is guaranteeing compliance with the law by involving different actors
in the process of political finance. This includes
detecting transgressions, investigating the facts and sanctioning misbehaviour. The remaining challenge is that often
laws on political finance are too weak to prevent corruption, and state agencies’ powers to act are limited.
Social oversight follows a different logic. Besides reporting
misbehaviour to state agencies, social control aims to empower citizens to sanction political actors by withdrawing
support and manifesting discontent. Such empowerment requires informing citizens about political finance during the
electoral process. However, the legal framework for such
disclosure is still limited in most countries where the law
does not require concomitant rendering of accounts. Therefore, informing citizens may require independent data gathering by non-governmental organisations, or translating
public data into an accessible format. Empowering the citizenry also requires shaping social norms to achieve a better
understanding of what is acceptable behaviour. While state
control is bound to the laws in place, social control may
develop different behavioural standards. A party accepting
lawful political contributions from a particular industry
(e.g. timber, weapons, polluting industries) in contradiction
with the declared political priority (conservation, disarmament, and environment) may be punished by the voter for
this contradiction. This is an opportunity and a challenge
for social oversight.
When assessing the corruption risks of political donations
influencing elected officeholders, state agencies face the
challenge of providing proof for the causal link between a
political donation and a favour rendered. This connection
is difficult to establish. First, private donations per se are
mostly legal and, unlike bribes, the transfer itself does not
provide evidence for a corrupt deal. Second, time gaps between campaign contributions and a future favours from
elected officeholders make it difficult to establish causal
links between both actions. Finally, elected officeholders
have wide discretionary powers, and are not legally obliged
to give reasons for their decisions and answer to their voters. These factors make it hard to prove that the motivation
for a given decision results from a campaign contribution
rather than a public interest rationale.
Technical expertise
Defending the public
interest
Again, social control operates on a different logic. A reasonable doubt about the causal connection between donations
and retributions might be sufficient to activate mechanisms
of social sanctions. Since officeholders are answerable to the
citizenry, CSOs have a vital role in providing evidence on
how campaign finance might be linked to decisions by officeholders. A large donation by a company in combination
with an increased share of public contracts can well be sufficient for voters to withdraw support from the government.
CSOs also have a vital role in remedying the effects of legal shortcomings and weak state controls. If the state fails
to guarantee a rule of law, CSOs often take on a controlof-controllers role. E.g. confronting state agencies when
parties and candidates provide flawed data may force the
former into adopting a more proactive stance. State control
is often activated by criticism from civil society.
Equally, CSO’s are fundamental in promoting democratic
standards during legal reforms. Political parties working on
political finance legislation, are effectively regulating their
own activities, which is a conflict of interest situation. Thus,
the voice of independent experts, academia, technical expertise, and CSOs defending public interest is vital to the
debate on reforming political finance laws and regulations.
Social control and control by state agencies are interdependent spheres when it comes to transparency. Only a strong
state agency can enforce reporting and disclosure requirements. This includes collecting such information from parties and candidates, verifying its accuracy and guaranteeing
disclosure to the public in a user-friendly manner. The press
and civil society can collect information and confront oversight bodies with data. But this intermittent process cannot substitute the role of state agencies in collecting comprehensive datasets and scrutinising as well as sanctioning
non-compliance with the law. Hence, state control and civil
society require mutual support in areas where their roles are
intertwined, while in other areas recognising their complementarity.
Download this Brief from
www.U4.no/themes/political-corruption