This is the peer reviewed version of the following article: Goda, Thomas, Onaran, Ozlem and
Stockhammer, Engelbert (2017) Income inequality and wealth concentration in the recent crisis.
Development And Change, 48(1), pp. 3-27., which has been published in final form at
https://doi.org/10.1111/dech.12280. This article may be used for non-commercial purposes in
accordance with Wiley Terms and Conditions for Self-Archiving.
1
Income Inequality and Wealth Concentration in the Recent Crisis
Thomas Goda, Özlem Onaran and Engelbert Stockhammer
Published as:
Goda, T, Onaran, Ö, Stockhammer, E, 2016. Income inequality and wealth concentration in the recent crisis.
Development and Change 48(1): 3–27.
_____________________________________________________________________________
ABSTRACT
This article shows that the increase of income inequality and global wealth concentration was an
important driver for the financial and Eurozone crisis. The high levels of income inequality
resulted in balance of payment imbalances and growing debt levels. Rising wealth concentration
contributed to the crisis because the increasing asset demand from the rich played a key role in
the growth of the structured credit market and enabled poor and middle-income households to
accumulate increasing amounts of debt. This analysis thereby puts both income and wealth
inequality to the epicentre of the recent crisis, and is crucial for social scientists analysing the
causes of the crisis. Our findings suggest that the policy response to the crisis must not be limited
to financial regulation but has to involve policies to address inequality by increasing the
bargaining power of labour as well as redistributive tax policies.
________________________________________
We would like to thank Matt Vidal and three anonymous referees for their helpful comments.
Moreover, we are grateful to Photis Lysandrou without whom this article would not have been
possible. Engelbert Stockhammer acknowledges financial support from the INET project ‘Rising
inequality as a structural cause of the present financial and economic crisis’ (INO13-00012).
2
INTRODUCTION
Economic inequality has become a prominent topic in public debate after the publication of
Piketty’s (2014) book Capital in the Twenty-First Century. The last time that the topic reached
such a prominence was in the 1930s when it was widely accepted that inequality was a cause for
the Great Depression (Eccles, 1951; Galbraith, 1975). As a response policy makers of developed
countries increased top marginal income and wealth taxes sharply, regulated markets and
strengthened the social welfare system during the middle of the twentieth century. The result of
these policies, which went hand in hand with the post-war boom in OECD countries, was a sharp
decline in inequality levels.
During the 1970s falling profits created growing discontent with the economic status quo by
the ruling elite, which in turn contributed to a push towards neoliberal reforms so that most
regions in the world deregulated markets, strengthened corporate control and lowered personal
and corporate taxes, resulting in a deterioration in working conditions and labour’s bargaining
power and a polarization of income and wealth at levels not seen since the 1930s (Crotty, 2012;
Piketty, 2014; Vidal, 2013).
Authors like Stiglitz (2012), van Treeck (2014) and Kumhof et al. (2015) argue that rising
income inequality was a root cause for the rapid growth of the US non-prime mortgage market
and the global balance of payment imbalances that contributed to the Great Recession. Moreover,
Lysandrou (2011b), Milanovic (2011) and Goda and Lysandrou (2014) stress that the global rise
in the absolute concentration of wealth was an important contributing factor to the financial crisis,
because the growing demand from very rich individuals for investable securities was a major
driver behind the growth of the structured credit market.
This article shows that the integration of these two strands of research, which analyse distinct
transmission mechanisms of the contribution of inequality to the crisis, is important for a better
understanding of the mechanisms behind the crisis. We therefore extend the existing literature on
the complex relation between inequality and financial instability by integrating the analysis of
income inequality and wealth concentration and its effects on consumption and debt levels,
balance of payment imbalances, and financial innovation more thoroughly than in the previous
literature. The article is also distinct in that it analyses the financial crisis in the US as well as the
sovereign debt crisis in the Eurozone. The crisis in the Eurozone and the global financial crisis
typically are analysed in isolation, but we argue that they are interconnected. To be more precise,
3
we argue that the Eurozone crisis was triggered by the financial crisis, and that in the US as well
as in the Eurozone high levels of inequality contributed to balance of payment imbalances and
growing private debt levels.
We believe this analysis is crucial for social scientists with an interest in the social
consequences of the crisis (see e.g. Bassens et al., 2013; Fujita, 2011; Munoz Martinez and
Marois, 2014; Sidaway, 2008) in order to better understand how causes of the crisis are related to
income and wealth inequality. The mainstream economic analysis of the crisis has been narrow
and fails to incorporate socio-economic variables like inequality in their analysis (see Stiglitz,
2011 for an in-depth discussion). Instead, the mainstream focuses on the regulation of global
financial markets (e.g., Davies, 2010; Major, 2012), central bank policy failures (e.g., Taylor,
2009), market failures (e.g., Ashcraft and Schuermann, 2008) and irrational behaviour (e.g.,
Akerlof and Shiller, 2009). Our study, on the contrary, puts inequality to the epicentre of the
crisis and is an attempt to question neoliberal policies, which were the driving force behind the
rise in inequality and still dominate policies under the heading of the so-called structural reforms
since the crisis, despite their failure to generate growth (Stockhammer, 2015; Vidal, 2013). The
results of this analysis strongly suggest that the policy response to the crisis must not be limited
to financial regulation but needs to involve policies that increase the bargaining power of labour
as well as redistributive wealth taxation.
The next section shows how the financial crisis began in the market for subprime derivatives
and morphed into a financial crisis, an economic crisis and, in the Eurozone, in a sovereign debt
crisis. The third section clarifies why income inequality was a main ingredient for the emergence
of debt-driven and export-driven growth models, and an important reason behind the rise of
current account imbalances. The fourth section illustrates how global wealth concentration
contributed to these developments and argues that increasing wealth holdings at the top were a
crucial driver behind the securitization of (subprime) loans. The overall findings of the article
and policy recommendations are consolidated in section five.
FROM THE US SUBPRIME CRISIS TO THE EUROZONE CRISIS
In summer 2007 the market for certain structured financial securities completely broke down.
The reason for this was that the super senior tranches of collateralized debt obligations (CDOs)
4
started to suffer losses because of rapidly rising delinquency and foreclosure rates on US
subprime mortgages. The collapse of the entire CDO market, in turn, led to uncertainty and panic
in the global banking sector because the exact extent of the balance sheet risk exposure of
financial institutions was unclear (Acharya et al., 2011; Shin, 2012).
The subsequent breakdown in trust between large commercial banks (many of whom owned
or sponsored investment vehicles that were directly exposed to this market segment) set in
motion a liquidity-solvency crisis spiral, which in September 2008 culminated in the paralysis of
the whole financial system when the world’s third largest investment bank, Lehman Brothers,
declared bankruptcy and the insurance company American International Group (AIG) collapsed.
The following flight to safe securities caused a decline in the government bond yields, most
notably in the US, UK and Germany, and interbank lending literally stopped. The freezing of the
interbank market meant that banks started to hoard liquidity, with the result that most households
and firms lost access to credit.
The result was a global recession in 2008/09 and, subsequently, the Eurozone crisis that
started in 2010. One outcome of the financial crisis and the recession was that European
governments needed to rescue two types of banks: (i) banks that bought the toxic securities that
triggered the subprime crisis, and (ii) highly leveraged banks that had a maturity mismatch and
could not roll-over their debt. Another outcome was that government revenues declined while
welfare spending increased. Accordingly, public deficits and public debt grew sharply in nearly
all Eurozone countries. During 2008 and 2009 long-term government bond yields of these
countries declined or stayed roughly stable due to the flight to safety by investors. However, in
2010 this situation started to change because investors became concerned about a possible
default, leading to a rise in the refinancing costs for all countries. This increase in yields was
relatively minor and temporary in those countries that had export-surpluses, whereas the
periphery countries Greece, Ireland, Portugal and to a lesser extent Spain (GIPS) experienced a
longer-lasting increase in risk premia.
The GIPS have in common that they experienced the build-up of a real estate bubble, rapidly
increasing private debt and significant current account deficits (ranging from -2.1 per cent in the
5
case of Ireland1 to -9.2 per cent in the case of Portugal), which were financed by capital inflows
from the rest of the world. An outcome of the 2007 crisis was that their real estate bubbles burst,
which meant that some of their banks went into trouble and unemployment rates rose sharply
along with a deep recession. The resulting increase in government expenditure and decrease in
government revenue, coupled with their current account deficits, low growth perspectives and
relatively weak institutions, meant that investors increasingly feared that these countries would
not be able to collect sufficient funds to repay their rapidly accumulating debt. This fear
manifested in increasing sovereign risk premia. 2 The hike in interest rates made a bailout
programme necessary as the refinancing costs for GIPS became too high. The accompanying
austerity measures that were required from the European Commission, the European Central
Bank and the IMF were detrimental. They resulted in a decrease in domestic demand that
contributed to a sharp increase in unemployment, social unrest, a long economic depression and
a further rise in debt to GDP ratios.
This experience stands in stark contrast to that of current account surplus countries in the
Eurozone (Germany Austria, Belgium, Finland and Netherlands). These countries not only
produced more competitive export goods but their institutions also were perceived as being more
effective,3 so that investors were confident that they would have no problem to raise the revenues
necessary to repay their debt. Consequently, the demand for their bonds increased again in 2011,
driving down their sovereign debt costs to historically low levels. Most countries engaged in a
policy of modest fiscal stimulus during the recession 2008/09. But, while southern European
countries shifted to sharp austerity after 2010, the fiscal policy stance in northern countries was
rather neutral. This group of countries thus experienced a quick if shallow recovery from the
1
Ireland is different from the other GIPS countries in that the source of its current account deficits were
repatriated profits by multinational corporations and it had trade surpluses, although these deteriorated in
the 2000s.
2
An important reason for the sharp increase in the yields of Greek government bonds was that prior to the
crisis the Greek administration misreported budgetary data, which came out when the new government
presented a deficit that was more than twice as high as expected (Hoque, 2013). Portugal also had
persistent deficits prior to the crisis, while Ireland and Spain had budget surpluses and very low public
debt to GDP ratios in 2007 (25 per cent and 36 per cent respectively) that only increased sharply because
of the recession and the high costs of their banking bailouts (especially in Ireland).
3
According to World Bank’s Worldwide Governance Indicators (WGI) the Eurozone export surplus
countries on average had a perceived government effectiveness score of 1.8 points in 2010, whereas the
GIPS countries had an average score of 1.0. The GIPS country with the highest score was Ireland (1.3),
while Finland was the country with the best score among the export surplus countries (2.2). The indicator
reflects the views of firms, citizens and experts and has a maximum value of 2.5.
6
2009 recession, although initially they were hit hard by the recession as a result of the sharp
decline of their exports. This recovery was only short lived however, with the result that in 2013
the growth of both the current account surplus and the GIPS countries was either stagnating or
negative.
This analysis shows that the main cause for the Eurozone crisis was not the lack of fiscal
discipline in the periphery, as argued by many mainstream analysts (e.g. Costa and Ricciuti,
2013; Schuknecht et al., 2011), but rather the outcome of the loss in market confidence and the
recession triggered by the financial crisis in combination with the current account imbalances
within the region and the structural flaws of the European economic policy regime. It was the
design of the European Monetary Union (EMU) that led to an escalation of the Eurozone crisis.
The EMU has supported transnational capital flows rather than leaning against financial bubbles
and it has imposed fiscal austerity in countries in recession. Most importantly the ECB has been
mainly concerned with inflation targeting and reluctant to act as a lender of last resort for
member states (Arestis and Sawyer, 2011; Sawyer, 2013; Stockhammer, 2016a; Storm and
Naastepad, 2015c). Effectively, ECB support for national financial systems has been conditional
on specific fiscal policy measures. In the standoff with Greece in spring 2015 the ECB has, by
withdrawing liquidity support, effectively shut down a member state’s financial system in order
to enforce a certain fiscal policy stance. The goal of financial stability was subordinated to a
political agenda. The initial trigger of the Eurozone crisis thus was the banking crisis, the
following recession and the loss of confidence, while the causes of the crisis lie in the domestic
property bubbles and the imbalances that had built up prior to the crisis. The reasons why the
crisis deepened and turned into a sovereign debt crisis are to be found in the EMU’s policy
regime however.
A distinctive feature of the pre-crisis era was an increase in income inequality within
developed countries as well as a global increase in absolute wealth concentration (Goda, 2014;
Piketty, 2014). While it is widely acknowledged that distributional issues have to figure
somewhere in the plot of these events, the question arises if income inequality and wealth
concentration were at the very root of the recent crisis. The remainder of this article intends to
answer this question.
7
INCOME INEQUALITY AND DEBT- AND EXPORT-DRIVEN GROWTH
Since the 1980s, there has been a clear reversal of the trends towards relatively egalitarian
income distribution during the post-war era. On the one hand, there has been a significant decline
in the share of wages in GDP across the globe (OECD, 2012; Onaran and Galanis, 2014;
Stockhammer, 2015, 2016b). Figure 1 shows the adjusted wage share in national income in the
developed world.4 The share of wages has fallen by 10 percentage points in the Eurozone, and
even more in Japan. In parallel to this, in English-speaking countries a sharp polarization of
personal income distribution and a rise in the remuneration of top managers have occurred since
the 1980s (Atkinson et al., 2011).
[Figure 1]
As can be seen in Figure 2, the share of the top 1 per cent of the income distribution in the US
has reached 18 per cent of GDP prior to the crisis, exceeding the levels before World War I and
the Great Depression; the UK followed a similar pattern. Since managerial wages are part of
wages, this has led to a more modest decline in the wage share in the US and the UK compared
to continental Europe. Top income shares did not experience the same surge in continental
Europe. In the case of Germany this can be explained partly by the fact that many companies
retained large parts of their rising profits (Behringer et al., 2014). Nevertheless, similar to the US
and the UK in Germany also a significant low wage segment emerged (Vidal, 2013).
Nevertheless, whether the rise in personal income inequality was caused by a rise in top incomes
or the generation of a low wage sector, in all the countries a trend towards greater inequality in
personal income distribution went along with a fall in the wage share.5
[Figure 2]
4
Wages are adjusted labour compensation (real compensation per employee multiplied by total
employment).
5
These developments are in line with a global trend of rising income inequality within countries, ‘about
80 per cent of the world’s population now lives in regions whose median country has a Gini close to 40’
(Palma, 2011: 87).
8
A fall in the wage share reflects falling unit labour costs, and increasing profitability.
Mainstream economic policy, informed by neoclassical economics, thus expects the decline in
the wage share to be associated with stronger growth and employment. However, since 1980
growth has not been particularly strong in developed countries, which is a puzzle for mainstream
economics. Post-Keynesian/Post-Kaleckian models6 suggest that wages have not only a role as
cost item but also as a source of demand. To be more precise, a rise in inequality in the form of a
fall in the share of wages will, other things being equal, suppress domestic consumption since the
marginal propensity to consume out of wages is higher than that out of profits. However, it may
also have a positive effect on investment due to increased profitability, and improved
international competitiveness might lead to higher net exports due to lower unit labour costs. In
order to assess the effects of wage moderation it is necessary to address the effects on all three
components of private demand. If the differentials in marginal propensity to consume between
wages and profits is relatively large, but the responsiveness of investment to profitability and net
exports to relative price changes are low, then the total effect of the increase in the profit share
on aggregate demand and hence growth would be negative, and the demand regime is called
wage-led. If the effect is positive, it is called profit-led. The question whether the negative effect
of lower wages on consumption or the positive effect on investment and net exports is larger is
an empirical issue.
Empirical research that has been conducted in an attempt to identify these opposite effects
(e.g. Hein and Vogel, 2008; Naastepad and Storm, 2006; Onaran and Galanis, 2014;
Stockhammer et al., 2009) suggests three important findings: firstly, consumption reacts more
sensitively to a decrease in the wage share than does investment, hence domestic demand
(consumption and investment) is wage-led in all countries. The character of the demand and
growth regimes thus depends crucially on the relevance of the net export effects. Secondly, the
effects via the international trade channel depend on the elasticity of exports and imports to
prices and labour costs as well as the degree of trade openness. Relatively closed large
6
Post-Keynesian economics builds on Keynesian theory of effective demand. It deviates from
mainstream Keynesianism in that it regards Keynes’ work as break with the neoclassical traditions. In
particular post-Keynesians reject the need for micro foundations and the marginal productivity theory of
income distribution. It often uses class analysis as a foundation of macroeconomic analysis. See Bhaduri
and Marglin (1990) and Lavoie (2009).
9
economies (like the US and Germany) tend to be wage-led as opposed to relatively small open
economies, where net exports may play a major role in determining the overall outcome. Thirdly,
in a large region like the Eurozone or in the current state of high international integration in the
world economy the international competitiveness effects of declining wage shares are eliminated
when the fall in the wage share takes place simultaneously across all countries.
The expected outcome of the race to the bottom in the wage share in Europe and in the global
economy since the 1980s should, therefore, have been a stagnation of global demand and growth.
So how did the world economy or individual countries manage to grow prior to the Great
Recession? Stagnation in demand was circumvented by two distinct growth models: (i) a debtdriven growth model in the US, UK, Australia in the core and in the periphery in the GIPS and
Eastern Europe; and (ii) an export-driven growth model in Germany, Austria and Japan in the
core. The debt-driven and the export-driven growth models are complementary in that the
export-driven growth regimes can pursue mercantilist models only in the presence of debt-driven
deficit countries. Hence both rely on increasing accumulation of debt, and they are both equally
fragile reflecting the global imbalances that have grown dramatically in the 2000s; the
unsustainability of these global imbalances became evident in the aftermath of the Great
Recession.
At the root of both models lie different ways to react to the same chronic domestic demand
deficiency due to declining wage shares. The way different countries dealt with this potential
crisis of demand depended on their structural parameters regarding their position in the global
value chains, history of industrial policies, employment relations and differences in
financialization. Financial deregulation of the 1980s and the role of the financial industry were
strongest in the US and the UK. In the periphery of Europe, European integration and the
liberalization of capital flows were determining factors in making debt-driven growth feasible.
International financial deregulation made persistent long-term current account imbalances in
the debt-driven growth regimes feasible without major currency adjustments, which were in
return financed by capital inflows from the export-driven countries with persistent current
account surpluses. In 2007 Germany had a current account surplus of 7.5 per cent of GDP, while
the US had a deficit of 5.1 per cent. Exchange rates were not adjusting to trade imbalances but
were determined by capital flows chasing financial return. International financial liberalization
has thus created the conditions for debt-driven and export-driven growth models to co-exist for
10
extended periods as long as the financial investors find the debt situation in the debt-driven
growth models sustainable.
As discussed in section two, within the Eurozone itself, the crisis laid bare former
divergences caused by the process of monetary union. Productivity and production structures did
not converge, and although inflation rates came down in all countries, the countries that had low
inflation prior to the Euro also had lower inflation afterwards, which led to the increasing
divergence of nominal unit labour costs (Stockhammer and Onaran, 2012). In conjunction with
differences in technological competitiveness and an economic boom built on rising property
prices and household debt, this resulted in sizable current account disequilibria across the
Eurozone.7 Accordingly, the southern and eastern periphery of Europe has experienced massive
capital inflows for more than a decade from the trade surplus countries (most of all Germany),
which has financed debt-driven spending and resulted in the accumulation of massive external
liabilities in the trade deficit countries.
In Greece it was mostly the government sector that accumulated debt, in Ireland, Portugal
and Spain it was rather the private sector, and in particular the household sector (Lapavitsas et al.,
2010): between 2000 and 2008 private household debt to GDP ratios increased by 62, 21 and 33
percentage points in Ireland, Portugal and Spain respectively, whereas it shrank in Germany by
11 percentage points (Stockhammer, 2015, 2016a). In the debt-driven countries, growth driven
by increasing debt, financed by capital inflows led to asset and/or property price bubbles, which
fuelled the increase in debt via equity withdrawals. In the export-driven countries, on the
contrary, net exports have provided the main driving force for demand. In the extreme case of
Germany, three quarters of GDP growth has been driven by net exports since 2000
(Stockhammer and Onaran, 2012).
To what extent does our argument differ from the existing literature? To begin with, most
mainstream economics regards the crisis foremost as a financial issue (e.g. Blanchard, 2009;
Brunnermeier, 2009; Roubini and Mihm, 2010), while distributional considerations are often
disregarded. There are some exceptions though. Rajan (2010) contends that skill-biased
technological change increased permanent inequality in the US, and induced the US government
to encourage credit growth in general and the subprime mortgage market in particular so as to
7
Storm and Naastepad (2015a; 2015b) argue that the debt-based spending boom and the low
technological competitiveness of peripheral Eurozone countries were more important in explaining these
disequilibria than unit labour cost differences.
11
expand consumption. Stiglitz (2009, 2012) also argues that aggregate demand would have been
insufficient without a rise in private debt levels that ‘fuelled a consumption boom that allowed
Americans to live beyond their means’ (Stiglitz, 2012: 54). In contrast to Rajan, for Stiglitz the
main reasons for this situation were that poor and middle-income households tried to keep up
with the richer parts of the society, and that rent seeking led to market distortions.
Kumhof and Ranciere (2010) and Kumhof et al. (2015) develop a dynamic stochastic general
equilibrium (DSGE) model with investors and workers, in which an increase in inequality results
in rising debt of workers that is financed from savings from investors. As workers become overindebted, the number of defaults increases, and a financial crisis emerges. A shortcoming of this
model is that it does not involve asset and property price bubbles and that lending is solely
driven by savings. In none of these mainstream contributions are the emergence of different
growth regimes and the role of inequality in contributing to balance of payment imbalances
central. The only exception is Kumhof et al. (2012), who extend the Kumhof and Ranciere (2010)
model to a two-country case where the rich population in countries with less developed financial
markets finances the rising debt of the poor population in countries with more developed
financial markets. However, they do not analyse the imbalances within the Eurozone, and,
specifically, they do not explain why countries with highly developed financial markets (like
Germany) also have financed the poor population in other countries.
The same is true for Fitoussi and Saraceno (2010), who argue that rising income inequality
depressed aggregate demand in both the US and in Europe. However, the increase in inequality
was accompanied by above potential growth rates in the US and UK as opposed to sluggish
growth rates in most continental European countries. These growth differences are explained by
the fact that financial deregulation increased the ability of US, UK and Spanish households to
indebt themselves, while this was not so easily possible for German, French and Italian
households. Moreover, the authors state that the relatively unsuccessful German export-driven
growth strategy (in terms of growth) can be explained by the more expansionary fiscal policy in
the US.
Among Post-Keynesian and Marxian economists the issue of income distribution has
featured more prominently. Two notable Post-Keynesian analyses are Palma (2009) and
Galbraith (2012). Palma discusses in detail the pre-crisis income polarization in the US, and he
argues that a crucial reason behind the crisis was that neoliberalism reduced the pressure for
12
large companies to engage in competitive struggles in the real economy so that rent seeking
intensified which, in turn, destabilized the system. Galbraith’s contribution mainly focusses on
pay disparities across industries and regions, and their contribution to global income inequality
trends during the last 30 years. Moreover, he argues that finance is an important factor to explain
these disparities and he claims, in line with Rajan (2010: 293), that ‘the Bush administration
launched the “ownership society”, overtly encouraging massive expansion of lending to weak
credits, and relaxing the regulatory standards that had previously protected credit quality in this
area. Before too long, the subprime boom was under way’.
Several other heterodox authors ― like Foster and Magdoff (2009), Hein (2012), Palley
(2012), Cynamon and Fazzari (2013) and van Treeck (2014) ― have offered analyses that
substantially overlap with ours. They show that prior to the crisis a structural demand gap in the
US, due to the fact that wages were increasing more slowly than productivity, was hidden by the
growth of the financial sector and increasing household debt of the bottom 95 per cent.8 While
this debt-driven consumption allowed the US to grow prior to the crisis, the demand impact
turned negative after the crisis when the bottom 95 per cent of households could no longer
finance their consumption with debt.9 As a result growth rates are now well below their pre-crisis
trends in the US (Cynamon and Fazzari, 2015; Palley, 2016). 10 Foster and Magdoff (2009),
Palley (2012) and van Treeck (2014) also stress that the debt-driven growth model led to a large
current account deficit in the US, and Behringer and van Treeck (2013) argue that rising top
income shares had similar effects in countries like the UK and Italy. The work of Hein (2012)
and Hein and Mundt (2012) are closest to ours. Both identify rising inequality, rising household
debt, global imbalances and financial deregulation as the main causes of the crisis; and they
distinguish between debt-driven and export-driven regimes.
8
Barba and Pivetti (2009), Hein (2012) and van Treeck (2014) argue that US households increased their
debt to keep up their consumption with richer parts of the population (the so called ‘keeping up with the
Joneses’ effect)
9
One reason why this debt-driven growth was no longer possible was a sharp decrease in the wealth of
poor and middle income households. Wolff (2012) shows that between 2007 and 2010 median household
wealth in the US nearly halved.
10
A study by Cripps et al. (2011), using a stock-flow consistent (SFC) model, furthermore suggests that
under the current conditions the pattern of underconsumption in some countries and over-borrowing in
other countries will prevail, with the outcome that it is likely that global imbalances and crises will reemerge.
13
In contrast to this analysis, most of the Marxist literature concentrates on overproduction (a
surplus of capital and lack of investment opportunities), rarely distinguishes between different
growth regimes and mainly focuses on US developments. Exceptions are Brenner (2009),
Dumenil and Levy (2011), Lim and Khor (2011) and Vidal (2013) who discuss international
imbalances and acknowledge debt-driven growth. A common shortcoming of this research is that
imbalances within the Eurozone are not discussed in relation to inequality.11 Moreover, these
studies mainly concentrate on demand formation in the real sector but do not analyse the impact
of wealth distribution and demand formation in the financial market in depth, to which we turn in
the next section.
GLOBAL WEALTH CONCENTRATION AND ASSET MARKETS
Prior to the current crisis, not only functional and personal income inequality but also the extent
of wealth accumulation at the top increased dramatically. Wealth concentration can be measured
in relative and absolute terms. Relative wealth concentration refers to the possession of
disproportionate shares of wealth at the top. It is well documented that relative wealth
concentration is normally higher than relative income concentration, and that the trend changes
in top wealth shares (Figure 3) have been to some extent similar to that of top income shares
(Figure 2). After the First World War the extreme top wealth shares in Europe and the US
decreased significantly, while they started to increase again from the late 1970s onwards. There
exists very little data for countries from other regions but estimates suggest that within inequality
has increased in most countries during the 2000s and that the global top 1 per cent share
currently is around 46 per cent of total global wealth (Goda, 2014).
[Figure 3]
In order to analyse the effect of wealth concentration on financial investment demand, it is
important to consider changes in the absolute amount of global wealth holdings at the top of the
11
Lapavitsas et al. (2010) emphasize the structural contradictions of the Euro as a single currency to
explain the imbalances; their focus is not on inequality as a root cause of the sovereign debt crisis.
14
wealth distribution. The amount of absolute wealth holdings is important insofar as it determines
how much financial investment demand the wealthy people have, and the global pool rather than
wealth in a single country in isolation is the relevant indicator as financial capital is highly
mobile. Unfortunately, ‘official publications do not report estimates of absolute inequality’
(Atkinson and Brandolini, 2010: 3). However, some private wealth reports provide estimates of
the amount of global wealth holdings of those individuals who have a net worth of at least US$1
million (primary residency excluded) — so-called high net worth individuals (HNWIs).
According to these reports, between 1986 and 2012 HNWIs’ wealth increased 6.6-fold —
from US$ 7.2 trillion to US$ 46.2 trillion — and billionaires’ wealth even more than 15-fold.12
The increase in absolute wealth concentration was especially steep in the years prior to the crisis.
HNWIs’ net wealth increased more than 1.5-fold between 2002 and 2007, from US$ 26.7 to
US$ 41 trillion, while the global wealth holdings of billionaires increased 2.3-fold to US$ 3.5
trillion. This growth can be explained partly by the growth of the HNWI population (from 7.3
million to 10.1 million individuals) and partly by the increase of the mean wealth per HNWI
(from US$ 3.66 million to US$ 4.03 million). The tremendous growth in wealth holdings at the
top means that Rockefeller today would not be within the top 20 of the global billionaires list and
that at the end of 2012 the four wealthiest men — Slim, Gates, Ortega and Buffet — were more
than twice as rich as Rockefeller was in 1937 (Goda, 2014).
One reason for this increase of absolute wealth holdings of HNWIs was an increase in top
incomes (Saez and Zucman, 2014). Personal income inequality and wealth concentration tend to
be self-reinforcing because high income households save a higher proportion of their income and
‘wealth has a substantial impact on the share of income earned by those in the top 0.5 percent of
the [adjusted gross income] distribution’ (Tuttle and Gauger, 2006: 506). Another reason for this
exceptional increase in wealth concentration was the sharp increase in global stock market prices
and real estate values, since increasing asset prices automatically translate into higher wealth
holdings of their owners, who mainly belong to the richest segment of the population (Wolff,
2010, 2012).13
12
During the same period global GDP only increased 4.8-fold in current terms.
In the US, ‘between 1983 and 2010, the top one percent received 38 percent of the total growth in net
worth, 41 percent of the total growth in non-home wealth, and 39 percent of the total increase in income.
The figures for the top 20 percent are 101 percent, 100 percent, and 104 percent, respectively–that is to
say, the upper quintile got it all!’ (Wolff, 2012: 44).
13
15
In contrast to income inequality, few studies discuss possible economic effects of the
increase in absolute wealth accumulation at the top. Froud et al. (2001) argue that household
savings from the richer parts of the US and UK society are increasingly invested in existing
financial securities rather than the real sector. The result is that companies cannot generate
enough returns to satisfy investors’ profit expectations. This ‘symptom of low returns’ forces
companies (i) to divert their activities into areas with higher returns, and (ii) to boost their share
prices, both of which lead to a ‘coupon type of capitalism’ in which the financial sector becomes
more and more important and stock market bubbles are building up. Similarly, Wisman and
Baker (2011) and Wisman (2013: 922) claim that by ‘seeking profitable outlets for its
dramatically increased income and wealth, the elite fuelled first a stock market boom and then,
after the high-tech bubble burst, a real-estate boom’ in the US.
Indeed, between 1997 and 2007 increasing global wealth holdings went hand in hand with a
sharp increase in stock market and housing prices in the US and the Eurozone. The fact that
global wealth holdings were increasing continuously and to a stronger degree than the asset
prices in the US and Eurozone is consistent with the view that the former were driven by the
latter (Figure 4). The resulting price rally in stock and real estate markets, in turn, contributed to
the existence of the above discussed debt-driven growth regime in the US, the UK and GIPS
countries as they provided greater collateral to low- and middle-income households, which
enabled them to accumulate increasing debt.
[Figure 4]
Political economists also have acknowledged that the toxic securities that triggered the crisis
were partly created because ‘there is a growing “wall of money” facing global financial markets
that is looking for investment opportunities’ (Engelen et al., 2010: 47), which means that the
crisis ‘is also a story of the financialization of consumer credit networks [that enabled] lenders of
all kinds to generate new assets’ (Langley, 2008: 136–37). However, in these discussions wealth
concentration normally is not mentioned but instead emphasis is laid on rising asset demand
from institutional investors, governments and sovereign wealth funds. This is a shortcoming,
given that the asset demand from the rich was higher than that of institutional investors. In 2007
16
HNWIs had more asset under management (US$ 41 trillion) than global pension funds (US$ 28
trillion), mutual funds (US$ 26 trillion) and insurance companies (US$ 20 trillion) (IFSL, 2008).
Milanovic (2011), Wisman (2013) and Foster and Magdoff (2009) partially address this
shortcoming, although in a different manner. Milanovic states that ‘[h]igh-net-worth individuals
and the financial sector were … keen to find new lending opportunities’ (2011: 195) to overcome
a shortage of investment opportunities. Wisman (2013: 940) argues that ‘investment funds were
being switched from production to speculation, which stimulated innovations in credit
instruments’. Foster and Magdoff (2009: 61) affirm that ‘the redistribution of wealth upward
(through reduced taxes and reductions in social services) ― the results of class war waged
unilaterally from above ― have not been enough to guarantee an ever-increasing spiral of return
on capital invested in the productive economy. Thus, continual recourse to new forms of
gambling, not production of goods or services, is what capital is generating in the pursuit of
profit’. However, these authors do not provide concrete evidence for these claims nor do they
specify a concrete transmission mechanism between wealth accumulation and the production of
structured securities.
Lysandrou (2011a, 2011b) is the first author to present data and theorize the link between the
increase in absolute wealth concentration and CDO production in more detail. His innovative
argument is that the increasing net wealth from HNWIs led to an increasing demand for financial
products (rather than material goods). This demand, in turn, motivated banks to engage in
financial innovation to overcome a global shortage of investable securities. To alleviate this
shortage the market for asset backed securities (ABS) and CDOs was rapidly expanded. A
shortcoming of Lysandrou’s work is that he does not provide strong empirical evidence for his
claim (especially regarding causation). To give credibility to this theory it needs to be shown that
(i) one driving force behind the mortgage securitization growth was a fall in the yield of
traditional debt securities, (ii) HNWIs contributed to this fall and (iii) these individuals also
created a demand pressure for CDOs.
Evidence regarding the first point has been provided by Caballero et al. (2008), Bernanke
(2011), and Goda et al. (2013). Especially after 2000 many emerging market economies (EMEs)
were experiencing high growth rates, but their debt security market could not keep up with this
development. EMEs’ bond markets stayed ‘underdeveloped’; at the end of 2007 the EMEs’ share
in global GDP was one-third whereas their share in world debt security markets was only ten per
17
cent (IMF, 2008). Due to this global mismatch investors were increasingly ‘forced’ to invest in
the US where most financial assets are produced (Caballero and Krishnamurthy, 2009). The
resulting capital inflows not only helped to finance the debt-driven growth model of the US, but
also led to the phenomena that the supply of traditional investment grade debt securities could
not keep up with the growing global demand for these securities. Government purchases from
export surplus countries like China lowered long-term yields of US Treasury and agency bonds,
while foreign and domestic private investor demand reduced US agency, corporate, and
municipal bonds yields (Bernanke, 2011; Bertaut et al., 2012; Goda et al., 2013).14 The depressed
yields, in turn, led to a search for alternative debt securities with a higher yield. An excess safe
asset demand on the part of investors was thus a chief force that drove the expansion of the US
CDO market (Goda et al., 2013).
But, in how far were HNWIs from the US and the rest of the world involved in this global
excess demand? To answer this question, Goda and Lysandrou (2014) estimate the size of
HNWIs’ US bonds holdings and their involvement in the demand pressure, and find that more
than half of HNWIs’ wealth is comprised of financial securities of which around half is
comprised of debt securities. Moreover, HNWIs bond holdings are heavily skewed towards the
US market which is by far the biggest and most liquid market in the world. The rise in HNWIs’
wealth holdings thus meant that HNWIs from the US and the rest of the world increased their
total holdings of US bonds by around 40 per cent between mid-2004 (US$ 2.1 trillion) and mid2007 (US$ 2.9 trillion).15 The rise in HNWIs bond holdings meant that very rich individuals
significantly depressed long-term bond yields in the US (Goda and Lysandrou, 2014). This result
suggests that HNWIs significantly contributed to the above mentioned shortage of traditional
14
Bernanke (2005, 2011) and Bertaut et al. (2012) argue that the US bond demand was mainly driven by
‘excess’ savings in emerging markets, but also by changing portfolio preferences in European countries.
We have two issues with this argument. First, theoretically it is based on a loanable funds interpretation of
financial markets where savings are invested. This contrasts with a Keynesian view, where finance and
credit (rather than saving) are the key for explaining capital flows (e.g. Borio and Disyatat, 2011). Second,
Goda et al. (2013) show that the demand from private US investors also increased substantially and partly
explain the depressed yields of AAA-rated agency, municipal and corporate bonds.
15
Goda and Lysandrou (2014) estimate that around 60 per cent of US individual bond holdings were held
by US HNWIs prior to the crisis, while 20 per cent to 30 per cent of foreign private bond holdings
stemmed from rest of the world HNWIs. Different estimates by Hager (2014) confirm that US bond
holdings are concentrated in the hands of the top 1 per cent of the population.
18
debt securities, which triggered a ‘search for yield’ by all global investors that helped to
encourage the demand for CDOs.16
As regards the third point it has to be shown that HNWIs also were involved in the demand
pressure for CDOs. Rich investors were not directly involved in this market, but indirectly via
hedge funds, which held nearly half of all issued CDOs by June 2007 (Blundell-Wignall, 2007).
The absence of rich individuals’ direct involvement most likely can be explained by the complex
nature of CDOs,17 whereas the dominant position of hedge funds can be mainly explained by two
factors: (i) the exceptional growth of this industry, 18 and (ii) the pressure that they faced to
generate above average yields by the investors whose funds were managed by the hedge funds
(Lysandrou, 2012). An important driver behind this growth and pressure was the increasing
investment of HNWIs, who increased their hedge fund assets approximately from US$ 500
billion to US$ 1.1 trillion between 2002 and 2007 (Goda and Lysandrou, 2014).
Hedge fund managers were content with their growing asset base, but it also provided them
with a problem. To maximize returns hedge funds rely on leverage, and to get access to cheap
credits they need to provide investment grade collateral to banks. Given that investment grade
bonds had historically low yields, hedge funds needed to find an alternative that was accepted by
banks and at the same time kept borrowing costs to a minimum. CDOs were the solution to this
problem. Their senior tranches could be used as collateral that gave a decent return, while their
equity tranches were seen as high yielding investment opportunity whose risk could be
controlled by using put options and credit default swaps.19 This strategy allowed hedge funds to
16
Around 70 per cent of all CDO tranches were investment grade, but although they had the same rating
as investment grade bonds their structure allowed them to provide better returns than these securities. The
underlying assets of CDOS were mainly low-rated ABS tranches (and non-investment grade loans and
bonds), which provided relatively high cash flows. The reason why most CDO tranches received
investment grade, despite the bad rating of their collateral, was the bundling of different assets from
different originators and the (wrong) assumption that debtors have independent default probabilities ―
see Blundell-Wignall (2007) and Coval et al. (2009) for more details.
17
An owner of ordinary debt securities can easily find out how risky the investment is and in how far the
risk of default changes over time. The same is true for ABS investors as the backing collateral also
consists of a single, homogenous class of assets. CDOs, by contrast, do not meet this transparency
criterion as they are backed by many different types of asset classes (in their simplest form a CDO is an
asset backed security consisting of many ABS). That is why each CDO’s price is negotiated over the
counter by the seller and the buyer, i.e. CDOs have no standard prices.
18
Hedge funds’ assets under management more than tripled during 2002–07, reaching US$ 2.2 trillion in
2007.
19
Put options enabled hedge funds to sell an equity tranche at a specified date at a specified price. Credit
default swaps gave hedge funds the right to be compensated in the case of default.
19
generate an above average return for their clients and high bonus payments for themselves, and
at the same time generated demand for banks to supply increasing amounts of CDOs. This
analysis suggests that the historically high level of absolute wealth concentration is crucial to
explain why the CDO market reached a size that was sufficiently large to endanger the global
financial system when it collapsed in August 2007. Our analysis of the effects of wealth
concentration on financial markets has focussed on the USA. This reflects the state of available
research. As of yet there are no studies that would investigate the impact of HNWI wealth
holdings on real estate prices and sovereign debt yields for European countries. This would be an
important area for future research.
CONCLUSIONS
Our analysis demonstrates that it is crucial to take both income and wealth inequality equally
into account to grasp the complex relationship between inequality and financial stability, and to
show that the financial crisis and the Eurozone crisis are interconnected. Figure 5 summarizes
our argument.
[Figure 5]
Rising income inequality has led to potentially stagnant demand, because the world economy
overall is in a wage-led demand regime. In neoliberalism this has been overcome via either debtdriven or export-driven growth models. The debt-driven growth model relied on asset and
property bubbles to generate credit that ultimately fuelled consumption. This allowed working
class households in OECD countries to maintain growing consumption while their incomes
stagnated (in particular in the US and the UK). These countries usually had large current account
deficits and effectively played the role of a growth engine of the world economy. The exportdriven growth model had stagnant domestic demand and used net export growth as the source of
demand growth. Both growth models are intrinsically unstable, since they both rely on increasing
debt to income ratios. In the debt-driven model household debt has risen to allow for growth.
However, the export-driven growth model also relies on rising debt, but it is not domestic debt,
but rising foreign debt of its trade partners. The debt-driven and export-driven growth models are
20
thus complementary and they have resulted in rising household debt, international imbalances
and rising international debt.
Global wealth concentration played an important role in providing the finance for these
unstable growth regimes. Rich households (or their trusts) save differently from working class
households: they save a higher share of their income and hold riskier assets. The superrich, or
more technically, HNWIs, played a crucial role in that (i) their increasing asset demand helped to
lower the yield of traditional bond classes, which put pressure on investors to seek alternative
investment grade fixed income securities that provided higher yields, and (ii) HNWIs were the
main investors in hedge funds, which, in turn, were the main buyers of CDOs. HNWIs thus
helped to create the institutions that aggressively developed new financial instruments and,
ultimately, they provided the funding for subprime loans and growing credit more broadly.
Economic inequality thus played a crucial role on both the supply and demand sides of the
market of the toxic securities that were at the epicentre of the financial crisis. While this has been
documented for the USA, the literature has yet to establish how the growing asset demand of
HNWIs has affected the stock market and housing prices in the Eurozone and to what extent they
enabled low- and middle-income households in debt-driven Eurozone countries to accumulate
debt. The banking crisis, recession and the loss of confidence that followed the subprime crisis
laid bare the unsustainability of this growth model and showed that economic inequality was a
crucial contributing factor not only for the crisis.
Many elements of our argument can be found in the literature. In particular the link between
income inequality and rising household debt has become widely accepted among many postKeynesians and, to a lesser extent, by Marxians and is also discussed at the critical fringes of the
mainstream (as discussed in section three). The emergence of debt-driven versus export-driven
growth regimes and the impact of wealth concentration on financial (in)stability are much less
widely recognized though. Importantly, most of the literature focuses on the US. Our approach
differs in several ways. Firstly, our internationally comparative analysis exposes that countries
have relied on debt- or export-driven growth models in reaction to the rise in inequality.
Secondly, we systematically highlight the link between inequality and demand formation in the
real and the financial sector and thereby integrate the analysis of income inequality and wealth
concentration and its effects on consumption and debt levels, balance of payment imbalances,
21
and financial innovation. Finally, our article also discusses the link between debt- and exportdriven growth regimes, wealth concentration, and the Eurozone crisis.
These findings suggest various avenues for future research. First, the interaction between
different growth regimes needs further analysis. In particular the contribution of capital inflows
to asset and property price bubbles in advanced economies is under-researched. Second, the
effect of inequality on the growing demand for financial assets, financial innovation and
financial fragility deserves a lot more attention than it has hitherto received. Third, there is need
to develop macroeconomic models that explicitly deal with the link between income distribution,
asset prices and wealth distribution. One type of model that would be very well suited for these
kind of analyses would be extended stock-flow consistent (SFC) models, originally developed by
Godley and Cripps (1983) and Godley and Zezza (1989). The currently existing SFC models (e.g.
Cripps et al., 2011) make important contributions in analysing the impact of wealth on flow
variables, but so far they have the shortcoming that they do not account for the existence of
different investor types (e.g. HNWIs versus ordinary households), different assets types, and the
quantity dimensions of assets (Lysandrou, 2014). The incorporation of all the key channels
analysed in our paper could help to overcome this shortcoming in future SFC models.
An important policy implication arising out of this analysis is that a more egalitarian
distribution of income is not a luxury that can be taken care of once the crisis and regulatory
issues have been resolved, but that it is necessary to reverse the actual level of absolute wealth
concentration and income inequality to help contain the inherent problems of the current mode of
capitalism. Given that income inequality and absolute wealth concentration have increased
further since the outbreak of the crisis (Goda, 2014; OECD, 2013), decisive government
intervention seems necessary to achieve this aim.
The policy mix requires both the restoration of the link between productivity and real wage
growth and progressive taxes and social policies. Hence minimum wages should increase in line
with inflation and productivity and the bargaining power of workers should be strengthened
through changes in the union legislation and collective bargaining coverage as well as the
strengthening of the welfare state. With regard to taxes, we agree with Piketty (2014) that a
wealth tax is needed. Additionally, top marginal income and estate tax rates should be raised. An
indexation of these taxes would be an appropriate solution to avoid very high concentrations of
income and wealth (as proposed most prominently by Shiller (2012)). One possible rule would
22
be to link top income and wealth taxes to median incomes and wealth holdings (e.g. a highest
marginal tax rate of 70 per cent for income above 10 times the median income). Finally, tax
avoidance and evasion opportunities have to be closed off. As existing governance arrangements
allow the rich to be highly mobile and secretive, these policies need to be implemented on a
global or at least regional scale (e.g. in the form of a minimum top marginal tax threshold in
OECD countries).
23
REFERENCES
Acharya, V.V., I. Drechsler and P. Schnabl. (2011) ‘A Pyrrhic Victory? Bank Bailouts and
Sovereign Credit Risk’. NBER Working Paper no 17136. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of
Economic Research.
Akerlof, G.A. and R.J. Shiller (2009) Animal Spirits: How Human Psychology Drives the
Economy, and Why it Matters for Global Capitalism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Press.
Arestis, P. and M. Sawyer (2011) ‘The Ongoing Euro Crisis’, Challenge 54(6): 6–13.
Ashcraft, A.B. and T. Schuermann (2008) ‘Understanding the Securitization of Subprime
Mortgage Credit’. Federal Reserve Bank Staff Report no 318. New York: Federal Reserve
Bank.
Atkinson, A.B. and A. Brandolini (2010) ‘On Analyzing the World Distribution of Income’, The
World Bank Economic Review 24(1): 1–37.
Atkinson, A.B., T. Piketty and E. Saez (2011) ‘Top Incomes in the Long Run of History’,
Journal of Economic Literature 49(1): 3–71.
Barba, A. and M. Pivetti (2009) ‘Rising Household Debt: Its Causes and Macroeconomic
Implications—a Long-Period Analysis’, Cambridge Journal of Economics 33(1): 113–37
Bassens, D., M. van Meeteren, B. Derudder and F. Witlox (2013) ‘No More Credit to Europe?
Cross-Border Bank Lending, Financial Integration, and the Rebirth of the National Scale as a
Credit Scorecard’, Environment and Planning A 45(10): 2399–419.
Behringer, J. and T. van Treeck (2013) ‘Income Distribution, Aggregate Demand and Current
Account: A Sectoral Perspective’. IMK Working Paper no 125. Düsseldorf: Hans-BöcklerStiftung.
Behringer, J., T. Theobald and T. van Treeck (2014) ‘Income and Wealth Distribution in
Germany: A Macro-Economic Perspective’. IMK Report no 99e-2014. Düsseldorf: HansBöckler-Stiftung.
Bernanke, B.S. (2005) ‘The Global Saving Glut and the U.S. Current Account Deficit’. Speech
delivered at the Sandridge Lecture, Virginia Association of Economists, Richmond (10
March).
Bernanke, B.S. (2011) ‘International Capital Flows and the Return to Safe Assets in the United
24
States’, Banque de France Financial Stability Review 15: 13–26.
Bertaut, C., L. Pounder DeMarco, S.B. Kamin and R.W. Tryon (2012) ‘ABS Inflows to the
United States and the Global Financial Crisis’, Journal of International Economics 88(2):
219–34.
Bhaduri, A. and S. Marglin (1990) ‘Unemployment and the Real Wage: The Economic Basis for
Contesting Political Ideologies’, Cambridge Journal of Economics 14(4): 375–93.
Blanchard, O. (2009) ‘The Crisis: Basic Mechanisms, and Appropriate Policies’. IMF Working
Paper no WP09/80. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.
Blundell-Wignall, A. (2007) ‘Structured Products: Implications for Financial Markets’,
Financial Market Trends 93(2): 27–57.
Borio, C., and P. Disyatat (2011) ‘Global Imbalances and the Financial Crisis: Link or No
Link?’. BIS Working Paper no 346. Basel: Bank for International Settlements.
Brenner, R. (2009) ‘What is Good for Goldman Sachs is Good for America. The Origins of the
Current Crisis’. Prologue to the Spanish translation of the book Economics of Global
Turbulences, published by Akal in May 2009. http://escholarship.org/uc/item/0sg0782h#page1 (accessed 26 February 2012).
Brunnermeier, M. (2009) ‘Deciphering the Liquidity and Credit Crunch 2007–2008’, Journal of
Economic Perspectives 23(1): 77–100.
Caballero, R.J. and A. Krishnamurthy (2009) ‘Global Imbalances and Financial Fragility’,
American Economic Review 99(2): 584–88.
Caballero, R.J., E. Farhi and P.-O. Gourinchas (2008) ‘An Equilibrium Model of ‘Global
Imbalances’ and Low Interest Rates’, American Economic Review 98(1): 358-93.
Costa, J. and R. Ricciuti (2013) ‘Sources for the Euro Crisis: Bad Regulation and Weak
Institutions in Peripheral Europe’. University of Verona Department of Economics Working
Paper no 15. Verona: University of Verona.
Coval, J., J. Jurek and E. Stafford (2009) ‘The Economics of Structured Finance’, Journal of
Economic Perspectives 23(1): 3–25.
Crotty, J.R. (2012) ‘The Great Austerity War: What Caused the US Deficit Crisis and Who
should Pay to Fix it?’, Cambridge Journal of Economics 36(1): 79–104.
Cynamon B.Z. and S.M. Fazzari (2013) ‘Inequality and Household Finance During the
Consumer Age’. Levy Economics Institute Working Paper no 752. Annandale-on-Hudson,
25
NY: Bard College.
Cynamon, B.Z. and S.M. Fazzari (2015) ‘Rising Inequality and Stagnation in the US Economy’,
European Journal of Economics and Economic Policies: Intervention 12(2): 170–82.
Davies, H. (2010) ‘Global Financial Regulation after the Credit Crisis’, Global Policy 1(2):
185–90.
Dumenil, G. and D. Levy (2011) The Crisis of Neoliberalism. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press.
Eccles, M.S. (1951) Beckoning Frontiers: Public and Personal Recollections. New York: Alfred
A. Knopf.
Engelen, E., I. Erturk, J. Froud, A. Leaver and K. Williams (2010) ‘Reconceptualizing Financial
Innovation: Frame, Conjuncture and Bricolage’, Economy and Society 39(1): 33–63.
Fitoussi, J.-P. and F. Saraceno (2010) ‘Inequality and the Macroeconomic Performance’. OFCE
Working Paper no 2010-13. Paris: Science Po.
Foster J.B. and F. Magdoff (2009) The Great Financial Crisis: Causes and Consequences. New
York: Monthly Review Press.
Froud, J., S. Johal, C. Haslam and K. Williams (2001) ‘Accumulation under Conditions of
Inequality’, Review of International Political Economy 8(1): 66–95.
Fujita, K. (2011) ‘Financial Crises, Japan’s State Regime Shift, and Tokyo’s Urban Policy’,
Environment and Planning A 43(2): 307–27.
Galbraith, J.K. (1975) The Great Crash 1929. Boston, MA: Houghton Mifflin.
Galbraith, J.K. (2012) Inequality and Instability. A Study of the World Economy Just Before the
Great Crisis. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Goda, T. (2014) ‘Global Trends in Relative and Absolute Wealth Concentration’. CIEF
Working Paper no 14–01. Medellin: Universidad EAFIT.
Goda, T. and P. Lysandrou (2014) ‘The Contribution of Wealth Concentration to the Subprime
Crisis: A Quantitative Estimation’, Cambridge Journal of Economics 38(2): 301–27.
Goda, T., P. Lysandrou and C. Stewart (2013) ‘The Contribution of US Bond Demand to the US
Bond Yield Conundrum of 2004 to 2007: An Empirical Investigation’, Journal of
International Financial Markets, Institutions & Money 27: 113–36.
Godley, W. and F. Cripps (1983) Macroeconomics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Godley, W. and G. Zezza (1986) ‘A Simple Real Stock Flow Monetary Model of the Italian
26
Economy’. University of Cambridge Department of Applied Economics Working Paper.
Cambridge: University of Cambridge.
Hager, S.B. (2014) ‘What Happened to the Bondholding Class? Public Debt, Power and the Top
One Per Cent’, New Political Economy 19(2): 155–82.
Hein, E. (2012) The Macroeconomics of Finance-Dominated Capitalism—and its Crisis.
Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Hein, E. and M. Mundt (2012) ‘Financialisation and the Requirements and Potentials for Wageled Recovery—a Review Focussing on the G20’. ILO Conditions of Work and Employment
Series no 37. Geneva: International Labour Organization.
Hein, E. and L. Vogel (2008) ‘Distribution and Growth Reconsidered—Empirical Results for
Six OECD Countries’, Cambridge Journal of Economics 32(3): 479–511.
Hoque, H. (2013) ‘From the Credit Crisis to the Sovereign Debt Crisis: Determinants of Share
Price Performance of Global Banks’, International Review of Financial Analysis 30: 334–50.
IFSL (2008). ‘Fund Management 2008’. Report from Financial Services in London.
www.ifsl.org.uk. (accessed 10 May 2010).
IMF (2008) Global Financial Stability Report: Financial Stress and Deleveraging. Washington,
DC: International Monetary Fund.
Kumhof, M. and R. Ranciere (2010) ‘Inequality, Leverage and Crises’. IMF Working Paper no
268. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.
Kumhof, M., C. Lebarz, R. Ranciere, A.W. Richter and N.A. Throckmorton (2012) ‘Income
Inequality and Current Account Imbalances’. IMF Working Paper no 12/08. Washington, DC:
International Monetary Fund.
Kumhof, M., R. Ranciére and P. Winant (2015) ‘Inequality, Leverage, and Crises’, American
Economic Review 105(3): 1217–45.
Langley, P. (2008) ‘Financialization and the Consumer Credit Boom’, Competition & Change
12(2): 133–47.
Lapavitsas, C. et al. (2010) ‘Eurozone Crisis: Beggar Thyself and Thy Neighbour’, Journal of
Balkan and Near Eastern Studies 12(4): 321–73.
Lavoie, M. (2009). Introduction to Post Keynesian economics. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Lim, M.-H. and H.E. Khor (2011) ‘From Marx to Morgan Stanley: Inequality and Financial
Crisis’, Development and Change 42(1): 209–27.
27
Lysandrou, P. (2011a) ‘Global Inequality as One of the Root Causes of the Financial Crisis: a
Suggested Explanation’, Economy and Society 40(3): 323–44.
Lysandrou, P. (2011b) ‘Global Inequality, Wealth Concentration and the Subprime Crisis: A
Marxian Commodity Theory Analysis’, Development and Change 42(1): 183–208.
Lysandrou, P. (2012) ‘The Primacy of Hedge Funds in the Subprime Crisis’, Journal of Post
Keynesian Economics 34(2): 225–54.
Lysandrou, P. (2014) ‘Post-Keynesian Stock-Flow Models after the Subprime Crisis: the Need
for Micro-Foundations’, European Journal of Economics and Economic Policies: Intervention
11(1): 113–26.
Major, A. (2012) ‘Neoliberalism and the New International Financial Architecture’, Review of
International Political Economy 19(4): 536–61.
Milanovic, B. (2011) The Haves and the Haves Not: A Brief Idiosyncratic History of Global
Inequality. New York: Basic Books.
Muñoz Martinez, H. and T. Marois (2014) ‘Capital Fixity and Mobility in Response to the
2008–09 Crisis: Variegated Neoliberalism in Mexico and Turkey’, Environment and Planning
D: Society and Space 32(6): 1102–19.
Naastepad, C.W.M. and S. Storm (2006) ‘OECD Demand Regimes (1960–2000)’, Journal of
Post Keynesian Economics 29(2): 211–46.
OECD (2012) ‘Labour Losing to Capital: What Explains the Declining Labour Share?’, in
OECD (ed) Employment Outlook, Chapter 3. Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation
and Development.
OECD (2013) ‘Crisis Squeezes Income and Puts Pressure on Inequality and Poverty’. New
results from the OECD Income Distribution Database. www.oecd.org/social/inequality.htm
(accessed 8 April 2014).
Onaran, Ö. And G. Galanis (2014) ‘Income Distribution and Aggregate Demand: National and
Global Effects’, Environment and Planning A 46(10): 2489–513.
Palley, T.I. (2012) From Financial Crisis to Stagnation: The Destruction of Shared Prosperity
and the Role of Economics. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.
Palley, T.I. (2016) ‘Inequality, the Financial Crisis, and Stagnation: Competing Stories and Why
They Matter’, Real-World Economics Review 74: 1–18.
Palma, J.G. (2009) ‘The Revenge of the Market on the Rentiers. Why Neo-Liberal Reports of
28
the End of History Turned Out to Be Premature’, Cambridge Journal of Economics 33(4):
829–69.
Palma, J.G. (2011) ‘Homogeneous Middles vs. Heterogeneous Tails, and the End of the
“Inverted-U”: It’s All About the Share of the Rich’, Development and Change 42(1): 87–153.
Piketty, T. (2014) Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.
Rajan, R.G. (2010) Fault Lines. How Hidden Fractures Still Threaten the World Economy.
Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Roubini, N. and S. Mihm (2010) Crisis Economics: A Crash Course in the Future. New York:
Penguin.
Saez, E. and G. Zucman (2014) ‘Wealth Inequality in the United States since 1913: Evidence
from capitalized income tax data’. NBER Working Paper no 20625. Cambridge, MA: National
Bureau of Economic Research.
Sawyer, M. (2013) ‘Alternative Economic Policies for the Economic and Monetary Union’,
Contributions to Political Economy 32(1): 11–27.
Schuknecht, L., P. Moutot, P. Rother and J. Stark (2011) ‘The Stability and Growth Pact Crisis
and Reform’. ECB Occasional Paper Series no 129. Frankfurt: European Central Bank.
Shiller, R. (2012) ‘Don’t Resent the Rich, Fix the Tax Code’. BloombergView, 06 March.
https://www.bloomberg.com/view/articles/2012-03-07/don-t-resent-the-rich-fix-the-tax-codepart-3-robert-shiller (accessed 5 June 2014).
Shin, H.S. (2012) ‘Global Banking Glut and Loan Risk Premium’, IMF Economic Review 60(2):
155-92.
Sidaway, J.D. (2008) ‘Subprime Crisis: American Crisis or Human Crisis?’, Environment and
Planning D: Society and Space 26(2): 195–98.
Stiglitz, J.E. (2009) ‘The Global Crisis, Social Protection and Jobs’, International Labour
Review 148(1–2): 1–13.
Stiglitz, J.E. (2011) ‘Rethinking Macroeconomics: What Failed, and How to Repair it’, Journal
of the European Economic Association 9(4): 591–645.
Stiglitz, J.E. (2012) The Price of Inequality. London: Penguin Books.
Stockhammer, E. (2015) ‘Rising Inequality as a Cause of the Present Crisis’, Cambridge
Journal of Economics 39(3): 935–58.
Stockhammer, E. (2016a) ‘Neoliberal Growth Models, Monetary Union and the Euro Crisis. A
29
Post-Keynesian Perspective’, New Political Economy 21(4): 365–79.
Stockhammer, E. (2016b) ‘Determinants of the Wage Share: A Panel Analysis of Advanced and
Developing Economies’, British Journal of Industrial Relations. DOI: 10.1111/bjir.12165.
Stockhammer, E. and Ö. Onaran (2012) ‘Rethinking Wage Policy in the Face of the Euro Crisis.
Implications of the Wage-Led Demand Regime’, International Review of Applied Economics
26(2): 191–203.
Stockhammer, E., Ö. Onaran and S. Ederer (2009) ‘Functional Income Distribution and
Aggregate Demand in the Eurozone’, Cambridge Journal of Economics 33(1): 139–59.
Storm, S. and C.W.M. Naastepad (2015a) ‘Europe’s Hunger Games: Income Distribution, Cost
Competitiveness and Crisis’, Cambridge Journal of Economics 39(3): 959–86.
Storm, S. and C.W.M. Naastepad (2015b) ‘Crisis and Recovery in the German Economy: The
Real Lessons’, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 32: 11–24.
Storm, S. and C.W.M. Naastepad (2015c) ‘NAIRU Economics and the Eurozone Crisis’,
International Review of Applied Economics 29(6): 843–77.
Taylor, J.B. (2009) ‘Economic Policy and the Financial Crisis: An Empirical Analysis of What
Went Wrong’, Critical Review 21(2–3): 341–64.
Tuttle, M.H. and J. Gauger (2006) ‘Wealth and the distribution of income: Permanent and
transitory effects’, Review of Income and Wealth 52(4): 493-508.
van Treeck, T. (2014) ‘Did Inequality Cause the U.S. Financial crisis?’, Journal of Economic
Surveys 28(3): 421–48.
Vidal, M. (2013) ‘Postfordism as a Dysfunctional Accumulation Regime: A Comparative
Analysis of the USA, the UK and Germany’, Work Employment Society 27(3): 451–71.
Wisman, J.D. (2013) ‘Wage Stagnation, Rising Inequality and the Financial Crisis of 2008’,
Cambridge Journal of Economics 37(4): 921–45.
Wisman, J.D. and B. Baker (2011) ‘Rising Inequality and the Financial Crisis of 1929 and
2008’. American University Department of Economics Working Paper no 2011–01.
Washington, DC: American University.
Wolff, E.N. (2010) ‘Recent Trends in Household Wealth in the United States: Rising Debt and
the Middle-Class Squeeze — An Update to 2007’. Levy Economics Institute Working Paper
no 589. Annandale-on-Hudson, NY: Bard College.
Wolff, E.N. (2012) ‘The Asset Price Meltdown and the Wealth of the Middle Class’. NBER
30
Working Paper no 18559. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.
31