The Le Chatelier Principle in Data Envelopment Analysis
by
W.E. Diewert and M.N.F. Mendoza*
October, 1996
W.E. Diewert: Department of Economics, University of British Columbia, Vancouver, BC
V6T 1Z1 Canada
M.N.F. Mendoza: 478 P. Burgos Street, Marikina, Metro Manila 1800, Philippines.
Our thanks to Knox Lovell for helpful comments.
October 24, 1996
Abstract
The paper gives a brief review of the nonparametric approach to efficiency measurement or Data Envelopment Analysis as it is known in the operations research literature.
Inequalities are derived between the efficiency measures when different assumptions are
made on the technology sets or on the behavior of managers. Of particular interest is the
derivation of a Le Chatelier Principle for measures of allocative inefficiency. Finally, DEA
methods for measuring the relative efficiency of production units are compared with the
more traditional index number and econometric methods.
Key words: efficiency measurement, data envelopment analysis, Le Chatelier Principle,
productivity, nonparametric measurement of technology, index numbers.
Classification code: C14, C43, C61, D61
1
1.
Introduction
Data Envelopment Analysis or (DEA) is the term used by Charnes and Cooper (1985)
and their co-workers to denote an area of analysis which is called the nonparameteric
approach to production theory1 or the measurement of the efficiency of production2 by
economists.
The basic idea in the case of similar firms producing one output and using 2 inputs is
due to Farrell (1957; 254). Let there be j firms, denote the output of firm j by y j ≥ 0 and
j
j
denote the amounts of input 1 and 2 used by firm j by x1 ≥ 0 and x2 ≥ 0 respectively,
for j = 1, 2, . . . , J. Calculate the input-output coefficients for each firm defined by xj1 /yj
and xj2 /y j for j = 1, 2, . . . , J . Now plot these pairs of input output coefficients in a
two dimensional diagram as in Figure 1 where we have labeled these pairs as the points
P 1 , P 2 , . . . , P 5 (so that j = 5).
Figure 1:
The convex hull of the 5 data points P 1 , . . . , P 5 in Figure 1 is the shaded set: it is the
set of all non-negative weighted averages of the 5 points where the weights sum up to 1.
The convex free disposal hull of the original 5 points is the shaded set plus all of the points
that lie to the north and east of the shaded set. Farrell took the boundary or frontier
of this set as an approximation to the unit output isoquant of the underlying production
function3 . In Figure 1, this frontier set is the piecewise linear curve AP 4 P 3 B. The Farrell
2
technical efficiency of the point P 1 was defined to be the ratio of distances OC/OP 1 , since
this is the fraction (of both inputs) that an efficient firm could use to produce the same
output as that produced by Firm 1. A point P i is regarded as being technically efficient
if its technical efficiency is unity.
Farrell (1957; 254) noted the formal similarity of his definition of technical efficiency
to Debreu’s (1951) coefficient of resource utilization.
Farrell (1957; 255) also defined two further efficiency concepts using a diagram similar
to Figure 1. Suppose Firm 1 faced the fixed input prices w1 and w2 for the two inputs.
Then we could form a family of isocost lines with slope - w1 /w2 and find the lowest such
isocost line that is just tangent to the free disposal convex hull of the 5 points. In Figure
1, this is the line DE which is tangent to the point P 3 . Farrell noted that even if the
point P 1 were shrunk in towards the origin to end up at the technically efficient point
C, the resulting point would still not be the cost minimizing input combination (which is
at P 3 ). Thus Farrell defined the price efficiency of P 1 as the ratio of distances OD/OC.
Finally, Farrell (1957; 255) defined the overall efficiency of Firm 1 as the ratio of distances
OD/OP 1 . This measure incorporates both technical and allocative inefficiency. A point
P i is overall efficient if its overall efficiency is unity.
There is a problem with Farrell’s measure of technical efficiency: Farrell’s definition
makes the points P 2 and P 5 in Figure 1 technically efficient when it seems clear that they
are not: P 2 is dominated by P 3 which uses less of input 1 to produce the same output and
P 5 is dominated by P 4 which uses less of input 2 to produce the same output. Charnes,
Cooper and Rhodes (1978; 437) and Färe and Lovell (1978; 151) both noticed this problem
with Farrell’s definition of technical efficiency and suggested remedies. However, in the
remainder of this paper we will stick with Farrell’s original definition of technical efficiency
(with a few modifications due to Mendoza (1989)).
Farrell’s basic ideas outlined above for the case of a one output, constant returns to
scale technology can be generalized in several ways: (i) we can relax the assumption of
constant returns to scale; (ii) we can extend the analysis to the multiple output, multiple
input case; (iii) we can generalize the analysis to cover situations where it is reasonable
to assume profit maximizing behaviour (or partial profit maximizing behaviour) rather
than cost minimizing behaviour and (iv) we can measure inefficiency in different metrics
(i.e., instead of measuring technical inefficiency in terms of a proportional shrinkage of
the input vector, we could choose to measure the inefficiency in terms of a basket of
outputs or a basket of outputs and inputs). Drawing on the work of Mendoza (1989) and
others, we shall indicate how the above generalizations can be implemented for the case
of technologies that produce only 2 outputs and utilize only 2 inputs. The generalization
to many outputs and inputs is straightforward. Section 2 below covers approaches that
use only quantity data while section 3 describes approaches that utilize both price and
3
quantity data. Section 3 also derives some interesting general relationships between various
measures of efficiency loss. Of particular interest is a Le Chatelier Principle for measures
of allocative inefficiency.
Mendoza (1989) also undertook an empirical comparison of 3 different methods for
measuring productivity change in the context of time series data. The 3 different methods
of comparison she considered were: (i) a nonparametric or DEA method; (ii) traditional
index number methods and (iii) an econometric method based on the estimation of a unit
profit function4 . In section 4 we give a summary of her results.
Drawing on the empirical and theoretical results reviewed in the previous sections, in
section 5 we compare the advantages and disadvantages of DEA methods for measuring
the relative efficiency of production units with the more traditional index number and
econometric methods.
2.
2.1
Efficiency tests using quantity data
The case of a convex technology
Suppose that we have quantity data on J production units that are producing 2
j
outputs using 2 inputs. Let ym
≥ 0 denote the amount of output m produced by “firm”
j
j for m = 1, 2, and let xk ≥ 0 denote the amount of input be used by firm j for k = 1, 2
and j = 1, 2, . . . , J.
We assume that each firm has the same basic technology except for efficiency differences. An approximation to the basic technology is defined to be the convex free disposal
hull of the observed quantity data {(y1j , y2j , xj1 , xj2 ) : j = 1, . . . , J}. This technology assumption is consistent with decreasing returns to scale (and constant returns to scale) but
not increasing returns to scale.
It is necessary to specify a direction in which possible inefficiencies are measured;
i.e., do we measure the inefficiency of observation i in terms of output m or input k or
some combination of outputs and inputs? Mendoza’s (1989) methodology allows for an
arbitrary efficiency direction5 , but for simplicity, we will restrict ourselves to the Debreu
(1951) - Farrell (1957) direction; i.e., we shall measure the inefficiency of observation i by
the number of multiples δi∗ of (xi1 , xi2 ) that could be thrown away by the ith firm if it were
on the efficient frontier spanned by the convex free disposal hull of the J observations.
If the ith observation is efficient relative to this frontier, then δi∗ = 0. The number δi∗
can be determined as the optimal objective function of the following linear programming
problem:6
4
δi∗ ≡ maxδi ≥0,λ1 ≥0,...,λJ ≥0 δi subject to :
j
ΣJj=1 y1 λj ≥ y1i ;
ΣJj=1 y2j λj ≥ y2i ;
ΣJj=1 xj1 λj ≤ xi1 − δixi1 ;
(1)
ΣJj=1 xj2 λj ≤ xi2 − δixi2 ;
ΣJj=1 λj = 1.
Thus we look for a convex combination of the J data points that can produce at least the
observation i combination of outputs (y1i , y2i ) and use at most (1−δi ) times the observation
ation i combination of inputs (xi1 , xi2 ). The largest such δi is δi∗ .
The linear programming problems (1) are run for each observation i and the resulting
δi∗ ≥ 0, serves to measure the relative efficiency of observation i; if δi∗ = 0, then observation
i is efficient. At least one of the J observations will be efficient.
We then turn now to the corresponding linear program that tests for efficiency under
the maintained hypothesis that the underlying technology is subject to constant returns
to scale.
2.2
The case of a convex, constant returns to scale technology
In this case, the approximation to the underlying technology set is taken to be the
free disposal hull of the convex cone spanned by the J data points. The inefficiency of
observation i is measured by the number of multiples δi∗∗ of the ith input vector (xi1 , xi2 )
that could be thrown away by the ith firm if it were on the above frontier and can be
calculated by solving the following linear program:7
δi∗∗ = maxδi ≥0,λ1≥0,...,λJ ≥0 δi subject to :
ΣJj=1 y1j λj ≥ y1i ;
ΣJj=1 y2j λj ≥ y2i ;
(2)
ΣJj=1 xj1 λj ≤ xi1 − δi xi1 ;
j
ΣJj=1 x2 λj ≤ xi2 − δi xi2 .
P
Note that the LP (2) is the same as (1) except that the constraint Jj=1 λj = 1 has been
dropped. Thus the optimal solution for (1) is feasible for (2) and thus δi∗∗ ≥ δi∗ ; i.e., the
constant returns to scale measure of inefficiency for observation i will equal to or greater
than the convex technology measure of inefficiency for observation i.
We turn now to models that are consistent with increasing returns to scale.
5
2.3
Quasiconcave technologies
We first need to define what we mean by a production possibilities set L(y1 ) that is
conditional on an amount y1 of output 1. Let S be the set of feasible outputs and inputs.
Then L(y1 ) is defined to be the set of (y2 , x1 , x2 ) such that (y1 , y2 , x1 , x2 ) belongs to S;
i.e., L(y1 ) is the set of other outputs y2 and inputs x1 and x2 that are consistent with the
production of y1 units of output 1. We assume that the family of production possibilities
sets L(y2 ) has the following three properties: (i) for each y1 ≥ 0, L(y1 ) is a closed, convex
set8 ; (ii) if y1′ ≤ y1′′ , then L(y1′′ ) is a subset of L(y1 )′ and (iii) the sets L(y1 ) exhibit free
disposal.
For each observation i, define the following set of indexes:
Ii1 ≡ {j : y1j ≥ y1i , j = 1, 2, . . . , J };
(3)
i.e., Ii1 is the set of observations j such that the amount of output 1 produced by observations j is equal to or greater than the amount of output 1 produced by observation i.
Note that observation i must belong to Ii1 .
Given our assumptions on the underlying technology, it can be seen that the free
j j j
disposal convex hull of the points (y2 , x1 , x2 ), j ∈ Ii1 , form an approximation to the set
L(y1i ). The frontier of this set is taken to be the efficient set. As usual, we measure the
inefficiency of observation i by the number of multiples δj∗∗∗ of the ith input vector (xi1 , xi2 )
that could be thrown away by the ith firm if it were on the above frontier. The number
can be calculated by solving the following linear program:9
δi∗∗∗ = maxδi ≥0,λ1 ≥0,...,λJ ≥0 δi subject to :
Σj∈I 1 y2j λj ≥ y2i ;
i
j
Σj∈I 1 x1 λj ≤ xi1 − δi xi1 ;
i
(4)
Σj∈I 1 xj2 λj ≤ xi2 − δi xi2 ;
i
Σj∈I 1 λj = 1.
i
On the left hand side of each constraint in (4), the indexes j must belong to the index set
Ii1 defined by (3) above.
Denote the optimal λj for (4) above by λ∗∗∗
for j ∈ Ii1 . By the last constraint in (4),
j
we have
Σj∈I 1 λ∗∗∗
= 1.
(5)
j
i
Using the definition (3),
λ∗∗∗
j
≥ 0 and (5), we can show that
Σj∈I 1 y1i λ∗∗∗
≥ y1i .
j
i
6
(6)
Using (1), (4) and (6), we see that the optimal solution for (4) is feasible for (1) and thus
we must have δi∗ ≥ δi∗∗∗ . Recall that we showed that δi∗∗ ≥ δi∗ and so we have
0 ≤ δi∗∗∗ ≤ δi∗ ≤ δi∗∗ .
(7)
Thus the efficiency loss measures generally increase (or remain constant) as we make
stronger assumptions on the underlying technology: the smallest loss measure δi∗∗∗ corresponds to a quasiconcave (in output 1) technology, the next measure δi∗ corresponds to a
convex technology, and the largest measure δi∗∗ corresponds to a constant returns to scale
convex technology.
In definition (3) and the LP (4), output 1 was singled out to play a special role.
Obviously, analogues to (3) and (4) could be constructed where output 2 played the
asymmetric role. In this latter case, the underlying technological assumption is that the
y2 = f (y1 , x1 , x2 ) production function is quasiconcave. This is a somewhat different technological assumption than our initial one, but both assumptions can be consistent with an
increasing returns to scale technology.10
This completes our brief overview of nonparametric efficiency tests that involve the
use of quantity data. We now turn to test that involve both price and quantity data so that
overall efficiency measures can be constructed in place of the technical efficiency measures
of this section.
3.
3.1
Efficiency tests using price and quantity data
The convex technology case
We make the same assumptions on the underlying technology as in section 2.1 above.
However, we now assume that each producer may be either minimizing cost or maximizing
profits. We consider each case in turn.
Case (i): Cost Minimization We assume that producer j faces the input prices (w1j , w2j )
for the two inputs. To determine whether producer i is minimizing cost subject to our
convex technology assumptions, we solve the following linear program:11
j
j
minλ1 ≥0,...,λJ ≥0 w1i (ΣJj=1 x1 λj ) + w2i (ΣJj=1 x2 λj )
subject to:
j
ΣJj=1 y1 λj ≥ y1i ;
ΣJj=1 y2j λj ≥ y2i ;
(8)
ΣJj=1 λj = 1 ;
≡ (1 − ε∗i )[w1i xi1 + w2i xi2 ].
7
(9)
The meaning of (9) is that we define the overall efficiency loss measure ε∗i by equating
(9) to the optimized objective function in (8). If we set λi = 1 and the other λj = 0,
we have a feasible solution for (8) which yields a value of the objective function equal to
w1i xi1 + w2i xi2 . Thus ε∗i ≥ 0. The number ε∗i can be interpreted as the number of multiples
of (xi1 , xi2 ) that we could throw away and obtain a shrunken firm i input vector that would
be on the minimum cost isocost line; i.e., 1 − ε∗i is an analogue to the overall efficiency
measure OD/OP 1 which occurred in Figure 1.
Comparing (1) and (8), it can be seen that the optimal λ∗j solution for (1) is a feasible
solution for (8) and thus:
0 ≤ δi∗ ≤ ε∗i
(10)
The inequality (10) simply reflects the fact that overall inefficiency is equal to or greater
than technical efficiency (recall Figure 1 again).
Case (ii): Profit Maximization We now assume that firm i also faces the output prices
(pj1 , pj2 ) for the two outputs. To determine whether producer i is maximizing profits subject
to our convex technology assumptions; we solve the following linear program:12
j
maxλ1 ≥0,...,λJ ≥0 Σ2m=1 pim (ΣJj=1 ym
λj ) − Σ2k=1 wki (ΣJj=1 xjk λj )
subject to:
ΣJj=1 λj = 1
≡ pi1 y1i + pi2 y2i − (1 − α∗i )[w1i xi1 + w2i xi2 ].
(11)
(12)
Equating (11) to (12) defines the efficiency loss measure α∗i for observation i. If we set
λi = 1 in (11) and the other λj = 0, we obtain a feasible value for the objective function
equal to pi1 y1i + pi2 y2i − [w1i xi1 + w2i xi2 ]. Thus α∗i ≥ 0. If αi∗ = 0, then observation i is efficient
relative to our assumptions on the technology and relative to the hypothesis of complete
profit maximization. The interpretation of α∗i is similar to that of ε∗i defined above by (9).
It can be seen that the optimal λ∗j solution to (8) is feasible for (11). Using this fact
and the inequalities in (8), Mendoza (1989; 76-77) shows that
ε∗i ≤ αi∗ .
(13)
In fact, Mendoza shows in general as the producer is assumed to optimize over more goods,
the corresponding efficiency loss measures cannot decrease; i.e., they will increase or stay
constant.
We now turn to the corresponding linear programs that test for the efficiency of
observation i under the maintained hypothesis that the underlying technology is subject
to constant returns to scale.
8
The convex conical technology case
Case (ii): Cost Minimization Guided by the results of section 2,2, it can be seen that
all we have to do is to drop the constraint ΣJj=1 λj = 1 from (8). The resulting optimized
i i
i i
objective function is set equal to (1 − ε∗∗
i )[w1 x1 + w2 x2 ]. Since the new LP has one less
constraint than (8), it will generally attain a smaller optimized objective function and so
∗
ε∗∗
i will generally be bigger than εi ; i.e.,
ε∗i ≤ ε∗∗
i .
(14)
By comparing the new LP to (2), we can also show
δi∗∗ ≤ ε∗∗
i .
(15)
The inequality (14) shows that making stronger assumptions on the underlying technology
tends to increase the efficiency loss measure and the inequality (15) shows that assuming
cost minimizing behaviour tends to increase the efficiency loss.13
Case (ii):
Profit Maximization As in section 2.2, we approximate the underlying
technology set by the free disposal hull of the convex cone spanned by the J data points.
To determine whether observation i is on the frontier of this set, we could attempt to
solve the LP problem (11) after dropping the constraint ΣJj=1 λj = 1. Unfortunately, the
resulting optimal objective function is either 0 or plus infinity. Hence a different approach
is required.
In order to obtain an operational approach, we consider a conditional profit maximization problem in place of the full profit maximization problem that appears in the
objective function of (11); i.e., we allow firm i to maximize profits excluding the cost of
one input (which is regarded as being fixed in the short run). Thus if the fixed input
is input 1, to determine whether producer i is maximizing (variable) profits subject to
our convex, conical technology assumptions, we solve the following linear programming
problem:14
j
maxλ1 ≥0,...,λj ≥0 Σ2m=1 pim (ΣJj=1 ym
λj ) − w2i (ΣJj=1 xj2 λj )
(16)
j
subject to : ΣJj=1 x1 λj ≤ xi1 ;
≡ [pi1 y1i + pi2 y2i ](1 + βi∗∗ ) − w2i xi2
(17)
where (17) serves to define the observation i efficiency loss measure βi∗∗ . Note that λi = 1
and the other λj = 0 is a feasible solution for (16).
We have changed the way we measure the loss of efficiency in (16) compared to
(11): the efficiency loss of firm i is now the number of extra multiples βi∗∗ of the firm i
observed output vector (y1i , y2i ) that an efficient firm could throw away and still be on the
same isoprofit surfaces firm i. Thus in (16), we measure the loss of efficiency in terms
9
of proportional output bundles whereas previously we had measured the loss in terms of
proportional input bundles. Since we have switched loss metrics, we cannot deduce that
βi∗∗ ≥ αi∗ where α∗i was defined by (12).
In order to obtain a loss measure α∗∗
i for observation i in our old input loss metric,
we need to solve the following linear programming problem:15
j
maxλ1 ≥0,...,λJ ≥0 Σ2m=1 pim (ΣJj=1 ym
λj ) − w1i xi1 − w2i (ΣJj=1 xj2 λj )
subject to: ΣJj=1 xi1 λj ≤ xi1 ;
i i
i i
≡ [pi1 y1i + pi2 y2i ] − (1 − α∗∗
i )[w1 x1 + w2 x2 ]
(18)
(19)
where (19) serves to define α∗∗
i . As usual, λi = 1 and the other λj = 0 is feasible for (18)
∗∗
and this fact implies that αi ≥ 0. Comparison of (2) and (18) shows that the optimal
solution to (2) generates a feasible αi for (18) and (19) and thus
δi∗∗ ≤ α∗∗
i ;
(20)
i.e., the observation i technical efficiency loss measure δi∗∗ is always equal to or less than
the overall observation i profit maximization loss α∗∗
i .
3.3
The quasiconcave technology case
We consider only the cost minimization case. More general cases are considered in
Mendoza’s (1989; 83) Test 6.
We make the same technology assumptions as were made in section 2.3. Recall the
index set Ii1 defined by (3). To determine whether producer i is minimizing cost subject to
our quasiconcave technology in output 1 assumption, we solve the following linear program:
minλ1 ≥0,...,λJ ≥0 w1i (Σj∈I 1 xi1 λj ) + w2i (Σj∈I 1 xj2 λj )
i
subject to:
j
Σj∈I 1 y1 λj
i
i
≥
y1i
;
Σj∈I 1 y2j λj ≥ y2i ;
(21)
i
Σj∈I 1 λj = 1 ;
i
i i
i i
≡ (1 − ε∗∗∗
i )[w1 x1 + w2 x2 ]
(22)
As usual, ε∗∗∗
is our measure of overall efficiency loss for observation i under our present
i
assumptions on the technology and on the producer’s behaviour. Since the index i belongs
to the index set Ii1 (recall (3)), it can be seen that λi = 1 and the other λj = 0 is feasible
for the LP(21) and gives rise to the feasible value for the objective function equal to
10
w1i xi1 + w2i xi2 . Thus ε∗∗∗
≥ 0. It is also possible to see that the optimal δi∗∗∗ , λ∗∗∗
solution
i
j
to (4) is a feasible εi , λj solution for (21). Thus
0 ≤ δj∗∗∗ ≤ ε∗∗∗
;
i
(23)
i.e., the cost minimizing overall efficiency loss for observation i, ε∗∗∗
i , will be equal to or
∗∗∗
greater than the technical efficiency loss for observation i, δi .
Comparing (21) with (8) and using the definition of the index set Ii1 (recall (3)), it
∗∗∗ solution a feasible solution for (8). Thus
can be seen that the optimal λ∗∗∗
j , εi
ε∗∗∗
≤ ε∗i ;
i
(24)
i.e., the observation i loss measure assuming a quasiconcave technology and cost minimizing
behaviour ε∗∗∗
will be equal to or less than the observation i loss measure assuming a convex
i
technology and cost minimizing behaviour ε∗i .
The inequalities derived in this section and the previous section can be summarized
by two rules. We assume that all efficiency losses are measured in the same metric. Rule
1: The nonparametric efficiency loss measures tend to grow as we make more restrictive
technological assumptions; i.e., the quasiconcave technology loss measure will be equal to
or less than the corresponding convex technology loss measure which in turn will be equal
to or less than the corresponding convex conical technology loss measure.
Rule 2:
The nonparametric efficiency loss measures tend to grow as we assume optimizing behaviour over a larger number of goods; i.e., the technical efficiency loss measure
will be equal to or less than the corresponding cost minimizing loss measure which will be
equal to or less than the corresponding profit maximizing loss measure. This is Mendoza’s
(1989; 76-77) Le Chatelier Principle for measures of allocative inefficiency.
We turn now to a brief description of some of Mendoza’s empirical results.
4.
An empirical comparison of alternative efficiency measures
Mendoza (1989) compared three alternative methods for computing annual rates of
productivity change for 4 Canadian production sectors over the years 1961 to 1980 using
Canadian input-output data. The 3 alternative methods were: (i) a method based on
DEA techniques; (ii) a method based on the use of superlative index numbers16 and (iii)
a method based on the statistical estimation of unit profit functions for each of the four
sectors.17 The 4 sectors were: (i) a resources sector; (ii) an export oriented manufacturing
sector; (iii) a domestic market oriented manufacturing sector and (iv) a services sector.
Each sector produced one output and used the outputs of the other 3 sectors as inputs. In
addition, each sector used 5 primary inputs: imports, labor, inventories, machinery and
equipment and an aggregate of land and structures. Thus each sector produced one output,
11
used 3 intermediate inputs and used 5 primary inputs. In the index number computations
and in the DEA analysis, the intermediate inputs were treated as negative outputs.
For each sector and of each year i, Mendoza calculated nonparametric measures of
efficiency loss that are analogous to the profit maximizing, convex conical loss measures βi∗∗
defined by (17) above.18 For sector 1, the most efficient observation occurred in 1973; for
sector 2, the efficient year was 1978; for sector 3, the efficient year was 1979 and for sector
4, the efficient years the last year 1980. As Mendoza (1989; 111) observed, her violation
indexes can be interpreted as chained indexes of technical change. Thus she used her
violation indexes to construct to year measures of technical change (or productivity change)
and these year to year nonparametric productivity change indexes were compared to the
corresponding index number measures of productivity change.20 Somewhat surprisingly,
the nonparametric and index number estimates of technical change are very similar except
that the magnitudes of the nonparametric changes tended to be substantially less than the
corresponding index number changes. These differences in magnitude are due to Mendoza’s
treatment of intermediate inputs21 ; a more appropriate treatment would greatly diminish
these differences in magnitude.
Mendoza’s (1989) econometric estimates of sectoral technical change are tabled on
page 129 of her thesis and compared graphically with her nonparametric estimates of
sectoral technical change on pages 133-134. Her results show that the econometric estimates of efficiency change are simply a highly smoothed version of the corresponding
nonparametric estimates.
Mendoza’s results are very encouraging: the three methods of computing annual
productivity change given roughly the same answers with the econometric estimates being
much less variable than the other two sets of estimates.
5.
A comparison of the alternative methods for measuring efficiency
We summarize our comparison of alternative methods in point form.
(i) Nonparametric of DEA techniques have an overwhelming advantage over index number and econometric methods when only quantity data are available. Index number methods cannot be implemented without a complete set of price and quantity data. Econometric
methods (i.e., production function methods) are not likely to be successful if only quantity
data are available due to limited degrees of freedom (see Diewert (1992)).
(ii) The relative efficiency of any single observation will tend to decrease as the sample
size increases. Actually, all three methods have this problem.
(iii) Nonparametric and econometric efficiency scores will tend to decrease (i.e., relative
inefficiencies will tend to increase) as we make stronger assumptions on the underlying
12
technology. Index number estimates of efficiency remain unchanged as we change our
assumptions on the technology.
(iv) Nonparametric and economic efficiency scores will tend to decrease as we make
stronger assumptions about the optimizing behaviour of producers; recall Rule 2 in section
3. It is not clear what will happen to econometric based efficiency scores under the
same conditions. Since index number methods are based on the assumption of complete
optimizing behaviour we cannot vary our assumptions on optimizing behaviour when using
index number methods.
(v) If we hold the number of observations in our sample constant but disaggregate the
data so that the number of inputs or outputs is increased, then nonparametric efficiency
scores will tend to increase22 . However, index number efficiency scores will generally
remain unaffected by increasing disaggregation23 . It is not clear what will happen using
econometric methods.
(vi) The cost of computing index number estimates of relative efficiency is extremely
low; the cost of the nonparametric estimates is low and the cost of computing econometric
estimates can be very high if the number of goods exceeds 10.
(vii) When complete price and quantity data are available, the nonparametric estimates
based on a constant returns to scale technology and complete profit maximizing behaviour
are approximately equal to the corresponding index number estimates. Econometric estimates based on the same assumptions will tend to be similar to the first two sets of
estimates (but much smoother in the time series context).
(viii) Nonparametric techniques can be adapted to deal with situations where input
prices are available but not output prices. Econometric techniques can also deal with this
situation but index number methods cannot be used in this situation.
(ix) Nonparametric methods may be severely biased due to measurement errors; i.e.,
the best or most efficient observation in a DEA study may be best simply because some
output was greatly overstated or some important input was greatly understated. Index
number methods are also subject to measurement errors but econometric methods may be
adapted to deal with gross outliers.
Our overall conclusion is that DEA methods for measuring relative efficiency can be
used profitably in a wide variety of situations when other methods are not practical or are
impossible to use.
13
Footnotes
1. See Hanoch and Rothschild (1972), Diewert (1980) (1981), Diewert and Parkan (1983)
and Varian (1984).
2.
See Farrell (1957), Afriat (1972), Färe and Lovell (1978), and Färe, Grosskopf and
Lovell (1985).
3.
Farrell (1957; 254) was assuming constant returns to scale in this part of his paper.
4.
For material on variable and unit profit functions, see Diewert (1973) (1974) and
Diewert and Wales (1992).
5.
See Mendoza (1989; 25-30).
6. See Mendoza (1989; 30) for a general version of Test 1. The use of linear programming
techniques to calculate nonparametric efficiencies was first suggested by Hoffman (1957;
284) and first used by Farrell and Fieldhouse (1962).
7.
See Mendoza (1989; 44) for a general version of Test 2.
8. If we represent the underlying technology by means of the production function y1 =
f (y2 , x1 , x2 ), assumption (i) implies that f is a quasiconcave function.
9. See Mendoza (1989; 54) for a general version of (4) which she calls Test 3. The one
output quasiconcavity test is due to Hanoch and Rothschild (1972).
10. Mendoza’s (1989; 54) Test 3 can also be modified to model quasiconcave technologies
of the form x1 = g(y1 , y2 , x2 ), where g is now a factor requirements function.
11.
See Mendoza (1989; 67) for a general version of (8) which she calls Test 4.
12.
This is Mendoza’s (1989; 88) Test 7. It is also a special case of her Test 4.
13. These results and the appropriate general test may be found in Mendoza (1989; 78),
which she calls Test 5.
14.
This problem is a special case of Mendoza’s (1989; 78) Test 5.
15.
This problem was not considered in Mendoza’s (1989) thesis.
16. Two index number formulae were used: (i) the Fisher ideal and (ii) the Translog or
Törnqvist formula. These index number methods of measuring productivity change are
described in Diewert (1992).
14
17.
The specific functional form used was Diewert and Wales’ (1987) (1988) (1992)
normalized quadratic with quadratic splines in the time trend. Constant returns to scale
were assumed and the fixed input was the structures and land aggregate.
18. See Mendoza (1989; 111) for a table of these violation indexes. Unfortunately, her
violation indexes are not quite analogous to the βi∗∗ defined by (17) due to her treatment
of intermediate inputs. Suppose that output 2 were an intermediate input. Then (16) and
(17) are still valid where the y2j are now negative numbers. The analogous Mendoza loss
measure εii is obtained by replacing (17) by the following expression that serves to define
εi : [pi1 y1i + pi2 y2i ] − w2i xi2 + [pi1 y1i + pi2 | y2i |]εi. Thus if the loss is positive, Mendoza’s loss
εi will always be less than our βi∗∗ .
19.
These nonparemetric year to year indexes are tables in Mendoza (1989; 114) and
plotted on pages 115-116.
20. The Translog indexes of productivity change are tables on page 120 and the Fisher
indexes are tabled on page 121. These estimates coincide to 4 decimal places (as we expect
from theoretical considerations). The index number estimates of productivity change for
the 4 sectors are compared graphically with the corresponding nonparametric estimates
on pages 122-125.
21.
See footnote 18.
22. As we disaggregate, the objective functions of the various linear programming problems will remain unchanged but the feasible regions for the problems become more constrained or smaller and hence the objective function minimums for the linear programming
problems will become larger. Hence, the loss measures will decrease or remain constant
and thus efficiency will tend to increase as we disaggregate. This point was first made by
Nunamaker (1985). The profit maximization problems (11) and (18) are not affected by
disaggregation.
23. This follows from the approximate consistency in aggregation property of superlative
index number formulae like the Fisher and Translog; see Diewert (1978; 889 and 895).
REFERENCES
Afriat, S.N. (1972), “Efficiency Estimation of Production Function”, International Economic Review 13, 568-598.
Charnes, A. and W.W. Cooper (1985), “Preface to Topics in Data Envelopment Analysis”,
Annals of Operations Research 2, 59-94.
15
Charnes, A., W.W. Cooper and E. Rhodes (1978), “Measuring the Efficiency of Decision
Making Units”, European Journal of Operational Research 2, 429-444.
Debreu, G. (1951), “The Coefficient of Resource Utilization”, Econometrica 19, 273-292.
Diewert, W.E. (1973), “Functional Forms for Profit and Transformation Functions”,
Journal of Economic Theory 6, 284-316.
Diewert, W.E. (1974), “Applications of Duality Theory”, pp. 106-171 in Frontiers of
Quantitative Economics, Volume II, MD.D. Intriligator and D.A. Kendrick (eds.),
Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Company.
Diewert, W.E. (1978), “Superlative Index Numbers and Consistency in Aggregation”,
Econometrica 46, 883-900.
Diewert, W.E. (1980), “Capital and the Theory of Productivity Measurement”, American
Economic Review 70, 260-267.
Diewert, W.E. (1981), “The Theory of Total Factor Productivity Measurement in Regulated Industries”, pp. 17-44 in Productivity Measurement in Regulated Industries,
Tom Cowing and R. Stephenson (eds.), New York: Academic Press.
Diewert, W.E. (1992), “The Measurement of Productivity”, Bulletin of Economic Research
44, 163-198.
Diewert, W.E. and C. Parkan (1983), “Linear Programming Tests of Regularity Conditions
for Production Functions,” pp. 131-158 in Quantitative Studies on Production and
Prices, W. Eichhorn, R. Henn, K. Neumann and R.W. Shephard (eds.), Wien: Physica
Verlag.
Diewert, W.E. and T.J. Wales (1987), “Flexible Functional Forms and Global Curvature
Conditions”, Econometrica 55, 43-68.
Diewert, W.E. and T.J. Wales (1988), “A Normalized Quadratic Semiflexible Functional
Form”, Journal of Econometrics 37, 327-342.
Diewert, W.E. and T.J. Wales (1992), “Quadratic Spline Models for Producer’s Supply
and Demand Functions”, International Economic Review 33, 705-722.
Färe, R. and C.A.K. Lovell (1978), “Measuring the Technical Efficiency of Production”,
Journal of Economic Theory 19, 150-162.
Färe, R., S. Grosskopf and C.A.K. Lovell (1985), The Measurement of Efficiency of
Production, Boston: Kluwer-Nijhoff.
Farrell, M.J. (1957), “The Measurement of Production Efficiency”, Journal of the Royal
Statistical Society, Series A, 120, 253-278.
16
Farrell, M.J. and M. Fieldhouse (1962), “Estimating Efficient Production Functions under
Increasing Returns to Scale”, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series A, 125,
252-267.
Hanoch, G. and M. Rothschild (1972), “Testing the Assumptions of Production Theory:
A Nonparametric Approach”, Journal of Political Economy 80, 256-275.
Hoffman, A.J. (1957), “Discussion Mr. Farrell’s Paper”, Journal of the Royal Statistical
Society, Series A, 120, p. 284.
Mendoza, M.N.F. (1989), Essays in Production Theory: Efficiency Measurement and
Comparative Statistics, Ph.D. Theses, University of British Columbia, Vancouver,
Canada.
Nunamaker, T.R. (1985), “Using Data Envelopment Analysis to Measure the Efficiency
of Non-profit Organisations: A Critical Evaluation”, Managerial and Decision Economics 6, 58-60.
Varian, H.R. (1984), “The Nonparametric Approach to Production Analysis”, Econometrica 52, 579-597.
17