Academia.edu no longer supports Internet Explorer.
To browse Academia.edu and the wider internet faster and more securely, please take a few seconds to upgrade your browser.
The response to the special 2019 issue of Studia Gilsoniana on economics was so positive that it led to the creation of the Aquinas School of Leadership School of Economics (ASLSE). This 2021 publication is, therefore, a second special issue of Studia Gilsoniana on the same theme and the second installment of ASLSE’s economic journals. We are delighted to present here further fruits of thought from the maturing Studia Gilsoniana and ASLSE partnership. Economics is held to be a value-free, scientific enterprise, and as such there can be no relationship between economics and religion. Ayn Rand, a well-known novelist-turned-philosopher, took this position in an unapologetic way in her writings, specifically in her novel Atlas Shrugged. The contrary position to what we might call the Randian “strict separation” thesis holds that economics and religion are related, in some way and to some degree, and therefore should be considered in tandem. The papers in this special edition of Studia Gilsoniana set out to show the extent and quality of the relationship between economics and religion from a variety of viewpoints and historical periods.
Econ Journal Watch, 2014
Professional economics would benefit from an infusion of religious formulations, particularly the notions that all humans are made in God’s image and are fallen creatures. This infusion would lead economics to more openly recognize the role of moral reflection in economic thinking and enhance the way in which economics conceives of the use of knowledge in both the private and public sectors. In addition, particular benefits might be realized in rethinking conceptions of entrepreneurship, competition, and opportunistic behavior. I provide examples of the ways Christian values shape my research agenda as an economist.
Edward Bailey contacted me in September 2014 to review this book, which was formerly unknown to me although my research deals with religion and economics. Edward seemed to have turned to me when he had particularly lengthy books on the topic to review (cf. my review of Philip Goodchild's Capitalism and Religion in IR 15/3), which I chose to understand as a compliment even if it put a heavy strain on a typically overcharged workload. Edward had written to me a few of times since to recall the deadline, apparently pressed by an eager author. I had to miss the deadline and request a delay, and it is with much regret that I have handed this in at the tail end of July 2015, a few months after Edward passed away. I would like to dedicate this to his memory and express my gratitude to him for having been a generous elder and a precious interlocutor over the years, since he first invited me to talk in one of his seminars at Middlesex when I was only a Masters student, and later on to Denton and Oxford. Robert Nelson's book could well have been titled 'Economics as Implicit Religion,' and it is indeed fitting to review it here in IR. The edition at hand of Economics as Religion is a 2014 reissue of the 2001 opus in addition to a short epilogue. It is the second book of a trilogy in which Nelson charts the rise of a 'modern secular religion of economics' that culminates in the twentieth century cultural ideology of the market. In his first volume, Reaching for Heaven on Earth. The Theological Meaning of Economics (Bowman and Little, 1993), Nelson argued that economics became 'the modern theology that .... replaced traditional theology as the set of doctrines that give meaning to our social reality and hope to our endeavors to improving our lives' (quote from Peter Boettke's review, cited in the epilogue p.342). The present volume pursues the task by analysing the works of the major twentieth century American economists to show how professional economists are equivalent to the priesthood of this religion of economics which justify, disseminate and legitimize in scientific discourse 'normative foundations required for a rapidly growing modern economy' (p.8). The third volume, The New Holy Wars : Economic Religion Versus Environmental Religion in Contemporary America (Penn State University Press, 2010), picks up on the argument made at the end of Religion as Economics and details how this religion of progress in economic dress has recently been opposed by a growing counter-religion of environmentalism. After a PhD in economics at Princeton, Nelson worked from 1975 to 1993 as an economic analysist in the Office of Policy Analysis of the US Secretary of the Interior, where he started realizing that the policy debates which he assisted and in which he participated were more normative than purely scientific, in other words that they were 'religious in character', and that this contradicted the pretentions of his disciplinary alma mater. He therefore embarked upon the project of enquiring into what he calls the 'theological foundations of modern economics' (p.xviii), a task he has since pursued as professor at the School of Public Policy of the University of Maryland. Although the whole of Nelson's enterprise rests on the argument that what passes for scientific and secular is in fact religious, his definition of religion is vague and the conceptual discussion poor when compared to the numerous detailed discussions that make up the volume. The elements of definition are scattered in the introductory section, where religion is said to be 'about making claims to truth', as well as 'about changing people to make them better understand the truth as it is seen by the initiated and thereby also changing their behavior' (p.xviii). Nelson also makes an oblique reference to a Supreme Court judgement which itself refers to Paul Tillich's conception of religion as expressing individual's ultimate concerns (p.xxiv). At the same time, the 'science' of economics is said to serve the 'social functions of religion' (p.xviii), which we imagine have something to do with legitimizing values and proposing a path for salvation (p.xx). Professional economists are said 'to serve as the priesthood of a modern secular religion of economic progress that serves sic many of the same functions in contemporary society as earlier Christian and other religions did in their time', defending 'economic efficiency' as the 'core value' and the 'greatest source of social legitimacy in the United States for the past century'. Overall and essentially, the argument revolves around the idea of religion as a system of foundational values and metaphysical underpinnings. One could summarize the argument by saying that secularization did not happen, or rather that it happened in a sense, but only as a transfer towards a new religion of economic progress (p.x) : 'The economics profession, .... is the priesthood of a powerful secular religionnor more accurately a set of secular religions, as they have been developed in the theories of the leading schools of economics of the modern age. Beneath the surface of their formal economic theorizing, economists are engaged in an act of delivering religious messages. Correctly understood, these messages are seen to be promises of the true path to a salvation in this worlddto a new heaven on earth. Because this path follows along a route of economic progresswith the technical understanding to show the way, it falls to the members of the economics profession (assisted by other social scientists) to assume the traditional role of the priesthood.' (p.xxi) The book therefore argues that the modern religion of progress was successfully reinterpreted in essentially economic terms by neo-classical liberal economics and its twentieth century avatars. In this perspective, the modern shift towards inner-worldly salvation aimed the end of material scarcity and the arrival of an era of abundance guaranteed by economic growth. Nelson threads his analysis of twentieth century economics with a rather well known narrative of Western modernization (cf. pp.266-7). By the modern age, the Christian religion has progressively lost its authority in public life and consequently did its morality cease to effectively restraint the pursuit of self-interest. This authority was transferred to science, which henceforth appeared to be the preferred vehicle for the investigation of God's Laws of Nature, and therefore as the dispenser of valid truth. Social sciences followed step and imposed themselves as the legitimate actors for the regulation of society. The discipline of economics was particularly prompt to present itself, since the times of Adam Smith (and even prior, in the works of the French Physiocrats, not mentioned by the author) as the social scientific equivalent of physics in the social sciences. In what are some of the best pages in the book, Nelson recalls in chapter 10 ('God Bless the Market') how Newtonian physics provided the template for eighteenth century economics and the Darwinian idea of the survival of the fittest in the nineteenth. Unable to follow physics' quantum and relativity revolutions, economics in the last century has continued to nourish the pretention of being the physics of social sciences, accompanied by an increasing (ab)use of mathematics. The bulk of the book charts the evolution of American economics from the works of Cambridge professor Paul Samuelson to the neoliberal free
The separation of Church and state is a myth. Politicians solicit the support of religious groups for election is only one example. Additionally, religion and economics are intertwined because in reality America is a country that has interdependent relationships between economics, politics, sociology, social relationships, education and religion. This paper makes an argument addressing the relationship between religion and economics in America. Also this paper identifies the inconsistency and ambiguities in Christianity. Christianity is inconsistent in America; not so much in the doctrines but in the way it is practiced and interpreted to congregations by ministers.
Economist Netherlands, 2005
This paper provides an overview of the relationship between economics and religion. It first considers the effects of economic incentives in the religious marketplace on consumers' demand for "religion." It then shows how this demand affects religious institutions and generates a supply of religious goods and services. Other topics include the structure of this religious marketplace and the related "marketplace for ideas" in a religiously pluralistic society. Empirical evidence is summarized for the effects on selected economic behaviors of religious affiliation and intensity of belief or practice.
Econ Journal Watch, 2014
Mainstream economics is constrained by methodological individualism, which ignores many aspects of human existence and interaction. Methodological individualism itself propagates certain attitudes and outlooks that can become self-fulfilling by channelling human behaviour into the simplistic straitjacket of self-interest. A sense of ethics and therefore of spirituality is necessary to understand the complexities of human and social behaviour as well as to ground economic policy advice in a fundamental morality.
2002
Throughout the human history, the religion has remained a fundamental feature of social construct and human behaviour. Religious orientation plays important role in shaping human perceptions about economic and non-economic activities. With few exceptions, religion has remained an un-explored area in economics. For most economists, narrative and metaphor have no place in a rational choice theory, which is a wrong belief. In fact, any approach that considers behavioural laws satisfying the criteria of objectivity, reproducibility, and refutability is scientific and falls in purview of rational choice framework. A few studies, however, do exist on economics of religion under rational choice concerning to households, groups, and entire “religious markets”. [Becker (1976); Iannaccone (1988, 1990, 1992, 1993); Mack and Leigland (1992)]. Rosenberg (1985) presents discussion of the limitations of neoclassical economic theory due to its reliance on exogenous differences in taste and preferen...
Religious Studies Review, 2020
Case Western Reserve law review, 2006
As the title suggests, this extended essay is a critique of mainstream economic theory (neoclassical and neo-Keynesian), which serves the function of a theology for the Capitalist religion -- a rationalization and legitimization of capitalist accumulation. The economics faculty constitute a secular priesthood with its own arcane form of self-referential theological discourse. The essay examines the discursive and institutional practices which systematically distort genuine understanding of the economic system in a way that rationalizes capitalist production.
Religion and Economics, 2020
The use of general descriptive names, registered names, trademarks, service marks, etc. in this publication does not imply, even in the absence of a specific statement, that such names are exempt from the relevant protective laws and regulations and therefore free for general use. The publisher, the authors and the editors are safe to assume that the advice and information in this book are believed to be true and accurate at the date of publication. Neither the publisher nor the authors or the editors give a warranty, expressed or implied, with respect to the material contained herein or for any errors or omissions that may have been made. The publisher remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Renewal, 2019
LAUREA IIII. Античний світ і Середні віки : Читання пам’яті професора Володимира Івановича Кадєєва. — Харків: «Контраст», 2021., 2021
Journal of Islamic Law Research, 2024
Socio – economic and legal dimensions of digital transformation. Selected contexts, 2021
Proceedings of the International Conference on Business Excellence
Nature Communications, 2018
The Journal of Chemical Physics, 2002
Roczniki Pedagogiczne, 2020
Journal of Exercise Rehabilitation, 2019
Bioconjugate Chemistry, 2010
Indian journal of physiology and pharmacology