econstor
A Service of
zbw
Leibniz-Informationszentrum
Wirtschaft
Make Your Publications Visible.
Leibniz Information Centre
for Economics
Schnabel, Isabel; Körner, Tobias
Conference Paper
Abolishing Public Guarantees in the Absence of
Market Discipline
Beiträge zur Jahrestagung des Vereins für Socialpolitik 2012: Neue Wege und
Herausforderungen für den Arbeitsmarkt des 21. Jahrhunderts - Session: Banking and
Public Policy, No. E15-V3
Provided in Cooperation with:
Verein für Socialpolitik / German Economic Association
Suggested Citation: Schnabel, Isabel; Körner, Tobias (2012) : Abolishing Public Guarantees
in the Absence of Market Discipline, Beiträge zur Jahrestagung des Vereins für Socialpolitik
2012: Neue Wege und Herausforderungen für den Arbeitsmarkt des 21. Jahrhunderts -
Session: Banking and Public Policy, No. E15-V3, ZBW - Deutsche Zentralbibliothek für
Wirtschaftswissenschaften, Leibniz-Informationszentrum Wirtschaft
This Version is available at:
http://hdl.handle.net/10419/65401
Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use:
Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your
Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes.
Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial
Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them
machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise
use the documents in public.
Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen
(insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open
gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you
genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated
licence.
www.econstor.eu
Abolishing Public Guarantees in the
Absence of Market Discipline†
Tobias Körner∗
Ruhr Graduate School in Economics
Isabel Schnabel∗∗
University of Mainz, CEPR, and MPI Bonn
March 1, 2012
Abstract:
This paper shows that the abolition of state guarantees to publicly owned banks in Ger-
many resulted in an increase in refinancing costs at German savings banks. Rather than
being the result of increased market discipline, the increase in refinancing costs is shown
to be driven by spillover effects from German Landesbanken who themselves had suffered
from the abolition of guarantees and who spread their own cost increase through the
public banking network. Higher refinancing costs and the resulting drop in bank charter
values translated into higher risk-taking at German savings banks.
Keywords: Public bail-out guarantees; savings banks; Landesbanken; market discipline;
bank risk-taking; banking networks.
JEL Classification: G21, G28, H11, L32.
†
We thank Thomas Bauer, Daniel Baumgarten, Hendrik Hakenes, Alfredo Paloyo, Christoph Schmidt,
and Hendrik Schmitz for their valuables comments and suggestions. We also benefited from comments
by participants of the RGS Workshop at RWI Essen. Financial support from the Leibniz Association
through RGS Econ and from the Fazit foundation is gratefully acknowledged.
∗
Address: Ruhr Graduate School in Economics c/o RWI Essen, Hohenzollernstraße 1-3, 45128 Essen,
Germany, phone +49-201-8149-517, tobias.koerner@rwi-essen.de.
∗∗
Address: Gutenberg School of Management and Economics, Johannes Gutenberg University Mainz,
55099 Mainz, Germany, phone +49-6131-39-24191, fax +49-6131-39-25588, e-mail isabel.schnabel@uni-
mainz.de. Corresponding author.
1 Introduction
In the recent financial crisis, large-scale bail-outs of banks occurred in all major banking
systems. This raised expectations that banks, especially systemic ones, can rely on gov-
ernment support in times of crisis. Such bail-out expectations are a concern for policy
makers and economists. They may reduce market discipline, give rise to excessive risk-
taking and distort competition in the banking sector. However, the empirical effects of
such guarantees are still not well understood because bail-out guarantees are hard to mea-
sure, especially if they are not explicit, but implicit (such as too-big-to-fail guarantees).1
In this paper, we try to shed more light on these issues by analyzing the effects of the
abolishment of explicit public guarantees to publicly owned banks – savings banks and
Landesbanken (state banks) – in Germany in the year 2001 (the ‘Brussels agreement’).
Our paper focuses on the effect of the reform on German savings banks’ refinancing costs
and risk-taking.2 Generally, the abolishment of public guarantees affects banks through
two different channels. The immediate effect is an increase in funding costs, translating
into lower margins and charter values. As high charter values tend to deter banks from
taking excessive risks, risk-taking incentives increase when charter values drop (see Keeley,
1990; Hellmann, Murdock, and Stiglitz, 2000). However, there is a countervailing effect
on risk-taking. In the absence of guarantees, bank creditors are no longer insulated from
losses. Therefore, they become more responsive to the banks’ individual risk profiles.
They exert “market discipline” by demanding higher risk premia or limiting banks’ access
to external finance.3 Higher market discipline should reduce risk-taking incentives. The
overall effect of an abolition of guarantees on banks’ risk-taking is thus ambiguous (see
Cordella and Yeyati, 2003; Hakenes and Schnabel, 2010).
We argue in this paper that these general predictions do not fully apply to German savings
banks who are part of a public banking network with a division of labor between Lan-
desbanken and savings banks. Whereas Landesbanken refinance largely through capital
1
An attempt to measure implicit guarantees was made by Gropp, Hakenes, and Schnabel (2011) who
show that bail-out guarantees also distort risk-taking incentives of banks that are not protected by explicit
or implicit government guarantees, but are standing in competition with protected banks.
2
Two recent studies analyze the same policy experiment. Whereas Fischer, Hainz, Rocholl, and Steffen
(2011) analyze the reaction of Landesbanken, Gropp, Gruendl, and Guettler (2011) focus on the reaction
of savings banks, just as we do. Both papers are discussed in more detail below.
3
Market discipline in banking has been analyzed, among others, by Flannery (1998), Flannery and
Sorescu (1996), Sironi (2003), and Gropp, Vesala, and Vulpes (2006).
1
markets and act as money center banks in the public banking network, savings banks are
locally operating retail banks. For a Landesbank refinancing in national and international
capital markets, explicit government guarantees are reflected immediately in lower bond
rates. In contrast, German savings banks rely mainly on customer deposit funding. As
most depositors are insured by deposit protection schemes, an additional protection in
the form of public guarantees is of minor importance and may not even be reflected in
deposit rates. Therefore, it is far from clear why an abolition of guarantees should have a
direct effect on savings banks’ funding costs. For the same reason, one would not expect
an increase in market discipline. Hence, the direct consequences of the abolishment of
public guarantees on savings banks are expected to be small.
However, Landesbanken and savings banks are connected through lending relationships
and ownership structures. Therefore, rising funding costs (and also higher risk-taking)
of Landesbanken after the abolition of guarantees may spill over to the corresponding
savings banks. In this way, risk-taking incentives of retail banks are altered, too, although
most of their creditors are not sensitive to the abolition of guarantees. While affecting
refinancing conditions of savings banks, the market discipline exerted through this channel
is likely to be small. Therefore, the indirect effects constitute a pure charter value effect,
unambiguously leading to increased risk-taking incentives of savings banks.
We test this line of reasoning using a difference-in-differences approach. We first analyze
the impact of the Brussels agreement on overall refinancing costs by comparing savings
banks with a control group of German cooperative banks who are similar to savings banks
in terms of network structures but who were never subject to public guarantees. Then,
to assess the impact of network structures, we make use of two distinct features of the
public banking network. First, savings banks are group-wise associated with their regional
Landesbank. Second, Landesbanken are heterogeneous, and the impact of the abolition of
guarantees on their funding costs varies considerably. This is reflected in different issuer
rating downgrades of Landesbanken announced by major rating agencies in face of the
abolition of guarantees. Our research design exploits this variation by defining subgroups
of savings banks with differing issuer rating downgrades of associated Landesbanken. By
comparing the refinancing costs of the different subgroups of savings banks before and
after the abolition of guarantees, we test whether charter value losses at Landesbanken
were transmitted to savings banks. We also check whether funding cost changes were
related to savings banks’ risk profiles, as would be expected in the presence of market
discipline. Finally, we analyze how banks’ risk-taking was affected by the reform.
2
The comparison between savings banks and (unguaranteed) cooperative banks reveals
that savings banks saw a rise in refinancing costs relative to cooperative banks after the
policy intervention. Moreover, the results support the presence of indirect effects through
banking networks. Within the group of savings banks, those with more severely down-
graded Landesbanken experienced a stronger increase in refinancing costs after the Brus-
sels agreement than savings banks with less severely downgraded Landesbanken. At the
same time, the increase in refinancing costs does not depend on variables measuring indi-
vidual bank risk of savings banks, contradicting the market discipline hypothesis. Finally,
consistent with the theoretical prediction, savings banks with more severely downgraded
Landesbanken increased their risk-taking relative to other savings banks.
The regression results imply that the abolition of public guarantees depressed the charter
values of German savings banks. However, this was not driven by their creditors demand-
ing higher risk premia. Despite the abolition of guarantees, the creditors of savings banks
still did not impose market discipline on savings banks. Rather, charter values of savings
banks appear to have been driven by their relationship to Landesbanken. Through the
public banking network, the drop in the charter values of Landesbanken spilled over to the
corresponding savings banks. In the absence of market discipline, reduced charter values
gave rise to higher risk-taking of savings banks. More generally, our paper highlights that
the effects of public guarantees – and of their removal – depend crucially on the structure
of banking systems.
Our paper is related to the large empirical literature on the incentive effects of bail-out
guarantees. A number of papers analyze the effects of implicit guarantees towards too-big-
to-fail banks on banks’ risk-taking. While some papers document excessive risk-taking at
such banks (Boyd and Runkle, 1993; Boyd and Gertler, 1994; Schnabel, 2009), others do
not find evidence of higher risk-taking of banks benefiting from public guarantees (Gropp,
Hakenes, and Schnabel, 2011). These mixed results can be explained by the ambiguity in
the theoretical predictions (see Cordella and Yeyati, 2003; Hakenes and Schnabel, 2010).
Another strand of the literature deals with the effects of deposit insurance on banks’ risk-
taking. Overall, this literature supports the view that deposit insurance induces excessive
risk-taking (Merton, 1977; Hovakimian and Kane, 2000; Demirguc-Kunt and Detragiache,
2002; Gropp and Vesala, 2004).
The papers most closely related to ours are two recent studies exploiting the same policy
reform as we do in order to identify the effects of public guarantees on banks’ risk-taking.
3
Interestingly, the two papers reach opposing conclusions. Fischer, Hainz, Rocholl, and
Steffen (2011) analyze the impact of the Brussels agreement on the risk-taking and loan
rates of German Landesbanken. They compare syndicated loans before and after 2001,
the date of the Brussels agreement. After 2001, the quality of loans where Landesbanken
acted as lead arrangers declined relative to a control sample of loans with other banks
as lead arrangers. The effect is particularly strong for Landesbanken with the highest
expected decrease in charter values. This indicates that Landesbanken increased risk-
taking due to the abolition of guarantees. The finding is consistent with evidence that
Landesbanken suffered particularly high losses during the subprime crisis (Hau and Thum,
2009), originating from investments following the Brussels agreement. Fischer, Hainz,
Rocholl, and Steffen (2011) do not discuss the potential effect of the abolition of guarantees
on market discipline. However, their results suggest that, even after 2005, the charter
value effect dominated the market discipline effect.
The paper by Gropp, Gruendl, and Guettler (2011) studies the effect of the Brussels
agreement on German savings banks, using a rich data set of savings banks’ corporate loan
customers. They document a reduction in the credit risk of savings banks’ customers after
2001. The effect is most pronounced for savings banks who were taking higher risks before
2001 and who presumably benefited most from public guarantees before the abolition.
The authors interpret these findings as an indication of greater market discipline after the
abolition of guarantees. Taken together with the results by Fischer, Hainz, Rocholl, and
Steffen (2011), this result is surprising, as – if anything – market discipline effects would
have been expected for Landesbanken whose liabilities are more risk-sensitive than those
of savings banks.4
Our own results are more in line with those by Fischer, Hainz, Rocholl, and Steffen (2011).
Just as that paper, our results stress the importance of charter value effects. Our paper
emphasizes that losses in charter values may spill over to other connected banks even if
those banks are not (or not strongly) affected themselves by the abolition of guarantees.
Such effects have to be taken into account by policy makers when designing an exit
strategy from the implicit guarantees built up during the recent crisis. An abolition of
guarantees is likely to lead to strong charter value effects, which affect not only the banks
4
Both Fischer, Hainz, Rocholl, and Steffen (2011) and Gropp, Gruendl, and Guettler (2011) focus on
the year 2001 (the date of the Brussels agreement) in their analyses. As is discussed in more detail in
Section 2, the actual abolition of guarantees took place no earlier than 2005. Therefore, one would not
expect strong market discipline effects before the reform came into effect.
4
themselves, but also banks connected to them through banking networks.
The paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2, we discuss the institutional background
and develop hypotheses to be tested in the empirical analysis. In the following sections,
we present the empirical analysis. In each section, we start by presenting the empirical
approach before showing and interpreting regression results. In Section 3, we analyze
the effect of the abolition of public guarantees on the overall refinancing costs of savings
banks, using cooperative banks as a control group in a difference-in-differences framework.
In Section 4, we test for the presence of indirect effects through regional banking networks.
In Section 5, we ask whether the reform led to an increase in market discipline for German
savings banks. Finally, we evaluate the effect of the reform on savings banks’ risk-taking
in Section 6. Section 7 concludes.
2 Institutions and Hypotheses
In the following, we examine two potential channels through which the removal of ex-
plicit public guarantees might have affected German savings banks: a direct channel that
presumes that savings banks’ creditors demand higher risk premia to compensate for
increased insolvency risks; and an indirect channel working through savings banks’ rela-
tionships with Landesbanken, who faced higher refinancing costs in capital markets after
the abolition of explicit support mechanism by the government. We start by describing
the institutional and network structures of savings banks and Landesbanken and then
outline the institutional details of the German banking reform leading to the abolition of
public guarantees. Based on the institutional background, we develop several hypotheses
that will be tested in the empirical analysis.
2.1 Germany’s Public Banking Network
Savings banks and Landesbanken belong to a network of state-owned financial institutions
that operates under the brand Sparkassen-Finanzgruppe. As of year-end 2010, the network
comprised 429 savings banks, 8 Landesbanken groups, and numerous specialized financial
institutions, such as mortgage banks and insurance companies. Most companies belonging
to the network are autonomous legal entities. There exists no top-to-bottom hierarchy,
5
but network companies are connected through memberships in regional and federal sav-
ings banks associations, direct and indirect capital holdings, and personal linkages, such
as multiple executive positions and informal career networks (Wittmann, 2004). For in-
stance, savings banks hold shares in the Landesbank of their region via the regional savings
banks associations. Therefore, the executives of the regional savings banks associations
and savings banks managers often hold supervisory board seats at their Landesbank.
In terms of assets and number of employees, savings banks and Landesbanken form the
most important part of the network. At the end of 2010, savings banks held assets
of about 1.1 trillion assets Euro and employed about 260.000 employees, whereas the
Landesbanken groups together held assets of 1.5 trillion Euros and employed some 49.000
employees. Thus, savings banks and Landesbanken hold the major share in the aggregated
business volume and total number of employees of Sparkassen-Finanzgruppe, which are
reported as 3.3 trillion Euro and 363.000, respectively.5 Savings banks and Landesbanken
together account for 30.5 percent of total assets of all German banks.6
Savings banks are locally or regionally operating universal banks chartered under public
law.7 Only municipalities are allowed to charter savings banks. The business activities
of savings banks are restricted by law to the geographical boundaries of the chartering
municipalities (‘regional principle’). Savings banks are supposed to support the munic-
ipalities in their duties in the economic, social and cultural sphere. They also serve as
Hausbanks to the municipalities. Until mid-year 2005, municipalities were fully liable to
the creditors of savings banks. As a consequence of the close ties between savings banks
and municipalities, the municipal parliaments are responsible for appointing the supervi-
sory board members of their savings bank. Many of the board members are members of
the parliaments themselves, and often they are believed to be closely associated with the
governing parties. In spite of these strong associations with municipalities, savings banks
are universal banks, which do not differ from their private competitors with regard to their
business operations. They are allowed to engage in any kind of banking business. The
cornerstone of their business model is retail banking; customer deposits are their most
important refinancing source, and medium- and long-term loans to private households
and firms dominate the asset side.
5
Figures are taken from DSGV (2011a).
6
The ratio was calculated on the basis of Deutsche Bundesbank (2011).
7
There also exist 6 non-public law savings banks that are historically organized as private-law stock
corporations.
6
Corresponding to the three-level structure of governmental bodies in Germany, which com-
prises the federal level (Bund), federal states (Länder), and municipalities, Landesbanken
form the second level in Germany’s public banking system. Landesbanken are directly
owned by the states and indirectly, through the regional savings banks associations, by
the savings banks.8 In contrast to savings banks, the business area of Landesbanken is
not geographically restricted by law. Within Germany, Landesbanken usually define the
geographical area of the respective state as their core business district. Although there is
a considerable degree of heterogeneity with regard to core business fields, specialization,
and internationalization, all Landesbanken groups can be defined as large, internationally
active wholesale banks (see Hackethal, 2004).9
The focus of Landesbanken on international markets and wholesale banking follows partly
from the division of labor between Landesbanken and savings banks. Landesbanken and
savings banks are not supposed to compete with each other. Rather, subsidiarity is
the central organizing principle of Sparkassen-Finanzgruppe (Wittmann, 2004). Savings
banks focus on retail banking in their home municipalities, whereas Landesbanken provide
loans and financial services to large corporate customers and seek refinancing predomi-
nantly in national and international interbank and capital markets.
Cooperation between Landesbanken and savings banks thus emerges from the natural ca-
pacity limits of savings banks and from the original role of Landesbanken as distributors
of liquidity among savings banks. For example, Landesbanken take over corporate cus-
tomers that have grown too large or have gone international. Also, Landesbanken act as
lead arrangers of syndicated loans for savings banks. More generally, they provide finan-
cial services and products for savings banks and savings banks’ customers that would be
too costly for single savings banks to produce. Furthermore, Landesbanken traditionally
serve as liquidity pools for the network banks. In this regard, savings banks deposit excess
liquidity at Landesbanken, and Landesbanken in turn grant credit lines to savings banks.
8
Originally, each West-German state had its own Landesbank. After reunification, the new Länder,
instead of chartering their own Landesbank, became shareholders of existing Landesbanken; the only
exception is Saxony, which founded SachsenLB in 1992. Due to mergers, integrations and majority
shareholdings among Landesbanken, the number of autonomous Landesbanken groups has been reduced
to 8.
9
With regard to internationalization, some Landesbanken are mainly active in neighboring countries,
whereas others understand themselves as global players. Some Landesbanken have access to retail de-
posits, while others depend mainly on wholesale funding. Some have specialized in certain business fields
such as ship and airplane finance (HSH Nordbank, NordLB), real estate finance (NordLB, LBB), or credit
cards (LBB), see Berger (2008).
7
As savings banks are legally and organizationally autonomous institutions, they are not
obliged to engage in any interbank relationship, neither with their associated Landesbank,
nor with any other Landesbank of the network. However, with regard to interbank lending,
evidence suggests that for the majority of savings banks Landesbanken appear to be the
preferred contracting partners (see Upper and Worms, 2004). This applies particularly
to the associated Landesbanken, i. e. those Landesbanken that are owned by the savings
banks of their region. As of year-end 2000, Landesbanken lent EUR 121.7 billion to
associated savings banks, which amounts to 60.8 percent of all liabilities of savings banks
to domestic banks (excluding Deutsche Bundesbank).10
2.2 The Abolition of Public Guarantees
Until 19 July 2005, the creditors of savings banks and Landesbanken were protected by
two explicit governmental support mechanisms, Anstaltslast and Gewährträgerhaftung.
Anstaltslast, often referred to as ‘maintenance obligation,’ is the obligation of the owners
of public banks to continuously enable their banks to fulfill their functions. This implied
a governmental bail-out guarantee for public banks: distressed savings banks were to be
bailed out by the chartering municipalities, and distressed Landesbanken by the states. It
did not imply an obligation for municipalities or states to run a distressed or unprofitable
bank forever. If, however, the municipalities or states decided to dissolve their bank, the
second support mechanism, Gewährträgerhaftung or ‘guarantor liability’ were to become
effective. According to guarantor liability, the municipalities are directly liable to the
creditors of savings banks that are not able to meet their financial obligations. Likewise,
the states are directly liable to the creditors of Landesbanken. Thus, taken together
these support mechanisms implied a very low if not ignorable default risk for creditors of
savings banks and Landesbanken. Creditors could lose money due to a bank failure only if
a Land or municipality defaulted on its debt – an event that is considered highly unlikely
due to explicit and implicit mutual support commitments of the federal government, the
states, and the municipalities (see Immenga and Rudo, 1998, p. 21). In the past, only
Anstaltslast has been of practical relevance, in particular with regard to Landesbanken,
which repeatedly benefited from capital injections by the states.11
10
Figures are calculated on the basis of the financial reports of Landesbanken and on the basis of
Deutsche Bundesbank (2001).
11
See Wiesel (2002) for examples of bail-outs of Landesbanken and savings banks.
8
There has been a long-standing debate whether public guarantees to Germany’s public
banking sector distort competition and thus should be abolished. In particular, it was
discussed whether the guarantees were in line with European competition law. Finally, on
December 21, 1999, the European Banking Federation, a lobby group of European banks,
filed a complaint against the Federal Republic of Germany at the European Commission,
arguing that the public guarantees are state aid that is incompatible with Article 87 of
the EC Treaty. In a proposal to the German government from 8 May 2001, the European
Commission made clear that it considered the public guarantees incompatible with the
EC Treaty. On 17 July 2001, the European Commission and the German government
agreed that maintenance obligation and guarantor liability were to be abolished by 18
July 2005. Furthermore, the agreement included a grandfathering clause according to
which liabilities existing on 18 July 2001 would continue to be covered by guarantor
liability. Besides, liabilities created between 18 July 2001 and 18 July 2005 would be
covered by guarantor liability only if they matured before year-end 2015.
Table 1: Issuer ratings of Landesbanken
Issuer rating before Shadow Downgrade Associated with
July 18, 2005 rating in notches savings banks in
HSH Nordbank AG AAA A 5 Hamburg
Schleswig-Holstein
Bremer Landesbank AAA A 5 Bremen
Lower Saxony (North-West)
NORD/LB AAA A 5 Lower Saxony (North-East, South)
Mecklenburg-Vorpommern
Saxony-Anhalt
WestLB AG AAA A– 6 North Rhine-Westphalia
Brandenburg
Helaba AAA A 5 Hesse
Thuringia
SachsenLB AAA A– 6 Saxony
LRP AAA BBB+ 7 Rhineland-Palatinate
LBBW AAA A+ 4 Baden-Württemberg
SaarLB AAA A 5 Saarland
BayernLB AAA A+ 4 Bavaria
Notes: The table shows the issuer ratings of Landesbanken before 18 July 2005 and issuer ratings announced on 01 July 2004
to be valid after 18 July 2005 (‘shadow ratings’; source: Fitch Ratings, press release from 1 July 2004). Furthermore, the
table shows the savings bank regions associated with the given Landesbanken.
Much of the political discussion about the consequences of the abolition of guarantees
9
for Germany’s public banking network revolved around the Landesbanken.12 The reason
is that Landesbanken predominantly rely on capital market funding and that lenders in
capital markets were expected to demand higher risk premia to compensate for the loss of
explicit government support. In fact, these expectations were mirrored in issuer ratings of
Landesbanken that were published by leading rating agencies in July 2004, one year before
the actual abolition of guarantees. The rating agency Fitch Ratings downgraded the AAA
issuer ratings of Landesbanken by 4 to 7 notches (see Table 1).13 This demonstrates that,
in the absence of explicit government support mechanisms, the liabilities of Landesbanken
were considered much riskier. Moreover, the heterogeneity in downgrades reveals that the
perceived default risk varied considerably among Landesbanken.
The issuer rating downgrades imply that the Brussels agreement constituted a substan-
tial loss in the charter values of Landesbanken. This is also documented by many media
reports, interviews and comments of industry experts that emphasized the historic di-
mensions of the agreement and the fundamental threat that it posed to the traditional
business model of Landesbanken. It is difficult, however, to pin down exact figures. Look-
ing at funding costs just before and after 18 July 2005 is misleading because Landesbanken
utilized the grandfathering clause to raise high volumes of government guaranteed funds
in the years before 2005 (see Fischer, Hainz, Rocholl, and Steffen, 2011). Therefore, there
was no need for Landesbanken to issue unsecured debt in the second half of the year 2005
or in 2006. Furthermore, it is occasionally reported that funding costs of Landesbanken
increased already before 2005. Thus, a before-after-comparison around July 2005 tends to
underestimate the true effect of the abolition of guarantees on the funding costs of Lan-
desbanken. Nevertheless, a comparison of interest rates on Landesbanken bonds might
give some indication of the actual increase in funding costs. Based on issues of BayernLB
and HSH Nordbank in February 2007, industry analysts estimate that interest rates rose
by 10 (senior unsecured debt) to 20 base points (subordinated debt) due to the abolition
of guarantees.14 It is emphasized, however, that spreads of corporate bonds generally
were very low at that time and that the reported numbers were likely to be still higher in
12
For example, Bundesbank board member Edgar Meister stated that the abolition of guarantees
predominantly affects Landesbanken (Börsen-Zeitung, 16 July 2005).
13
Fitch announced even earlier that Landesbanken will be downgraded from AAA to the single A range
due to the abolition of guarantees (Fitch Ratings, 2003). Likewise, Standard & Poor’s developed counter-
factual ratings for Landesbanken already at an earlier stage, ranging from BBB to A, see Handelsblatt,
November 14, 2003, ‘Landesbanken droht Rating-Schock.’
14
See Börsen-Zeitung, 22 March 2007, ‘Trend zu engeren Spreads kommt Instituten zugute.’
10
regimes with higher spreads.
In contrast to Landesbanken, the implications of the abolition of guarantees for the fund-
ing costs of savings banks are less obvious. The principal reason is that funding of savings
banks – as implied by the division of labor between savings banks and Landesbanken –
relies mainly on customer deposit funding. As of year-end 2000, customer deposits ac-
counted for 60.7 percent of total assets of savings banks (see Figure 1).15 Since depositors
are largely insulated from losses by legally mandated depositor protection schemes, it has
been conjectured that they will hardly be responsive to the abolition of guarantees (Ger-
man Council of Economic Experts, 2004, esp. pp. 374). In particular, it seems unlikely
that depositors asked for higher interest rates on savings products to compensate for the
loss of government back-up.
Other sources of external funding for savings banks are interbank loans and bonds payable
to the bearer. As the share of bonds in total assets at year-end 2000 amounted to only
4.8 percent (see Figure 1), the importance of bonds is relatively limited. Besides, bonds
are often sold as savings products to private customers.16 Therefore, the majority of
bondholders enjoy the same protection as depositors.17
Finally, lending from banks accounted for 24.4 percent of savings banks’ total assets (see
Figure 1). According to Güde (1995), this balance sheet position is composed of quite
diverse types of liabilities that differ with regard to creditors, maturities, and motivation
for borrowing. For example, savings banks distribute loans from public development banks
to participants of development programs. Moreover, and more importantly in our context,
savings banks call on credit lines from Landesbanken to compensate temporary liquidity
shortages (Güde, 1995, p. 275). Finally, savings banks take out medium- and long-term
bank loans for funding purposes. In this regard, bank loans improve the maturity match
of liabilities (typically short-term customer deposits) and assets (typically medium- to
15
Here and in the following, we report the early figures instead of more recent ones because the situation
at the time of the Brussels agreement is more relevant for understanding the potential impact of the
agreement on savings banks.
16
In 2010, 25.2 percent of bonds payable to the bearer were sold to monetary financial institutions,
whereas 74.8 percent where sold to other clients (DSGV, 2011b).
17
Solvency and liquidity of the banks of Sparkassen-Finanzgruppe is supposed to be ensured by 11
regional guarantee funds of savings banks as well as two guarantee funds of Landesbanken and mortgage
banks (‘Institutssicherung’). If required, these funds grant mutual support to each other (‘Haftungsver-
bund’). The statutes of the guarantee funds for savings banks imply that the protection of bond holding
customers is given the same priority as the protection of depositors, see Art. 2, Mustersatzung für die
Sparkassenstützungsfonds der Regionalverbände.
11
Figure 1: Aggregate balance sheet of savings banks
Assets Liabilities
Cash and balances at
central banks: 2.0%
Loans to banks: 7.6%
Liabilities to banks: 24.4%
Loans to non-banks: 60.1%
Liabilities to non-banks: 60.7%
Bonds and other fixed-income
securities: 19.8%
B d 4
Bonds: 4.8%
8%
Shares and other non-fixed Subordinated debt: 1.6%
income securities: 6.0% Other liabilities: 4.3%
Other assets: 4.4% Capital: 4.2%
Notes: The figure shows the share of aggregate balance sheet positions in
total aggregate assets of savings banks in percent as of year-end 2000. Total
aggregate assets amounted to EUR 953.9 billion. Source: Own calculations
based on Deutsche Bundesbank (2001).
long-term customer loans) and thus enable savings banks to meet regulatory liquidity
requirements (see, e.g. Hackethal, 2004, p. 82).18
The German banking reform constitutes a natural experiment, which can be exploited
for identification. The reform affected only a subset of German banks, which enables us
to use a difference-in-differences approach. Moreover, within the group of treated banks,
not all subjects were treated to the same extent, suggesting varying treatment intensities.
Importantly, the reform was forced upon Germany by the EU Commission, therefore it
can be treated as exogenous.
18
As of year-end 2000, the share of medium- to long-term loans from banks in total liabilities to domestic
banks (excluding Deutsche Bundesbank) amounted to 89.8 percent (Deutsche Bundesbank, 2001). This
figure also includes forwarded loans of public development banks.
12
2.3 Hypotheses
We now formulate several hypotheses on the potential effects of the abolition of guarantees
on German savings banks. The theoretical literature stresses two types of effects of public
guarantees, both working through the banks’ refinancing conditions (see, for example,
Cordella and Yeyati, 2003; Hakenes and Schnabel, 2010). First, guarantees imply lower
refinancing costs because investors require no (or lower) risk premia as compensation
for default risk. Second, guarantees reduce investors’ incentives to differentiate between
riskier and less riskier banks, and hence to exert market discipline. Therefore, an abolition
of public guarantees should raise refinancing costs. The rise should be more pronounced
for riskier than for safer banks. This leads us to the first two hypotheses.
Hypothesis 1 (Refinancing Costs) The abolition of state guarantees led to an in-
crease in refinancing costs at German savings banks.
This first hypothesis leaves it open why savings banks’ refinancing costs increased. It is
compatible both with direct effects (Hypothesis 2) and indirect effects (Hypothesis 3).
However, these two hypotheses offer distinct additional predictions. Note that the three
hypotheses are not mutually exclusive.
Hypothesis 2 (Market Discipline) The abolition of state guarantees led to an in-
crease in refinancing costs at riskier savings banks relative to less risky savings banks.
If public guarantees affected savings banks directly because their creditors reacted to
higher risk perceptions, this should show up in a stronger differentiation across savings
banks with different risk profiles. This hypothesis features prominently in the literature
on bail-out guarantees and also in the paper by Gropp, Gruendl, and Guettler (2011).
However, as outlined above, most creditors of savings banks may be insensitive to bank
risk. In addition, the major part of interbank liabilities of savings banks is held by their
regional Landesbank. Therefore, we hypothesize that the abolition of guarantees may
have worked indirectly through the banking networks with the Landesbanken who them-
selves suffered from higher risk premia according to their own risk exposures. Specifically,
Landesbanken may have charged higher interest rates on loans to savings banks to com-
pensate for the loss in their own charter values or to simply pass through deteriorating
13
funding conditions on international capital markets. In addition, savings banks would be
affected through their ownership in Landesbanken. Then the effect of the abolition of
guarantees should be strongest for those savings banks whose Landesbank suffered most
from the abolition of guarantees.
Hypothesis 3 (Indirect Effects Through Banking Networks) The abolition of
state guarantees led to an increase in refinancing costs at savings banks whose Landes-
banken were more strongly affected by the abolition of guarantees relative to those whose
Landesbanken were less affected.
Finally, much of the literature on public bail-out guarantees deals with the implications
for banks’ risk-taking. In theory, higher charter values may deter banks from taking ex-
cessive risks (see Keeley, 1990; Hellmann, Murdock, and Stiglitz, 2000). According to this
charter value view, an increase in refinancing costs after the abolition of guarantees, and
the resulting drop in savings banks’ charter values, imply higher risk-taking at formerly
protected banks. However, there may be a countervailing effect: According to the mar-
ket discipline view, which was explored, among others, by Flannery (1998), Sironi (2003)
and Gropp, Vesala, and Vulpes (2006), the greater sensitivity of refinancing costs to risk
reduces incentives for bank risk-taking. Hence, the three hypotheses above do not give
clear predictions about the resulting change in banks’ risk-taking. Whereas the first and
third hypothesis tend to support an increase in banks’ risk-taking, the second suggests a
decrease.
The empirical analysis will show that the evidence strongly supports Hypotheses 1 and
3, but rejects Hypothesis 2. Under this constellation, theory unambiguously predicts an
increase in banks’ risk-taking, which is confirmed by the empirical evidence.
3 Refinancing Costs
We start by analyzing the impact of the abolition of guarantees on the overall refinancing
costs of savings banks. To this end, we compare the refinancing costs of savings banks
before and after the abolition of guarantees with those of non-guaranteed banks in a
difference-in-differences fashion. This corresponds to a test of Hypothesis 1. We first
describe the empirical approach before presenting regression results.
14
3.1 Empirical Approach
In order to gauge the effect of the reform on overall refinancing costs, we choose German
cooperative banks as a comparison group to German savings banks.19 These banks are
a natural choice, since within the overall population of banks in Germany, they are most
similar to savings banks. They are also embedded in a network structure with a division
of labor between small retail banks and large capital-market orientated institutions. Just
as savings banks, cooperative banks are legally autonomous entities, each of them having
its own managing board and supervisory board. Cooperative banks also operate locally,
following a ‘regional principle’, and they mostly engage in retail banking. The main differ-
ence between saving banks and cooperative banks is their ownership status. Cooperative
banks are privately owned by their members and thus, in contrast to savings banks, they
are not tied to the municipalities or any other governmental authority. Moreover, coop-
erative banks on average are smaller than savings banks in terms of total assets, and they
rely on average even more on customer deposit funding than savings banks.
To estimate the effect of the abolition of guarantees on refinancing costs of savings banks,
we estimate the following regression model:
yist = γi + λt + δ1 · savingsbank · after2001 + δ2 · savingsbank · after2005 + β ′ xst + ǫist (1)
The dependent variable yist is a measure of refinancing costs of bank i in state s at
time t. It is measured as the ratio of interest expenses over interest-bearing liabilities,
or, alternatively, over total assets.20 In addition, we present results using net interest
margins (again divided by total assets) as dependent variables because, in theory, the
effect on banks’ risk-taking works through interest margins. On the right-hand-side, we
include bank fixed effects γi , time fixed effects λt , two interaction terms of a savings bank
dummy variable and the dummy variables after2001 and after2005, indicating the period
after the given years, plus a vector of control variables xst that vary across states and
over time. The coefficients of major interest are δ1 and δ2 . They give us the effect of
the banking reform on savings banks’ refinancing costs. We include two interaction terms
because the reform had two decisive dates: the first was the Brussels agreement in July
2001, the second the actual abolition in July 2005. While the guarantees were still in
19
A similar procedure has been followed by Gropp, Gruendl, and Guettler (2011).
20
All variable definitions and data sources are summarized in the Appendix.
15
force between 2001 and 2005, the anticipation of their abolition already influenced banks
before 2005.
All time-invariant bank characteristics are captured by the bank fixed effects, γi . Besides,
factors that change over time but are common to both savings banks and cooperative
banks are captured by the time fixed effects, λt . Given that the sample banks operate
at the regional level, we also control for regional business cycles by including the annual
growth rate of real GDP at the state level. In addition, we control for regional bank
competition. First, we relate the number of regionally operating banks to the population
in the federal states. Second, we include the population density (number of inhabitants
per square kilometer). This is motivated by the fact that banks in the past tended to
withdraw retail business from sparsely populated areas leaving behind less competitive
local deposit and loan markets. Since savings banks’ and cooperative banks’ refinancing
costs may react differently to changes in the economic and competitive environment, we
allow for differential effects of the regional control variables for the two banking groups.
Annual bank balance sheet data are taken from Bureau van Dijk’s Bankscope Database,
which covers nearly all financial reports of savings banks in the given time period and
roughly 60 percent of the financial reports of cooperative banks. Since most savings
banks and cooperative banks do not publish consolidated financial reports, we use uncon-
solidated reports throughout. Moreover, all sample banks report according to national
accounting standards (HGB). The regressions refer to the years 1996 until 2007.
3.2 Results
Table 2 shows the results of the comparison between savings banks and cooperative banks
before and after the abolition of guarantees. We indeed find an increase in refinancing
costs of savings banks in reaction to the bank reform. Relative to cooperative banks,
interest expense to liabilities of savings banks increased by 0.033 percentage points after
the Brussels agreement (column 1 of Table 2). The increase is statistically significant at
the 10 percent level. After 2005, refinancing costs increased further by 0.047 percentage
points. This further increase is statistically significant at the 1 percent level. Given a
mean value of the dependent variable for the savings banks of 3.3 percent, with a standard
deviation of 0.64, the increase appears quite moderate. With regard to interest expense
over total assets, the increase is slightly larger (column 2 of Table 2). Again, the results
16
indicate that refinancing became more expensive for savings banks after 2001 and even
more expensive after 2005. Hence, the regression results confirm Hypothesis 1 – the
abolition of state guarantees led to an increase in refinancing costs at German savings
banks, albeit a small one. Consistent with an increase in refinancing costs, interest margins
of savings banks declined (column 3 of Table 2). However, after 2005 we do not observe
a further decline but rather a statistically significant increase. This increase compensates
for the decline after 2001; the sum of the two coefficients is not statistically significant.
Hence, compared to the period before 2001, the difference in interest margins between
savings banks and cooperative has not changed.
Table 2: Interest expense and margins of savings banks relative to cooperative banks
(1) (2) (3)
Interest expense/ Interest expense/ Interest margin/
liabilities total assets total assets
Savings bank × after 2001 0.033∗ 0.052∗∗ −0.093∗∗∗
(0.019) (0.021) (0.024)
Savings bank × after 2005 0.049∗∗∗ 0.049∗∗∗ 0.136∗∗∗
(0.011) (0.011) (0.014)
Real GDP growth 1.177∗∗∗ 1.022∗∗∗ −0.016
(0.258) (0.243) (0.278)
Real GDP growth × savings bank −1.257∗∗∗ −0.861∗∗∗ −1.072∗∗∗
(0.320) (0.314) (0.336)
Population density −0.001 0.000 0.002
(0.002) (0.002) (0.002)
Population density × savings bank −0.010∗∗∗ −0.009∗∗∗ −0.000
(0.003) (0.003) (0.003)
Banks per 100,000 inhabitants 0.166∗∗∗ 0.154∗∗∗ −0.085∗∗∗
(0.013) (0.017) (0.015)
Banks per 100,000 inhabitants × savings bank −0.041∗∗∗ −0.027∗ 0.060∗∗∗
(0.014) (0.016) (0.017)
Sum of rows (1) and (2) 0.082∗∗∗ 0.101∗∗∗ 0.044
(0.023) (0.024) (0.029)
R2 within 0.84 0.84 0.51
Observations 16980 16980 16980
Notes: All models include year fixed effects and bank fixed effects. Standard errors clustered at the bank level are given in
parentheses. *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10, 5 and 1 percent level, respectively. In the bottom, the sum of the
estimated coefficients of the two savings bank-after dummies is reported, as well as standard errors and significance levels
from testing the hypothesis that these coefficients sum up to zero. Detailed variable descriptions are given in the Appendix.
The regional business cycle and competition appear to affect refinancing costs of savings
banks and cooperative banks differently (see the interaction terms of the regional variables
17
with the savings bank dummy in columns 1 and 2 of Table 2). For instance, the coefficient
of real GDP growth is positive and statistically significant, whereas the coefficient of the
interaction between real GDP growth and the savings banks dummy is negative. The
sum of both coefficients is not statistically different from zero. Hence, there is a positive
association between regional GDP growth and interest expense for cooperative banks,
whereas such an association does not exist for savings banks. In contrast, the population
density affects interest expense of savings banks negatively, whereas it does not affect
the interest expense of cooperative banks. Bank competition, measured by the number
of banks per population, is associated positively with interest expense for both savings
banks and cooperative banks. However, the coefficient of the savings bank interaction
again is statistically significant.
These results document the importance of allowing for heterogeneous regional effects.
However, they also raise concern about the comparability of savings bank and cooper-
ative banks. In addition, the comparability of savings banks and cooperative banks is
complicated by singular events in the cooperative network in 2005 and 2006 that may
have caused structural breaks in the time series.21 Since these effects coincide with the
abolition of guarantees in the savings bank sector, the preceding results have to be inter-
preted with caution. Therefore, in the following regressions, we use a modified approach
exploiting the variation within the savings bank sector.
Summing up, the results from the difference-in-differences regression indicate a positive
effect of the abolition of guarantees on savings banks’ refinancing costs and a temporary
negative effect on interest margins. This supports the first hypothesis. Note that the
increase in refinancing costs is also consistent with Hypotheses 2 and 3. Both a drop
in the charter values of Landesbanken and the transmission to savings banks (indirect
effects), and the pricing of savings’ banks default risk (market discipline) imply an increase
in average refinancing costs of savings banks. However, in light of the grandfathering
clause, it seems unlikely that market discipline was already fully effective before 2005
when savings banks’ liabilities were still completely covered by guarantor liability. In
contrast, it is well conceivable that Landesbanken raised interbank rates already before
2005 because the drop in their charter value occurred already in 2001. Hence, the timing
21
These events were related to the conversion of the cooperative banks’ central institutes in joint stock
companies (2005/2006) as well as one-time tax refunds (2006). See Deutsche Bundesbank (2006, p. 27)
and Deutsche Bundesbank (2007, p. 20, Fn. 4).
18
of the increase in savings banks’ refinancing costs is consistent with Hypothesis 3, but
less so with Hypothesis 2.
4 Indirect Effects Through Banking Networks
A comparison of savings banks and an untreated control group is informative about
changes in mean outcomes induced by the policy intervention, but it does not tell us
anything about the underlying mechanisms. In particular, this kind of comparison is not
suitable to explore our two hypotheses about the channels through which savings banks
were affected by the abolition of guarantees. Therefore, we now restrict our sample to
saving banks and exploit the heterogeneity within the group of savings banks.22 Hypothe-
ses 2 and 3 imply that the banking reform did not affect all savings banks to the same
degree. Therefore, we now allow for varying treatment intensities for different savings
banks. In this section, we examine whether bank network structures, in particular those
between savings banks and their corresponding Landesbank, affect the size of the impact
that the abolition of guarantees had on savings banks. In Section 4, we test whether the
effect differs with respect to savings banks’ risk profiles.
4.1 Empirical Approach
Hypothesis 3 predicts that the effect of the reform on refinancing costs is stronger for sav-
ings banks whose Landesbanken were themselves more strongly affected by the abolition
of guarantees. To test this hypothesis, we have to classify the Landesbanken according to
their expected loss in charter value stemming from the abolition of guarantees. The het-
erogeneity in expected charter value losses is reflected in the issuer ratings of unguaranteed
Landesbanken that were published by major rating agencies already one year ahead of the
actual abolition. A strong downgrade implies a sharp increase in refinancing cost in cap-
ital markets, and thus a high loss in charter value. Specifically, we use the issuer ratings
published by Fitch Ratings in July 2004 (see Table 1).23 We divide the Landesbanken
22
Looking at savings banks only is also advantageous for reasons of sample homogeneity. Although
cooperative banks are similar to savings banks in many regards, savings banks certainly are more com-
parable to other savings banks than to cooperative banks.
23
Table 1 also shows the correspondence between savings banks and Landesbanken.
19
into two groups. One group consists of Landesbanken downgraded by 4 or 5 notches (from
AAA to A+ or A), and the other group consists of Landesbanken downgraded by 6 or 7
notches (from AAA to A– or BBB+). This dichotomous classification is motivated by the
fact that within the single A range the difference in bond rates between bonds rated A
and A– is larger than the difference between bonds rated A+ and A. Moreover, the differ-
ence between A+ and A is relatively small and similar to the difference between A– and
BBB+. Thus, the dichotomous classification reflects the discontinuity at the transition
from A to A–. Using this classification, we estimate the following regression model:
yist = γi + λt + δ1 · High Landesbank downgrade · after2001
+δ2 · High Landesbank downgrade · after2005 + β ′ xst + ǫist (2)
Remember that this regression only includes savings banks. The dummy variable High
Landesbank downgrade indicates a savings bank whose Landesbank was strongly down-
graded (i. e. by 6 or 7 notches) and the remaining notation is as in Equation 1. Alter-
natively, instead of the dichotomous classification, we specify a downgrade variable that
ranges from 4 to 7 and interact this variable with the two after dummy variables. This
approach uses the full rating information, but comes at the cost of ignoring the described
discontinuity. Hypothesis 3 (indirect effects through banking networks) implies a pos-
itive sign of δ2 and potentially also of δ1 . To avoid confounding effects, the vector of
control variables again includes measures of regional economic growth and regional bank
competition.
4.2 Results
The regression results in Table 3 show that interest expenses (both over liabilities and total
assets) at savings banks belonging to the high-downgrade group rose by 7 basis points
after 2001 relative to savings banks belonging to the low-downgrade group (columns 1
and 3). The increase is highly statistically significant. The relative increase in refinancing
costs is augmented by a further increase after 2005, leading to a total difference of about
10 basis points. Hence, savings banks in the high-downgrade group experienced a total
increase in refinancing costs that was approximately 10 basis points higher than at savings
banks in the low-downgrade group.24 The time structure of the increase is similar to that
24
The common trend in refinancing costs is captured by the time fixed effects.
20
in the savings banks/cooperative banks comparison.
Similar results are obtained in the alternative specification where the downgrade variable
enters numerically (columns 2 and 4 of Table 3). The stronger the downgrade of the
associated Landesbank, the higher is the relative increase in interest expenses after 2001.
For example, a Landesbanken downgrade by one notch is associated with an increase in
interest expense over liabilities (or assets) of savings banks by about 5 basis points after
2001 and a further increase of around 2 basis point after 2005. The regression coefficients
are again highly statistically significant. The results on the interest margin (columns 5
and 6) indicate a stronger decline in the margins of savings banks associated with highly
downgraded Landesbanken. In the dichotomous specification, the effect concentrates on
the period after 2005, whereas the alternative specification has a similar pattern over time
as the one explaining interest expenses.
These results strongly support the hypothesis that savings banks were indirectly affected
by the abolition of guarantees through their lending relationships with Landesbanken.
They suggest that Landesbanken adjusted lending terms for savings banks in response to
the Brussels agreement and that those Landesbanken that were expected to be affected
most by the abolition of guarantees raised interbank loan rates for savings banks more
than other Landesbanken.
With regard to timing, the adjustments were initiated already before the actual abolition
of guarantees in 2005. Although it has been occasionally reported that lending terms of
Landesbanken in capital markets deteriorated already before July 2005, it seems unlikely
that the increase in savings banks’ interest expense is simply due to a pass-through of
Landesbanken rates to savings banks. Rather, we conjecture that Landesbanken antici-
pated their own refinancing costs to increase sharply after 2005 and charged higher rates
on interbank loans to savings banks preemptively. Supporting evidence on this conjecture
is presented in Table 4. The table displays results of regressions that relate the actual
increase in refinancing costs of Landesbanken around 2005 to savings banks’ interest ex-
pense and margins in the transition period as well as after 2005. Specifically, we measure
the change in the refinancing costs of Landesbanken by the growth of interest expenses
over liabilities between 2004 and 2006 (calculated by taking differences in logs). This
variable is interacted with the two after dummy variables. As can be seen from Table 4,
the increase in savings banks’ interest expense depends positively on the growth of inter-
est expenses of the associated Landesbank between 2004 and 2006. This is true not only
21
Table 3: Impact of Landesbanken downgrades on interest expense and margins of
savings banks
Interest expense/ Interest expense/ Interest margin/
liabilities total assets total assets
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
High Landesbank downgrade × after 2001 0.070∗∗∗ 0.070∗∗∗ −0.040
(0.021) (0.020) (0.025)
High Landesbank downgrade × after 2005 0.033∗∗ 0.039∗∗∗ −0.096∗∗∗
(0.015) (0.014) (0.021)
Landesbank downgrade × after 2001 0.055∗∗∗ 0.053∗∗∗ −0.029∗∗
(0.012) (0.011) (0.012)
Landesbank downgrade × after 2005 0.022∗∗ 0.025∗∗∗ −0.048∗∗∗
(0.009) (0.008) (0.011)
Real GDP growth 0.119 0.041 0.177 0.107 −0.321 −0.241
(0.322) (0.328) (0.307) (0.313) (0.350) (0.350)
Population density 0.002 0.005 0.003 0.006 −0.002 −0.005
(0.003) (0.004) (0.003) (0.004) (0.003) (0.003)
Banks per 100,000 inhabitants 0.097∗∗∗ 0.088∗∗∗ 0.104∗∗∗ 0.096∗∗∗ −0.027 −0.028
(0.019) (0.017) (0.018) (0.017) (0.023) (0.022)
Sum of rows (1) and (2) 0.104∗∗∗ 0.110∗∗∗ −0.136∗∗∗
(0.024) (0.023) (0.032)
Sum of rows (3) and (4) 0.076∗∗∗ 0.078∗∗∗ −0.077∗∗∗
(0.014) (0.013) (0.017)
R2 within 0.87 0.87 0.87 0.87 0.65 0.65
Observations 6003 6003 6003 6003 6003 6003
Notes: All models include year fixed effects, bank fixed effects, and Eastern-German year effects to account for differing
East-West trends. Standard errors clustered at the bank level are given in parentheses. *, ** and *** denote significance at
the 10, 5 and 1 percent level, respectively. In the bottom, the sum of the estimated coefficients of the two downgrade-after
variables is reported, as well as standard errors and significance levels from testing the hypothesis that these coefficients
sum up to zero. Detailed variable descriptions are given in the Appendix.
after 2005 (second row), but already in the transition period between 2001 and 2004 (first
row). This indicates that Landesbanken took into account the expected future increases
in refinancing costs when pricing interbank loans to savings banks in the transition period.
5 Market Discipline
Although we find strong evidence for the hypothesis that the abolition of guarantees af-
fected savings banks through Landesbanken, this does not exclude the possibility that the
abolition of guarantees also increased market discipline for savings banks. In fact, it may
22
Table 4: Interest expense growth of Landesbanken and interest expense and margins of
savings banks
(1) (2) (3)
Interest expense/ Interest expense/ Interest margin/
liabilities total assets total assets
Interest expense growth of 0.432∗∗∗ 0.403∗∗∗ −0.085
Landesbank around 2005 × year 2001–2004 (0.109) (0.106) (0.119)
Interest expense growth of 0.617∗∗∗ 0.609∗∗∗ −0.100
Landesbank around 2005 × after 2005 (0.138) (0.131) (0.179)
Real GDP growth 0.509 0.559∗ −0.313
(0.339) (0.324) (0.370)
Population density 0.001 0.002 −0.002
(0.003) (0.003) (0.003)
Banks per 100,000 inhabitants 0.102∗∗∗ 0.111∗∗∗ −0.058∗∗
(0.017) (0.016) (0.023)
Difference of rows (2) and (1) 0.185 0.207∗ −0.015
(0.115) (0.109) (0.152)
R2 within 0.87 0.87 0.65
Observations 6003 6003 6003
Notes: All models include year fixed effects, bank fixed effects, and Eastern-German year effects to account for differing
East-West trends. Standard errors clustered at the bank level are given in parentheses. *, ** and *** denote significance
at the 10, 5 and 1 percent level, respectively. In the bottom, the difference of the estimated coefficients of the two interest
expense-after variables is reported, as well as standard errors and significance levels from testing the hypothesis that the
difference is equal to zero. Detailed variable descriptions are given in the Appendix.
be that the risk profiles of savings banks are correlated with those of their Landesbank,
implying that the above results may have captured market discipline effects rather than
the indirect network effects advocated above. To account for this possibility, we now
analyze whether the increase in refinancing costs of savings banks varies with individual
bank risk.
5.1 Empirical Approach
To explore whether the abolition of guarantees increased market discipline at savings
banks, we test whether riskier savings banks incurred higher increases in refinancing costs
than less risky savings banks after the abolition of guarantees. Hence, we run a regression
model explaining savings banks’ refinancing costs (interest expenses over liablities),25
allowing the effect of the abolition of guarantees to depend on the individual risk profile
25
Employing interest expense to total assets as dependent variable leads to very similar results.
23
of savings banks:
yist = γi + λt + δ1 · risk1996−2000 · after2001 + δ2 · risk2001−2004 · after2005 + β ′ xst + ǫist (3)
Given that savings bank liabilities were still fully guaranteed until 2005, we do not expect
to find a significant coefficient in the transition period (corresponding to δ1 ) even under
Hypothesis 2. In contrast, δ2 is expected to be positive if market discipline is at work
because bank debt was no longer guaranteed after 2005.
We employ three different measures of bank risk commonly used in the literature, based
on financial reporting data: bank capitalization, risk provisions, and bank liquidity. While
each of these measures has some shortcomings, we hope to capture the relevant risk char-
acteristics of savings banks, in particular those that matter most for the providers of
external funding to savings banks. In this regard, the use of publicly available finan-
cial reporting data seems adequate, since creditors of savings banks generally will also
mainly rely on this type of data.26 To capture the risk profile of savings banks at the
time of the abolition of guarantees, we calculate averages over the years preceding the
intervention years; that is, we take averages over 1996-2000 for the interaction with the
transition-period dummy, and averages over 2001-2004 for the interaction with the after-
2005 dummy. Taking averages over several years reduces measurement error. Besides,
creditors are also likely to take into account past developments.
To measure a bank’s capitalization, we relate book equity to total assets. The higher
the ratio, the better is a bank able to absorb unexpected losses. In order to account for
risks on the asset side, we employ financial reporting information on risk provisions on
loans and certain fixed-income securities (henceforth denoted reference assets). High risk
provisions relative to reference assets indicate risky investment strategies. A disadvantage
of this measure is that it is backward-looking. When risk provisions are built up, it is not
clear when the underlying investments have been made. Besides, HGB accounting rules
enable banks to smooth out deteriorating asset quality silently. Thus, risk provisions tend
to understate asset risk. As a measure of resilience against unexpected liquidity shocks,
we relate liquid assets to total assets. The more liquid the assets of a bank are, the better
26
Gropp, Gruendl, and Guettler (2011) measure banks’ risk-taking using z-scores. However, z-scores
based on balance sheet data with very few observations in the time dimension are not very reliable.
Z-scores based on market data are not feasible here, as none of the sample banks is publicly traded.
24
it is able to cope with unexpected withdrawals of deposits or with borrowers refusing to
renew credit lines.
5.2 Results
The results of this approach are displayed in Table 5. The first three columns present the
results of separate regressions for each risk measure. Column 4 contains the results of a
regression with all risk measures on the right hand side, column 5 adds the interaction
terms from the previous section.27 It is striking that the coefficients on the interaction
terms almost exclusively are not statistically significant. Hence, the increase in refinancing
costs of savings banks does not depend on individual bank risk, neither in the transition
period, nor after the actual abolition of guarantees. The only exception is the interac-
tion between the liquidity measure and the transition-period dummy. However, the sign
of the coefficient is positive, suggesting that interest expenses are the higher, the more
liquid assets a savings bank holds. This is implausible and contradicts the market dis-
cipline hypothesis.28 In contrast, the downgrade variables used in the previous section
continue to be positive and statistically significant (column 5 of Table 5). Hence, we can
exclude the possibility that differences in savings banks’ risk characteristics among the
two downgrade groups drive the results of the previous section. Moreover, the results
reject Hypothesis 2 because there is no indication that creditors exerted market discipline
by demanding higher interest rates from those savings banks that were riskier in terms of
capital endowment, liquidity buffers, or borrower risk.
As was mentioned above, it is not surprising that we can reject the market discipline hy-
pothesis for the transition period. Creditors of savings banks were still fully protected by
the guarantee schemes. Hence, there was no need for creditors of savings banks to adjust
interest rates to individual risk profiles. Even providers of long-term funds maturing after
July 2005 had no incentives to care about savings banks’ creditworthiness, since munici-
palities continued to be liable for their obligations. In contrast, creditors’ incentives could
be expected to change after July 2005 when both guarantor liability and maintenance
27
The lower number of observations is owed to the fact that some banks enter the sample in later years,
such that average risk measures cannot be computed for these banks.
28
From the viewpoint of market discipline, most other coefficients carry the ‘wrong’ sign, too. We
refrain from interpreting these coefficients, since none of them is statistically significant. Note that the
implausible result regarding bank liquidity disappears in the final column of Table 5.
25
Table 5: Impact of individual bank risk on interest expenses of savings banks
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
Book equity/total assets 1996–2000 0.014 0.014 0.015
× year 2001–2004 (0.012) (0.013) (0.012)
Book equity/total assets 2001–2004 −0.015 −0.017 −0.015
× after 2005 (0.012) (0.012) (0.012)
Liquid assets/total assets 1996–2000 0.002∗∗ 0.003∗∗ 0.002
× year 2001–2004 (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
Liquid assets/total assets 2001–2004 0.002 0.002 0.001
× after 2005 (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
Risk provisions/reference assets 1996–2000 −0.031 −0.003 −0.011
× year 2001–2004 (0.031) (0.032) (0.032)
Risk provisions/reference assets 2001–2004 −0.038 −0.040 −0.049
× after 2005 (0.039) (0.039) (0.040)
High Landesbank downgrade × after 2001 0.061∗∗∗
(0.021)
High Landesbank downgrade × after 2005 0.040∗∗
(0.016)
Real GDP growth 0.403 0.415 0.465 0.385 0.204
(0.340) (0.336) (0.338) (0.339) (0.332)
Population density 0.002 0.002 0.002 0.002 0.002
(0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003)
Banks per 100,000 inhabitants 0.135∗∗∗ 0.137∗∗∗ 0.136∗∗∗ 0.137∗∗∗ 0.098∗∗∗
(0.016) (0.016) (0.016) (0.016) (0.019)
R2 within 0.87 0.87 0.87 0.87 0.87
Observations 5700 5700 5700 5700 5700
Notes: All models include year fixed effects, bank fixed effects, and Eastern-German year effects to account for
differing East-West trends. Standard errors clustered at the bank level are given in parentheses. *, ** and ***
denote significance at the 10, 5 and 1 percent level, respectively. Detailed variable descriptions are given in the
Appendix.
obligation were legally terminated. Clearly, a savings bank without any institutionalized
government support mechanisms should ceteris paribus be considered less creditworthy
than a savings bank protected by explicit guarantee schemes. Nevertheless, creditors of
savings bank apparently did not react to these changes. This can be explained by the
liability structure of savings banks. Liabilities are dominated by deposits from customers
who could afford to ignore the changes in July 2005, since they still could rely on com-
prehensive depositor protection schemes. Other liabilities of savings banks mainly stem
from interbank loans from Landesbanken who tend to lend on equal terms to banks within
the network, generally ignoring the riskiness of individual borrower banks. Our results
26
suggest that other types of liabilities, especially traded bonds, are not important enough
to induce measurable market discipline for savings banks (cf. Figure 1).
6 Bank Risk
In the final section, we analyze how the observed changes in refinancing costs translated
into changes in savings banks’ risk-taking. We have seen that the regressions explaining
refinancing costs supported an overall increase in refinancing costs at German savings
banks (Hypothesis 1). This increase was explained by indirect effects through savings
banks’ relationship with Landesbanken (Hypothesis 3) rather than market discipline (Hy-
pothesis 2). This suggests that the abolition of guarantees constituted a pure charter
value effect for German savings banks. In theory, the reduction in charter values leads
to stronger risk-taking incentives because banks seek compensation for reduced charter
values by following riskier business strategies. Hence, in the absence of market discipline,
the abolition of guarantees should lead to higher risk-taking at German savings banks.
We test this prediction using similar estimation procedures as in the preceding sections.
6.1 Empirical Approach
We analyze the determinants of savings banks’ risk-taking, employing a regression model
that is analogous to Equation 2:
riskist = γi + λt + δ1 · High Landesbank downgrade · after2001
+δ2 · High Landesbank downgrade · after2005 + β ′ xst + ǫist (4)
We regress measures of bank risk on the interaction of the downgrade intensity of Lan-
desbanken with dummies indicating the years after 2001 and 2005, respectively, plus the
same set of control variables as before. We conjecture that the variation in charter value
losses of Landesbanken (as implied by heterogenous issuer rating downgrades) also induces
variation in charter value losses at savings banks. As shown in Section 4, funding costs
of savings banks are linked to charter values of associated Landesbanken through lending
relationships. Moreover, it is the savings banks as owners of the Landesbanken who will
27
ultimately incur any financial disadvantage at Landesbanken implied by the abolition of
guarantees. Finally, higher funding costs of Landesbanken and reduced interest margins
make shareholdings in Landesbanken less valuable. Thus, a decrease in the charter values
of Landesbanken implies also a decrease in charter values of savings banks.
As dependent variables we use the risk measures introduced in the previous section.
Generally, the same measurement issues as discussed before apply here, too. However,
since we consider a relatively long time period before and after the policy intervention
some of these problems might be attenuated. In particular, risk provisions become much
more informative, since smoothing strategies in accounting cannot mask risky investment
behavior over the long run. Furthermore, to show that the results do not depend on the
specifics of our variable definitions, we employ two additional measures of bank risk. The
first is the ratio of security reserves to total assets (as an alternative to the book equity
to total assets ratio). Security reserves are accumulated profits that have been retained
for the purpose of capital formation. They form the most important capital element for
savings banks, since retaining profits is practically the only possibility for savings banks
to strengthen their capital basis. Therefore, security reserves form on average about 95
percent of the book equity of savings banks. In addition, we relate risk provisions to book
equity rather than banks’ reference assets. This ratio indicates to which extent losses are
covered by a bank’s capital buffer.
6.2 Results
According to the regression results displayed in Table 6, risk-taking of banks in the high-
vs. low-downgrade group differed significantly after the banking reform. Compared to
savings banks belonging to the low-downgrade group, savings banks belonging to the
high-downgrade group decreased their capital ratios after 2001 (columns 1 and 3), re-
duced their liquidity (column 5), and increased risk provisions (both relative to reference
assets and book equity, columns 7 and 9). All these changes are statistically significant
at the 1 percent level. Hence, all risk measures indicate a relative increase in risk of
savings banks whose Landesbanken were downgraded more severely. Again, the results
are qualitatively the same when using the four-point downgrade-variable instead of the
dichotomous classification (even-numbered columns of Table 6). After 2005, the differ-
entials in capital and liquidity ratios increased further, whereas the differentials in risk
28
Table 6: Risk taking of savings banks
Security reserves/ Book equity/ Liquid assets/ Risk provisions/ Risk provisions/
total assets total assets total assets reference assets book equity
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)
High Landesbank downgrade × after 2001 −0.232∗∗∗ −0.190∗∗∗ −1.848∗∗∗ 0.079∗∗∗ 2.257∗∗∗
(0.046) (0.041) (0.491) (0.028) (0.669)
High Landesbank downgrade × after 2005 −0.064∗ −0.086∗∗ −1.533∗∗∗ −0.055∗∗ −0.543
(0.038) (0.038) (0.478) (0.024) (0.524)
Landesbank downgrade × after 2001 −0.092∗∗∗ −0.069∗∗∗ −0.944∗∗∗ 0.033∗∗ 0.888∗∗∗
(0.028) (0.024) (0.267) (0.015) (0.332)
Landesbank downgrade × after 2005 −0.024 −0.021 −0.628∗∗ −0.009 0.101
(0.023) (0.022) (0.247) (0.013) (0.275)
Real GDP growth −0.709 −1.055∗ −0.841 −1.101∗∗ −10.601 −11.013 −1.718∗∗∗ −1.503∗∗∗ −41.247∗∗∗ −35.692∗∗∗
29
(0.564) (0.574) (0.532) (0.536) (7.514) (7.415) (0.533) (0.544) (12.311) (12.637)
Population density −0.006 −0.013 −0.011 −0.016∗ 0.008 −0.063 −0.001 0.001 0.022 0.090
(0.009) (0.010) (0.008) (0.009) (0.067) (0.073) (0.003) (0.003) (0.076) (0.080)
Banks per 100,000 inhabitants 0.064 0.019 0.025 −0.023 0.034 −0.228 0.009 0.013 0.233 0.485
(0.044) (0.045) (0.040) (0.040) (0.428) (0.420) (0.023) (0.022) (0.535) (0.492)
Sum of rows (1) and (2) −0.296∗∗∗ −0.276∗∗∗ −3.380∗∗∗ 0.024 1.714∗∗
(0.069) (0.063) (0.681) 0.031 (0.700)
Sum of rows (3) and (4) −0.116∗∗ −0.090∗∗ −1.572∗∗∗ 0.024 0.989∗∗∗
(0.045) (0.038) (0.364) (0.016) (0.346)
R2 within 0.60 0.59 0.60 0.60 0.17 0.16 0.21 0.21 0.18 0.17
Observations 6078 6078 6078 6078 6078 6078 6078 6078 6077 6077
Notes: All models include year fixed effects, bank fixed effects, and Eastern-German year effects to account for differing East-West trends. Standard errors clustered
at the bank level are given in parentheses. *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10, 5 and 1 percent level, respectively. In the bottom, the sum of the estimated
coefficients of the two downgrade-after variables is reported, as well as standard errors and significance levels from testing the hypothesis that these coefficients
sum up to zero. Detailed variable descriptions are given in the Appendix.
provisions tended to revert and are statistically significant for only one of the two mea-
sures for the period after 2005 (see sums of coefficients in the last two lines of columns 7
to 10).29
In a robustness check, we also compare savings banks and cooperative banks, similar
to the analysis in Section 3, to measure the absolute (rather than relative) effect of the
abolition of guarantees on German savings banks. As was explained earlier, we believe
that a comparison within the savings banks sample is much cleaner due to singular events
in the cooperative sector. Moreover, capital ratios of savings banks and cooperative banks
are not directly comparable. Savings banks rely almost exclusively on retained profits,
whereas capital of cooperative banks stems also from member shares. Despite these
shortcomings, we report the results of the comparison in Table A.3 in the Appendix. All
risk measures point in the same direction: after 2001, savings banks decreased capital and
liquidity and increased risk provisions compared to cooperative banks. The coefficients
are statistically significant throughout (first row of Table A.3).30 An additional change
occurred after 2005 with regard to capital and liquidity (second row of Table A.3). These
results indicate that the abolition of guarantees was associated with higher risk-taking of
savings banks, again confirming the theoretical predictions.31
The results on savings banks’ risk-taking are consistent with theoretical predictions when
we combine them with our earlier findings. When the abolition of guarantees was agreed
on in July 2001, savings banks experienced a decrease in charter values, which increased
risk-taking incentives. At the same time, liabilities continued to be guaranteed during
the transition period until July 2005, and hence there was no market discipline, which
could have mitigated risk-taking incentives. Even after the actual abolition of guarantees,
savings banks creditors have not become sensitive for individual risk-taking of savings
banks, as was shown in Section 5. Therefore, it is not surprising that the differential
in banks’ risk-taking becomes even larger after 2005 for most risk measures. In theory,
an abolition of guarantees in the absence of market discipline unambiguously raises the
risk-taking of banks. This is confirmed by our empirical results.
29
For the other measure, the sum of the coefficients of both interactions is still positive, but not
statistically different from zero.
30
We do not analyze security reserves for lack of an equivalent balance sheet position at cooperative
banks.
31
As a further robustness check, we delete cooperative banks from the sample that underwent the
aforementioned extraordinary reporting events. The results remain largely unchanged (Table A.4 in the
Appendix).
30
7 Conclusion
Our analysis has shown that the abolition of public guarantees towards the German public
banking sector raised the refinancing costs of German savings banks and thereby depressed
their charter values. Our works suggests that this was not driven by higher risk premia on
banks’ refinancing because the extent of cost increases was not related to savings banks’
risk profiles. Hence, in contrast to earlier work by Gropp, Gruendl, and Guettler (2011),
we do not find any indication that the creditors of savings banks started to impose market
discipline after the abolition of government guarantees. Rather, the increase in refinancing
costs appears to have been driven by the savings banks’ relationship to Landesbanken.
Due to lending relationships and ownership structures, the drop in the charter values of
Landesbanken, as documented by Fischer, Hainz, Rocholl, and Steffen (2011), spilled over
to the corresponding savings banks. Since market discipline was not effective, the drop
in charter value translated into higher risk-taking, confirming theoretical predictions.
The most interesting result from our paper is that the effects of public guarantees – and
of their removal – depend crucially on the structure of banking systems. In a world
where financial institutions are highly interconnected, a shock to one bank is likely to
spill over to other banks in the system. This aspect becomes relevant when policy makers
want to design an exit strategy from the implicit guarantees built up during the recent
financial crisis. The message of our paper is that a removal of such guarantees, just as
the guarantees themselves, is likely to diffuse into the remaining financial system.
31
References
Berger, H. (2008): “Wie definieren Landesbanken ihre Wachstumsfelder?,” Zeitschrift
für das gesamte Kreditwesen, 19, 958–973.
Boyd, J. H., and M. Gertler (1994): “The Role of Large Banks in the Recent U.S.
Banking Crisis,” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, 18(1), 2–21.
Boyd, J. H., and D. E. Runkle (1993): “Size and Performance of Banking Firms:
Testing the Predictions of Theory,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 31(1), 47–67.
Cordella, T., and E. L. Yeyati (2003): “Bank Bailouts: Moral Hazard vs. Value
Effect,” Journal of Financial Intermediation, 12, 300–330.
Demirguc-Kunt, A., and E. Detragiache (2002): “Does Deposit Insurance In-
crease Banking System Stability? An Empirical Investigation,” Journal of Monetary
Economics, 49(7), 1373–1406.
Deutsche Bundesbank (2001): Monthly Report.
(2006): Monthly Report.
(2007): Monthly Report.
(2011): Monthly Report.
DSGV (2011a): Finanzbericht 2010.
(2011b): Statistisches Beiheft 2010.
Fischer, M., C. Hainz, J. Rocholl, and S. Steffen (2011): “Government Guar-
antees and Bank Risk Taking Incentives,” Working paper.
Fitch Ratings (2003): Germany, Special Report: Why Landesbanks are Single A Range.
Flannery, M. J. (1998): “Using Market Information in Prudential Bank Supervision:
A Review of the U.S. Empirical Evidence,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking,
30(3), 273–305.
Flannery, M. J., and S. M. Sorescu (1996): “Evidence of Bank Market Discipline
in Subordinated Debenture Yields: 1983-1991,” Journal of Finance, 51(4), 1347–1377.
32
Güde, U. (1995): Geschäftspolitik der Sparkassen. Deutscher Sparkassenverlag,
Stuttgart, 6 edn.
German Council of Economic Experts (2004): “External Successes - Internal Chal-
lenges,” Annual Report 2004/2005, Wiesbaden.
Gropp, R., C. Gruendl, and A. Guettler (2011): “The Impact of Public Guaran-
tees on Bank Risk Taking: Evidence From a Natural Experiment,” European Central
Bank Working Paper No. 1272.
Gropp, R., H. Hakenes, and I. Schnabel (2011): “Competition, Risk-Shifting, and
Public Bail-out Guarantees,” Review of Financial Studies, 24(6), 2084–2120.
Gropp, R., and J. Vesala (2004): “Deposit insurance, moral hazard and market
monitoring,” Review of Finance, 8(4), 571–602.
Gropp, R., J. Vesala, and G. Vulpes (2006): “Equity and Bond Market Signals as
Leading Indicators of Bank Fragility,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 38(2),
399–428.
Hackethal, A. (2004): “German Banks and Banking Structure,” in The German Fi-
nancial System, ed. by J. P. Krahnen, and R. H. Schmidt, chap. 3, pp. 71–81. Oxford
University Press, Oxford.
Hakenes, H., and I. Schnabel (2010): “Banks Without Parachutes – Competitive
Effects of Government Bail-out Policies,” Journal of Financial Stability, 6, 156–168.
Hau, H., and M. Thum (2009): “Subprime crisis and board (in-) competence: private
versus public banks in Germany,” Economic Policy, 24, 701–752.
Hellmann, T. F., K. C. Murdock, and J. E. Stiglitz (2000): “Liberalization,
Moral Hazard in Banking, and Prudential Regulation: Are Capital Requirements
Enough?,” American Economic Review, 90(1), 147–165.
Hovakimian, A., and E. J. Kane (2000): “Effectiveness of Capital Regulation at U.S.
Commercial Banks, 1985-1994,” Journal of Finance, 55(1), 451–468.
Immenga, U., and J. Rudo (1998): Unlimited liability of state-owned banks under the
EC-rules of state aids. Springer, Berlin.
33
Keeley, M. C. (1990): “Deposit Insurance, Risk, and Market Power in Banking,”
American Economic Review, 80(5), 1183–1200.
Merton, R. (1977): “An Analytical Derivation of the Cost of Deposit Insurance and
Loan Guarantees,” Journal of Banking and Finance, 1(1), 3–11.
Schnabel, I. (2009): “The Role of Liquidity and Implicit Guarantees in the German
Twin Crisis of 1931,” Journal of International Money and Finance, 28, 1–25.
Sironi, A. (2003): “Testing for Market Discipline in the European Banking Industry:
Evidence from Subordinated Debt Issues,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking,
35(3), 443–72.
Upper, C., and A. Worms (2004): “Estimating bilateral exposures in the German
interbank market: Is there a danger of contagion?,” European Economic Review, 48(4),
827–849.
Wiesel, E. (2002): “Sparkassen und Landesbanken auf dem Prüfstand des europäischen
Wettbewerbsrechts,” Zeitschrift für Bankrecht und Bankwirtschaft, (4), 288–299.
Wittmann, A. (2004): Der Sparkassenverbund. Deutscher Gemeindeverlag, Stuttgart.
34
A Appendix
A.1 Variable Description
A.1.1 Bank Data
For each bank variable, one percent of the observations were winsorized. The savings
bank sample and the cooperative bank sample were winsorized separately.
Interest expense/liabilities. Interest expense divided by interest bearing liabilities in
percent. Interest bearing liabilities are loans from banks, liabilities to customers, subor-
dinated debt, and participation certificates. Liabilities are averaged over the current and
previous year. Source: Own calculations based on Bankscope.
Interest expense/total assets. Interest expense divided by total assets in percent.
Total assets are averaged over the current and previous year. Source: Own calculations
based on Bankscope.
Interest margin/total assets. Interest income minus interest expense divided by total
assets in percent. Interest income includes interest from lending, money market transac-
tions, and fixed-income securities. Total assets are averaged over the current and previous
year. Source: Own calculations based on Bankscope.
Security reserves/total assets. Profits retained and accumulated divided by total
assets in percent. Source: Own calculations based on Bankscope.
Book equity/total assets. Book equity divided by total assets in percent. Book equity
is total assets minus total liabilities. Book equity of public-law savings banks typically
consists of security reserves, balance sheet profits, and capital contributions of ‘silent’ (i. e.
non-controlling) partners (Stille Einlagen). Book equity of cooperative banks additionally
consists of share capital. Source: Own calculations based on Bankscope.
Liquid assets/total assets. Liquid assets divided by total assets in percent. Liquid
assets are: cash, treasury securities and bills of exchange eligible for advances from central
banks, due from banks on demand, bonds and other fixed-income securities, shares and
other non-fixed income securities, recovery claims against public authorities. Source: Own
calculations based on Bankscope.
35
Risk provisions/reference assets. Risk provisions minus income from write-backs
and releases from risk provisions divided by reference assets in percent. Reference assets
are assets that risk provisions can be made for. These include loans to banks, loans to
customers, bonds and other fixed-income securities, shares and other non-fixed income
securities. Source: Own calculations based on Bankscope.
Risk provisions/book equity. Risk provisions minus income from write-backs and
releases from risk provisions divided by book equity in percent. Book equity is total
assets minus total liabilities. Source: Own calculations based on Bankscope.
A.1.2 Control Variables
Real GDP growth. Yearly difference in log real GDP of federal states. Source: Own
calculations based on data from the Federal Statistical Office (Destatis).
Population density. Number of inhabitants per km2 in each federal state. Source: Own
calculations based on data from the Federal Statistical Office (Destatis).
Banks per 100,000 inhabitants. Number of savings banks, cooperative banks, and
other regional banks per 100,000 inhabitants in each federal state. Source: Own cal-
culations based on data from Deutsche Bundesbank and the Federal Statistical Office
(Destatis).
36
A.2 Appendix Tables
Table A.1: Descriptive statistics for the savings banks sample
Mean St. D. Min Max Median Obs.
Interest expense/liabilities (%) 3.30 0.64 1.86 4.78 3.34 6003
Interest expense/assets (%) 3.08 0.60 1.72 4.49 3.12 6003
Interest margin/assets (%) 2.28 0.48 0.91 3.54 2.26 6003
Security reserves/assets (%) 4.35 1.02 1.90 7.98 4.22 6078
Book equity/assets (%) 4.55 1.00 2.45 8.14 4.41 6078
Liquid assets/assets (%) 31.11 11.10 9.10 69.26 29.44 6078
Risk provisons/reference assets (%) 0.52 0.36 -0.50 1.97 0.50 6078
Risk provisions/book equity (%) 11.23 8.55 -11.31 49.36 10.31 6077
Table A.2: Descriptive statistics for the cooperative banks sample
Mean St. D. Min Max Median Obs.
Interest expense/liabilities (%) 3.14 0.68 1.66 4.97 3.17 10977
Interest expense/assets (%) 2.90 0.65 1.51 4.65 2.93 10977
Interest margin/assets (%) 2.59 0.52 0.60 4.01 2.61 10977
Book equity/assets (%) 5.43 1.29 2.68 10.90 5.25 12092
Liquid assets/assets (%) 26.87 9.90 6.66 62.27 25.50 12092
Risk provisons/reference assets (%) 0.52 0.41 -0.53 2.27 0.46 12092
Risk provisions/book equity (%) 9.27 7.82 -8.94 50.00 8.05 12092
37
Table A.3: Risk taking of savings banks relative to cooperative banks
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Book equity/ Liquid assets/ Risk provisions/ Risk provisions/
total assets total assets reference assets book equity
Savings bank × after 2001 −0.111∗∗∗ −1.459∗∗∗ 0.078∗∗∗ 2.544∗∗∗
(0.039) (0.483) (0.025) (0.541)
Savings bank × after 2005 −0.065∗∗ −0.970∗∗∗ 0.002 −0.425
(0.029) (0.293) (0.018) (0.370)
Real GDP growth 0.072 −18.536∗∗∗ −0.715∗ −12.094
(0.423) (5.216) (0.394) (7.617)
Real GDP growth × savings bank −2.232∗∗∗ 16.808∗∗ −1.253∗∗∗ −22.885∗∗
(0.493) (6.570) (0.460) (9.742)
Population density −0.003 0.016 0.000 0.029
38
(0.004) (0.034) (0.001) (0.025)
Population density × savings bank −0.007 0.045 0.002 0.084
(0.007) (0.065) (0.003) (0.076)
Banks per 100,000 inhabitants 0.011 −2.294∗∗∗ −0.006 0.060
(0.029) (0.302) (0.012) (0.245)
Banks per 100,000 inhabitants × savings bank −0.031 0.524 0.044∗∗∗ 1.258∗∗∗
(0.031) (0.322) (0.017) (0.370)
Sum of rows (1) and (2) −0.175∗∗∗ −2.430∗∗∗ 0.079∗∗∗ 2.119∗∗∗
(0.055) (0.583) (0.028) (0.611)
R2 within 0.48 0.10 0.13 0.10
Observations 18170 18170 18170 18169
Notes: All models include year fixed effects and bank fixed effects. Standard errors clustered at the bank level are given in parentheses. *, **
and *** denote significance at the 10, 5 and 1 percent level, respectively. In the bottom, the sum of the estimated coefficients of the two savings
bank-after dummies is reported, as well as standard errors and significance levels from testing the hypothesis that these coefficients sum up to
zero. Detailed variable descriptions are given in the Appendix.
Table A.4: Risk taking of savings banks relative to cooperative banks,
excluding years with extraordinary accounting events
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Book equity/ Liquid assets/ Risk provisions/ Risk provisions/
total assets total assets reference assets book equity
Savings bank × after 2001 −0.086∗∗ −1.324∗∗∗ 0.116∗∗∗ 3.044∗∗∗
(0.038) (0.486) (0.025) (0.550)
Savings bank × after 2005 −0.023 −1.258∗∗∗ 0.073∗∗∗ 0.630∗
(0.027) (0.306) (0.018) (0.376)
Real GDP growth 0.738 −29.056∗∗∗ −1.245∗∗∗ −18.294∗∗
(0.464) (5.875) (0.419) (8.487)
Real GDP growth × savings bank −2.791∗∗∗ 21.423∗∗∗ 0.319 −0.945
(0.569) (7.451) (0.500) (10.707)
Population density −0.002 0.013 0.000 0.027
39
(0.003) (0.034) (0.001) (0.024)
Population density × savings bank −0.009 0.047 0.003 0.097
(0.006) (0.065) (0.003) (0.076)
Banks per 100,000 inhabitants −0.020 −2.339∗∗∗ −0.014 −0.040
(0.025) (0.295) (0.012) (0.248)
Banks per 100,000 inhabitants × savings bank −0.016 0.584∗ 0.058∗∗∗ 1.435∗∗∗
(0.030) (0.321) (0.017) (0.371)
Sum of rows (1) and (2) −0.109∗∗ −2.582∗∗∗ 0.188∗∗∗ 3.673∗∗∗
(0.051) (0.598) (0.029) (0.631)
R2 within 0.47 0.11 0.13 0.10
Observations 16925 16925 16925 16924
Notes: All models include year fixed effects and bank fixed effects. Standard errors clustered at the bank level are given in parentheses. *, **
and *** denote significance at the 10, 5 and 1 percent level, respectively. In the bottom, the sum of the estimated coefficients of the two savings
bank-after dummies is reported, as well as standard errors and significance levels from testing the hypothesis that these coefficients sum up to
zero. Detailed variable descriptions are given in the Appendix.