The importance of competition in developing countries for productivity and
innovation
Background paper for World Development Report
Draft: not for citation without permission
Wendy Carlin and Paul Seabright
1.
Introduction
What has recent research taught us about the link between the strength and the character
of competition and the overall levels of productivity and innovation in the economy?
How can these lessons be translated into advice for public authorities wishing to use
competitive forces as an ally in the interest of improving productivity and innovation?
And finally, how does the usefulness of these lessons depend on the overall level of
development of the economy concerned? Can poor countries borrow policies “off-theshelf” from more prosperous ones or does there need to be appropriate technology in this
as in other fields? These three issues are the focus of this paper.
We discuss what competition is, how it can be measured and what are the channels
through which it can be expected to influence productivity and innovation. In doing so
we emphasize five facts which are even more important for developing than for
developed countries. These are that:
•
•
•
•
There are major differences between firms, even those in the same country and
the same market, and enjoying in principle access to the same technologies. These
differences encompass size, culture, organization and productivity.
Because of these differences, competition works not just through incentives (by
inducing all firms to be productive) but through selection (by reallocating demand
between firms with differing productivity levels, and by inducing exit and entry of
firms from the market). There is overwhelming empirical evidence that
competition cannot work effectively without selection.
Selection can nevertheless be highly disruptive, in the sense that it involves
potentially large fixed costs of entry and exit, and the breaking of business
relationships in which the parties may have made substantial investments.
The strength of competition between firms is a function not just of the behaviour
of the firms themselves towards each other, but also of the external environment
within which they compete: the state of transport and communications, the
framework of laws and regulations, the effectiveness of the financial system in
matching investment resources with entrepreneurial opportunities, the information
available to consumers and so on. We use the term “competitive infrastructure” to
refer to this ensemble of external environmental conditions, and we offer reasons
for thinking that it will be particularly inadequate in many developing countries.
•
When this competitive infrastructure is inadequate, the incentive effect of
competition will be weak. The selection effect, however, can be adversely
affected in two ways, not mutually exclusive. It may be weak (in that there is
relatively little entry and exit, or reallocation of demand between firms). It may
also be inefficient (in that, whether weak or not, such selection as occurs involves
a large amount of disruption for a small or negligible gain in productivity and
innovation).
In asking what competition is and how it can be measured, we must emphasise that
although the structure of markets has often been used as a description of the strength of
competition, it is at best an imperfect indication of the underlying competitive process.
What matters is the tendency of firms to strive after economic rewards, and thereby to
improve the efficiency of their existing products and activities as well as to create new
ones. A long tradition in economics has emphasised the multiplicity of the factors that
contribute to such an outcome, factors that have little in common beyond their helping to
liberate the energies of the entrepreneur. As we shall describe, this picture of the
determinants of efficiency and innovation finds considerable support in recent empirical
work, particularly that based on the analysis of panel data.
To define competition, we follow Stigler’s (Palgrave 1987) preference for the classical
usage of the term: competition in the product market is identified as a rivalry that arises
when two or more firms strive for something that not all can obtain. He defines the
central elements of competition: the freedom of traders to use their resources where they
will, and exchange them at any price they will.
A consequence of the definition of competition as rivalry is that it makes clear that
competition depends, paradoxically, on exclusion: I may compete with someone else to
buy livestock at auction, but the keenness of our competition depends on the knowledge
that the successful bidder will be able to exclude the other from enjoying the benefits fo
the livestock. At a minimum, therefore, competition requires there to be some framework
of expectations and rights, which may be more or less formal, and which makes it clear
what are the payoffs to competitive success. These can be described as property rights,
provided these are understood in a broad sense encompassing intellectual property and
those other aspects of the law that circumscribe what individuals may do with their
property (such as tax and regulatory laws). Since property rights enforce exclusion,
moreover, it follows that the vigour of competition cannot simply be measured by the
speed with which resources change hands: if resources never change hands the result is
economic sclerosis, while if they change hands continually the result is likely to be
anarchy.
The key to resolving this paradox is the durability of resources over time. If durability
were not an issue then competition at one time would have no implications for
competition at any other time: I may compete to get a reservation at a very popular
restaurant, and my excluding someone else may not prevent them from competing
equally vigorously with me for a table the following evening. But in practice the objects
of competition are typically assets: they may include anything from a durable good such
as a house or bullock or building site, to capital goods such as a factory, a
communications network or a licence to exploit intellectual property, to a goodwill asset
such as a customer base or a brand name (whose value depends upon there being a certain
persistence through time of customers’ buying habits). This means that the outcome of
competition in the present has implications for the character of competition in the future.
In particular, the incentives to acquire an asset may conflict with the incentives to use an
asset efficiently once it is acquired. We describe the nature of this conflict in more detail
in section 2 below.
What conditions are necessary for competition to thrive? The importance of a competitive
infrastructure has long been appreciated. In the Wealth of Nations, for example, Adam
Smith summarized the central role of competition in improving the efficiency of a market
economy and pointed to the way in which the state should target its intervention to
maximize the impact of competitive forces:
“Good roads, canals and navigable rivers, by diminishing the expense of carriage, put the
remote parts of the country more nearly upon a level with those in the neighbourhood of
the town. They are upon that account the greatest of all improvements. They encourage
the cultivation of the remote, which must always be the most extensive circle of the
country. They are advantageous to the town, by breaking down the monopoly of the
country in its neighbourhood. They are advantageous even to that part of the country.
Though they introduce some rival commodities into the old market, they open many new
markets to its product. Monopoly, besides, is a great enemy to good management, which
can never be universally established but in consequence of that free and universal
competition which forces everybody to have recourse to it for the sake of self-defence.”
(1776, Pelican edition 1970, p. 251)
“China seems to have been long stationary, and had probably long ago acquired that full
complement of riches which is consistent with the nature of its laws and institutions. But
this complement may be much inferior to what, with other laws and institutions, the
nature of its soil, climate, and situation might admit of. A country which neglects or
despises foreign commerce, and which admits the vessels of foreign nations into one or
two of its ports only, cannot transact the same quantity of business which it might do with
different laws and institutions. In a country, too, where though the rich or the owners of
large capitals enjoy a good deal of security, the poor or the owners of small capitals enjoy
scarce any … the quantity of stock employed in all the different branches of business
transacted within it can never be equal to what the nature and extent of that business
might admit. In every different branch, the oppression of the poor must establish the
monopoly of the rich, who, by engrossing the whole trade to themselves, will be able to
make very large profits.” (pp. 197-198).
As these passages suggest, competition improves productivity in the following ways:
- it allows the greater efficiency from the division of labour and the associated
gains from specialization to be reaped
-
it extends the market for more efficient producers. This allows market
selection to operate.
it introduces new low cost sources of supply and new products
it raises management effort and squeezes out inefficiencies.
Each of these processes comes into play because of on the one hand, the incentive of
achieving at least temporary super-normal profits through innovation1 and on the other,
of the threat that innovation by existing and potential firms poses to the survival of
incumbents in the market. In addition to establishing a framework for linking competition
to performance, Smith identified the role for policy. The role of the state in maximizing
the impact of competitive forces is:
- to extend and improve the physical transportation, communication and
information infrastructure
- to establish openness to trade
- to establish the appropriate laws and institutions to facilitate new entry and to
challenge entrenched monopolies.
The emphasis on the importance of both physical and institutional infrastructure to
competition will strike some readers as obvious but is often overlooked in discussions of
competition policy. Anti-trust policy has traditionally concerned itself with features of the
competitors, while the overall vigour of competition requires attention also to the
physical infrastructure of transportation, the legal infrastructure of contract enforcement,
licensing and regulation of internal and external trade, the financial and regulatory
infrastructure that allows entry and growth of new firms, and finally the communications
infrastructure that allow information to flow freely between buyers and sellers and break
down pre-existing informational monopolies.
In Smith’s day the responsibility of the state for such infrastructure may have seemed
relatively clear-cut. This remains the case in relation to the establishment and
enforcement of a legal framework to uphold contracts. The state is also responsible for
controlling its ‘grabbing hand’ (Sheifer and Vishny, 1998) and for facilitating openness
to trade – not only to international trade but trade at a much more local level. But in terms
of the provision of physical and communications infrastructure, more recent
developments have added a new twist, which is that important elements of infrastructure
may themselves be supplied by private firms. Indeed, public authorities have increasingly
found themselves required to adjudicate the terms and conditions under which private
firms may supply goods or services, among the main benefits of which are to facilitate
vigorous competition in markets downstream. Examples are telecommunications
networks, computer operating systems, airports and rail networks. In every case a
difficult trade-off is involved: obliging such goods or services to be supplied too cheaply
may improve the downstream competitive environment today, but at the price of
diminishing the incentives for future innovation in competitive infrastructure. In certain
specific contexts (telecoms access pricing for instance, or the grant of patents for
intellectual property) the terms of this trade-off have been fairly rigorously explored. But
1
We interpret innovation very broadly to mean the introduction of products new to the local market and of
methods of production new to the local firms.
the fact of such a trade-off underlies a great many difficult questions in the general field
of competition policy, broadly interpreted.
To diagnose the role that competition plays in developing economies and how that role
can be enhanced is a complex task. This paper proceeds as follows. In section 2 we
discuss alternative ways of measuring the strength of competition. In section 3, we
discuss the promotion of competition, focusing on the trade-off between static and
dynamic considerations. In particular, we identify how different industry and country
characteristics affect the way that firms compete and spell out the implications of these
differences for policy design.
In section 4 (the longest in the paper), we turn from the nature of how firms compete to
the question of what effect that competition has on economic performance. We develop
the argument sketched above that competition operates on aggregate performance and
innovation through selection as well as having a direct influence on productivity
performance within surviving firms. We summarise what is known empirically about
these difference channels of influence.
In section 5, we discuss how policy can use this knowledge to affect competition in ways
that enhance overall productivity and innovation. We pay particular attention to
differences between countries and the differential suitability of particular policies to
different country settings. Section 6 makes some concluding remarks.
2.
Measuring the vigour of competition
One common and intuitive starting point for measuring competition is the extent to which
production is concentrated in the hands of a few firms, each of which therefore faces
comparatively little rivalry. The crudest measure of this concentration is simply the
number of firms that are operating in the same or a recognisably similar market. To be
useful this measure depends on there being some practical method of defining the
relevant market (see Neven et.al., 1993, chapter 2), which essentially means finding
goods and services that are reasonably close substitutes for each other while being distant
substitutes for all other goods or services. But while the number of firms may be a useful
first indicator, it may be seriously misleading when there are important differences in
size, strength and productivity between firms (as there are in most markets in all
countries, a phenomenon we document in section 4 below). For example, the exit of one
large firm and entry of many small ones may reduce measured concentration but lower
the vigour of the rivalry faced by the remaining large firms. This problem has been
observed in many transition countries where the exit of one or two large enterprises from
an industry along with the simultaneous entry of many new small firms has resulted in a
reduction in effective competition (see Kattuman and Domanski, 1998 on Poland). One
way of dealing with this is by calculating measures of market power at the firm rather
than the market level, in particular by looking directly at the market share of each
individual firm. Another way is to summarise the structure of the market in a way that is
sensitive to dispersion: the Herfindahl-Hirschman index (the sum of the squares of the
market shares of the firms) is the best-known such measure, and one used in many policy
applications.
A second way of measuring competition is to look at the consequences of market
structure rather than market structure itself, and specifically at the freedom firms have to
choose prices (and other business strategies) independently of any concern about losing
business to other firms. A natural way to do this is to estimate the so-called residual
elasticity of demand for the firm’s own products, namely the extent to which a price rise
by the firm would lead customers to substitute away, either to rival firms or away from
the product altogether. When sophisticated data are available this elasticity can
sometimes be estimated econometrically (see Hausman et.al., 1992, for an application to
the case of beer), and it is particularly useful to do so when products are differentiated so
that the notion of a single product market may make little sense. However, even in the
absence of suitable data it may be a useful organising framework in which to think about
the competition faced by a firm: does the qualitative evidence suggest that the firm faces
significant constraints on its ability to raise prices?
A third and altogether different approach to measuring competition is to look directly at
the behaviour of firms and to infer from this the extent of the rivalry they believe
themselves to face. In particular, the price-cost margin charged by a profit-maximising
firm facing constant marginal costs (given by the technology and not capable of being
influenced by the firm itself) will be inversely proportional to the own-price elasticity of
demand for its products. If price-cost margins can be reliably measured, therefore, they
may themselves be an inverse indicator of the vigour of competition in the market.
Are these three ways of measuring competition consistent with one another? Table 1
looks at the relation between these three types of measure using data from the World
Bank/EBRD business environment survey:
• As a measure of market structure we use the number of competitors reported by
the respondent in the market for its main product, dividing firms into those
reporting respectively no competitors, between one and three competitors and
more than three competitors.
• As a measure of firms’ freedom to raise prices we use their response to a question
asking them what would be the consequence of a 10% rise in the real price of
their product by 10%, scoring from one (for firms reporting that most customers
would switch to rival suppliers) to four (for firms reporting that most customers
would continue to buy in similar quantities as previously).
• As a measure of firms’ behaviour we use their (self-reported) price-cost margin.
We report mean values of the second and third measure for firms categorised by the first
measure, and sub-categorised by ownership status (state firm, privatised firm and other)
in order to control for different degrees of commitment to profit-maximising behaviour.
The answers clearly indicate that in markets with no competitors firms report lower ownprice elasticities of demand and higher price-cost margins than in markets with 1-3
competitors, though the effect is weaker for state firms than others (as one might expect
given their weaker incentives for profit-maximisation).
Table 1
Market power (10% test) and price-cost margin
by ownership and number of competitors
Competitors:
None
1 to 3
>3
Total
105
163
1,009
1,277
18.3
15.3
15.4
15.6
2.65
2.38
2.13
2.20
187
112
359
658
16.2
12.4
17.2
16.0
3.09
2.47
2.25
2.51
104
252
1,808
2,164
22.3
20.7
17.8
18.3
2.45
2.38
2.01
2.08
396
527
3,176
4,099
18.5
17.2
16.9
17.1
2.80
2.40
2.08
2.18
Privatized
(number)
% price-cost
margin
10% test (answer
from 1 - all
customers switch to 4 - customers
continue to buy as
before)
State
(number)
% price-cost
margin
10% test (answer
from 1 to 4)
New firm
(number)
% price-cost
margin
10% test (answer
from 1 to 4)
Total
(number)
% price-cost
margin
10% test (answer
from 1 to 4)
Table 2
Determinants of price-cost margin
ion number
ation method
observations
t power (10% test):
would fall a lot
would fall slightly
ange in sales
t share
er of competitors:
ompetitors
than 3 competitors
ew firm with no competitors:
3 competitors
ore than 3 competitors
ate firm with no competitors:
3 competitors
than 3 competitors
ant
1
OLS
3175
Coefficient
t-ratio
2.53
3.23
5.69
3.19
4.01
5.76
14.89
29.28
2
OLS
2037
Coefficient
t-ratio
2.07
2.82
5.73
0.05
1.93
2.60
4.21
3.21
0.99
1.66
9.82
-6.14
-8.25
-1.43
-4.11
2.78
0.33
0.63
2.46
-1.33
-2.02
-0.44
-0.96
0.78
3
2SLS
2037
Coefficient
t-ratio
6.73
8.83
12.62
1.41
1.72
3.41
11.49
4.95
Table 2 shows the significant link between market power as measured by the 10% test
and the price-cost margin. It really is true that firms reporting that sales would not fall
much in response to a price rise, profit from that knowledge to raise their margins. Firms
replying that there would be no significant change in sales have margins nearly 6
percentage points above those replying that most customers would switch to their rivals.
More interestingly still, individual market share has additional predictive power, as does
the number of competitors in the market. When we take into account (as in equation 3)
that market structure variables work via their effect on market power, so that we control
for the endogeneity of the market power variable, the observed effect of market power on
price-cost margins more than doubles. Firms replying that there would be no significant
change in sales have margins more than 12 percentage points above those replying that
most customers would switch to their rivals.
Indeed, the comparative insignificance of most of the market structure (number of
competitors) variables in equation 2 does not mean they are unimportant: rather, they
work almost entirely through their effect on market power. Table 3 illustrates:
Table 3
Determinants of market power
Ordered logit, n=2313, industry and country controls
Coefficient
Std. Err.
z-value
Market share
State firm
New entrant
Number of competitors:
1-3 competitors
More than 3 competitors
0.006
0.170
0.057
0.00
0.12
0.09
3.86
1.43
0.60
-0.853
-1.163
0.17
0.15
-5.13
-7.78
Threshold 1
Threshold 2
Threshold 3
-1.382
-0.213
1.283
0.27
0.27
0.27
The variables for number of competitors are extremely significant, and large in absolute
magnitude. They mean that, other things equal, firms with more than 3 competitors will
report nearly one point less on the market power scale (which runs from 1 to 4).
What is the significance of these findings? They show that market structure, market
power and behavioural measures of competition are consistent with one another, that they
complement one another, and that they may give a very useful indication of the general
state of competition in a market. However, this does not mean that the picture they give is
complete. Far from it. In particular, all three kinds of measure focus on short-term
diagnosis and ignore indicators of the longer-term competitive evolution of the markets
concerned:
1) Current market structure variables leave out potential competitors – those that
could threaten entry into the market even though they currently leave no imprint
upon it. In some markets potential competitors are a more credible threat than in
others, particularly where sunk costs are high (as in many physical network
industries). No analysis of the state of competition can afford to ignore such
differences between the circumstances of different industries (a point to which we
return below).
2) Price elasticities as measured at a point in time may give an inaccurate impression
of the extent to which established markets are under threat from future challenge.
3) High price-cost margins are not always an indication of undesirable market
power. They may be a temporary reward for innovation, and everything depends
on whether they act as a signal for rivals to emulate the success of the firms that
enjoy them.
Unfortunately, there exist no simple measures of the vigour of potential or future
competition with which the three kinds of measure of current competition can be
systematically compared. Inevitably diagnosis must be conducted on a more qualitative
and common-sense basis as a result. Nevertheless, as we discuss below, useful
conclusions for policy can still be drawn.
3. Promoting competition
3.1 Static versus dynamic considerations
Our discussions of definition and measurement have emphasized the importance of both
static and dynamic perspectives on competition. Competition is about rivalry in the
acquisition of assets, and also about rivalry in their use, and we cannot assume that
conditions which are favourable to one will always be favourable to the other.
What does this imply for how competition can be promoted? Different approaches to
competition policy can be characterised according to the relative emphasis they place on
incentives for the acquisition of assets versus incentives for their use. Traditional antitrust policy has very much concentrated on the latter, on ensuring that those in charge of
productive assets use them in efficient ways, and has seen allocative inefficiency through
the charging of price above marginal cost as the greatest threat. In contrast, competition
policy of the Chicago school has focussed instead on removing obstacles to the efficient
acquisition of assets, reasoning that owners who will not use assets efficiently once they
are acquired will not wish to compete vigorously to acquire them in the first place. It
seems reasonable to suggest that the intellectual pendulum has in recent years swung
away from an exclusive focus on the efficient use of assets and towards a greater concern
with their efficient acquisition (the increasing use of auctions for allocating such assets as
radio spectrum being a logical culmination of this trend). Nevertheless, those competing
to acquire assets are unable to commit very precisely to the way in which such assets will
be used once they are acquired, and it is these failures of commitment that make
inefficient use a potentially serious area of concern. There are several main reasons for
these failures of commitment:
1) Very often information about the economic characteristics of the asset (and its
compatibility with the economic characteristics of the owner) does not become
available until after it is acquired. An entrant to a market may come to realise it is
not as effective a competitor as it thought it would be. However, incentives for
exit are not symmetric with those of entry, and frequently it may be difficult for
the assets of a failing firm to be efficiently reallocated to a more efficient
competitor. Something similar is true of firms that, though not misinformed about
market conditions, nevertheless have skills that are suited to only temporary
configurations of circumstances, but whose comparative advantage in a certain
activity expires before their strategic advantage based on incumbency. Thus firms
which are well suited to engage in foreign trade in a highly protectionist regime
(because they have good contacts with government agencies, for example) may be
very poorly suited to a more liberal environment, but their mere presence and
control over distribution channels may be a major barrier to entry by other,
potentially more efficient firms.
2) The owner of an asset can rarely be bound to a precise policy (say on prices) at
the time of acquisition, and after entry to a market will set its prices and
investments ignoring any externalities on customers or competitors. Privatized
utilities have frequently behaved in this way when regulatory regimes have been
weak.
3) Few economically productive assets have single owners, but are usually owned
and controlled by groups of interested parties (such as shareholders), who may
bargain after the acquisition in inefficient ways. Unless there is an efficient
market for corporate control, firms controlling productive assets may not
maximise the rents from those assets, because of the nature of bargaining between
managers, workers and shareholders. Thus firms privatised to coalitions of
workers (this is sometimes known as “insider” privatisation”) may be unable to
raise outside capital for much-needed investment because of an inability to
commit to a credible repayment schedule.
Broadly speaking, public policy has focussed on the following mechanisms to overcome
these three sources of commitment failure:
1) Bankruptcy law, unemployment benefit and other such means to remove
barriers to exit of ineffectively performing firms.
2) The creation of competitive infrastructure (including the removal of such
barriers to entry as trade restrictions, licensing regulation, switching costs
between competitors and obstacles to information transmission) in order to
create ex post rivalry, so that firms failing to use assets efficiently can be
quickly challenged by others.
3) The prohibition of collusion (including collusion by merger) so that firms do
indeed react to the removal of entry barriers by strenuous rivalry.
4) Direct intervention to control behaviour (such as price regulation) when the
outcome of such rivalry does not internalise all the relevant ex post
externalities.
All of these mechanisms have their weaknesses due to the likelihood that they will only
imperfectly be implemented: bankruptcy law may soften but not remove all barriers to
exit, trade liberalisation may remove only some entry barriers and so on. But there are
two problems in addition that may arise when these mechanisms work too well:
•
•
First, the only way to bring about credible ex post rivalry for an asset such as a
market presence may be to share the asset. In the case of some assets subject to
large scale economies that may impose large efficiency costs. However, there has
been much evolution over time in ways of sharing access to assets more
efficiently than was true in the past (the unbundling of the local loop in fixed-line
telephony being an important example).
Secondly, ex post rivalry may weaken the incentives for ex ante rivalry, that is for
the competition to acquire the assets in the first place.
How much this second problem matters depends upon whether important real
investments are needed up front in order to acquire and efficiently to use the asset. If the
asset is the right to trade a certain good, very little real investment is required up front
and consequently there will be little damage done by making that right subject to
vigorous ex post rivalry. If the asset is a detailed piece of intellectual property that can
only be achieved by intensive and expensive research and development, then strong ex
post rivalry may have a large and damaging impact. Intermediate cases include those
where the formal intellectual property (such as a trade-mark) may be slight but the
complementary investments in distribution and know-how may be considerable; here the
adverse effect of ex post rivalry will depend on the extent to which such investments can
be recouped on exit.
The qualification “real” is important because investments purely to bid for a licence (say
in a spectrum auction) do not count as real investments in this sense: if ex post
competition reduces the rents bidders are prepared to pay up front there is no reduction in
overall economic efficiency, only a reduction in the transfer which ultimately comes from
consumers to the auctioneers of the asset.
What this suggests is that arguments for a general softening of ex post rivalry purely on
the grounds that up front real investments are sometimes required should be dismissed.
(Journalistic opinions can sometimes be heard to the effect that “the information
economy requires cooperation, not competition”.) Competitive infrastructure should
indeed be directed towards creating vigorous ex post rivalry as a general rule. But there
may be grounds for a softening of such rivalry when a clear necessity can be
demonstrated for recouping up-front real investment. Intellectual property law creates a
framework for such arguments within a particular class of cases, but its applicability is
obviously limited to those kinds of knowledge investment that can be sufficiently
codified to fall under the appropriate law. Many kinds of knowledge investment are not
of this kind: how to run a franchise operation, how to organise a car assembly plant, how
to train hotel staff, how to deploy a fleet of buses. Other up-front investments may
require major capital resources whose value does not reside in intellectual property as
such: a semiconductor plant, an oil refinery, a fibre-optic network. Many such
investments will indeed be adequately protected by the natural obstacles to ex post rivalry
that the existing competitive infrastructure cannot completely remove. But there will be
cases where more explicit protection may be required, though these will need to be
demonstrated on a case by case basis.
3.2 Industry variation in the nature of anti-competitive problems
To the extent that these kinds of consideration differ from industry to industry, policy
will need to be sensitive to the industry type. For example, Sutton (1991) points to the
difference between industries characterized by exogenous and endogenous sunk costs.
The key difference between the exogenous and endogenous sunk cost industries is the
source of economies of scale. In the former, it is production economies of scale and in the
latter it is overheads such as advertizing and R&D. Marketing and R&D expenditures are
endogenous in the sense that there is no upper limit to their scope for generating scale
economies as long as extra spending generates the prospect of an ‘innovation’. This
means that whereas production economies of scale are the key determinant of the
concentration of exogenous sunk cost industries, they appear to have little role in the
concentration of R&D and advertizing intensive industries.
Exogenous sunk cost industries can be
- low sunk cost industries, in which entry barriers are low. We would expect entry to be
concentrated here and competition can probably be policed with a relatively light
hand. However, there will be limited scope for productivity growth.
Alternatively, they can be
- high exogenous sunk cost industries. Here the main problem is likely to be the slow
exit of loss-makers, and the consequent weak incentives for productive operation
within the industry in the absence of a credible threat of exit.
However, to the extent that some of these sunk costs are the result of artificial
regulations, liberalization may transform some such industries into
- endogenous sunk cost industries. Here it is important to distinguish the cases where
the endogenous sunk costs are genuinely productivity-enhancing and those where
they are purely exclusionary (as in pre-emptive patenting or brand proliferation
strategies).
Davies and Lyons (1996) use Sutton’s distinction to classify industries in Europe.
Exogenous sunk cost industries, which are referred to as Type 1 industries, account for
just over half of manufacturing industries and are mainly associated with the processing
of materials (iron and steel, cement, foundries, grain-milling, textiles, wood-processing).
These industries are the least concentrated. However, as shown in appendix 1, there are
some highly concentrated Type 1 industries and potential competition problems may
arise there.
Endogenous sunk cost industries (Type 2 industries) are advertizing-intensive, R&Dintensive or both advertizing and R&D-intensive. The last group are much the most
concentrated. Table 4 summarizes the characteristics of industries that are relevant for
understanding how competition works.
Table 4. Competition and industry type: a classification of industries in Europe
Exogenous sunk
cost industries
Endogenous sunk cost industries
Adv. -intensive
R&D-intensive
Share of manuf.
industries
Typical industries
1/2
1/8
1/4
iron and steel,
cement, foundries,
grain-milling,
textiles, woodprocessing
food, drink and
tobacco
chemicals,
engineering and
transport
equipment
Concentration?
Multi-nationality?
Traded?
4th
4th
mixed
3rd
2nd
low
2nd
3rd
high
Adv. and R&Dintensive
1/8
cars, domestic
electrical
appliances,
pharmaceuticals
and soaps and
detergents
1st
1st
high
Determinants of
concentration
production econs
of scale
production economies of scale weak influence
Source: Davies and Lyons (1996), chapter 14.
In appendix 1, we report the results of the Davies and Lyons’ study of concentration and
its likely connection to anti-competitive problems in European industry. Whilst this
analysis is not of direct use to developing economies, the considerations that lie behind it
are helpful in showing how policy makers should conduct a systematic analysis so as to
identify potential problem industries. The following guidelines refer to the patterns
displayed in Table A1 in the appendix.
• Classify industries by the domestic concentration ratio. Highly concentrated
industries are the ones where competition problems are likely to be found.
• Use the EU bench-mark to help to establish the underlying industry characteristics
such as the extent of production economies of scale and to classify industries into
exogenous and endogenous sunk cost industries.
• Compare the extent of trade integration by industry with the EU bench-mark. The
EU-benchmark gives an indication of the potential for trade integration by industry.
Table A1 shows that there is considerable variation across industries in the extent to
which trade can alleviate potential anti-competitive problems. Weak competition is
likely to be found in highly concentrated industries with low trade.
• The limited role of trade in advertizing-intensive industries even in the European
market is especially striking. Such industries constitute potential problems in respect
of competition.
• Pay particular attention to Type 1 (i.e. exogenous sunk cost) industries with high
concentration. Such industries may be characterized by large production economies
of scale – in some cases national producers lobby for protection from market
pressures for the rationalization of the industry at an international level.
• Note the role of multinational ownership. Davies and Lyons argue that multinational
ownership in an industry is a method through which leading international firms
control the flow of international trade and may therefore present anti-competitive
problems. However, it is unlikely that policy makers in developing countries will be
able to effectively deal with such problems. Similarly with the highly concentrated
but highly traded R&D intensive industries, the investigation of possible anticompetitive R&D and advertizing strategies will lie outside the scope of national
authorities in developing countries.
• Identify policies of public procurement. This has been a major method through which
specific industries have been protected in European countries.
3.3 Country variation in the nature of anti-competitive problems
Similarly, to the extent that these types of consideration differ from country to country,
policy may well need to be sensitive to the country type. For example:
-
small open economies will be ones in which entry from foreign firms provides most
of the necessary ex post rivalry (subject to the industry variation discussed above),
-
-
-
while large closed economies are ones in which the state of domestic infrastructure
may constitute a competitive bottleneck. Trade liberalization may bring foreign goods
to the border, but most consumers do not live at the border, either geographically or
in the sense of having information equivalent to those of world consumers.
Economies in which literacy levels are low and information transmission is expensive
will have weak ex post competition in most spheres, so protection of up-front
investments is likely to be less often a convincing argument for softening rivalry. This
is because vigorous competition often requires consumers to make informed
comparisons between rival products, and literacy and education greatly increase the
quality of such consumer scrutiny.
Poor countries are unlikely to need to do much primary research and development,
but will need to focus on the investments required for adapting existing technologies
and best practice from other markets for domestic implementation. This means that
intellectual property based up-front investments are likely to be of less importance
than in advanced countries
However, the poor state of physical infrastructure in many developing countries
means that both costs of investment and willingness to pay for improvements are high
(particularly in such areas as telecommunications). This consideration probably
diminishes the importance of ex post rivalry in the construction of physical networks.
Overall these considerations suggest that for many developing countries, policies to
increase ex post competition are likely to be at least as important as they are for rich
countries. The only significant exception concerns those physical infrastructure industries
(such as telecommunications) where capacity shortages are more important than the
inefficient utilisation of existing capacity.
In section 5 below we return to these issues after reviewing the empirical evidence.
4.
The influence of competition on behaviour and performance
In this section, attention is shifted from the nature of how firms compete to the question
of what effect that competition has on economic performance. The competitive struggle
involves the growth and decline of firms, the entry of new ones and the exit of poor
performers. We would view the competitive process as an efficient one if it is able to
separate out the good from the bad performers, to induce the entry of low cost firms that
may challenge the incumbents and to facilitate the exit of the firms with low efficiency.
To identify how the competitive process operates, we therefore need data on the rise and
fall of firms, the significance of entry and of exit. This is a much more onerous data
collection task than is required for snap-shots of industry structure at a point in time.
As will be seen, the evidence points overwhelmingly to the fact that competition works
not just by creating incentives for given firms to perform better but by sorting between
more and less successful firms. It might be thought that this would be less important for
developing countries than for others, because such countries have a greater need for
“catch-up” and a lesser need for original innovation, and catch-up might be considered
less a matter of risk-taking and more a matter of simply observing and implementing
international best practice. But in fact the evidence is clear: catch-up is as risky and
turbulent a process as original innovation, and so the sorting effects of competition are at
least as important in developing as in industrialised countries.
In confronting the evidence, what are we looking for? A number of theoretical models
help to identify how competition might affect performance. We focus on models that
present testable hypotheses and for which we can provide some empirical evidence. We
separate out four effects on which to focus the theoretical and empirical discussion:
- the selection effect (how the market operates to reallocate market shares from
lower to higher productivity firms),
- the incentive effect on incumbents (how rivalry alters behaviour)
- the entry effect (how new suppliers enter the market and thus affect aggregate
performance both by virtue of the new capacity that they bring and by
influencing incumbents), and
- the exit effect (how poor performers are able to leave the market and release
resources).
We begin with a model that provides an overview of the competitive process and follow
this by highlighting models that provide additional insights about how competition may
raise productivity within firms.
4.1 Selection, entry and internal restructuring
Aghion and Schankerman (2000) develop a simple model to investigate the effects of
competition on performance. They use a model of monopolistic competitive producers of
differentiated products in which location on a circle is the measure of product
differentiation. Both incumbent firms and potential entrants are characterized by
asymmetric production costs, either high or low cost. Unit transportation costs measure
the intensity of product market competition. They look at three cases. In the first case
where there is no entry and the productivity levels of firms are fixed, the welfare effects
of lowering transportation costs – i.e. of improving the competitive infrastructure – arise
from the direct effect of greater competition in lowering the profit margins of both high
and low cost firms and from the selection effect as the market share of the low cost firms
increases. The only offsetting negative effect arises from the impact of greater
concentration of market share on the product variety available. They show that welfare
increases as competitive infrastructure improves and that it increases more, the greater is
the initial cost asymmetry between firms. This model therefore predicts that the scope for
competitive infrastructure policies to improve the selection effect depends on the level of
cost asymmetries. If cost asymmetries are masked by other distortions such as subsidies
or other forms of budget softness, then selection will not occur. Hence policies that
reduce subsidies will complement policies that improve the intensity of competition.
The second effect introduces incentive effects for incumbents to exert effort to undertake
restructuring. (We examine a broader class of models that address the question of why an
increase in competition may influence firm performance below.) If effort costs are
convex and there are no costs (such as bankruptcy costs) associated with a low market
share, then there is a stronger incentive for low cost firms to restructure than high cost
ones. This raises the degree of cost asymmetry and enhances the efficiency improving
effect of market selection. The model therefore predicts that in a more developed
economy, there will be a greater degree of cost asymmetry. Moreover the corollary is that
since a lower level of cost asymmetry lowers the returns from increased competition, it is
likely to tilt the political balance from those who may favour more competition (low cost
firms) to those who will unambiguously lose from greater competition (high cost firms).
The result may be a low-competition trap, characterizing developing economies.
The third result derives from the role of entry. In a standard model with homogeneous
cost firms (e.g. Tirole 1988), an increase in competition in the market will have the effect
of deterring entry because the rents available to a new entrant are reduced. This is a static
version of the standard Schumpeterian argument that higher rents are the necessary
inducement for innovation. However, Aghion and Schankerman show that this result can
be reversed if potential entrants and incumbents vary in their productivity levels. An
increase in the intensity of competition in the market may induce low cost entrants to
come in, since although rents will be squeezed by the greater competition, low cost firms
will be able to capture a greater share of the market. The net effect may be sufficient to
induce productivity-enhancing entry. The entry effect of an enhanced competitive
infrastructure will not work if the initial level of competition and the initial cost
asymmetry are too low. The reason is that both low and high cost firms enter and the
market selection effect is too weak to sort the firms.
This model is useful because it provides predictions about how an increase in competition
would affect aggregate productivity through its effects on incumbents and on the entry
decision, as well as via market selection. The model also brings to the fore how other
reform policies (such as hardening enterprise budget constraints by reducing implicit or
explicit subsidies) interact with policies to increase competition. In addition, it identifies
how a low competition- low productivity trap can persist.
4.2 Incentive effects for incumbents
There have been many attempts to model the mechanisms through which increased
competitive pressure influences the behaviour of the individual firm. The puzzle arises
because on the face of it, a monopolist has the same incentive to improve efficiency as a
producer in a competitive market. Why should an increase in competitive pressure
increase efficiency? One response is to identify increased competitive pressure as
operating on the margin of slack that characterizes a firm with agency problems. We
highlight two channels through which this could operate: first, the link between
competition and managerial effort and second, the impact of competition on the
bargained effort of workers.
Competition and managerial effort
More competition may make comparison of
managerial performance easier and hence elicit greater effort from managers, thereby
improving efficiency (Holmstrom, 1982, Hart, 1983). Vickers (1995) extended this
argument by highlighting the significance of comparisons of performance for the future
rewards in the managerial labour market. Because of such ‘reputation effects’, greater
competition will prompt greater managerial effort. It has also been argued (Willig, 1987)
that tougher competition makes profits more responsive to managerial effort. This may
encourage greater effort unless the offsetting impact of more competition in depressing
demand for the firm’s product is too large. Willig’s model identifies a possible source of
ambiguity in the relationship between competition and managerial effort and hence
between competition and performance. Willig’s point is an important one – an increase in
competition is an increase in the adversity facing the firm. If this is too strong, then the
effect may be counterproductive.
It is usually assumed that the manager of a firm derives a private benefit from this
position, which will be lost if the firm closes down. If increased competition increases the
threat of bankruptcy, then this will raise the manager’s effort. However, as we will see
below in the discussion of exit, the efficacy of this incentive depends on the nature and
enforcement of the bankruptcy code.
The standard Schumpeterian argument is that if competition in the product market is too
strong (ex post competition), it can have deleterious effects on innovation because it
dissipates the rewards from innovation (ex ante competition). This means that the
incentive to sink the costs necessary to innovate is reduced. However, he also emphasizes
the spur to innovation that a heightened competitive threat can represent. The emergence
of new competitors will threaten the temporary monopoly profits from innovation and
increase the incentive of the incumbents to shorten the innovation cycle. Except in the
pure entrepreneurial firm, this effect can operate through managerial incentives since
introducing new products or processes involves managerial effort. The point is that
effort-minimizing managers can survive by delaying innovations subject to the constraint
of keeping the firm afloat. If more competition reduces profits now and in future periods,
the manager has to introduce innovations earlier in order to survive. The result is faster
productivity growth (Aghion, Dewatripont and Rey 1997).
In emphasizing the role of managerial effort in establishing the link between competition
and efficiency, these models rely on the existence of an agency problem between the
owners of the firm and the managers. The agency problem creates a zone of managerial
discretion bounded below by the threat of bankruptcy and the associated loss of private
benefits to the manager and above by the ability of the owners to exert control over the
manager. This suggests that the effect of an increase in competition is likely to be
influenced by the significance of the agency problem and by how close to binding is the
threat of bankruptcy. If there is no significant agency problem then an increase in
competition will not have much purchase on performance through the mechanisms
described. By contrast, if the agency problem is substantial, then the ability of
competition to enhance efficiency through influencing managerial effort is greater. In this
framework, at the level of the firm, corporate governance and competition are substitutes.
In developing countries and transition countries, good corporate governance is likely to
be rare. This highlights the potential role for competition to improve performance.
Looking at the second margin – namely, the scope for managerial slack created by the
failure of financial pressure to bite – highlights the role of the bankruptcy system and its
enforcement. For a given bankruptcy system, we would expect to see more managerial
effort expended to improve efficiency in a firm in greater financial distress. In a similar
fashion to the corporate governance argument, this will weaken the impact of an increase
in competition. To put this another way, if the bankruptcy system is relatively ineffective,
then an increase in competition can act as a substitute in increasing managerial effort. For
firms protected from the financial discipline of bankruptcy for other reasons, competition
can provide a substitute. It should be noted that the effectiveness of financial discipline
will depend not only on nature of bankruptcy code and on legal enforcement but also on
the state of the banking system – if banks are awash with non-performing loans, then they
will expect a bail-out from the state and not call in non-performing loans. Under such
conditions, firms will feel little financial pressure. Equally, introducing harsh competition
in a situation in which firms are close to bankruptcy will have little pay-off.
Competition and bargained effort
A second channel through which more competition
can raise productivity arises if workers also share in the firm’s rents and engage in a
bargain over wages and effort. In a static context, effort can refer to manning levels and
in a dynamic context, to the introduction of new technology. A bargaining model predicts
that in the static case, for example, bargained productivity levels will increase when
workers’ bargaining power is reduced and when the rents available to firms in the product
market are reduced. Hence for a given structure of union organization and bargaining
power, greater competition will lower rents, raise bargained effort and hence productivity
(Grout, 1984, Haskel 1991)
Numbers of competitors – non-linear or non-monotonic effects
Both Schumpeterian
and Sutton-inspired models predict that the number of competitors in the market (as
measured for example by a standard indicator of market concentration) is not necessarily
a good measure of the effective rivalry in the market, once account is taken of both static
and dynamic considerations. In particular, innovators need the prospect of some market
power as a reward to innovation, but monopolists that face no challenge will merely rest
on the laurels of their past success. It is likely, therefore, that markets with many
competitors will undertake little innovation, though this may not be true if firms can find
“niche” markets in which to enjoy some perhaps temporary market power. Likewise, it
seems probable that monopolists with no competitors will be inefficient and not
particularly innovative. The most important lesson is the need to challenge monopolists,
not to increase the intensity of competition once a certain threshold has been reached.
The important question will therefore be: how much competition is “enough”?
We summarise the main messages of the theoretical literature in section 4.3
4.3 Key theoretical findings
• If both incumbents and potential entrants have varying productivity levels, a better
competitive infrastructure will raise aggregate productivity by shifting market shares
to more productive firms and by encouraging entry by more rather than less
productive firms. In addition, it may increase the relative rewards to more rather than
less productive firms from improvements in performance.
• Less productive firms will definitely lose out from increased competition and will
therefore oppose measures to improve the competitive infrastructure.
• A given improvement in the competitive infrastructure will have a greater effect on
aggregate productivity, the greater is the initial extent of heterogeneity in productivity
levels between firms. Hence other policies that mask productivity differentials such as
current or capital subsidies or condoning tax arrears will weaken the impact of
improvements in competitive infrastructure.
• The impact of heightened competition on ‘within-firm’ performance will be greater,
the weaker is the quality of corporate governance and the less actual financial
pressure from the threat of bankruptcy the firm is under. Improvements in the
effectiveness of the bankruptcy code will not only raise managerial effort but also
contribute to aggregate productivity growth by expediting the exit of poor performers.
• There may not be a monotonic relationship between the number of competitors in a
market and the intensity of rivalry. There may be more intense rivalry with “a few”
competitors than with either many or none.
4.4 Evidence on the role of competition in productivity growth in market economies
– advanced and less developed
4.4.1 The selection effect: the contribution of entry, exit and growth to overall
productivity change
What effects of competition on performance are found and what is their economic
significance? The recent availability of census data in the form of panels has allowed the
dynamics of competition to be documented in market economies for the first time
(though we shall also refer where appropriate to some of the conclusions of older cross-
sectional studies). By tracking the entry, exit, growth and merger of firms over a period
of time, it is possible to measure how each process contributes in an accounting sense to
the improvement in productivity. Why do we want to know this? As we have seen,
different policy tools impinge on different aspects of the competitive process and if some
dimensions appear to be important in well-functioning market economies but are much
less evident or absent in developing ones, then we have a clearer diagnosis of the source
of the problem and a better idea of how policy can best be targeted.
Advanced market economies
As we shall see, the information available on the contribution of entry and exit, selection
and within-firm changes to aggregate productivity growth in developing countries is
fragmentary. To make sense of the available data, it is necessary to establish a benchmark from an advanced market economy. This tells us what can be expected in a
reasonably well-functioning economy. In this regard, Baldwin’s detailed study of
Canadian industry is very instructive (Baldwin, 1993). The data relate to the
manufacturing sector for the decade of the 1970s. He separates the contributions to the
competitive process of greenfield entry (entry of a firm by opening a new plant) and
closedown exit (exit of a firm by closure of a plant/s), merger (entry of a firm to the
industry by acquisition of an existing plant and exit of a firm from the industry by
divestiture of a plant) and the change in the relative position of incumbents. The latter
combines the two effects of market selection (more efficient incumbents secure increases
in market share) and the improvement in the efficiency of incumbents.
Baldwin identifies considerable mobility of firms in Canadian industry. Looking on a
year-to year basis, the effect of greenfield entry for manufacturing looks insignificant
(accounting for about 1% of employment). Entrants are initially small and about one-half
die before they are 10 years old. But the competitive impact of entry – even in an
accounting sense – is substantial over a ten year time frame. After a decade, firms that did
not exist at the beginning of the decade but are still there at the end, account for 16% of
output. Firms that were present at the beginning of the decade but not at the end
accounted for 18% of output at the beginning.
• This means that greenfield entry and closedown exit are substantial determinants of
the evolution of the industry. It is incorrect to view the industry as characterized by a
stable complement of firms with ‘churning’ at the margins.
Second, although entry by merger or exit by divestiture does not change the capacity in
the industry it changes the control: a new owner is present in the industry. Only about 1%
of employment is affected by this on an annual basis. But over a decade about 12% of
output is produced by plants that were acquired by firms outside the industry in that
period and the same amount of start-or-period output is accounted for by plants taken
over during the period.
• Changes in control therefore exert a significant impact on industry structure over a
decade.
•
Greenfield entry and exit and entry and exit by merger/divestiture seem to be
substitute mechanisms that are characteristic of different industries – the former in
less concentrated industries and the latter in more concentrated industries.
Third, for survivors – i.e. firms that were present at the beginning and the end of the
decade – about one-third of firms declined in absolute size and these were about 50%
larger at the beginning of the decade than were the firms that grew. Hence there is
regression to the mean in firm size. On average, the three largest firms in an industry lost
nearly 25% of their market share in the decade.
• Even within survivors, competitive pressure produces significant reallocations of
market shares.
But what is the effect of this competitive process on productivity? The Canadian data
show that
• survivor firms open plants that have much higher than average productivity; the
plants that they close do not have productivity levels lower than the average for the
industry.
• exiting firms close plants that are much less productive than average (even allowing
for size differences)
• entering firms come in smaller and with lower productivity than average; learning by
those entrants that survive results in growth and their productivity rises to the average
in about 10 years.
In terms of productivity growth over a decade,
• just over one-half is due to productivity gains within survivors and this is
overwhelmingly in the firms that are gaining market share
• one-fifth is due to the market selection effect as higher productivity survivors gain
market share
• the remaining contribution of nearly 30% comes from the effects of plant entry and
exit. New firm entrants are found to replace other small firms that exit (20%). And
amongst surviving firms, new plants supplant old plants that are closed (7%). Hence,
there is a substantial impact of entry and exit on productivity growth.
Table 5. Effects of competition on industry structure and performance: Canadian
manufacturing
1. Changes in market share over 10 years
Total market share
transferred from
unsuccessful to
successful firms over a
decade
market share
44%
industry type
2. Changes in productivity over ten years
Due to: greenfield entry
and closedown exit
Due to: acquisition
entry and exit
20%
less concentrated
7%
more concentrated
Due to:
reallocation
between
survivors
(selection)
17%
Accounting
for
productivity
growth
100%
Due to: new plants of
new firms replacing
plants of exiting firms
20%
Due to: plant openings
by survivors that
replace plant closures
by survivors
7%
Due to: reallocation
between plants of
survivors
(selection)
21%
Due to:
productivity
growth within
survivors
53%
Source: Baldwin, 1993.
Baldwin’s results establish a clear picture of mobility and productivity growth.
Bartelsman & Doms (2000) report many, though not all, of the other important findings
of the literature on mobility and productivity from longitudinal micro data-sets.
• Even in apparently competitive economies such as the United States there is a large
dispersion in measured productivity between the most and the least productive firms
at any point in time. Caves et.al. (1992) report that US firms on average are only 67%
as efficient as the most efficient firms in their industries, and give comparable
findings for the UK, Australia, Korea and Japan. At the plant level, Haskel (2000)
confirms for the UK that the ratio of productivity at the 90th to that at the 10th
percentile of plants in a narrowly defined sub-industry within a region was still 2.5;
for the manufacturing sector as a whole it was 4.8. These findings confirm the extent
of the heterogeneity of productivity across plants and firms in well-functioning
market economies.
• Bartelsman and Doms (2000) conclude that observed productivity differences are
unlikely to be due to measurement error because productivity differences are
correlated with wages, use of technology and export success. Moreover, higher
productivity plants are found to have higher output growth and to be less likely to
exit.
• In line with Baldwin’s findings for firms, the change in productivity within existing
plants accounts for less than half of overall productivity growth over time, the
remainder being accounted for by a combination of entry and exit, and reallocation of
market shares between existing producers (see Foster, Haltiwanger and Krizan, 1998,
for the US and Disney, Haskel and Heden, 2000, for the UK).
• This effect is asymmetrically distributed across the business cycle, with within-plant
growth becoming negligible or negative during recessions. This suggests that
business cycle fluctuations may have contradictory effects: entry may be more
inefficient in booms but booms may foster within firm productivity growth, whilst
recessions may hasten the exit of weak firms but dampen productivity growth in
survivors. Unfortunately there is no clear evidence on these inferences. Some
indication that too many low productivity plants enter in booms is provided in
Disney, Haskel and Heden, 2000.
• Dispersion of productivity does not necessarily decline over time; indeed Dhrymes
(1991) estimated for a balanced panel of large plants in US high-tech industries that
the ratio of TFP in the 90th to the 20th percentile increased from about 2 to about 2.75
between 1972 and 1987. This phenomenon is particularly likely to occur in
innovative industries where the pace of innovation by leading plants may be faster
than the speed of dissemination of best practice from them to others.
These results mean that the process of reallocating market shares amongst existing firms
and between firm births and deaths is empirically a major part of the mechanism through
which productivity advances. In this sense, competition is central to productivity growth.
If competitive pressure also influences productivity growth within survivors, then the
‘accounting contribution’ of exit, entry and market selection is a lower bound for the
influence of the competitive process on overall productivity performance.2 After looking
at the evidence on mobility in developing countries, we turn to studies that look for the
effects of competitive pressure on performance within surviving firms.
Developing countries
Tybout (2000) discusses points of comparison between productivity in manufacturing
firms in advanced market economies and in LDCs.
• The most striking difference between the manufacturing sectors in developed and
developing countries is the difference in the size distribution of plants and firms
(Tybout 2000 Table 1). In the US, 70% of employment is in plants with more than
100 workers and less than 5% in plants with less than 10 workers. In middle income
countries, the proportion in large (>100) plants is 50-60% and in micro plants (<10)
about 20%. But in 14 poor countries, the mean share of employment in micro plants
was 60%.
• The degree of measured cross-sectional productivity dispersion does not appear to be
systematically higher in LDCs than in advanced market economies (Tybout, 2000).
Caution should be attached to these findings because of their dependence on
controversial methods of estimation. In particular, the fact that LDCs are likely to
have fewer firms operating at or near best-practice levels makes it more likely that
observations of these firms will be treated as reflecting measurement error in
stochastic methods of estimation. This possibility is reinforced by the work of Corbo
& De Melo (1986) which found Chilean firms to have very low productivity using
deterministic estimation methods, and merely average productivity (relative to other
countries) using stochastic methods.
• Rates of entry and exit appear to be as high or higher in LDCs than in advanced
market economies, though there is evidence that fewer entrants attain large sizes; this
may indicate that the degree of competitive pressure they exert on incumbents is more
limited (Tybout, 2000).
• The exception to this generalization for LDCs is that there are some signs that in
middle income countries such as Taiwan and Korea where the entry costs into higher
size categories are very low, market share turnover rates (i.e. the percentage of the
market captured over say, five years, by new entrants) are even higher than in
advanced (and more slowly growing) market economies (Tybout, 2000).
• In a longitudinal micro study of Israeli manufacturing, Griliches & Regev (1995) find
most productivity growth to have come within firms. This was during a period (197988) when TFP growth was negligible overall. These results may reflect the weakness
of the competitive infrastructure, which inhibited the role of selection and entry
2
Other studies of panel census data provide similar results as to the mobility of firms and the intensity of
the competitive process (e.g. between the US and Canada (Baldwin, 1993, ch. 6, 15), between US and UK,
Disney et al. 2000 Table 11). Direct comparisons are difficult because of differences in data sources and in
decomposition methods.
•
effects, as compared with its effectiveness in a more advanced market economy
(where as we have seen only about one-half of productivity growth is accounted for
by within-firm effects).
Evidence from Chile, Colombia, Israel and Taiwan show that exiting plants have
lower than average productivity and that their productivity declines prior to exit
(Griliches and Regev’s ‘shadow of death’ effect). Tybout (2000) also reports that the
entering plants are less productive than incumbents on average in Chile and Colombia
– this may indicate that the entry process is LDCs is skewed toward the small singleplant firm component of entry, whereas in advanced market economies as discussed
above, there is a second entry process of high productivity plants owned by multiplant firms.
These results indicate that the competitive process is not operating in the same way in
LDCs as it is in advanced economies. The problem is not one of stasis but of a more
disorderly and less creative turbulence process than is characteristic of advanced market
economies. From the limited evidence available, there appears to be a serious problem in
the competitive infrastructure that prevents small firms from growing to become serious
rivals for the large firms in many industries. Barriers that are maintained by the state
between the informal and the formal sector may play a large part in this (Tybout 2000).
4.4.2 The incentive effect: competition and within-firm performance
Advanced market economies
One approach to measuring the impact of competitive pressure on performance within
survivors is to estimate the determinants of total factor productivity, looking particularly
for the influence of various measures of competition. The idea is to use the change in
output as the dependent variable so as to test for the impact of competition on (a)
productivity growth using a level term for the competition variable and on (b) the level of
productivity using a change in competition term. Panel data is required in order to be able
to control for firm fixed effects. Surprisingly, serious empirical analysis of the
relationship between competition and productivity levels and growth has taken place only
recently even in advanced economies. Using UK data, Nickell (1996) found evidence that
the extent of competition measured at firm level affects both the level and the growth of
productivity. It was also the case that firms in less concentrated industries had higher TFP
growth rates. Nickell found that a 25% increase in market share was associated with a 1%
fall in the level of TFP in the long run. He found that the difference in productivity
growth between firms at the 80th and 20th percentile of the rents distribution to be about 4
percentage points. However, correcting for the selection bias that exists in a sample of
surviving firms suggests that Nickell’s estimates are biased upwards.3
3
Disney, Haskel and Heden (2000) argue that small firms are likely to be more prevalent in more
competitive markets, and are less likely to be able to withstand adverse shocks. Hence only those with
positive shocks survive. This implies a positive correlation between competition and productivity between
survivors. They confirm the presence of the selection bias by comparing the estimated elasticities for the
competition variables across samples that include survivors only, large firms only and survivors as well as
It was argued earlier that if one of the routes through which competitive pressure raises
performance is by its effect in increasing managerial effort, then one would predict that
the quality of corporate governance and financial pressure would each be substitutes for
competition. Nickell, Nicolatsis and Dryden (1997) tested for this effect using the same
data set as Nickell (1996). They find that the impact of competition on productivity
growth is lower when firms are under financial pressure or when there is a dominant
external shareholder from the financial sector.4
Hay and Liu (1997) use the motivation of a 'Willig-type' mechanism to link managerial
effort in reducing costs to market share and price-cost margin. When competition is
fiercer, the relationship between efficiency and performance is tighter and therefore the
incentive is stronger for the manager to raise efficiency. They investigate this hypothesis
by estimating the efficiency of 174 large firms in 17 UK manufacturing sectors (using a
frontier production function to identify the relative efficiency of firms). Their first finding
is that in all but two industries, there are efficiency differences between firms that persist
over time and in all but four industries, there is also significant time-varying firm
inefficiency. They find that the relationship between relative efficiency and market share
varies across sectors, indicating the existence of differences in the pressure of
competition across industries. This is quite consistent with the picture of mobility within
industries described above and with the hypothesis that competition will work differently
in different kinds of industries. They find that the pressure of competition as indicated by
a fall in market share leads to subsequent improved performance.
Developing countries
A number of studies have examined the extent to which trade liberalisation exerts
competitive pressure on firms. Levinsohn (1993) finds evidence that liberalisation
reduces price-cost margins in Turkish industries where pricing above marginal cost was
previously significant (he does not test the possibility that marginal costs themselves
might respond endogenously). Other studies have examined a more direct link between
trade liberalization and productivity levels, and have tended to find a positive association,
though Tybout (2000) cautions that problems of endogeneity cannot be ruled out
(inefficient industries may lobby harder for protection). In a careful study using panel
data on manufacturing firms in Indonesia from 1982-1995, Bartel and Harrison (1999)
find that public sector firms that have been protected from import competition are poor
productivity performers.
entrants and exitors. Once selection bias is corrected for, the productivity growth difference between firms
at the 80th and 20th percentiles of the rents distribution is only about 1 percentage point. The productivity
level effect is reduced by about 50%.
4
Ng & Seabright (2000) use a panel study of the airline industry to look at the effects of competition and
state ownership on costs of operation, exploiting data on employee remuneration to test the hypothesis that
firms with market power or weak corporate governance share the resulting rents with employees. They find
a strong adverse impact of state ownership on costs, and a weaker but still significant association between
costs and market power, but are unable to find a significant interaction between the two kinds of influence.
4.4.3 Other results on competition and performance
• There is some evidence from cross-sections that plants are more productive if they
belong to relatively productive firms (see Baily et.al. 1992). If supported by panel
evidence this would reinforce what common sense and case-studies already suggest,
namely that ownership is an important means whereby know-how is transferred
between plants.
• A related aspect of ownership is the finding by Disney et.al. (2000) that, of the part of
UK productivity growth that is due to entry and exit, the overwhelming share comes
from entry and exit of plants belonging to multi-plant firms (this is a much higher
contribution than that found by Baldwin for Canada, for reasons that are not yet
clear). This indicates that managerial decision-making guided by market signals is
playing a very significant role in overall productivity growth: “pure” market selection
is less important (for reasons that may have to do with the inefficiencies induced by
barriers to entry and exit).
• A very few studies consider the possibility that competitive pressure may have a nonlinear or even non-monotonic (first increasing then decreasing) relation to efficiency.
Green & Mayes (1991) show on UK data what was earlier demonstrated by Caves &
Barton (1990) for the US, namely a non-monotonic relation between the 5-firm
concentration ratio and efficiency, in which the greatest efficiency is associated with
intermediate levels of concentration. Bresnahan & Reiss (1991) find a (weakly)
monotonic but decidedly non-linear effect of entry on prices, with most of the
competitive impact coming from the first two entrants to challenge a monopolist, and
a levelling out once market participants number around five.
• Direct evidence on competition and innovations is provided by Blundell, Griffith and
Van Reenen (1995, 1999). They find that decreases in domestic concentration ratios
and increases in openness to trade are associated ceteris paribus with higher numbers
of innovations and patents. This is consistent with the results of a quite different
methodology (bench-marking using case studies) in which Baily and Gersbach (1995)
found that ‘head-to-head’ competition in the same market resulted in faster
innovation in several manufacturing industries.
• Gonenc, Maher and Nicoletti (2000) surveyed the effect of pro-competitive
regulatory reform in previously regulated industries in OECD countries. The study
included largely competitive industries such as road freight, air passenger transport
and retail distribution. They found clear evidence that liberalization of entry and
prices in most cases resulted in improved static and dynamic efficiency, enhanced
quality and lower prices to consumers.
We now summarise the evidence that has accumulated on the impact of liberalization and
the introduction of competition in the transition countries. We look first at performance
and then at policy.
4.5
Competition and performance in transition economies
The transition of the former communist economies represents a dramatic exogenous
change in competition. This upheaval may teach us a great deal about how competition
becomes established and how it affects the economy, although the large number of
changes taking place simultaneously makes for considerable difficulties in establishing
causality. The planned economies operated without competition and without
entrepreneurs. Ironically, from a Marxian as well as a Schumpeterian perspective, this
was a recipe for stagnation. Although many analysts expected substantial productivity
gains for transition countries as resources were reallocated across industries following
price liberalization, this has not occurred. Carlin, Fries, Schaffer and Seabright (2000)
show that cross-industry reallocation contributed less than 5% of overall productivity
growth in Poland, Hungary and the Czech Republic from 1991-6, a slightly lower
proportion than in Austria and France over the same period. The fact that even in Poland
in the period of output growth, such cross industry effects have been small, suggests that
the first order effect of the introduction of competition is to improve performance within
industries.
The impact of competition on performance through managerial incentives and through
innovation all have resonance in the transition context. In transition (as in the context of
developing countries), product innovation refers much more to the introduction of
products new to the market than to the introduction of products that are new per se. As
we have argued above, this might be expected to be a less risky task than that of
innovating at the technological frontier. However, the evidence reviewed for developing
countries suggests that ‘copying’ best-practice products, processes and organizational
structures by existing firms is by no means straightforward. The analysis of transition
reveals that in the short-run, the introduction of a market economy and of the opportunity
to copy best-practice can have a deleterious impact on firm performance if it produces
‘disorganization’.
To see what this means let us summarize the arguments of Blanchard & Kremer (1997).
They model the initial situation prior to widespread market liberalization in transition
economies as one of long chains of production involving bilateral monopoly relationships
between firms. In a bilateral monopoly, there is one supplier and one buyer. The outcome
of a bargaining game between the two is inherently indeterminate. Under central
planning, targets were imposed on the pairs of buyers and sellers and this solved the
indeterminacy. But once planning ended and markets were introduced, the bargaining
problem between pairs of buyers and sellers re-emerged. A collapse in the existing
convention could trigger a breakdown of the production chain. The entry of new sources
of supply would put an end to the underlying problem but may take considerable time.
Until new chains of supply are established, there may be a collapse in output and hence
productivity within existing firms. Hence in the short-run more competition may worsen
firm performance. Only when the ‘disorganization phase’ is over, can more competition
raise performance. Evidence for the initially deleterious impact of increased competition
because of its effects on disorganization has been found by Konings and Walsh (1999) as
well as by Blanchard and Kremer (1997).
There are rather few systematic studies of the impact of competitive conditions on
enterprise performance in transition countries. As yet, there is no analysis of industry
evolution during the transition using census panel data to include entrants, exits, selection
effects amongst survivors and performance changes of survivors. The generally poor
quality of data and the absence of good measures of competition at firm level suggest that
the results may not be robust. Djankov and Murrell (2000) pool 13 studies and report a
positive impact of competition on performance. For the countries outside the CIS, they
find that both domestic and foreign competition are effective, whilst for CIS countries, it
is domestic competition that appears to matter. Brown and Earle (2000) estimate TFP
equations for a large panel of Russian firms (firms with more than 100 employees) and
find evidence that better transportation infrastructure (in addition to more standard
indicators of competition in the product market such as concentration indices and import
competition – which were included in the Djankov and Murrell meta-analysis) has a large
positive effect on performance. Brown and Earle (2000) also find evidence in the
Russian data of the substitution effect between corporate governance and competition
found in the UK by Nickell, Nicolatsis and Dryden (1997). The effect on TFP of
competition is less in non-state firms.
One specific focus of the joint EBRD and World Bank enterprise survey conducted in
1999 across 25 transition countries was the examination of the role of competition in
enterprise performance. Early results were published in the EBRD’s Transition Report of
1999; more thorough analysis is found in Carlin, Fries, Schaffer and Seabright (CFSS,
2000). They find that competition has an important effect on sales and productivity
growth, though there the effect is non-monotonic: some degree of perceived market
power is associated with higher performance, but competitive pressure is also important,
especially pressure from foreign suppliers. Firms with 1-3 competitors in the market for
their main product have clearly better performance than either monopolists or firms with
more than three competitors. A similar non-monotonic effect is found upon firms’
decisions to develop and improve their products, but market power has an unambiguously
negative impact on purely defensive (cost-reducing) restructuring activity.
Carlin, Haskel & Seabright (2000) use data from the same survey to show that
restructuring activity has a much weaker association with improved performance in
countries characterised by poor competitive infrastructure. They conclude that “not only
does the absence of a stable business environment make productivity improvements
harder to achieve. It also makes it likely that any improvements in productivity that are
attained will come at a much greater cost in broken business relationships, needlessly
squandered assets, and pointless business failure”.
4.6 Competition and competition policy
Evidence from transition countries is also informative about how competition policy law
and implementation may influence competition. There does not appear to be systematic
evidence on this question from either developing or advanced countries. Dutz and
Vagliasindi (2000a, 2000b, 2000c) present the first attempt to collect systematic data on
competition law, implementation and its impact on competition in 20 transition countries.
They report wide cross-country differences in both competition policy rules and in
implementation. As shown in Table A2 in appendix 2, they classify both laws and
implementation along three dimensions: enforcement against anti-competitive acts
(legislative bans), advocacy (directives) and institutional effectiveness (legal safeguards).
They find a strong correlation between the quality of rules and their implementation
across countries.
They investigate the impact of competition policy rules and implementation on
competition using two measures of competition. In the first study (Dutz and Vagliasindi
2000b) they measure competition by enterprise mobility: an economy-wide indicator that
captures the frequency with which private enterprises expanded employment over the
1997-1999 period, weighted by the corresponding proportion of expanding firms that
increase labour productivity. In the second study (Dutz and Vagliasindi 2000c) their
dependent variable is the average frequency with which enterprises face a more
competitive environment (the proportion of firms facing at least one competitor in the
domestic market) in 1999. Both measures are constructed at the country level from the
World Bank/ EBRD enterprise survey data used in CFSS (2000).
They find that both rules and implementation (as measured by the indices constructed on
the basis of Table A2) improve enterprise mobility and that the effect of implementation
is more important (18 observations). They also find that better corporate governance and
stronger foreign competition increase economy-wide enterprise mobility. In the second
study (20 observations), the proportion of firms facing at least one competitor in the
country is regressed on the twice-lagged competition policy implementation variable and
the change in implementation over the previous two years. They also use the overall state
of privatisation and variables assessing the hardness of enterprise budget constraints as
explanatory variables. They find that more effective competition policy implementation
results in more intense competition.
5
Regulating competition
Competition has to be adequate to do two things: first, to keep up pressure on existing
firms to operate efficiently and innovatively, and secondly, to replace firms that fail to do
so with others, without causing excessive and wasteful industrial turbulence. By
“turbulence” we refer to those aspects of industrial restructuring that involve substantial
fixed costs: most notably the entry and exit of firms and plants, but also the breaking of
business relationships that represent significant specific investments, and the
abandonment of fixed or intangible assets. Entry and exit of plants and firms are lumpy
processes, and they create casualties. The immediate liquidation value of a firm’s assets
is rarely anything like the firm’s value as a going concern, even if these assets may
eventually be redeployed in more productive combinations elsewhere. Market entry is
notoriously at the mercy of imperfections in capital markets as well as in markets for
products, services and human resources.
It seems likely that an adequate competitive infrastructure matters not just because it
makes competition more intense, but also because it reduces the turbulence and waste
that can sometimes be associated with the selection effect of competition. When market
signals are informative, when customers are able to choose on the basis of good
information between rival suppliers, when finance is available for productive
investments, when the success of firms is determined more by the intrinsic quality of
their products than by the accidents of their location or their relations with government,
then the selection that occurs through competition is more likely to favour genuinely
productive firms. Fortunately, too, these conditions are also ones that favour the
maintenance of effective pressure on existing firms, which will be more motivated to
improve their productivity if they know that productivity is the most important
determinant of business survival.
5.1
Pressure on existing firms
As far as the first task is concerned, most of the evidence we have cited strongly
corroborates the economists’ hunch that unchallenged monopolists are substantially less
efficient than firms that face a credible challenge. The difficulty lies in establishing what
constitutes a credible challenge. In most industries in most countries it seems reasonably
clear that around three to five5 seriously competing firms in each market are enough to
ensure that most of the benefits of competition are realised without too many of the
associated costs (three may of course be too many if economies of scale are very
important, an issue we take up again below). This suggests that (again with the exception
of a very few industries with unusually large sunk up-front investments) the issue is not
so much whether the right degree of rivalry varies between industries or between
countries – it does not, or not very much. The issue is rather what it takes for three to five
firms to be in the same market, and to be competing seriously. The evidence that would
allow one to conclude that this is so will indeed be very sensitive to country and industry
circumstances as discussed in section 1.
It is evident that for three to five firms to be in the same market is not an all-or-nothing
matter but depends on how closely their products are perceived as substitutable in the
minds of buyers. Sometimes this is just a matter of product definition (an issue familiar to
anti-trust enforcers). A large volume maker of small cars, a maker of luxury sports cars
and a maker of people-carriers will exert rather little competitive pressure on each other.
The question is not whether they are or are not in “the same market”, but rather that,
5
Nickell (1996) uses a survey question ‘Have you five or fewer competitors in the market for your
product(s)?’ He writes: ‘the evidence provided by Stewart (1990) indicates that this variable has
considerable discriminatory power. For example, union wage effects are considerably smaller in
‘competitive’ firms.’ He adds: “Somewhat fortuitously the number five appears to be quite important
according to the evidence in Bresnahan and Reiss (1991). They find that increases in the number of firms
operating in a market up to around five have significant effects in reducing market power”
given their relatively low substitutability, the presence of three of them is unlikely to
constitute “enough” competition.
Even for products that are in principle close substitutes, competition may be relatively
weak if there are geographical or informational barriers between them. Defining the
relevant geographical market is often treated as a relatively straightforward matter in
industrialised countries: it is usually national, sometimes international for certain highlytraded goods, and sometimes sub-national for certain services or for goods tied to service
after-markets. In many developing (and transition) countries the poor state of local
infrastructure may make it inappropriate to assume national markets even for goods that
are in principle highly tradeable. If there are barriers to acquiring premises so that only
one producer has an outlet in each town, a consumer wishing to purchase from a rival
producer may have to undertake a costly and time-consuming journey that may make the
purchase uneconomic. This may encourage both producers to raise their prices since their
residual demand elasticities are lower (in consequence, firms may specifically seek to
strengthen the “switching costs” that make it harder for consumers to arbitrage between
them; see Klemperer, 1995). Opportunities for local officials to gain from maintaining
such barriers through regulations will reinforce the detrimental impact of weak
competition.
Note that this will be a less serious problem for durable products whose purchase price is
high relative to the transport costs, and also for those that can be sufficiently precisely
described (in a catalogue, say) for consumers to make informed comparisons without
seeing the goods in person. However, it is important to note that the theoretical possibility
of informed consumers’ arbitraging prices (through internet shopping, for example) is not
enough to establish real competition between the producers, unless enough consumers are
actually willing to do so to exert powerful downward pressure on producers’ prices. In
the case of homogeneous products one would not necessarily expect to see significant
inter-regional shopping, since its mere possibility might keep producer prices closely
aligned. But for differentiated products where it would be implausible that consumers’
preferences were precisely determined by their location, unless significant inter-regional
shopping were observed competition would clearly not be “enough”.
In developing countries it may be also much harder to conclude that the presence of
imported products implies realistic competition with those produced domestically. This is
partly because of the infrastructural constraints we have already discussed: in large
countries, most consumers do not live on or near the border, and may not be in a position
to purchase goods that can theoretically be imported (this is particularly important for
those products that depend on after-sales service). It is also because of product
differentiation; many imports will be of very different quality or specification to those
produced domestically. This does not make import liberalisation any less important:
indeed, the transfer of know-how through gaining familiarity with imported products is a
very important part of the process of development, especially where there is a systematic
need to upgrade product quality (as in many transition economies; indeed as we have
noted, CFSS 2000, find that perceived pressure from foreign competitors is a more
significant determinant of firm performance than perceived pressure from domestic
competitors). But it may limit the strictly competitive benefits that can be expected to
flow from trade liberalisation, and suggest that additional measures to strengthen
domestic competition may be necessary.
If three or more firms can indeed be said to be in the same market, what determines
whether or not they are competing seriously? The credibility of domestic policies to
police collusion is only part – though an important part - of the answer. Many LDCs do
not have a tradition of forbidding collusion, nor a tradition of press openness that makes
it easier for evidence about collusion to surface. Policing collusion may in consequence
be far from straightforward, especially if an attempt to do so succeeds only in replacing
collusion between firms with collusion between those same firms and their supposed
regulators (see Laffont, 1999). These considerations strengthen the argument for
improving competitive infrastructure, especially in removing entry barriers and barriers
to inter-regional and international trade, since such measures bring into the market
competitors that, by history and culture, are less likely to seek collusion with incumbent
firms. They also strengthen the case for improving information flows in the economy (the
fear that these will help firms to collude more than customers to shop around is largely
unfounded, since firms are probably colluding anyway).
Asymmetries in the size or financial power of the competing firms may also be an
important obstacle to serious competition. As noted in section 3, in many LDCs firms are
on average much smaller than in industrialised countries, yet this is often compatible with
the presence of one or two large firms in many industries. Baldwin (1993)’s conclusion
for Canada that entry and exit are not just about churning at the margin while a stable
core of large firms continues unaffected probably does not apply so clearly to many
LDCs. In many instances these asymmetries arise because of regulatory and other
obstacles to the growth of small firms. In some cases, therefore, it may be appropriate for
competition authorities to take a similarly asymmetric attitude to mergers: to encourage
them among second-rank firms while strongly discouraging them among leading firms.
Indeed, collusion through merger is all the more to be feared because some quite good
arguments will be marshalled in its favour. Significant competition in the previously
sheltered environment of many LDCs is certain to lead to a great deal of exit from the
industry, and often rationalisation of industry assets through merger will be less wasteful
than their exit and subsequent re-entry. However, many firms seeking to collude through
merger will exaggerate the competitive threat (say from imports) in order to justify
mergers as a route to increased competitiveness. The competition authorities will need to
be particularly vigilant to ensure that mergers are not used among the only existing
competitors in an industry in the face of a largely theoretical threat from imports that
compete only slightly with domestic production. Conversely, permission of mergers
among firms that appear to have large domestic market shares makes sense only if there
is visible commitment to strong competition with foreign firms (something that has been
conspicuously present in the industrial policy of South Korea – see Amsden & Singh,
1994 – and conspicuously absent from the industrial policy of India, to take two striking
examples).
This brings us to the aspect of competition as a source of pressure on existing firms. How
can the few industries that are exceptions to the “Three-to-Five” Rule be recognised?
There seem to be two distinct types of industry concerned. One kind is industries based
on physical networks producing mainly non-traded services. Electricity, gas and water
services are the most important; telecommunications used to be considered such a service
but it has now become accepted that the scope for competition in telephony is much
greater than was once thought. In the case of these services the record of state
management has been very poor in almost all LDCs, so that reforms to introduce more
commercial behaviour are highly desirable, but the dangers of allowing such behaviour to
be unregulated are very great. Here the challenge to a monopoly has to come in part from
public institutions and not from competing firms. Fortunately there is by now a large
literature on the application of regulatory experience in LDCs, so we need not consider
the issue further here.
The second kind of industry where scale economies matter is those where large up-front
investments are required to produce traded goods, and particularly industries where the
scale of the investment required is endogenous to the intensity of competition perceived
by firms. These are industries where (as Sutton, 1991, argues) increasing the size of the
domestic market by improving the competitive infrastructure may simply lead to
increased concentration. For industries where the up-front investments consist primarily
of R&D, international competition can provide most of the necessary ex post competitive
challenge. Pharmaceuticals, aerospace, and semiconductors are obvious examples, but it
is equally obvious that for most LDCs, investing heavily in these industries is neither a
feasible nor a desirable option. High-technology industries do not all have to be large
scale, as the success of the Indian software industry has recently demonstrated (see
Banerjee & Duflo, 2000), and it is more important to find a balance between a country’s
skill base and the appropriate use for those skills than to invest in technology per se.
More complex issues, though, are raised by industries where advertising is the main
source of endogenous sunk costs (foods, consumer goods, and other branded products
being most important). Fortunately the growth of international communications
(including satellite television) means that imported goods may need lower investments to
break into the domestic market, and therefore it may be feasible to expose domestic
producers to foreign competition without limiting their ability to grow domestically. Very
few developing countries have markets big enough to support three or more domestic
producers of, say, household appliances – but that need not prevent a single such
producer from being exposed to vigorous competition from imported brands. In many
ways, import competition can be presented as an opportunity and not just a threat to many
LDCs: it is what allows them to obtain the benefits of scale without the costs of
monopoly. The more vigorous and dynamic developing countries have long ago begun to
absorb this message.
5.2
Replacement of poor performers: exit and entry
What about the second task, that of replacing firms that fail to perform? The evidence we
have cited suggests that reallocation of production towards more efficient plants, and the
entry and exit of plants, both play an extremely important role in productivity change. In
practical terms, this means that the authorities in LDCs need to be prepared for the fact
that in many industries, over a decade or so, establishments producing anything between
a tenth and a quarter of current output will disappear. This is a natural and more or less
inevitable process even in healthy growing economies. Ill-considered attempts to prevent
it from happening, by propping up failing firms or by regulations preventing firms from
closing subsidiary plants, will only undermine the productivity growth that is the best
hope for employment and income growth in the long run. Indeed, it is doubtful whether
policy is even capable of preventing exit; attempts to do so usually make the exit process
more random rather than reducing its overall incidence. To the extent that plant closure
imposes significant social costs, these are best met by explicit retraining and relocation
measures and not by barriers to closure in the first place.
Similarly, barriers to entry of new firms and plants need to be streamlined: many LDCs
face serious barriers already because of imperfect financial markets and poor
infrastructure; it is therefore doubly important to remove unnecessary regulatory
obstacles (complex licensing procedures or taxation systems, restrictions on letting of
premises or changes of use). Finally, it is important to remember how many obstacles
exist not just to entry of new firms but growth from small size to large. (Many policies
designed to “favour small firms” inadvertently contribute to this by abruptly removing
favourable measures when firms reach a certain size).
Overall, entry and exit of both firms and plants play a role in productivity and innovation
that is as inevitable as it is important. Misguided policies may shift their incidence (fewer
large firms may fail, but more small firms, for example) but cannot realistically be
expected to abolish them altogether. The task of public policy is to ensure that as far as
possible this turbulence serves to augment productivity and innovation rather than to
undermine them.
6
Concluding comments.
A set of obstacles to the growth of small firms appear to characterize LDCs. These
comprise regulatory barriers between the formal and the informal sectors (taxation,
business registration and regulation costs, labour costs), physical and communications
infrastructure that limit the size of the market and prevent local firms from competing in
an extended market. Such obstacles appear to impose a heavy inefficiency on LDCs not
just because they preventing the exploitation of economies of scale (which appear often
to be surprisingly modest according to Tybout (2000)), but chiefly because they prevent
competition from operating effectively. There is plenty of turbulence amongst small firms
but the obstacles to entering the formal sector of the economy appear to prevent the
‘normal’ process through which a proportion of small firms grow to challenge established
operators in the market.
This implies that competition policy (in the familiar sense of anti-trust intervention) is
only one of the tools that governments need to use to promote competition in LDCs, and
is often far from the most important. The state of transport, telecommunications, finance,
regulation and licensing provisions, all contribute to ensuring that new firms can pose a
realistic challenge to established firms. This challenge will often be resisted, not least by
the lobbying activities of established firms that will deploy arguments about the
responsibility of government to prevent “wasteful” competition. These arguments will
appear all the more seductive because there is plenty of evidence that competition can
indeed be very wasteful at times. However, the clue to making it less wasteful lies not in
softening the impact of competition altogether, but rather in improving the competitive
infrastructure so that firms recognise that their most effective response to increased
competitive pressure lies in productivity and innovation.
References
Aghion, P., Dewatripont, M. and P. Rey. (1997) ‘Corporate governance, competition
policy and industrial policy’, European Economic Review 41.
Aghion, P. and M. Schankerman (2000). ‘A model of market-enhancing infrastructure’,
mimeo, UCL.
Amsden, A. and A. Singh (1994) ‘The optimal degree of competition and dynamic
efficiency in Japan and Korea’, 38.
Baily, M and H. Gersbach (1995). ‘Efficiency in manufacturing and the need for global
competition’ Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (microeconomics).
Baldwin, J.R. (1993) The Dynamics of Industrial Competition Cambridge: CUP.
Banerjee, A. & E. Duflo (2000): “Reputation Effects and the Limits of Contracting: a
study of the Indian software industry”, Quarterly Journal of Economics.
Bartel A. and Harrison, A., ‘Ownership versus environment: Why are public sector firms
inefficient?’ NBER WP 7043
Bartelsman, E., and Doms, M., (2000), “Understanding Productivity: Lessons from
Longitudinal Microdata”, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol 38, No 3, pp. 569594.
Blanchard, O. and M. Kremer, (1997), ‘Disorganization’, Quarterly Journal of
Economics, Vol. 112, No. 4, pp 1091-1126.
Blundell, R., Griffith, R. and Van Reenen, J. (1995). ‘Dynamic count models of
technological innovation’ Economic Journal March 333-44
Blundell, R., Griffith, R. and Van Reenen, J. (1999). ‘Market structure and innovation:
evidence from British manufacturing firms’, Review of Economic Studies. July
Bresnahan, T. & P. Reiss (1991): “Entry and Competition in Concentrated Markets”,
Journal of Political Economy, vol. 99, no. 5.
Brown, J. D. and J.S. Earle (2000). ‘Competition, geography, and firm performance:
lessons from Russia’, Mimeo. SITE, Stockholm.
Carlin, W., Fries, S., Schaffer, M. and Seabright, P. (2000). ‘Competition and Enterprise
Performance in Transition Economies: Evidence from a Cross-country Survey’,
mimeo, UCL.
Carlin, W., J. Haskel & P. Seabright (2000). “Understanding ‘the essential fact about
capitalism’: markets, competition and creative destruction”, National Institute
Economic Review, forthcoming.
Caves, R. E. (1998), “Industrial Organisation and New Findings on the Turnover and
Mobility of Firms”, Journal of Economic Literature, XXXVI, December, 19471982.
Disney, R., Haskel, J., and Heden, Y. (2000), “Restructuring and productivity growth in
UK establishments”, draft paper available from <www.qmw.ac.uk/~ugte153>.
Davies, S.W. and Lyons, B.(1996). Industrial Organization in the European Union
Oxford: OUP
Disney, R., J. Haskel and Y. Heden (2000). ‘Restructuring and productivity growth in
UK manufacturing’ mimeo, Queen Mary and Westfield College, April 2000
Djankov, S. and P. Murrell (2000). “Enterprise restructuring in transition: a quantitative
survey”, Mimeo, World Bank, April, 2000.
Dunne, T., Roberts, M. and Samuelson, L. (1989), ‘The growth and failure of US
Manufacturing plants’, QJE 104(4), 671-698
Dutz, M. A. and M. Vagliasindi (2000a). ‘Competition policy implementation in
transition economics: an empirical assessment’ EBRD WP No. 47.
Dutz, M. A. and M. Vagliasindi (2000b), ‘Rules versus implementation: Determinants of
competition policy effectiveness in transition economies’, EBRD mimeo.
Dutz, M. A. and M. Vagliasindi (2000c), ‘The impact of competition policy on structural
concentration in domestic markets’, EBRD mimeo.
Gonenc, R., M. Maher and G. Nicoletti (2000), ‘The implementation and the effects of
regulatory reform: Past experience and current issues’, OECD Economics
Department Working Papers, No. 251.
Green, A. & D. Mayes (1991): “Technical Inefficiency In Manufacturing Industries”, The
Economic Journal, 101, May 1991.
Griliches, Z and H. Regev (1995) ‘Firm productivity in Israeli industry 1979-1988’,
Journal of Econometrics, 65
Grout, P. (1984). ‘Investment and wages in the absence of binding contracts: a Nash
bargaining approach’, Econometrica 52.
Haskel, J. (1991), ‘Imperfect competition, work practices and productivity growth’,
Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 53, No.3, pp 265-277.
Hay, D.A. and Liu, G.S. (1997), ‘The efficiency of firms: what difference does
competition make?’, Economic Journal, Vol. 107, No. 442, pp 597-617.
Haskel, J. (1991). ‘Imperfect competition, work practices and productivity growth’,
Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 53.
Hopenhayn, H (1992) ‘Entry, exit and firm dynamics in long-run equilibrium’
Econometrica 60
Hart, O. (1983). ‘The market mechanism as an incentive schem’ Bell Journal of
Economics 14.
Haskel, J. and Szmanski (1997) ‘The effects of privatization, competition and
restructuring on productivity growth in UK manufacturing’ QMW DP 286
Johnson, S., J. McMillan and C. Woodruff (1999) ‘Contract enforcement in transition’
EBRD Working Paper No. 45.
Kattuman, P. A. and R.S. Domanski (1998). ‘Industrial concentration under shock
therapy: Poland in early transition years’ Centre for Business Research,
Cambridge University, Working Paper No. 76.
Konings, J. and Walsh, P.P. (1999) ‘Disorganisation in the process of transition: firmlevel evidence from Ukraine’ Economics of Transition 7 (1), pp. 29-46.
Levinsohn, J and A. Petrin (1999) ‘When industries become more productive, do firms?’,
NBER WP no. 6893
Levinsohn, J (1993) ‘Testing the import-as-market-discipline hypothesis’, Journal of
International Economics, 35.)
Marx, K. (1867) Capital Volume. 1 , Harmondsworth: Penguin edition 1976
Ng, C.K. & P. Seabright (2000): “Competition, Privatisation and Productive Efficiency:
evidence from the airline industry”, Economic Journal, forthcoming.
Nickell, S. (1996) ‘Competition and corporate performance’ Journal of Political
Economy, Vol. 104, No.4, pp 724-746.
Nickell, S., Nicolitsas, D. and N. Dryden (1997) ‘What makes firms perform well?’
European Economic Review, 41, pp 783-796.
Shleifer, A. & R. Vishny (1994). ‘Politicians and firms’ Quarterly Journal of Economics
pp. 995-1025.
Shleifer, A. & R. Vishny (1998) ed. The Grabbing Hand: Government Pathologies and
their Cures. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Smith, Adam, (1776), The Wealth of Nations, , Harmondsworth: Pelican edition 1970.
Sutton, J. (1991). Sunk Costs and Market Structure: Price Competition, Advertising, and
the Evolution of Concentration Cambridge, Mass.: CUP
Tirole, J. (1988). The Theory of Industrial Organization. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Tybout, J. R. (2000). ‘Manufacturing firms in developing countries: how well do they do
and why?’ Journal of Economic Literature XXXVIII (March 2000) pp. 11-44
Vickers, J. (1995) ‘Concepts of competition’, Oxford Economic Papers, 47.
Willig, R. (1987). ‘Corporate governance and market structure’ in Razin, A. and Sadka,
E. (eds) Economic Policy in Theory and Practice London: MacMillan
Appendix 1: Concentration and competition in European industries
Table A1 lists the most concentrated industries in the European economy. This data
comes from Davies and Lyons (1996). These are the 3-digit NACE industries (of the total
of 100) that have a 5-firm concentration ratio in the European market of more than 25%
or for which the average national 4-firm concentration ratio is more than 45%.
Industries are classified into three groups according to the extent of trade. ‘Local’
industries have intra-EU imports relative to apparent EU consumption of less than 15%
and extra EU-trade intensity of more than 50%; ‘Global’ industries have extra EU
imports plus exports relative to apparent consumption of more than 80%. ‘Intermediate’
are all the other high concentration industries.
Type 1 industries are exogenous sunk cost industries and the endogenous sunk cost
industries are divided into 2A (advertizing-intensive), 2R (R&D-intensive) and 2AR
(both advertizing- and R&D-intensive).
Davies and Lyons argue that the set of industries listed in Table A1 contains most of
those that have a potential anti-competitive problem (at a more disaggregated level, some
other industries may enter). In particular, the list of industries in the first panel ‘Local’ is
likely to present the most problems for the competition authorities. Even in the European
market, these industries are not traded extensively. This ‘natural protection’ is reinforced
by government intervention in several industries through public procurement and
regulation as indicated in the table. Most industries in the list have been the subject of
competition policy investigations. It is striking that many are advertizing-intensive, which
highlights the anti-competitive role that can be played by marketing in industries where
international trade is not an effective way of delivering competitive pressure.
They emphasize that for the highly concentrated industries in the third ‘Global’ panel, all
except four are R&D-intensive and highly multinational. These characteristics imply that
strategies (e.g. R&D budgets) are being designed at a global level and that competition
issues cannot be judged at national or even EU level alone. Of more direct concern to
competition authorities are the four Type 1 industries. These are industries producing
standardized products with substantial production scale economies and are ‘sensitive
sectors’ in which governments have frequently intervened to protect national firms from
being eliminated through restructuring under the pressure of international competition.
Table A1. The most concentrated industries in Europe
Industry
LOCAL
cement
sugar
shipbuilding
starch
beer
soft drinks
tobacco
Type
1
1
1
1
2A
2A
2A
Econ. of scale
Public procure.
Regulation
Multinationality
X
X
X
X
X
oil and fat
chocolate
rail stock
insulated wire
& cable
soap & det.
paint & ink
2A
2A
2R
2R
INTERMED
glass
asbestos
fish products
steel-forming
cold
distilling
rubber
telecom/measu
ring equip
basic chem
cycle & motor
cycle
tractors/ag.
machin.
Type
1
1
1
1
GLOBAL
steel tubes
non-ferrous
metal
abrasives
iron & steel
computers &
office mach.
domestic/office
chem.
man-made
fibres
electrical
equip.
transmission
equip.
aerospace
electric
lighting
medical
instruments
motor vehicle
parts
ind. & agric.
chem.
optical instru.
radio & TV
motor vehicles
domestic
electr.
X
X
X
2AR
2AR
X
X
Econ. of scale
Public procure.
2A
2R
2R
Regulation
X
Multinationality
X
X
X
2R
2R
X
X
2AR
X
X
Type
1
1
Econ. of scale
1
1
2R
Public procure.
X
Regulation
Multinationality
X
X
X
X
X
2R
2R
X
2R
X
2R
X
2R
2R
X
X
X
2R
X
2R
X
X
2R
2AR
2AR
2AR
2AR
X
X
X
X
appliances
Source: Davies and Lyons (1996), pp. 242-243. Economies of scale is defined as MES>500; public
procurement and regulated are classified as such in European Economy 1990 (cited by Davies and Lyons,
Table 14.1); multinationality refers to above average multinational production in the industry.
Appendix 2. Classification of competition policy law and implementation in
transition countries (Dutz and Vagliasindi, (2000a, 2000b)
Table A2. Scoring for cross-country comparisons of competition policy law and
implementation
Law
1. Enforcement against anti-competitive acts
enterprises
abuse of dominance IF
definition includes more
than market share and if
abuse of dominance rather
than just dominance
hard core cartels IF
exemptions exclude
practices that restrain
competition
IF horizontal and vertical
agreements are prohibited
only if they limit
competition
IF only mergers that lead to
sign. limit of competition
are illegal
state executive
IF anti-comp. activities of
bodies
regional or local state exec.
bodies are illegal
fines
IF penalties are not unduly
limited
2. Advocacy
infrastructure
privatization
education
IF agency has power to
change rules or introduce
new rules to promote
competition
IF agency has power to
break up assets (including
pro-competition
restructuring before
privatization)
IF agency has mandate to
disseminate reports to
Parliament, public.
3. Institutional effectiveness
independence
IF head of competition
authority is either formally
independent
(appointed/answerable to
Parliament) or sufficient
checks and balances
appeal
IF law ensures right of
appeal to independent entity
transparency
IF all decisions required to
Implementation
0.25
IF violations at least 10% of
decisions; half for at least 1
violation
0.25
0.25
IF violations at least 10% of
decisions; half for at least 1
violation
0.25
0.25
IF violations at least 10% of
decisions; half for at least 1
violation
0.25
0.25
IF in at least 10% cases,
mergers are modified; half
for at least 1 case
IF violations at least 10% of
decisions; half for at least 1
violation
IF one of 3 largest fines per
year is in ‘hard core cartel’
0.25
1
IF at least 50% comments
on infrastructure regulations
accepted; half if 1
1
1
IF at least 50% comments
on privatization regulations
accepted; half if 1
1
1
IF at least one speech
directed to consumers; half
if to small bus.
1
1
IF political independence of
competition authority not
compromised
1
1
IF appeals judged on
economic content (rather
than on due process)
If general public deemed
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
be published or publicly
available
Source: Dutz and Vagliasindi (2000a, 2000b, 2000c).
almost always aware of
competition law provisions