OECD Economic Studies No. 27. 1996/11 zyxwvutsrqponmlkjih
COMPETITION. PRODUCTIVITY AND EFFICIENCY
Dirk Pilat
TABLE OF CONTENTS
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
108
The evidence on productivity gaps . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Productivity gaps in manufacturing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Productivity gaps in services . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
109
109
Explaining productivity levels . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
The role of factor intensity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Other explanations for productivity differences . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
The impact of competition . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
119
119
The determinants of productivity growth . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Capitat accumulation. RGD and technological diffusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
The impact of competition . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
127
129
Concluding remarks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
131)
Annex: Comparing productivity levels: measurement issues . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
133
Bibliography . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
143
116
120
122
127
The author is grateful for helpful comments a n d suggestions from Bart van Ark. Paul Atkinson.
Sveinbjorn Blondal. Martine Durand. lsrgen Elmeskov. Michael P. Feiner. Robert Ford. Peter Jarrett.
Toshi Kato. Joaquim Oliveira Martins. Stefano Scarpetta and Nick Vanston . H e is i n d e b t e d to H e r v e
Bource. Catherine Chapuis. Martine Levasseur. Brenda Livsey-Coates a n d Sandra Raymond for their
assistance .
INTRODUCTION
Iro8
Productivity gains form the basis of improvements in real incomes and welfare.
Slow productivity growth limits the rate at which real incomes can improve, and
also increases the likelihood of conflicting demands concerning the distribution of
income (Englander and Gurney, 1994). The slowdown of productivity growth in the
OECD area over the past decade therefore has important ramifications. However,
even though productivity growth has slowed down, productivity levels still differ
substantially across the OECD area, possibly indicating an under-utilised potential
for growth and catch-up with other countries.
Productivity growth is influenced by a range of factors, and most studies
suggest that there is no simple way t o boost it (Englander and Gurney, 1994a).
Apart from some specific options, such as investment in education, RGD or infrastructure, policies to boost productivity often focus on the framework conditions for
productivity growth. The degree of competition in a particular country or sector is
often considered to be among the most important of such factors, since a lack of
competition reduces the pressure on firms to incorporate better technology, remove
organisational slack and improve productivity performance.
In analysing productivity growth across countries, a distinction can be made
between three different processes. First, productivity growth can result from innovative activity. For the productivity leader in a particular industry, productivity growth
is to a considerable extent conditional on the development of new products and
processes. Over the first two or three decades of the post-war period, most innovative activity was concentrated in the United States, as both private firms and the
public sector engaged in large RGD efforts At that time, much of the RGD efforts in
other countries were directed at adapting and borrowing technology developed in
the United States (Englander and Gurney, 1994a). However, a s indicated below,
productivity leadership in the OECD has become more diversified and innovation is
currently more widespread across countries.
Second, productivity growth may also be d u e t o reduced (technical)
inefficiency.' An inefficient firm or industry uses more resources and factor inputs
than required by a particular technology, thus tying resources to low-productivity
activities and reducing the overall allocative efficiency of an economy. Exposure to a
higher level of competition forces inefficient firms to restructure, freeing resources
Competition, productivity and eficiency zyxwvutsr
for other productive uses. This process of resource (re-)allocation, which includes
the entry and exit of firms, provides an important contribution to the structural
change of OECD economies (OECD, 1995).
A third process that can be distinguished is technological diffusion. Firms can
improve productivity by adopting production processes and products developed
elsewhere (imitation). This allows them to improve productivity in a relatively
straightforward way, as they do not have to engage in, often costly, innovative
activity. Diffusion differs conceptually from efficiency gains, a s the latter relates to
improvements made in using a given technology - even when this technology is
outdated by international standards.
Across countries diffusion relates to the ability of countries with low productivity levels and/or a low level of technology to incorporate {he stock of technology
developed in more advanced economies (i.e. catch-up). Recent studies (Coe and
Helpman, 1995; Eaton and Kortum, 1995~1,1995b; OECD, 1996) suggest that currently, even for the United States, technology developed abroad provides an important contribution t o productivity growth.
Research suggests that all three processes (i.e.innovation, efficiency gains and
diffusion) are influenced by competitive conditions. The diffusion of technology is
promoted by openness t o international competition, and competition forces firms
to incorporate new production processes and technology. Efficiency is also closely
linked to competition, as weak competition may result in management and workers
appropriating rents in the form of organisational slack and overstaffing. The link
between innovation and competition is less clear-cut, and has been quite controversial in the literature. Currently, most studies suggest that a low degree of
competition, a s expressed in high concentration rates, is not conducive to innovative activity
This paper discusses the empirical evidence on cross-country productivity gaps
and analyses the link between productivity and competition. It first reviews whether
low productivity levels are common across the OECD area, and then tries to assess
which factors, including competitive conditions, contribute t o low productivity or
inefficient behaviour. Next, the paper discusses whether the rate of productivity
growth is affected by weak competition. The final section draws some conclusions
THE EVIDENCE ON PRODUCTIVITY GAPS
Productivity gaps in manufacturing
There is no obvious and simple way to measure productivity gaps, and each
measure has some drawbacks. Three methods are commonly used. A first method
(Van Ark and Pilat, 1993; Van Ark, forthcoming) relies on cross-country comparisons
of productivity levels. An industry in a particular country may be relatively produc-
4
OECD
Economic Studies No. 2 7, I996/11 zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
tive by national standards, but may have a low productivity level compared with
best practice abroad.
The main problem for this type of international productivity comparisons is the
lack of appropriate conversion factors for real output. Exchange rates are not
suitable, since they are strongly influenced by monetary phenomena, and in general
d o not reflect real price differences between countries. In principle, industry-specific
conversion factors (or purchasing power parities - PPPs) are required that reflect
these differentials across countries. Recent studies have made such conversion
factors available for a large range of OECD countries (Van Ark and Wagner, 1996;
Van Ark, forthcoming).
Some evidence on the basis of these studies is presented in Table 1 . It reports
estimates of absolute levels of labour productivity (value added per person engaged
and per h o u r worked) in the manufacturing sector over the period 1960-95. The
average productivity performance of the United States continues t o outrank that of
the other major economies (Japan,Germany and France), although Japan in particular has made considerable productivity gains over the past decades. High labour
productivity levels, in particular in terms of hours worked, are also estimated for
Belgium, Finland, the Netherlands and S ~ e d e n The
. ~ manufacturing sectors in
these small OECD economies tend to be more specialised than those of the large
countries and are, apart from Sweden, relatively capital-intensive (Pilat, 1996),
contributing t o a high level of labour productivity.
In the middle of the OECD productivity range are a number of foliower countries (the United Kingdom, Canada, Australia and Spain) with somewhat lower
productivity levels, although in particular the United Kingdom and Spain have made
substantial progress over the past decades. Canada’s manufacturing productivity
level was relatively high during the 1970s and 1 9 8 0 ~but
~ its level has fallen substantially over the past decade. The bottom range of productivity performance in Table 1
is made up by Mexico and Portugal, that are still quite far behind in productivity
levels Evidende presented in the table also suggests that US productivity performance improved relative to many countries in the 1 9 8 0 ~ ~
More detailed estimates of labour productivity levels, for selected manufacturing industries, are presented in Table 2 On the basis of detailed data for value
added, employment and hours worked, productivity levels were estimated for
36 industries in 9 countries (Pilat, 1996) Table 2 shows benchmark estimates for
1987 and updated estimates for 1993. The countries included in the Table cover only
a sample of manufacturing productivity performance within the OECD, but the
relative productivity performance of these countries is relatively well documented in
a range of country-specific studies
LLE
!
Table 2 suggests that the United States remains the productivity leader
for total manufacturing, but also indicates that the leadership in particular
Relative labour productivity levels in manufacturing
Table 1 . zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
1960-95, United States = 100
United States
lapan
Germany
France
United Kingdom
Canada
1995'
I985
I973
.I 960
Value
added per
person
engaged
Value
added per
hour
worked
Value
added per
person
engaged
Value
added per
hour
worked
Value
added per
person
engaged
Value
added per
hour
worked
Value
added per
person
engaged
Value
added per
hour
worked
100 0
25 1
60 6
47 5
48 6
69 1
100 0
19 2
56 0
45 9
45 0
68 5
100 0
55 4
72 5
66 0
52 0
81 3
100.0
48.5
76.1
70.0
53.6
82.5
100 0
78 2
75 6
72 3
54 7
82 0
100 0
68 8
86 4
85 8
59 7
84 3
100 0
74 8
63 1
70 I
59 6
68 4
100 0
72 8
81 4
85 1
69 7
69 6
49.9
70.9
58.3
32.4
88.2
54 2
83 1
63 9
34 3
85 8
23 9
48 8
68 3
56 5
06 4
71 9
31 4
07 I
50 3
81 1
82 8
51 7
04 7
00 8
Australia
50 5
52 9
50 2
Belgium2
45 6
45 3
60 7
Fin la 1zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
1d
49 2
45 9
54 4
Mexico'
24 7
26 6
34 2
The Netherlands
50 8
52 8
76 8
Portugal2 3
15 7
na
25 3
Spain2 3
29 2
I5 4
20 4
Sweden
49 8
66 0
48 5
n.a.
37.8
79.6
na
79 8
87 3
na
na
73 7
26 7
40 1
75 4
96 5
na
67 6
90 3
Or latest available year
The productivity estimates for these countries are directly derived from industry-of-origin studies and thus exclude PPPs from expenditure studies They are
therefore not strictly comparable to the estimates for the other countries
3
Portugal/USA and Spain/USA are inferential estimates based on benchmark studies for Portugal/UK and SpainiUK that were linked to the other countries by the
UK/USA comparison
Based on I987 benchmark estimates from Table 2 updated with time series from Van Ark (forthcoming) and BLS (1995) Benchmark estimates for
Source
Finland/USA Belgium/USA and Mexico/USA are from Van Ark (forthcoming) Benchmark estimate for Portugal/UK based on Peres Lopes (1994) for Spain/USA
from Van Ark [ 1995)
1
2
Table 2 .
Manufacturing labour productivity levels in major OECD economies, 1987 and 1993
Value added per hour worked, leader country = 100'
Industrial sectors
United States
lapan
Germany
France
United Kingdom
Canada
Australia
Netherlands
Sweden
Panel A: 1987
Food beverages and tobacco
32 3
100.0
Textiles, clothing and footwear
38 1
67 4
Wood products and furniture
69 5
156
Paper products and printing
97 2
47 5
Chemical products
52 9
80 8
Non-metallic mineral products
77 0
55 1
Basic metal products
94 4
100.0
Metal products
86 3
76 0
Machinery and equipment
99 0
85 6
E 1 ect r i ca 1 in a ch i n e ry
00.0
82 7
Transport equipment
96 9
100.0
Ot lizyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
e r man u fa ct u r i n g
00.0
39 4
75.3
60.1
50.2
61.2
60.1
67. I
80.3
76.3
73.8
67.6
76.7
45.3
65 3
61 7
52 4
65 0
58 0
100.0
77 0
57 3
100.0
90 0
84 9
40 1
46 1
47 4
38 I
64 7
59 5
59 9
74 2
50 6
65 4
51 3
42 1
52 5
596
546
638
81 4
680
75 1
893
70 1
642
664
69 7
583
459
422
327
532
449
56 4
57 I
42 3
61 1
358
39 3
330
95.4
100.0
100.0
62.7
100.0
97.7
80.3
68.9
59.1
93.7
47.0
47.2
57 3
60 8
64 1
100.0
72 4
75 5
93 3
100.0
66 5
75 6
55 8
67 0
Tota 1 ma i i u fact u r I ng
Coefficient of variation2
00.0
66 5
78.5
80 3
59 4
76.0
51.8
98.5
82 0
I6 9
41 4
20.5
31 0
26 I
22.7
28.0
28.4
29 2
643
463
526
676
526
784
879
548
55 5
51 9
51 1
32 3
27 I
537
398
774
568
359
464
280
96.6
100.0
72 a
66 5
71 9
Panel B: 19933
Food, beverages and tobacco
Textiles, clothing and footwear
Wood products and furniture
Paper products and printing
C he in i ca I prod uct s
Non-metallic mineral products
Basic metal products
Metal products
Machinery and equipment
Electrical machinery
100.0
78.3
56.0
85.0
66.9
81.8
76.8
68.9
160.0
80.3
356
41 9
176
497
526
629
78 3
676
674
890
826
703
506
566
509
739
780
672
587
540
87 0
67 I
55 3
64 3
56 9
99 4
63 3
46 4
67 3
78 9
41.7
51.5
28. I
76.4
79.7
70.6
61.4
42.5
47.9
48.2
100.0
64.5
100.0
100.0
70.4
54.0
34.6
82.2
100.0
89 4
81 0
100.0
100.0
45 2
100.0
Table 2. Manufacturing labour productivity levels in major zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
OECD economies, 1987 and I993 (cont.I
Value added per hour worked, leader country = 100'
industrial sectors
United States
lapan
Germany
France
Unitecl Kingdom
Canada
Australia
Netherlands
Sweden
Panel B: 1993?
Transport equipment
Other manufacturing
100.0
100.0
41 4
82 6
396
85 0
31 4
47 8
43 5
71 9
335
455
22 1
41 8
27 0
49 5
47 4
Total manufacturing
100.0
76.6
81 3
84.2
64. I
71.3
52.0
95.6
91.8
884
The procliictivity level of the leader country in each industry is indicated in bold
The coefhcient of variation is the standard deviation divided by the mean expressed as a percentage It is calculated over the 35 industries for which estimates are
available (see Table A 2 )
3
Productivity levels for Germany are for 1992
Data for 1987 based on Table A2 1993 updated from 1987 benchmark using output and employment series from STAN data-base (OECD 1995a) Hours
Source
worked for 1993 are only available for total manufacturing (BLS 1995) Consequently the trend in hours worked at the sectoral level IS assumed to be
identical to the trencl for total manufacturing
i
2
OECD Economic Studies No. 2 7. 1996111 zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
manufacturing industries has become more d i ~ e r s i f i e dIn
. ~ 1987, the United States
was the productivity leader in food products and electrical machinery, the
Netherlands in textiles and chemical products, Japan in basic metal products and
Sweden in metal products. By 1993, some of these relative positions had changed,
with Swedish productivity performance in particular improving substantially.
The productivity estimates in Table 2 cover only the 12 most important sectors.
The more detailed estimates of productivity, for all 36 industries, suggest that in
almost one-third of all industries, the United States remains the world productivity
leader. In other industries, the leadership has passed to other countries, e.g. lapan
in some heavy industries (iron and steel, shipbuilding), the Netherlands in some
light and capital-intensive industries (textiles, industrial chemicals) and Canada
and Sweden in some resource-related industries (non-ferrous metals and paper
products, respectively).
Furthermore, there appears to be a shared leadership in’ several industries,
e.g. in food products (United States and the Netherlands) and in motor vehicles
(United States, Japan).Table 2 also shows that the inter-sectoral variation in productivity performance, a s expressed in the coefficient of variation, is by far the
largest in japan. This indicates that whereas some industries in Japan are among
the world productivity leaders, others are relatively far behind (McKinsey, 1993;
Van Ark and Pilat, 1993). Consequently, the average productivity level of the lapanese manufacturing sector remains below that of the United States and several
other OECD economies.
More evidence on productivity differences, although specific to individual
countries, is available from a second approach to international comparisons,
namely country-specific case studies. Two examples of such studies are those by the
McKinsey Global Institute (McKinsey, 1993, 1994, 1995) and the Nati~nalInstitute
of Economic and Social Research (Steedman and Wagner, 1989).Case studies have
the advantage that products and firms can be carefully matched and several sources
of bias at the aggregate level can be avoided. A problem with this method is that it
is not always easy to generalise the results from case studies to a more aggregate
level
/114
Most case studies compared the productivity levels of two or more OECD
countries for individual industries. In general, they found large differences in performance across the OECD area. Table 3 shows some of the evidence for selected
manufacturing industries in seven OECD countries.8 In food products, the United
States is the undisputed productivity leader, with particularly Japan trailing far
behind. In motor vehicles, Japan and the United States are the world productivity
leaders, clearly outperforming the European countries In computer equipment,
there appear to be only small differences between the three major OECD countries
for which data are available
Comfxtition. Droductivitv and zyxwvutsrqponml
effrcienw zyxwvutsrq
Table 3.
Productivity gaps in case studies, USA = 100
Manufacturing industries
Food
products.'
1990
United States
lapan
Germany
France
Spain
Italy
Sweden
100 0
32 0
70 0
na
na
na
58 0
Services
Motor
vehicles and
equipment.2
1992
computers
and parts,?
1990
100 0
1187
58 5
56 7
100 0
95 0
89 0
na
na
na
na
40 4
39 8
79 0
B a n k ~ n g . ~ Retailing,s
1992
1990
I000
na
55 0
50 0
na
25 0
66 0
1000
44 0
89 0
87 0
73 0
na
84 0
Construction,6
1990
100 0
66 0
91 0
93 0
84 0
91 0
77 0
Value added per hour worked at industry PPPs See McKinsey (1995)
Value added per employee at industry PPPs See McKinsey (1994) Productivity level for Sweden refers to passenger
cars only
Value added per hour worked See Baily and Gersbach (1995)
3
Transactions per employee in payments and cash withdrawal See McKinsey (1995)
4
Value added per full-time equivalent employee in general merchandise retailing See McKinsey ( 1995) Productivity
5
level for Japan refers to 1987 see McKinsey (1994)
Value added per employee See McKinsey (1994)
6
Source McKinsey Global Institute (1993, 1994, 1995), Baily and Gersbach (1995)
1
2
A third approach to productivity comparisons (Caves, 1992; Mayes et al., 1994;
Perelman, 1995) uses estimates of production frontiers and measures inefficiency a s
the gap between observed efficiency in a particular firm and the estimated efficiency
frontier of the industry to which the firm belongs (see note I )
This approach also provides some useful evidence, although it can mainly be
used to analyse the existence of inefficiency within a country. Although some
attempts have been made to derive estimates of international efficiency frontiers for
manufacturing (Fecher and Perelman, 1992; Perelman, 1995),the data are often not
particularly comparable across countries and the derived efficiency measures are of
doubtful value. Five countries (Australia, Canada, Japan, the United Kingdom and
the United States) have been covered by studies of domestic efficiency frontiers,
and in each a significant level of inefficiency was found in many industries (Caves et
al., 1992, Mayes et al., 1994) In general, this is interpreted a s each industry having
a long "tail" of inefficient firms, i.e. firms that could produce substantially more
output with existing inputs
The results of this latter approach are more difficult to interpret than the rather
straightforward comparison of output per person or per h o u r worked. For instance,
an industry in a particular country may be characterised by a high level of efficiency,
implying that all (or most) firms are close t o the estimated efficiency frontier for
4
OECD Economic Studies No. 2 7, I996i11 zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
that industry and country. However, a high level of domestic efficiency does not
exclude a low level of productivity compared to other countries, as firms in a
country may be using outdated technology compared to firms in other countries.
Productivity gaps in services
There t h u s appears to be widespread evidence of large productivity differences
in the manufacturing sector, both within countries and across countries. Given the
low degree of international and domestic competition in several services, productivity might be expected to vary even more there.
Data constraints limit the scope of productivity analysis for the service sector
and most of the available work on international productivity comparisons therefore
pertains to the manufacturing sector. However, for some services, crude comparisons of productivity across countries are possible Where productivity comparisons can be made, most of the available evidence points to a large variation in
productivity in services across the OECD (Table 4 ) .
In electricity, output per person differs widely between countries, with the
United States, Japan, Canada and Norway having the highest productivity levels.
Substantial differences in productivity performance also exist within the distribution sector, suggesting sizeable scope for productivity growth in several countries
T h e highest productivity levels are estimated for the United States, France,
Germany, Belgium and Luxembourg, whereas low productivity levels are estimated
for Japan, the United Kingdom and some of the smaller OECD economies.
In airlines, considerable differences in cost efficiency exist between countries.
In this sector, the highest cost levels tend to be found in continental Europe
(including Ireland), and the lowest in Australia, t h e United States, the United
Kingdom, Finland and New Zealand Among the larger countries, the high costs
levels of Japan and France stand out. In telecommunications, productivity is relatively low in the smaller European countries, but also in Germany. Productivity
differences in postal services and railways also appear substantial, although this
evidence has a somewhat historical character. Nevertheless, productivity differences
appear quite large in these sectors as well.
/1/6
Some evidence on productivity gaps in services can also be drawn from more
detailed industry-specific comparisons across countries (Baily, 1993; McKinsey,
1992, 1994, 1995; Table 3). These studies cover the experience of selected service
industries in the United States, Japan, Germany, France, Italy, the United Kingdom,
Spain and Sweden. On the whole, they suggest t h e existence of considerable slack
in services in many countries and considerable variation in performance across
countries.
Table 4. Productivity and efficiency in selected service industries
Electricity
United States
Japan
Germany
France
Italy
United Kingdom
Canada
Aust ra 1 ia
Austria
Belgium
Denmark
Finland
Greece
Ice1a nd
Ireland
Luxembourg
Netherlands
New Zealand
Norway
Portugal
Spain
Airlines
Distribution
Retail
Telecommunications
Postal
Services
Railways
Operating
expense
per available
tonne kilometre,
1993 (US$)
Revenue
per employee,
I992
(USA = 100)
Mainlines
Per
100 inhabitants,
1992
Average
technical
efficiency,
1975-88'
Average
technical
efhciency
1986-88*
100 0
0 45
100 0
56
na
70 7
0 84
0 71
46
44
0 797
100 7
80 6
63 1
na
na
0 457
0 620
0 88
68 3
72 3
0 72
89 3
52
41
0 720
0 722
59 5
77 6
68 9
45
0 850
58 4
na
0 43
0 54
0 731
0 638
0 746
73 9
59
na
na
2.9
59 4
60 1
70 6
49
18
86 8
73 4
77 9
44
3.2
105 0
94 1
3.3
3.1
86 6
56 4
68 6
85 9
58 6
53 4
48 0
43
58
54
2.5
37 1
62 2
36 9
44
n.a.
n.a.
1i.a.
3. I
38 3
68 7
75 1
60 3
39 6
52 7
54
31
101 3
130 1
132 7
61
54 8
88 0
3.4
95 2
77 8
85 8
0 35
I 08
1 04
1 00
0 44
0 47
na
I 46
na
0 48
0 44
65 2
49
44
8.0
42 3
92 9
1 10
52 2
53
0 893
na
0 600
0 732
0 198
0 387
na
0 355
0 787
0 924
na
0 630
0 630
0 523
0 653
0 564
na
0 731
0 562
0 797
na
0 516
1.2
3.3
45 4
52 8
0 83
58 9
31
77 6
45 7
0 66
74 2
40
na
na
0 692
0 647
Gigawatt-hour
per person
engaged,
I993
Distribution GDP
per person
engaged,
1990
(USA = 100)
8.2
100 0
6.3
2.2
60 3
78 5
3.8
96 6
95 3
94 8
2.2
5.5
1.6
per employee,
I990
fUSA = loo)
na
0 594
Tau,? zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
4 . Product.. ty and efficiency in selected service industries (cont.)
~~
Electricity
Gigawatt- hou r
per person
engaged,
I993
Ai rl i nes
Distrr bution
Distribution GDP
per person
engaged
I990
(USA = 100)
per employee
I990
(USA = 100)
Operating
expense
per available
tonne kilometre
1993
(US$)
Telecommunications
Revenue
per employee
1992
Mainlines
per
100 inhabitants
(USA = 100)
I992
Railways
Average
technical
efficiency
1975-88'
1
I
Sweden
Switzerland
n.a.
Turkey
n.a.
1.
5.6
50.4
100. I
27.4
Average
techn ica I
efhciency
I 986-882
68
0.755
0 662
61
0.574
0.736
I6
n.a.
0.769
Defined as output relative to inputs, where output is the sum of the number of letters delivered and the financial operations performed, inputs include employees,
number of motor vehicles and number of postal offices used lsee Perelman and Pestieau (1994) for details].
2.
See note 1 . Output is the combination of gross hauled tonne-kilometres by freight trains and gross hauled tonne-kilometres by passenger trains The inputs are
engines and railcars, employment, and electrified and non-electrified lines lsee Pestieau ( 1993)l.
Source: Electricity based on OECDAEA (1995) and national sources for employment; Distribution GDP per person based on OECD National Accounts and national
sources, converted with 1990 PPP for expenditure on goods from OECD (1993); Retail sales per employee based on EC (1993) and national sources, converted
with same PPP; Airlines based on data provided by the Institute of Air Transport, Paris, for major airline companies; Telecommunications from OECD (1995b);
Postal services from Perelman and Pestieau (1994); Railways from Pestieau (1993).
Competition, productivity and efficiency zyxwvutsrq
EXPLAl NzyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
I N G PRODUCTIVITY LEVELS
The role of factor intensity
Part of the difference in manufacturing productivity between countries can be
explained by differences in factor use, reflecting differences in factor endowments
and relative factor prices (Salter, 1966). Firms in countries such as Mexico and
Portugal are faced with relatively low labour costs and consequently choose relatively labour-intensive production techniques, leading to low levels of labour productivity (see Table 1 ).zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
Best practice technologies from more advanced countries
may be of little relevance to these firms, a s such technologies are often based on a
different set of factor prices.
Table 5
Explanations of productivity gaps in manufacturing, 1989
All levels relative to the United States
Value added per hour worked
Relative capital intensity
Value added per unit of fixed capital
Total factor productivity (TFPI'
Relative level of workforce
q ua 1 i fi ca t ions
TFP adlusted for labour force skills'
TFP adlusted for skills and industrial
structure?
Japan
Germany
France
United Kingdom
United States
73 9
84 0
102 2
82 3
83 6
91 I
132 2
69 0
84 1
62 0
75 6
82 0
66 8
100 0
100 0
100 0
100 0
97 7
83 o
98 5
84 5
95 9
86 5
95 2
69 1
100 0
100 0
85 7
78 9
84 8
69 2
100 0
76 5
96 6
81 I
Value added per hour worked adjusted for capital per worker
1 zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
2
TFP adlusted for educational qualihcations of the manufacturing workforce For lapan the adlustment o n l y takes
account of general qualihcations for the other countries the adlustment also incorporates vocational
qualifications Workforce qualihcations are for 1987
TFP adlusted for the composition of manufacturing industrial composition based on 1987 data
3
Source Labour productivity levels are from Van Ark (1996) Adjustment factors are based on Van Ark and Pilat (1993)
for japan and Germany relative to the United States and on Van Ark (1993) for France and the United
Kingdom relative to the United States
To some extent, differences in factor prices also affect productivity differentials
between countries with more similar factor endowments, such as those reported in
Table 2. Thus, part of the difference in labour productivity across countries can be
explained by differences in capital intensity and capital productivity For instance,
japan and the United Kingdom have relatively low levels of capital intensity in their
manufacturing sector and relatively high levels of capital productivity (Table 5 ) . For
these countries, capital intensity explains a substantial part of the labour productiv-
1/9/
OECD
Economic Studies No. 2 7, I996I11 zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
ity gap with the United States, more than 25 per cent of the gap between Japan and
the United States, and almost 13 per cent of the gap between the United Kingdom
and the United States However, for France, Canada and the Netherlands, which
have more capital-intensive manufacturing industries than the United States (Pilat,
1996), an adjustment for capital intensity does not help to explain the labour
productivity gap with the United States. In general, this implies that capital productivity in the manufacturing sector of these countries is relatively low. However, the
comparison of real capital stocks and capital productivity across countries is more
difficult than the comparison of real output, implying that these numbers should be
evaluated with care.’
An adjustment for the average educational skills of the manufacturing work
force explains only little of the productivity gap. Although the average IeveI of
schooling in the United States is among the highest in the OECD (Englander and
Gurney, 1994a),the average skill level of its manufacturing work force - measured by
the qualification levels of manufacturing workers - is not very different from that of
other major OECD countries (Van Ark and Pilat, 1993; Table 5). In addition, the
experience with transplant production suggests that companies are able to match
the productivity of their parent company abroad by using local labour, suggesting
that educational differences are not a binding constraint for the achievement of
high productivity, as appropriate in-company training can reduce such differences
(McKhsey, 1993; Baily and Gersbach, 1995).
Other explanations for productivity differences
Differences in labour productivity may also be the result of structural differences, i.e. differences in the composition of output within a particutar industry or
sector. The McKinsey studies (McKinsey, 1993) suggests that this factor plays only a
limited role in most industries. However, for some of the industries shown in Annex
Table 2 this factor probably plays an important role For instance, Japan is one of
the few countries in the OECD that produces supertankers, contributing to a high
level of labour productivity in shipbuilding. In addition, the productivity leaders in
the aircraft industry, the United States and France, are the main producers of large
passenger aircraft. At the aggregate level, an adjustment for industrial structure
does not contribute much t o the overall explanation of productivity gaps, however
(Table 5). In fact, an adjustment for industrial structure increases Germany’s productivity gap with the United States, a s the industrial structure of Germany is more
geared towards industries with high absolute levels of labour productivity (Van Ark
and Pilat, 1993).
b?@.
The combined adjustments for capital intensity, labour force qualifcatjons and
industrial structure explain more than 45 per cent of the Japan-US productivity gap,
and almost 20 per cent of the UK-US productivity gap. For Germany and France, the
*
Competition, productivity and eficiency zyxwvutsrqp
combined adjustments fail to provide any explanation for the productivity gap with
the United States, although the adjustment for educational skills reduces the productivity gap somewhat.
More evidence on explanatory factors for productivity differences, although
somewhat specific to individual countries, is available from the country-specific
studies mentioned above, and primarily from the McKinsey studies (McKinsey,
1993, 1994, 1995). These studies generally confirm that differences in capital and
skill intensity do not explain much of the productivity gaps in manufacturing. They
also suggest that access to technology is not a major explanatory factor for productivity differentials across OECD countries. Much technology is embodied in capital
goods, which tend to be easily accessible in the world market. There are, however,
major differences in the degree to which the latest technology is incorporated in the
production process, suggesting that new technology is only slowly diffused across
countries.
Economies of scale do appear to play some role, at least for some countries
For japan relative to the Unjted States, Van Ark and Piiat 1993) found that the small
size of establishments in many lapanese industries contributed substantially to the
low level of average productivity. Similar evidence was presented by the McKinsey
work (Baily and Gersbach, 1995). These studies found that sub-optimal scale and
craft production processes still made up a substantial part of Japanese (e.g.in food
manufacturing) and German industry (e.g.in beer production and in metalworking),
contributing to low productivity levels in these industries.
Firms are increasingly looking across national borders to analyse the performance of their major competitors and of the productivity leaders in a particular
industry. This is particularly the case in global markets, where firms are faced with a
high degree of competition. This ”benchmarking” allows them to look at best
practice and sets standards for their own performance. In this context, the McKinsey
studies found that much of the differences across countries with regards to productivity performance actually resulted from the “organisation of functions and
tasks”.I2These differences are often the result of an accumulation of small improvements over a long period of time, regarding both workfloor organisation and the
management of the firm (Baily and Gersbach, 1995).
If differences in productivity levels across countries are not just the result of
differences in factor endowments or structural effects, then the gap in productivity
levels between countries can partly be taken a s the gap between best available
(average) practice and average implemented practice in a particular country This
would suggest the existence of considerable scope for catch-up In addition, the
large variation in productivity performance in some countries indicates that the
catch-up process with US productivity levels has not been uniform across industries, suggesting that productivity growth in some sectors may have suffered from
structural rigidities, other than the availability of technoiogy (Englander and
4
OECD zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
Economic Studies No. 27. /996/11
Gurney, 199423). T h e evidence on productivity differentials also indicates that even
within the United States, catch-up possibilities may exist in some sectors.
Where services are concerned, country-specific factors appear to affect productivity levels to some degree For instance, in electricity, favourable resource endowments in some countries (e.g. Canada and Norway) allow a high share of hydropower in electricity production, contributing to high productivity levels in these
countries. In distribution, a substantial part of the differences in productivity
appears related to structural characteristics (population density, land prices, etc.).
In airlines, specific factors such as higher fuel costs, shorter stage lengths and
higher fly-over costs reduce the efficiency of European airlines relative to US-based
carriers ( H s j , Kato and Pilat, 1996)
The impact of competition
The impact of competition on productivity is not so easy to evaluate The
degree of competition in a particular industry is difficult to measure and is determined by many different factors. Competition also does not affect productivity in a
direct and easily measurable way, a s tends to be the case with production factors
such as capital or technology. Rather, it is an important determinant of the conditions under which productivity growth occurs and under which high productivity
levels may emerge
A first look at the link between productivity levels and competition is provided
in Table 6. It shows pooled correlations between a set of competition-related
variables and labour productivity levels, for 9 countries and 36 industries The
correlations distinguish between different types of industries, based o n a typology
by market structure (Oliveira Martins, Scarpetta and Pilat, 1997) This typology
allows a distinction between different types of competitive behaviour. For instance,
fragmented, homogeneous industries are most likely to be characterised by perfect
competition. Firms in these industries are typically small and the goods produced
by these industries are relatively homogeneous Examples of such industries
include food products and textiles. On the other extreme, segmented, differentiated
industries are mostly made up of large firms, producing highly sophisticated and
differentiated goods. Examples of such industries include drugs and medicines, as
well as electrical and computer equipment.
First, as expected, relative levels of capital intensity are positively and significantly related to labour productivity levels Concentration rates are not correlated
to productivity levels in fragmented industries, but there appears to be a significant
negative link for segmented industries, suggesting that high concentration is not
conducive to productivity in these industries Entry rates have a positive impact on
productivity levels, particularly in fragmented, homogeneous industries, where entry
/122zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
is easiest and firms are relatively small
Table 6
Correlations between productivity levels and structural variables'
T-statistics in parenthesis
Trade Variables
Market structure
groups 2
Capital intensity
level
Concentration
rate
Entry
rate
Export
intensity
Import
penetration
MFN tariff
rates
Rate of
core NTBs
Fragmented, homogeneous
0.05
(0.36)
0.44
(3.97)
Fragmented, differentiated
0. I6
(0.78)
( I .70)
-0 20
(-1 2 1 )
-0 30
(-1 86)
-0 10
(-0 58)
0 41
12 68)
0.3 1
-0 09
-0 19
0 06
0 20
( 2 05)
zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCB
(-0 85)
(-I 95)
(0 57)
Segmented, homogeneous
-0.35
(-2.51 )
0.15
(1.19)
0 24
( 2 17)
0 07
(0 59)
-0 18
(-1 57)
-0 05
(-0 40)
Segmented, differentiated
-0.31
(-2.12)
0.36
(2.90)
0 04
( 0 40)
-0 15
(-1 44)
0 03
(0 32)
0 23
( 2 18)
I.
The Table shows correlations between structural variables and the pooled sample of labour productivity estimates For all 9 countries and 36 industries For which
estimates could be derived. Concentration rates (see Van Ark and Monnikhof. 1996) are only available for the United States, lapan, Germany, France and the United
Kingdom Entry rates are only available for the United States, lapan, Germany, the United Kingdom, Canada and the Netherlands.
2.
Detail on the classification of industries by market structure is available in Oliveira Martins, Scarpetta and Pilat (1997).
Source. Calculations on the basis of labour productivity levels reported in Annex Table A2; capital intensity levels from Pilat (1996);concentration rates from Van Ark
and Monnikhof (1996); entry rates from Schwalbach (19911, Management and Coordination Agency (1989/90 and 1993/94) and Kleijweg and Lever (1994),
export intensity and import penetration from STAN database (OECD, 1995a): tariff barriers and NTBs from OECD (19960).
OECD Economic
zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
Studies No. 2 7. I996/11 zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
The trade variables also provide some interesting results. Export intensity and
tariff barriers are only correlated with productivity levels in homogeneous industries, i.e, those industries where price competition is most important. Though not
significant, the negative link between import intensity and productivity levels is
more difficult t o interpret, although it could indicate that import penetration
increases if industries in a particular country can not match high productivity levels
abroad. Non-tariff barriers (NTBs) appear positively linked to high productivity
levels, but only in differentiated industries. This result is surprising and difficult to
interpret, as NTBs are primarily used in declining industries, most of which tend to
produce homogeneous goods.
The correlation analysis is somewhat elaborated in the regression analysis of
Table 7. It appears that some of the variation in manufacturing labour productivity
levels seems related to the exposure of sectors to international competition, a s
measured by tariff barriers and export intensity, while, a s expected, a much larger
part appears due to differences in capital intensity T h e regressions only explain
about half of the variation in productivity levels, however. This is not surprising, a s a
complete model of productivity levels is difficult to test empirically. Many relevant
variables, for instance work force qualifications or the degree of foreign direct
investment by industry, are not available at a sufficient level of detail and are thus
difficult to integrate in a regression analysis
In the McKinsey work, the degree t o which firms implement modern technology
was directly related to their exposure to competition A firm in a sheltered market
has few incentives to choose an efficient technology and reduce resource use, but
can spend the rents it earns on technical inefficiency and organisational slack. For
Germany, lapan and the United States, Baily and Gersbach (1995) argued that
differences in the use of modern technology were strongly correlated with the extent
to which entire industries were exposed to competition with best-practice firms,
either by international trade or by competition with transplant companies. In general, domestic competition by itself was insufficient to bring firms - and hence
entire industries - up to global best practice productivity levels.
The work on efficiency frontier measurement also provides some links between
competition variables and inefficient behaviour (Caves, et al., 1992). Of particular
interest are two types of explanations:
- Competitive conditions. In most countries efficiency within an industry
declines beyond a certain level of concentration, suggesting that high levels
of concentration are detrimental to efficiency. In Japan and Canada, exportoriented industries were found to be more efficient than import-competing
industries, whereas import competition favourably affected efficiency in the
United States and the United Kingdom Furthermore, tariff protection (in
Japan and in Australia) and entry-restricting regulations (in japan) were
found t o have a negative impact on efficiency. T h i s suggests that
Table 7. Regressions explaining labour productivity levels in manufacturing, I987
Dependent variable is real value added per hour worked (in logs),
t-statistics in parenthesis'
Capital
Constant
intens it y
level
(in logs)
0 477
30 1
0 267
0 504
300
0 260
0 510
297
0 258
-0 250
(-3 24)
0 522
300
0 255
-0 238
(-3 09)
0 526
297
0 254
Import
penetration
R2
(in logs)
(in logs)
( i n logs)
(adi)
3 414
17 84)
0 189
(4 80)
Equation 2
3 773
1831)
0 154
( 3 92)
0 091
(4 06)
Equation 3
3 866
18 53)
0 145
( 3 69)
0 086
(384)
3 829
( I 8 85)
0 162
(4 20)
0 103
( 4 63)
3 916
(19 02)
0 154
( 3 98)
0 098
( 4 39)
Equation 5
Standard
errors
of regression
Tariff
measures
Equation I
Equation 4
Nob
Export
intensity
-0 065
(-2 14)
-0 056
(-1 88)
1 zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
The eqiiations include hxeci country effectsand sectoral effects They are based on the pooled sample of productivity estimates for 9 countries and 36 industries
(see Annex)
See source note to Table 6
Source
OECD Economic Studies No. 2 7, I996111 zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
competition reduces the spread in performance within an industry, probably
by removing the most inefficient firms and by boosting performance in other
firms. In general, domestic competition appears to play a larger role than
international competition in promoting efficiency (i.e. eliminating intrasector efficiency differences) within a given sector in an individual country.
-
Organisational and managerial influences. Although difficult t o measure, t h e
ultimate source of inefficiency is often related to the management of a
particular firm. Only some aspects of this factor have been analysed, however. For instance, Caves and Burton (1992) found that many U S firms had
diversified their activities too much in the 197Os, leading to a decline in
efficiency.
Apart from these competition-related reasons, other explanations for inefficiency in these studies of efficiency frontiers were provided by industrial dynamics
(fast-growing industries are likely to show a larger variation in perFormance), spatial
disparities (efficiency is likely to difFer in a geographically diversified market) and
heterogeneity of products (which implies that the calculated efficiency frontier may
not be appropriate for the industry as a whole)
For services, the link between competition and productivity can often only be
made in a rather descriptive way, as few hard indicators of competition are available Within private services, the profit motive provides incentives for managers to
enhance productivity, although regulations can limit the impact of competition.
Regulations may also prevent firms from using business practices developed in
other countries (OECD, 1 9 9 5 ~ )For
. sectors controlled by public enterprises, profitmaximising behaviour is likely to play a more limited role in managers’ decisionmaking.
Across different sectors, there are some indications that competition matters.
In electricity, the variation in productivity tends t o be large even for countries with a
similar composition of supply, suggesting that pure efficiency differences may play
some role. For instance, productivity levels in the United States are substantially
higher than in many other countries, even though the bulk of U S electricity production is based on combustible fuels
In distribution, part of the variation in productivity seems due to a high degree
of regulation in some countries, principally limitations on large-scale establishments and restrictive zoning laws ( H s j et al., 1996) In airlines, the evidence suggests that deregulated markets (primarily the United States, the United Kingdom,
Canada, Australia and New Zealand) have much lower costs and are much more
efficient than regulated markets (mainly those of many countries in continental
Europe)
Within public enterprises and in particular in sectors that were, until recently,
j126 zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
generally considered to be natural monopolies (e.g telecommunications, railways,
Competition, productivity and eficiency zyxwvutsrqp
postal services), the link between efficiency and competition is probably stronger
The lack of competition in these sectors and the high degree of public ownership
have reduced incentives for cost-minimisation and efficiency improvements and
have often led to a substantial degree of overstaffing (Pera, 1989). Furthermore,
public enterprises tend to have lower internal efficiency than private enterprises
(OECD, 1994).
In telecommunications, technological improvements and the rationalisation of
activities, partly due to increased out-sourcing, have substantially increased productivity. This trend, and the ensuing fall in costs and prices have been strongest in
countries with competitive telecommunications markets (OECD, 1995b) For European railways, the evidence (Pestieau, 1993) suggests that some of the efficiency
differences between companies (Table 4 ) are related to t h e degree of autonomy
under which railways operate. Research on postal services within Europe (Perelman
and Pestieau, 1994; Table 4 ) also suggests a link between efficiency and the degree
of regulation and managerial autonomy of postal service companies
Case studies of service productivity also often relate the existence of slack to a
lack of competition (Baily, 1993) For instance, case studies of t h e banking industry
suggested that this sector was characterised by considerable inefficiency, and few
incentives to adopt new technology and available innovations before competitive
pressures increased. Similar conclusions were drawn from case studies on airlines,
construct ion and telecom m U n i ca t ions.
THE DETERMlNANTS OF PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH
Capital accumulation, R I D and technological diffusion
The analysis of productivity levels generates useful insights in cross-country
productivity differences and the links with competition The analysis of productivity
growth is a more standard tool of economic analysis and may also provide useful
views on the impact of competition Most research suggests that capital accurnulation, RGD expenditure and human capital accumulation are the prime drivers of
productivity growth (Englander and Gurney, 1994a; OECD, 1996).
Unfortunately, human capital is difficult t o integrate in detailed sectoral productivity analysis, due to data constraints. However, a regression analysis of manufacturing productivity growth at the sectoral level suggests that labour productivity
growth is indeed positively affected by the growth of capital intensity, and also by
the growth of the available RCD stock (RGD expenditure, accumulated over 5 years)
per person engaged (Table 8)
In recent years, much attention has focused on the role of technological diffusion Recent studies (Coe and Helpman, 1 9 9 5 ; OECD, 1995; Eaton and Kortum,
1995a, 1995b) suggest an important role of foreign RGD in productivity growth,
rzzyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
lk zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
Table 8. Estimates of labour productivity growth for manufacturing industries, 1981-90
Dependent variable is real growth of value added per person employed, t-statistics in parenthesis
~
~~
Competition variables
Growth of
capital
i n te ns i ty
Growth of
RGD stock
per person
Tariff
measures
( i n logs)
Equation l 2
0.370
(5.69)
0 196
( 7 37)
Equation 22
0.330
(4.93)
0 200
( 7 48)
-0 262
(-1 02)
Equation 33
0.36 1
(4.89)
0 287
( 7 64)
-0 761
(-3 08)
Equation 42
0.48 1
(6.17)
Equation 52
0.3 15
(4.01)
Nob'
lad')
Standard
error of
equation
0 664
( 3 29)
0 536
2 23
315
0 623
( 3 02)
0 529
2 22
31 1
0 491
2 32
I92
- 1 363
(-3 29)
0 513
2 29
25 I
-0 759
(-I 92)
0 566
2 13
242
Export
intensity
( i n logs)
Entry
rate
( i n logs)
( i n logs)
I058
( 2 13)
0 889
(361)
0 256
( 7 00)
1974 Labour
productivity
level
R2
There are some differences in the coverage of the equations, due to availability of the basic data. Data on RGD stocks are not available for Australia, Belgiuin and
Norway, while entry rates are only available for the United States, lapan, Germany, the United Kingdom, Canada, Belgium, the Netherlands and Norway, 1974
procluctivity levels could not be derived for Australia
2
Equations include fixecl country and fixecl sectoral effects
Equation includes only fixed country effects Fixed sectoral effects were not significant
3
Source Calculations are based on STAN data-base, RGD stocks are calculated on the basis of RCD flows from OECD's ANBERD data-base (OECD. 199513).other
variables are derived from sources cliioted i n Table 6
1
Competition, productivity and efficiency zyxwvutsrqp
attesting t o the importance of diffusion. A recent OECD study (OECD, 1996) concluded that: technology diffusion often accounted for more than half of total factor
productivity growth; that its contribution was typically larger than that of direct
RGD; and that the role of technological diffusion increased from the 1970s to the
1980s. Not surprisingly, this study also found that technological diffusion was
particularly important for smaller countries.
Productivity growth also depends on the starting point, with low initial levels
permitting faster growth This catch-up factor has given rise to a substantial literature, which tends to conclude that countries can catch-up with the productivity level
of the leader country, providing that they have a sufficient stock of education and
basic knowledge to absorb technology from abroad (Abramovitz, 1989). Among
OECD countries, catch-up and convergence of income and productivity levels has
been observed at the macro-economic level. Table 8 (equations 4 and 5) confirms
that some element of catch-up is also at work at the industry level in the manufacturing sector, with low initial productivity contributing to more rapid productivity
growth.
The impact of competition
As indicated before, the impact of competition o n productivity growth is likely
to be more indirect. By allowing inefficiencies to persist, weak competition may
affect productivity growth. A lack of competition may also put insufficient pressure
on management to improve productivity performance and incorporate new technology, and thus contribute to a productivity gap with best practice
The regression analysis reported in Table 8 appears t o confirm that the degree
of competition has some impact o n productivity growth. Tariff measures appear to
have a negative effect on labour productivity growth, whereas export intensity
affects productivity growth positively. These results support the view that exposure
to international competition promotes productivity growth. There are a number of
alternative interpretations of the link between exports and productivity per-formance, however (Englander and Gurney, 1994a). For instance, competition on the
international market can contribute to cost minimisation, but exports may also
allow specialisation and economies of scale
It also appears that a dynamic product market, a s measured by entry rates,
provides a positive contribution to productivity growth. High entry (and exit) rates
could ensure that only the best (and most productive) firms survive the competitive
process, thus promoting productivity growth in an industry (Nickell, 1996)
The impact of competition on productivity growth is confirmed by a number OF
other studies, many based on industry- or firm-level panel data for individual
countries (e.g. Haskel, 1991). These studies found that high degrees of market
concentration and market share have an adverse effect on the level of total factor
4
OECD Economic Studies No. 27, I996/11 zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
productivity. A more recent study for the United Kingdom (Nickell, 1996) confirmed
this result, but also found that competition, measured by an increase in the number
of competitors or lower levels of rents, is associated with higher total factor productivity growth.
A reduction in technical inefficiency within countries may also contribute to
TFP growth. Although few studies have covered this aspect, the available evidence
(Perelman, 1995), suggests that technical efficiency in the manufacturing sector of
most OECD countries has actually declined over the period 1970-87 (i.e.the spread
in productivity performance within industries has increased). According to this
study, the main exceptions to this were Belgium and Japan,where improvements in
technical efficiency provided a sizeable contribution t o TFP growth over this period.
For services, the available evidence suggests a positive contribution of efficiency
improvements t o TFP growth in most OECD countries over the period 1971-86
(Fecher-and Perelman, 1992).
The determinants of productivity growth may also differ according to market
structure type (Table 9). It appears that the growth of capital intensity contributes to
productivity growth in segmented, homogeneous industries, i.e. industries with
high s u n k costs, but has no significant ef€ect in the other sectors. The growth of
RGD stocks contributes to productivity growth throughout all sectors, but its effect
is by far the strongest in segmented, differentiated industries, although it is also
substantial in fragmented, differentiated industries. The negative contribution of
tariff measures to productivity growth is strongest in homogeneous industries,
where price competition is likely to be most intense High entry rates provide a
positive, and significant contribution to productivity growth, except in segmented,
differentiated industries which are most likely t o be characterised by oiigopolistic
ma rket st ru ct u res .
The link between competition and productivity growth is perhaps most clearly
demonstrated by the experiences with service sector deregulation in many OECD
countries (Winston, 1993; H 0 j , Kato and Pilat, 1996). For instance, the deregulation
of the US airline market since 1978 and that of the United Kingdom over the 1980s
led to a sharp restructuring of the industry and a large increase in productivity. The
deregulation of road freight transport in many OECD countries {OECD, 1990) and of
the telecommunications industry in the United States, the United Kingdom and
Japan (Harris, et al., 1995) led t o similar experiences
CONCLUDING REMARKS
E
Although the evidence is scattered and incomplete, a number of conclusions
emerge from the discussion above. First, it appears that inefficiency and low productivity levels are widespread in both manufacturing and services, and throughout
the OECD area, suggesting a substantial potential for further productivity growth in
Table 9
Estimates of labour productivity growth for manufacturing, by market structure, 198 1-90'
Dependent variable is real growth of value added per person employed, t-statistics in parenthesis
competition variables
Constant
Growth of
capital
intensity
Growth of
RGD stock
per person
Tariff
measures
(in logs)
Entry
rates
(in logs)
R2
(adi)
Nob
A11 industries 2
0.409
(5.72)
0.216
(5.67)
1.862
(5.25)
0 386
i92
Fragmented, homogeneous
0.136
(1.28)
0.037
(0.75)
0.976
(2.26)
0.096
63
Fragmented, differentiated
0.207
(0.62)
0.352
(2.94)
3.635
(2.60)
0 398
22
Segmented, homogeneous
0.502
(4.12)
0. I98
(2.34)
1.91 1
(2.85)
0.353
66
Segmented, differentiated
0.210
( I .36)
0.399
(5.65)
0.633
(0.60)
0.573
41
Equations are based on pooled data for the United States, Japan. Germany, the United Kingdom, Canada and the Netherlands.
This equation is similar to equation 3 reported in Table 8, but excludes fixed country effects.
Source. Calculations based on STAN database (OECD. 1995a).
1.
2.
OECD Economic Studies No. 2 7. I996I11 zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
many countries. The great variation in the speed of catch-up across industries may
indicate that structural factors inhibit productivity growth in some sectors.
Second, the variation in productivity levels and growth rates across countries
appears to some extent related to the degree of competition facing industries and
sectors in different countries. International competition, both in the form of trade
and of direct foreign investment, appears to be an important element in achieving
high levels of efficiency, while case studies suggest that the highest levels of
efficiency are achieved by industries competing with best (global) practice. Productivity growth in manufacturing appears positively affected by open borders, a high
export intensity and favourable entry conditions Openness also allows firms to
learn from and benchmark their performance against that of their international
com pet itors
There are also some signs that high entry rates are conducive to productivity
and that a high degree of concentration is not Furthermore, sectors with a rapid
growth of RGD stocks enjoy more rapid productivity growth. Industry-specific catchup appears to play a role in explaining productivity growth, indicating the importance of technological diffusion and openness. In service sectors, governmentimposed regulations are often an important restriction on competition, preventing
entry and reducing the benefits of competition. Regulatory reform in many service
sectors has led to an increase in competition and almost invariably to higher
productivity growth.
Finally, the evidence from studies on efficiency frontiers suggests that a low
degree of competition within a country, as indicated by low entry rates or a high
degree of concentration, is likely to lead to a high variation in efficiency and
productive performance and consequently to sub-optimal average productivity.
However, if inefficient behaviour results from a lack of competition within a market
or a high degree of regulation, the policy implications are more obvious than if
inefficiencies result from other factors such as differences in the product mix or a
geographically diversified market
Annex
COMPARING PRODUCTIVITY LEVELS:
MEASUREMENT ISSUES
This annex briefly describes the methodology and data that were used to
compute the labour productivity levels for manufacturing presented in the main text
of the paper.I3 Productivity estimates were calculated for 9 countries, with industrydetail for 36 sectors. Two main problems had to be solved. The first relates to the
conversion of value added in national currencies to a common currency. The second
problem concerns the basic sources on value added, employment and hours
worked.
In principle, the appropriate conversion factors for productivity comparisons
need to be derived from a comparison of producer prices for specific goods. Such
prices are sampled for most countries for the construction of the overall producer
price index, but these data are often not available for outside analysis and may be
difficult t o compare across countries Another source of producer price
information -at least for manufactured products - is the census of manufacturing
industries. Most countries publish such a census, which shows production values
and output quantities for a range of products, in principle allowing the comparison
of producer prices and the derivation of appropriate conversion factors. This
approach, the “industry-of-origin” approach, has been used in a range of studies,
starting with some early work at OEEC (Paige and Bombach, 1959). Recently, most
efforts in this area have been made by a group of researchers at the University of
Groningen (Van Ark and Pilat, 1993; Van Ark and Wagner, 1996; Van Ark,
forthcoming).
The results of this approach have been scrutinised in a number of studies The
results of a comparison for Germany, Japan and the United States (Van Ark and
Pilat, 1993) were carefully checked by work at McKinsey (McKinsey, 1993; Baily and
Gersbach, 1995; Gersbach and Van Ark, 1995). The McKinsey work profited from
detailed knowledge by industry experts and price information at the firm level.
Substantial changes were made to some price comparisons (mainly for investment
goods), but price comparisons for more homogeneous products (iron and steel,
,131
OECD
Economic Studies No. 27, I996111
beer) were hardly affected. The overall perspective on Japanese and German
productivity performance changed little, however.
There are a number of problems involved in using the industry-of-origin
approach:
- The “prices” derived from the manufacturing census relate to average prices
or “unit values” (i.e.values divided by quantities). If a country is producing a
wide range of qualities and varieties of a particular good, the “price” is rather
crude for comparative purposes. In a cross-country context, quality
differences between countries may not be properly accounted for. This issue
is less likely t o be a problem for industries producing relatively
homogeneous goods
- Unit values are available o n l y for a sample of goods, and can be compared
among countries for an even smaller sample, partly because of
confidentiality problems. In addition, the production structure of countries
tends to be far less comparable than the expenditure structure. Both
problems imply that the unit values only cover part of the manufacturing
sector, and that an aggregation procedure is required to cover manufacturing
a s a whole.
- The third major problem is double deflation
Comparisons of labour
productivity or total factor productivity are generally based o n value added
by industry, which implies, in principle, that conversion measures for both
output and intermediate input are required In practice, conversion factors
for intermediate input are very difficult to derive in a cross-country context
Most studies have therefore tended to apply the conversion factors at the
producer level directly to value added (i.e. single deflation, see Van Ark,
forthcoming)
1134
Although the production approach is theoretically the correct approach to
sectoral productivity comparisons, it is therefore not without some measurement
problems. Some authors have therefore used the more widely available price
information (purchasing power parities or PPPs) on the expenditure side (Jorgenson
and Kuroda, 1992; Kuroda, 1996).This type of information is available for almost all
OECD Member countries at a fairly dis-aggregated level and new comparisons of
this type are made on a regular basis. Extensive data sets are available for 1985
(OECD, 1987), 1990 (OECD, 1993) and 1993 (OECD, 1996a). T h e 1990 price
comparisons covered about 2500 goods and services, and detailed comparisons are
available for about 220 “basic headings”. The price comparisons are based o n
detailed product descriptions, which generally ensures a rather high quality of the
price comparisons.
Competition, Productivity and Efficiency
Where productivity measurement is concerned, these price comparisons are
rather problematic, however There are five problems in using expenditure PPPs for
sectoral productivity comparisons:
- Distribution and transport margins. PPPs on the expenditure side are based
on comparisons of prices at the retail (for consumer goods) or wholesale (for
investment goods) level This implies that distribution and transport margins
are added to the producer price, and that cross-country differences in the
size of these margins affect the estimated price level
- Indirect taxes less subsidies. Prices at the expenditure level include indirect
taxes less subsidies, implying that differences in VAT and other indirect taxes
(duties) across countries affect the measurement of the relative price level
- International trade. International productivity comparisons should be based
on the output produced in a country. However, part of this output is
exported and not counted in comparisons of expenditure prices, while
imported goods are taken into account in expenditure comparisons, but
should be excluded for producer price comparisons
- Intermediate goods. Expenditure comparisons only cover goods entering
final expenditure (see above). Intermediate goods, that form the bulk of
output in many sectors of the economy, are not covered.
- Double deflation. Even after "peeling off" distribution margins and net
indirect taxes, and after adjusting for international trade, the prices derived
still refer t o output only. No information is available on prices of
intermediate goods that would allow double deflation
Providing data are available on the distribution margins by country (and
preferably by sector), it is fairly simple to adjust for distribution margins (Hooper
and Vrankovich, 1995). It is also fairly simple to adjust for taxes and subsidies
Adjusting for international trade is not so easy (Hooper and Vrankovich, 1995), a s
information on the price levels of exports, imports and domestic production is
required. Although some simplifying assumptions can be made, no simple solution
is available and many expenditure studies (lorgenson and Kuroda, 1992) have not
addressed this problem. The fourth problem, that of intermediate goods, can not be
addressed if only expenditure PPPs are used Most studies of this type use price
ratios of other goods to f i l l these gaps. The fifth problem, that of double deflation,
is inherent to international comparisons on the production side and no satisfactory
solution is available
There therefore appear to be advantages and disadvantages t o both the
production and expenditure approaches The production approach has the merit OF
basing its price information directly on the producer price concept This is in
contrast to the expenditure approach, where a n u m b e r of adjustments are required,
potentially introducing substantial measurement errors. The production approach is
/35/
OECD Economic Studies No. 27, /996/11 zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
also the only approach that allows the derivation of price information for
intermediate goods. However, for investment goods the production approach tends
to offer less information.
In principle, detailed productivity comparisons might benefit from a mix of the
two approaches. Therefore, this paper uses a mix of industry-of-origin and
expenditure PPPs for the conversion of value added to a common currency. Table AI
shows the conversion factors that were used by industry. Industry-of-origin price
comparisons for the nine countries (see source note to Table A2) were used where
possible, and could be applied in more than 65 per cent of all cases These price
ratios are all based on binary price comparisons between the United States and one
other country j 4 Conversion factors from the McKinsey studies were used for Japan
and Germany for those industries where these estimates were availabie (Gersbach
and Van Ark, 1995) Expenditure PPPs, adjusted for net indirect tax rates and
industry-specific distribution margins, were used for the other cases.I5
Nevertheless, for about 20 cases n o suitable PPP was available from either the
production or expenditure side, or the basic data were inadequate, impiying that no
productivity level could be estimated
Table AI indicates that for both the European countries and Japan, 1987
manufacturing price levels were on average substantially above US price levels. T h e
relative price levels of Canada and Australia were - on average - almost identical to
those in the United States. The variation in price levels across industries is
considerable, however, particularly in Japan, and to a lesser degree also in France
and the Netherlands.
Following the derivation of the PPPs, the main problem for the estimation of
productivity levels is the availability of a suitable and comparable data-base. The
starting point for data collection was OECD’s STAN database {OECD, 1995a), and
the industry detail presented in that database. However, these data are closely
linked to the national accounts of each country, which often implies that output and
employment information are not derived from consistent data sources (Van Ark,
forthcoming). In addition, since STAN is an estimated data-base, some of the
industry data appeared to be implausible when compared across countries. For
most countries, detailed information was therefore derived from national
production censuses These sources have the advantage that output and
employment information are based on a single source.I6 Furthermore, the industry
detail available in production censuses often allows the reclassification of
industries to achieve cross-country comparability. An adjustment for hours worked
was based on the estimates of hours worked in the country-specific studies (see
note to Table A2).
/136
Relative labour productivity was subsequently calculated on the basis of the
conversion factors of Table A I , and the value added, employment and h o u r s worked
information from the production censuses and national studies. As shown in
Table A2, the results indicate a wide range in labour productivity levels.
Table A l .
Relative price levels for manufacturing industries, major OECD economies, I987
Industry-specific Purchasing Power Parity divided by the Exchange Rate, United States = 100
Industrial sectors
(STAN classification)
Food Products
Beverages
Tobacco
Textiles
Clothing
Leather products
Footwear
Wood products
Furniture
Paper products
Printing, publishing
Industrial chemicals
Drugs and medicines
Chemical products, nec
Petroleum refineries
Petroleum and coal products
Rubber products
Plastic products
Pottery, china, etc
Glass products
Non-meta I 1 i c m i nera I products
Iron and steel
Non-ferrous metals
Metal products
Office and computing machinery
Machinery and equipment, nec
Radio, TV and comm equipment
Electrical apparatus, nec
Shipbuilding and repair
Railroad equipment
Motor vehicles
Motorcycles and bicycles
Aircraft
i
lapan
Germany
France
United Kingdom
Canada
I84 0
153 I
78 3
I25 6
I23 9
I44 4
I44 4
326 0
115.1
132.4
67.2
145.0
161.7
123.6
156.1
149.4
123.I
145.4
118.0
169.2
1 i 1.6
1 11.6
107.8
130 I
96 1
77 8
11 9
13 2
94 I
94 1
50 5
1128
134 1
74 7
106 5
105 7
91 6
92 2
I06 0
390.3
188.4
197.0
54.4
1300
125.6
124.1
171 I
171.7
235.6
161.9
105.7
184 7
145 2
145 2
73 9
73 9
86 6
84 7
30 9
30 9
30 9
00 7
60 8
96 8
06 0
01 7
96 0
102 7
142.4
122.4
122.4
09.4
09.4
28.9
42.4
10.6
35.9
10.6
04.4
22.7
26.7
27.2
36.7
162 8
148.3
139.9
139.9
139.9
120. I
109.5
106.7
149.4
22 I .8
159.0
197.2
255.0
103 6
I03 6
I03 6
105 4
105 4
89 9
89 9
I06 2
106 2
106 2
103 9
121 7
109 3
99 8
99 8
120 9
120 9
82 9
112.8
89.0
123.6
132.0
100 0
92.8
101 3
124. I
97 3
97 3
97 3
101 4
101 4
92 9
97 3
99 0
99 0
99 0
97 1
108 1
98 7
105.1
105.1
I24 5
120.6
95.4
243.5
92 I
2 12.2
226.5
187.6
167.9
n.a.
na
na
na
na
1128
na
191.9
121.9
125.5
179.7
94.4
n.a.
97.5
139.9
95.0
95.0
95.0
125.1
n.a.
144.5
118.6
118.6
136.4
162.9
Australia
Netherlands
Sweden
93 4
120 4
I53 8
85 5
108 1
I52 8
47 6
64 2
67 2
1190
14 5
166 1
1105
24 4
153 3
127 3zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJ
96 2
132 3
90 9
96 2
132 3
144 7
36 7
160 1
115.4
198.1
126 1
1130
1129
94.0
250.2
101 7
101 7
188.5
93 1
93 1
93 1
92.4
na
87 8
93 1
103 8
103 8
103 8
I04 9
1 I96
110 1
75.8
75.8
131 5
142 7
149. I
141.0
79 7
101 7
Ill I
Ill 1
101 7
101 7
91 3
91 3
91 3
I42 6
na
139.8
163.2
163.2
126.0
139.3
166.4
131.7
122 4
122 4
122 4
I28 2
128 2
103 0
122 4
1353
135 3
135 3
111 2
I30 0
1125
142.9
142.9
138 2
134 I
2 10.6
266.0
122 4
na
227.8
Economic Studies No. 2 7, I996111
.-..-zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
CT,
CI)
zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
h
3
\
U
C
2 zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
L
3
-m
U
C
-
c
zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
0
..-0zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
U
c-'
m
C
a,
.-m
L
m
>
U
Lc-
E
U
m
a,
0
C
a,
.U
m E
2
a,
U
0
X zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
M
C
W
U
Table A2
Manufacturing labour productivity levels in major zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
OECD economies, I987
Value added per hour worked, leader country = 100'
~
Industrial sectors
(STAN classification)
Food products
Beverages
Tobacco
Texti 1es
Clothing
Leather products
Footwear
Wood products
Furniture
Paper products
Printing , publishing
lndust ria I chemicals
Drugs and medicines
Chemical products, nec
Petroleum refineries
Petroleum and coal products
Rubber products
Plastic products
Pottery, china, etc.
Glass products
Non-metallic mineral products
Iron and steel
Non-ferrous metals
Metal products
Office and computing machinery
Machinery and equipment,nec
Radio, TV and comm. equipment
Electrical apparatus, nec
Shipbuilding and repair
Ra i I road equipment
Motor vehicles
Motorcycles and bicycles
Aircraft
~~
United States
lapan
Germany
France
United Kingdom
100.0
100.0
75 0
64 0
90 I
74 9
70 7
59 6
88 I
87 8
100.0
86 4
100.0
31 7
47 6
38 1
41 0
41 5
37 3
51 8
14 I
I8 9
42 3
47 5
56 6
83 0
66 1
62 9
41 8
96 7
42 1
39 7
81 5
48 5
100.0
60 1
86 5
52 9
92 6
84 8
80 2
100.0
52 5
95 I
52 8
41 7
66 3
54 6
65 3
61 6
68 4
71 9
55 0
49 4
57 0
57 1
53 4
54 5
61 2
58 5
61 2
54 2
78 4
61 2
66 7
57 4
66 5
69 3
79 5
86 8
62 6
78 7
79 5
59 4
60 9
33 5
71 5
42 5
57 6
66 8
53 5
100.0
69 4
61 5
63 8
68 6
60 0
46 3
56 0
67 3
60 8
52 3
54 4
30 6
na
86 5
60 9
71 I
93 9
100.0
54 6
na
65 3
43 6
64 6
45 1
52 3
51 0
52 6
61 3
33 7
47 4
30 0
87 6
61 2
59 8
58 7
73 8
46 6
72 7
69 7
43 6
51 6
65 4
68 5
61 0
57 6
71 6
67 9
53 5
50 6
36 4
27 5
51 5
100.0
57 7
77 3
88 4
75 0
69 7
79 4
67 4
83 9
94 5
98 2
75 8
100.0
100.0
100.0
74 2
90 7
I00.0
100.0
IOO.0
100.0
93 5
86 7
64 5
28 6
100.0
83 5
Canada
62 7
44 0
65 6
64 2
63 5
55 1
62 2
58 9
67 4
82 3
60 3
90 1
73 5
65 2
44 0
Australia
47 7
49 0
42 2
44 0
47 7
48 5
51 2
27 2
43 5
41 7
59 5
57 8
38 9
47 I
24 5
100.0
na
77 4
67 2
97 5
63 8
68 0
72 4
100.8
79 8
42 1
70 2
71 4
61 2
49 1
42 9
69 7
57 5
54 5
45 5
68 2
47 8
40 8
74 9
48 1
33 9
67 1
46 6
36 8
32 3
23 3
44 7
Netherlands
83 3
76 5
63 4
100.0
100.0
100.0
104.0
100.0
100.0
85 9
51 0
100.0
72 7
89 8
86 6
76 0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
86 9
59 6
na
78 4
35 8
65 7
91 4
87 7
51 7
na
53 2
Sweden
62 2
58 3
68 7
62 1
64 6
78 I
62 I
54 4
80 4
100.0
70 1
65 7
75 3
52 9
100.0
89 8
86 6
75 5
58 9
80 0
69 6
80 3
93 5
100.0
40 7
74 1
78 4
72 3
39 0
20 8
66 6
na
na
na
na
na
na
78 3
29 6
56 2
33 5
33 7
38 8
OECD Economic Studies No. 2 7, /996/11 zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
C
W
U
W
3
zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
v)
in
U
-cm
L
W
5
W
2
.-m
E
r
in
z
m
-o
m
C
m
“a
O“
09
- d
Y.,
-
N
zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
U
5
U
M
.-c
Y
U
-01
odM
MY.,
-?
o\
Y.,
-
6
N
W
.-
4.a
C
3
U
W
U?-’
C
- M
E
Ll.
NY.,
0
CO
-
9
M
>
C
m
2
U
C
m
a
m
-
b.01 L”
- N
M
d
‘0
O
-b.
d
U)
W
r
m
65
7J
W
4-2
.-
C
3
-c
0
E ‘mr;
9u .U
c
25
U)
- m
.m 7?
L
z3 z
4
-ofj140 zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
f’”
Competition, Productivity and Efjkiency zyxwvuts
NOTES
Efficiency and productivity are related, but not identical concepts (Sharpe, 1995). A firm
I. zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
o r industry is considered t o be inefficient if it could produce more output with existing
inputs, be. the firm is not on the production possibility curve, but within it. Productivity
relates the quantity of output produced to one o r more inputs used in its production,
irrespective of the efficiency of their use.
2.
The paper by Symeonides (I997) provides an extensive discussion of the link between
competition and innovation.
3.
Finland’s rapid productivity gains over the past decade are closely related to the
significant restructuring of i t s manufacturing sector over the period I99 I - 1994.
4.
Table I shows only estimates of labour productivity. However, the high share of labour
compensation in total value added implies that labour productivity levels tend to be a
reasonable approximation of TFP levels. TFP levels are more difficult t o calculate as the
measurement of real capital stocks across countries poses several methodological
difficulties (Blades, 1993; Maddison, 1993). Table 5 below presents some estimates of
TFP levels for total manufacturing, based on standardised estimates of capital stocks for
these countries (see Van Ark, forthcoming).
5.
T o convert value added t o a common currency, PPPs from available industry-of-origin
studies were applied where possible, whereas (adjusted) expenditwe PPPs were applied
in the other cases (see Annex for methodological details). For a few industries no
suitable PPP could be estimated, or the basis data were inadequate, and consequently no
productivity estimate could be derived.
6. The productivity estimates in Table 2 differ somewhat from those in the countryspecific studies because of two main methodological differences. First, the countryspecific studies do not estimate conversion factors for all industries, but sometimes
apply the PPP of one industry to another industry. In most cases, the current study
applies expenditure-based PPPs to industries for which no industry-of-origin estimate is
available. Second, the industry breakdown in the current study is more detailed than
that of the country-specific studies, which affects the estimated productivity level for
total manufacturing. The Annex and Pilat (I996) provide more details on the estimation
procedure.
7. Table 2 presents results only for the largest sectors. More detailed estimates, for
35 manufacturing industries in 9 countries, are available in the Annex.
141/
OECD Economic Studies No. 2 7, I996111
8.
The productivity estimates in Table 3 differ somewhat from those in Table 2 and
Table A2, primarily due t o differences in the basic data, related t o the precise definition
of an industry. However, the main thrust of the results tends to be the same.
9. A disadvantage of these studies is their rather historical character, as most of them
cover inefficiency in the 1970s.
10.
In some services (e.g. electricity and transport), physical measures are a relatively sound
basis t o measure real output, thus reducing problems with the conversion of output to a
common currency. For some other services (e.g. distribution, construction)
comparisons of expenditure price levels provide a reasonable basis to convert real
output (e.g. Baily, 1993), as prices of these services tend t o be influenced only little by
trade and transport margins o r international trade (see Annex).
11.
Average levels of capital productivity and capital intensity may also conceal a large
variation in capital intensity and capital productivity across countries. For instance, the
low level of capital intensity in Japanese manufacturing obscures large differences among
industries (Pilat, I996), with the iron and steel industry, shipbuilding and motor vehicles
in Japan having very high levels of capital intensity compared t o these industries in other
OECD countries.
12. This factor is related t o X-inefficiency (Leibenstein, I966), which are efficiency
differences resulting from organisational, effort and skill-related factors.
( I 996).
13. A more extensive description of data and methodology is available in Pi4at zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfe
Most industry-of-origin studies have taken the United States as the reference basis for
14. zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
productivity comparisons, partly because the United States is generally considered t o be
the productivity leader in manufacturing, and partly because the quality of its data.
There are also studies (O’Mahony, 1992; Freudenberg and Unal-Kesenci, 1994) that
have taken a European country as the basis, e.g. Germany or the United Kingdom. The
results from these various studies are generally not transi-tive, i.e. a comparison between
t w o countries may not be consistent with a comparison through a third country. This
issue is not addressed here, although recent studies have shown how transitive results
can be derived (Pilat and Prasada Rao, 1996).
IS.
The shaded figures in Table A I are based o n (adjusted) expenditure PPPs. More detail
on the adjustment factors, including the detailed distribution margins by industry, is
available in Pilat (I 996).
16. The production census data are discussed in more detail in Van Ark (forthcoming) and
in the country-specific studies quoted in that study.
Competition, Productivity and Efficiency
BIBLlOGRAPHY
ABRAMOVITZ, M. ( I 989), Thinking About Growth, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
ARK, B. Van (I993), International Comparisons of Output and Productivity, Groningen Growth
and Development Centre, Monograph Series, No. I, Groningen.
ARK, B. Van (I995), “Produccion y productividad en el sector manufacturer0 espafiol. Un
analisis comparativo I950- I 992”, lnformacion Comercial Espaiiola. La actividad empreserial
en Espaiia, No. 746, pp. 67-77, Madrid.
ARK, B. Van ( I996), “Productivity and competitiveness in manufacturing: A comparison of
Europe, Japan and the United States”, in: B. Van Ark and K. Wagner (eds.), International
Productivity Differences: Measurement and Explanations, North Holland, Amszerdam,
pp. 23-52.
ARK, B. Van (forthcoming), The Economics of Convergence - A Comparative Analysis of Industrial
zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
Edward Elgar, Aldershot.
Productivity since I 950,
ARK, B. Van and E. MONNIKHOF (I996), “Size distribution of output and employment: A
data set for manufacturing industries in five OECD countries, 1960s- I990”, OECD Economics Department Working Paper, No. 166, Paris.
ARK, B. Van, and D. PILAT (I993), “Productivity Levels in Germany, Japan and the United
States: differences and causes”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics,
N o 2, December, pp. 1-48.
ARK, B. Van and K. WAGNER (eds.) ( I996), International Productivity Differences: Measurement
and Explanations, North Holland, Amsterdam.
BAILY, M.N. ( l993), “Competition, regulation and efficiency in service industries”, Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics, No. 2, December, pp. 7 I - 130.
BAILY, M. and H. GERSBACH (I 995), “Efficiency in manufacturing and the need for global
competition”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics, pp. 307-358.
BLADES, D. (I993), “Comparing capital stocks”, in: A. Szirmai, B. Van Ark and D.Pilae (eds.),
Explaining Economic Growth, North Holland, Amsterdam, pp. 399-409.
Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) (I995), “Output per Hour, Hourly Compensation, and Unit
Labor Costs in Manufacturing - Indexes, 1950- I993”, Office of Productivity and Technology, Washington, DC.
CAVES, R.E. et al. (I 992), Industrial Efficiency in Six Nations, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.
CAVES, R.E. and D.R. BARTON (1990), Efficiency in U.S. Manufacturing Industries, MIT Press,
Cambridge.
143/
OECD Economic Studies No. 2 7, I996I11
COE, D.T. and E. HELPMAN ( I 995), “International R&D spillovers”, European Economic
Review 39, pp. 859-887.
EATON, J. AND S. KORTUM ( I 995a), “Trade in ideas: patenting and productivity in the
OECD”, NBER Working Paper No. 5049, Cambridge MA.
EATON, J. and S. KORTUM ( I 995b), “Engines of growth: domestic and foreign sources of
innovation”, NBER Working Paper No. 5207, Cambridge MA.
ENGLANDER, S. and A. GURNEY ( I 994), “OECD productivity growth: medium-term
trends”, OECD Economic Studies, No. 22, Spring, pp. I I I- 129.
ENGLANDER, S. and A. GURNEY ( I 994a), “Medium-term determinants of OECD productivity”, OECD Economic Studies, No. 22, Spring, pp. 49- 109.
European Commission (EC) ( I993), Retailing in the European Single Market 1993, Brussek.
FECHER, F. and S. PERELMAN ( I992), “Productivity growth and technical efficiency in OECD
industrial activities”, in Caves ( I 992), pp. 459-488.
FREUDENBERG, M. and D. UNAL-KESENCI ( I 994), “France-Allemagne : prix et productivite
dans le secteur manufacturier”, €conomie Internationale, No. 60, 4e trimestre I 994,
pp. 33-70.
GERSBACH, H. and B. VAN ARK ( I 995), “Micro foundations for international productivity
comparisons”, Research Memorandum, No. 572, Institute of Economic Research, University of Groningen.
HARRIS, R.G., M.CAVE, T. NAMBU, H. TSUBOUCHI and F. KUROSAWA ( I 995), “International comparison of privatization and deregulation among the USA, the UK and Japan
- Volume I: Telecommunications”, The Keizai Bunseki, No. I4 I , December, Tokyo.
HASKEL, J. ( I 99 I), “Imperfect competition, work practices and productivity growth”, Oxford
Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 53, No. 3, pp. 265-279.
HOOPER, P. and E. VRANKOVICH ( 1995), “International comparisons of the levels of unit
labor costs in manufacturing”, International Finance Discussion Papers, No. 527, Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington D.C.
H0J,J., T. KATO and D. PILAT ( I 996), “Deregulation and privatisation in the service sector”,
OECD Economic Studies, No. 25, 1995/11, pp. 37-74, Paris.
JORGENSON, D.W. and M. KURODA ( I992), “Productivity and international competitiveness in Japan and the United States, 1960-1985 ”, Economic Studies Quarterly, Vol. 43,
December, pp. 3 13-325.
KLEIJWEG, A.J.M. and M.H.C. LEVER (I994), “Entry and exit in Dutch manufacturing industries”, EIM Research Report, No. 9409.
KURODA, M. ( I 996), “International competitiveness and Japanese industries”, in B. Van Ark
and K. Wagner (eds.), International Productivity Differences: Measurement and Explanations,
North Holland, Amsterdam, pp. 107- I4 I.
LEIBENSTEIN, H. ( I966), “Allocative efficiency vs. X-efficiency”, American Economic Review,
Vol. 56, pp. 392-415.
MADDISON, A. ( I 993), “5tandardised estimates of fixed capital stocks: a six country comparison”, lnnovazione e Materie Prime, April.
Competition, Productivity and Eficiency zyxwvuts
Management and Coordination Agency (I989/90 and I993/94), japan Statistical Yearbook,
Statistics Bureau, Tokyo.
MAYES, D., C. HARRIS and M. LANSBURY (1994), lnefficiency in Industry, Harvester
Wheatsheaf, New York.
McKinsey ( I 992), Service Sector Productivity, McKinsey Global Institute, Washington D.C.
McKinsey ( I 993), Manufacturing Productivity, McKinsey Global Institute, Washington D.C.
McKinsey ( I 994), Employment Performance, McKinsey Global Institute, Washington D.C.
McKinsey ( I995), Sweden’s Economic Performance, McKinsey Global Institute, Stockholm.
NICKELL, zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
S.J. ( I 996), “Competition and Corporate Performance”, journal of Political Economy,
Vol. 104, NO. 4, pp. 724-746.
OECD ( I987), Purchasing Power Parities and Real Expenditures, 1985, Paris.
OECD ( I990), Competition Policy and the Deregulation of Road Transport, Paris.
OECD ( I993), Purchasing Power Parities and Real Expenditures, 1990, Vol. 2, GK Results, Paris.
OECD ( I994), Assessing Structural Reform: Lessons for the future, Paris.
OECD ( I995), “Structural Change and Employment: Empirical Evidence for 8 OECD Countries, STI Review, No. 15, pp. 133-175.
OECD ( I995a), The OECD STAN Database for Industrial Analysis, 1974- 1993, Paris.
OECD (I995b), Communications Outlook, Paris.
OECD ( I995c), “Regulatory reform, market access and international contestability of markets
- analytical framework”, TD/TCNVP(95)87, Paris.
OECD (I995d), The OECD ANBERD Datbase, Paris.
OECD ( I996), Technology, Productivity and job Creation, Paris.
OECD (I996a), Purchasing Power Parities and Real Expenditures, 1993, Vol. I, EKS Results, Paris.
OECD ( I996b), Indicators of Government Assistance, Paris.
OECDllEA (I995), Electricity Information - 1994, Paris.
O’MAHONY ( I992), “Productivity levels in British and German manufacturing industry”,
National Institute Economic Review, Number 139, February, pp. 46-63.
OLIVEIRA MARTINS, I., S. SCARPETTA and D. PILAT (I997), “Mark-up pricing, market
structure and the business cycle”, OECD Economic Studies, No. 27, Vol. 1996/11, OECD,
Paris.
PAIGE, D. and G. BOMBACH (I959), A Comparison of National Output and Productivity, OEEC,
Paris.
PERA, A. (I989), “Deregulation and privatization in an economy-wide context”, OECD Economic Studies, No. 12, Spring, pp. 159-204.
PERELMAN,
S. (I995), “R&D, technological progress and efficiency change in industrial
activities”, Review of Income and Wealth, 4 I, pp. 349-366.
PERELMAN, S. and P. PESTIEAU (1994), “A Comparative performance study of postal
services: A productive efficiency approach”, Annales d’€conomie et de Sfatistique, No. 33,
pp. 187-202.
4
OECD Economic Studies No. 2 7, I996111 zyxwvutsrqponmlkjihgfedcbaZYXWVUTSRQPONMLKJIHGFEDCBA
PERES LOPES, L.M.
(I 994), “Manufacturing productivity in Portugal in a comparative perspec-
tive”, Notas Economicas, No. 4, Universidade de Coimbra.
PESTIEAU, P. ( I993), “Performance and competition in services”, in Market Services and
European Integration, European Economy, No. 3, pp. 125- 148.
PILAT, D. ( I996), “Labour productivity levels in OECD Countries: estimates for manufacturing and selected service sectors”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 169,
OECD, Paris.
PILAT, D. and D.S. PRASADA R A 0 (I 996), “Multilateral comparisons of output, productivity
and purchasing power parities in manufacturing”, Review of Income and Weakh, Vol. 42,
NO. 2, pp. I 13- 130.
SALTER, W.E.G. ( I966), Productivity and Technical Change, Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge.
SCHWALBACH, J. ( I99 I), “Entry, Exit Concentration and Market Contestability”, in
P. Geroski and J. Schwalbach (eds.), Entry and Market Contestability, Basil Blackwell,
Oxford.
SHARPE, A. ( I 995), “International perspectives on productivity and efficiency”, Review of
Income and Wealth, Vol. 41, No. 2, June, pp. 221-237.
STEEDMAN, H. and K-WAGNER (I 989), “Productivity, machinery and skills: clothing manufacture in Britain and Germany”, National Institute Economic Review, No. 128.
SYMEONIDES, G. (I 997), “Innovation, firm size and market structure: Schumpeterian
Hypotheses and Some New Themes”, OECD Economic Studies, No. 27, Vol. 1996111,
OECD, Paris (forthcoming).
WINSTON, C. ( I993), “Economic deregulation: days of reckoning for microeconomists”,
journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXI, September, pp. 1263- 1289.