Journal of Comparative Economics 27, 131–149 (1999)
Article ID jcec.1998.1562, available online at http://www.idealibrary.com on
Prices in the Two Germanies*
Erik Dietzenbacher 1
University of Groningen, P.O. Box 800, NL-9700 AV Groningen, The Netherlands
E-mail: E.Dietzenbacher@eco.rug.nl
and
Hans-Jürgen Wagener
Frankfurt Institute for Transformation Studies, Europa–Universität Viadrina, P.O. Box 776,
D-15207 Frankfurt/Oder, Germany
Received October 14, 1997, revised October 19, 1998
Dietzenbacher, Erik, and Wagener, Hans-Jürgen—Prices in the Two Germanies
Comparative evaluations across economic systems are often hampered by the typical
valuation problem, that is, market prices have a different meaning than planned prices.
This paper considers prices in the two Germanies and the widely accepted hypothesis that
East German prices did not reflect relative scarcities as well as did West German prices.
To test this hypothesis empirically, Seton’s eigenprices are adopted as the standard of
valuation. On the whole, the hypothesis is rejected in the sense that West German prices
deviated from this standard of valuation by just as much as did East German prices. Closer
inspection of the prices at the sectoral level provides an explanation for this unexpected
result. J. Comp. Econom., March 1999, 27(1), pp. 131–149. University of Groningen, P.O.
Box 800, NL-9700 AV Groningen, The Netherlands; and Frankfurt Institute for Transformation Studies, Europa–Universität Viadrina, P.O. Box 776, D-15207 Frankfurt/Oder,
Germany © 1999 Academic Press
Key Words: prices; economic systems; Germany; transformation.
Journal of Economic Literature Classification Numbers: P51, D46, C67.
1. INTRODUCTION
Since the collapse of the communist planned economies a large amount of
information and data has become available. This would seem to allow an
* We thank two anonymous referees and the Editor of this journal for their helpful comments and
suggestions.
1
To whom correspondence should be addressed. Fax: 131 50 363 3720.
131
0147-5967/99 $30.00
Copyright © 1999 by Academic Press
All rights of reproduction in any form reserved.
132
DIETZENBACHER AND WAGENER
assessment of the real comparative performance of market and centrally planned
economies in the years preceding the collapse. The case of the two Germanies
seems to be a model case for comparative evaluation, because a culturally and
economically fairly homogeneous nation was split into two. West Germany, i.e.,
the former Federal Republic of Germany, FRG, pursued capitalism, while East
Germany, i.e., the former German Democratic Republic, GDR, created a communist economic system. After 40 years of separate development, the socialist
eastern part was in a desperate economic state and its political system collapsed.
The nation was reunified and the western part accepted the task of recapitalizing
the east. Comparative national accounting should now help to explain what
happened.
Unfortunately, comparative evaluations across economic systems are hampered by the typical valuation problem. That is, prices serve widely different
functions in market economies and in centrally planned economies and they are
formed by different methods. Yet, in both systems, prices are used to construct
aggregate indicators. These are difficult to interpret if we do not have information
on the precise nature of the prices that were used. Therefore, comparisons across
economic systems on the basis of such indicators must be treated with caution.
In Germany, the question of whether or not the database necessary for such
comparisons can be reconstructed from the statistical material that has become
available (Statistisches Bundesamt, 1993) has been hotly debated. The stumbling
block recurrent in the arguments is the use of prices. “The dilemma of valuation
cannot be solved. This is so because a planned economy, other than a market
economy, has no logically consistent system of valuation” (Utzig 1993, p. 9; our
translation). If this statement is interpreted as asserting that prices in a planned
economy are arbitrarily set exchange ratios without any relation to relative
scarcities or economic valuations and capitalist market prices are close to
equilibrium levels, it is a hypothesis in need of empirical testing on both sides of
the wall.
The hypothesis has been widely accepted, although its empirical verification
has not been attempted. A plausible explanation for this omission may be that all
problems with distorted GDR prices were believed to be circumvented by
reconstructing East German statistical aggregates using rational West German
prices. This is an economically meaningless exercise because a different set of
prices would have implied a different set of quantities (Lützel, 1993, p. 75). The
fact that exactly the same procedure is frequently applied without hesitation
when prices of a different base year are used in order to make comparisons over
time provides no vindication.
This paper attempts to test the hypothesis that West German prices reflected
relative scarcities much better than did East German prices. To do so, we need
a set of prices derived from a logically consistent system of valuation that can
serve as a standard of evaluation. In order to assess the degree of distortion from
this standard, it makes no sense to measure the deviation of East German prices
PRICES IN THE TWO GERMANIES
133
TABLE 1
Original Input–Output Table
Z
V
t*
y
—
—
x*
y
x
v
t
from West German prices. A theoretically more satisfactory method should use
the East German set of prices and quantities and the West German set of prices
and quantities separately and see how much they deviate from a normative
standard.
To this end, we adopt Seton’s eigenprices (Seton, 1985, 1992) as a systemspecific set of rational prices derived from a logically consistent process of
valuation. These prices reflect marginal revenue products and marginal costs;
thus, they fulfill the equilibrium criteria for logically equivalent solutions in the
cases of perfect competition and perfect planning. Seton’s eigenprices have been
used to evaluate pricing behavior in different economies and different economic
systems. The calculations have shown, in most cases, that communistadministered pricing leads to considerably greater distortions than pricing in
capitalist competitive systems (Seton, 1985; Steenge, 1985). In the following
section, the model of eigenprices is discussed briefly. Section 3 presents the data.
Section 4 contains the results and Section 5 presents the conclusions.
2. THE CONCEPT OF EIGENPRICES
In this section, we discuss briefly the concept of eigenprices (Seton, 1981,
1982, 1985, 1989, 1992), which is based on two transformations. First, factor
prices are transformed into product prices following the typical price calculations
in input– output analysis. 2 Second, by specifying the distribution of income to the
primary factors, factor prices are determined from product prices. 3 Combining
these two transformations yields an eigensystem from which the prices are solved
as eigenvectors.
Consider an economy with n production sectors and m primary factors. Our
starting point is the input– output table (Table 1). Z is the n 3 n matrix of
intermediate deliveries; its typical element z ij denotes how much of product i is
bought by sector j, to be used as an intermediate input. y is the n 3 1 vector of
2
For example, see Miller and Blair (1985, pp. 351–357). Generalizations, which are based on the
same considerations, include two- and three-channel prices (Bródy, 1970, Sekerka et al., 1970,
Brown and Licari, 1977, Seton, 1977, 1993, and Fink, 1981).
3
In deriving the second transformation we follow an approach that differs from Seton’s.
134
DIETZENBACHER AND WAGENER
final demands; its typical element y i denotes the purchases of product i for final
use purposes, i.e., for private and government consumption, investment, and
exports. x is the n 3 1 output vector; its typical element x i denotes the value of
the output of product i. V is the m 3 n matrix of factor inputs, including imports;
its typical element v kj denotes the payments of sector j for the use of factor k. t*
is the 1 3 n row vector of surpluses (t j ). 4 Such a surplus may consist of indirect
taxes, subsidies, and certain profits as parts of the operating surplus. When
countries with different economic systems are compared, the exact contents of
the surplus row will be different. Therefore, it is obtained as a residual row. The
corresponding totals are denoted as y 5 e9n y, t 5 t*e n and v 5 Ve n , where e n is
the n 3 1 summation vector, i.e., e9n 5 (1, . . . , 1).
It should be noted that all entries in the input– output table record transactions
in money terms, e.g., millions of German marks. Prices, however, depend on the
measurement of physical flows, which cannot be obtained from the observed
data. This adds to the usual problem of measuring the output of service sectors
and the inputs of capital and heterogeneous labor. In order to circumvent the
problem of unavailable physical data, it is common practice to interpret these
entries in physical terms. This can be established by setting each current price
equal to one. Implicitly, this means that the physical units of measurement are
chosen so that the current price of one unit of product i, or one unit of factor k,
equals 1. In what follows, we derive the eigenprices p i for the products and f k for
the factors, according to a well-defined equilibrium concept. An eigenprice p i 5
1.2, for example, indicates that the equilibrium price is 20% higher than the
current price.
For a given situation as described by the input– output table, eigenprices are
the prices that would occur if the sectoral surpluses were obtained according to
a uniform rate t, which is called the eigensurplus ratio. Note that it is explicitly
assumed that all quantities remain fixed. It is our aim to analyze the effects of this
change on the prices, given the current physical structure of the economy as
reflected by Table 1. Applying the new prices p i and f k to the quantities in Table
1 and using s* for the new surplus row yields a new, revalued input– output table
(Table 2). The sectoral surpluses s j are obtained as a share t of the primary factor
costs. That is, s j 5 t ( f 1 v 1j 1 . . . 1 f k v kj ), or s* 5 tf*V using matrix notation.
Column j in Table 2 now yields p j x j 5 ¥ i p i z ij 1 ¥ k f k v kj 1 s j 5 ¥ i p i z ij 1 (1 1
t )¥ k f k v kj . Dividing both sides by x j and using the common definitions for input
coefficients, i.e., a ij [ z ij /x j and b kj [ v kj /x j , 5 gives the price per unit of product
j (5 1, . . . , n) as p j 5 ¥ i p i a ij 1 (1 1 t )¥ k f k b kj . In matrix notation,
4
Vectors are by definition column vectors. A prime is used to denote transposition, so that t* is a
row vector.
5
The coefficient a ij gives the input of product i required per unit of output of product j and b kj
gives the input of factor k required per unit of output of product j. Note that the coefficient matrices
A and B are calculated from Table 1, which is given.
PRICES IN THE TWO GERMANIES
135
TABLE 2
Revalued Input–Output Table
p̂Z
f̂V
s*
p̂y
—
—
p*x̂
p*y
p* 5 p*A 1 ~1 1 t !f*B.
p̂x
f̂v
s
(1)
This equation may be rewritten as
p* 5 ~1 1 t !f*C ,
with C ; B~I 2 A! 21 .
(2)
Equation (2) describes how the product prices are obtained from the factor prices
and the uniform eigensurplus ratio. In order to derive a similar, but reversed,
transformation we first consider the quantity side of the model.
Using the definitions for the input matrices A [ Zx̂ 21 and B [ Vx̂ 21, it follows
that the first n rows of Table 1 may be written as x 5 Ax 1 y or x 5 (I 2 A) 21y.
The typical element (i, j) of the matrix (I 2 A) 21 describes how much of product
i needs to be produced in order to satisfy a final demand of one unit of product
j. For the next k rows, describing the factor use, in Table 1 we have v 5 Bx 5
B(I 2 A) 21y 5 Cy. So the element c kj denotes the total amount of factor k that
is required for one unit of final demand for product j.
The elements c kj are now used to distribute the income to the factors. Product
j is sold on the market for final products at a price p j and in the amount y j , thus
generating p j y j as income in sector j. Satisfying a final demand of y j units of
product j requires c kj y j units of factor k. In distributing p j y j , each factor k is
rewarded according to its own contribution to p j y j . 6 This yields c kj p j y j for factor
k (5 1, . . . , m). Note that the remainder, p j y j (1 2 ¥ k c kj ), is allocated to
surpluses. The total receipts of factor k are obtained by summing over j, so as to
yield ¥ j c kj p j y j . Dividing this value by the total number ( v k ) of units of factor k
that is used provides the factor price f k . Thus, f k 5 ¥ j p j c kj y j / v k , or in matrix
notation,
f* 5 p*N,
with N ; ŷC*v̂ 21 .
(3)
Equation (3) shows how factor prices are obtained from product prices. Combining Eqs. (2) and (3) yields
6
Although this distribution seems appropriate, it is not the only possibility (Fink, 1982). Other
types of income distribution lead to different equilibrium prices but these may create difficulties with
the empirical implementation and/or computation.
136
DIETZENBACHER AND WAGENER
~1/1 1 t !p* 5 p*NC
and ~1/1 1 t !f* 5 f*CN.
(4)
The vector p* of eigenprices for the products is calculated as the left eigenvector
corresponding to the dominant eigenvalue 1/1 1 t of the matrix NC. The
eigenprices for the factors are then obtained from Eq. (3) as f* 5 p*N. 7 Since
eigenvectors are only unique up to a scalar multiple, a scaling technique is
required to obtain the final results. We adopt Seton’s scaling procedure in which
product prices are chosen such that the total value of final demand, which equals
GDP for the case of a closed economy, remains constant. That is,
p*y 5 e9n y
or
O p y 5 O y 5 y.
i i i
i i
(5)
A consequence of scaling Eq. (5) is that the product prices are on average equal
to 1, which reflects their current price. This does not necessarily hold for the
factor prices, however. Suppose that the rate t turns out to be lower than the
overall surplus rate t/e9m v 5 t/( y 2 t) in Table 1. Using v 5 Cy and Eqs. (2)
and (5), we have f*v 5 f*Cy 5 p*y/(1 1 t ) 5 y/(1 1 t ) 5 (t 1 e9m v)/(1 1
t ) . e9m v. Hence, t , t/( y 2 t) if and only if f*v . e9m v, implying that the
weighted average of the factor prices is larger than 1.
Eigenprices require that the surplus be distributed according to a uniform
ratio. 8 This eigensurplus ratio t can be interpreted as an overall measure for the
discrepancy between prices and the real costs of production, i.e., in terms of the
payments for the factors. It is easily seen that the row s* in Table 2 vanishes
completely if factor prices become (1 1 t ) f k instead of f k . In other words, if all
surpluses were redistributed to the primary factors, the factor prices f k could be
increased by 100t%, given the same product prices p i . Equivalently, leaving the
factor prices f k the same, the product prices p i could be decreased by 100(t/1 1
t)% to become (1/1 1 t ) p i , to cover exactly the costs of the primary factors.
In an empirical comparison between countries or between points in time, a
larger eigensurplus ratio t indicates that a smaller part of the product price pays
for the primary costs of production (see, for instance, Dietzenbacher and Steenge,
1985, or Steenge, 1985). This endogenously determined parameter t is inherent
or eigen 9 for the economy under consideration. The numerical values for the
prices p i and f k indicate whether the current prices are more or less consistent
with the framework of a uniform distribution of the country’s eigensurplus.
Consider an economy in which prices are determined by markets and an
economy in which prices are set by the planning authorities. Suppose that, in the
7
An alternative procedure, which yields the same results, computes f* as the left eigenvector
corresponding to the dominant eigenvalue 1/1 1 t of the matrix CN after which p* is obtained from
(2) as p* 5 (1 1 t)f*C.
8
Dietzenbacher (1990) discusses the case where this ratio does not need to be uniform but is
allowed to be sector-specific. This leads to generalized eigenprices.
9
“Eigen” in German and Dutch means “own” or “characteristic.”
PRICES IN THE TWO GERMANIES
137
first economy, some markets are characterized by strong competition that drives
profits to zero while, in a few other markets, monopolistic forces prevail. On
average, the overall surplus is modest so that t will be relatively close to zero.
The eigenprices, however, may be expected to differ from the current prices. In
order to force the system into a uniform distribution of the surplus, prices on
competitive markets will rise, i.e., p i . 1, and those on monopolistic markets
will fall, i.e., p j , 1. For the centrally planned economy, suppose that a
substantial part of the production costs is spent on the maintenance of the
government body. This will result in a positive value for t. If the planning
authorities set the product prices more or less equal to the costs plus a uniform
markup to account for the government, we will find that p i ' 1 and f k ' 1. On
the other hand, if the planning authorities decide that basic needs ought to be
cheap while luxury goods should be expensive, we will find p i . 1 for basic
needs and p j , 1 for luxury goods.
As the model shows, eigenprices are standardized so that they can be compared directly with actual prices. An eigenprice below unity indicates the overvaluation of the respective product. The cause may be monopolistic practices,
special taxes, levies, and tariffs, or random errors of the planner. An eigenprice
above unity signals the opposite distortion caused usually by a severe form of
overcompetition, subsidies, or, again, planners’ errors. It should be borne in
mind, however, that a difference between eigenprices and actual prices may also
indicate a distortion in the quantity system. It was assumed that the quantity
system behind a given input– output table reflects valuations and constraints
characteristic of the economy in its current state. An eigenprice above 1,
indicating undervaluation of a given commodity, thus may also reflect the fact
that the domestic production of this commodity uses too many resources compared either to its domestic substitutes or to production by international competitors.
3. THE DATA
The starting point for calculating eigenprices is comparable input– output
tables. Major difficulties arise because national accounting differed fundamentally between the two economic systems. We mention a few of the most serious
differences. First, West German national accounting followed the System of
National Accounts concept while East German national accounting followed the
Material Product System concept, which allocated nonmaterial services to the
sphere of consumption (United Nations, 1977, or Boda and Stäglin, 1990).
Second, prices in both systems were influenced by government policy. In the
west, market prices reflected taxes and subsidies and only in rare cases, e.g.,
public transport, were they directly set by political authorities. In the east, price
setting was the responsibility of the central planner who, in principle, followed
simple cost-plus pricing rules. However, costs were influenced by intricate
138
DIETZENBACHER AND WAGENER
TABLE 3
Domestic Production a
Zd
L
m*
Yd
—
—
x9d
e958Y d
xd
Le 58
m*e 58
a
Z d , domestic intermediate deliveries (a 58 3 58 matrix); Y d , final use of domestic production (a
58 3 5 matrix); x d , total domestic production (a 58 3 1 vector); L, primary cost categories (a 5 3
58 matrix); and m*, imports of intermediate goods by productive sectors (a 1 3 58 vector).
financial flows, i.e., charges and subsidies, which were meant to supplement the
quantity planning system. End-user prices thus became an instrument of economic policy that was used extensively in the sphere of consumer goods.
Third, in a market system, economic data are confidential at the firm level.
This difficulty may be overcome by laws on statistical reporting. However, in a
planned system, some data were confidential at the national level. In the GDR,
authorities were reticent to publish data on true economic performance and even
tried to give an unrealistically positive picture of the economic state of affairs.
Due to the continuous need for hard currency credit, foreign trade statistics were
notorious for this manipulation and balance of payments statistics have never
been published. This led observers to argue that data were falsified. Most
specialists, however, share the opinion that basic statistical material in the GDR
reflects the true situation of the economy and can be used for empirical purposes
(Kockel, 1992).
It is a cumbersome task to make East and West German input– output tables
comparable or, in particular, to rearrange and recalculate the East German table
according to West German standards. Ludwig and Stäglin (1993) prepared a
GDR table for 1987 having 58 sectors, which includes a table of imports and
which can be compared to the West German input– output table. The Statistisches
Bundesamt publishes FRG tables for even years. For the purpose of comparison,
it has also provided a table for 1987 which, however, is less detailed with respect
TABLE 4
Imports a
a
Zm
Ym
m*
e958Y m
xm
Z m , import of commodity i by sector j (a 58 3 58 matrix); Y m , import for final use (a 58 3 5
matrix); and x m , total imports (a 58 3 1 vector).
PRICES IN THE TWO GERMANIES
139
TABLE 5
Domestic Production and Imports
Zd 1 Zm
L
x9m
Yd 1 Ym
—
—
x9d 1 x9m
e958(Y d 1 Y m )
xd 1 xm
Le 58
x9m e 58
to imports. Therefore, we are using the 1987 table of East Germany and the 1988
table of West Germany (Statistisches Bundesamt, 1994) as the basic material for
the computation of eigenprices.
In open economies, foreign trade causes difficulties in the construction of
input– output tables. While exports are an element of final use, imports can be
treated in different ways. Tables 3–5 are usually available and the format is
indicated in brackets.
Input– output analysis and the concept of eigenprices start from the idea that
the production structure is described by input coefficients. These are obtained by
dividing each element of a column in the Z matrix by its corresponding column
total. Looking at Table 3, an obvious problem arises. Input coefficients reflect
only domestically produced inputs, imports are treated as a primary factor of
production. It makes technologically little sense to differentiate between domestically produced and imported steel for the production of cars, and to compute
input coefficients by relating domestic total car production to the use of domestically produced steel, since steel is assumed to be a homogeneous product. Table
5 does not resolve the issue. Indeed, the Z matrix now reflects total inputs and can
be interpreted in a technologically meaningful way. However, the row and
column sums do not represent production, but domestic production plus total
imports. A nonnegligible part of imports goes directly into final use. Therefore,
the input coefficients are distorted in this case also.
The only compromise possible, given the data of Tables 3–5, is Table 6, which
has Z d 1 Z m as its Z matrix but excludes all imports that are not used as
intermediate products. In Table 6, x mp is the vector of imports that are used in the
TABLE 6
Domestic Production with Imported Intermediate Goods
Zd 1 Zm
L
x9mp
Yd
—
—
x*d 1 x*mp
e958Y d
x d 1 x mp
Le 58
x9mp e 58
140
DIETZENBACHER AND WAGENER
TABLE 7
The Input–Output Table Used for Eigenprice Calculations
Z 5 Zd 1 Zm
V
t*
y 5 Yde5
—
—
x* 5 x9d 1 x9mp
y
x 5 x d 1 x mp
v
t
production process, or productive imports. The aggregate amount x d 1 x mp can
be interpreted as the total output necessesary to produce Y d with productive
imports included. Each sector j has a primary input (x mp ) j that supports total
production.
A second difficulty with the data set derives from the difference in economic
systems between West and East Germany. Usually, western input– output statistics record labor income as income from hired labor, while the income of the
self-employed, including family workers, is included in the income from entrepreneurial activities and capital. This is unsatisfactory, in general, but especially
so when we make comparisons with socialist economic systems. For these
systems, all labor is considered since self-employment does not exist. Hence, the
published figures for labor income represent total labor income. In order to make
the necessary corrections for West Germany, we followed the method of Bedau
and Klatt (1992). We calculate the average income of hired labor, multiply it by
the number of self-employed, including family workers, and add this amount to
the row of income from hired labor. The necessary data can be found in
Statistisches Bundesamt (1994, p. 316). Thus, we obtain rows for labor input and
capital input that are fairly representative and comparable. Lack of separate data
for self-employed persons in sectors 51, i.e., services of renting buildings and
lodgings, and 55, i.e., other market-determined services, made it necessary to
aggregate the two.
A final remark on the data concerns the services of banks, i.e., sector 49, which
are a notorious problem in input– output tables. The most important product of
banks is interest margins, for which it is not clear who is the end user of the
concomitant services. Hence, these are recorded as deliveries to the sector itself.
In fact, the input– output data of this sector cannot be interpreted in any meaningful way. We follow the usual practice of not making an attempt to do so.
4. THE RESULTS
The concept of eigenprices was discussed using Table 1 and the actual data
underlying our empirical results were presented as Table 6. For the sake of
clarity, both tables are integrated in Table 7.
The matrix V records the following three rows; labor, capital, i.e., deprecia-
PRICES IN THE TWO GERMANIES
141
tions, and imports, i.e., the row x9mp in Table 6. The row t* with surpluses covers
indirect taxes minus subsidies and income from entrepreneurial activity and
capital for West Germany and a row published as “differences” for East Germany. Calculating eigenprices from Table 7 yields the results presented in Tables
8 and 9. Table 8 presents the eigenprices p i for the products, the contribution
( p i y i ) of sector i to final demand measured in eigenprices, and this contribution
as a percentage. We can now measure the overall deviance, d, as the weighted
sum of the squared sectoral deviances. This yields
d 5 D 1/ 2,
where D 5
O
iÞ49
$~ p i 2 1! 2 @ p i y i /
O
p y #%.
iÞ49 i i
Note that we have omitted sector 49, i.e., services of banks, from the overall
deviance for the reasons indicated above. Since ¥ i p i y i 5 ¥ i y i from the normalization of eigenprices, dropping sector 49 causes a small inconsistency in the
weighting scheme for which we do not correct. The results for d, based on Table
8, are d GDR 5 0.1647 and d FRG 5 0.1611. Comparing these values for overall
deviances reveals that actual prices in East Germany at the end of the 1980’s did
not deviate significantly more from eigenprices than did actual prices in West
Germany. The data do not support the hypothesis under examination. In other
words, on the whole, East German prices did not reflect relative scarcities
significantly worse than did West German prices. This is an astonishing result
because earlier calculations of eigenprices by Seton (1985) and Steenge (1985)
and other measures of price deviations by Fink (1981) always derived substantial
differences between market economies and planned economies. Indeed, one
should be careful in comparing the overall deviance between input– output tables
of different sizes. However, not all of the earlier calculations used tables with
considerably fewer sectors than we have. For example, Seton (1985, p. 116)
reports overall deviances of 0.2862 for the USSR in 1972 using a 56-sector
classification, 0.1228 for Japan in 1970 using a 60-sector table, and 0.1229 for
West Germany in 1970 based on a 44-sector classification.
Closer inspection of the eigenprices in Table 8 yields some explanation for the
surprising result. The first 8 sectors represent primary production and utilities.
Under the conditions of West German capitalism, market forces do not play a
dominant role here. Products of agriculture (sector 1) and mining (6 and 7) are
undervalued or, given their subsidized prices, use up too many resources.
Communally produced utilities, such as gas (4) and water (5), appear to be
overvalued, suggesting some monopolistic practices. This segment of total production does not exhibit significant differences between east and west, but there
is no reason that we should expect any differences. However, in sectors 9 through
40, coverering manufacturing, in which market forces should prevail, West
German pricing behavior is considerably better than that of East Germany with
few exceptions. The exceptions are petroleum products (10), ships (24), and
tobacco products (40), of which the first and the last are characterized by huge
excise taxes and the middle by state subsidies. Sectors 41 and 42, covering
142
DIETZENBACHER AND WAGENER
TABLE 8
Eigenprices for the Products a
GDR (1987)
FRG (1988)
i
pi
p iy i
%
pi
p iy i
%
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
0.8934
1.1024
1.0595
1.2478
0.8943
0.9971
0.9782
1.2647
0.8603
0.9753
0.9106
0.8300
0.8446
0.7788
0.9558
1.0592
1.1547
0.9795
0.9351
0.8263
1.0092
1.1632
1.0579
0.7417
0.9763
0.8876
0.9333
0.8118
0.8359
1.0865
0.9236
0.9505
0.7673
0.8333
0.9813
0.9371
0.9118
1.2718
0.5675
0.2004
0.9242
0.8782
0.6248
10643.8
461.9
2047.0
482.9
0.0
3969.5
1775.5
1005.5
16291.9
11702.7
1099.1
1326.3
2352.2
704.1
1708.0
5859.3
1817.4
327.2
4198.7
6635.4
35393.9
2677.7
12576.7
2256.9
153.3
21976.4
2308.0
4499.2
2431.7
637.8
6887.1
1095.9
860.2
577.5
4158.8
9452.7
7993.1
41340.6
4093.0
1054.7
20479.0
9339.1
5003.5
2.5
0.1
0.5
0.1
0.0
0.9
0.4
0.2
3.8
2.7
0.3
0.3
0.6
0.2
0.4
1.4
0.4
0.1
1.0
1.6
8.3
0.6
3.0
0.5
0.0
5.2
0.5
1.1
0.6
0.1
1.6
0.3
0.2
0.1
1.0
2.2
1.9
9.7
1.0
0.2
4.8
2.2
1.2
1.2753
1.1114
0.9923
0.8474
0.8264
1.4952
1.1776
1.1591
1.0076
0.7631
1.0104
1.0626
0.9625
1.0986
1.0156
1.1124
1.1302
1.0904
1.0055
1.0469
1.0770
1.0435
1.0646
1.1825
1.0649
1.0633
0.9829
1.0260
0.9262
1.1414
1.0668
1.0788
1.0251
1.0023
1.0905
1.0783
1.0341
1.0943
0.8965
0.2670
1.0125
0.9149
0.9515
15138.1
2499.6
24884.9
6073.1
13.2
2329.6
997.4
139.1
86116.8
19510.4
17698.5
7334.0
6529.3
2772.9
4273.8
20357.3
12518.3
2236.4
13111.8
19051.9
134751.0
18340.8
176061.7
4384.6
5600.4
105603.8
14029.3
27630.3
7094.4
2260.0
30763.9
7244.2
7516.1
2476.7
6764.7
19624.4
22599.3
117905.9
15306.9
4830.7
115258.8
56523.6
71086.9
0.7
0.1
1.1
0.3
0.0
0.1
0.0
0.0
3.9
0.9
0.8
0.3
0.3
0.1
0.2
0.9
0.6
0.1
0.6
0.9
6.1
0.8
7.9
0.2
0.3
4.8
0.6
1.2
0.3
0.1
1.4
0.3
0.3
0.1
0.3
0.9
1.0
5.3
0.7
0.2
5.2
2.6
3.2
PRICES IN THE TWO GERMANIES
143
TABLE 8—Continued
GDR (1987)
i
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
51155
52
53
54
56
57
58
Total
a
FRG (1988)
pi
p iy i
%
pi
p iy i
%
1.0359
1.1166
1.0351
1.1929
1.0661
3.3617
0.2905
1.0294
1.0690
0.7722
0.6657
1.1933
1.0913
1.2761
9395.0
7834.9
4326.6
1984.9
7732.3
463.9
336.5
8746.7
16401.9
2468.6
289.6
73262.9
13197.2
8264.1
2.2
1.8
1.0
0.5
1.8
—
0.1
2.1
3.9
0.6
0.1
17.2
3.1
1.9
1.0456
2.0122
1.0911
0.9788
0.9710
4.5773
0.8037
0.6006
1.0272
1.0358
0.7354
1.1332
0.9489
1.1530
126970.2
13833.6
8784.5
26341.6
44350.5
40770.4
23552.0
146411.6
39842.3
33958.4
11141.7
330319.5
132737.8
40377.1
5.7
0.6
0.4
1.2
2.0
—
1.1
6.6
1.8
1.5
0.5
14.9
6.0
1.8
426360
100
2256636
100
The sectoral classification is given in the Appendix.
construction, indicate that West German performance is slightly better than East
German. The rest of the sectors are services. If we neglect banks (49), the major
deviations from unity in the west are rail transport (45), which is notorious for not
covering its costs, and the aggregate of sectors 51 (renting of structures and
lodgings) and 55 (other market determined services), which appears to be heavily
overpriced with significant consequences for the overall deviance because of its
weight of about 7% in West Germany. In these sectors the indicated overvaluation or underutilization of resources is due partly to incorrect capital stock
estimates of houses and buildings, which constitute a major part of total national
wealth. Also, the last 4 sectors representing health care, public authorities, and
nonprofit organizations have a rather large weight but no scarcity-led pricing
practice.
To sum up, the unexpected similarity of the overall deviance between actual
prices and eigenprices in East and West Germany does not warrant the conclusion that East German pricing was not so bad after all because it was guided,
more or less, by relative scarcities. In those sectors where market forces prevail
in the west, East German actual prices deviate significantly more from eigenprices. However, the similarity of the overall indicator testifies to the fact that a
sizeable part of West German GNP is not produced under competitive market
conditions. Obviously this is the case in sectors with predominant public ownership rights and strong government influence. This is a positive, not a normative,
statement.
144
DIETZENBACHER AND WAGENER
TABLE 9
Further Results
Eigensurplus ratio t
Eigenprices f k
Labor
Capital
Import
Actual cost ratio t/(y 2 t)
Rescaled eigenprices f̃ k
Labor
Capital
Import
GDR (1987)
FRG (1988)
0.3687
0.1497
1.0587
1.0306
1.0105
0.4178
1.1038
1.0285
1.0313
0.2433
1.0220
0.9949
0.9755
1.0206
0.9510
0.9536
The upper part of Table 9 reports the eigensurplus ratio and the eigenprices for
the factors. As far as the eigensurplus ratio t is concerned, the West German
system is expected to exhibit a smaller t than the East German system because
we cannot compute eigenprices net of direct taxes and West Germany relies
much more upon direct taxes than did East Germany. The eigensurplus ratio t
represents, to some extent, the monopoly charge or value-added tax that an
external authority, i.e., the government, is able to impose upon the system. If
many of the taxes and levies are indirect, this charge will be higher than when
direct taxes form a major share of total taxes.
The results confirm this hypothesis. By implication, we see that a much larger
share of total revenue accrues to productive factors in West Germany. Alternatively, in East Germany, the system managers, i.e., the government and the
central planners, can dispose directly of a larger share of total product. This
leaves aside direct taxes and the fact that in East Germany the government as
owner of productive capital has a claim on capital rentals, which, as a rule, they
extracted from the enterprises and added to the state budget. However, consumption need not be relatively smaller in the east than in the west because the
government can use the extracted surplus for any purpose. In East Germany, the
subsidization of consumer prices and housing rents was extreme and we note that
eigenprices were calculated from input– output tables in producer prices. On the
other hand, a smaller share of total product was subject to the competitive regime
or, in Marxist terminology, to commodity–money relations in the East.
Our system employs three primary factors of production, labor, capital, and
imports. Their eigenprices ( f k ) are proportional to the factors’ productive contribution, i.e., its marginal revenue product. As we stated already in Section 2, the
weighted average of the factor rentals need not be equal to 1. In both cases, all
eigenprices of factors are greater than 1, which cannot be interpreted as undervaluation of factors of production.
PRICES IN THE TWO GERMANIES
145
In explaining these large values for the factor eigenprices, recall from Section
2 that f*v . e9m v if and only if t , t/( y 2 t). Eigenprices are computed so as
to distribute the surplus according to a uniform ratio. Factor payments as a share
of total final demand amount to 1/1 1 t when eigenprices are used and to 1 2
(t/y) in the actually observed input– output table. So, t , t/( y 2 t) implies
1/1 1 t . 1 2 (t/y), indicating that a larger share of total final demand is
available for factor payments. Thus, in comparing the eigenprices ( f k ) for the
factors with their current prices, i.e., 1, a comparison of t with t/( y 2 t) is
implicitly involved. For East Germany, we find that t 5 36.87% and t/( y 2 t)
5 41.78%; for West Germany we have t 5 14.97% and t/( y 2 t) 5 24.33%.
Note that the eigenprices indicate that the gap between t and t/( y 2 t) is larger
for West Germany than for East Germany, in the sense that the deviation from
unity is larger.
To allow for a proper comparison in terms of under- or overvaluation, we use
rescaled eigenprices (f̃ k ) for factors. These are obtained from the eigenprices by
applying a correction for the change in the total factor payments as a share of
total final demand, that is, f̃ k 5 f k [1 2 (t/y)](1 1 t ). These rescaled eigenprices
are on average equal to 1, i.e., f̃*v 5 e9m v. It is interesting to note that the
eigenprices ( p i ) for the products and the rescaled eigenprices (f̃ k ) for the factors
yield a uniform distribution of the current surplus t across the sectors.
The results for the rescaled eigenprices are presented in the lower part of Table
9. They indicate that labor is undervalued to a similar extent in both countries.
Capital and imports are overvalued, but significantly more in West Germany than
in East Germany.
5. CONCLUSION
Eigenprices can be used as a rational standard in order to evaluate actual
pricing behavior and to compare structural data between different economic
systems. Eigenprices cannot be used to compare levels of output or income
between two systems. For such comparisons, the old index number problem
remains. Varying the assumptions and the databases for the two Germanies, the
results turned out not to be sensitive to minor changes. Eigenprices are a quite
robust standard of valuation.
Our starting hypothesis that prices in a socialist planned economy are less
rational than prices in a capitalist market economy has not been supported
unambiguously by the data for the two Germanies at the end of the 1980’s. The
reason for this rather unexpected result is revealed by closer inspection of the
calculated eigenprices. The West German economy is not a pure capitalist market
economy; rather it is a mixed economy with some sectors, mainly manufacturing,
subject to competitive market processes and others, mainly primary production
and noncommercial services, under heavy government influence. Hence, actual
146
DIETZENBACHER AND WAGENER
prices deviate significantly from a logically consistent system of valuation in the
latter case.
Regarding East German pricing behavior, our results conform more with
intuitive expectations. The process of price planning, which was interactive
between the firms, i.e., the so-called Kombinate, and the price-setting administration, did follow some uniform rules but, in the end, it resulted in major
deviations from a rational system of valuation. These deviations are distributed
more evenly over the whole profile of sectors of production than were the
deviations in West Germany. The factors causing such deviations, such as
deliberate policy choices, differences in monopoly power between individual
sectors, and planners’ errors, can be detected only after closer analysis.
How do our results apply to the reliability of using national accounting statistics
to make comparisons? First of all, calculations in eigenprices will yield more useful
comparisons over time and economic systems. If the comparisons are based on data
in actual prices, reservations are in order. However, West German data are used for
international and intertemporal comparisons without hesitation. The present study
has indicated that, by implication, East German data deserve a similar treatment
since, on the whole, they are not worse than West German data.
APPENDIX
List of the 58 Sectors of the Input–Output Table Used in This Study
1. Agricultural products
2. Forestry and fishery products, etc.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
Electric power, steam, hot water
Gas
Water
Coal, products of coal mining
Products of mining (excluding coal, crude petroleum, natural gas)
Crude petroleum, natural gas
9. Chemical products (including nuclear fuel)
10. Refined petroleum products
11. Plastic products
12. Rubber products
13. Stones and clays, building and construction materials, etc.
14. Ceramic products
15. Glass and glass products
16.
17.
18.
19.
Iron and steel
Nonferrous metals, semifinished products thereof
Foundry products
Products of drawing plants, cold rolling mills, etc.
PRICES IN THE TWO GERMANIES
20.
21.
22.
23.
24.
25.
Structural metal products, rolling stock
Machinery and equipment (excluding electrical)
Office machinery, automatic data processing equipment
Road vehicles
Ships, boats, and floating structures
Aircraft and spacecraft
26.
27.
28.
29.
Electrical machinery, equipment, and appliances
Precision and optical instruments, clocks, and watches
Tools and finished metal products
Musical instruments, games and toys, sporting goods, etc.
30.
31.
32.
33.
34.
35.
36.
37.
Wood
Wood products
Pulp, paper, and board
Products of paper and board
Products of printing and duplicating
Leather and leather products, footwear
Textiles
Wearing apparel
147
38. Food products (excluding beverages)
39. Beverages
40. Tobacco products
41. Building and civil engineering works, etc.
42. Installation and building completion works
43.
44.
45.
46.
47.
48.
Services of wholesale trade, etc., recovery
Services of retail trade
Railway services
Water transport services, services of ports, etc.
Communication services
Other transport services, n.e.c.
49.
50.
51.
52.
53.
54.
55.
Banking services
Insurance services (excluding social security funds)
Real estate renting services
Market services of hotels and restaurants, homes, and hostels
Market services of education, research, culture, and publishing services
Health and veterinary market services
Other market services, n.e.c.
56. Services of central and local government
57. Services of social security funds
58. Services of private nonprofit institutions, domestic services
148
DIETZENBACHER AND WAGENER
REFERENCES
Bedau, Klaus D., and Klatt, Helmut, Die Entwicklung der gesamtwirtschaftlichen Arbeitseinkommensquote und ihre Einflußen [The Development of the Aggregate Rate of Earned Income
and the Factors Influencing It], Discussion Paper 47. Berlin: German Institute for Economic
Research, 1992.
Boda, György, and Stäglin, Reiner, “Intersystem Comparison between the Federal Republic of
Germany and Hungary on the Basis of SNA Type and MPS Type Input–Output Tables.”
Vierteljahr. Wirschaft. 4, 363–377, 1990.
Bródy, András. Proportions, Prices and Planning. Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1970.
Brown, Alan A., and Licari, Joseph A., “Price Formation Models and Economic Efficiency.” In Alan
Abouchar, Ed., The Socialist Price Mechanism, pp. 184 –230. Durham, NC: Duke Univ. Press,
1977.
Dietzenbacher, Erik, and Steenge, Albert E., “Seton’s Eigenprices: Comparisons between Post-War
Holland and Hungary.” In Anatoli Smyshlyaev, Ed., Input–Output Modeling, pp. 237–248.
Berlin: Springer-Verlag, 1985.
Dietzenbacher, Erik, “Seton’s Eigenprices: Further Evidence.” Econ. Systems Res. 2, 2:103–123, June
1990.
Fink, Gerhard, “Price Distortions in the Austrian and in the Hungarian Economy.” Z. Nationalökon.
41, 1–2:111–132, 1981.
Fink, Gerhard, “International Comparisons with Input–Output Models.” In Reiner Stäglin, Ed.,
International Use of Input–Output Analysis, pp. 231–258. Göttingen: Vandenhoeck & Ruprecht, 1982.
Kockel, Klaus, “Ausgewählte Probleme der früheren DDR-Statistik” [Some Problems of Statistics in
the Former GDR]. Allgemeines Statistisches Archiv 76, 1:1–14, 1992.
Ludwig, Udo, and Stäglin, Reiner, “Problems in Comparing Input–Output Tables for East and West
Germany.” Econ. Systems Res. 5, 2:137–147, June 1993.
Lützel, Heinrich, “Sinn und Unsinn einer Umbewertung” [Sense and Nonsense of a Reevaluation].
In Statistisches Bundesamt, Rückrechnungen gesamtwirtschaftlicher Daten für die ehemalige
DDR [Backward Calculations of National Accounting Data for the Former GDR], pp. 73– 82.
Stuttgart: Metzler-Poeschel, 1993.
Miller, Ronald E., and Blair, Peter D. Input–Output Analysis: Foundations and Extensions. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice–Hall, 1985.
Sekerka, B., Kyn, O., and Hejl, L., “Price Systems Computable from Input–Output Coefficients.” In
Anne P. Carter and András Bródy, Eds, Contributions to Input–Output Analysis, pp. 183–203.
Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1970.
Seton, Francis, “The Question of Ideological Obstacles to Rational Price Setting in Communist
Countries.” In Alan Abouchar, Ed., The Socialist Price Mechanism, pp. 10 –39. Durham, NC:
Duke Univ. Press, 1977.
Seton, Francis, “A Quasi-Competitive Price Basis for Intersystem Comparisons of Economic Structure and Performance.” J. Comp. Econ. 5, 4:367–391, Dec. 1981.
Seton, Francis, “Relative Prices across Space and Time—The Production of Commodities by Means
of Commodities and Factors.” In Béla Csikós-Nagy, Douglas Hague, and Graham Hall, Eds,
The Economics of Relative Prices, pp. 24 – 45. London: Macmillan, 1982.
Seton, Francis. Cost, Use and Value—The Evaluation of Performance, Structure, and Prices across
Time, Space, and Economic Systems. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1985.
Seton, Francis, “Eigenprices Revisited—Recapitulation and Apologia.” Econ. Systems Res. 1, 2:273–
283, June 1989.
Seton, Francis. The Economics of Cost, Use, and Value, 2nd ed. Oxford: Oxford Univ. Press, 1992.
Seton, Francis, “Price Models Based on Input–Output Analysis: East and West.” Econ. Systems Res.
5, 2:101–111, June 1993.
PRICES IN THE TWO GERMANIES
149
Statistisches Bundesamt. Rückrechnungen gesamtwirtschaftlicher Daten für die ehemalige DDR
[Backward Calculations of National Accounting Data for the Former GDR]. Stuttgart:
Metzler–Poeschel, 1993.
Statistisches Bundesamt. Volkswirtschaftliche Gesamtrechnungen, Fachserie 18, Reihe 2, Input–
Output-Tabellen 1986, 1988, 1990 [National Accounts, Series 18, Part 2, Input–Output Tables
1986, 1988, 1990]. Stuttgart: Metzler–Poeschel, 1994.
Steenge, Albert E., “Time-Series Analysis for the Netherlands and Hungary.” Special Annex in Seton
(1985), pp. 129 –162.
United Nations. Comparison of the System of National Accounts and the System of Balances of the
National Economy, Part II, Series F, No. 20. New York: United Nations, 1977.
Utzig, Siegfried, “Welche ökonomische Aussagefähigkeit enthalten Rückrechnungen ehemaliger
DDR-Statistiken?” [What Is the Economic Meaning of Calculating Backwards Statistics of
the Former GDR?]. In Statistisches Bundesamt, Rückrechnungen gesamtwirtschaftlicher
Daten für die ehemalige DDR [Backward Calculations of National Accounting Data for the
Former GDR], pp. 3–12. Stuttgart: Metzler–Poeschel, 1993.