23rd WORLD CONGRESS OF POLITICAL SCIENCE
INTERNATIONAL POLITICAL SCIENCE ASSOCIATION
July 19-24, 2014, Montréal, Québec-Canada.
Mexican Clientelism Revisited
Luz María Cruz Parcero
Universidad Nacional Autónoma de México, UNAM
luzmaparcero@yahoo.com.mx
Abstract
Contemporary analysis of clientelism aims to revisit the core of the concept in order
to study its potencial capacity for making work the relationships between social
groups and the State.
The paper is about a PH D research in wich is pointed out the topic of
clientelistic relationships in the contemporary Mexican State. Heading from the
main research in rural communities it is possible to identify bridges wich have
allowed the moving of the relationships marked by clientelistic relationships to
some horizontal linkages. The question is whether it is possible that new client
networks may contain structural and functional elements capable of activating
networks of social capital.
1
Introduction
As Luigi Graziano (1973, 16-17) pointed, all political systems are more or less
clientelars and it is important to analyze three properties (structural, political and as
a development condicional element in a society) in order to establish how deep is
the clientelar structure. Their role is more important than we think, when we seek
clientelism, we find it (Médard, 1998).
While the above statements are true, one of the issues that seem most
important for the study of clientelism today is to see what are the characteristics of
the exchange, how to dress, how it is structured and how it works in contemporary
organizations.
Following the first studies of patronage from an antropological perspective,
many authors have described clientelism as a dyadic monolitic structure that
represent the worst form of political domination and it’s mainly focuse in the
electoral arena. From the point of view of a mexican historian clientelism “is one of
the oldest and most persistent opponents of the republic and democracy in Mexico”
that has been with us during the past five centuries (Semo 2012, 583). However
contemporary scholars discussion tends to point out the subtile and profund
differences between the past and present clientelism (Audelo, 2004; Combes,
2011; Gay, 1998), although most of these studies have focused on the election
issue and exchange of favors for votes (Auyero, 1997; Díaz Cayeros-EstévezMagaloni: 2007; Fox: 1994, 1995, 2012; Freidenberg, 2014; Schedler 2004).
As clientelism in not only electoral, we can find new forms of intermediation
as a condensation of past reminiscences and the addition of new mechanisms of
intermediation through mediators called brokers that provide new features and
ways of client relationship, which involves rethinking problems and methodological
approaches to the subject. This new forms compel us to search on the new
mechanisms that let see the clientelism as a new way for the communication of
interests and groups based on new elements of collective organization and identity.
From a theoretical point of view the discussion involves a very important
issue about democracy and representation. Like a kaleidoscope, democratic theory
2
has many reflections and despite being a deeply rooted phenomenon, clientelism
is still an opaque and low light reflection.
In order to analyze the clientelism properties in contemporary Mexico is
important to look at its structure nowadays (not more as the same as the vertical
structure described for authors in the middle seventies), therefore our proposition is
to study clientelism not as the anthropological perspective that points out types of
traditional domination with a legitimacy of subordination and described a face to
face relationship where one is the dominant, but as a multifunctional structure with
a very powerful function as the replacement structures described by Robert Merton
(1965) and also into a new dimension of elements of collective organization and
identity (Gay 1998,14).
Conceptual definition and attributes
In order to define and look for the attributes of clientelism, we can find three main
perspectives: the anthropological, the political sociology and that of the political
science.
Since the British social anthropology of the fifties, there are studies that
describe forms of client relationship in Mediterranean societies. In this perspective,
client relations are not only systems of domination but domination of any legitimate
way. Without entering into the realm of the legal or formal, we would be affirming
that it is Weber types of traditional domination with a legitimacy of subordination.
The anthropological vision focus on community relations and individual
bonds,
in pre-industrial societies, the individual exists not isolated but part of an
institution-the community, be it urban or rural, which covers all their
identities, including those associated with kinship and family. In
modern societies, the individual becomes political unity. This
empowerment of the individual also generates a process of
atomization. The notion of citizenship requires that individuals feel a
sense of belonging to a unit supraordinaria: the state. (Gunes-Ayata,
1997, p 47).
Since the anthropological perspective, fifteen years later we find a turning
point with Robert K. Merton (1965), who studied the functions of the political
3
machine and described how functional deficiencies of the official structure generate
what he called replacement structures (unofficial) to rise existing needs. The
contribution of Merton is a major conceptual leap and a major contribution to
sociology and political science to analyze these intermediary structures in the
sphere of the State.
Another face of the phenomenon has been described by Gunes-Ayata,
when she points how patronage linked elites with local leaders and also with the
central government. At the same time, the positions of the local patterns could be
shored up, and these guys could channel resources from the central government to
consolidate their own power and their private profit. Similarly, sometimes could
reduce the impact of predatory central government had on local communities. With
the expansion of the state administration, local officials even got to be more or less
attractive given their connections and their access to power centers located
beyond the town. With modernization the amount of roles dedicated to linking
positions and competition among local elites increased spread, but continued to
prevail demands for implementation and particularistic distribution of public policies
and benefits. The research indicated that patronage was not only inevitable but
also functional (Gunes-Ayata, 1997, pp. 43-44).
While in traditional networks of patronage recognition is based on
adscriptive criteria such as land titles, etc., she finds that in the new models is
based on performance, the ability to use the links that can transcend the local level
for access to centers of power and positions of control over the distribution of
resources and services (Gunes-Ayata, 1997, p. 50).
The concept lands in political science after touring the anthropological
visions and political sociology to explore the mechanisms by which bureaucracies
are the necessary support to the growing functional state machinery. According to
Weingrod, the difference between the anthropological approach and political
science is that for the former, it is a type of social relationship and the second
designates a characteristic of a system of government (Briquet p. 18).
A classic definition for Political Science is given by Jean-François Médard in 1976:
The client relationship is a relationship of personal dependence that is
not linked to kinship, which is based on reciprocal exchanges of favors
4
between two people, the employer and the client, which control
unequal resources (...). It is a bilateral, particularistic and blurred (...)
relationship; a reciprocal relationship (...) which is a mutually
beneficial exchange between unequal partners (Médard, 1976).
In general, the concept has been used for any type of asymmetrical
exchange ratio and increased use has been applied to the field of exchange of
votes for favors, goods and/or services, leaving the other side exchanges:
economic, political, religious, psychological, military, judicial, administrative,
educational, etc. (Médard, 1976, p. 117).
Beyond an exhaustive review of the contributions to the studies on the
subject, it seems interesting to place five issues that are relevant in the discussion
of the clientelism in contemporary societies, and can afford to take a step towards
review of the concept from the new features that define the new forms and oiled
the mechanisms by which becomes functional in their relationship with the
bureaucracy. These five issues that I will address soon are some notes regarding
the concept and its attributes, its functional aspects and clientelism think the
proposal as a mechanism of social coordination.
1. Clientelism not only refer to the voting exchange, it’s a language and a
practice that permeates social and political relations. In addition to its relationship
with the electoral arena, it is important to look at the other faces of the phenomena.
It is important to take account the other exchanges pointed out by Médard:
economic, political, religious, psychological, military, judicial, administrative,
educational, etc.
2. In terms of it’s position in the State structure it is important to focus on its
pontential as a parallel channel for the promotion of interests, not only in the scope
of the personal interests but also inscribed into an institutional order in wich its
linkage function act as a bridge between the complex bureaucratic web of the State
and the people that is in a marginal position in the same State. This perspective
has been studied by Briquet and Sawicki when they said that the political machine
is a device to reduce the compensation of public institutions dysfunctions allowing
marginal populations integration within the formal political system (Briquet 1998,
16).
5
3. It is also a mean of connection for the resources exchange (economic,
political, religious, psychological, military, judicial, administrative, educational, etc.),
and as Robert Gay pointed out about the brasilian case, it seems that clientelism
has become a means to collective rather than individual assets. Contemporary
clientelism shows both hierarchical and relational elements as elements of
collective organization and identity (Gay 1998).
4. It has become a mechanism of social coordination in a new network form.
In this point is important to distinguish between political coordination in Lechner
terms that means the State is in the top and it is a hierarchical relation with a
centralized power and the coordination in the form of networks that seem to be
more horizontal.1
5. In the scope of the rational choice approach, which reviews the
phenomenon of clientelism from merely utilitarian exchange rates; it is a
relationship in which the actor weigh the costs and potential benefits of trade,
however, contrasted with anthropological, we find that agents can maximize other
relationships that not always are linked with the utility. In this vein, think about the
notion of reciprocity may help to better understand the phenomenon; it is about
moral standards that force you to pay the benefits. This is to see if the client
relationship is perceived as legitimate or as collaborative and an exploitative
relationship; in this perspective, is a relationship between the balance of trade and
the legitimacy of the relationship (Auyero, 1997, pp. 30-33).
A good image to represent the perspective of political science is that of a
river with many tributaries. In one tributarie flow a formal or official way of
intermediation through political parties and the representative institutions; the other
Coordination through networks is understood as "horizontal coordination between different stakeholders in the
same case in order to negotiate and agree on a solution" (Lechner 1997, 14). Messner points out what constitutes a
network: it is an institutional invention that meets the characteristics of a polycentric society; combines vertical
and horizontal communication, but is a specific type of coordination, different forms of policy coordination or
coordination by the market; link different organizations, establishing an interaction between their representatives
(not about relationships within a single organization); it is politic when it meets state authorities (which may be
different instances in conflict with each other) and / or political parties with economic and social actors; the in it
tend to be more informal than formal (not involving the formation of a new organization); relationships that exist
within tend to be more informal; there is interdependence between the participants in it; it’s goal is to formulate
and implement collective decisions around particular shared issue; the starting point is a conflict or diversity of
interests that it channeled through competitive cooperation (Lechner 1997, 14).
1
6
is where it flows informal relationships that exist through lobbyists or interest but
does not have organizations formally recognized in the context of the state; it is the
same phenomenon that is inserted differently in state structures.
It turns out that these forms exist in a particular state, from the sociohistorical, political and economic processes that define them. Briquet (1998, 14-16)
notes that when the issue of patronage is treated as parallel to the penetration of
the state instrument (about the sixties) one can see two approaches: first integrator
traditional and the other as obstacle to the attainment of the objectives assigned to
that integration. It is a process that creates opportunities for social mobility and
appropriation of power resources through mediation circuits from a state center.
More like a device attenuating compensation dysfunctions of public institutions that
allows marginalized groups integrating the official political system, whereby Merton
renamed it the (unofficial) replacement structures that allow meet existing needs.
From the ponit of view of the Political Science it is important to take account
of the functional capacities of clientelism, as a replacement structure in the State,
and take account if it is possible that this kind of structure may transform itself from
vertical linkages to horizontal ones.
The context. Clientelistic State and clientelistic structures.
The revision of this phenomenon also implies to consider the context on wich
clientelism networks are developed. Unless the democratization process wich
contents are mainly related to the electoral arena, the oligarchical form of the
Mexican State organization (with some kind of assistencial and interventionist
machinery, and some kind of civil society expressions) is still like a pyramid.
Unless some signs of democratization our transition to democracy is not yet
completed. The corporativist regime that emerges since the post revolucionary
process is strongly rooted in the State institutions, the language that links high
bureaucracy with people is still, in many fields clientelistic in its exchanging forms.
Since the post revolutionary process we most recognize the growth of the
State that favored that some organizations, that have not been incorporated in their
institutional frameworks but have spread like client networks for better and for
7
worse, and have occupied certain spaces outside the margins of the institutional
framewoks of the state.
From this perspective we can see two faces of clientelism: as a selfcontradiction of that big and oligarchical form of the state, in wich the counterpart
of the same dynamics of growth or expansion brings with his inability to catch or
order everything that happens in that what Easton called the black box of the
political system; also as a capacity that generates functional areas outside of legal
frameworks and political system that defines which has resulted in new
mechanisms
that
refunctionalized
one
of
its
most
traditional
forms
of
intermediation: patron-client with the emergence of a new figure: the broker whose
role is to link clients interests and demands with those of the patron and vice versa.
The context for the study is then that space of development of a "set of
practices, habits, rituals and unwritten rules that organize competition among
actors", the space where conflicts, agreements and disagreements are processed
and operate (Villa, 2012, p. 173). We must assume that with the mexican form of
corporatism it was not possible to promote a different type of state structure to its
essence.
However, in today’s panorama we can see subtle changes that require us to
study the phenomenon from certain empirical evidence that account for relevant
changes to a democratic context.
In Latinamerican context Robert Gay observe that the brasilian clientelism
has been change and become a means to obtain collective goods instead of the
traditional particular ones. In order to this change contemporary clientelism shows
jerarquical and relational elements but also elements of collective organization and
identity (Gay 1998,14).
As a political process, the change is gradual and involves the juxtaposition
of the older and the new forms of clientelism. In this perspective our question is if it
is possible to find a kind of social capital emergence into this new forms of
clientelistic networks.
8
As we can’t find pure traditional or pure modern structures is important to
measure the structure and contextual data to find how deep is the clientelar
structure and how this structure is moving forward through new forms of linkages.
From the classics to the contemporary functions
Around the sixties and seventies, a dominant perspective in studies of clientelism
was one that was based on the idea that the development of democracy would
result from loss of patronage ways that were detrimental to their development; from
an evolutionary view, it is understandable the allocated negative value-laden in
client relations. A new way to observe the phenomenon is based on certain traits
rather than obstacles, that are part of the mechanisms by which institutions may
incorporate the demands and needs of a wide variety of groups and interests in a
logic of institutional efficiency (Briquet and Sawicki 1998).
Médard himself recognizes an evolution of the dominant paradigms in the
social sciences and their adaptation to clientelist phenomenon. Notes that the first
works were placed in a perspective of development and political modernization that
after a while has been rejected to make way for the adoption of a constructivist
perspective that generates a series of reflections concerning the nature of
clientelist phenomenon (Médard, 1998, pp. 307-8).
Once we can establish that the democratization process did not meet the
objectives clear from the political scene woven different relationships from the
original patronage ones. In order to look at the refuncionlization patterns it would
be necessary to take account on the components and mechanisms of action and
try to establish what kind of links between actors are played as part of patronage
networks in contemporary states and how they are inserted into the formal
structures of the state. As Briquet and Sawicki pointed out, it’s important to seek for
the relationships that oiled the mechanisms of action between communities and
government agencies, recognized as informal and formal actors in the same State,
land on which you can point a tension between democratic and bureaucratic logic
(Briquet and Sawicki 1998 , 6).
9
To Médard, the phenomenon can be seen as cutting patrimonial practices,
to understand its nature that need to be interpreted under the patronage of the
sociology of social exchange and anthropology of the gift, which allows not only to
understand the phenomenon as a mere manipulation of the rulers to the ruled, but
also to observe the aspirations and demands of the latter (Médard, 1998, p. 309).
It is also necessary to consider that the same forms of trade have changed
and the sharply hierarchical patron-client dyad that allowed for many years to
explain the phenomenon from more resources with which had the pattern has
faded to make way for relationships which customers can now access valuable
resources requires that the former pattern, which gives the terms of trade more
even obligatory. Levitsky (2007) and Magaloni Diaz-Cayeros and Estévez (2007)
have observed certain diversification mechanisms that have allowed the survival of
patronage to the pair of related provision of public goods mechanisms relations.
Javier Auyero placed reflection on a prime topic related to transformation of
clientelism in forms of collective action from two perspectives: network whose
malfunction collapses and transforms the reciprocal rivalry or oiled patronage
networks, in good operating support collective action.
In these studies, vertical networks do not need to break that collective action
emerges; some of its key stakeholders (employers, mediators and / or clients), for
many reasons, from threats to existing agreements or attempts to improve the
position in the political field, get to organize collective action, which in some cases
can be violent (Auyero 2012: 22-23).
Rethinking clientelism
Other relevant issue relates to the need to rethink the concept of clientelism and
determine how their use remains valid from the observation of the different
attributes and designed from the second half of the twentieth century functions, try
to think of a renewal of the lenses with which the concept has been revised. In
general, the attributes assigned to the client relations: patrimonial, personalistic,
asymmetric, waste of traditional social forms, signs of dysfunctional institutions or
pathologies of the political system, limit our scope of vision and impossible to see it
as one of many ways collective action or social coordination with a potential to
10
become a kind of social capital. If, according to Ostrom and Ahn (2003), the
essence of the perspective of social / collective action capital consists of analyzing
the factors that affect the ability of individuals to solve collective action problems
related to economic and political development, it would be relevant see the
mechanisms involved in clientelism to determine the extent social relations in
which these coordination mechanisms mediating limited clientele, promote or
facilitate the ability of individuals and / or associations to resolve these collective
action problems.
The proposal is to open a new line that allows to develop the analysis of the
clientelist phenomenon from a reverse position: see the phenomenom as one of
many forms of collective action or social coordination. In Mexico I think the
challenges of the analysis can be oriented in three ways, the first relating to the
definition of conciliation and mediation mechanisms at the level of government
agencies, the second has to do with the bargaining power to from the equalization
of resources and the autonomy they have manipulated once submissive and
clienteles and the third with the opportunity to observe what could be considered
as seed capital.
As Médard points in a very relevant observation for our purposes, we can
see analytically relevant contrasts of principles that seem incompatible, however,
the fact that theoretically combines these types are incompatible and that is where
this type of work have much to contribute.
I think the space where those bridges capable of communicating with the
patronage capital weave their common elements are: trust, reciprocity and rules.
Regarding the first approach, the definition of the mechanisms for
consultation and government intermediation Carl Lane has reviewed clientelism as
an addenda concept, arguing that modern institutional forms and patronage were
not only compatible but complementary upon recognition of spaces informality
where the constitutional or legal frameworks fail to meet all the needs of the
community and its members (Gunes-Ayata, p. 46).
In this logic the proposal made Briquet is provocative in the sense of starting
with getting rid of those perspectives to analyze the rational bureaucracy, like L.
11
Graziano, from which the notion of patronage, to escape the forms of
arrangements public relations and refer to a series of private agreements that exist
outside the institutional, hindering what has been called modernization. For him it is
a kind of formal logic in which the institutional design follows a legal-rational order
and on the other the real political scenario in which informality is constructed. The
interesting thing about the review is to make Briquet clientelistic forms as
mechanisms that provide functionality to a state apparatus whose dimensions
exceed their current capacities of order and regulation. To study from this
perspective it is not enough only to guide the analysis to the description of dynamic
aspects is also important to distinguish the forms of participation and mobilization
of groups whose collective interests are structured within the framework of rational
processes of political negotiation.
The other perspective leads us to review positions traditionally analyzed as
opposing the clientelism and forms of social capital. For Coleman (1990), social
capital is a function that helps the cooperation relationship between trusted
systems and the strength of social capital is established. This author looks at the
relationship of reciprocity one of the features that distinguish the forms of social
capital patronage when defined in terms of expectations that are directly
proportional to the obligations. Thus, it appears that in the form of vertical
structuring of client relations precludes a type of reciprocal exchange, while
privatized and monopolized public goods.
But clientelism personal relationship implies that both people should know
well enough to build a relationship of loyalty and trust, is for that reason that the
relationship is also called lop-sided friendship (Pitt-Rivers, 1961) or friend
interested (Schröter , 2010, p. 146). It is a voluntary relationship that distinguishes
clientelism notions as slavery or servitude.
On the other hand, clientelism is also treated as a relationship based on
mutual trust "to compensate for the uncertainty about the performance of a contract
like exchange (Máiz, 2003: 14) relationship. If there is no such trust, the employer
must provide incentives to create additional motivation, which can easily become
coercion "(Schröter, 2010, p. 147).
12
To analyze the issue from this perspective can help uncover the incentives
can mobilize a latent group to achieve cooperative behaviors in an organization or
institution (Olson 1992: 71).
As a conclusion of this paper and as points to advance the discussion of the
topic, it seems necessary to rethink the concept of patronage from the shape and
size of contemporary states, the concept is still valid as it allows, as pointed Briquet
(1998, p 21), to account for how they can be structured in a particular way the
institutions to identify activities that political modernity and describe characteristics
of the relationships between groups and institutions beyond the circumscribed
space relations of rural communities and identify gaps that appear frequently
between actual operating logics of political systems and normative models from
which we have sought to establish their legitimacy in ideological categories of
"modernity" policy.
A proposal for rethinking the concept necessarily involves the review of
current mechanisms still exist the ties that bind together. The other approach
involves the review of the concept from the new forms of joint while allowing jump
one obstacle and marked by Auyero (1997, p. 36-7) vs. the patronage opposition.
These provide greater elasticity to the concept in order to capture
phenomena observed in contemporary states. The empirical work is certainly
needed to trap source new forms of articulation that occur as forms of cooperation
based on patronage networks.
We face a great methodological challenge in order to explain the
coexistence of two basic models: the older ones, characterized by a clear vertical
structure where interests are clearly particularized and privatized and the
emergence of new structures more horizontal with aggregated interests that
combines some forms of the old model with new forms that haven’t yet been
characterized.
Focused in this terms, I think that the study of this changes is for great value
for the quality of democracy, wich is the issue that convene us today.
13
Bibliography
Auyero, J. (2012). The Winding Roads of Political Ethnography. Pleiad (10), 15-36.
(1997). Favors by votes?. Studies on Contemporary Political Patronage. Buenos
Aires, Argentina: Losada.
Bouissou, J.-M. (1998). Le clientélisme organisé démocratie dans une moderne.
Le cas des Koenkai japonaises in Briquet J.-L., & F. Sawicki, Le Clientélisme
Politique dans les Sociétés Contemporaines. Paris, France: Presses Universitaires
de France.
Briquet, J.-L. (1998). The clientélaire politique. Clientélisme processus et politiques
in Briquet J.-L., & F. Sawicki, Le politique dans les sociétés clientélisme
contemporaines (pp. 7-37). Paris, France: Presses Universitaires de France.
Coleman, J. S. (1990). Foundations of Social Theory. England: The Belknap Press
of Harvard University Press.
Combes, H. (2011). Where are we with the study of clientelism? Desacatos (36),
13-32.
Fox, J. (1995). Local Governance and Citizen Participation, Capital Formation and
Enabling Policy Environments, in R. Wilson, & R. (Cramer, International Workshop
and Good Local Government (Vol. II) Austin, United States. Univerity of Texas.
(2012). State Power and Clientelism: Eight propositions for discussion, in T.
Hilgers, clientelism in Latinamerican Everyday Politics (pp. 187-207). Basingstoke:
Palgrave Macmillan.
(1994). The Difficult Transition from Clientelism to Citizenship: Lessons from
Mexico. World Politics, 46, 151-184.
Gunes-Ayata, A. (1997). Patronage: premodern, modern, postmodern. In J.
Auyero? Favors for votes?. Studies on contemporary political patronage. (pp. 4363). Buenos Aires, Argentina: Losada.
Kitschelet, H., & Wilkinson, S. I. (2007). Patrons, Clients, and Policies. Patterns of
Democratic Accountability and Political Competition. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge
University Press.
14
Magaloni, B., Diaz-Cayeros, A., & Estévez, F. (2007). Clientelism and portfolio
diversification: a model of electoral investment with applications to Mexico in
Kitschelet H., & SI Wilkinson, Patrons, Clients, and Policies. Patterns of
Democratic Accountability and Political Competition (pp. 182-205), Cambridge, UK:
Cambridge University Press.
Médard, J.-F. (1976). Le rapport de clientéle. Du phénomène social a l'analyze
politique. Revue de science politique français (1), 103-119.
Médard, J.-F. (1998). Afterword. In J.-L. Briquet, & F. Sawicki, Le politique dans les
sociétés clientélisme contemporaines (pp. 307-316). Paris, France: PUF.
Merton, R. (1965). Elements of sociologique théorie et méthode. Paris, France:
Plon.
Ostrom, E., & Ahn, T. (2003). A social capital perspective from the social sciences:
social capital and collective action in Mexican Journal of Sociology, 65 year (1),
155-233.
Schröter, B. (2010). Political patronage: the ghost exists and how she dresses?
(Social UN-I., Ed) in Mexican Journal of Sociology, 72 (1), 141-175.
Tocqueville, A. (1957). Democracy in America. Mexico, Mexico: Fondo de Cultura
Económica.
Villa, F. M. (2012). Power and Institutions in uncertain statism and democracy.
(The cycle of state interventionism and his regime: Argentina, Brazil, Italy, Russia
and Mexico from 1929 to 2010 study of comparative politics.). Thesis for the
degree of Doctor of Political and Social Science. Ciudad Universitaria, Mexico.
15