The Health Care Crisis and What To Do About It

Download as doc, pdf, or txt
Download as doc, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 20
At a glance
Powered by AI
The US spends more on healthcare than other countries but doesn't get better outcomes. Rampant costs are due to fragmentation and inefficiency in the system.

The main problem is the fragmentation of the system with many private insurers and providers adding costs without improving care.

Other countries that have implemented single-payer systems spend less per capita and achieve better health outcomes. The evidence clearly shows a single-payer system would be more effective and cheaper for the US.

The Health Care Crisis and What to Do About

It
By Paul Krugman, Robin Wells

Can We Say No? The Challenge of Rationing Health Care


by Henry J. Aaron and William B. Schwartz, with Melissa Cox
Brookings Institution, 199 pp., $44.95; $18.95 (paper)

The Health Care Mess: How We Got into It and What It Will Take to Get Out
by Julius Richmond and Rashi Fein
Harvard University Press, 320 pp., $26.95

Healthy, Wealthy, and Wise: Five Steps to a Better Health Care System
by John F. Cogan, R. Glenn Hubbard, and Daniel P. Kessler
American Enterprise Institute/Hoover Institution, 130 pp., $18.00

Thirteen years ago Bill Clinton became president partly because he promised to
do something about rising health care costs. Although Clinton's chances of
reforming the US health care system looked quite good at first, the effort soon ran
aground. Since then a combination of factors—the unwillingness of other
politicians to confront the insurance and other lobbies that so successfully
frustrated the Clinton effort, a temporary remission in the growth of health care
spending as HMOs briefly managed to limit cost increases, and the general
distraction of a nation focused first on the gloriousness of getting rich, then on
terrorism—have kept health care off the top of the agenda.

But medical costs are once again rising rapidly, forcing health care back into
political prominence. Indeed, the problem of medical costs is so pervasive that it
underlies three quite different policy crises. First is the increasingly rapid
unraveling of employer- based health insurance. Second is the plight of Medicaid,
an increasingly crucial program that is under both fiscal and political attack.
Third is the long-term problem of the federal government's solvency, which is, as
we'll explain, largely a problem of health care costs.
The good news is that we know more about the economics of health care than we
did when Clinton tried and failed to remake the system. There's now a large body
of evidence on what works and what doesn't work in health care, and it's not hard
to see how to make dramatic improvements in US practice. As we'll see, the
evidence clearly shows that the key problem with the US health care system is its
fragmentation. A history of failed attempts to introduce universal health
insurance has left us with a system in which the government pays directly or
indirectly for more than half of the nation's health care, but the actual delivery
both of insurance and of care is undertaken by a crazy quilt of private insurers,
for-profit hospitals, and other players who add cost without adding value. A
Canadian-style single-payer system, in which the government directly provides
insurance, would almost surely be both cheaper and more effective than what we
now have. And we could do even better if we learned from "integrated" systems,
like the Veterans Administration, that directly provide some health care as well as
medical insurance.

The bad news is that Washington currently seems incapable of accepting what the
evidence on health care says. In particular, the Bush administration is under the
influence of both industry lobbyists, especially those representing the drug
companies, and a free-market ideology that is wholly inappropriate to health care
issues. As a result, it seems determined to pursue policies that will increase the
fragmentation of our system and swell the ranks of the uninsured.

Before we talk about reform, however, let's talk about the current state of the US
health care system. Let us begin by asking a seemingly naive question: What's
wrong with spending ever more on health care?
1.
Is health care spending a problem?

In 1960 the United States spent only 5.2 percent of GDP on health care. By 2004
that number had risen to 16 percent. At this point America spends more on
health care than it does on food. But what's wrong with that?

The starting point for any discussion of rising health care costs has to be the
realization that these rising costs are, in an important sense, a sign of progress.
Here's how the Congressional Budget Office puts it, in the latest edition of its
annual publication The Long-Term Budget Outlook:

Growth in health care spending has outstripped economic growth regardless of


the source of its funding.... The major factor associated with that growth has been
the development and increasing use of new medical technology.... In the health
care field, unlike in many sectors of the economy, technological advances have
generally raised costs rather than lowered them.

Notice the three points in that quote. First, health care spending is rising rapidly
"regardless of the source of its funding." Translation: although much health care
is paid for by the government, this isn't a simple case of runaway government
spending, because private spending is rising at a comparably fast clip.
"Comparing common benefits," says the Kaiser Family Foundation,

changes in Medicare spending in the last three decades has largely tracked the
growth rate in private health insurance premiums. Typically, Medicare increases
have been lower than those of private health insurance.

Second, "new medical technology" is the major factor in rising spending: we


spend more on medicine because there's more that medicine can do. Third, in
medical care, "technological advances have generally raised costs rather than
lowered them": although new technology surely produces cost savings in
medicine, as elsewhere, the additional spending that takes place as a result of the
expansion of medical possibilities outweighs those savings.

So far, this sounds like a happy story. We've found new ways to help people, and
are spending more to take advantage of the opportunity. Why not view rising
medical spending, like rising spending on, say, home entertainment systems,
simply as a rational response to expanded choice? We would suggest two
answers.
The first is that the US health care system is extremely inefficient, and this
inefficiency becomes more costly as the health care sector becomes a larger
fraction of the economy. Suppose, for example, that we believe that 30 percent of
US health care spending is wasted, and always has been. In 1960, when health
care was only 5.2 percent of GDP, that meant waste equal to only 1.5 percent of
GDP. Now that the share of health care in the economy has more than tripled, so
has the waste.

This inefficiency is a bad thing in itself. What makes it literally fatal to thousands
of Americans each year is that the inefficiency of our health care system
exacerbates a second problem: our health care system often makes irrational
choices, and rising costs exacerbate those irrationalities. Specifically, American
health care tends to divide the population into insiders and outsiders. Insiders,
who have good insurance, receive everything modern medicine can provide, no
matter how expensive. Outsiders, who have poor insurance or none at all, receive
very little. To take just one example, one study found that among Americans
diagnosed with colorectal cancer, those without insurance were 70 percent more
likely than those with insurance to die over the next three years.

In response to new medical technology, the system spends even more on insiders.
But it compensates for higher spending on insiders, in part, by consigning more
people to outsider status—robbing Peter of basic care in order to pay for Paul's
state-of-the-art treatment. Thus we have the cruel paradox that medical progress
is bad for many Americans' health.

This description of our health care problems may sound abstract. But we can
make it concrete by looking at the crisis now afflicting employer-based health
insurance.

2.
The unraveling of employer-based insurance

In 2003 only 16 percent of health care spending consisted of out-of-pocket


expenditures by consumers. The rest was paid for by insurance, public or private.
As we'll see, this heavy reliance on insurance disturbs some economists, who
believe that doctors and patients fail to make rational decisions about spending
because third parties bear the costs of medical treatment. But it's no use wishing
that health care were sold like ordinary consumer goods, with individuals paying
out of pocket for what they need. By its very nature, most health spending must
be covered by insurance.
The reason is simple: in any given year, most people have small medical bills,
while a few people have very large bills. In 2003, health spending roughly
followed the "80–20 rule": 20 percent of the population accounted for 80 percent
of expenses. Half the population had virtually no medical expenses; a mere 1
percent of the population accounted for 22 percent of expenses.

Here's how Henry Aaron and his coauthors summarize the implication of these
numbers in their book Can We Say No?: "Most health costs are incurred by a
small proportion of the population whose expenses greatly exceed plausible limits
on out-of-pocket spending." In other words, if people had to pay for medical care
the way they pay for groceries, they would have to forego most of what modern
medicine has to offer, because they would quickly run out of funds in the face of
medical emergencies.

So the only way modern medical care can be made available to anyone other than
the very rich is through health insurance. Yet it's very difficult for the private
sector to provide such insurance, because health insurance suffers from a
particularly acute case of a well-known economic problem known as adverse
selection. Here's how it works: imagine an insurer who offered policies to anyone,
with the annual premium set to cover the average person's health care expenses,
plus the administrative costs of running the insurance company. Who would sign
up? The answer, unfortunately, is that the insurer's customers wouldn't be a
representative sample of the population. Healthy people, with little reason to
expect high medical bills, would probably shun policies priced to reflect the
average person's health costs. On the other hand, unhealthy people would find
the policies very attractive.

You can see where this is going. The insurance company would quickly find that
because its clientele was tilted toward those with high medical costs, its actual
costs per customer were much higher than those of the average member of the
population. So it would have to raise premiums to cover those higher costs.
However, this would disproportionately drive off its healthier customers, leaving
it with an even less healthy customer base, requiring a further rise in premiums,
and so on.

Insurance companies deal with these problems, to some extent, by carefully


screening applicants to identify those with a high risk of needing expensive
treatment, and either rejecting such applicants or charging them higher
premiums. But such screening is itself expensive. Furthermore, it tends to screen
out exactly those who most need insurance.
Most advanced countries have dealt with the defects of private health insurance
in a straightforward way, by making health insurance a government service.
Through Medicare, the United States has in effect done the same thing for its
seniors. We also have Medicaid, a means-tested program that provides health
insurance to many of the poor and near poor. But nonelderly, nonpoor Americans
are on their own. In practice, only a tiny fraction of nonelderly Americans (5.3
percent in 2003) buy private insurance for themselves. The rest of those not
covered by Medicare or Medicaid get insurance, if at all, through their employers.

Employer-based insurance is a peculiarly American institution. As Julius


Richmond and Rashi Fein tell us in The Health Care Mess, the dominant role of
such insurance is the result of historical accident rather than deliberate policy.
World War II caused a labor shortage, but employers were subject to controls
that prevented them from attracting workers by offering higher wages. Health
benefits, however, weren't controlled, and so became a way for employers to
compete for workers. Once employers began offering medical benefits, they also
realized that it was a form of compensation workers valued highly because it
protected them from risk. Moreover, the tax law favored employer-based
insurance, because employers' contributions weren't considered part of workers'
taxable income. Today, the value of the tax subsidy for employer-based insurance
is estimated at around $150 billion a year.

Employer-based insurance has historically offered a partial solution to the


problem of adverse selection. In principle, adverse selection can still occur even if
health insurance comes with a job rather than as a stand-alone policy. This would
occur if workers with health problems flocked to companies that offered health
insurance, while healthy workers took jobs at companies that didn't offer
insurance and offered higher wages instead. But until recently health insurance
was a sufficiently small consideration in job choice that large corporations
offering good health benefits, like General Motors, could safely assume that the
health status of their employees was representative of the population at large and
that adverse selection wasn't inflating the cost of health insurance.

In 2004, according to census estimates, 63.1 percent of Americans under sixty-


five received health insurance through their employers or family members'
employers. Given the inherent difficulties of providing health insurance through
the private sector, that's an impressive number. But it left more than a third of
nonelderly Americans out of the system. Moreover, the number of outsiders is
growing: the share of nonelderly Americans with employment-based health
insurance was 67.7 percent as recently as 2000. And this trend seems certain to
continue, even accelerate, because the whole system of employer-based health
care is under severe strain.

We can identify several reasons for that strain, but mainly it comes down to the
issue of costs. Providing health insurance looked like a good way for employers to
reward their employees when it was a small part of the pay package. Today,
however, the annual cost of coverage for a family of four is estimated by the
Kaiser Family Foundation at more than $10,000. One way to look at it is to say
that that's roughly what a worker earning minimum wage and working full time
earns in a year. It's more than half the annual earnings of the average Wal-Mart
employee.

Health care costs at current levels override the incentives that have historically
supported employer-based health insurance. Now that health costs loom so large,
companies that provide generous benefits are in effect paying some of their
workers much more than the going wage—or, more to the point, more than
competitors pay similar workers. Inevitably, this creates pressure to reduce or
eliminate health benefits. And companies that can't cut benefits enough to stay
competitive—such as GM—find their very existence at risk.

Rising health costs have also ended the ability of employer-based insurance plans
to avoid the problem of adverse selection. Anecdotal evidence suggests that
workers who know they have health problems actively seek out jobs with
companies that still offer generous benefits. On the other side, employers are
starting to make hiring decisions based on likely health costs. For example, an
internal Wal-Mart memo, reported by The New York Times in October, suggested
adding tasks requiring physical exertion to jobs that don't really require it as a
way to screen out individuals with potential health risks.

So rising health care costs are undermining the institution of employer-based


coverage. We'd suggest that the drop in the number of insured so far only hints at
the scale of the problem: we may well be seeing the whole institution unraveling.

Notice that this unraveling is the byproduct of what should be a good thing:
advances in medical technology, which lead doctors to spend more on their
patients. This leads to higher insurance costs, which causes employers to stop
providing health coverage. The result is that many people are thrown into the
world of the uninsured, where even basic care is often hard to get. As we said, we
rob Peter of basic care in order to provide Paul with state-of-the-art treatment.
Fortunately, some of the adverse consequences of the decline in employer-based
coverage have been muted by a crucial government program, Medicaid. But
Medicaid is facing its own pressures.

3.
Medicaid and Medicare

The US health care system is more privatized than that of any other advanced
country, but nearly half of total health care spending nonetheless comes from the
government. Most of this government spending is accounted for by two great
social insurance programs, Medicare and Medicaid. Although Medicare gets most
of the public attention, let's focus first on Medicaid, which is a far more important
program than most middle-class Americans realize.

In The Health Care Mess Richmond and Fein tell us that Medicaid, like
employer-based health insurance, came into existence through a sort of historical
accident. As Lyndon Johnson made his big push to create Medicare, the
American Medical Association, in a last-ditch effort to block so-called "socialized
medicine" (actually only the insurance is socialized; the medical care is provided
by the private sector), began disparaging Johnson's plan by claiming that it would
do nothing to help the truly needy. In a masterful piece of political jujitsu,
Johnson responded by adding a second program, Medicaid, targeted specifically
at helping the poor and near poor.

Today, Medicaid is a crucial part of the American safety net. In 2004 Medicaid
covered almost as many people as its senior partner, Medicare—37.5 million
versus 39.7 million.

Medicaid has grown rapidly in recent years because it has been picking up the
slack from the unraveling system of employer-based insurance. Between 2000
and 2004 the number of Americans covered by Medicaid rose by a remarkable
eight million. Over the same period the ranks of the uninsured rose by six
million. So without the growth of Medicaid, the uninsured population would have
exploded, and we'd be facing a severe crisis in medical care.

But Medicaid, even as it becomes increasingly essential to tens of millions of


Americans, is also becoming increasingly vulnerable to political attack. To some
extent this reflects the political weakness of any means-tested program serving
the poor and near poor. As the British welfare scholar Richard Titmuss said,
"Programs for the poor are poor programs." Unlike Medicare's clients—the feared
senior group—Medicaid recipients aren't a potent political constituency: they are,
on average, poor and poorly educated, with low voter participation. As a result,
funding for Medicaid depends on politicians' sense of decency, always a fragile
foundation for policy.

The complex structure of Medicaid also makes it vulnerable. Unlike Medicare,


which is a purely federal program, Medicaid is a federal-state matching program,
in which states provide on average about 40 percent of the funds. Since state
governments, unlike the federal government, can't engage in open-ended deficit
financing, this dependence on state funds exposes Medicaid to pressure
whenever state budgets are hard-pressed. And state budgets are hard-pressed
these days for a variety of reasons, not least the rapidly rising cost of Medicaid
itself.

The result is that, like employer-based health insurance, Medicaid faces a


possible unraveling in the face of rising health costs. An example of how that
unraveling might take place is South Carolina's request for a waiver of federal
rules to allow it to restructure the state's Medicaid program into a system of
private accounts. We'll discuss later in this essay the strange persistence, in the
teeth of all available evidence, of the belief that the private sector can provide
health insurance more efficiently than the government. The main point for now is
that South Carolina's proposed reform would seriously weaken the medical safety
net: recipients would be given a voucher to purchase health insurance, but many
would find the voucher inadequate, and would end up being denied care. And if
South Carolina gets its waiver, other states will probably follow its lead.

Medicare's situation is very different. Unlike employer-based insurance or


Medicaid, Medicare faces no imminent threat of large cuts. Although the federal
government is deep in deficit, it's not currently having any difficulty borrowing,
largely from abroad, to cover the gap. Also, the political constituency behind
Medicare remains extremely powerful. Yet federal deficits can't go on forever;
even the US government must eventually find a way to pay its bills. And the long-
term outlook for federal finances is dire, mainly because of Medicare and
Medicaid.

The chart in figure 1 illustrates the centrality of health care costs to America's
long-term budget problems. The chart shows the Congressional Budget Office's
baseline projection of spending over the next twenty-five years on the three big
entitlement programs, Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid, measured as a
percentage of GDP. Not long ago advocates of Social Security privatization tried
to use projections like this one to foster a sense of crisis about the retirement
system. As was pointed out last year in these pages,[1] however, there is no
program called Socialsecuritymedicareandmedicaid. In fact, as the chart shows,
Social Security, whose costs will rise solely because of the aging of the population,
represents only a small part of the problem. Most of the problem comes from the
two health care programs, whose spending is rising mainly because of the general
rise in medical costs.

To be fair, there is a demographic component to Medicare and Medicaid


spending too—Medicare because it only serves Americans over sixty-five,
Medicaid because the elderly, although a minority of the program's beneficiaries,
account for most of its spending. Still, the principal factor in both programs'
rising costs is what the CBO calls "excess cost growth"—the persistent tendency of
health care spending per beneficiary to grow faster than per capita income, owing
to advancing medical technology. Without this excess cost growth, the CBO
estimates that entitlement spending would rise by only 3.7 percent of GDP over
the next twenty-five years. That's a significant rise, but not overwhelming, and
could be addressed with moderate tax increases and possibly benefit cuts. But
because of excess cost growth the projected rise in spending is a crushing burden
—about 10 percent of GDP over the next twenty-five years, and even more
thereafter.

Rising health care spending, then, is driving a triple crisis. The fastest-moving
piece of that crisis is the unraveling of employer-based coverage. There's a
gradually building crisis in Medicaid. And there's a long-term federal budget
crisis driven mainly by rising health care spending.

So what are we going to do about health care?

4.
The "consumer-directed" diversion

As we pointed out at the beginning of this essay, one of the two big reasons to be
concerned about rising spending on health care is that as the health care sector
grows, its inefficiency becomes increasingly important. And almost everyone
agrees that the US health care system is extremely inefficient. But there are wide
disagreements about the nature of that inefficiency. And the analysts who have
the ear of the Bush administration are committed, for ideological reasons, to a
view that is clearly wrong.
We've already alluded to the underlying view behind the Bush administration's
health care proposals: it's the view that insurance leads people to consume too
much health care. The 2004 Economic Report of the President, which devoted a
chapter to health care, illustrated the alleged problem with a parable about the
clothing industry:

Suppose, for example, that an individual could purchase a clothing insurance


policy with a "coinsurance" rate of 20 percent, meaning that after paying the
insurance premium, the holder of the insurance policy would have to pay only 20
cents on the dollar for all clothing purchases. An individual with such a policy
would be expected to spend substantially more on clothes—due to larger quantity
and higher quality purchases—with the 80 percent discount than he would at the
full price.... The clothing insurance example suggests an inherent inefficiency in
the use of insurance to pay for things that have little intrinsic risk or uncertainty.

The report then asserts that "inefficiencies of this sort are pervasive in the US
health care system"—although, tellingly, it fails to match the parable about
clothing with any real examples from health care.

The view that Americans consume too much health care because insurers pay the
bills leads to what is currently being called the "consumer-directed" approach to
health care reform. The virtues of such an approach are the theme of John Cogan,
Glenn Hubbard, and Daniel Kessler's Healthy, Wealthy, and Wise. The main idea
is that people should pay more of their medical expenses out of pocket. And the
way to reduce public reliance on insurance, reformers from the right wing
believe, is to remove the tax advantages that currently favor health insurance over
out-of-pocket spending. Indeed, last year Bush's tax reform commission
proposed taxing some employment-based health benefits. The administration,
recognizing how politically explosive such a move would be, rejected the
proposal. Instead of raising taxes on health insurance, the administration has
decided to cut taxes on out-of-pocket spending.

Cogan, Hubbard, and Kessler call for making all out-of-pocket medical spending
tax-deductible, although tax experts from both parties say that this would present
an enforcement nightmare. (Douglas Holtz-Eakin, the former head of the
Congressional Budget Office, put it this way: "If you want to have a personal
relationship with the IRS do that [i.e., make all medical spending tax deductible]
because we are going to have to investigate everybody's home to see if their
running shoes are a medical expense.") The administration's proposals so far are
more limited, focusing on an expanded system of tax-advantaged health savings
accounts. Individuals can shelter part of their income from taxes by depositing it
in such accounts, then withdraw money from these accounts to pay medical bills.

What's wrong with consumer-directed health care? One immediate disadvantage


is that health savings accounts, whatever their ostensible goals, are yet another
tax break for the wealthy, who have already been showered with tax breaks under
Bush. The right to pay medical expenses with pre-tax income is worth a lot to
high-income individuals who face a marginal income tax rate of 35 percent, but
little or nothing to lower-income Americans who face a marginal tax rate of 10
percent or less, and lack the ability to place the maximum allowed amount in
their savings accounts.

A deeper disadvantage is that such accounts tend to undermine employment-


based health care, because they encourage adverse selection: health savings
accounts are attractive to healthier individuals, who will be tempted to opt out of
company plans, leaving less healthy individuals behind.

Yet another problem with consumer-directed care is that the evidence says that
people don't, in fact, make wise decisions when paying for medical care out of
pocket. A classic study by the Rand Corporation found that when people pay
medical expenses themselves rather than relying on insurance, they do cut back
on their consumption of health care—but that they cut back on valuable as well as
questionable medical procedures, showing no ability to set sensible priorities.

But perhaps the biggest objection to consumer-directed health reform is that its
advocates have misdiagnosed the problem. They believe that Americans have too
much health insurance; the 2004 Economic Report of the President condemned
the fact that insurance currently pays for "many events that have little
uncertainty, such as routine dental care, annual medical exams, and
vaccinations," and for "relatively low-expense items, such as an office visit to the
doctor for a sore throat." The implication is that health costs are too high because
people who don't pay their own medical bills consume too much routine dental
care and are too ready to visit the doctor about a sore throat. And that argument
is all wrong. Excessive consumption of routine care, or small-expense items, can't
be a major source of health care inefficiency, because such items don't account
for a major share of medical costs.

Remember the 80–20 rule: the great bulk of medical expenses are accounted for
by a small number of people requiring very expensive treatment. When you think
of the problem of health care costs, you shouldn't envision visits to the family
physician to talk about a sore throat; you should think about coronary bypass
operations, dialysis, and chemotherapy. Nobody is proposing a consumer-
directed health care plan that would force individuals to pay a large share of
extreme medical expenses, such as the costs of chemotherapy, out of pocket. And
that means that consumer-directed health care can't promote savings on the
treatments that account for most of what we spend on health care.

The administration's plans for consumer-directed health care, then, are a


diversion from meaningful health care reform, and will actually worsen our
health care problems. In fact, some reformers privately hope that George W.
Bush manages to get his health care plans passed, because they believe that they
will hasten the collapse of employment-based coverage and pave the way for real
reform. (The suffering along the way would be huge.)

But what would real reform look like?

5.
Single-payer and beyond

How do we know that the US health care system is highly inefficient? An


important part of the evidence takes the form of international comparisons. Table
1 compares US health care with the systems of three other advanced countries.
It's clear from the table that the United States has achieved something
remarkable. We spend far more on health care than other advanced countries—
almost twice as much per capita as France, almost two and a half times as much
as Britain. Yet we do considerably worse even than the British on basic measures
of health performance, such as life expectancy and infant mortality.

One might argue that the US health care system actually provides better care than
foreign systems, but that the effects of this superior care are more than offset by
unhealthy US lifestyles. Ezra Klein of The American Prospect calls this the "well-
we-eat-more-cheeseburgers" argument. But a variety of evidence refutes this
argument. The data in Table 1 show that the United States does not stand out in
the quantity of care, as measured by such indicators as the number of physicians,
nurses, and hospital beds per capita. Nor does the US stand out in terms of the
quality of care: a recent study published in Health Affairs that compared quality
of care across advanced countries found no US advantage. On the contrary, "the
United States often stands out for inefficient care and errors and is an outlier on
access/cost barriers."[2] That is, our health care system makes more mistakes than
those of other countries, and is unique in denying necessary care to people who
lack insurance and can't pay cash. The frequent claim that the United States pays
high medical prices to avoid long waiting lists for care also fails to hold up in the
face of the evidence: there are long waiting lists for elective surgery in some non-
US systems, but not all, and the procedures for which these waiting lists exist
account for only 3 percent of US health care spending.[3]

So why does US health care cost so much? Part of the answer is that doctors, like
other highly skilled workers, are paid much more in the United States than in
other advanced countries. But the main source of high US costs is probably the
unique degree to which the US system relies on private rather than public health
insurance, reflected in the uniquely high US share of private spending in total
health care expenditure.

Over the years since the failure of the Clinton health plan, a great deal of evidence
has accumulated on the relative merits of private and public health insurance. As
far as we have been able to ascertain, all of that evidence indicates that public
insurance of the kind available in several European countries and others such as
Taiwan achieves equal or better results at much lower cost. This conclusion
applies to comparisons within the United States as well as across countries. For
example, a study conducted by researchers at the Urban Institute found that

per capita spending for an adult Medicaid beneficiary in poor health would rise
from $9,615 to $14,785 if the person were insured privately and received services
consistent with private utilization levels and private provider payment rates.[4]

The cost advantage of public health insurance appears to arise from two main
sources. The first is lower administrative costs. Private insurers spend large sums
fighting adverse selection, trying to identify and screen out high-cost customers.
Systems such as Medicare, which covers every American sixty-five or older, or the
Canadian single-payer system, which covers everyone, avoid these costs. In 2003
Medicare spent less than 2 percent of its resources on administration, while
private insurance companies spent more than 13 percent.

At the same time, the fragmentation of a system that relies largely on private
insurance leads both to administrative complexity because of differences in
coverage among individuals and to what is, in effect, a zero-sum struggle between
different players in the system, each trying to stick others with the bill. Many
estimates suggest that the paperwork imposed on health care providers by the
fragmentation of the US system costs several times as much as the direct costs
borne by the insurers.
The second source of savings in a system of public health insurance is the ability
to bargain with suppliers, especially drug companies, for lower prices. Residents
of the United States notoriously pay much higher prices for prescription drugs
than residents of other advanced countries, including Canada. What is less
known is that both Medicaid and, to an even greater extent, the Veterans'
Administration, get discounts similar to or greater than those received by the
Canadian health system.

We're talking about large cost savings. Indeed, the available evidence suggests
that if the United States were to replace its current complex mix of health
insurance systems with standardized, universal coverage, the savings would be so
large that we could cover all those currently uninsured, yet end up spending less
overall. That's what happened in Taiwan, which adopted a single-payer system in
1995: the percentage of the population with health insurance soared from 57
percent to 97 percent, yet health care costs actually grew more slowly than one
would have predicted from trends before the change in system.

If US politicians could be persuaded of the advantages of a public health


insurance system, the next step would be to convince them of the virtues, in at
least some cases, of honest-to-God socialized medicine, in which government
employees provide the care as well as the money. Exhibit A for the advantages of
government provision is the Veterans' Administration, which runs its own
hospitals and clinics, and provides some of the best-quality health care in
America at far lower cost than the private sector. How does the VA do it? It turns
out that there are many advantages to having a single health care organization
provide individuals with what amounts to lifetime care. For example, the VA has
taken the lead in introducing electronic medical records, which it can do far more
easily than a private hospital chain because its patients stay with it for decades.
The VA also invests heavily and systematically in preventive care, because unlike
private health care providers it can expect to realize financial benefits from
measures that keep its clients out of the hospital.

In summary, then, the obvious way to make the US health care system more
efficient is to make it more like the systems of other advanced countries, and
more like the most efficient parts of our own system. That means a shift from
private insurance to public insurance, and greater government involvement in the
provision of health care—if not publicly run hospitals and clinics, at least a much
larger government role in creating integrated record-keeping and quality control.
Such a system would probably allow individuals to purchase additional medical
care, as they can in Britain (although not in Canada). But the core of the system
would be government insurance—"Medicare for all," as Ted Kennedy puts it.

Unfortunately, the US political system seems unready to do what is both obvious


and humane. The 2003 legislation that added drug coverage to Medicare
illustrates some of the political difficulties. Although it's rarely described this
way, Medicare is a single-payer system covering many of the health costs of older
Americans. (Canada's universal single-payer system is, in fact, also called
Medicare.) And it has some though not all the advantages of broader single-payer
systems, notably low administrative costs.

But in adding a drug benefit to Medicare, the Bush administration and its allies in
Congress were driven both by a desire to appease the insurance and
pharmaceutical lobbies and by an ideology that insists on the superiority of the
private sector even when the public sector has demonstrably lower costs. So they
devised a plan that works very differently from traditional Medicare. In fact,
Medicare Part D, the drug benefit, isn't a program in which the government
provides drug insurance. It's a program in which private insurance companies
receive subsidies to offer insurance—and seniors aren't allowed to deal directly
with Medicare.

The insertion of private intermediaries into the program has several unfortunate
consequences. First, as millions of seniors have discovered, it makes the system
extremely complex and obscure. It's virtually impossible for most people to figure
out which of the many drug plans now on offer is best. This complexity, coupled
with the Katrina-like obliviousness of administration officials to a widely
predicted disaster, also led to the program's catastrophic initial failure to manage
the problem of "dual eligibles," i.e., older Medicaid recipients whose drug
coverage was supposed to be transferred to Medicare. When the program started
up in January, hundreds of thousands of these dual eligibles found that they had
fallen through the cracks, that their old coverage had been canceled but their new
coverage had not been put into effect.

Second, the private intermediaries add substantial administrative costs to the


program. It's reasonably certain that if seniors had been offered the choice of
receiving a straightforward drug benefit directly from Medicare, the vast majority
would have chosen to pass up the private drug plans, which wouldn't have been
able to offer comparable benefits because of their administrative expenses. But
the drug bill avoided that embarrassing outcome by denying seniors that choice.
Finally, by fragmenting the purchase of drugs among many private plans, the
administration denied Medicare the ability to bargain for lower prices from the
drug companies. And the legislation, reflecting pressures from those companies,
included a provision specifically prohibiting Medicare from intervening to help
the private plans get lower prices.

In short, ideology and interest groups led the Bush administration to set up a
new, costly Medicare benefit in such a way as to systematically forfeit all the
advantages of public health insurance.

6.
Beyond reform: How much health care should we have?

Imagine, for a moment, that some future US administration were to push


through a fundamental reform of health care that covered all the uninsured,
replaced private insurance with a single-payer system, and took heed of the VA's
lessons about the advantages of integrated health care. Would our health care
problems be solved?

No. Although real reform would bring great improvement in our situation,
continuing technological progress in health care still poses a deep dilemma: How
much of what we can do should we do?

The medical profession, understandably, has a bias toward doing whatever will
bring medical benefit. If that means performing an expensive surgical procedure
on an elderly patient who probably has only a few years to live, so be it. But as
medical technology advances, it becomes possible to spend ever larger sums on
medically useful care. Indeed, at some point it will become possible to spend the
entire GDP on health care. Obviously, we won't do this. But how will we make
choices about what not to do?

In a classic 1984 book, Painful Prescription: Rationing Hospital Care, Henry


Aaron and William Schwartz studied the medical choices made by the British
system, which has long operated under tight budget limits that force it to make
hard choices in a way that US medical care does not. Can We Say No? is an
update of that work. It's a valuable survey of the real medical issues involved in
British rationing, and gives a taste of the dilemmas the US system will eventually
face.

The operative word, however, is "eventually." Reading Can We Say No?, one
might come away with the impression that the problem of how to ration care is
the central issue in current health care policy. This impression is reinforced by
Aaron and his co-authors' decision to compare the US system only with that of
Britain, which spends far less on health care than other advanced countries, and
correspondingly is forced to do a lot of rationing. A comparison with, say, France,
which spends far less than the United States but considerably more than Britain,
would give a very different impression: in many respects France consumes more,
not less, health care than the United States, but it can do so at lower cost because
our system is so inefficient.

The result of Aaron et al.'s single-minded focus on the problem of rationing is a


somewhat skewed perspective on current policy issues. Most notably, they argue
that the reason we need universal health coverage is that a universal system can
ration care in a way that private insurance can't. This seems to miss the two main
immediate arguments for universal care—that it would cover those now
uninsured, and that it would be cheaper than our current system. A national
health care system will also be better at rationing when the time comes, but that
hardly seems like the prime argument for adopting such a system today.

Our Princeton colleague Uwe Reinhardt, a leading economic expert on health


care, put it this way: our focus right now should be on eliminating the gross
inefficiencies we know exist in the US health care system. If we do that, we will be
able to cover the uninsured while spending less than we do now. Only then
should we address the issue of what not to do; that's tomorrow's issue, not
today's.

7.
Can we fix health care?

Health policy experts know a lot more about the economics of health care now
than they did when Bill Clinton tried to remake the US health care system. And
there's overwhelming evidence that the United States could get better health care
at lower cost if we were willing to put that knowledge into practice. But the
political obstacles remain daunting.

A mere shift of power from Republicans to Democrats would not, in itself, be


enough to give us sensible health care reform. While Democrats would have
written a less perverse drug bill, it's not clear that they are ready to embrace a
single-payer system. Even liberal economists and scholars at progressive think
tanks tend to shy away from proposing a straightforward system of national
health insurance. Instead, they propose fairly complex compromise plans.
Typically, such plans try to achieve universal coverage by requiring everyone to
buy health insurance, the way everyone is forced to buy car insurance, and deal
with those who can't afford to purchase insurance through a system of subsidies.
Proponents of such plans make a few arguments for their superiority to a single-
payer system, mainly the (dubious) claim that single-payer would reduce medical
innovation. But the main reason for not proposing single-payer is political fear:
reformers believe that private insurers are too powerful to cut out of the loop, and
that a single-payer plan would be too easily demonized by business and political
propagandists as "big government."

These are the same political calculations that led Bill Clinton to reject a single-
payer system in 1993, even though his advisers believed that a single-payer
system would be the least expensive way to provide universal coverage. Instead,
he proposed a complex plan designed to preserve a role for private health
insurers. But the plan backfired. The insurers opposed it anyway, most famously
with their "Harry and Louise" ads. And the plan's complexity left the public
baffled.

We believe that the compromise plans being proposed by the cautious reformers
would run into the same political problems, and that it would be politically
smarter as well as economically superior to go for broke: to propose a
straightforward single-payer system, and try to sell voters on the huge advantages
such a sys-tem would bring. But this would mean taking on the drug and insur-
ance companies rather than trying to co-opt them, and even progressive policy
wonks, let alone Democratic politicians, still seem too timid to do that.

So what will really happen to American health care? Many people in this field
believe that in the end America will end up with national health insurance, and
perhaps with a lot of direct government provision of health care, simply because
nothing else works. But things may have to get much worse before reality can
break through the combination of powerful interest groups and free-market
ideology.

—February 22, 2006

Email to a friend

Notes

[1]
"America's Senior Moment," The New York Review, March 10, 2005.
Cathy Schoen, Robin Osborn, Phuong Trang Huynh, Michelle Doty, Kinga
[2]

Zapert, Jordon Peugh, and Karen Davis, "Taking the Pulse of Health Care
Systems: Experiences of Patients with Health Problems in Six Countries," Health
Affairs Web exclusive, November 3, 2005.

Gerard F. Anderson, Peter S. Hussey, Bianca K. Frogner, and Hugh R. Waters,


[3]

"Health Spending in the United States and the Rest of the Industrialized World,"
Health Affairs, Vol. 24, No. 4 (July/August 2005), pp. 903–914.

"Medicaid: A Lower-Cost Approach to Serving a High-Cost Population," policy


[4]

brief by the Kaiser Commission on Medicaid and the Uninsured, March 2004.

You might also like