The document discusses the causes of the 2008 financial crisis. It explains that a surge in subprime lending, fueled by relaxed lending standards, led to a housing bubble. As risky mortgages were packaged and sold globally, investors' risk aversion declined too far. When the bubble burst and housing prices declined, widespread foreclosures and defaults on mortgages triggered the crisis. The Federal Reserve and Treasury took unprecedented steps to contain the damage, but their actions may have created new risks for the future.
The document discusses the causes of the 2008 financial crisis. It explains that a surge in subprime lending, fueled by relaxed lending standards, led to a housing bubble. As risky mortgages were packaged and sold globally, investors' risk aversion declined too far. When the bubble burst and housing prices declined, widespread foreclosures and defaults on mortgages triggered the crisis. The Federal Reserve and Treasury took unprecedented steps to contain the damage, but their actions may have created new risks for the future.
The document discusses the causes of the 2008 financial crisis. It explains that a surge in subprime lending, fueled by relaxed lending standards, led to a housing bubble. As risky mortgages were packaged and sold globally, investors' risk aversion declined too far. When the bubble burst and housing prices declined, widespread foreclosures and defaults on mortgages triggered the crisis. The Federal Reserve and Treasury took unprecedented steps to contain the damage, but their actions may have created new risks for the future.
The document discusses the causes of the 2008 financial crisis. It explains that a surge in subprime lending, fueled by relaxed lending standards, led to a housing bubble. As risky mortgages were packaged and sold globally, investors' risk aversion declined too far. When the bubble burst and housing prices declined, widespread foreclosures and defaults on mortgages triggered the crisis. The Federal Reserve and Treasury took unprecedented steps to contain the damage, but their actions may have created new risks for the future.
Response, and Consequences Lyle E. Gramley * T o anyone other than an economist, economics tends to be a fairly dull subject. But to make it a bit more interesting, I have a story to tell. If you dont remember anything else I say, you will probably remember this story. A young lad goes to see his father, and he says, Daddy, can you explain to me how the economy works? Oh yes, my son, Ill be happy to do that. Every morning, I go to work in our family-owned business. All of our family money is tied up in that business. That, my son, is capital. You notice that things work smoothly around the house. When it is time to eat, food is on the table. When you need some clean clothes, just open your drawers; they are all laid out for you. That requires management. Your mother supplies the management. We have a maid who does the housework, the dishes, and the laundry. That, my son, is labor. When you were born some ten years ago, that was productivity. When your baby brother was born just a few months ago, that was the future. That, my son, is how the economy works. The young lad couldnt fgure out a thing from this story. But a few days later, something happened that made everything clear. He heard his baby brother crying. So, he went down to see what was wrong, and as he entered the babys room, his nose told him that the babys diaper needed changing. He went to fnd his mother, but she was fast asleep. He knew that if he awakened her, she would be very angry. So, he went to the other end of the house to the maids room, and the door was closed. He knocked, and he knocked, and he knocked. Finally, the door opened. There stood his father in a rather disheveled condition. His father snapped, What do you want? The young man said, The babys diaper needs changing. Dont bother me with that! scolded his father, as he whacked him on the bottom and closed the door. With that, the economics lesson was perfectly clear. When management sleeps, capital takes advantage of labor, productivity suffers, and the future stinks. Like Hernando de Soto, I will also discuss the fnancial crisis. My story is going to * Lyle Gramley (51) is senior economic advisor to Soleil Securities Group. From 197780 Mr. Gramley served as a member of the Presidents Council of Economic Advisors, and from 198085 he served as a member of the Federal Reserve Board of Governors. THE ANNUAL PROCEEDINGS OF THE WEALTH AND WELL-BEING OF NATIONS 136 sound rather different from Mr. de Sotos, but our stories are not competitive; they are complementary. It is certainly true that the lack of information on who owned what made the crisis much more severe. But I will discuss developments in the mortgage market that were the trigger for the 2008 fnancial crisis, steps that were taken by the Federal Reserve and the Treasury to contain the damage, and then to the potential problems those steps have created for the future. In the frst few charts I present here, many of the fgures are truncated at 2006 so that we can see what the world looked like leading up to the crisis. Beginning around the middle of 1990 and continuing for a decade or more, we had an enormous increase in the demand for homes. We added approximately twelve million new households to the ranks of homeowners (see Figure 1). One of the reasons for this increase in demand for homes was the fact that mortgage interest rates were relatively low (see Figure 2). But I think the far more important contributor to the increased demand was an unprecedented expansion in the availability of credit to immigrants, to minorities, and to people in lower- and middle-income brackets. I am speaking here of individuals who were borrowing in the subprime mortgage market. Although the housing stock is very large, it is relatively fxed. If we have a signifcant increase in demand and the stock is fxed, prices are going to rise. Housing prices rose relative to median incomes (see Figure 3). Under normal circumstances, we would have expected the increase in prices to cut off the boom, because higher prices mean lower affordability. But that was countered by a progressive relaxation of mortgage standards, so the boom went on. First, I will describe how subprime lending came to play a dominant role in the housing market. Subprime loans have been around for a long time. They are simply loans available at higher interest rates to more risky borrowers. But government interest in promoting home ownership has been a factor. In 1979, Congress passed the Community Reinvestment Act, and the Act was strengthened in 1993. The Community Reinvestment Act encourages federal depository institutions to lend in communities from which they have received deposits. But the word encourages is perhaps not strong enough to describe the impact. An institution that is a federally regulated depository institution has to set goals for the proportion of its loans that go to low- and middle-income borrowers and to minorities, with those goals refecting the demographic characteristics of the area it serves. If the institution fails to take those goals seriously, it is marked down on its examination report. Perhaps it is only a slight exaggeration, therefore, to say that the U.S. Government is one of the offcial sponsors of subprime lending. Another contributor was the demise of the Savings and Loan (S&L) industry in the late 1980s and early 1990s. Savings & Loans were portfolio lenders, making loans and holding them in portfolios; they took all the risk. That tends to focus the mind and keep one prudent. Leadership at mortgage lending passed to mortgage banks, which had very little skin in the game, and to mortgage brokers who had none at all. It is very easy for mortgage lenders to become more lax in lending standards if the trend is going in this direction. Unlike S&Ls, mortgage banks sell these loans in the secondary market. We needed 137 a sizeable secondary market to absorb all those mortgages being generated, but that had been developing for some time. Indeed it had become the principal source of capital to fnance household debt. The government had a role to play here, too, through the government-sponsored enterprises, particularly Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. The growing use of the Internet to obtain mortgages also played a role because that made for a national mortgage market. If an individual whose local lender didnt offer the kind of terms he thought were appropriate, he could search the Internet and fnd someone who would make a loan with a lower rate or easier terms. We had to have a substantial infow of funds to fnance this surge in mortgages. Much of it was coming from funds abroad, generated by a glut of savings internationally, particularly in the emerging nations of Asia. And then we had to have a decline in risk aversion, as these products were becoming riskier and riskier. Indeed, by the end of 2006, investors were buying garbage and begging for more. Figure 4 illustrates the decline in risk aversion, which shows the yield spread between junk bonds and 10-year Treasuries. This spread is a refection of the risk that investors perceive, for which they require compensation. A normal spread is approximately six to eight percentage points. By the middle 2000s, it was down to half of that or less. Ironically, there was some basis for decline in risk aversion because the world appeared to be becoming a more stable place. If we consider real GDP in the United States (see Figure 5), we see that after the middle 1980s, recessions (shown by the shaded vertical lines) were less frequent and much shorter. Infation, which had been a signifcant problem in the 1970s, was brought under control. More stable economies were characteristic abroad as well as at home, and infation came down everywhere. This period has been called the Great Moderation. But, of course, the decline in risk aversion went much too far. Looking back, it is diffcult to understand why smart people did not fgure out that something funny was going on. A few lonely souls did foresee the problems ahead, but they were very few and very lonely, and no one paid much attention. On the other hand, the list of those who didnt fgure it out was very long indeed. The list includes economists (I am one of them), mortgage lenders, credit agencies, investors (not just in the United States, but abroad as well), the Federal Reserve, the Treasury, and central banks and fnance ministries all around the world. None of us saw this happening. Understandably, you may ask, How could people have been so blind? Well, things looked a little different during this period. Consider, for example, delinquency and foreclosure rates for all mortgages (Figures 6a and 6b, respectively), and delinquency and foreclosure rates for the most toxic products, adjustable rate subprime mortgages (Figures 6c and 6d, respectively). In 2006, delinquency and foreclosure rates were still below where they had been about fve years earlier, and indeed, for the adjustable rate subprime mortgages, the foreclosure rate was signifcantly below what it had been fve years earlier. But probably the most diffcult problem of interpretation in this period was what to make of the signifcant run up in home prices. Figures 7a7c show the three major home price indices provided by the National Association of Realtors. Although we experienced a severe recession from 1973 to 1975 and a severe recession with THE 2008 FINANCIAL CRISIS: CAUSES, RESPONSE, AND CONSEQUENCES THE ANNUAL PROCEEDINGS OF THE WEALTH AND WELL-BEING OF NATIONS 138 extremely high interest rates in the early 1980s, we never experienced a signifcant decline in home prices nationally. People somehow convinced themselves that a fall in home prices simply wasnt going to happenthat it couldnt happen. There seemed to be something about the housing market that was differentthat we were not going to experience a signifcant drop in home prices. The house of cards began to collapse in early 2007 with failures of large frms in the subprime market. It spread from the subprime market to other areas in the mortgage market in the second quarter, and from there to other fnancial sectors in the third quarter, and around the globe. I thought it might be interesting to see if we could quantify how serious this fnancial crisis was, and I thought of two ways, which I describe below. The Federal Reserve Bank in Kansas City has constructed a Financial Stress Index (FSI). On the left-hand side of Figure 8, notice the increase in the FSI. This was the credit crunch of 199091. At that time, Chairman Alan Greenspan of the Federal Reserve said it posed ffty-mile-an-hour headwinds through the economy. Those headwinds created a mild recession. Later, we had another increase in the FSI in the fourth quarter of 1998, associated with the failure of Long-Term Capital Management. In late 2008, the level of fnancial stress was literally seven times what it had been in the credit crunch of 1991. Seven times as high. Another way of quantifying the magnitude of the fnancial crisis is to look at business and consumer borrowing (see Figure 9). In the credit crunch of 199091 and the recession that accompanied it, the annual rate of business and consumer borrowing declined by $500 billion. In the credit crunch of 2007 to 2009, and the recession that ensued, business and consumer borrowing fell $2.7 trillion. It was a fnancial tsunami that hit the United States and the rest of the globe. It threatened to push our economy into another Great Depression. Figure 10 illustrates further that this recession has been the deepest and longest in recent history. Housing starts declined by 75 percent. We had never seen anything like this before. Payroll employment to date has declined 7.2 million (see Figure 11). That decline is continuing. The median duration of unemployment increased to eighteen weeks, 50 percent higher than anything we had seen previously (see Figure 12). Household net worth declined by $14 trillion, roughly 25 percent, although we have gained some of that back again (see Figure 13). I want to discuss now some of the steps that we took to moderate the crisis. Figure 14 summarizes some of what the Fed has done in response to the crisis. 1 The 1 There are two books that I would recommend that help us to understand these events. The frst is called Lords of Finance by Liaquat Ahamed. Lords of Finance is about the four great central bankers of the frst half of the twentieth century: Benjamin Strong of the Federal Re- serve Bank of New York, Montague Norman of the Bank of England, Emile Moreau of the Banque de France, and Hjalmar Schacht of the German Reichsbank. The story is how these four central bankersgreat though they werefollowing the monetary orthodoxy of their time, pushed the global economy into the Great Depression. The second book is In Fed We Trust, by David Wessel of The Wall Street Journal. It is a story about how the Federal Reserve, 139 frst item on that list, reducing short-term interest rates to near-zero, has been an aggressive move in what we would consider traditional monetary policychanging the short-term interest rates to either invigorate or slow down the economy. But when the fnancial markets are frozen up, conventional monetary policy will not do very much. The Fed was forced to innovate to get things going in credit markets that were essentially not functioning at all. For example, the Fed created the Primary Dealer Credit Facility. When Bear Stearns began to fail and was merged into JP Morgan in March of 2008, the large investment banks in New York fnally couldnt borrow at all. They typically fnanced themselves short-term. The only way for them to gain access to money now was to sell long-term securities. This would have aggravated the crisis by putting downward pressure on securities markets. In response, the Fed created for the frst time an opportunity for large investment banks to borrow directly at the Federal Reserve. The Commercial Paper Facility was another important innovation. With the failure of Lehman Brothers in September of 2008, commercial paper frms that typically fnanced inventories, payroll, and receivables by issuing commercial paper for three to six months, found that they couldnt fnd fnancing for longer than overnight. Some couldnt fnance themselves at all. The Federal Reserve created a facility by which they could borrow directly from the Federal Reserve to fnance themselves. These kinds of operations required use of Section 13-3a of the Federal Reserve Act, which permits the Federal Reserve to loan to any individual, partnership, or corporation under unusual exigent circumstances. That clause was used over and over again in the lending areas that I mentioned here. All in all, the Fed put out about $1.7 trillion in loans. Many of those loans have been paid back at this point. From late 200809, the Fed also began to buy long-term treasury securities, agency issues, and mortgage-backed securities to try to invigorate the housing market. So far, they have purchased almost a trillion dollars worth of those securities. The program for buying long-term Treasury securities ended in October 2009, and the program for buying agency debt and mortgage-backed securities ends in September 2010. In this process, the Fed has been accused of doing things that it should not have done. Congress is unhappy about the fact that the Fed has put considerable sums of taxpayers money at risk. But there was no clear alternative. The Fed had to act quickly and could not wait for Congress to decide what to do. The criticism has been made that the Fed was engaged in adhockerythat it had no overall plan for how it was going to deal with the crisis. But Fed offcials never knew from one day to the next what was going to happen. They had no choice but to do whatever it took to prevent utter disaster. The Federal government, under both the Bush and Obama administrations, took important actions as well (see Figure 15), including injecting equity capital in banks; taking over Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac; increasing deposit insurance from $100,000 and to some degree the Treasury, followed quite different policies and kept us from slipping into a depression. THE 2008 FINANCIAL CRISIS: CAUSES, RESPONSE, AND CONSEQUENCES THE ANNUAL PROCEEDINGS OF THE WEALTH AND WELL-BEING OF NATIONS 140 per account to $250, 000 per account in an attempt to stabilize confdence; extending deposit insurance to money market mutual funds when a run had developed in the fall of 2008; through the FDIC, providing loan guarantees so that banks could issue medium-term debt; adopting a fscal stimulus program equal to one-half of one percent of GDP; and providing loans to auto producers and assistance to the housing industry. These same kinds of things were going on abroad as well as at home. Many countries rescued their banking systems. Many countries adopted fscal stimulus programs and, in many cases, on a scale much larger than in the United States. Ireland, for example, nationalized its entire banking system. China adopted a stimulus program, which, relative to the size of its economy, was 2.5 times as large as the U.S. stimulus program. But it worked. We are seeing signs of recovery now, both in the United States and in the global economy. In the third quarter of 2009, real GDP rose at a 3.5 percent annual rate. At this point, there were many questions about whether or not we were really experiencing a recovery. Figures 16a16d show a number of reliable indicators that have convinced me that we are in a recovery. We have had a signifcant decline in initial claims for unemployment insurance (see Figure 16a). We have had six months in a row of increases in the index of leading economic indicators (see Figure 16b). The Industrial Supply Management (ISM) Composite Index for manufacturing and nonmanufacturing (see Figures 16c and 16d, respectively) have now moved up to over ffty, which is the breaking point between expansion and contraction. In my mind, there is really no question anymore of whether we are in a recovery we are. The question now is, what kind of a recovery is it going to be? My view which is also the consensus viewis that this is going to be a very moderate recovery by postwar standards. Normally, we expect real GDP to increase by about 6 percent in the frst year of recovery. We will be lucky if it does half that well. There are two major reasons for this. First, fnancial markets have been healing, and this process continues, but it is not over yet. In Figure 17, we can see that the interest rate spread between corporate Baa issues and ten-year Treasury issues is still 3 percentage pointsa lot lower than the 6 percentage points at the peak of the crisis, but not down to the 1.5 to 2 percentage point fgure that we normally see. Investors are still reluctant to lend. The monthly data on bank loans to businesses and consumers (see Figure 18) is still falling more rapidly than anything we have seen in the entire postwar period. We know from studies by economists Rogoff and Reinhartstudies of major fnancial crises in other countriesthat it often takes three years before real GDP returns to the pre-crisis level. As Rogoff and Reinhart say, there is no reason why it wont happen here. The second reason for a moderate recovery is the state of the consumer. The typical consumer still has a lot of debt. His wealth is greatly reduced from where it was. But the major problem is that he doesnt have the income to spend aggressively. Real aggregate wages and salaries are still declining because of the drop-off in employment and the moderation of wage rates (see Figure 19). Consumers now are a much more disciplined group than they were a few years ago. They have learned 141 that they cannot count on increases in the value of their 401K or the value in their home to provide all the funds they need for their retirement years, for educating their children, and so on. They have to do some of the hard lifting themselves, and the savings rate is moving up (see Figure 20). But now because markets are improving, we are beginning to worry about infation. We need to break down the thinking about infation into two parts: 1) what is going to happen in the next several years, and 2) what might happen in the longer run? Unit labor costs and consumer prices are closely tied together (see Figure 21). They have to be. If consumer prices were to rise much more rapidly than unit labor costs, corporate profts would soar. If consumer prices were to rise signifcantly slower than unit labor costs, corporate profts would collapse. In considering unit labor costs (see Figure 22), what we see is that they are in negative territory because productivity is doing very well, and compensation per hour is moderating (see Figures 23 and 24, respectively). And all the signs are that this is continuing. The GDP fgures for the third quarter of 2009 imply a large increase in productivity in that quartersomewhere between 7 and 8 percent at an annual rate. The year-over- year number in productivity in the third quarter will be somewhere between 3.5 and 4 percent. As long as we have a moderate recovery with continued high unemployment, unpleasant though that may be, it is going to mean a very low-infation environment. But we do have to wonder about what may lie ahead given what has happened in terms of monetary and fscal policy. We have an enormous federal defcit. Figure 25 shows that the Administrations outlook for 2019 is a defcit equal to 4 percent of the GDP, which is almost as large as anything we have seen in any time in the postwar periodand Administration fgures are always overoptimistic. We have a Federal Reserve balance sheet that has increased from approximately $800 billion in August of 2008 to over $2 trillion at the present (see Figure 26). This has created a signifcant increase in bank reserves, but has not created a signifcant increase in the money supply. As seen in Figure 27, M2 is growing at less than 7 percent a year because most bank reserves are primarily held as excess reserves. The level of excess reserves in August of 2008 was about $2 billion. It is now over $800 billion (see Figure 28). If those excess reserves were suddenly and dramatically converted to loans and securities, M2 would explode and we would have infationary problems. The Fed does, however, have an exit strategy. The Fed will need to shrink the balance sheet and raise interest rates to normal levels. (For a summary of the Federal Reserves exist strategy, see Figure 29). That cannot start now because the economy still needs nourishment. Some of the shrinking of the balance sheet will occur as loans are automatically paid down as fnancial markets improve, and that process has begun. Some of it will occur when these special lending facilities are closed as markets begin to function normally. The Fed has told us that it is going to rely heavily on reverse repurchase agreements. Repurchase agreements have been in use for a long time to add to the bank reserves; reverse repurchase agreements would subtract from bank reserves, but they have never been used on a large scale before. The Fed is engaging in conversations with market participants about how that will work. THE 2008 FINANCIAL CRISIS: CAUSES, RESPONSE, AND CONSEQUENCES THE ANNUAL PROCEEDINGS OF THE WEALTH AND WELL-BEING OF NATIONS 142 The most important tool that the Fed has to keep infation under control is a new tool: payment of interest on reserves. The Fed is now paying interest of of one percent on reserves that banks hold with it. When the time comes to raise the federal funds rate, that rate on reserves will be raised as well. What that means is that no bank will want to lend in the federal funds market at less than what they can earn with the Fed, because they would be taking some risk by doing so. But the concern remains that banks may still fuel infation if they see attractive opportunities to make loans or buy securities. The Fed has an answer for that as well. The Fed is going to offer longer-term depositswith maturities of a month, three months, or six monthsat higher interest rates to discourage acquisition of loans or securities from taking place at too rapid a pace. These are new policy instruments that have never before been used. The room for policy error is greater, to be sure, but it is not rocket science. The Feds argument is that the decisions that have to be made are basically the same kind that are always requireddetermining when it is time to start tightening up monetary policy and how fast to do it. We also need an exit strategy for the federal defcit. The Administration has said that it will put forth a solid plan to reduce the defcit longer run in connection with the next budget. Lets hope it does. If it doesnt, will this mean infation? We have a big defcit; does that necessarily mean infation? Not at all. Defcits mean infation only if the debt is monetized. The Fed has told us in no uncertain terms that the debt will not be monetized. But if we have big defcits and we dont monetize them, that will mean very high real interest rates. And that will be extremely damaging to the housing market, to business investment and productivity, and to the long-term growth of the economy. Thus it is essential that the Obama Administration does indeed come through with a meaningful defcit-reduction plan. There is one other area that requires attention, and that is the regulatory reform of fnancial institutions. (For a summary of necessary regulatory reforms, see Figure 30.) The list of what needs to be done in this area is not extensive, but a few things stand out as particularly important. We are certainly going to have to bring nonbank fnancial institutions that are large enough to create systemic risk under the umbrella of federal supervision. We are going to have to have signifcantly higher capital requirements. An interesting idea is to make capital requirements a function of the degree of systemic risk that the institution creates. We need procedures for managing failures of nonbank fnancial institutions other than letting them go bankrupt something like what we do for banks with the FDIC. We need compensation systems that discourage excessive risk taking and a consumer protection agency that will police the marketing of credit to consumers. If we do all of these things, will that guarantee that we are not going to have another fnancial crisis? Hardly. But it is certainly less likely and it gives us better tools to deal with the crisis if one comes. 143 Figure 1 Figure 2 Figure 3 THE 2008 FINANCIAL CRISIS: CAUSES, RESPONSE, AND CONSEQUENCES THE ANNUAL PROCEEDINGS OF THE WEALTH AND WELL-BEING OF NATIONS 144 Figure 6a Figure 4 Figure 5 145 Figure 6b Figure 6c Figure 6d THE 2008 FINANCIAL CRISIS: CAUSES, RESPONSE, AND CONSEQUENCES THE ANNUAL PROCEEDINGS OF THE WEALTH AND WELL-BEING OF NATIONS 146 Figure 7c Figure 7a Figure 7b 147 Figure 8 Figure 9 Figure 10 THE 2008 FINANCIAL CRISIS: CAUSES, RESPONSE, AND CONSEQUENCES THE ANNUAL PROCEEDINGS OF THE WEALTH AND WELL-BEING OF NATIONS 148 Figure 13 Figure 11 Figure 12 149 Figure 14 Actions Taken by the Federal Reserve Reduced short-term interest rates to near zero Created a Term Auction Facility Increased swap lines with foreign central banks Assisted in the bailout of Bear Stearns and AIG Created a Primary Dealer Credit Facility Created a Term Securities Lending Facility Created a Commercial Paper Funding Facility Created a facility to assist money market mutual funds Created a Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility Purchased large quantities of long-term Treasury securities, agency debt and mortgage-backed securities THE 2008 FINANCIAL CRISIS: CAUSES, RESPONSE, AND CONSEQUENCES Figure 15 Actions Taken by the Federal Government Injected equity capital into banks Took over Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac Increased deposit insurance to $250,000 per account Extended deposit insurance to money market mutual funds Provided loan guarantees for newly-issued bank debt Adopted a fscal stimulus program amounting to one-half percent of GDP Provided loans to domestic auto producers Adopted measures to help stabilize the housing industry THE ANNUAL PROCEEDINGS OF THE WEALTH AND WELL-BEING OF NATIONS 150 Figure 16a Figure 16b Figure 16c 151 THE 2008 FINANCIAL CRISIS: CAUSES, RESPONSE, AND CONSEQUENCES Figure 18 Figure 16d Figure 17 THE ANNUAL PROCEEDINGS OF THE WEALTH AND WELL-BEING OF NATIONS 152 Figure 19 Figure 20 Figure 21 153 Figure 24 Figure 22 Figure 23 THE 2008 FINANCIAL CRISIS: CAUSES, RESPONSE, AND CONSEQUENCES THE ANNUAL PROCEEDINGS OF THE WEALTH AND WELL-BEING OF NATIONS 154 Figure 25 Figure 26 Figure 27 155 Figure 28 THE 2008 FINANCIAL CRISIS: CAUSES, RESPONSE, AND CONSEQUENCES THE ANNUAL PROCEEDINGS OF THE WEALTH AND WELL-BEING OF NATIONS 156 Figure 30 Regulatory Reform of Financial Institutions Nonbank fnancial institutions posing potential systemic risk will be subject to supervision and regulation similar to banks Capital requirements will be raised and designed to discourage excessive risk taking Capital requirements may be based on the systemic importance of frms Procedures will be developed for managing failures of nonbank fnancial institutions similar to those employed by the FDIC for banks Compensation systems will be regulated to discourage excessive risk taking A consumer protection agency will police marketing of credit to consumers Figure 29 The Federal Reserves Exit Strategy The Fed needs to do two things: Shrink the balance sheet to reduce bank reserves Raise interest rates to normal levels Shrinking the balance sheet: Loans will be paid down automatically as fnancial conditions improve Special lending facilities will be closed Reverse repurchase agreements will be used Long-term securities can be sold if necessary Interest paid on reserves will be employed to pin in excess reserves: Rate paid on demand deposits will be raised with the federal funds rate Longer-term deposits at higher rates will be offered to control the rate at which excess reserves are put to work by banks making loans or acquiring securities
The Wall Street Journal Guide to the End of Wall Street as We Know It: What You Need to Know About the Greatest Financial Crisis of Our Time—and How to Survive It