ShahWaliAllahtheMughalsandtheByzantines20141 PDF
ShahWaliAllahtheMughalsandtheByzantines20141 PDF
ShahWaliAllahtheMughalsandtheByzantines20141 PDF
of Empires: Shh Wal Allh of Delhi, the Mughals, and the Byzantines
Vasileios Syros
Access provided by Freie Universitaet Berlin (27 May 2013 18:28 GMT)
An Early Modern South Asian Thinker
on the Rise and Decline of Empires:
Shāh Walı̄ Allāh of Delhi, the Mughals,
and the Byzantines *
vasileios syros
Finnish Center of Political Thought
and Conceptual Change/
Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin
Ihuman
n the eighteenth century, Western intellectual history witnessed
the production of a rich body of writing on the origins and decay of
civilization and the emergence and fall of empires, exemplified
by such monumental works as Baron de Montesquieu’s (1689–1755)
Considérations sur les causes de la grandeur des Romains et de leur déca-
dence (Reflections on the Causes of the Greatness of the Romans and
Their Decline, 1734), Giambattista Vico’s (1668–1744) Scienza Nuova
(New Science, 1745), and Edward Gibbon’s (1737–1794) History of
the Decline and Fall of the Roman Empire (1776–1788). The quest to
identify the forces that shape social evolution and the factors involved
in the formation and decline of the state is not a phenomenon unique
to the Western intellectual scene, however. In the eighteenth-century
Mughal context, Shāh Walī Allāh Dihlawī (1703–1762), an emi-
nent Sufi and theologian, propounded a theory of civilization and the
* Thanks are due to Muzaffar Alam, Razi Aquil, Christos Baloglou, Jonathan Har-
ris, Anthony Kaldellis, Dimitris Krallis, and Niketas Siniossoglou for reading drafts of the
paper and offering valuable feedback. I would also like to acknowledge the financial support
provided by the Centre of Excellence in Political Thought and Conceptual Change of the
Academy of Finland (2008–2011) and the Marty Martin Center for the Advanced Study of
Religion at the University of Chicago (2010/2011).
793
794 journal of world history, december 2012
1
For an intriguing comparison of Shāh Walī Allāh’s and Jean-Jacques Rousseau’s
(1712–1778) ideas, see Jacques Berque, L’islam au temps du monde (Paris: Sindbad, 1984),
chap. “Un contemporain islamo-indien de Jean-Jacques Rousseau,” pp. 113–146. Early
modern European perceptions of the Mughal Empire are surveyed in Frederick G. Whelan,
Enlightenment Political Thought and Non-Western Societies: Sultans and Savages (New York:
Routledge, 2009), esp. chap. “Burke, India, and Orientalism,” pp. 103–129.
2
On Shāh Walī Allāh’s life and works, see Mawlavi M. Hidayat Husain, “The Persian
Autobiography of Shāh Walīullah bin ‘Abd al-Raḥīm al-Dihlavī: Its English Translation
and a List of His Works,” Journal of the Asiatic Society of Bengal 8 (1912): 161–175; as well
as Jens Bakker, Šāh Walīy Allāh ad-Dihlawīy (1703–1762) und sein Aufenthalt in Mekka und
Medina: Ein Beitrag zur Erforschung des islamischen Reformdenkens im frühen 18. Jahrhundert
(Berlin: EB-Verleg, 2010); Ghulam H. Jalbani, Life of Shah Waliyullah (Lahore: Sh. Muham-
mad Ashraf, 1978); Fazle Mahmud, “An Exhaustive Study of the Life of Shah Wali Allah
Dehlavi,” Oriental College Magazine 33 (1956): 1–45; as well as the following articles in
M. Ikram Chaghatai, ed., Shah Waliullah (1703–1762): His Religious and Political Thought
(Lahore: Sang-e-Meel Publications, 2005; henceforth SWRPT): Marcia K. Hermansen,
“Shāh Walī Allāh” (pp. 11–14); A. S. Bazmee Ansari, “Shah Wali Allah al-Dihlawi” (pp.
15–18); Bashir A. Dar, “Wali Allah: His Life and Times” (pp. 19–50; first published in Iqbal
Review 6, no. 3 [1965]: 1–36); Abdul H. Siddiqi, “Shah Wali Allah Dihlawi” (pp. 51–77;
first published in Mian M. Sharif, ed., A History of Muslim Philosophy: With Short Accounts of
Other Disciplines and the Modern Renaissance in Muslim Lands [Wiesbaden: O. Harrassowitz,
1966], 2:1557–1579); and Alessandro Bausani, “Note su Shāh Walīullāh di Delhi (1703–
1762),” Annali dell’ Istituto Orientale di Napoli, n.s., 10 (1960): 93–147. Also broadly on the
intellectual climate in Shāh Walī Allāh’s time, consult Saiyid A. A. Rizvi, Shāh Walī-Allāh
and His Times: A Study of Eighteenth Century Islām, Politics and Society in India (Canberra:
Ma’rifat Publishing House, 1980), esp. pp. 111–202; and, in general, Peter J. Marshall, ed.,
The Eighteenth Century in Indian History: Evolution or Revolution? (New Delhi: Oxford Uni-
versity Press, 2003); Seema Alavi, ed., The Eighteenth Century in India (New Delhi: Oxford
University Press, 2002).
3
Shāh Walī Allāh ibn ‘Abd al-Raḥīm, Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, 2 vols. (Cairo: Dār
al-Turāth, 1978); English trans.: The Conclusive Argument from God: Shāh Walī Allāh of
Delhi’s Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bāligha, trans. Marcia K. Hermansen (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1996; repr.,
Syros: The Rise and Decline of Empires 795
Islamabad: International Islamic University, Islamic Research Institute, 2003). I have relied
on the English translations of some of the Arabic, Persian, and Byzantine sources mentioned
throughout this paper with some amendments not indicated due to space limitations. On
the Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, see the following chapters in SWRPT: Marcia K. Hermansen,
“Shah Wali Allah’s Hujjat Allah al-Baligha” (pp. 529–552); Hermansen, “Shāh Walī Allāh
of Delhi’s Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bāligha: Tension between the Universal and the Particular in an
Eighteenth-Century Islamic Theory of Religious Revelation” (pp. 597–614; first published
in Studia Islamica 63 [1986]: 143–157); Sabih A. Kamali, “The Concept of Human Nature
in Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah and Its Relation to Shāh Walīy Allāh’s Doctrine of Fiqh” (pp.
553–596; first published in Islamic Culture 36, no. 3 [1962]: 207–224; 36, no. 4 [1962]:
256–274); as well as Fazle Mahmud, “Shah Wali Allah’s Hujjatullahil balighah,” Journal of
the Arabic and Persian Society of the Panjab University 5, no. 4/6:1 (1960/61): 1–28.
4
Shah Waliyullah, Al-Budur al-Bāzighah, trans. Ghulam N. Jalbani, 2nd ed. (New
Delhi: Kitab Bhavan, 2005); Full Moon Appearing on the Horizon: English Translation of Shah
Wali Allah (Al-Budur al-Bazighah), trans. Johannes M. S. Baljon (Lahore: Sh. Muhammad
Ashraf, 1990). On the Al-Budūr al-Bāzighah as a source of Shah Walī Allāh’s political ideas,
see Saeeda Khatoon, “Shāh Walī Allāh’s Philosophy of Society—an Outline,” Hamdard
Islamicus 7, no. 4 (1984): 57–67, repr. in SWRPT, pp. 421–431; Ghulam N. Jalbani, Teach-
ings of Shāh Walīyullāh of Delhi (Lahore: Sh. Muhammad Ashraf, 1967; repr., New Delhi:
Nusrat Ali Nasri Lor Kitab Bhavan, 1988), pp. 126–147; Muhammad ‘A. Baqi, “Theories
of State and Problems of Sociology as Expounded by an Indian Muslim Divine of the Eigh-
teenth Century,” Islamic Review 38 (1950): 9–14. A comparative study of the Ḥujjat Allāh
al-Bālighah and Al-Budūr al-Bāzighah remains a desideratum.
5
Ayesha Jalal, Partisans of Allah: Jihad in South Asia (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard Uni-
versity Press, 2008), pp. 40–57. Consider also Muhammad T. Mallick, “Rationale of Jihād
as Expounded by Shāh Walī Allāh of Delhi,” Journal of the Pakistan Historical Society 34
(1986): 14–25.
796 journal of world history, december 2012
cal and social realities that prevailed in late Mughal India. Although
I do not mean to dissociate Shāh Walī Allāh’s private writings from
his philosophical works and will occasionally include references to
his letters, my goal is to uncover the broader political program that
he articulates, one that extends beyond Mughal political realities. As
such, my analysis contrasts sharply with the traditional image of Shāh
Walī Allāh as the representative of a rabid trend of anti-Hinduism and
the harbinger of revivalist movements in South Asia.6 I show that his
rationalistic approach to the dynamics of social life and mechanics of
power reflects a nuanced understanding of the process of state 7 forma-
tion that heretofore has not found its due place in modern narratives
of imperial state building and decline.8
6
See, for example, Mahmood A. Ghazi, Islamic Renaissance in South Asia 1707–1867:
The Role of Shāh Walī Allāh and His Successors (Islamabad: Islamic Research Institute/Inter-
national Islamic University, 2002); Ahmad Dallal, “The Origins and Objectives of Islamic
Revivalist Thought, 1750–1850,” Journal of the American Oriental Society 113 (1993): 341–
359; Muhammad al-Faruque, “Some Aspects of Muslim Revivalist Movements in India
During the 18th Century: The Activities of Shāh Walī-Allāh of Delhi,” Islamic Culture 63
(1989): 19–41; Shafi A. Khan, “Nationalist ‘Ulama’s Interpretation of Shāh Walī Allah’s
Thought and Movement,” Journal of the Pakistan Historical Society 37 (1989): 209–248;
Saiyid Athar Abbas Rizvi, Muslim Revivalist Movements in Northern India in the Sixteenth and
Seventeenth Centuries (Agra: Agra University Press, 1965; repr., New Delhi: M. Manoharlal,
1993).
7
Shāh Walī Allāh uses the Arabic term madīnah, which literally means “city” and is
roughly equivalent to the Greek polis, in the sense of a political entity that encompasses a
number of cities and is characterized by an administrative and governmental organization
similar to that of the modern state. Accordingly, Shāh Walī Allāh envisions the caliphate as
incorporating a multiplicity of existing states and political units. On the meaning of madīna
and its derivatives in medieval Arab political writing, see Soheil M. Afnan, A Philosophical
Lexicon in Persian and Arabic (Beirut: Imprimerie Catholique, 1969; repr., Tehran: Nashr-i
Nuqrih, 1362 [1983]), s.v. madīna (278–279); Dimitri Gutas, “The Meaning of madīnah in
al-Fārābī’s ‘Political’ Philosophy,” in The Greek Strand in Islamic Political Thought, ed. Emma
Gannagé et al. (= Mélanges de l’Université Saint-Joseph; 57; Beirut: Dār el-Machreq, 2004),
pp. 259–279. For a useful orientation to the various definitions of the concept of “empire,”
consult Kathleen D. Morrison, “Sources, Approaches, Definitions,” in Empires: Perspectives
from Archaeology and History, ed. Susan E. Alcock et al. (Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 2001), pp. 1–9, esp. 1–3.
8
Given the enormous amount of scholarship on imperial ascendancy and decline, I
confine myself to mentioning some of the most important studies I consulted in the process
of writing this paper: Niall Ferguson, “Complexity and Collapse: Empires on the Edge of
Chaos,” Foreign Affairs 89, no. 2 (2010): 18–32; Peter Turchin, Historical Dynamics: Why
States Rise and Fall (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2003); Alexander J. Motyl,
Imperial Ends: The Decay, Collapse, and Revival of Empires (New York: Columbia University
Press, 2001); Motyl, “Thinking about Empire,” in After Empire: Multiethnic Societies and
Nation-Building: The Soviet Union and the Russian, Ottoman, and Habsburg Empires, ed. Karen
Barkey and Mark von Hagen (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1997), pp. 19–29; Charles
Tilly, “How Empires End,” in Barkey and von Hagen, After Empire, pp. 1–11; Emil Brix et
al., eds., The Decline of Empires (Vienna: Verlag für Geschichte und Politik; Munich: Olden-
Syros: The Rise and Decline of Empires 797
bourg Verlag, 2001); Richard Lorenz, ed., Das Verdämmern der Macht: Vom Untergang grosser
Reiche (Frankfurt a. M.: Fischer TB Verlag, 2000); Paul M. Kennedy, The Rise and Fall of the
Great Powers: Economic Change and Military Conflict from 1500 to 2000 (New York: Ran-
dom House, 1987); Joseph A. Tainter, The Collapse of Complex Societies (Cambridge: Cam-
bridge University Press, 1988); Michael W. Doyle, Empires (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University
Press, 1986); Carlo M. Cipolla, ed., The Economic Decline of Empires (London: Methuen,
1970); Shmuel N. Eisenstadt, ed., The Decline of Empires (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-
Hall, 1967); Shmuel N. Eisenstadt, The Political Systems of Empires (London: Free Press of
Glencoe, 1963; repr., New Brunswick: Transaction Publishers, 1993); and Geir Lundestad,
ed., The Fall of Great Powers: Peace, Stability, and Legitimacy (Oslo: Scandinavian Univer-
sity Press, 1994). For stimulating reflections on the history of empires and its relevance to
current debates on the role of the United States as a global power, see Craig Calhoun et
al., eds., Lessons of Empire: Imperial Histories and American Power (New York: New Press,
2006). The phenomenon of state failure is discussed in Robert I. Rotberg, ed., When States
Fail: Causes and Consequences (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2004). On the
theme of decline, consult, e.g., Daron Acemoglu and James A. Robinson, Why Nations Fail:
The Origins of Power, Prosperity and Poverty (New York: Crown Publishers, 2012); Rein-
hart Koselleck and Paul Widmer, eds., Niedergang: Studien zu einem geschichtlichen Thema
(Stuttgart: Klett-Cotta, 1980); Peter Burke, “Tradition and Experience: The Idea of Decline
from Bruni to Gibbon,” in Edward Gibbon and the Decline and Fall of the Roman Empire,
ed. Glenn W. Bowersock et al. (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1977), pp.
87–102; Randolph Starn, “Meaning-Levels in the Theme of Historical Decline,” History
and Theory 14 (1975): 1–31.
9
On the sources of Shāh Walī Allāh’s political ideas, see the remarks by Muzaffar
Alam, The Languages of Political Islam: India 1200–1800 (London: Hurst, 2004), pp. 50,
171–173; as well as Muhammad al-Ghazali, The Socio-Political Thought of Shāh Walī Allāh
(Islamabad: International Institute of Islamic Thought and Islamic Research Institute,
2001; repr., New Delhi: Adam Publishers and Distributors, 2004), pp. 33–43; and Saiyid A.
A. Rizvi, “The Political Thoughts of Shāh Walī Allāh,” Abr-Nahrain 16 (1975/76): 91–107,
91–92, repr. in SWRPT, pp. 277–308. A general treatment of Shāh Walī Allāh’s political
theory can be found in Mahmood A. Ghazi, “State and Politics in the Philosophy of Shah
Waliy Allah,” Islamic Studies 23 (1984): 353–371, repr. in SWRPT, pp. 225–241.
798 journal of world history, december 2012
this article might be of more than historical relevance for the study of
Shāh Walī Allāh’s political thought. I specifically examine how Shāh
Walī Allāh uses the examples of the Sassanians and Byzantine empires
as heuristic devices to illustrate the process of decay of Mughal power.
I also point to parallels between Shāh Walī Allāh’s ideas on the eco-
nomic dimensions of imperial decay and the ways in which Byzantine
statesmen and literati theorized remedies for the weaknesses of Byzan-
tine society in the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries.
10
For a similar interpretation, see Johannes M. S. Baljon, “Social and Economic Ideas
of Shah Wali Allah,” in Readings in Islamic Economic Thought, ed. Abul Hasan M. Sadeq and
Aidit Ghazali (Dhaka: Islamic Foundation Bangladesh, 2006), pp. 356–368, 358. The term
irtifāq (literal meaning: support) derives from the Arabic root r.f.q., which signifies kindness
or gentleness. For further discussion, see Hermansen, The Conclusive Argument from God,
pp. xviii–xix.
11
Waliyullah, Al-Budūr al-Bāzighah, pp. 48–49; Baljon, Full Moon Appearing on the
Horizon, pp. 56–58. See further Abdul A. Islahi, “Shah Wali Allah’s Concept of Al-Irtifaqat
(Stages of Socio-Economic Development),” Journal of Objective Studies 1–2 (1990): 46–63,
51 (repr. in Fazlur R. Faridi, ed., Aspects of Islamic Economics and the Economy of Indian
Syros: The Rise and Decline of Empires 799
such as avarice and envy soon creep in, giving rise to social tensions
and disputes, and some men seek to overpower others or are naturally
inclined to plunder and kill. Hence, the members of the community
feel compelled to appoint a ruler, who possesses abundant resources and
is able to attract wise men from other countries, to correct and punish
evildoers and collect taxes. In the fourth irtifāq a caliph is appointed to
merge together and rule over preexisting states and kingdoms.12
All men need food, drink, and shelter. In Shāh Walī Allāh’s view,
every species has a law implanted into the breasts of its individuals, and
all creatures strive to meet their needs. But man has three capacities
that are not found in other animals. First, he possesses a comprehensive
view: while animals are directed to an objective perceived through the
senses or to an imagined objective driven by their physical needs such
as hunger, thirst, and lust, man is uniquely endowed with the ability to
perceive and strive after a rational benefit that has no motivation in his
physical nature. This prompts human beings to establish a social order,
perfect their character, and seek mutual affection. Second, while ani-
mals desire things such as food to fulfill their needs and protect them-
selves against the cold, man has been equipped with aesthetic sensibil-
ity (zarāfah). He thus tries to move beyond the level of bare necessity
and aspires to aesthetic and emotional delight and elegance, a beautiful
partner, delicious food, good clothing, and a comfortable house. Third,
man is characterized by takāmul, that is, an inner drive toward self-
perfection. Men of intelligence discover and develop the appropriate
supports of civilization, look for water resources or dig wells and store
water, learn which seeds are edible and figure out how to cook or store
them; those who are unable to discover those supports on their own
perceive their utility and follow what the “wise” propose to them.13
Shāh Walī Allāh comes very close to Montesquieu when he
acknowledges that differences in temperaments and social mores exist
Muslims [New Delhi: Institute of Objective Studies, 1993], pp. 73–93); as well as Sabih A.
Kamali, “Shah Waliy Allah’s Doctrine of Irtifaqat,” Iqbal 11, no. 3 (1963): 1–17, repr. in
SWRPT, pp. 401–420.
12
Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, 1:39; Hermansen, The Conclusive Argument from God, pp.
117–118.
13
Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, 1:38; Hermansen, The Conclusive Argument from God, pp.
115–116; Waliyullah, Al-Budūr al-Bāzighah, pp. 22–23; Baljon, Full Moon Appearing on the
Horizon, p. 32. See also the discussion in Johannes M. S. Baljon, “The Ethics of Shâh Walî
Allâh Dihlawî (1703–62),” in Akten des VII. Kongresses für Arabistik und Islamwissenschaft,
ed. Albert Dietrich (Göttingen: Vandenhoeck und Ruprecht, 1976), pp. 66–73, 67–69, repr.
in SWRPT, pp. 397–405.
800 journal of world history, december 2012
among various peoples and explains that the three capabilities unique
to men are not found in equal measure in all nations. On one level,
he explains, are primitive societies such as the Bedouins, who live on
mountain peaks and in regions far from sound climates. On another,
higher level are settled populations and the urban centers of healthful
regions that are inhabited by people endowed by nature with superior
virtues and produce wise men.14
14
Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, 1:39; Hermansen, The Conclusive Argument from God, p. 117.
15
Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, 1:40; Hermansen, The Conclusive Argument from God, p. 121.
16
Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, 1:39–40; Hermansen, The Conclusive Argument from God,
p. 119; Waliyullah, Al-Budūr al-Bāzighah, pp. 53–54; Baljon, Full Moon Appearing on the
Horizon, pp. 61–63.
Syros: The Rise and Decline of Empires 801
17
Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, 1:40; Hermansen, The Conclusive Argument from God, pp.
119–120.
18
Compare Plato, Politeia, 372A–374E.
19
Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, 1:41–42; Hermansen, The Conclusive Argument from God,
p. 127.
20
Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, 1:43–44; Hermansen, The Conclusive Argument from God,
p. 128.
802 journal of world history, december 2012
21
Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, 1:42; Hermansen, The Conclusive Argument from God, p. 127.
22
Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, 1:45; Hermansen, The Conclusive Argument from God, p. 129.
23
Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, 1:45; Hermansen, The Conclusive Argument from God, p. 132.
Syros: The Rise and Decline of Empires 803
24
Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, 1:45–46; Hermansen, The Conclusive Argument from God,
pp. 132–133; Waliyullah, Al-Budūr al-Bāzighah, pp. 79–81; Baljon, Full Moon Appearing on
the Horizon, pp. 86–88.
25
Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, 1:46; Hermansen, The Conclusive Argument from God, p. 133.
804 journal of world history, december 2012
remunerate his aides.26 Able and loyal administrators protect the ruler
from evil just as the hands carry weapons and protect the entire body.
They also proffer advice to the ruler just like the mind and the senses
provide information to the human organism. The ruler’s ministers must
be trustworthy, carry out orders, and bear goodwill both in private and
in public. The ruler must be quick to dismiss any official who strays
from these principles.27
Shāh Walī Allāh enumerates five principal aides and court func-
tionaries: (1) the judge (qāḍī); (2) the commander of the armed forces
(‘amīr) in charge of selecting and training soldiers, deploying spies, and
gathering intelligence about the plans of potential enemies; (3) the
governor of the city (sā‘īs), who is in charge of appointing a leader
for each group; (4) the revenue collector (‘āmil); and (5) the minister
(wakīl), whose function is to administer the income and expenditure
and minister to the ruler’s daily needs.28 In the al-Budūr al-Bāzighah,
Shāh Walī Allāh provides an expanded list that includes another two
offices: (1) the head of religious affairs (shaikh-ul Islām) in charge of
propagating religion and providing spiritual guidance, and (2) the sage
(ḥakīm) who possesses expertise on medicine, poetry, astrology, history,
mathematics, and letter writing.29
The ruler should have the ability to distinguish between those who
pretend to love him out of fear or greed and those who genuinely sup-
port his rule. He should also be able to discern each person’s merits,
monitor the conduct and activities of the state officials, and keep
abreast of new developments. He must select a number of assistants
proportionate to the needs and the size of the state and must deter-
mine their salaries. Shāh Walī Allāh recommends that the ruler adopt
a just system of collecting land taxes without burdening the people;
taxes should be levied on those who possess large property and wealth
derived from husbandry, agriculture, and commercial pursuits.30
In his exposition of the modes conducive to stable and lasting rule,
26
Waliyullah, Al-Budūr al-Bāzighah, pp. 77–78; Baljon, Full Moon Appearing on the
Horizon, pp. 85–86.
27
Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, 1:46; Hermansen, The Conclusive Argument from God, p. 134.
28
Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, 1:46–47; Hermansen, The Conclusive Argument from God,
pp. 135–136; Waliyullah, Al-Budūr al-Bāzighah, pp. 94–96; Baljon, Full Moon Appearing on
the Horizon, pp. 99–101.
29
Waliyullah, Al-Budūr al-Bāzighah, pp. 94–95; Baljon, Full Moon Appearing on the
Horizon, p. 100.
30
Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, 1:46; Hermansen, The Conclusive Argument from God, pp.
134–135.
Syros: The Rise and Decline of Empires 805
The Caliphate
The fourth irtifāq signals the apex of political organization. In each
city a ruler is appointed, courageous persons gather around him,
and wealth is collected in the form of taxes. The differences in the
temperaments and abilities of the kings elicit friction: certain rulers
attempt to conquer another’s territory or fight one another for unim-
portant reasons, such as desire for wealth or land or due to envy, greed,
resentment, and malice. Thus, the kings were compelled to appoint a
caliph or to obey a single ruler who has the authority of the caliph-
ate (khilāfah). The true caliph holds undisputed sway over his realm
and possesses so much military might and equipment that it is almost
impossible for another person to challenge him. Just as the head of the
state soothes or remedies social tensions, the fourth irtifāq is the sci-
ence that examines the policies of the cities and their rulers and the
means whereby collaboration among people of various regions can be
fostered. And just as political authority within the first political com-
munities originates in a primordial compact the caliph is appointed
upon the consent of the rulers of existing states. The caliph must be
on guard against all factors that can jeopardize his authority: emergen-
cies, natural calamities, disarray and factious commotion, the expen-
diture of large amounts of money, and wicked individuals who plunder
Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, 1:46; Hermansen, The Conclusive Argument from God, p. 135.
31
806 journal of world history, december 2012
the property of the people, incarcerate their sons, and dishonor their
wives.32
One of Shāh Walī Allāh’s novelties is that he offers one of the most
analytically refined accounts of the origin, nature, and function of the
caliphate. Shāh Walī Allāh goes beyond previous Islamic writers such
as al-Fārābī, who envisage the caliphate as the pinnacle of a constant
process of associational evolution starting from the creation of sim-
ple types of political organization.33 As al-Fārābī puts it, the increase
of human needs leads to more complex forms of social organization
and culminates in the creation of a universal state encompassing all
existing nations. In order to secure the means for his subsistence, man
by nature needs various things that he cannot acquire by himself, so
he relies on mutual aid and is compelled to live in association with
others. The increase of men results in the formation of communities,
some of which are perfect, some of which are imperfect. The imperfect
types include the union of people in a village, a quarter, a street, or in
a house. The perfect types can be classified into small, medium, and
great: the small one is the union of the inhabitants of the city in the
territory of any nation, the middle one results from the formation of
one nation in a certain region, and the great one signals the union of
all the communities of the inhabited world.34 Just as people living in a
city strive for those things that allow them to attain ultimate perfection
through mutual collaboration, the excellent nation is one in which
all of its cities aspire to felicity. Accordingly, the excellent universal
state can come into being when all the nations that compose it work
together to reach felicity.35
32
Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, 1:45; Hermansen, The Conclusive Argument from God, p.
137. See also Waliyullah, Al-Budūr al-Bāzighah, pp. 97–98; Baljon, Full Moon Appearing on
the Horizon, pp. 101–103.
33
On the reception of al-Fārābī’s political ideas in the Indo-Islamic world as medi-
ated by Ṭūsī’s Nasirean Ethics, see Saiyid A. A. Rizvi, Religious and Intellectual History of
the Muslims in Akbar’s Reign, with Special Reference to Abuʾl Fazl (1556–1605) (New Delhi:
M. Manoharlal Publishers, 1975), pp. 355–357.
34
Al-Farabi on the Perfect State: Abū Naṣr al-Fārābī’s Mabādiʾ ārāʾ ahl al-madīna al-fāḍila.
A revised text with introduction, translation, and commentary by Richard Walzer (Oxford:
Clarendon Press, 1985; repr., Chicago: KAZI Publications, 1998), Arabic text p. 228,
English trans. p. 229. Consider also Al-Farabi, The Political Writings: Selected Aphorisms and
Other Texts, trans. Charles E. Butterworth (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 2001),
pp. 23–26, 46. For further discussion, see Patricia Crone, God’s Rule: Government and Islam
(New York: Columbia University Press, 2004), pp. 177, 260–261, 343; Shlomo Pines, “The
Societies Providing for the Bare Necessities of Life According to Ibn Khaldūn and to the
Philosophers,” Studia Islamica 34 (1971): 125–138, repr., in Pines, The Collected Works of
Shlomo Pines, vol. 3, Studies in the History of Arabic Philosophy, ed. Sarah Stroumsa (Jerusa-
lem: Magnes Press, 1996), pp. 217–230.
35
Al-Farabi on the Perfect State, p. 230/231, as well as pp. 424, 432–433, 497.
Syros: The Rise and Decline of Empires 807
36
The following account is based on Abdur R. Bhat, Political Thought of Shah Waliul-
lâh (An Analytical Study) (New Delhi: Delhi, Rightway Publication, 2002), chap. “Shah
Waliullah’s Political Theory in Islamic Context,” pp. 65–73; Aziz Ahmad, “An Eighteenth-
Century Theory of the Caliphate,” Studia Islamica 28 (1968): 135–144. Consider also
Johannes M. S. Baljon, Religion and Thought of Shāh Walī Allāh Dihlawī, 1703–1762 (Leiden:
E. J. Brill, 1986), pp. 121–125, 195–196.
37
A precedent of this distinction can be found in the Fatāwā-i-Jahāndārī (Precepts on
[World] Rulership) of Ziyā’ al-Dīn Baranī (1284–1356), a confidant of the sultan of Delhi
Muḥammad bin Tughluq (ca. 1300–1351, r. 1325–1351) and major historian of fourteenth-
century India: Baranī distinguishes two forms of justice, one that aims at general equal-
ity (‘adl-i musāwāt-i talabī-yi ‘ām) and one concerned with special equality (adl-i musāwāt-i
talabī-yi khāss). The former is the ideal form of justice, can be realized only in the Islamic
setting, and was exemplified by Caliph ‘Umar (ca. 586–644, r. 634–644). The latter was
applied by the Persian king Anūshirwān (Chosroes I, r. 531–579) and presupposes the exis-
tence of a ruler acting as an arbitrator and settling disputes. For further references and com-
ment, see Alam, The Languages of Political Islam, pp. 38–39.
808 journal of world history, december 2012
38
Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, 1:48–49; Hermansen, The Conclusive Argument from God,
pp. 138–139.
39
Aristotle, Politics 1253a1–3. On the following, see also Vasileios Syros, “Shadows in
Heaven and Clouds on Earth: The Emergence of Social Life and Political Authority in the
Early Modern Islamic Empires,” Viator 43, no. 2 (2012): 377–406.
40
Naṣīr al-Ṭūsī, Akhlāq-i Nāṣirī (Lahore: Punjab University, 1952), p. 242; The Nasirean
Ethics by Naṣīr ad-Dīn Ṭūsī, trans. from the Persian George M. Wickens (London: Allen and
Unwin, 1964), p. 189. See also Guang-Zhen Sun, “Nasir ad-Din Tusi on Social Coopera-
tion and the Division of Labor: Fragment from The Nasirean Ethics,” Journal of Institutional
Economics 5 (2008): 403–413.
Syros: The Rise and Decline of Empires 809
41
Al-Ṭūsī, Akhlāq-i Nāṣirī, p. 243; The Nasirean Ethics, pp. 190–191.
42
[Jalāl al-Dīn Dawwānī], Practical Philosophy of the Muhammadan People, trans. W. F.
Thompson (London: W. H. Allen, 1839; repr., Karachi: Karimsons, 1977); The English Trans
lation of the Akhlak-i-Jalali: A Code of Morality in Persian composed by Jalal-ud-Din Moham-
mad Alias Allama Dawwani, trans. S. H. Deen (Lahore: Sh. Mubarak Ali, 1939). Scholarly
discussions of Dawwānī’s political ideas include Erwin I. J. Rosenthal, Political Thought in
Medieval Islam: An Introductory Outline (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1958),
chap. “Al-Dawwāni: Application and Integration,” pp. 210–223; Mohammed-Taqi Dan-
ishpazhouh, “An Annotated Bibliography on Government and Statecraft,” trans. Andrew
Newman, in Authority and Political Culture in Shi‘ism, ed. Said Amir Arjomand (Albany:
State University of New York Press, 1988), pp. 213–239, esp. 221–222; Muhammad A. Haq,
“A Critical Study of Jalāl al-Dīn al-Dawwāni’s Contribution to Social Philosophy” (PhD
diss., Aligarh Muslim University, n.d.).
43
Practical Philosophy of the Muhammadan People, pp. 318–320, 245–250; Deen, The
English Translation of the Akhlak-i-Jalali, pp. 161–162, 126–128.
44
Practical Philosophy of the Muhammadan People, p. 321; Deen, The English Translation
of the Akhlak-i-Jalali, p. 163.
45
Practical Philosophy of the Muhammadan People, p. 322; Deen, The English Translation
of the Akhlak-i-Jalali, p. 163.
810 journal of world history, december 2012
46
Practical Philosophy of the Muhammadan People, pp. 324–325; Deen, The English Trans-
lation of the Akhlak-i-Jalali, pp. 164–165.
47
Alam, The Languages of Political Islam, p. 50; Alam, “State Building under the
Mughals: Religion, Culture and Politics,” in L’Héritage timouride: Iran-Asie centrale-Inde
XVe–XVIIIe siècles, pp. 105–128, 111–117; Rizvi, Religious and Intellectual History of the Mus-
lims in Akbar’s Reign, pp. 355–356, 366–369.
48
In the administrative manual (dastūr al-‘amal) issued by Akbar in 1594, the Nasirean
Ethics was included in the standard readings for Mughal officials—see Mukātabāt-i-‘Allāmī
(Inshā’i Abu’l Faẓl) Daftar I: Letters of the Emperor Akbar in English Translation, ed. Mansura
Haidar (New Delhi: M. Manoharlal Publishers, 1998), p. 79.
49
Abū’l-Faẓl ‘Allāmī, Āīn-i Akbarī, trans. Henry Blochmann, 2nd ed. (Calcutta: Asi-
atic Society of Bengal, 1927), p. 2.
Syros: The Rise and Decline of Empires 811
exalted rank and high station. Unless the ruler regulates the affairs of
the people and acts as the refuge of the vulnerable members of human
society, clandestine rebels and insurgents, who are driven by tyrannical
feelings and engage in contumacious and aberrant conduct, will seek to
disturb the nobility and the common people.50
A salient theme in Shāh Walī Allāh’s theory of the state is the
variety of ways whereby domestic balance can be maintained and har-
monious interaction among various social groups can be ensured. Shāh
Walī Allāh evokes the “circle of justice” formula in medieval Islamic
political literature. And these ideas are rooted even further back in
history, in the works of ancient political thinkers, such as Plato, and
Iranian ideals of rulership.
According to Shāh Walī Allāh, the various parts of the state are
interrelated; the preservation of balance and harmony is like salt sea-
soning food.51 The third irtifāq necessitates the appointment of a ruler
in charge of maintaining social balance and domestic tranquillity; with
the multiplication of cities and states, in the fourth irtifāq a caliph is
appointed to erase interstate conflicts.52 Shāh Walī Allāh is particularly
emphatic about the caliph’s function in maintaining balance among
opposing and conflicting elements and purging the body politic of
excesses. The ideal caliph ought to be on his guard against revolution-
ary activities and subversive tendencies, must create an extensive net-
work of spies and informers, and must effectively employ perspicacity
about human character. As soon as he sees a faction forming among his
men, he should swiftly form another group and ensure that it will not
connive with the rebels. It is vital that this new group obey the caliph’s
commands, show goodwill toward him, and pray for him, acclaiming
his glory in large assemblies and on coins bearing his name.53
The ruler’s duty to uphold the delicate equilibrium among the vari-
ous segments of the body politic is compared in medieval Islamic writ-
ing to the physician’s function in maintaining the equilibrium (i‘tidāl)
50
Muḥammad Bāqir Najm-i Sānī, Advice on the Art of Governance: An Indo-Islamic Mir-
ror for Princes (Mau’iẓah-i Jahāngīrī), ed. and trans. Sajida S. Alvi (Albany: State University
of New York Press, 1989), Persian text p. 147/English trans. p. 45.
51
Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, 1:44; Hermansen, The Conclusive Argument from God, pp.
129–130. See also Waliyullah, Al-Budūr al-Bāzighah, pp. 85–86; Baljon, Full Moon Appearing
on the Horizon, pp. 91–93.
52
Waliyullah, Al-Budūr al-Bāzighah, pp. 49–50; Baljon, Full Moon Appearing on the
Horizon, p. 58.
53
Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, 1:49; Hermansen, The Conclusive Argument from God, p. 139.
812 journal of world history, december 2012
54
For further discussion on the use of medical metaphors in early modern Islamic
political writing, see Vasileios Syros, “Galenic Medicine and Domestic Stability in Early
Modern Florence and Islamic Empires,” Journal of Early Modern History 17, no. 1 (2013,
forthcoming).
55
Alam, The Languages of Political Islam, pp. 47, 57–58, 61, 140; A. J. Halepota, Philoso-
phy of Shah Waliullah (Lahore: Sind Sagar Academy, [197-?]), p. 166.
56
Waliyullah, Al-Budūr al-Bāzighah, pp. 49–50; Baljon, Full Moon Appearing on the
Horizon, p. 58. See also Alam, The Languages of Political Islam, p. 173.
57
Antony Black, The West and Islam: Religion and Political Thought in World History
(Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2008), pp. 58, 104–105; Black, The History of Islamic
Political Thought: From the Prophet to the Present (Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press;
New York: Routledge, 2001), pp. 53–54, 111.
58
My discussion of the “circle of justice” is based on the following studies by Linda T.
Darling: “Islamic Empires, the Ottoman Empire and the Circle of Justice,” in Constitutional
Politics in the Middle East: With Special Reference to Turkey, Iraq, Iran and Afghanistan, ed.
Saïd Amir Arjomand (Oxford: Hart Publishing, 2008), pp. 11–32; “Political Change and
Political Discourse in the Early Modern Mediterranean World,” Journal of Interdisciplinary
History 38 (2008): 505–531; “Medieval Egyptian Society and the Concept of the Circle of
Justice,” Mamlūk Studies Review 10 (2006): 1–17; “‘Do Justice, Do Justice, For That Is Para-
dise’: Middle Eastern Advice for Indian Muslim Rulers,” Comparative Studies of South Asia,
Africa and the Middle East 22 (2002): 3–19; as well as Jennifer A. London, “The ‘Circle of
Justice,’” History of Political Thought 32 (2011): 425–447; Maria E. Subtelny, Le monde est un
jardin: Aspects de l’histoire culturelle de l’Iran médiéval (Paris: Association pour l’avancement
des études iraniennes, 2002), chap. “Le cercle de justice: l’éthique dans le gouvernement,”
pp. 53–76; Joseph Sadan, “A ‘Closed-Circuit’ Saying on Practical Justice,” Jerusalem Studies
in Arabic and Islam 10 (1987): 325–341; Ann K. S. Lambton, “Justice in the Medieval Per-
sian Theory of Kingship,” Studia Islamica 17 (1962): 91–119, repr. in Lambton, Theory and
Practice in Medieval Persian Government (London: Variorum, 1980), no. 4.
Syros: The Rise and Decline of Empires 813
59
Ihsān ‘Abbās, ed., ‘Ahd Ardashīr (Beirut: Dār al-Ṣādir, 1967), p. 98; Mario Grignaschi,
“Quelques spécimens de la littérature sassanide conservés dans les bibliothèques d’Istanbul,”
Journal Asiatique 254 (1966): 1–142, 46–90. For another set of maxims on rulership that
bears the title Ā‘īn-i Ardashīr and has been ascribed to Ardashīr, see Grignaschi, “Quelques
spécimens de la littérature sassanide,” pp. 91–133.
60
Naṣīr al-Ṭūsī, Akhlāq-i Nāṣirī, p. 303; The Nasirean Ethics, p. 230.
814 journal of world history, december 2012
61
Practical Philosophy of the Muhammadan People, pp. 388–390; Deen, The English Trans-
lation of Akhlak-i-Jalali, pp. 201–203. See also Black, The History of Islamic Political Thought,
p. 185.
62
Practical Philosophy of the Muhammadan People, pp. 384–385; Deen, The English Trans-
lation of Akhlak-i-Jalali, pp. 199–200.
63
Practical Philosophy of the Muhammadan People, p. 388; Deen, The English Translation
of Akhlak-i-Jalali, p. 201.
64
Practical Philosophy of the Muhammadan People, pp. 325–326, 383–384; Deen, The
English Translation of Akhlak-i-Jalali, pp. 165, 199.
Syros: The Rise and Decline of Empires 815
65
Mohammad Habib and Afsar U. S. Khan, The Political Theory of the Delhi Sultanate
(Including a Translation of Ziauddin Barani’s Fatāwā-i Jahāndārī, Circa, 1358–9 a.d.) (Alla-
habad: Kitab Mahal, [1961]), pp. 38, 97. On Baranī’s ideas on social organization, see also
Iqtidar A. Khan, “Medieval Indian Notions of Secular Statecraft in Retrospect,” Social Sci-
entist 14 (1986): 3–15, 6–7. Baranī’s views on price control are discussed in Najaf Haider,
“Justice and Political Authority in Medieval Indian Islam,” in Justice: Political, Social, Juridi-
cal, ed. Rajeev Bhargava et al. (New Delhi: SAGE Publications, 2006), pp. 75–93; Irfan
Habib, “Ziya Barani’s Vision of the State,” Medieval History Journal 2 (1999): 19–36; and
Habib, “The Price Regulations of ‘Alā’ uddīn Khaljī—A Defence of Ziā’ Baranī,’ Indian
Economic and Social History Review 21 (1984): 393–414.
66
Abū’l-Faẓl ‘Allāmī, Āīn-i Akbarī, p. 2. On Abū’l-Faẓl’s use of medical analogies, see
also the discussion in Peter Hardy, “Abul Fazl’s Portrait of the Perfect Padshah: A Political
Philosophy for Mughal India—or a Personal Puff for a Pal,” in Islam in India: Studies and
Commentaries, vol. 2, Religion and Religious Education, ed. Christian W. Troll (New Delhi:
Vikas Pub. House, 1985), pp. 114–137, 133–135.
816 journal of world history, december 2012
67
Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, 1:44; Hermansen, The Conclusive Argument from God, pp.
129–130; Waliyullah, Al-Budūr al-Bāzighah, pp. 85–86; Baljon, Full Moon Appearing on
the Horizon, pp. 91–93. For earlier Indo-Islamic ideas on emergencies, see Vasileios Syros,
“Indian Emergencies: Baranī’s Fatāwā-i Jahāndārī, the Diseases of the Body Politic, and
Machiavelli’s accidenti,” Philosophy East and West 62, no. 4 (2012): 545–573.
Syros: The Rise and Decline of Empires 817
will prompt them to visit his realm more often. He should also make
sure that farmers do not leave the land uncultivated and should offer
incentives for artisans to improve their work. Finally, the ruler should
encourage the people to acquire skills such as calligraphy, arithmetic,
history, medicine, and methods of advancing knowledge. Protective
measures include being able to distinguish immoral from moral habits,
identify which citizens are in need of support, and employ the best
craftsmen.68
Imperial Decline
Shāh Walī Allāh’s theory about the caliphate in the general sense
revolves around the two major factors which, in his view, account for
imperial decline in his own day: (1) the depletion of the public trea-
sury, and (2) parasitism, or the fact that many people seek to secure
income by serving as soldiers or by becoming ‘ulamā’ (religious schol-
ars), ascetics, and poets and by receiving gifts from the rulers. The lat-
ter causes heavy taxation on farmers and traders, then the constant
increase of taxes leads to the ruin of the productive classes and incites
those who survive to stand up against taxation and rebel against the
government.69
In his private writings and letters, Shāh Walī Allāh berates the fact
that wealth came to be concentrated in the hands of Hindus.70 But,
more importantly, he construes the malfunction of the Mughal govern-
ment as a sign of moral decadence and overall failure to implement the
teachings of Islam. In an eleventh-hour attempt to save the Mughal
state from ultimate downfall, Shāh Walī Allāh called on the Afghan
ruler Aḥmad Shāh Abdālī (d. 1772) to invade India. He offers fulsome
praise of the Afghan warlord for his bravery and foresight and urges
him to launch a full-scale operation against the Marathas and Jats and
to wipe out polytheistic practices.71
Shāh Walī Allāh’s epistles on Mughal political disintegration
should be read against the background of a series of events that led to
68
Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, 1:44–45; Hermansen, The Conclusive Argument from God,
pp. 130–131.
69
Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, 1:40; Hermansen, The Conclusive Argument from God, p.
131.
70
Khalid A. Nizami, ed., Shāh Valī Dihlavī ke siyāsī maktūbāt (Delhi: Nadvat al-Musan-
nifin, 1969), pp. 102–105.
71
Nizami, Shāh Valī Dihlavī ke siyāsī maktūbāt, pp. 15, 52. See also Jalbani, Teachings of
Shāh Walīullah of Delhi, pp. 114–117.
818 journal of world history, december 2012
the gradual decay of Mughal rule:72 the incursions by Maratha, Jat, and
Sikh forces;73 the invasion of the army of the Iranian ruler Nādir Shāh
(1688–1747, r. 1736–1747) in 1739, which struck a blow to the stature
of the emperor and strained the Empire economically and militarily; a
devastating military debacle of the Mughal forces at the battle of Kar-
nal on 24 February 1739 and the massive slaughter of residents of Delhi
perpetrated by soldiers that gave rise to popular resentment; and the
constant plots and intrigues of the nobles and courtiers. The situation
came to a head when, after the death of the Mughal ruler Muḥammad
Shāh (d. 1748), his son and successor Aḥmad Shāh Bahādur (1725–
1775, r. 1748–1754) became a pliant tool in the hands of influential
ministers and nobles, which rendered the Empire’s capital vulnerable
to assaults by rebels.
Shāh Walī Allāh reproves the imperial administration for its inabil-
ity to suppress sedition. He points to the Jats’ taking over Gujarat and
Malwa; the rulers’ luxurious way of life, profligate spending, and self-
aggrandizement; the irregular and disrupted flow of revenues from the
provinces; the corruption of local governors and tax agents in the col-
lection and administration of revenue; and the oppression of the lower
social strata of the population. In addition to the letters which he sent
to Aḥmad Shāh Abdālī, Shāh Walī Allāh made a direct appeal to the
emperor and the nobles and spelled out an elaborate program intended
to ensure the stability and continued existence of the Empire:74
72
On Mughal “decline,” see, e.g., Douglas E. Streusand, Islamic Gunpowder Empires:
Ottomans, Safavids, and Mughals (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 2011), pp. 283–287;
Muzaffar Alam, The Crisis of Empire in Mughal North India: Awadh and the Punjab, 1707–48
(Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1986; repr., 1997); Andrea Hintze, The Mughal Empire and
Its Decline: An Interpretation of the Sources of Social Power (Aldershot: Ashgate, 1997); Karen
Leonard, “The ‘Great Firm’ Theory of the Decline of the Mughal Empire,” Comparative
Studies in Society and History 21 (1979): 151–167; John F. Richards, “The Imperial Crisis in
the Deccan,” Journal of Asian Studies 35 (1976): 236–256, repr. in Richards, Power, Adminis-
tration and Finance in Mughal India (Aldershot: Variorum, 1993), no. 12; M. Athar Ali, “The
Passing of Empire: The Mughal Case,” Modern Asian Studies 9 (1975): 385–396, repr. in Ali,
Mughal India: Studies in Polity, Ideas, Society, and Culture (New Delhi: Oxford University
Press, 2006), pp. 337–349; Saiyid A. A. Rizvi, “The Breakdown of Traditional Society,” in
The Cambridge History of Islam, vol. 2A, The Indian Sub-continent, South-East Asia, Africa and
the Muslim West, ed. Peter M. Holt et al. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1970;
repr., 1980), pp. 67–96.
73
See, in general, Catherine B. Asher and Cynthia Talbot, India before Europe (Cam-
bridge: Cambridge University Press, 2006), chap. “Challenging Central Authority, 1650–
1750,” pp. 225–255.
74
The following account is based on Islahi, “Shah Wali Allah’s Concept of Al-Irtifaqat
(Stages of Socio-Economic Development),” pp. 48–49; Fazl-e-Mahmud Asiri, “Shah Wali
Allah as a Politician,” Islamic Literature 7 (1955): 35–41.
Syros: The Rise and Decline of Empires 819
75
For a similar interpretation, see A. J. Halepota, “Shāh Waliyullāh and Iqbāl, the Phi-
losophers of Modern Age,” Islamic Studies 13 (1974): 225–233, repr. in SWRPT, pp. 649–656;
Halepota, “Affinity of Iqbāl with Shāh Walī Allāh,” Iqbal Review 15 (1974): 65–72; Fazlur
Rahman, “The Thinker of Crisis Shah Waliy-Ullah,” Pakistan Quarterly (1956): 44–48.
76
Shāh Walī Allāh’s political activities are discussed in A. Sattar Khan and Zulfiqar
Anwar, “The Movement of Shah Waliullah and Its Political Impact,” Journal of the Research
Society of Pakistan 32, no. 4 (1995): 13–23; Freeland Abbott, “The Decline of the Mughal
Empire and Shah Waliullah,” Muslim World 52 (1962): 115–123; Aziz Ahmad, “Political
and Religious Ideas of Shāh Walī-Ullāh of Delhi,” Muslim World 52 (1962): 22–30, esp.
28–30, partly repr. in Ahmad, Studies in Islamic Culture in the Indian Environment (Oxford:
Clarendon Press, 1964), pp. 201–209; Franco Coslovi, “Osservazioni sul ruolo di ‘Šāh
Walīullāh Dihlawī’ e ‘Šāh ‘Abd al-‘Azīz’ nella ‘Naqšbandiyya’ Indiana,” Annali dell’ Istituto
Orientale di Napoli, n.s., 29 (1979): 73–84, esp. 73–81; Irfan M. Habib, “The Political Role
of Shaikh Ahmad Sirhindi and Shah Waliullah,” in Indian History Congress: Proceedings of
the Twenty-third Session Aligarh—1960, pt. I (Calcutta, 1961), pp. 209–223; Sh. Muhammad
Ikram, “Shah Waliullah (I) (Life and Achievements in the Religious Sphere),” in A History
of the Freedom Movement (Being the Story of Muslim Struggle for the Freedom of Hind-Pakistan,
1707–1947), vol. 1, 1707–1831 (Karachi: Pakistan Historical Society, 1957), pp. 491–511;
Khaliq A. Nizami, “Shah Waliullah (II) (His Work in the Political Field),” in A History of
the Freedom Movement, 1:512–541; Nizami, “Shah Wali-Ullah Dehlavi and Indian Politics
in the 18th Century,” Islamic Culture 25 (1951): 133–145, repr. in SWRPT, pp. 143–157;
‘Ubaidullah Sindhi, Shah Wali Allah and His Political Movement [in Urdu] (Lahore: Sindh
Sagar Akademy, 1952).
77
On the history of the order, see Butrus Abu-Manneh, The Naqshbandiyya-Khâlidiyya
Sufi Order (Paris: Librairie d’Amérique et d’Orient, 2008); Itzchak Weismann, The Naqsh-
bandiyya: Orthodoxy and Activism in a Worldwide Sufi Tradition (London: Routledge, 2007);
820 journal of world history, december 2012
and eastern Islamic empires, rulers often had to muster the support of
the order to legitimize and consolidate their rule and secure popular
support.78
Sajida S. Alvi, “The Naqshbandī Mujaddidī Sufi Order’s Ascendancy in Central Asia
through the Eyes of Its Masters and Disciples (1010s–1200s/1600s–1800s),” in Reason and
Inspiration in Islam: Theology, Philosophy and Mysticism in Muslim Thought, ed. Todd Lawson
(London: I. B. Tauris, 2005), pp. 418–431; Elisabeth Özdalga, ed., Naqshbandis in Western
and Central Asia: Change and Continuity (Istanbul: Svenska Forskningsinstitutet Istanbul,
1999); Marc Gaborieau et al., eds., Naqshbandis: Cheminements et situation actuelle d’un ordre
mystique musulman (Istanbul: Isis, 1990); Richard Foltz, “The Central Asian Naqshbandī
Connections of the Mughal Emperors,” Journal of Islamic Studies 7 (1996): 229–239; Hamid
Algar, “The Naqshbandi Order: A Preliminary Survey of Its History and Significance,” Stu-
dia Islamica 44 (1976): 123–152. A number of seminal essays dealing with Sufi influences on
medieval Indian society have been reprinted in Raziuddin Aquil, ed., Sufism and Society in
Medieval India (New Delhi: Oxford University Press, 2010). Consult also Raziuddin Aquil’s
introduction to Sufism and Society, pp. ix–xxiv.
78
Jürgen Paul, Die politische und soziale Bedeutung der Naqšbandiyya in Mittelasien im
15. Jahrhundert (Berlin: W. de Gruyter, 1991), chap. “Politische Tätigkeit,” pp. 208–244;
and Jo-Ann Gross, “Khoja Ahrar: A Study of the Perceptions of Religious Power and Pres-
tige in the Late Timurid Period” (PhD diss., New York University, 1982). The role of the
Naqshbandi order in Mughal political life is discussed in Muzaffar Alam, “The Mughals,
the Sufi Shaikhs and the Formation of the Akbari Dispensation,” Modern Asian Studies 43
(2009): 135–174; David W. Damrel, “The ‘Naqshbandī Reaction’ Reconsidered,” in Beyond
Turk and Hindu: Rethinking Religious Identities in Islamicate South Asia, ed. David Gilmar-
tin and Bruce B. Lawrence (Gainesville: University Press of Florida, 2000), pp. 176–198;
Arthur F. Buehler, Sufi Heirs of the Prophet: The Indian Naqshbandiyya and the Rise of the
Mediating Sufi Shaykh (Columbia: University of South Carolina Press, 1998); Muhammad
Farman, “Shaikh Ahmad Sirhindi,” in A History of Muslim Philosophy, ed. Mian M. Sharif
(Wiesbaden: O. Harrassowitz, 1966), 2:873–883; Khaliq A. Nizami, “Naqshbandi Influence
on Mughal Rulers and Politics,” Islamic Culture 39 (1965): 41–52; Rizvi, Muslim Revivalist
Movements in Northern India in the Sixteenth and Seventeenth Centuries, “The Naqshbandis,”
pp. 176–201; and Wilfred Cantwell Smith, “The ‘ulamā’ in Indian Politics,” in Politics and
Society in India, ed. Cyril H. Philips (London: Allen and Unwin, 1963), pp. 39–51.
79
The Arabic term ‘ajam generally refers to a foreigner (non-Arab), but is often used to
designate an Iranian/Persian as is the case with Shāh Walī Allāh’s discussion of Sassanian
political history. See, in general, Mohamad Tavakoli-Targhi, “Contested Memories of Pre-
Islamic Iran,” Medieval History Journal 2 (1999): 245–275.
Syros: The Rise and Decline of Empires 821
80
Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, 1:105; Hermansen, The Conclusive Argument from God,
p. 306. For references to Byzantine and Sassanian political history and royal practices in
earlier Indo-Islamic political literature, consider, e.g., Afsar Afzal ud-din, “The Fatawa-i-
Jahandari of Zia ud-din Barni, Translation with Introduction and Notes” (PhD diss., School
of Oriental and African Studies, 1955), pp. 107, 152–153, 417–418, 424–429, 450–451,
466, 484–491.
81
Ḥujjat Allāh al-Bālighah, 1:105–106; Hermansen, The Conclusive Argument from God,
pp. 306–307.
822 journal of world history, december 2012
82
Byzantine views on the Mongols and the emergence of the Islamic empires of central
Asia are discussed in, e.g., Antonis K. Petrides, “Georgios Pachymeres between Ethnog-
raphy and Narrative: Συγγραφικαὶ Ἱστορίαι 3.3–5,” Greek, Roman and Byzantine Studies 49
(2009): 141–164, esp. 295–296, 316–317; Nikolaos Nikoloudes, “Byzantine Historians on
the Wars of Timur,” Journal of Oriental and African Studies 8 (1996): 83–94; Alexis G. K. [C.]
Savvides, “The Knowledge of the Byzantines about the Turkish-Speaking World of Asia,
the Balkans and Central Europe through Name Giving,” in Communication in Byzantium,
ed. Nikos G. Moschonas (Athens: National Hellenic Research Foundation/Institute for
Byzantine Research, 1993), pp. 711–727 [both in Greek]; Savvides, Byzantium in the Near
East: Its Relations with the Seljuk Sultanate of Rum in Asia Minor, the Armenians of Cilicia and
the Mongols, A.D. c. 1192–1237 (Thessalonike: Center for Byzantine Studies/University of
Thessaloniki, 1981); John W. Barker, Manuel II Palaeologus (1391–1425): A Study in Late
Byzantine Statesmanship (New Brunswick, N.J.: Rutgers University Press, 1969), Appendix
XVIII: “Byzantine Relations with Timur,” pp. 504–509. Also of note are John S. Langdon,
“Byzantium’s Initial Encounter with the Chinggisids: An Introduction to the Byzantino-
Mongolica,” Viator 29 (1998): 95–139; Angeliki E. Laiou, “On Political Geography: The
Black Sea of Pachymeres,” in The Making of Byzantine History, ed. Roderick Beaton and
Charlotte Roueché (Aldershot: Variorum, 1993), pp. 94–121, 112–121; Bruce G. Lippard,
“The Mongols and Byzantium, 1243–1341” (PhD diss., Indiana University, 1983); Maria-
Mathilde Alexandrescu-Dersca, La campagne de Timur en Anatolie (1402) (Bucharest:
Monitorul Oficial şi Imprimeriile Statului, Imprimeria Naţionalǎ, 1942; 2nd ed., London:
Variorum Reprints, 1977); Andreas Graf, “Die Tataren im Spiegel der byzantinischen Lit-
eratur,” in Jubilee Volume in Honour of Prof. Bernhard Heller on the Occasion of His Seventieth
Birthday, ed. Alexander Scheiber (Budapest, 1941), pp. 77–85; Fedor I. Uspensky, “Byz-
antine Historians on the Mongols and the Egyptian Mamluks,” Vizantiysky Vremmenik 24
(1923–1926): 1–16 (in Russian); Ottokar Intze, “Tamerlan und Bajazet in den Literaturen
des Abendlandes” (Erlangen: E. Th. Jacob, 1912), pp. 5–9. On Byzantine perceptions of
Islam and the Arabs, see Wolfram Brandes, “Der frühe Islam in der byzantinischen Histo-
riographie: Anmerkungen zur Quellenproblematik der Chronographia des Theophanes,” in
Jenseits der Grenzen: Beiträge zur spätantiken und frühmittelalterlichen Geschichtsschreibung,
ed. Andreas Goltz et al. (Berlin: W. de Gruyter, 2009), pp. 313–343; Elizabeth M. Jef-
freys, “The Image of the Arabs in Byzantine Literature,” in The 17th International Byzantine
Congress: Major Papers (New Rochelle, N.Y.: A. D. Caratzas, 1986), pp. 305–323; Spe-
ros Vryonis Jr.,“Byzantine Attitudes toward Islam during the Late Middle Ages,” Greek,
Roman and Byzantine Studies 12 (1971): 263–286, repr. in Vryonis, Studies on Byzantium,
Seljuks, and Ottomans: Reprinted Studies (Malibu: Undena Publications, 1981), no. 8; Alain
Ducellier, “Mentalité historique et realités politiques: L’Islam et les Musulmans vus par les
Byzantins du XIIIème siècle,” Byzantinische Forschungen 4 (1972): 31–63; John Meyendorff,
“Byzantine Views of Islam,” Dumbarton Oaks Papers 18 (1964): 114–132; and Wolfgang
Eichner, “Die Nachrichten über den Islam bei den Byzantinern,” Islam 23 (1936): 133–162
and 197–244.
Syros: The Rise and Decline of Empires 823
83
For medieval Islamic ideas on kingship, see, e.g., Anne F. Broadbridge, Kingship and
Ideology in the Islamic and Mongol Worlds (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2008);
Aziz al-Azmeh, Muslim Kingship: Power and the Sacred in Muslim, Christian, and Pagan Polities
(London: I. B. Tauris, 1997); Saiyid A. A. Rizvi, “Kingship in Islam: Islamic Universalism
through the Caliphate,” in Patterns of Kingship and Authority in Traditional Asia, ed. Ian
Mabbett (London: Croom Helm, 1985), pp. 108–130; Rizvi, “Kingship in Islam: A Histori-
cal Analysis,” in Kingship in Asia and Early America, ed. Arthur L. Basham (Mexico City:
El Colegio de México, 1981), pp. 29–82; Tilman Nagel, Staat und Glaubensgemeinschaft im
Islam: Geschichte der politischen Ordnungsvorstellungen der Muslime, 2 vols. (Zurich: Arte-
mis, 1981); Roy P. Mottahedeh, “Some Attitudes towards Monarchy and Absolutism in the
Eastern Islamic World of the Eleventh and Twelfth Centuries A.D.,” Israel Oriental Studies
10 (1980): 86–91.
84
For further discussion, see the following studies by Bernard Lewis: The Political Lan-
guage of Islam (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1988), pp. 55, 93, 96–97; “Malik,”
Cahiers de Tunisie 35 (1987): 101–109; “Usurpers and Tyrants: Notes on Some Islamic
Terms,” in Logos Islamikos, ed. Roger M. Savory and Dionisius A. Agius (Toronto: Pontifical
Institute of Mediaeval Studies, 1984), pp. 259–267, both repr. in Lewis, Political Words and
Ideas in Islam (Princeton, N.J.: M. Wiener Publishers, 2008), pp. 77–86 and 49–58, respec-
tively. Note also Fred Halliday, “Monarchies in the Middle East: A Concluding Appraisal,”
in Middle East Monarchies: The Challenge of Modernity, ed. Joseph Kostiner (Boulder, Colo.:
Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2000), pp. 289–303, 292–293; Ami Ayalon, Language and Change
in the Arab Middle East: The Evolution of Modern Political Discourse (New York: Oxford Uni-
versity Press, 1987), chap. “Sultans, Kings, Emperors,” pp. 29–42; Ayalon, “Malik in Modern
Middle Eastern Titulature,” Die Welt des Islams 23/24 (1984): 306–319, esp. 307–312; Herib-
ert Busse, “Herrschertypen im Koran,” in Die Islamische Welt zwischen Mittelalter und Neuzeit,
ed. Ulrich Haarmann und Peter Bachmann (Wiesbaden: F. Steiner, 1979), pp. 56–80, esp.
67–71; Arent J. Wensinck-[Georges Vajda], s.v. “Fir‛awn,” in Encyclopedia of Islam, new
ed. (Leiden: E. J. Brill; London: Luzac, 1965), vol. 2, pt. 2: 917–918. Medieval Islamic per-
ceptions of ancient Egypt are surveyed in Konrad Hirschler, “The ‘Pharaoh’ Anecdote in
Pre-Modern Arabic Historiography,” Journal of Arabic and Islamic Studies 10 (2010): 45–74;
Ulrich Haarmann, “Medieval Muslim Perceptions of Pharaonic Egypt,” in Ancient Egyptian
Literature: History and Forms, ed. Antonio Loprieno (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1996), pp. 605–627;
Haarmann, “Das pharaonische Ägypten bei islamischen Autoren des Mittelalters,” in Zum
Bild Ägyptens im Mittelalter und in der Renaissance, ed. Erik Hornung (Freiburg [i. Ü.]: Uni-
versitätsverlag Freiburg Schweiz, 1990), pp. 29–58; Hans R. Roemer, “Der Islam und das
Erbe der Pharaonen: Neuere Erkenntnisse zu einem alten Thema,” in Ägypten—Dauer und
Wandel (Mainz am Rhein: P. v. Zabern, 1985), pp. 123–129; Michael Cook, “Pharaonic
History in Medieval Egypt,” Studia Islamica 57 (1983): 67–103. Consider also Adam Silver-
stein, “The Qur’ānic Pharaoh,” in New Pespectives on the Qur’ān: The Qur’ān in Its Historical
Context 2, ed. Gabriel Said Reynolds (London: Routledge, 2011), pp. 467–477; and Reuven
Firestone, “Pharaoh,” in Encyclopaedia of the Qur’ān, ed. Jane D. McAuliffe (Leiden: Brill,
2004), 4:66–68. For a general treatment of medieval Islamic views of the pre-Islamic era, see
Monika Springberg-Hinsen, Die Zeit vor dem Islam in arabischen Universalgeschichten des 9.
und 12. Jahrhunderts (Würzburg: Echter; Altenberge: Telos-Verlag, 1989).
824 journal of world history, december 2012
the pharaohs for such virtues as generosity, piety, and dedication to the
welfare of their subjects.85
One of the first references to Byzantium (al-rūm) appears in the
Qur’ān in the context of the Byzantine-Sassanid war at the beginning
of the seventh century.86 Just like Shāh Walī Allāh, a number of Arab
writers saw Byzantine emperors (qayṣar) and Sassanian kings (kisrā) as
exemplifying a form of royal rule incompatible with the principles of
Islam.87 However, whereas the Persian Empire proved very vulnerable
to Muslim attacks and quickly fell under the sway of Islam, Byzantium
in the aftermath of the Arabs’ efforts to capture Constantinople, espe-
cially in the tenth century, came to be widely perceived as a resilient
political and military power that posed a formidable and lasting chal-
lenge to its Arab neighbors and that would perish only with the coming
of the Day of Judgment.88 Al-Jāḥiẓ (781–869) notes that Mu‘āwiyah’s
(602–680, r. 661–680) ascension to power as the first Caliph of the
Umayyad dynasty marked a period of oppression and violence in which
the imamate mutated into a kind of kingdom as the one during Chos-
roes’s reign and the caliphate degenerated into a tyranny that only per-
tained to a caesar (≈ Byzantine emperor).89
85
Okasha El-Daly, Egyptology: The Missing Millennium: Ancient Egypt in Medieval Arabic
Writings (London: UCL Press, 2005), pp. 122–126.
86
On the etymology and use of the term rūm and its derivatives in medieval Arabic
writing, see Nadia Maria El Cheikh, Byzantium Viewed by the Arabs (Cambridge, Mass.:
Center for Middle Eastern Studies of Harvard University, 2004), pp. 21–33; as well as Niko-
lai Serikoff, “Rūmī and yūnānī: Towards the Understanding of the Greek language in the
Medieval Muslim World,” in East and West in the Crusader States: Context—Contacts—Con-
frontations, ed. Krijnie Ciggaar et al. (Leuven: Peeters, 1996), pp. 169–194, esp. 172–183.
87
El Cheikh, Byzantium Viewed by the Arabs, pp. 86–87. On Byzantium’s image in
medieval Islam and Byzantine-Arab relations, see in addition to El Cheikh: Olof Heilo,
“Seeing Eye to Eye: Islamic Universalism in the Roman and Byzantine Worlds, 7th to 10th
Centuries” (diss., University of Vienna, 2010); Ulrike Koenen and Martina Müller-Wiener,
eds., Grenzgänge im östlichen Mittelmeerraum: Byzanz und die islamische Welt vom 9. bis 13.
Jahrhundert (Wiesdaben: Reichert Verlag, 2008); Michael Bonner, ed., Arab-Byzantine Rela-
tions in Early Islamic Times (Aldershot: Ashgate, 2004); Ahmad M. H. Shboul, “Arab Islamic
Perceptions of Byzantine Religion and Culture,” in Muslim Perceptions of Other Religions:
A Historical Survey, ed. Jacques Waardenburg (New York: Oxford University Press, 1999),
pp. 122–135; Shboul, “Arab Attitudes towards Byzantium: Official, Learned, Popular,” in
ΚΑΘΗΓΗΤΡΙΑ: Essays Presented to Joan Hussey for her 80th Birthday (Camberley, Sur-
rey: Porphyrogenitus, 1988), pp. 111–128; and Speros Vryonis Jr., “Byzantium and Islam,
Seven–Seventeenth Century,” East European Quarterly 11 (1968): 205–240, repr. in Vry-
onis, Byzantium: Its Internal History and Relations with the Muslim World: Collected Studies
(London: Variorum Reprints, 1971), no. 9.
88
El Cheikh, Byzantium Viewed by the Arabs, p. 70; David Cook, “Muslim Apocalyptic
and Jihād,” Jerusalem Studies in Arabic and Islam 20 (1996): 66–104, esp. 83–96.
89
Ḥasan al-Sandūbī, ed., Rasāʾil al-Jāḥiz: Wa-hiya rasāʾil muntaqāt min kutub lil-Jāḥiẓ
lam tunshar qabl al-ān (Cairo: Yuṭlab min al-maktabah al-Tijārīyah al-Kubra, 1933), p. 117;
Syros: The Rise and Decline of Empires 825
Charles Pellat, “La Nâbita de Djâhiz: Un document important pour l’histoire politico-reli-
gieuse de l’Islâm,” Annales de l’Institut d’Études Orientales 10 (1952): 302–325, 314. See also
El Cheikh, Byzantium Viewed by the Arabs, p. 87; Lewis, The Political Language of Islam, p. 55.
90
Abī al-Qāsim ibn Ḥawqal al-Naṣībī, Kītāb ṣūrat al-ard (Beirut: Manshurat Dar Mak-
tabat al-Hayāh, [1963]), p. 181; Ibn Hauqal, Configuration de la terre (Kitab Surat al-ard),
trans. Johannes H. Kramers and G. Wiet (Paris: G. P. Maisonneuve et Larose, 1964), 1:194.
91
El Cheikh, Byzantium Viewed by the Arabs, p. 197.
92
Ibn Khaldûn, The Muqaddimah: An Introduction to History, trans. Franz Rosenthal
(New York: Pantheon Books, 1958), 2:50.
93
Averroès (Ibn Rušd), Commentaire moyen à la Rhétorique d’Aristote, ed. and French
trans. Maroun Aouad (Paris: Vrin, 2002), 2:70. For further discussion, see Commentaire
moyen à la Rhétorique, 3:35; as well as Rémi Brague, The Legend of the Middle Ages: Philosophi-
cal Explorations of Medieval Christianity, Judaism, and Islam, trans. from the French Lydia G.
Cochrane (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2009), pp. 122–123.
826 journal of world history, december 2012
94
General accounts of the decline of the Byzantine Empire include Jonathan Harris,
The End of Byzantium (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 2010); John F. Haldon,
“The Byzantine Empire,” in The Dynamics of Ancient Empires: State Power from Assyria to
Byzantium, ed. Ian Morris and Walter Scheidel (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2009), pp.
205–254; Motyl, Imperial Ends, pp. 59–61; Franz Georg Maier, “Byzanz: Selbstbehauptung
und Zerfall einer Großmacht,” in Das Verdämmern der Macht: Vom Untergang großer Reiche,
ed. Richard Lorenz (Frankfurt a. M.: Fischer Taschenbuch Verlag, 2000), pp. 44–59; Peter
Schreiner, “Schein und Sein: Überlegungen zu den Ursachen des Untergangs des byzan-
tinischen Reiches,” Historische Zeitschrift 266 (1998): 625–647; Donald M. Nicol: “Der Fall
von Byzanz,” in Das Ende der Weltreiche: Von den Persern bis zur Sowjetunion, ed. Alexander
Demandt (Munich: C. H. Beck, 1997), pp. 61–73; Nicol, “Der Niedergang von Byzanz,”
in Byzanz, ed. Franz G. Maier (Frankfurt a. M.: Fischer, 1973; repr., Augsburg: Weltbild-
Verl., 1998), pp. 348–406; Nicol, Church and Society in the Last Centuries of Byzantium:
The Birkbeck Lectures, 1977 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1979; repr., 1993);
Klaus-Peter Matschke, “Der Untergang einer Großmacht. Thesen und Hypothesen zur Stel-
lung von Byzanz in einer vergleichenden Niedergangsgeschichte von Staaten und Gesell-
schaften,” Zeitschrift für Geschichtswissenschaft 37 (1989): 890–904; Franz Tinnefeld, “Zur
Krise des Spätmittelalters in Byzanz,” in Europa 1400: Die Krise des Spätmittelalters, ed. Fer-
dinand Seibt and Winfried Eberhard (Stuttgart: Klett-Cotta, 1984), pp. 284–294; as well as
Ivan Dujčev, “Die Krise der spätbyzantinischen Gesellschaft und die türkische Eroberung
des 14. Jahrhunderts,” Jahrbücher für Geschichte Osteuropas 21 (1973): 481–492; Peter Cha-
ranis, “Economic Factors in the Decline of the Byzantine Empire,” Journal of Economic His-
tory 13 (1953): 412–424, repr. in Charanis, Social, Economic and Political Life in the Byzantine
Empire, no. 9; Dionysios A. Zakythinos, Crise monétaire et crise économique à Byzance du XIIIe
au XVe siècle (Athens: L’Hellénisme contemporain, 1948); Rodolphe Guilland, “Vénalité
et favoritisme à Byzance,” Revue des Études Byzantines 10 (1952): 35–46; and, in general,
Warren Treadgold, A History of the Byzantine State and Society (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford
University Press, 1997); Donald M. Nicol, The Last Centuries of Byzantium, 1261–1453,
2nd ed. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1993). A detailed discussion of the role of
the Byzantine Empire in Mediterranean trade appears in Angeliki E. Laiou [-Thomadakis],
“The Byzantine Economy in the Mediterranean Trade System; Thirteenth–Fifteenth Cen-
turies,” Dumbarton Oaks Papers 34–35 (1980/81): 177–222, repr. in Laiou, Gender, Society
and Economic Life in Byzantium (Hampshire: Variorum, 1992), no. 7. Consider also Lazaros
Houmanidis, Byzantine Commerce, the Impact on It of Arab Expansion and of the Rise of the
Italian Cities (Thessalonike, 1968).
95
I am grateful to Professor Anthony Kaldellis for discussions on this point.
Syros: The Rise and Decline of Empires 827
who ascribed the social tensions that arose during Nikephoros Pho-
kas’s reign to high taxation and the exploitation of the people, John
Skylitzes (late eleventh century) mentions in his Synopsis Historiōn (A
Synopsis of Histories) that Phokas, who was vilified by some of his
contemporaries as a belligerent ruler, incurred the hatred of his subjects
by imposing excessive taxation and turning a blind eye to the abuses
of the military and the plundering and pillage of the people’s prop-
erty. Skylitzes denounces Phokas’s policies to create additional sources
of revenues and raise supplement taxes: in particular, he criticizes the
Byzantine emperor for abrogating some of the financial benefits of the
members of the senate on the pretext of lacking funds to sustain the
war effort, terminating the financial aid offered to religious houses and
churches, and passing a law that prohibited the expansion of ecclesias-
tical property. Last but not least, the emperor caused the devaluation
of the existing currency (nomisma) by introducing an additional form
of currency, the tetarteron.96
The degeneration of Byzantine political strength was visible as
early as the eleventh century,97 as evidenced by Michael Attaleiates’s
(1020/1030–1085) references to misgovernment and venality in the
imperial administration as the prime causes of Byzantine decadence
especially in the aftermath of the Byzantine army’s defeat by Seljuq
96
Hans Thurn, ed., Ioannis Scylitzae Synopsis historiarum (Berlin: De Gruyter, 1973),
pp. 273–274; John Skylitzes, A Synopsis of Byzantine History, 811–1057, trans. John Wortley
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Presss, 2010), pp. 262–264. Skylitzes’s views on Pho-
kas’s reign are discussed in Eirene-Sophia Kiapidou, John Skylitzes’ Synopsis of Histories and
Its Sources (811–1057): A Contribution to Byzantine Historiography during the 11th Century [in
Greek] (Athens: Kanakes, 2010), pp. 345–359. See, in general, also Rosemary Morris, “The
Two Faces of Nikephoros Phokas,” Byzantine and Modern Greek Studies 12 (1988): 83–115.
On the tetarteron in particular, consult Cécile Morrisson, “Monnayage et monnaies,” in
Économie et société à Byzance (VIIIe–XIIe siècle): Textes et documents, ed. Sophie Métivier
(Paris: Publications de la Sorbonne, 2007), pp. 157–165, 163; Michael F. Hendy, Studies in
the Byzantine Monetary Economy, c. 300–1450 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
1985), pp. 506–508; Hendy, “Light Weight Solidi, Tetartera, and The Book of the Prefect,”
Byzantinische Zeitschrift 65 (1972): 57–80, repr. in Hendy, The Economy, Fiscal Administra-
tion and Coinage of Byzantium (Northampton: Variorum Reprints, 1989), no. 9; Hélène
Ahrweiler[-Glykatzi], “Nouvelle hypothèse sur le tétartèron d’or et la politique monétaire
de Nicéphore Phocas,” Zbornik Radova Vizantološkog Instituta 8 (1963): 1–9, repr. in Ahrwei-
ler, Etudes sur les structures administratives et sociales de Byzance (London: Variorum Reprints,
1971), no. 3. Gustave Schlumberger’s Un empereur byzantin au dixième siècle, Nicéphore Pho-
cas (Paris: Librairie de Firmin-Didot et cie, 1890) is an older study, but still valuable for its
insights into Byzatine-Arab relations during Phokas’s reign.
97
An extensive treatment of critiques of Byzantine leadership as articulated in Byz-
antine historiography in the period between the sixth and thirteenth centuries appears in
Franz Hermann Tinnefeld, Kategorien der Kaiserkritik in der byzantinischen Historiographie von
Prokop bis Niketas Choniates (Munich: W. Fink, 1971).
828 journal of world history, december 2012
98
For further discussion, see Paul J. Alexander, “The Strength of Empire and Capital as
Seen through Byzantine Eyes,” Speculum 37 (1962): 339–357, 356–357, repr. in Alexander,
Religious and Political History and Thought in the Byzantine Empire (London: Variorum, 1978),
no. 3. The process of economic decline in twelfth-century Byzantium has been studied by
Alan Harvey, “Economy,” in Palgrave Advances in Byzantine History, ed. Jonathan Harris
(London: Palgrave Macmillan, 2005), pp. 83–99, esp. 91–96; Harvey, Economic Expansion in
the Byzantine Empire 900–1200 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990); Michael F.
Hendy, “Byzantium, 1081–1204: An Economic Reappraisal,” Transactions of The Royal His-
torical Society, ser. 5, 20 (1970): 31–52, repr. in Hendy, The Economy, Fiscal Administration
and Coinage of Byzantium, no. 2. For other aspects of the decay of Byzantine power during
the same period, see Vassiliki N. Vlyssidou, ed., The Empire in Crisis (?): Byzantium in the
11th Century (1025–1081) (Athens: National Hellenic Research Foundation/Institute for
Byzantine Research, 2003); Judith Herrin, “The Collapse of the Byzantine Empire in the
Twelfth Century: A Study of Medieval Economy,” University of Birmingham Historical Jour-
nal 12 (1970): 188–203; Speros Vryonis Jr., “Byzantium: The Social Basis of Decline in the
Eleventh Century,” Greek, Roman and Byzantine Studies 2 (1959): 157–175, repr. in Vryonis,
Byzantium: Its Internal History and Relations with the Muslim World, no. 2. On the erosion of
Byzantine identity and the spread of Islam in Asia Minor, see Speros Vryonis Jr., The Decline
of Medieval Hellenism in Asia Minor and the Process of Islamization from the Eleventh through
the Fifteenth Century (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1971; repr., 1986); and, in
general, Manzikert to Lepanto: The Byzantine World and the Turks 1071–1571 [= Byzantinische
Forschungen 16 (1991)], ed. Anthony Bryer and Michael Ursinus (Amsterdam: A. M. Hak-
kert, 1991); Alexis G. Savvides, The Turks and Byzantium, vol. 1, Pre-Ottoman Tribes in Asia
and in the Balkans [in Greek] (Athens: Domos, 1996). For the thirteenth and fourteenth
centuries, see George Georgiades Arnakis, The Early Osmanlis: A Contribution to the Problem
of the Fall of Hellenism in Asia Minor (1282–1337) [in Greek] (Athens: N. Frandjeskakis,
1947; repr., Athens: Archipelagos, 2008). Finally, Muslim reactions to the Byzantine defeat
at Mantzikert are covered in El Cheikh, Byzantium Viewed by the Arabs, pp. 178–181. Also
of value are the following studies by Speros Vryonis Jr.: “A Personal History of the History
of the Battle of Mantzikert,” in Byzantine Asia Minor (6th–12th cent.) (Athens: National
Hellenic Research Foundation/Institute for Byzantine Research, 1998), pp. 225–244; “The
Greek and Arabic Sources on the Battle of Mantzikert, 1071 A.D.,” in Byzantine Studies:
Essays on the Slavic World and the Eleventh Century, ed. Speros Vryonis Jr. (New Rochelle,
N.Y.: Aristide D. Caratzas, 1992), pp. 125–140; as well as Claude Cahen, “La campagne de
Mantzikert d’après les sources musulmanes,” Byzantion 9 (1934): 613–642.
99
Miguel Ataliates, Historia, ed. and parallel Spanish trans. Immaculada Pérez Martín
(Madrid: Consejo Superior de Investigaciones Científicas, 2002), pp. 144–145; Wladimir
Brunet de Presle and Immanuel Bekker, eds., Michaelis Attaliotae historia (Bonn: Weber,
1853), pp. 195–198. An English translation of Attaleiates’s History by Anthony Kaldellis
Syros: The Rise and Decline of Empires 829
and Dimitris Krallis for the Dumbarton Oaks Medieval Library series is currently in prepa-
ration. On Attaleiates’s views on the military disintegration of the Byzantine Empire, see
Speros Vryonis Jr., “The Eleventh Century: Was There a Crisis in the Empire? The Decline
of Quality and Quantity in the Byzantine Armed Forces,” in Vlyssidou, The Empire in Crisis
(?), pp. 17–43, 18–34. Attaleiates’s political ideas are discussed in Dimitris Krallis, Michael
Attaleiates and the Politics of Imperial Decline in Eleventh-Century Byzantium (Tempe: Ari-
zona Center for Medieval and Renaissance Studies, 2012); Krallis, “‘Democratic’ Action
in Eleventh-Century Byzantium: Michael Attaleiates’s ‘Republicanism’ in Context,” Viator
40 (2009): 35–53; Anthony Kaldellis, “A Byzantine Argument for the Equivalence of all
Religions: Michael Attaleiates on Ancient and Modern Romans,” International Journal of the
Classical Tradition 14 (2007): 1–20; and Alexander Kazhdan, Studies on Byzantine Literature
of the Eleventh and Twelfth Centuries (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; Paris: Édi-
tions de la Maison des Sciences de l’Homme, 1984), “The Social Views of Michael Atta-
leiates,” pp. 23–86.
100
The economic aspects of Byzantine decay are examined in Angeliki E. Laiou and
Cécile Morrisson, The Byzantine Economy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2007),
pp. 228–230; and, in general, the studies by Angeliki E. Laiou, “Economic Thought and
Ideology,” and “The Byzantine Economy: An Overview,” both in The Economic History of
Byzantium: From the Seventh through the Fifteenth Century, ed. Angeliki E. Laiou (Washing
ton, D.C.: Dumbarton Oaks Research Library and Collection, 2002), pp. 1123–1144 and
1145–1164, respectively. Consider also Christos P. Baloglou, “Economic Thought in the
Last Byzantine Period,” in Ancient and Medieval Economic Ideas and Concepts of Social Justice,
ed. S. Todd Lowry and Barry Gordon (Leiden: Brill, 1998), pp. 405–438; Alexander N. Dio-
medes, “Economic Vicissitudes of the Decaying Byzantium,” Revue des Sciences Économiques
et Financières 8 (1939): 277–303 [in Greek]. For heavy taxation as a cause of Byzantium’s
fall, see notably Peter Schreiner, “Zentralmacht und Steuerhölle. Die Steuerlast im Byzan-
tinischen Reich,” in Mit dem Zehnten fing es an: Eine Kulturgeschichte der Steuer, ed. Uwe
Schulze, 2n ed. (Munich: C. H. Beck, 1986), pp. 64–73. Critiques of monastic property
are discussed in Peter Charanis, “The Monastic Properties and the State in the Byzantine
Empire,” Dumbarton Oaks Papers 4 (1948): 53–118, repr. in Charanis, Social, Economic and
Political Life in the Byzantine Empire: Collected Studies (London: Variorum Reprints, 1973),
no. 1. On tax exemptions, see Nicolas Oikonomidès, Fiscalité et exemption fiscale à Byz-
ance (IXe-XIe s.) (Athens: National Hellenic Research Foundation/Institute for Byzantine
Research, 1996). Consider also Emili[o] Herman, “Zum kirchlichen Benefizialwesen im
Byzantinischen Reich,” Studia et Documenta Historiae et Iuris 3 (1937): 253–264. For late
830 journal of world history, december 2012
Byzantine debates on decline, see, e.g., Speros Vryonis Jr., “Crises and Anxieties in Fifteenth
Century Byzantium: The Reassertion of Old, and the Emergence of New Cultural Forms,”
in Islamic and Middle Eastern Societies, ed. Robert Olson (Brattleboro, Vt.: Amana Books,
1987), pp. 100–125; Jan-Louis van Dieten, “Politische Ideologie und Niedergang im Byzanz
der Palaiologen,” Zeitschrift für Historische Forschung 6 (1979): 1–35; Ihor Ševčenko, “The
Decline of Byzantium Seen through the Eyes of Its Intellectuals,” Dumbarton Oaks Papers
15 (1961): 169–186, repr. in Ševčenko, Society and Intellectual Life in Late Byzantium (Lon-
don: Variorum Reprints, 1981), no. 2; Franz Dölger, “Politische und geistige Strömungen
im sterbenden Byzanz,” Jahrbuch der Österreichischen Byzantinisischen Gesellschaft 3 (1954):
3–18; Hans-Georg Beck, Theodoros Metochites, die Krise des byzantinischen Weltbildes im 14.
Jahrhundert (Munich: C. H. Beck, 1952).
101
The factors that led to the famine are surveyed in Angeliki Laiou, “The Provision-
ing of Constantinople during the Winter of 1306–1307,” Byzantion 37 (1967): 91–113. On
Andronikos’s rule in general, see Angeliki Laiou, Constantinople and the Latins: The Foreign
Policy of Andronicus II, 1282–1328 (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1972);
Ursula Victoria Bosch, Kaiser Andronikos III. Palaiologos: Versuch einer Darstellung der byzan-
tinischen Geschichte in den Jahren 1321–1341 (Amsterdam: A. M. Hakkert, 1965).
102
The Correspondence of Athanasius I, Patriarch of Constantinople: Letters to the Emperor
Andronicus II, Members of the Imperial Family, and Officials, ed., trans., and comm. Alice-
Mary Maffry Talbot (Washington, D.C.: Dumbarton Oaks Center for Byzantine Studies,
1975), Letter 93 (Greek text p. 242, English trans. p. 243). On Athanasios, see Correspon-
dence of Athanasius I, “General Introduction,” pp. xv–xxxi; as well as Emmanuel Patedakis,
“Athanasios I Patriarch of Constantinople (1289–1293, 1303–1309): A Critical Edition
with Introduction and Commentary of Selected Unpublished Works” (PhD diss., University
of Oxford, 2004); John L. Boojamra, The Church and Social Reform: The Policies of the Patri-
arch Athanasios of Constantinople (New York: Fordham University Press, 1993); Boojamra,
“Social Thought and Reforms of Athanasios of Constantinople (1289–1293; 1303–1309),”
Byzantion 55 (1985): 332–382; Boojamra, Church Reform in the Late Byzantine Empire: A
Study of the Patriarchate of Athanasios of Constantinople (Thessalonike: Patriarchal Institute
for Patristic Studies, 1982); Demetrios J. Constantelos, “Life and Social Welfare Activ-
ity of Patriarch Athanasios I (1289–1293, 1303–1309) of Constantinople,” in Byzantine
Ecclesiastical Personalities, ed. Nomikos M. Vaporis (= The Byzantine Fellowship Lectures;
2) (Brookline, Mass.: Holy Cross Orthodox Press, 1975), pp. 73–88; Klaus-Peter Matschke,
“Politik und Kirche im spätbyzantinischen Reich: Athanasios I., Patriarch von Konstanti-
nopel 1289–1293; 1303–1309,” Wissenschaftliche Zeitschrift der Karl-Marx-Universität Leipzig:
Gesellschafts- und Sprachwissenschaftliche Reihe 15 (1966): 479–486, repr. in Matschke, Das
spätbyzantinische Konstantinopel: Alte und neue Beiträge zur Stadtgeschichte zwischen 1261 und
1453 (Hamburg: Verlag Dr. Kovač, 2008), pp. 89–113; and with an eye to the relations
between Athanasios and Andronikos, Joseph Gill, “Emperor Andronikos II and the Patri-
Syros: The Rise and Decline of Empires 831
arch Athanasius I,” Byzantina 2 (1970): 13–19; and Nicolae Bănescu, “Le patriarche Atha-
nase Ier et Andronic II Paléologue: État religieux, politique et social de l’empire,” Académie
roumaine. Bulletin de la section historique 23 (1942): 28–56. Consider also Joseph Kalothetos’s
(fl. 1336–1341) biography of Athanasios: “Vios kai politeia tou en agiois patros ēmōn archi-
episkopou Kōnstantinoupoleōs Athanasiou,” in Ioseph Kalothetou Suggramata, ed. Demetrios
G. Tsames (Thessalonike: Center for Byzantine Studies, 1980), pp. 453–502.
103
The Correspondence of Athanasius I Patriarch of Constantinople, Letter 65 (152/153).
104
Ibid., Letter 93 (242/243).
105
Ibid., Letter 68 (160 and 162/163 and 165). On the transportation of grain supplies
and food provisions in the Byzantine Empire, see Johannes Koder, “Maritime Trade and the
Food Supply for Constantinople in the Middle Ages,” in Travel in the Byzantine World, ed.
Ruth Makrides (Aldershot: Ashgate, 2002), pp. 109–124; John L. Teall, “The Grain Supply
of the Byzantine Empire, 330–1025,” Dumbarton Oaks Papers 13 (1959): 87–139; Georges
I. Brătianu [Bratianu], “Nouvelles contributions à l’étude de l’approvisionnement de Con-
stantinople sous les Paléologues et les empereurs ottomans,” Byzantion 6 (1931): 641–656;
Brătianu, “La question de l’approvisionnement de Constantinople à l’époque byzantine et
ottomane,” Byzantion 5 (1929/30): 83–107.
106
The Correspondence of Athanasius I Patriarch of Constantinople, Letter 100 (256/257).
See also ibid., Letter 106 (266/267).
107
Ibid., Letter 106 (266/267).
108
Vasileios Syros, “Between Chimera and Charybdis: Byzantine and Post-Byzantine
Views on the Political Organization of the Italian City-States,” Journal of Early Modern
History 14 (2010): 451–504, 467–472; Angeliki E. Laiou, “Economic Concerns and Atti-
tudes of the Intellectuals of Thessalonike,” Dumbarton Oaks Papers 57 [= Symposium on Late
Byzantine Thessalonike] (2003): 205–223; Laiou, “Social Justice: Exchange and Prosperity in
Byzantium,” Proceedings of the Academy of Athens 74 (1999): 107–132 [in Greek]; Peter Cha-
ranis, “On the Social Structure and Economic Organization of the Byzantine Empire in the
Thirteenth Century and Later,” Byzantinoslavica 12:94–153, repr. in Charanis, Social, Eco-
nomic and Political Life in the Byzantine Empire, no. 4. On the Zealot revolution, see John W.
Barker, “Late Byzantine Thessalonike: A Second City’s Challenges and Responses,” Dumbar-
ton Oaks Papers 57 (2003): 5–33, esp. 14–21; Donald M. Nicol, The Reluctant Emperor: A
Biography of John Cantacuzene, Byzantine Emperor and Monk, c. 1295–1383 (Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 1996), pp. 45–83; Konstantinos Kotsiopoulos, “The Zealots
of Thessalonike and their Popular Basis,” Ta Vyzantina 18 (1995/96): 277–284 [in Greek];
Klaus-Peter Matschke, “Thessalonike und die Zeloten: Bemerkungen zu einem Schlüssel-
ereignis der spätbyzantinischen Stadts- und Reichsgeschichte,” Byzantinoslavica 55 (1994):
832 journal of world history, december 2012
r. 1328–1341) death in June 1341, his chief minister, John Kanta
kouzenos (1292–1383), served as the effective regent for John V (1332–
1391), Andronikos’s infant son, and proclaimed himself emperor four
months later. In 1342, a political group that called themselves Zealots
and were led by the grand duke (= commander-in-chief of the Byzan-
tine navy) Alexios Apokaukos (late thirteenth century–1345) set up
a popular regime in Thessalonike. The conflict touched off a series of
revolts in other cities, with the nobility backing Kantakouzenos and
the middle and lower classes supporting John V and the Zealots. The
Zealot regime came to an end when Kantakouzenos recovered Thes-
salonike in 1350.
Nikephoros Choumnos’s (1250/55–1327) speech Thessalonikeusi
sumvouleutikos peri Dikaiosunēs (Exhortatory Oration on Justice) pro-
vides intriguing insights into the background of the events surrounding
the Zealot movement and a vivid description of the poverty conditions
19–43; Matschke, Fortschritt und Reaktion in Byzanz im 14. Jahrhundert: Konstantinopel in der
Bürgerkriegsperiode von 1341 bis 1354 (Berlin: Akademie-Verlag, 1971); Daphne Papadatou,
“Political Associations in the Late Byzantine Period: The Zealots and Sailors of Thessa-
lonica,” Balkan Studies 28 (1987): 3–23; Peter Charanis, “Internal Strife in Byzantium during
the Fourteenth Century,” Byzantion 15 (1941): 208–230, repr. in Charanis, Social, Economic
and Political Life in the Byzantine Empire, no. 6; Oreste Tafrali, Thessalonique au quatorzième
siècle (Paris: P. Geuthner, 1913; repr., Thessalonike: Idryma Meleton Hersonesou tou Aimou,
1993); and in general Günter Weiss, Johannes Kantakuzenos—Aristokrat, Staatsmann, Kaiser
und Mönch—in der Gesellschaftsentwicklung von Byzanz im 14. Jahrhundert (Wiesbaden: O.
Harrassowitz, 1969); Franz Dölger, “Johannes VI. Kantakuzenos als dynastischer Legitimist,”
Seminarium Kondakovianum 10 (1938): 19–30, repr. in Dölger, Παρασπορα: 30 Aufsätze zur
Geschichte, Kultur und Sprache des byzantinischen Reiches (Munich: Buch-Kunstverlag Ettal,
1961), pp. 194–207. On the intellectual life of late Byzantine Thessalonike, consult Costas
N. Constantinides, “The Origin of the Flourishing of Learning in Thessaloniki during the
Fourteenth Century,” Dodonē 21 (1992): 133–150 [in Greek]; Daniele Bianconi, Tessalonica
nell’età dei Paleologi: Le pratiche intellettuali nel riflesso della cultura scritta (Centre d’études
byzantines, néo-helléniques et sud-esteuropéennes, École des Hautes Études en Sciences
Sociales, 2005); Franz Tinnefeld, “Intellectuals in Late Byzantine Thessalonike,” Dumbarton
Oaks Papers 57 (2003): 153–172; Vassilis Katsaros, “Literary and Intellectual Life in Byzan-
tine Thessaloniki,” in Queen of the Worthy: Thessaloniki, History and Culture, ed. Ioannes K.
Hassiotis (Thessalonike: Paratiritis, 1997), pp. 305–332; Constantine N. Constantinides,
“The Beginnings of the Intellectual Acme in Thessalonike in the 14th Century,” Dōdōnē 21
(1992): 133–150 [in Greek]; Ioannes E. Anastasios, “Education in Thessalonike in the 14th
Century,” Vuzantina 13 (1985): 909–921 [in Greek]; Donald M. “Thessalonica as a Cultural
Centre in the Fourteenth Century,” in Ē Thessalonikē metaxu Anatolēs kai Duseos (Thessa-
lonike: Etaireia Makedonikōn Spoudōn, 1982), pp. 121–131, repr. in Nicol, Studies in Late
Byzantine History and Prosopography (London: Variorum Reprints, 1986), no. 10; as well as
the articles in Macedonia during the Palaeologan Era (Thessalonike: Aristotle University of
Thessalonike, 1992), esp. Basiliki Papoulia, “Intellectual Currents in Macedonia during the
Fourteenth Century” (pp. 63–73) and Alkmini Stavridou-Zafraka, “The Physiognomy of
Thessalonike as the Second City of the Byzantine Empire during the Palaeologan Era” (pp.
75–84) [both in Greek].
Syros: The Rise and Decline of Empires 833
109
Jean F. Boissonade, Anecdota græca e codicibus regiis (Paris: Excusum in Regio Typog-
rapheo, 1830; repr., Hildesheim: Olms, 1962), 2:137–187.
110
On Choumnos, see Ihor Ševčenko, Études sur la polémique entre Théodore Métochite
et Nicéphore Choumnos: La vie intellectuelle et politique à Byzance sous les premiers Paléologues
(Brussels: Byzantion, 1962); and Jean Verpeaux, Nicéphore Choumnos: Homme d’État et
humaniste byzantin (ca 1250/1255–1327) (Paris: A. et J. Picard, 1959).
111
Verpeaux, Nicéphore Choumnos, p. 35.
112
Tinnefeld, “Intellectuals in Late Byzantine Thessalonike,” p. 165.
113
Boissonade, Anecdota græca e codicibus regiis, 2:168–169. See also Zakythinos, Crise
monétaire et crise économique à Byzance, pp. 46–47.
114
The text was first edited by Vasileios Laourdas, “Thoma Magistrou Tois Thessaloni-
keusi peri omonoias,” Epistēmonikē Epetēris Scholēs Nomikōn kai Oikonomikōn Epistēmōn Aris-
toteleiou Panepistēmiou Thessalonikēs 12 (1969): 751–775, 753–768, and has been reprinted
with facing modern Greek translation (pp. 66–115) and commentary (pp. 116–140) in
Sotiria Triantari-Mara, The Political Thought of Fourteenth Century in Thessaloniki: Oration to
the Thessalonicans on Concord by Thomas Magistros; an Approach on the Contribution of Politi-
cal Philosophy to Modern Times (Athens: Herodotos, 2002). Surveys of Magister’s life and
oeuvre include Sotiria A. Triantari, Politics, Rhetoric and Communication in the Fourteenth
and the Twenty-first Century: Oration about Kingdom and about State of Thomas Magistros
[in Greek] (Thessalonike: A. Stamoulis, 2009), pp. 17–37; Bianconi, Tessalonica nell’età dei
Paleologi, pp. 72–90; and Stephanos K. Skalistes, Thomas Magistros: His Life and Œuvre [in
Greek] (Thessalonike: Aristotle University of Thessaloniki, 1984).
115
For Magister’s contribution to the reception and study of the classical legacy,
see Niels Gaul, Thomas Magistros und die spätbyzantische Sophistik: Studien zum Humanis-
mus urbaner Eliten in der frühen Palaiologenzeit (Wiesbaden: O. Harrassowitz, 2011); Gaul,
“Moschopulos, Lopadiotes, Phrankopulos (?), Magistros, Staphidakes: Prosopographisches
und Methodologisches zur Lexikographie des frühen 14. Jahrhunderts,” Super alta perennis
4 (2008): 163–196, 184–190; Gaul, “The Twitching Shroud: Collective Construction of
Paideia in the Circle of Thomas Magistros,” Segno e Testo 5 (2007): 263–340; Vasileios Laour-
das, “Classical Philology in Thessalonike in the Fourteenth Century,” Etaireia Makedonikōn
Spoudōn. Idruma Meletōn Hersonesou tou Aimou 37 (1960): 5–20 [in Greek]. On late
834 journal of world history, december 2012
Byzantine philologists in general, see Sophia Mergiali, L’Enseignement et les Lettrés [sic] pen-
dant l’époque des Paléologues (1261–1453) (Athens: Société des Amis du Peuple, Centre
d’Études Byzantines, 1996), pp. 49–59.
116
There is no scholarly consensus as to which of the two events Magister is referring
to. I am inclined to the view that Magister alludes to both the conflict between Andronikos
II and his grandson Andronikos III and the events that precipitated the Zealot revolt. For
a similar interpretation and review of previous scholarship, see Triantari-Mara, The Political
Thought of Fourteenth Century in Thessaloniki, pp. 37–53. On the conflict between Androni-
kos II and his grandson, see Nicol, The Last Centuries of Byzantium, chap. “The Question
of the Succession and the First Civil War,” pp. 151–166; as well as Leonidas Mavrommatis,
The First Palaiologoi: Problems of Political Praxis and Ideology (Athens: Syllogos pros Diadosin
ton Hellenikon Grammaton, 1983), pp. 52–78; Konstantinos P. Kyrris, Byzantium in the 14th
Century (Nicosia: Lampousa, 1982) [both in Greek].
117
Patrologia Græca; 145, ed. Jacques-Paul Migne (Paris: J.-P. Migne and Garnier,
1904), pp. 447–495 and 495–547; partial English trans. in Social and Political Thought in
Byzantium, from Justinian I to the Last Palaeologus; Passages from Byzantine Writers and Docu-
ments, trans. Ernest Barker (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1957), pp. 163–168 and 168–173,
respectively; modern Greek trans. and commentary in Triantari, Politics, Rhetoric and Com-
munication in the Fourteenth and the Twenty-First Century, pp. 166–403; Italian trans. Toma
Magistro, La regalità, ed. and trans. Paola Volpe Cacciatore (Naples: M. D’Auria, 1997).
Scholarly treatments of Magister’s political ideas include: Sotiria [A.] Triantari[-Mara], Poli-
tics, Rhetoric and Communication in the Fourteenth and the Twenty-first Century, pp. 75–164;
Triantari, The Political Views of Byzantine Thinkers from Tenth to Thirteenth Century (Thessa-
lonike: Herodotos, 2002), pp. 167–257; Triantari, “Political Views in Thomas More’s Utopia
and Thomas Magistros’s On Kingship and On the State,” Parnassos 44 (2002): 317–338 [all
in Greek]; Christos P. Baloglou, “Thomas Magistros’ Vorschläge zur Wirtschafts- und Sozi-
alpolitik,” Byzantinoslavica 60 (1999): 60–70; Ioannis G. Leontiadis, “Untersuchungen zum
Staatsverständnis der Byzantiner aufgrund der Fürsten- bzw. Untertanenspiegel (13. bis 15.
Jahrhundert)” (PhD diss., University of Vienna, 1997), pp. 107–149; Léon-Pierre Raybaud,
Le gouvernement et l’administration centrale de l’empire byzantin sous les premiers Paléologues
(1258–1354) (Paris: Sirey, 1968), pp. 24–35. For a study that situates Magister in the history
of late Byzantine advice literature, see Konstantinos D. S. Paidas, The Byzantine Mirrors of
Princes of the Late Period (1254–1403): Expressions of the Byzantine Royal Ideal [in Greek]
(Athens: Grigoris, 2006).
Syros: The Rise and Decline of Empires 835
Providence that causes the fluctuations in the affairs of the world and
transfers sovereignty from one people to another. In the fictional Dialo-
gos plousiōn kai penētōn (Dialogue [between] Rich and Poor, ca. 1344),
Makremvolites captures the feverish strife and social rifts that con-
vulsed the Byzantine world in the thirteenth century and points to the
suffering of the poor, who were at the mercy of the wealthy.118
Another major late Byzantine intellectual who witnessed the reper-
cussions of the Zealot episode and got embroiled in contemporary
debates on the economic and social ills that plagued the empire was
Nikolaos Kavasilas (ca. 1322–ca. 1390), a cleric and scion of a promi-
nent noble family from Thessalonike. In his Peri tokou (On Interest),
an oration addressed to Anna of Savoy (Palaiologina, 1306–ca. 1365)
that was written around 1351, he expresses unqualified disdain for the
rich who, as he observes, engage in unjust actions, seek profit by ruin-
ing others, and behave like robbers, thieves, and wild animals.119
In his Logos kata tokizontōn (Oration against Usurers), Kavasilas
118
Ihor Ševčenko, “Alexios Makrembolites and His Dialogue between the Rich and the
Poor,” in Zbornik Radova Vizantološkog Instituta 6 (1960): 187–228, 213, 225, repr. in Šev
čenko, Society and Intellectual Life in Late Byzantium (London: Variorum Reprints, 1981),
no. 7. Makrembolites’s social ideas are discussed also in Dimitrios G. Magriplis, “Sociologi-
cal Approaches to Byzantine History: Conclusions from the Study of Alexios Makremvoli-
tis’ Dialogue between the Rich and the Poor (14th Century),” Vyzantinos Domos 15 (2006):
107–124 [in Greek]; Klaus-Peter Matschke and Franz Tinnefeld, Die Gesellschaft im späten
Byzanz: Gruppen, Strukturen und Lebensformen (Cologne: Böhlau, 2001), pp. 344–347; Eva
de Vries-van der Velden, L’élite byzantine devant l’avance turque à l’époque de la guerre civile
de 1341 à 1354 (Amsterdam: J. C. Gieben, 1989), pp. 251–289; and Costas P. Kyrres, “Elé-
ments traditionnels et éléments révolutionnaires dans l’idéologie d’Aléxios Makrembolitès
et d’autres intellectuels byzantins du XIVe s.,” in Actes du XIVe Congrès International des
Etudes Byzantines (Bucharest: Editura Academiei Republicii Socialiste România, 1975),
2:177–188.
119
Rodolphe Guilland, “Le Traité inédit ‘sur l’usure’ de Nicolas Cabasilas,” in Eis
mnēmēn Spyridōnos Lamprou (Athens: Epitropē Ekdoseōs tōn kataloipōn Spyridōnos Lam-
prou, 1935), pp. 269–277, 274; Laiou, “Economic Concerns and Attitudes of the Intellectu-
als of Thessalonike,” p. 217; Matschke and Tinnefeld, Die Gesellschaft im späten Byzanz, pp.
347–349. See further Marie-Hélène Congourdeau, “Hésychasme et palamisme,” in Histoire
du christianisme, vol. 6, Un temps d’épreuves (1274–1453) (Paris: G. Beauchesne, 1990), pp.
557–563, 508–510; Christos P. Baloglou, “Kavasilas’ Economic Thought,” Byzantiaka 16
(1996): 191–213 [in Greek]; as well as Niketas Siniossoglou, Radical Platonism in Byzantium:
Illumination and Utopia in Gemistos Plethon (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2011),
pp. 359–369; Peter Charanis, “Observations on the ‘Anti-Zealot’ Discourse of Cabasilas,”
Revue des Etudes Sud-Est Européennes 9 (1971): 369–376, repr. in Charanis, Social, Economic
and Political Life in the Byzantine Empire, no. 7. For Kavasilas’s life and works, consult Marie-
Hélène Congourdeau, Correspondance de Nicolas Cabasilas (Paris: Les Belles Lettres, 2010),
pp. xi–xvii; Yannis Spiteris and Carmelo G. Conticello, “Nicola Cabasilas Chamaetos,” in La
Théologie byzantine et sa tradition, vol. 2, XIIIe–XIXe s., ed. Carmelo G. Conticello and Vassa
Conticello (Turnhout: Brepols, 2002), pp. 315–410; Yannis Spiteris and Patrizia Morelli,
Cabasilas, teologo e mistico bizantino: Nicola Cabasilas Chamaetos, e la sua sintesi teologica (Rome:
Lipa, 1996); Constantine N. Tsirpanlis, “The Career and Writings of Nicolas Cabasilas,”
836 journal of world history, december 2012
Byzantion 49 (1979): 414–427; George T. Dennis, “Nicholas Cabasilas Chamaëtos and His
Discourse on Abuses Committed by Authorities against Sacred Things,” Byzantine Studies/
Études Byzantines 5 (1978): 80–87, repr. in Dennis, Byzantium and the Franks, 1350–1420
(London: Variorum Reprints, 1982), no. 11; Horst Müller-Asshoff, “Beobachtungen an den
Hauptschriften des Gregorios Palamas und Nikolaos Kabasilas,” Byzantinische Zeitschrift 70
(1977): 22–41; Athanasios A. Angelopoulos, Nikolaos Kavasilas Chamaetos, His Life and
Work (A Contribution to Macedonian Byzantine Prosopography) [in Greek] (Thessalonike:
Patriarchal Institute for Patristic Studies, 1970); Sévérien Salaville, “Quelques précisions
pour la biographie de Nicolas Cabasilas,” in Proceedings of the Ninth International Congress of
Byzantine Studies (Athens: Myrtides, 1958), 3:215–226; as well as the following studies by
Ihor Ševčenko: “Nicolas Cabasilas’ ‘Anti-Zealot’ Discourse: A Reinterpretation,” Dumbar-
ton Oaks Papers 11 (1957): 81–171; “The Author’s Draft of Nicolas Cabasilas’ ‘Anti-Zealot’
Discourse in Parisinus Gr. 1276,” Dumbarton Oaks Papers 14 (1960): 181–201; “A Postcript
on Nicolas Cabasilas’ ‘Anti-Zealot’ Discourse,” Dumbarton Oaks Papers 16 (1962): 403–408,
all three repr. in Ševčenko, Society and Intellectual Life in Late Byzantium, nos. 6, 5, and 4,
respectively. A survey of Byzantine attitudes to interest appears in Lazaros T. Houmanidis,
“On Usury during the Byzantine Era,” Vuzantinai Meletai 6 (1995): 104–122 [in Greek].
120
Patrologia Graeca 150: 727–750. See also Laiou, “Economic Concerns and Attitudes
of the Intellectuals of Thessalonike,” p. 213; Matschke and Tinnefeld, Die Gesellschaft im
späten Byzanz, pp. 349–355.
121
Laiou, “Economic Concerns and Attitudes of the Intellectuals of Thessalonike,” p.
215.
122
For further references and discussion, see Jonathan Harris, “Laonikos Chalkokon-
dyles and the Rise of Ottoman Turks,” Byzantine and Modern Greek Studies 27 (2003): 153–
170; Harris, “The Influence of Plethon’s Idea of Fate on the Historian Laonikos Chalko-
kondyles,” in Proceedings of the International Congress on Plethon and His Time, Mystras, ed.
Syros: The Rise and Decline of Empires 837
Conclusion
George Gemistos Plethon: The Last of the Hellenes (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1986; repr.,
2000), pp. 92–109; N. Patrick Peritore, “The Political Thought of Gemistos Plethon: A
Renaissance Byzantine Reformer,” Polity 10 (1977): 168–191; Johannes Irmscher, “Die
Wandlungen der Staatsidee im ausgehenden Byzanz,” Rivista di cultura classica e medioevale
19 (1977): 446–450; J. Duncan M. Derret, “Gemistus Plethon, the Essenes, and More’s
Utopia,” Bibliothèque d’Humanisme et Renaissance 27 (1965): 579–606; John Mamalakis,
“The Impact of Contemporary Events on George Gemistos’ Ideas,” in Proceedings of the
Ninth International Congress of Byzantine Studies, ed. S. Kyriakides et al. [in Greek] (Athens:
Typographeion Myrtidi, 1956), 2:498–532, esp. 504–511; Johannes Draseke, “Plethons und
Bessarions Denkschriften über die Angelegenheiten im Peloponnes,” Neue Jahrbücher für
das klassische Altertum, Geschichte und deutsche Literatur 27 (1911): 102–119; and Henry F.
Tozer, “A Byzantine Reformer,” Journal of Hellenic Studies 7 (1886): 353–380.
124
Georgios Gemistos to Manuel Palaeologus concerning the Affairs in the Peloponnese—
Lampros, Palaiologeia kai Peloponnēsiaka, 3:246–265—partial English trans. in Barker, Social
and Political Thought in Byzantium, pp. 198–206. Consider also Finlay’s translation in Balo-
glou, “George Finlay and Georgios Gemistos Plethon,” pp. 36–42.
125
Lampros, Palaiologeia kai Peloponnēsiaka, 3:263. Plethon’s economic ideas are dis-
cussed in Christos P. Baloglou, “Economic Thought in the Last Byzantine Period,” pp.
405–438, 424–430; Baloglou, Georgios Gemistos-Plethon: Ökonomisches Denken in der spät-
byzantinischen Geisteswelt (Athens: Historical Publications St. D. Basilopoulos, 1998); Sav-
vas P. Spentzas, G. Gemistos Plethon, the Philosopher of Mystra: His Economic, Social and Fiscal
Views [in Greek] (Athens: Ekdoseis M. Kardamitsa, 1987).
Syros: The Rise and Decline of Empires 839
126
Bernard Lewis, What Went Wrong? The Clash between Islam and Modernity in the
Middle East (New York: Perennial, 2003), chap. “Modernization and Social Equality,” pp.
82–95.
127
Lewis, What Went Wrong?, chap. “Secularism and the Civil Society,” pp. 96–116.
128
See, for example, the following two collections of essays edited by Peter F. Bang and
Christopher A. Bayly: Tributary Empires in Global History (Houndmills: Palgrave Macmil-
lan, 2011) and Tributary Empires in History: Comparative Perspectives from Antiquity to the
Late Medieval [= The Medieval History Journal 6, no. 2 (2003)]. The comparative study of the
Roman, Mughal, and Ottoman empires is the subject of the international research project
“Tributary Empires Compared” at the SAXO Institute at the University of Copenhagen. A
comparative investigation of the decline of the Ottoman, Safavid, and Mughal empires can
be found in Rohan D’Souza, “Crisis before the Fall: Some Speculations on the Decline of
the Ottomans, Safavids and Mughals,” Social Scientist 30 (2002): 3–30. See also in general:
Stephen F. Dale, The Muslim Empires of the Ottomans, Safavids, and Mughals (Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 2010); Francis Robinson, “Ottomans-Safavids-Mughals:
Shared Knowledge and Connective Systems,” Journal of Islamic Studies 8 (1997): 151–184;
Halil Berktay, “Three Empires and the Societies they Governed: Iran, India and the Otto-
man Empire,” Journal of Peasant Studies 18 (1992) [= New Approaches to State and Peasant
in Ottoman History, ed. Halil Berktay and Suraiya Faroqhi]: 247–263; İ. Metin Kunt, “The
Later Muslim Empires: Ottomans, Safavids, Mughals,” in Islam: The Religious and Political
Life of a World Community, ed. Marjorie Kelly (New York: Praeger, 1984), pp. 113–136.
840 journal of world history, december 2012