Darby 1975
Darby 1975
Darby 1975
SUMMARY
‘The author wishes to acknowledge helpful conversations with Armen Alchian, Milton Friedman,
and John Pippenger, with the usual acknowledgement that only credit for wisdom but not blame
for remaining errors can be shared. An earlier version of this paper was presented at the meetings
of the Western Economic Association, Las Vegas, Nevada, June 11, 1974. H. Irving Forman drew
the diagrams.
1. See Irving Fisher, “A Statistical Relation Between Unemployment and Price Changes,”
conveniently reprinted as “I Discovered the Phillips Curve” (1973). A constant hazard of any foray
into macroeconomics, including this one, is the significant probability that Fisher has already dis-
cussed the matter somewhere in his voluminous writings, only better. The basic idea of expected
inflations’ being reflected in interest rates derives from as early as Fisher (1896).
since both borrower and lender will agree to allow for inflation-induced
decreases in the real principal value at the rate a,.5 Observation of
higher rates of inflation will cause the expected rate of inflation to rise
and approach the new equilibrium rate of inflation pl . Since the increase
in the equilibrium rate of inflation ( p l - po) is equal to the increase in
the rate of growth of the money supply (gl - go), it is argued that
nominal interest rates will increase by the same amount in final
equilibrium.
In the standard presentations it is assumed that the liquidity effects
and income effects exactly cancel in their effects on the real interest
rate so that the nominal interest rate increases in final equilibrium by
exactly the increase in the rate of inflation ( p I - po = g, - go). This
assumption has not been firmly based however on either static or
dynamic analysis. If there is a negative interest elasticity of the demand
for monef and the nominal interest rate is increased, the desired ratio
of money to income will fall. This may affect both real income and the
real rate of interest.
5. These statements are based on continuous compounding. If annual compounding were used,
the right hand side would be increased by the interaction term ru.
6. This appears to depend on the conditions of money supply. Benjamin Klein (1970; 1974)
has developed an estimator of the yield paid on demand deposits. This yield usually moves in
proportion to the yield on short-term bonds. I (1972) have shown that, for the postwar U.S. data,
the net effect of changes in interest rates was zero for a fully specified stock-adjustment model,
Peltzman (1969) had previously found similar results for a stock-adjustmentmodel using consumer
expenditures as a proxy for an appropriatemix of wealth and cyclical portions of income.
DARBY: INTEREST RATES 269
l l t
'0
Cagan and Gandolfi (1969) and Gibson (May, 1970; May/June, 1970)
have argued that the time pattern of effects of monetary policy on
interest rates can be used to obtain information about the lags in the
effect of monetary policy on nominal income.10 Since there must be
significant increases in real income and the price level to stop the decline
of the interest rate and start its increase, the trough of interest rate
changes would provide a measure of the time lag between an increase
in monetary growth and its significant effect on nominal income. This
argument assumes that the expectations effect is not operative at the
time of trough, but this may be unreasonable for economies that have
undergone large monetary swings in the past.
A more crucial difficulty - it appears to me - is that the interest rate
used is typically for short-term marketable securities." The cyclical
response of this class of interest rates can be explained by variations in
yield differentials without reference to effects of real income and the
price level on the demand for money. Bankers use marketable securities
as an adjustment asset (or secondary reserve) to absorb the shocks of
10. Note also that Cagan and Gandolfi examine the problem as stated here (a maintained increase
in the growth rate of money) while Gibson's work tends to emphasize the effects of once-and-for-all
changes in the money supply. This would seem to explain the shorter length of time for interest rates
to bottom out found by Gibson than was found by Cagan and Gandolfi. Excess cash balances will
continue to increase for some time in the continued increase case as opposed to the one-shot increase
case studied by Gibson.
11. For example, the commercial paper rate is used by Cagan and Gandolfi (1969)and Treasury
Bill rates by Gibson (May/June 1970).
DARBY: INTEREST RATES 271
The first term on the right hand side is the gross receipts per dollar, the
second term is the tax liability shifted from borrower to lender, and the
third term is the change in the real value of the principal sum. If the
real after-tax interest rate is constant at 7 *in long-term equilibrium,
then the nominal rate of interest, for a constant T, is given by
Fisher’s view that expected inflation rates are quite sluggish appears
more plausible.
Empirical estimates of the formation of expectations based on the
simple Fisher equation (2) instead of the corrected version (4)are subject
to considerable doubt. Specification bias due to constraining the coeffi-
cient of the expected rate of inflation to unity will exist for some methods.
Other methods use the equation (2) only for the interpretation of uncon-
strained results, so that the interpretation - but not the estimates
themselves - is affected. These problems are completely separate from
the specification difficulties of models which interpret correlation of
short-lag rates of inflation and the nominal interest rate as capturing
the expectations effect instead of the ‘income effect.’
If we consider the standard data on disposable income under expected
inflation there will be two main types of upward bias: (1) The real burden
of the inflationary tax on money will be added to the “true” income and
savings data. (2) Net interest payments by government and consumers
will increase stated income and savings by the amount of the return of
capital portion of interest payments.
as banks begin to increase their loans and decrease their demand (at least
in a flow sense)for marketable securities.
On the other hand, as time passes and nominal income adjusts to its
new steeper growth path, the rate of inflation will increase, then over-
shoot, and eventually settle at a rate (gl - go) above the original rate.
This increased rate of inflation will cause the expected rate of inflation
to rise and the difference between nominal and real interest rates to
increase.13 The nominal interest rate must rise by 1/(1 - r ) basis points
for each basis point increase in the expected rate of inflation, where T is
the marginal income tax rate, in order to leave borrowers’ and lenders’
expected payments and receipts unaffected in real terms. Achievement
of full adjustment takes many years in the postwar U.S.
Whether the real rate of interest is unaffected in full equilibrium is
not known. It could be unaffected, rise, or fall depending on whether
the desired ratio of money to income is altered and how this effects the
aggregate production function and real savings ratio. Convincing empir-
ical evidence is lacking. Real interest rates on marketable securities may
also be affected if there is a significant segmentation of the capital market
remaining in the long-run which alters yield differentials. The initial
segmentation implied by the financial effect is consistent with either no
or some residual long-run capital market segmentation.
The idealized pattern of the cyclical adjustment of interest rates to
an increase in the rate of growth in the money supply is illustrated in
Figure 2.
Figure 2. The Complete Model of Effects of Monetary Policy on Interest Rates
‘0
13. Indeed expectations may adjust before inflation is experienced under certain informational
conditions in which the change in the growth rate of the money supply is observed or announced
that leads to direct predictions of future inflation. See Darby (forthcoming) for a detailed analysis
of the use of such exogenous information in the formation of expectations.
DARBY: INTEREST RATES 275
REFERENCES
T. J. Sargent, “Anticipated Inflation and the Nominal Rate of Interest,” Quarterly journal of
Economics, 86 (May 1972). 212-26.
, “Commodity Price Expectations and the Interest Rate,” Quarterly Journal of Eco-
nomics, 83 (February 1969), 127-40.
, “Rational Expectatons, the Real Rate of Interest, and the Natural Rate of Unemploy-
ment,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, No. 2, 1973, 429-80.
B. W. Sprinkel, Money and Markets. Homewood, Ill.: Irwin, 1971
F. G. Steindl, “Price Expectations and Interest Rates,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 5
(November 1973), 939-49.
J. Tobin, “Money and Economic Growth,” Econometrica, 33 (October 1965),671-84.
S. Turnovsky, “Empirical Evidence on the Formation of Price Expectations,” Journal of the
American Statistical Association, 65 (December 19701, 1441-54.
W. P. Yohe and D. S. Karnosky, “Interest Rates and Price Level Changes, 1952-69,” Federal Reserve
Bank of St. Louis Reuiew, 51 (December 1969). 18-29.