Majority Rule - A Cause of War, Peter Emerson
Majority Rule - A Cause of War, Peter Emerson
Majority Rule - A Cause of War, Peter Emerson
Introduction
Democracy, as practised in most countries nowadays, is
adversarial. The fact that presidents andlor policies are
changed as the result of a vote rather than as a consequence
of a bloody revolution or war is to be welcomed. Sometimes,
however, the distinction between peaceful and violent change
is muddled. Indeed, the use of divisive voting procedures has
often exacerbated tensions in societies that have then
tumbled into violence. Win-or-lose voting procedures — i.e.
yes-or-no majority votes in decision-making and single
preference systems in elections — along with a practice which
is based on these voting methodologies, namely, that of
majority rule, have often been part of the problem.
An Historical Background
In earlier times and in many cultures, the democratic process
was rather more inclusive. In yesterday’s America, for
example, ‘The tribes gathered and discussed the issue at
hand, listening and speaking until common understanding
had been reached. [a] practice of government by
consensus Similarly, in parts of Africa, ‘Majority rule was
a foreign notion’? and instead, to quote Tanzania-is first
President, Julius Nyerere, ‘The elders talk until they agree.
This “talking until you agree" is the essential of the traditional
African concept of democracy’.“ The sub-Saharan attitude to
conflict resolution was also rather different: to quote an
example from Ethiopia, ‘If someone is quarrelling with
someone else, then the court will set itself the sole task of
ending the conflict while granting to each that he is in the
right’?
A more exclusive form of democracy emerged in Europe
and America where philosophers like Jean-Jacques
Rousseau and Jeremy Bentham spoke of ‘le volonté général,
the general will’ and ‘the greatest good of the greatest
number’. Having seen the errors and horrors caused by
various forms of minority rule, especially those of the absolute
monarchs, it seemed obvious to them and many others that
rule by a majority would be a huge improvement. Hence,
today, we have statements such as ‘Democracy rests upon
the principles of majority rule’.6 Few would disagree.
There then came a huge mistake: it was assumed that a
majority opinion could be identified by a majority vote. Despite
huge advances in so many fields of science, including that of
social choice, this assumption still holds. Thus many believe
that ‘Democracy works on the basis of a decision by the
majority’,7 and that ‘Democracy is based on majority
decision’? The world — or at least the Western world —
appears to be committed to the majority vote.9
In many countries, then, current democratic structures are
based on a majority vote form of decision-making. As a direct
consequence of this, most parliaments divide into two —
government and opposition — either under single-party rule or
in majority/grand coalitions. While some international
organizations try to operate in consensus — and by that is
meant a verbal consensus — many forums base their
decisions on a (simple, weighted, qualified or consociational)
majority vote. Such an adversarial democratic structure is
perhaps adequate in some jurisdictions; elsewhere, however,
it has been a recipe for division, violence and, at worst, war.
This chapter will examine some of the dreadful
consequences which have resulted from this Western, if not
now universal, practice of majoritarianism,” first in decision-
making, secondly, in elections. In addition, it will question the
logic of such a polity with particular reference to conflict
resolution work.
Majoritarianism in Decision-Making
There are a number of instances where simplistic voting
procedures and/or inadequate democratic structures have at
the very least exacerbated tensions in society. They include i)
majority vote plebiscites on secession; and ii) majority votes
taken in parliaments and international organizations.
The Caucasus
Lessons were unlearnt. When Mikhail Gorbachev introduced
his policy of perestroika, the USSR started to break up. In
1991, Georgia opted out.“ Whereupon Abkhazia and South
Ossetia, and very nearly Ajaria as well, opted out of Georgia:
on October 3, 1999 in Abkhazia, in an 88 percent turnout, 97
percent supported independence; and on February 18, 2007,
South Ossetia followed with a 99 percent margin. Hence
more violence: in 1992, it was between the region and the
nation; in 2008, it was outright war between Georgia and
Russia.“ Meanwhile, in Nagorno-Karabakh on December 10,
1991, i.e. after its war, a majority of 99.89 percent voted for
independence, and only 24 individuals bravely said ‘no’.’6
In today’s Russian Federation, the prospect of a similar
chain of events has come to be called ‘matrioshka
nationa|ism’,” named after the famous Russian dolls: lurking
within every majority is another minority; within that, a smaller
one; in every smaller one, a tiny one; and inside that again, a
miniscule one. There is the fear, certainly among some
Russian politicians, that if one part of the Federation were to
opt out — like Chechnya — others would surely follow; which
partly explains why the two recent wars in that Republic were
so bitter.
The Balkans
In Yugoslavia in the 1990s, a major political question was the
dichotomy, ‘Are you Serb or Croat?’ For many people in what
is now Croatia, this closed question was of course
unanswerable: the partners in or children of a mixed
marriage; those who were neither Orthodox nor Catholic;
those like the \/lahs or the Roma who were of another ethnic
minority; and most tragically of all perhaps, those Slavs and
others who were trying to move beyond any sort of
antagonistic nationalism. Alas, the binary format was chosen
for the Croatian referendum question in May 1991:
independence, ‘yes or no?’ The Serb minority in the Krajina —
three areas in Croatia which had a predominantly Serb
population — organized their own ballot one week earlier. In
the latter poll, a turn-out of 95 percent voted by a 90 percent
margin to stay in Yugoslavia. The international community did
not recognize it. In the other poll, 93 percent of an 84 percent
turnout voted for Croatian independence. This result was
recognized. The other consequence of both votes was war.
In November 1991, the EU set up the Badinter
Commission, a team of international lawyers to consider the
problems of Yugoslavia.’8 It endorsed the referendum and, as
a result, there was a spate of such ballots: votes in Slovenia,
Croatia, Macedonia (polls which preceded the work of the
commission) and Bosnia were recognised; votes which did
not produce the required result, as in Montenegro, were
repeated; and votes which were not wanted were just not
recognized — Republika Srpska, Herzeg-Bosna, Sandzak,
and Kosovo — unless or until, of course, the West changed its
mind.” The Commission did not, however, question the
methodology of the majority vote. The final comment comes
from Sarajevo’s now legendary newspaper, Oslobodjenje: ‘all
the wars in the former Yugoslavia started with a
referendum’.2°
Rwanda
In the 1930s, the Belgian authorities issued everyone in
Rwanda with an ID card. The question was closed: ‘Are you
Hutu or Tutsi?’ Now Rwandan society was quite unlike
Kenya’s, for example, where different tribal groups speak
different languages. In Rwanda, in contrast, they all live
cheek by jowl and everyone speaks the one language,
Kinyarwanda. The Belgians nevertheless decided to split
everyone into two, and thus they converted a social
distinction into a tribal one. Those who were tall were called
Tutsi, the small were the Hutu (the Twa were ignored), and
anyone of average build was asked if they had ten or more
cows; in effect, another closed question. Those who said ‘yes
were classified as Tutsi; the ‘no’s were Hutu?’
Having supported a form of minority rule — in which the
tiniest minority, the colonialists, were on top — the authorities
post-WWII changed their minds and argued for its opposite,
majority rule. So the losers of yesterday could become the
winners of tomorrow. Little wonder, then, that when the
lnterahamwe launched their gruesome genocide in 1994, the
slogan they used was ‘Rubanda Nyamwinshi’, ‘the majority
people’.22
Sudan
In all the words that have been written on the Rwandan
genocide, few have questioned the practice of interpreting the
principle of majority rule to mean the practice of majority
voting. Instead, as in the Balkans, so too in Africa, the
international community blunders on. In July 2002, British
diplomats were present in Kenya when the two sides to the
civil war in Sudan, the Khartoum government and the
Sudanese People’s Liberation Movement, SPLMP3 signed the
Machakos Protocol to end that war. Inter alia, this agreement
promised a binary referendum in South Sudan on whether or
not the latter could have independence. Here was the answer
the South wanted. But if one part of the country could gain its
objectives by waging a war, and then negotiating a settlement
to hold a referendum, then why not another? In a word,
balkanization. ‘[I]f the South were to secede, this would open
a Pandora’s box in the whole of Sudan.’2“‘
The first consequence took place in what was already a
very turbulent region: Darfur. Literally within months, in early
2003, another ‘movement’, the Sudanese Liberation
Movement, SLMF5 again with an army to match, resorted to
violence. The government responded with its now notorious
Janjaweed.26
The South Sudan referendum was held in January 2011
and, on the whole, it passed off peacefully; the actual
handover of power is scheduled for July 2011. A second
consequence of Machakos, however, is that further
referendums are already in the pipeline. Within Sudan, the oil-
rich region of Abyei on the border between North and South is
due to hold its own referendum shortly; there has already
been some violence there. Meanwhile, South Kurdufan and
Blue Nile are due to hold consultations on the initial basis of
an eitherlor question.
Consequences further afield may be even more traumatic.
Somaliland now wants a referendum to secede from the rest
of Somalia. They are the first. And elsewhere? Will the
Moslem North try to secede from the Christian South in
Nigeria, a land that has often seen violence in Kaduna, which
straddles the two, including post-election violence in April
2011? Will something similar happen in Ivory Coast, a land
which saw two rivals from a previous civil war participate in a
win-or-lose election and which, partly as a result, descended
into more violence? (see below). Consequences in the DRC
could be even worse.
In effect, the international community has now exported
the right of self-determination and the practice of binary
plebiscites to a continent of almost unlimited ethnic or tribal
diversity. Little could be more unwise. South Sudan may be
just the calm before the storm. I hope not; suffice here to say,
however, that when Slovenia held its referendum in 1990,
many people did not realize that there would very soon be
ghastly consequences elsewhere in Yugoslavia.
Multi-option referendums
The referendum has been suggested and/or used in a
number of other conflict zones, often with serious
consequences. One was proposed for Kashmir in 1947, but
never implemented; Northern Ireland held its border poll in
1972, to which the mainly Catholic Social Democratic and
Labour Party, SDLP, organized a boycott;27 and in 1999, East
Timor’s referendum led to massive post-ballot violence.
In contrast, some jurisdictions have used multi-option
ballots: Newfoundland held a three-option poll in 1948,
Singapore did the same in 1962 and so did Puerto Rico five
years later; while in Guam in 1982, there were six options on
the ballot paper, and just in case that was not enough, a
further seventh option was left blank, for any other
suggestion.” All of these polls were held under a form of two-
round voting, TRS, and all passed off peacefully. Preferential
polls could be even more inclusive.
Ukraine
Kenya
C6te d’|voire
Some systems are more suitable for plural societies: the more
sophisticated forms of PR-list, for example. But any system
that allows the voter to cast only one preference — i.e. which
thus restricts the voter’s ability to express his/her full opinion
— is not much better than the majority vote used in decision-
making. Elections under such a system in places like Bosnia
and Kosova are often little more than sectarian headcounts.38
The same was true in elections for the Council of
Representatives in Iraq and for the House of People (Wolesi
Jirga) in Afghanistan, the former under PR-list, the latter
under the single non-transferable vote, SNTV; again, both are
single preference forms of voting. Therefore they are often
inaccurate. Furthermore they are divisive if not indeed
dangerous.
Some countries have tried to devise a more inclusive, or
at least a non-sectarian, electoral system. Lebanon uses a
multiple form of FPP such that, in any constituency where
there are say, 25 percent Maronite, 50 percent Shia and 25
percent Sunni, any party wishing to stand must nominate four
candidates: 1 Maronite, 2 Shia and 1 Sunni. Furthermore, the
voter must vote for 1 + 2 + 1 candidates, and the easiest way
for them to do so is to just vote for the party ticket.39 Dagestan
has devised another non-sectarian system: in one
constituency, all the candidates of every party must be of one
religion; in a second constituency, they are all of another faith;
and so on.4° Of those other electoral systems which allow the
voter to cast his/her preferences across the sectarian divide,
the most inclusive are probably PR-STV and the quota Borda
system, OBS, not least because they are not based on party
labels or ‘designations’.“’
Conflict Resolution
If the political process is to be a means by which disputes can
be resolved peacefully, it should be one of mediation, just as
it was originally in Africa. Now in seeking to arbitrate any
dispute, domestic, industrial or political, professional
mediators seldom ask questions which are closed. Rather,
they talk to both or all parties, firstly to find outjust what
options exist. Next, in a process that is sometimes called
shuttle diplomacy, they try to improve on some of these
options, to make them more acceptable to the other parties.
And finally, they aim to identify that option which enjoys the
widest level of support from all concerned. In any instances of
violence, internal or external, the eventual resolution will often
consist of a compromise. In other words, as in Africa, the
mediators will treat both or all sides (at least initially) as if they
were both or all (at least to some extent) right.
In the Middle East, the best option on offer is probably the
two-state solution, not least because neither Palestine nor
Israel would contemplate the ideal — the one-state solution —
for as long as either believes in majority rule.
In other scenarios, too, the outcome must often involve a
form of power-sharing. This should consist of the following:
An inclusive polity
In short, voting procedures should be ‘peace-ful’, that is, the
democratic process should be a vital part of the peace
process, and the relevant voting procedures should enable
the voters to use the democratic process as an act of
reconciliation, if of course such is their wish.
In decision-making, the very structure of the ballot should
allow the voter to cast a preference for those options that
have been proposed by the erstwhile foe. If a negotiation
relies on a majoritarian process, the various participants
might well keep their cards fairly close to their chests. After
all, ‘Once your fall-back positions are published, you have
already fallen back to them’.“2 If the final vote were to be
preferential, however — and this author would suggest the
MBC — then those concerned could reveal and even adjust
their own preferences at any stage of the debate.“
In elections, the voter in NI should be able to vote for both
a Catholic and a Protestant.“ Likewise those in Bosnia
should be able to cast their preferences across the gender,
the party and the ethno-religious divides. As noted above, the
Lebanese have an electoral system that could, in theory, take
religion out of politics. Unfortunately, their system of
governance actually entrenches sectarianism, just like the
consociational decision-making in the Belfast Agreement.“
Finally, in governance, just as the people elect the
parliament (and, if the electoral system is a good one, that
parliament will represent all the people), so too parliament
should elect the government, again by a system of PR, such
that the government represents the entire parliament. The
only methodology for a parliament to elect a cabinet in which
each member undertakes a different responsibility and yet
which, overall, represents the given parliament proportionally,
is the matrix vote.“ In many conflict zones — Kenya and
Zimbabwe, for example — negotiations on power-sharing have
been both problematic and protracted. In Belgium, too,
forming a government can involve seemingly endless
negotiations, and on February 17, 2011, Brussels inherited
the mantle previously held by Baghdad and before that
Amsterdam, for the longest running talks on forming a
government: 250 days.”
Conclusions
A voting procedure is inadequate if the choice of
options/candidates and/or the ability of the voter to express a
full opinion has been excessively restricted. In some conflict
zones, the outcome of a vote has been different to that of the
opinion poll. In Northern Ireland, for example, throughout the
troubles, the public consistently expressed support for
integrated education, mixed housing and power-sharing; alas,
in elections, in large part, those same individuals chose
politicians who at the time opposed such measures.
Furthermore, while the British government realized that the
choice of electoral system was very important — and hence,
they reintroduced PR-STV in 1972 — they continued to use
FPP elections for Westminster. In February 1974, the
Unionists got 53 percent of the vote and 92 percent of the
seats. So the FPP voting system was part of the
discrimination that caused and then fed ‘the Troubles’.
Likewise in Bosnia, ‘public opinion polls in May and June
1990, and again in November 1991, also showed
overwhelming majorities (in the range of 70 to 90 percent)
against separation from Yugoslavia and against an ethnically
divided republic’."‘8 Yet the single-preference electoral system
used in 1990, TRS, gave the voters little choice, and the
result was an overwhelming victory for the three ethnic
parties.
Sometimes, then, the use of majority voting in parliaments
and referendums, the use of simplistic single-preference
electoral systems, and the absence of any voting mechanism
by which a parliament can elect a government, have given
results which, as a minimum, do not reflect the general will;
and at worst, they have been a cause of war. There are,
however, better more inclusive voting procedures.
Appendix: Abbreviations