MFIs and Transactions Cost (Final)
MFIs and Transactions Cost (Final)
MFIs and Transactions Cost (Final)
Jovi C. Dacanay
Department of Economics
I would like to thank the following who have guided and inspired me in the course of
Professor Victor Venida for his patience and guidance during our Economic Research
Professor Noel De Guzman for his valuable comments before, during and after the
presentation,
My family, friends and colleagues from the University of Asia and the Pacific for helping,
2
3
ABSTRACT
problem or issue which the study addresses is to determine how MFIs in the Philippines
are able to attain operational self-sufficiency, the established indicator for financial
phenomenon may be verified by the following research question: does the behavior of
operational and transactions costs among group and individual microfinance lenders
manifest experience or learning curve spillovers and a U-shaped supply curve? The
study has two objectives. First, using appropriate measures of financial and social
performance, the study shall empirically verify the phenomenon of experience or learning
curve spillovers among MFIs. Second is to estimate the supply curve for loans to the
The results of the pooled least squares with cross-section random effects
regression estimation show that both NGOs and rural banks are attaining both objectives
spillover effects of learning, that is, fast learning for rural banks and moderate learning
for NGOs. Operational and transactions costs are high but decreasing for both rural
banks and NGOs. Older, more mature NGOs and rural banks are able to set transactions
cost at the prescribed level of 11%-25%. Such costs ensure that the MFIs operate in
4
TABLE OF CONTENTS
Acknowledgments ……………………………………………………………….………..2
Abstract ………………………………………………………………………….………..4
D. Methodology ………………..………………………………………….….…….13
Chapter II. Operational Self-Sufficiency, Cost per Dollar of Loan and Transactions
C. Theoretical Issues…………………………………..……………………..….…23
D. Empirical Issues…….…………………………………...……………….…...….27
A. Hypothesis…………………...…………………………………………….…..…27
C. Methodology………………………………………………………….…...……..42
D. Data Sources……………………………………………………...…..………….52
5
B. Learning Curve Spillover and U-Shaped Supply Curve Analysis.…...…….…...59
Bibliography ......................................................................................................................76
Appendices……………………………………………………………………………….80
6
LIST OF TABLES
Table 4.1 Transactions Cost of Rural Banks and NGOs from 2000 to 2011 by Age ......53
Table 4.2 Transactions Cost of Rural Banks and NGOs (2000 to 2011) by Age and
Table 4.3 Relevant Information on Chosen Rural Banks and NGOs (2000-2011) ..........55
Table 4.4 Transaction Cost per Borrower of Rural Banks and NGOs (2000 to 2011) by
Table 4.5 Selected Indicators for Operational Efficiency and Social Performance….....57
Table 4.6 Variables Used for the Learning Curve Spillover and U-Shaped Supply Curve
Regressions………………………………………………..…………….……….59
Table 4.9 U-Shaped Supply Curve Regression for Rural Banks and NGOs………..….68
Table 4.10 Experience or Learning Curve Spillover, Transactions Cost and a U-Shaped
7
LIST OF FIGURES
Figure 3.1 Why Poor Consumers Did Not Receive Loans ................................................30
Figure 3.2 Why Money Lenders Lend at High Interest Rates ...........................................32
Figure 3.5 Profit Margin, Operational Self-Sufficiency and Return on Assets for Rural
Figure 4.1 Experience Curve for Rural Banks and NGOs .................................................61
Figure 4.2 Experience Curve for Rural Banks and NGOs using Asset Specificity ……..63
Figure 4.3 Estimated U-Shaped Supply Curve for Rural Banks and NGOs……….……66
Figure 4.4 Transactions Cost and Experience or Learning Curve Spillovers ....................66
Figure 4.5 Operational and Social Outreach Efficiency among Rural Banks and NGOs .70
8
LIST OF APPENDICES
Table C.2 Experience Curve Regression on Personnel Cost per Dollar of Loan………86
Table C.3 U-Shaped Supply Curve Regression on Cost per Dollar of Loan…………..87
9
CHAPTER I
INTRODUCTION
regulatory environment. For four years in a row (2009-2012), the Economist Intelligence
Unit’s global survey has ranked the Philippines as number one in the world in terms of
policy and regulatory framework for microfinance. The Philippines is also consistently
ranked at the top ten for having a good microfinance business environment. The survey
noted that the Philippines recorded material gains in transparency in pricing given the
The study investigates the relationship between transactions cost and operational
costly. This leads to the main problem of the paper: In spite of the presence of
transactions cost, can the microfinance industry achieve operational efficiency? The
study has two objectives. First, using appropriate measures of financial and social
performance, the study shall empirically verify a downward sloping experience curve.
Second is to estimate the supply curve for loans to the unbanked poor and verify that it is
U-shaped. Both objectives shall lead the study to a verification of decreasing operations
cost and transactions cost, thereby allowing MFIs to operate more efficiently.
10
B. Significance of the Research Question
The Philippines has a favorable regulatory environment which allows rural banks
made accessible to the unbanked, that is, micro entrepreneurs. Reason is that the
regulatory environment allows rural banks to financially include them. Why? There has
been a significant increase in the number of active borrowers in the Philippines since
1994. Microfinance activities have been existing previous to the 1997 establishment the
regulatory body called National Credit Council. Through microfinance, the unbanked,
that is, micro entrepreneurs who do not have access to the lending activities and practices
of commercial banks, had access to loans. Now, financial services to the poor are
provided by NGOs, cooperative and rural banks. (Economic Intelligence Unit (EIU),
Previous regulation by the Central Bank of the Philippines had directed credit,
also called subsidized credit which did not work. Reason: micro entrepreneurs have to
be trained and assisted in order to finance and operate a business viably. There was a
policy environment that enhances financial inclusion and effective financial access to the
transparency in lending and data collection for existing NGOs can be improved so as to
closely monitor and evaluate the financial and social outreach performance of these
MFIs. The Philippines scored low on a supporting institutional framework which would
11
standards of accounting, dispute settlements for unfair and time-consuming loan
processes, an integrated credit bureau and policy and practice of financial transactions
through agents (EIU 2013). Even if the microfinance industry has allowed e-commerce,
Globe Telecom, to be made available for the payment of loans, loan officers are crucial in
order to monitor and ensure the regular payment of loans. All these seem to denote high
transactions cost.
Such high transactions costs may hinder the further expansion of financial access
to the unbanked, as there is still 2.9 million families which are unserved by microfinance
67%, unmet demand for micro loans to the entrepreneurial poor, henceforth denoted as
the unbanked.
specificity to explain the reason for high operating costs among MFIs. However, such
types of costs also imply experience and learning. The theoretical formulation of
experience, learning and transactions costs proper to the microfinance industry is non-
existent to date.
Due to a lack of access to actual data per firm over the amount of loans and
interest charged to each borrower, the study focused on annual data per MFI made
mission drift in an MFI. Indicators used in the regressions are based on the accepted
12
accounting variables which are accessible through the MIX website. As a consequence,
relevant variables in the study are interest rates charged to micro-borrowers, human asset
specificity and social performance. The indicators used in the global industry are
operating expense ratio (also known as operating cost per dollar of loan), personnel
expense ratio and the social efficiency index. The computations used by the industry
The social performance indicators used in the study are number of borrowers,
depth of outreach (Average loan size over GDP per capita also termed as national loan
size), and the social efficiency index (Operating Expense Ratio x cost per borrower)
The phenomenon of multiple loans across various MFIs cannot be observed from
the data used, as this phenomenon would involve detailed MFI data. Anecdotal
information claim that some MFIs apply for a loan to other MFIs so as to repay their
loans, leading to over-indebtedness. Previous to 2011, MFIs were allowed to lend only
up to US$3,500. However, a BSP circular issued in 2011 has allowed rural banks to lend
up to US$7,000.
D. Methodology
Exchange Portal, the likelihood of a U-shaped supply curve for loans to the unbanked
poor, due to the high unit cost of transactions, shall be discussed. Then, an analysis of
measures for the microfinance industry, and, indicators for cumulated output shall be
13
done. Operational self-sufficiency is the measurement used to denote financial viability
among MFIs, whereas, the social performance index and the number of women
borrowers and outreach are the variables used to indicate social performance. The
regression estimation procedure, using unbalanced panel data, with cross-section random
effects shall be performed in order to evaluate whether or not the chosen MFIs for the
study are either: (a) decreasing their transactions cost but at a constant or level of
E. Definition of Terms
The following terms are used based on the stated definitions. The
conceptualization and definition of these terms follow Armendáriz and Szafarz (2011)
expenses consume the majority of the income of most microlenders’ loan portfolios, so
this component is the largest determinant of the rate the borrowers end up paying
strategies in order to reach the unbanked and entrepreneurial poor. Financial outcomes
would indicate a lowering of portfolio at risk (90 days), constant or sustained returns to
social objective, which is extending credit by targeting the poor and the excluded, the
14
adaptation of services and products to target customers, and improvement in the equity
Specifically, the social performance of MFIs refers to their mission: the alleviation of
poverty by extending credit to the unbanked poor, while at the same time operating cost
Transaction costs in credit markets therefore are indirect financial costs generated
by various processes, including the cost of searching and collecting relevant information.
They are indirect costs caused by frictions in the flow of credit funds, preventing credit
lending consist of the costs of administering credit, coordination costs and the costs of the
risk of default. It is further highlighted that administrative costs are those which are
coordination costs are those resources a financial institution dedicates to ensuring that
15
CHAPTER II
This chapter contains a review of related literature grouped into those which
A. Historical Development
Past government initiatives for poverty alleviation in the 60s to 80s were focused
on direct credit and guarantee programs, which provided massive credit subsidies to bring
down the cost of borrowing for target sectors. These programs resulted in very limited
effectivity and outreach, and at a great cost to the government’s budget. These programs
were met with massive repayment problems, capture of funds by large-scale borrowers,
neglect of deposit mobilization and huge fiscal costs for the government. (Jimenez and
Roman 2011).
Learning from these experiences, the government policies of the last decade have
shaped reforms to develop a market oriented financial and credit policy environment that
promotes and supports private institutions to broaden and deepen their services; while
government will instead focus not on the actual provision of credit but on creating the
enabling policy environment. It is during this period that the National Strategy for
Microfinance was created imbibing the following principles: 1) Greater role of the private
enabling policy environment that facilitates the increased participation of the private
16
Non-participation of government line agencies in the implementation of credit and
guarantee programs.4 Several laws were enacted in support of this strategy namely;
Social Reform and Poverty Alleviation Act, Agriculture and Fisheries Modernization
Act, Barangay Micro-Business Enterprises Act, Executive Order 138 and the General
Banking Act of 2000. With the National Strategy for Microfinance and the subsequent
policy issuances and laws that were passed, the microfinance market has been driven by
the private sector with the government only providing the enabling policy and regulatory
environment. The strategy also laid the groundwork for the establishment of a regulatory
framework for microfinance as well as the uniform set of performance standards for all
Given this backdrop, there are now three types of institutions that provide
rural banks. The success factor in developing a range of microfinance institutions is that
institutions recognizing the strength of each type in delivering microfinance services. The
current players include eight microfinance oriented banks and 187 thrift and rural banks
with some level of microfinance operations, approximately 300 NGOs where around 30
will have sizeable and significant microfinance portfolios, and 50 cooperatives engaged
services to approximately 1.3 to 1.5 million families. (Jimenez and Roman, 2011). This
number amounts to close to a third of the entrepreneurial poor. (Also see Microfinance
17
Internationally, women, usually, are the clientele, low level of credit available to
the poor in spite of the possibility of high returns (Ashta, 2009; Armendáriz and Szafarz,
2011). The mission of the MFI is to alleviate poverty by extending credit to the
unbanked poor. There are two factors which prompts an MFI to increase its average
loan size over time, thereby lowering depth of outreach. First, progressive lending,
which, in the microfinance jargon, pertains to the idea that existing clients can reach up to
higher credit ceilings after observing a “clean” repayment record at the end of each credit
clients in order to finance a larger number of poor clients whose average loan size is
relatively small. These two explanations are in line with the MFI social objective.
B. Policy Issues
policy and regulatory environment conducive to financial inclusion. This stems from the
recognition that financial inclusion is a worthy policy objective that could and should be
pursued alongside the promotion of stability and efficiency in the financial system. It is
also believed that financial inclusion is a key component of inclusive growth. The BSP is
government’s vision for the financial sector: “an inclusive financial system which
provides for the evolving needs of a diverse public” (Philippine Development Plan 2011-
2016). The financial inclusion initiatives of the BSP are focused on the major areas of:
18
In spite of the absence of a regulatory body for NGOs, the BSP regulates NGOs
through circulars and ordinances. The BSP aims at promoting transparency and good
governance among MFIs through the Issuance of Rules Regarding the Relationship
(Circular 725, 16 June 2011). This issuance recognizes the possible synergy between a
this has become a successful model for some, the issuance aims to ensure that the banks
with related microfinance NGOs are able to safely and viably coexist by mitigating
possible operational, governance and reputational risks. The salient features of the
issuance includes a) requiring clear contractual agreements between the two entities, b)
prohibiting bank personnel from holding any concurrent, full time positions that may
issuing general principle sand standards that will govern the business relationships
between banks and their related NGOs/foundations. (BSP Financial Inclusion Initiatives
(US$3,500). In December 2011, BSP issued Circular 744 that allows banks to offer the
resort to borrowing from other MFIs so as to pay the outstanding balance from a loan.
There is still, however, a need for an integrated credit bureau. Under the Republic
Act 9510 (also known as the Credit Information Act (CISA)), signed into law in 2008, all
19
credit bureau under the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC). A crucial
component of the legislated is the creation of the Central Credit Information Corporation
(CCIC) to receive and consolidate the credit data and to act as a central registry of credit
and replace the existing system of fragmented credit bureaus. Although the law’s
implementing rules and regulation were approved in May 2009, the establishment of the
Central Credit Information Corporation (CICC) has not yet resulted in the operation of a
functioning, active credit bureau. Under the CISA implementing rules and regulations,
the proposed corporation will have a seed capital of Php 75 million. But so far, CCIC
only received Php 17.5 million. The future central depositary of credit history is also still
looking for an office, still forming the organization chart, and outlining plans for the rest
of the year.
Meanwhile, the private sector is pursuing its own initiative. The Banker’s
Association of the Philippines (BAP) has its own credit bureau, which the Rural Bankers
Association of the Philippines, the association of rural banks, is also using. BAP’s credit
pertaining to unpaid loans, loans under litigation, bounced checks and credit card debt.
To encourage rural banks to subscribe to the database BAP-CB lowered the fee for each
inquiry from Php 11 (US$ 0.25) to Php 5.6 (US$ 0.13) and removed the upfront
subscription fee. As of January 2011, twenty rural banks have joined the bureau. Access
to credit information can help rural banks identify whether loan applicants already have
outstanding loans and avoid the problem of over-indebtedness, which can be harmful to
20
the borrowers, the banks and the sector as a whole. BAP’s credit bureau is almost
As a result, the system of fragmented credit bureaus remains intact. For example,
cooperatives based in Mindanao have formed their own credit bureau called CCBOL.
Perhaps the most promising initiative was taken by the leading MFIs. In early 2013, the
CARD Bank, CARD NGO, Negros Women, Ahon sa Hirap and ASA Philippines), which
together serve about 70 percent of the estimated one million micro-borrowers in the
country, signed a memorandum of agreement on the creation of the credit bureau called
the “Microfinance Data Sharing System (MiDAS)”. Initially, MiDAS is meant to focus
on negative information, i.e. delinquent borrowers, with the view later on of establishing
MiDAS are unique to its users, the microfinance institutions, with a special feature that
allows for Barangay (town or village) level search for delinquent borrowers. It is the
intention of the founders to expand the coverage of the credit bureau to other MFIs as
New rules issued by the BSP and effective July 1, 2012 outlaw the use of flat
interest rate calculation methods for regulated institutions. Unregulated NGO-MFIs and
cooperatives are encouraged to follow suit but the BSP lacks the authority to require them
to do so. This makes the calculation of an effective interest rate difficult. Through the
flat balance calculation method, the interest rate is applied to the initial loan amount
throughout the entire loan term. Through this method the borrower pays interest on the
full loan amount even though the amount they have over the loan term is less and less as
21
they repay the loan. Interest rates calculated using the flat balance appear much cheaper
than declining balance rates, but are in fact nearly twice as expensive. For example, an
annual interest rate of 15% charged on a flat balance results in almost the same amount in
interest payments as an annual interest rate of 30% charged on a declining balance. This
can make comparison between the prices of loans difficult, posing a serious obstacle to
MFIs in terms of their ability to make informed price-setting decisions and to clients in
terms of comparing the prices of the loan products available to them. Through the
declining, or reducing, balance interest rate calculation method, the lender charges
interest on the loan balance that the borrower has not yet repaid. This amount declines
over time as the borrower repays the loan, so that interest is only charged on money that
C. Theoretical Issues
causal link as to why there is low level of credit supplied to the poor in spite of high
demand. There is a high demand for credit among the entrepreneurial poor, but these
borrowers have high transactions cost, and commercial lenders would incur low profit.
The transactions cost come about as more effort is needed among commercial lenders,
that is, monitoring costs to ensure frequent and constant payment of loans has to be done.
As a result, there is a discontinuous marginal revenue curve for borrowers among the
micro-borrowers or the entrepreneurial poor vis-à-vis borrowers from small and medium
enterprises. This phenomenon partly explains the existence for a U-shaped supply curve,
a downward sloping steep supply curve for low levels of borrowings, after which it
22
reaches a minimum point, then the supply curve slopes upwards for higher levels of
transactions cost either by individual lending (rural banks) or group lending but with
individual liability (NGOs). NGOs tend to have high information cost, thus, they seek
other sources of funding, i.e. donors or investors (Ashta,2009). With transactions cost
MFIs, i.e. vertically integrated firm has to be the structure due to asset specific
transactions. (Williamson 1989). Skilled loan officers invest time and effort in order to
of loans. This investment of time and effort may be viewed as a sunk cost for both NGOs
and rural banks. Through time, there is an observed decrease in operational costs per
borrower, reflecting the possibility of a downward sloping experience curve for the
economic organization. Questions such as the following are germane: Why are there so
economic organization and best informs the study of these matters? Striking differences
common theory of contract informs all? What core features- in human, technology, and
process respects- does such a common theory of contract rely on? These queries go to the
23
As compared with other approaches to the study of economic organization,
transaction cost economics (1) is more micro-analytic, this means that the behavior of
agents within a firm explain governance costs which are usually not covered within the
scope of the governance costs of the market. (2) is more self-conscious about its
behavioral assumptions, (3) introduces and develops the economic importance of asset
specificity, (4) relies more on comparative institutional analysis, (5) regards the business
firm as a governance structure rather than a production function, (6) places greater weight
on the ex post institutions of contract, with special emphasis on private ordering (as
compared with court ordering), and (7) works out of a combined law, economics and
organization perspective. The basic transaction cost economics strategy for deriving
governance structures (the adaptive capacities and associated costs of which differ) in a
However, the crux, or what gives a rationale for a transactions cost perspective is
that the stage or process of transactions can be divided into several phases. Previous
process of production. For a service industry such as banking, once a borrower has been
properly screened for investment viability by the loan officers of the commercial bank,
the fulfillment of the requirements and therefore the terms of agreement of the contract
are understood by the borrower who holds oneself liable to the conditions for borrowing.
to transactions cost. The economic counterpart of friction is transaction cost: for that
24
exchange operate harmoniously, or are there frequent misunderstandings and conflicts
that lead to delays, breakdowns, and other malfunctions? Transaction cost analysis entails
shall now be discussed. The discussion centers on the reasons why credit does not reach
the poor. First, it has been observed that there is a lack of available complementary
inputs when lending to micro-entrepreneurs. For example, there is a lack of financial and
accounting education, there is insufficient financial capital to invest and acquire human
capital, land or entrepreneurial ability in order to improve the productivity of land or any
foregoing business activity. Second, investment is not based on the marginal productivity
of capital or the returns on capital, but on the risk-adjusted returns. The poor may
promise higher returns but they also represent much higher risk (Akerlof 1970; Stiglitz
and Weiss 1981). An adverse selection problem usually happens. These problems have
been reduced by monitoring but such activity lead to high cost due to the small scale of
the loan made available to many borrowers. This aspect characterizes the asset
specificity of negotiations for loans and the monitoring of loan payments. Third, is the
transactions cost of loans. Partly, these are the costs of monitoring and of creating legal
liens on whatever collateral the poor may have to offer. But besides these, the time the
banker spent in helping an illiterate man fill out an application form (to have his
particulars available), the time spent to process the loan and to take back cash in small
25
D. Empirical Issues
Empirical findings based on various data sources show that there is a difference in
performance when more years are covered per MFI. This may imply that the number of
(financial revenue over the sum of financial expense, impairment loss and operating
expense), and, the capacity to sustain outreach targets with commercial funding and
explanation is given; i.e. social performance, financial performance and the current
in India, using indicators of transactions cost, especially with group lending, making use
importance of commercially operated MFIs, which allows the recognition of the role of
transactions cost when examining the interest rates charged by MFIs. The results
highlight the mistakes committed by the government of India in handling the MFIs in
Andhra Pradesh. Microfinance activity was governed by state sponsored loans crowding-
out private sector initiative and the needed financial discipline which arises through
a way to increase patronage within the region of Andhra Pradesh. The government of
India decided to stop microfinance activity in this state leading to client drop-out, access
26
CHAPTER III
This section defines the research hypothesis, presents the theoretical framework
A. Hypotheses
The research hypothesis to be tested in the study is: higher experience or learning
(BSP) plays an important role in monitoring operating costs and operational self-
sufficiency. But only rural banks are regulated by the BSP. Thus, the study shall
proceed with an analysis for rural banks and another analysis for NGOs.
Operating costs for rural banks may manifest higher experience or learning curve
spillover effects and lesser transactions cost than NGOs. This phenomenon may be due
standards for operational self-sufficiency, and the larger average loan portfolios,
Operating costs for NGOs may manifest lower experience or learning curve
spillover effects and may have higher transactions cost than rural banks. This
phenomenon may be due to their shorter commercial lending experience, the non-
regulated nature of their operations, and, smaller average loan portfolios in comparison to
27
B. Theoretical and Conceptual Framework
The theoretical approach to the study of the efficiency and productivity of MFIs
focuses on the manner in which transactions between the micro-borrower and the loan
officer are done. For group-lending MFIs, loans per borrower are radically of a smaller
size than that of commercial banks, henceforth referred to as the traditional banking
sector, with loans averaging to at most a tenth of loans given by the traditional banking
sector to their borrowers. Also, borrowers of MFIs may operate their business in remote
areas, far from the nearest MFI. As a consequence, loan officers of MFIs usually have to
travel to these areas weekly so as to collect loan payments from a group of borrowers,
usually numbering to 30-40 in the Philippines. Some loan officers of group lending
borrowers collect more often than once a week. This process involves time and effort for
collection period, i.e. 52 collection periods annually, so as to ensure that borrowers repay
their loans.
simply rural banks, do not have to go to the area where their individual borrowers operate
their business. The borrowers go to the most accessible rural bank in order to turn-in
their weekly repayment. Given this background the theoretical approach most
appropriate to the study of the efficiency and productivity of MFIs in the Philippines
marginal costs are much higher for the poorer people than for richer people. The
28
economies of scale effect of the transactions cost explanation remains, as well as the
ultimate increase in risks with over-indebtedness, and the supply curve becomes
downward sloping as loan size increases for richer people. The final curve is U-shaped as
in the standard literature because after some point over-borrowing by rich people
All the above reasons imply that even if there are no usury laws in a country,
lending to the poor is not possible for the commercial sector, as illustrated in Figure 3,
which puts together the Marginal Revenue curve (MR) and supply curve for loans (based
on the marginal cost curve). Although the simplistic model that is proposed suffers from
Although other authors may have said the same thing, the representation is new and may
Figure 3.1 shows that the first portion of the MR curve does not have any
equilibrium with the supply curve. As a result, the organized sector did not lend to the
poor. The associated average revenue (AR) curve is consequently of little relevance to
any monopolistic banker who decides to enter the market. The final equilibrium is at low
rates of interest (ro) but is available only to wealthy borrowers. Since this end of the
market is more likely to be subject to (perfect) competition, interest rates are not going to
be much higher than marginal cost, but we can associate a demand curve if for
institutional reasons there is monopoly power. In this case, the demand curve would start
at the same level as this portion of the discontinuous supply curve and (in the simple
linear case) would slope downward at half the speed (the ARrich curve would take twice
29
as long as the MRrich curve to reach the X axis). Interest rates would then be higher at rm.
(Ashta, 2009)
capital available only to not so poor borrowers. The supply curve is U shaped owing to
asymmetric information and transaction costs. As a result, poor people do not receive
loans but wealthier people do, at a fairly low interest rate, ro if there is competition and rm
Why do money lenders lend at high interest rates? Figure 3.1 illustrates this
graphically, using the discontinuous marginal revenue curve and U-shaped supply curve
lower the supply curve of credit facing poorer borrowers. As a result, they also get loans,
30
but at higher interest rates of rMLm, much higher than the rates charged by the organized
sector of ro to richer borrowers. Since moneylenders are monopolistic, they charge rates
on the associated Average Revenue curve. The supply curve of moneylenders cannot fall
lower because their costs are high for various reasons: no access to cheap deposits, little
access to debt from the organized sector (they may get personal loans by pledging
personal assets), making them reliant only on their own equity capital. This equity capital
may also suffer from seasonal variations in demand, indicating that the moneylender may
have to recover higher interest rates in the busy season. (Ashta, 2009)
a result, they push down the supply curve for poorer borrowers to the dashed line shown
in the diagram. They charge high interest rates rML, much higher than the interest rates ro
charged by the competitive organized sector to the wealthier borrowers. (Ashta, 2009)
profitable, why don’t new entrants like banks increase competition and drive down
interest rates and profits? At the very least, they should drive these down to rMLc. The
suggested answers are several and are similar to reasons why banks don't come in.
(Ashta, 2009)
The first is based on transaction cost or barriers to entry. A new entrant has high
start-up costs: if he is not from the locality, he does not know the customers and does not
have the case histories. These are developed by experience. Also, it is difficult, time
consuming and expensive to market and monitor in isolated villages, driving up costs
especially for small transaction sizes. As a result, a new entrant faces higher risks and
higher costs than the local established moneylender. (Ashta, 2009) (See Figure 3.2)
31
Also, the existence of more than one moneylender (competition as opposed to
monopoly) breaks down the business model of the established moneylender. The
borrower could shift from one moneylender to another. Greater competition will increase
default rates to the first institution, drive down interest rates and reduce the total number
Finally, more important, the market equilibrium in this segment would remain at
OD in Figure 3.2 and interest rates would not fall below the MR curve. Thus,
moneylending and other business would be competing only for lowering profits to the
32
segment as a whole. All this means that the market of DC for loans in this segment is still
not being served and, in the face of excess labor available to people in the same segment,
2009)
How can microcredit overcome information asymmetry and other barriers? One
organizations is group lending. Although there are many different forms of group lending
banking, etc.), the essential method consists in lending to individuals in a group, and
using group pressure to ensure repayment by individuals. This group pressure may come,
for example, if other members of the group would get loans only if the first borrowers
pay back. As a result of this, people would not like to form groups with others who are
unlikely to pay back. Thus, the adverse selection problem is avoided without the bank
progressive lending. Thus, if the borrower’s project can be divided into a series of
projects, the MFI lends a small amount first for one project and the next loan is given
only if the first one is repaid. Thus, the borrower is assured of funding for his project, if
he can overcome the moral hazard issues of being capable of managing the project and be
willing to repay. Another method used by MFIs is to collect repayments in public. Thus,
an agent passes at a fixed time once a week and all the borrowers are present and repay
him in front of everybody. This reduces collection costs as well as creates a social
33
pressure to repay on time. In some MFIs, there are also medals given for a series of
successful repayments, acting as further reinforcements both for the individual receiving
the medal as well as the others watching him receive it. (Ashta, 2009)
The third tool mentioned above was frequent repayments. The fourth tool is non-
traditional collateral. A fifth method used by MFIs is to focus on women. All of the
above methods do not necessarily require information being transferred from the
individual borrower to the bank, but they overcome the problems of asymmetric
information. However, a sixth method is used to improve the information available to the
MFI. This includes contacting neighbors to find out information about a potential
borrower. Some MFIs also encourage cross reporting where borrowers are encouraged to
be whistle blowers, in the interest of the larger group, if they think that some borrower is
The final result of all these factors is illustrated in Figure 3.3. For graphic
simplicity the average revenue curve of the moneylender is taken off but we can see he is
charging the higher monopolistic rate. Since no market is yet saturated, MFIs may also be
in the position of monopolies. As a result they would charge interest rates somewhere
between rMFIc and rMFIm, depending on whether their mission is purely social and purely
These developments have led to money flowing from the MFIs to the poor to the
extent of DD': with moneylenders, the market obtained OD, with MFIs, it obtains OD'.
If the supply curve only shifts downward in this range and not outward to the
right, it would also affect the equilibrium solution for richer markets. As shown in Figure
3.3, the market of the poor now extends from OA earlier to OA' because these people
34
now demand more loans since their productivity has gone up. The next segment therefore
shifts to the right and the MR curve of the rich shifts to MR'RICH. (Ashta, 2009)
information asymmetry. As a result, they push down the supply curve for poorer
borrowers further to the dotted line shown in the diagram. At the same time, group
monitoring and involvement may actually boost the performance on projects and push the
MR curve of the poor to MR’. The MFIs charge interest rates rMFIc, or rMFIm, depending
on whether there is competition or monopoly in the local market, in either case much
higher than the interest rates ro charged by the organized sector to the wealthier
borrowers, but much lower than the interest rates rML charged by money-lender. (Ashta,
2009)
The perfect competition equilibrium interest rate to the rich rises from ro to r'o.
Some rich borrowers borrow less. Correspondingly, the unserved people in the poor
market is D'C' since only those willing to pay interest rates above r'o will be able to use
the capital with their available labor, given the new human capital thanks to MFIs, other
flows may not affect the national markets of developing countries immediately, they
would affect the relative availability of credit in developed countries and the raising of
35
Transactions cost economics can then be applied to the microfinance industry.
payment history would be possible only with the specialized effort applied by loan
officers who have invested time and effort to provide information and education to
micro-borrowers who may not have acquired the education necessary to carry-on and
manage financial and business negotiations. The type of transactions cost proper to
dedicated specificity and human asset specificity. (Williamson, 1989 and Besanko, et al,
36
transactions, which often require a large number of instances, i.e. renegotiations. The
and would require specific talents and communication capabilities on the part of the loan
officers. These human-asset specific relationships enable the MFI to incur agency costs.
The study focuses only on the asset specific causes of transactions cost, and specifically,
on those which refer to human assets such as skills and capabilities which allow a longer
term duration of negotiations between the micro-borrower and the loan officer.
As the scale of the transactions increase, the firm’s demand for borrowings
increase, and a vertically integrated firm can better exploit economies of scale and scope
the transaction for any given level of asset specificity. This process involves a learning
phase for each firm involved in microfinance or micro-credit lending. (See Figure 3.4)
37
The experience of a firm at any given age may be measured in a number of ways
including, inter alia, the age of the firm, the cumulative prior output of the firm, which for
microfinance would mean average loan balance per borrower, and, number of active
borrowers, the average tenure of its employees, or the average length of related work
experience of its employees. The most popular implementation assumes that the current
unit cost of a firm of age v, c(v), is a decreasing function of its cumulative prior output,
𝜈
𝛾(𝜈) = ∫0 𝑥(𝑠)𝑑𝑠, where 𝑥(𝑠) is the firm’s output given its market share at age v. In
rule, a functional form for cost, c(v), using constant elasticity to scale, of the following
form:
is assumed. (Arrow 1962, Thompson, 2010). For equation (1), c refers to cost, m refers
to fixed costs, 𝑦̅ is the cumulated industry output at the end of the period and refers to
industry. Note that the equation used to estimate the experience curve uses firm figures
but the result will refer to the total industry as market shares per firm in the MFI industry
are not significantly different from each other, i.e. the Hirshman-Herfindahl index is <
0.15, indicating that market shares per firm in terms of number of borrowers and gross
loan portfolio have a close to a perfectly competitive market structure. (Ghemawat and
Appendix B.1-B.2. This specification of the learning curve assumes that with a close to
38
competitive market structure, cost structures are not significantly different and spillovers
occur. Proprietary experience per firm due to the existence of patents is almost nil.
The differences in the cost curves will depend on the spillover parameter, , the
mean of the assumed exponential function, which is also interpreted as a rate or speed of
cost decrease. Lower levels of would indicate a faster learning time since the intercept
at time = 0 would also be higher. Thus, from Figure 3.4, | 3 | < | 2 | < | 1 |. Note that
the spillover rate is the reciprocal of the coefficient of the variables indicating cumulative
output, when a regression estimation is done on unit cost as dependent variable and a
cumulative output indicator as regressor. Ghemawat and Spence (1985) would refer to
Scale economies may be present for the commercial banking sector. However,
such may not be the case for banks dealing with micro-entrepreneurs. The decrease in
may not necessarily denote scale economies but may just be an indication that more
acquire a higher level of learning, thereby, lessening the costs of monitoring. This
flattens rightwards. Passive learning, a phenomenon which gives rise to learning from
(Thompson, 2010). A firm that increases productivity through passive learning will be
39
The experience curve, also synonymously termed as the learning curve, is the
curve that relates unit costs to accumulated volume (Spence, 1981, Ghemawat and
Spence, 1985). The learning curve is believed to characterize the costs in some industrial
(Spence, 1981). When there is a learning curve, the short-run output decision is a type of
investment decision. It affects the cumulated output, a stock, and through it, future costs
and market position (Spence, 1981). When additions to output lower future costs, it is
appropriate for the firm to go beyond the short-run profit maximizing level of output.
Thus, on an optimal output path for a firm, marginal short-run profits, as a function of
output are negative. In fact an optimal path is one in which, at every time, t, marginal
short-run profits equal the present value of the total cost reduction over all subsequent
level that is competitive and sustainable, i.e. greater than 100%, averaging to 107% for
NGOs and 118% for rural banks. Younger rural banks and NGOs usually experience
higher levels of operational self-sufficiency but eventually, the OSS converges to 107% -
118%. When such levels of operational self-sufficiency are being observed, then the
bank is able to achieve financial sustainability in its operations, that is, operational along
with social performance efficiency are both achieved. Transactions cost may still
increase as loan officers adjust to the demands of micro-borrowers as they demand higher
loans. But at this stage, more competitive levels of interest rates may be applied to
micro-borrowers, thus, allowing the supply curve for credit to start increasing.
40
The contribution of Ghemawat and Spence (1985) to the learning curve literature
is when they derive a cost function with constant elasticity to scale production, thereby
allowing an industry-wide trend for learning curves. When firms have constant elasticity
to scale production functions, then, market dominance does not exist, the possibility of
proprietary knowledge does not occur and information diffusion happens frequently. The
decreasing unit cost trend with cumulated output represents the industry-wide marginal
cost curve. This observation was also mentioned in Randon et al (2006) when applying
non-strategic learning curve spillovers to the semiconductor industry. They agree with
Spence (1985) that as long as the industry structure is close to a competitive market
model, spillovers occur even in the event of high research and development expenditures
absence of market dominance leads to two effects: the efficiency effect and the
disincentive effect. Spillovers, according to Ghemawat and Spence (1985) causes costs
to decline, the efficiency effect, but they also tilt the marginal cost toward the current unit
cost and hence makes output choices less aggressive. This phenomenon may explain
why firms in the microfinance industry do not aggressively offer different types of loan
products to their borrowers, even if unit costs have declined due to extensive lending
experience. However, because of the competitive nature of the industry, unit costs
The manner in which NGOs and rural banks deal with micro-creditors, i.e.
manners in which group and individual lending is done is made known to those in the
microfinance industry. Thus, experience and learning curve spillovers occur among
41
personnel of rural banks and NGOs thereby lowering entry barriers into the industry, and
these experience and learning curve spillovers result to cost declines in operational and
transactions cost.
decrease in operational and transactions cost in the case of the microfinance industry,
with cumulated output, differs from economies of scale. Economies of scale refer to the
ability to perform activities at a lower unit cost when those activities are performed on a
larger scale at a given point in time. The behavior of the experience or learning curve
spillover refers to reductions in unit costs due to cumulated experience over time.
Economies of scale may be substantial even when learning or experience is minimal. This
experience may be substantial even when economies of scale are minimal, as in such
Braeutigam, 2014). In industries wherein asset specificity occurs due to the diversity of
transactions handled by loan officers, initially high costs may happen in transactions and
negotiations carried out even by skilled personnel. Through time, learning occurs on the
C. Methodology
To be able to test the stated hypotheses, the empirical methodology shall proceed
with two steps, which also pertain to the objectives of study. The study therefore
attempts to empirically verify (1) a decreasing cost over cumulative output indicated by
age, also called a learning or experience curve spillover, and (2) a U-shaped supply
42
function, for the microfinance industry. Pooled least squares regression with cross-
The coefficient of age upon establishment and average loan balance per borrower
shall be the indicator for experience or learning curve spillovers. The greater the spill-
over effects, the greater the capacity of the MFI to decrease transactions cost, assuming
that the data covers a time period from zero output up to a planning period. The
reciprocal of the coefficient of the cumulative output shall be the indicator for the
spillover rate as the regression model to be performed will not be a logarithmic function.
each MFI and to the whole MFI industry is likely to result to a trend towards lowering
transactions cost.
Due to the unique nature of MFI operations, wherein, the human capital
specificity of each transaction with borrowers is also a function of the average loan per
borrower, a regression shall be performed for both rural banks and NGOs with human
personnel expense per average loan portfolio per borrower, accounts for more than 50%
of operating expenses. Thus, the study would verify if MFIs undergo a learning curve as
regards transactions with micro-borrowers. The data only extends to aggregates per firm
and not by loan officer or employee per firm. Thus, the study shall use average loan per
borrower and age upon establishment as the indicator for cumulative output, the
operating expense ratio or cost per dollar of loan as the indicator for unit cost, and,
personnel expense ratio or the personnel cost per dollar of loan as the indicator for human
43
The functional form used for the learning or experience curve assumes spillovers,
that is, rivals learn from each other’s experience, i.e. organizational structures are made
known to all in the industry, due to the presence of a regulatory body monitoring the
financial viability of the players. If learning is neither too slow nor too rapid, no
Using the operating expense ratio as the cost indicator of MFI operations and
per borrower, number of active borrowers, capitalization, size, actual age (upon
establishment), square of actual age, and, outreach as explanatory variables, can be done,
answering objective 1. The regression model used is adapted from Cull, Demirgüç-Kunt,
Morduch (2007) who used the same independent variables to explain financial
performance. In their empirical model, labor and capital costs were included as
regressors. For the study, the operating expense ratio was been used, indicator for unit
cost, as a dependent variable and cumulated output would be indicated by age upon
establishment, and, average loan balance per borrower for objective 1. The estimated
regression for equations (3.2) and (3.3) shall be plotted with age upon establishment and
operating expense ratio (unit cost indicator) and personnel expense ratio (asset specificity
indicator).
The reciprocal of the coefficient of average loan balance per borrower and age
upon establishment shall be the indicators for the experience or learning curve spillover
rate. Through time, it has been observed, microfinance firms increase their average loan
balance per borrower as they are more capable, with greater experience, to monitor and
44
asymptotic curve, the square of age shall be included in the regression equation. The
experience curve can be estimated using the following equation, with the operating
Operating Cost per dollar of Loanijt (Operating Expense Ratio) = αij + β1 OSSijt +
Note that performance indicators have been used as regressors in the empirical
model. This specification was used due to the need for MFIs to achieve the regulated or
standard levels for operational self-sufficiency, which should be greater than 100%. This
level of operational self-sufficiency has to be reached even while achieving its social
outreach motives. The meaning of the above-mentioned explanatory variables and the
decreasing operating cost per dollar of loan across time, i.e. more years of experience by
the micro-borrower in transacting with the MFIs and its personnel. As mentioned by
Shankar (2007), transactions costs do seem to decrease with time for the Philippines. In
fact, there is much hope for interest rates charged to micro-borrowers due to an
expectation that as micro-lenders acquire more experience they learn to lend more
45
efficiently (Rosenberg, et al, 2013). Thus, what is expected to be observed for operating
costs must also be observed for transactions cost, the main cost driver for MFIs. This
observation will be verified through the following regression, with the personnel expense
Personnel Cost per dollar of Loanijt (Personnel Expense Ratio) = αij + β1 OSSijt +
cost improvements happen as firms (or the whole industry in a given market) acquire
more experience. Eventually, efficiency lessons are learned, and the experience curve
flattens out. At this point efficiency improves slowly even in the absence of
there is hope that the pressure of competition will force lenders to find more efficient
delivery systems (Rosenberg, et al, 2013). There seems to be, therefore, a global
evidence for a flattening operating cost curve for the microfinance industry, as micro-
lenders such as MFIs, gain more lending experience to micro-borrowers with time or age.
The study shall use high quality data reported in the Microfinance Information
eXchange Portal (MIX). Profitability patterns can be observed across the two main
46
institutional types, also denoted as lending types in the study, identified in the MIX are as
follows:
lending contracts between a lender and a single borrower. Liability for repaying the loan
rests with the individual borrower only, although in some cases another individual might
serve as a guarantor;
2. NGO group lenders: institutions that employ contracts based on a group with
either joint or individual liability implemented with solidarity groups (in the spirit of
contracts used initially at the Grameen Bank in Bangladesh and at BancoSol in Bolivia).
Loans are made to individuals within the group, which has between 30 to 40 members
In a study by Morduch et al (2007), it has been observed that village banks have
the highest portfolio yields (indicator of financial self-sufficiency) and expense ratios
(indicator of operating cost self-sufficiency), but at the same time has the lowest return
on assets (indicator of profitability). The individual based lenders are observed to have
the most financial and cost efficient mode of operations and are also the most profitable.
For RP, the MIX data can only specify the type of market, i.e. poor vis-à-vis
better-off clients. Rural banks usually lend individually. Grameen type rural banks loan
to groups, but liability is rendered to each individual member of the group. NGOs lend to
groups but liability for loans can either be individual or by group. But accounting for
liability cannot be observed from the MIX data. From Figure 3.5, it can be observed that
rural banks have financial and cost efficient mode of operations and are also the most
profitable.
47
Figure 3.5
Profit Margin, Operational Self-Sufficiency and Return on Assets for
Rural Banks and NGOs
100%
80%
60%
40%
20% 13%
2% -2% 2% Profit Margin
0% OSS
Rural Banks NGOs
ROA
-20%
This observation shows that the analysis of the operational efficiency by lending
type i, referring to either individual-based lenders such as rural banks, or, group lenders
or NGOs, across j firms and t years, from 2003 to 2011, would be affected by the level of
operating and transactions cost, and vice versa. When costs per loan transaction are
placed as dependent variable, the equation may be interpreted as a supply for loans
function, obtaining the regression procedure to account for Objective 2 of the study. The
basic regression model to be used, with the personnel expense ratio used an the indicator
48
Transactions Costijt (Personnel Expense Ratio) = αij + β1 OSSijt + β2 Average Loan
Due to the large percentage share of personnel expense per dollar of loan to
operating expense per dollar of loan, the same set of explanatory variables in equation
(3.5) shall also be done with operating expense per dollar of loan, the indicator for unit
Operating Costsijt (Operating Cost per Dollar of loan) = αij + β1 OSSijt + β2 Average
average loan balance per borrower, the indicator used for human asset specificity.
Transactions cost also signifies the personnel cost per dollar of loan. It shall be regressed
on OSS (operational self-sufficiency by MFI institution, i.e. rural bank or NGO), average
loan balance per borrower, the square of the average loan balance per borrower (to
49
capture either an asymptotic behavior or a U-shaped curve, number of active borrowers).
MFI History would refer to age and scale of the MFI, and, orientation would refer to the
target market or outreach and type of outreach such as the number of women borrowers.
The capital structure indicator shall not use the debt-to-equity ratio but shall use the gross
loan portfolio over assets, as the debt-to-equity ratio for MFIs would need more
information on funding sources. Note that the expected signs for equations (3.4) and
(3.5) are the same as the expected signs for equations (3.2) and (3.3), and the explanatory
variables are the same except for an additional variable which the square of the average
loan balance per borrower which serves as the indicator for the behavior of costs.
If the supply curve is expected to be U-shaped, then the curve reaches a minimum
increases. More loan officers and personnel have to be employed in order to process and
assess the viability of bigger loan amounts, as well as assess the credit history and
capacity to pay of the borrower. When the supply curve of MFIs starts to slope upwards,
then one can say that the behavior of the loan officers and personnel would compare and
follow the usual behavior of personnel employed in commercial banks. Note that
equations (3.4) and (3.5) incorporate the experience or learning curve spillover indicators.
These regressors aim to capture the existence of a supply curve in the microfinance
When the learning curve spillovers are large enough as to influence players in the
marginal cost curve that flattens at a minimum point. It may start increasing as
50
cumulated output increases, that is, when micro-borrowers are more capable of handling
transparent with their data, and thus, their financial and operational viability. This
attempt would imply that they observe the rules on the financial and operational self-
sufficiency indicators imposed on all MFIs. However, the two main types of lenders
studied: rural banks (mostly individual lenders) and NGOs (combination of individual
and group lenders), would competitively behave differently, i.e. outreach vis-à-vis
profitability. Thus, the NGOs will have to be analyzed separately from the rural banks.
Some types of lenders try to attract the better-off borrowers (high profitability ratios)
and/or sustainable borrowers (low operational costs). This may be true for rural banks.
D. Data Sources
Data for the study was obtained from the Microfinance Information eXchange
Portal (MIX), which accounts for close to 60% of the total number of active borrowers
around the world. MIX is the premier source, open access, incorporated since 2002, for
dedicated to serving the financial sector needs for low-income clients. MIX fulfills its
and social performance information covering approximately 2,000 MFIs around the
51
world. MIX is a non-profit organization headquartered in Washington, DC with regional
The current study uses the MIX portal for financial and social performance data
for 104 MFIs, i.e. rural banks, NGOs and credit cooperatives. A total of only 50 MFIs:
18 Rural Banks and 32 NGOs, with historical data from 1998 to 2011, are included in
the dataset. Not all MFIs have a complete set of financial and social performance
52
CHAPTER IV
ANALYSIS OF RESULTS
The results of the study shall be discussed based on the objectives proposed.
MFIs
based on financial viability and outreach, show the following results. A comparison of
operational self-sufficiency, and outreach was done with rural banks and NGOs based on
the MIX Portal database from 2000-2011 with a total of 50 rural banks and 32 NGO. It
can be seen that more mature MFIs are able to achieve lower levels of personnel expense
per dollar of loan, i.e. less than US$ 26.00. Due to the strict regulatory nature of the
commercial banking system, most rural banks are able to control their transactions to less
Table 4.1
Transactions Cost (Personnel Expense per US$100 of Loan) of Rural Banks and
NGOs from 2000 to 2011 by Age
Annual Age
Transactions Cost Young Mature Total Remarks on
(Personnel Expense Outreach
per US$100 of Rural NGOs Rural NGOs Rural NGOs
Loan) Banks Banks Banks
Low: Less than $26 0 4 46 10 46 14 Narrow to
Moderate: $26-$50 1 2 2 10 3 12 moderate
Moderate to
High: $51-$100 0 0 0 3 0 3 broad with
several network
affiliations
Total 1 6 48 23 49 29
Source: MIX Market Data (http://www.mixmarket.org/)
Note: Commercial sources of funds is the usual source of funding for all MFIs.
53
Not only are rural banks able to control their transactions cost, they are also able
to strictly observe low risk and financially sustainable operations. NGOs, most of whom
are not regulated, operate to sustain profits, decrease risk but increase outreach. Most
rural banks are mature, whose client size mostly have a medium to large asset size. Also,
rural banks have a market clientele or target market ranging from micro firms (better-off
micro firms) to small and high end businesses. NGOs vary from young and new to
mature firms. Client outreach is composed of small to large firms (by asset size). But
NGOs primarily target low end (or poor) businesses as clients, indicated by a narrow to
Table 4.2
Transactions Cost (Personnel Expense per US$100 of Loan) of Rural Banks and NGOs
(2000 to 2011) by Age and Operational Self-Sufficiency (OSS)
Age and Operational Self-Sufficiency (OSS)
Transactions Young Mature Total
Cost Rural Remarks
Rural Banks
(Personnel Banks NGOs Rural Banks NGOs
Expense per on
NGOs
Outreach
OSS > 1
OSS > 1
OSS > 1
OSS > 1
OSS < 1
OSS < 1
OSS < 1
OSS < 1
US$100 of
Total
Total
Total
Total
Loan)
Low: Less 0 4 4 2 44 46 2 8 10 46 14
than $26 Narrow to
Moderate: 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 8 10 3 12 moderate
$26-$50
Moderate
to broad
High: 0 0 0 3 3 0 3 with
$51-$100 several
network
affiliations
Total 0 1 1 0 6 6 4 44 48 7 16 23 49 29
Source: MIX Market Data (http://www.mixmarket.org/)
Note: The lowest level of operational self-sufficiency achieved by a bank from 2000 to 2011 is
0.48, and, 0.18 for NGOs for all samples. Commercial sources of funds is the usual source of
funding for all MFIs.
Rural banks are primarily focused on profitability as seen in the average profit
margin, OSS and ROA’s of the 50 listed rural banks in the MIX Portal. Cost per
54
borrower is close to double that of NGOs but NGOs have more than double the number
of active borrowers. Loans extended by rural banks are more than double that of NGOs
Table 4.3.
Relevant Information on Chosen Rural Banks and NGOs (2000-2011)
Portfolio at Risk
(90 days) (in %)
Borrower (US$)
Selected (in %)
Indicators by
Lending Type
Rural Banks
Mean 13 118 2 7.5 102 17,436 668 46 22
Median 12 114 2 6.0 79 9,683 454 33 19
Maximum 49 195 16 44.0 528 267,282 7,139 521 92
Minimum -108 48 -16 0.0 20 208 46 4 2
Number of 276 279 229 181 194 256 256 255 229
Observations
NGOs
Mean -2 107 52,380 6.8 44 118 8 45
Median 8 108 3% 18,603 3.0 38 93 6 41
Maximum 46 185 23 606,488 50.0 165 1,414 69 124
Minimum -463 18 -96 837 0.0 11 30 3 20
Number of 214 214 188 153 183 226 226 223 189
Observations
Source: MIX Market Data (http://www.mixmarket.org/)
2005 and 2006 to 2012. One can observe an increase in the average loan balance per
borrower as the well an increase in the number of active borrowers for both rural banks
55
Table 4.4
Transaction Cost per Borrower of Rural Banks and NGOs (2000 to 2011) by Age, Operational Self-Sufficiency (OSS) and Profitability (Return on Assets (ROS) and Return on Equity (ROE))
Annual Age
Transaction Young Mature Total
Rural Banks NGOs Rural Banks NGOs Remarks
Cost Rural
NGOs
(in US$) OSS < 1 OSS > 1 Total OSS < 1 OSS > 1 Total OSS < 1 OSS > 1 Total OSS < 1 OSS > 1 Total Banks
56
Kasagana-Ka, Kazama
Moderate: 1st Valley Bank, FAIR Bank, PBC, RB
0 0 0 0 0 0 0 5 CEVI Grameen, KCCDFI, 5 5 5
$26-$50 Montevista, Progressive Bank
MILAMDEC
2000-2005
2006-2012
2000-2005
2006-2012
2000-2005
2006-2012
2000-2005
2006-2012
2000-2005
2006-2012
Statistics
Maximum 2461 7139 1.95 1.91 219 163 195 1,040 490 871
Minimum 46 62 0.66 0.48 9 2 41 11 6 1
Mean 76 129 1.04 1.09 139 97 133 182 137 322
NGOs
sufficiency indicator, can be observed with NGOs. However, their social efficiency
index falls within poor levels, with a slight improvement to moderate level in 2006 to
2012. One can compare this with rural banks, whose social efficiency index improved in
2006-2012. The social efficiency index is computed as the cost per dollar of loan (or
operating expense ratio) over cost per borrower and allows one to compare MFIs with
different credit methodologies. NGOs seem to face several factors which make the cost
of per dollar of loan more expensive. For example, MFIs in the Philippines provide
complementary services such as health or training which will increase operating expenses
57
but are not directly related to the cost of providing the loan. For NGOs, however, these
All the regression results made use of a pooled least squares with cross-section
random effects model. The estimation obtained a strong correlation between fixed and
random effects, as the heterogeneity among rural banks and NGOs takes into account the
varying intercepts, the indicator of fixed costs, of the regressions obtained per firm. The
random effects model gave the correct signs for the explanatory variables, thereby giving
sound theoretical results. The Durbin-Watson statistic obtained in all the regressions was
less than 1.4, indicating problems of serial correlation. Problems of endogeneity among
the explanatory variables are expected in the regression, as the other explanatory
In spite of all the limitations of the regression model used, the study focuses on
the level of significance that would be obtained from the coefficients of the cumulated
output indicators. The levels of significance obtained from the regression with random
effects and the regression without random effects did not differ significantly.
The regression on the learning curve and the U-shaped supply curve shall use the
following variables with their corresponding significance and expected signs. (See Table
4.6). Specific indicators shall be observed in the regressions: (a) For the experience or
learning curve spillover regression, the presence of spillovers among MFIs shall be
captured through a learning curve that levels-off as the amount of cumulated output over
time increases. These indicators shall be age and the square of age upon establishment,
58
and average loan balance per borrower; (b) For a U-shaped supply curve, also known as
that it reaches a minimum then increases as the supply of loans increases. The
and negative.
Table 4.6
Variables Used for the Learning Curve and U-Shaped Supply Curve Regressions
Relevance and Computation and Commercial Bank or
Variable Used Expected Sign for all Regressions Traditional Banking Equivalent
This ratio provides the best indicator Operating Expense over Average Loan
of the overall efficiency of a lending Portfolio.
institution. Also referred to as the Goal is lower than 35% for urban MFIs
Efficiency Ratio, measuring the but leading MFIs have 10% or lower.
Operational institutional cost of delivering loan Similar to the Efficiency Ratio or
Expense Ratio services compared to the average Cost/Income ratio used by the
also called loan size of its portfolio. traditional banking sector to determine
Cost per Therefore, a general rule is the how efficiently the bank uses its assets
Dollar of lower the Operating Expense Ratio, and liabilities within internal operations
Loan. the higher the efficiency. related to the loan portfolio. This ratio
This variable is used as the measures the amount of non-interest
dependent variable for the expenses (operating expenses,
regression in the learning curve, excluding provisions of loan losses)
indicator for cost per unit. needed to support operating revenues.
Used as an indicator for asset
specificity, or, human asset Compensation or salaries over
Personnel specificity. Average Loan Portfolio
Expense Ratio Used as the dependent variable for No equivalent with the traditional
the regression on transaction cost banking sector
as asset specificity.
Financial Revenue over (Financial
Indicator for Financial Self- Expense + Impairment Loss +
Sufficiency, and, thus Operating Expense)
sustainability.
Financial revenues are revenues from
Used as an explanatory variable for the loan portfolio and from other
Operational the learning curve and transactions financial assets and are broken out
Self- cost regression. separately and by type of income
Sufficiency Expected to have a negative sign (interest, fee).
MFIs operate with the goal of Equal to or greater than 100%
achieving sustainability. Thus, it No equivalent with the traditional
acts as an explanatory variable for banking sector
indicating efficiency of operations
60
A proxy for how efficiently the
institution is providing loans while
neutralizing the effects of average
loan size on efficiency (both
operating expense ratio and cost per
borrower are each heavily Operating Expense Ratio over Cost per
influenced by the loan size). Borrower (Operating Expenses over
Social The Social Efficiency Index allows Number of Active Borrowers). This is
Efficiency for a more direct comparison of an index.
Index different types of MFIs with No equivalent with the traditional
different credit methodologies. banking sector
Used as an explanatory variable for
the regression on the learning curve
and transactions cost.
Expected to have either a positive or
negative sign.
Source: MicroRate (2014), Rosenberg, et al (2013), MIX Market Data
(http://www.mixmarket.org/)
From Figure 4.1, it can be observed that rural banks do have higher experience or
learning curve spillover rates than NGOs, when we use age upon establishment as the
61
Table 4.7
Experience or Learning Curve Spillover Regression
(For Rural Banks and NGOs)
Method: Pooled Least Squares with Cross-Section Random Effects
Operating Expense per Average
Explanatory Variables Expected Loan Portfolio
Sign
Rural Banks NGOs
C + 69.52 *** 122.69 ***
6.41 12.58
Operational Self-Sufficiency - -11.58 *** -22.70 ***
(OSS) 2.81 4.48
Average Loan Balance per - -0.002 ** -0.04 **
Borrower 0.001 0.02
Number of Active Borrowers + 8.81E-05 *** 1.74E-05 *
1.72E-05 1.16E-05
Debt-to-Equity Ratio + or - -0.90 *** 0.03 na
0.29 0.12
Gross Loan Portfolio over + or - -30.91 *** -56.29 ***
Total Assets 4.79 5.89
Age upon Establishment - -0.40 ** -0.71 *
0.22 0.62
Age upon Establishment + 0.005 * 0.03 *
Squared 0.004 0.02
Scale (1 small, 2 medium, 3 -3.56 *** 1.57 na
large) + or -
1.03 1.40
Outreach (1 small, 2 medium, + or - 1.08 na -0.95 na
3 large) 0.96 1.78
Women Borrowers as a + or - 3.59 ** -7.72 na
Percent of Total Borrowers 1.77 6.26
0.07 *** 0.01 na
Social Efficiency Index + or -
0.02 0.03
Adjusted R-squared 0.53 0.39
F-statistic 15.45 10.71
Durbin-Watson Statistic 1.35 0.82
Cross-Sections Included 45 29
Total Unbalanced Panel Observations 140 165
Years Covered 2001-2011 2000-2011
Source: Author’s Estimates, MIX Market Data (http://www.mixmarket.org/)
Note: Italicized numbers refer to the standard deviation. Regression uses White
diagonal standard errors and covariance (degrees of freedom corrected). All p-
values of the F-statistic are very significant or p less than 0.01. p-values used
are: *** p less than 0.01, ** p less than 0.05 and greater than 0.01, * p less than
0.15 and greater than 0.05. Swamy and Arora estimator of component variances.
62
From Table 4.7, we would observe a lower coefficient level, in absolute terms, for
age upon establishment for rural banks than for NGOs, as a lower coefficient for age
would refer to a higher experience or learning curve spillover rate, the reciprocal of the
coefficient indicates the spillover rate. The square of age is positive and moderately
significant for the regression for NGOs and rural banks, stating that the curve flattens as
age increases. The slower learning process for NGOs may be due to the high social
efficiency index as NGOs face high levels of operational expenses when training loan
When the dependent variable is changed into the asset specificity indicator, which
is the personnel expense ratio, it can be observed that the learning curve flattens out with
age, but the regression result no longer holds age and the square of age as a significant
explanatory variable for rural banks, only for NGOs. (See Figure 4.2)
63
Table 4.8
Experience or Learning Curve Spillover Regression and Asset Specificity
(For Rural Banks and NGOs)
Method: Pooled Least Squares with Cross-Section Random Effects
Personnel Expense per Average
Explanatory Variables Expected Loan Portfolio
Sign
Rural Banks NGOs
C + 25.93 *** 59.15 ***
3.47 8.09
Operational Self-Sufficiency - -6.46 *** -17.47 ***
(OSS) 1.69 2.71
Average Loan Balance per - -0.0005 * -0.03 **
Borrower 0.0004 0.02
Number of Active Borrowers + 4.66E-05 *** -3.01E-06 na
6.71E-06 6.27E-06
Debt-to-Equity Ratio + or - -0.31 ** -0.04 na
0.14 0.06
Gross Loan Portfolio over + or - -7.48 *** -15.78 ***
Total Assets 2.29 3.93
Age upon Establishment - 0.10 na -0.55 *
0.11 0.43
Age upon Establishment 0.001 na 0.03 ***
Squared +
0.002 0.01
Scale (1 small, 2 medium, 3 -0.86 * 0.48 na
large) + or -
0.51 0.90
Outreach (1 small, 2 medium, + or - -0.65 * 0.59 na
3 large) 0.42 1.11
Women Borrowers as a + or - 1.12 * -2.90 na
Percent of Total Borrowers 0.77 3.32
0.08 *** 0.04 *
Social Efficiency Index + or -
0.02 0.02
Adjusted R-squared 0.58 0.33
F-statistic 13.51 7.07
Durbin-Watson Statistic 1.25 0.91
Cross-Sections Included 43 28
Total Unbalanced Panel Observations 102 136
Years Covered 2003-2010 2003-2011
Source: Author’s Estimates, MIX Market Data (http://www.mixmarket.org/)
Note: Italicized numbers refer to the standard deviation. Regression uses White
diagonal standard errors and covariance (degrees of freedom corrected). All p-
values of the F-statistic are very significant or p less than 0.01. p-values used
are: *** p less than 0.01, ** p less than 0.05 and greater than 0.01, * p less than
0.15 and greater than 0.05. Swamy and Arora estimator of component
variances.
64
The average loan balance per borrower for rural banks and NGOs continues to be
negative and moderately significant with the regression on transactions cost. We can
conclude that the experience or learning curve spillover phenomenon among MFIs is
explained by increasing average loan balance per borrower and age for NGOs. For rural
banks, age of the establishment no longer explains transactions cost (See Table 4.8).
Once the operational expense ratio has reached a low level of US$20, asset specificity no
longer plays a significant role as micro-borrowers increase their average loan size. The
goal of continuing efficient operations along with social performance requires a high
level of capability among loan officers and personnel when dealing with higher average
loan portfolios among micro-entrepreneurs. NGOs, on the other hand, are already on
their way to achieving higher spillover effects. Both operating costs and transactions cost
are not yet achieving an asymptotic level, but they are decreasing.
learning curve spillovers with the presence of a U-shaped supply curve. This time, the
other indicator for accumulated output, average loan balance per borrower, shall be used.
This is also the indicator for output for the U-shaped supply curve. (See Figure 4.3)
When the personnel expense ratio, the indicator used for asset specificity is
graphed using average loan balance per borrower on the abscissa, a steep downward
sloping experience curve can be observed not only for NGOs but also for rural banks.
While the evidence of a flattening experience can be observed with rural banks, the
experience curve for NGOs seem to be reaching a low personnel cost per dollar of loan.
The average loan balance per borrower, however, has not increased and thus a flattening
65
66
From the regression results of Table 4.9, one can see the consistently negative
sign of operational self-sufficiency and outreach for both NGOs and rural banks. The
extent of outreach through the social efficiency index and the high level of operational
and personnel cost vis-à-vis age upon establishment and the average loan balance per
borrower. Only rural banks seem to manifest a slightly increasing marginal cost curve,
denoting the well-behaved portion of the supply curve for an individual firm.
Thus, in response to objective 2, the results from Table 4.9 seem to indicate that
only rural banks are starting to manifest a well-behaved supply curve as they are no
longer operating at the steep portion of the marginal cost curve (See Figures 4.3 to 4.4).
Operating costs are decreasing as the average amount of loan portfolio increase. The
learning curve spillover effects among rural banks is already manifesting a marginal cost
curve that has reached a minimum level, and is on its way towards an upward sloping
marginal cost curve. On the other hand NGOs, most of whom have a narrow extent of
outreach, i.e. only dealing with small borrowers, and, with smaller average loan
portfolios per borrower than rural banks, do not reflect an upward sloping marginal cost
curve. In fact, most NGOs are not yet operating at the minimum level of operating costs,
unlike that of rural banks. Average loan balance per borrower hardly reach US$500 (See
Figure 4.4). Transactions costs for NGOs, however, are approaching the minimum level
reached by rural banks but over-all operating cost, that is, cost per dollar of loan, are still
far from the minimum level of operating costs per dollar of loan achieved by rural banks.
International regulatory bodies for MFIs put the standard to be within the range of
67
Table 4.9
U-Shaped Supply Curve Regression for Rural Banks and NGOs
(With Transactions Cost and Experience or Learning Curve Spillovers)
Method: Pooled Least Squares with Cross-Section Random Effects
Personnel Expense per Operating Expense per
Explanatory Expected Average Loan Portfolio Average Loan Portfolio
Variables Sign
Rural Banks NGOs Rural Banks NGOs
C + 26.10 *** 49.94 *** 68.23 *** 113.69 ***
3.32 10.96 5.86 15.22
Operational Self- - -6.29 *** -17.24 *** -10.80 *** -22.04 ***
Sufficiency (OSS) 1.69 2.90 2.79 4.61
Average Loan -0.002 * -0.01 na -0.006 *** -0.03 na
Balance per -
Borrower 0.001 0.07 0.002 0.09
Average Loan 2.7E-07 * -3.4E-05 na 9.3E-07 ** -2.3E-05 na
Balance per +
Borrower Squared 2.2E-07 0.0001 3.7E-07 0.0002
Number of Active + 4.7E-05 ** 1.3E-06 na 8.0E-05 *** 2.3E-05 **
Borrowers 6.7E-06 6.3E-06 1.7E-05 1.1E-05
Debt-to-Equity + or - -0.32 ** -0.03 na -1.00 *** -0.02 na
Ratio 0.14 0.06 0.28 0.12
Gross Loan -7.78 *** -15.02 *** -32.70 *** -56.01 ***
Portfolio over + or -
Total Assets 2.26 4.11 4.72 5.95
Age upon - -0.04 * 0.42 ** -0.11 * 0.21 na
Establishment 0.04 0.22 0.07 0.29
Scale (1 small, -0.73 na 0.39 na -2.93 *** 1.16 na
2 medium, 3 large) + or -
0.52 0.93 1.04 1.39
Outreach (1 small, + or - -0.71 * -0.20 na 0.68 na -1.01 na
2 medium, 3 large) 0.43 1.11 1.00 1.79
Number of Women + or - 1.06 na -2.50 na 3.94 ** -7.26 na
Borrowers 0.77 3.49 1.75 6.32
Social Efficiency 0.06 *** 0.05 * 0.06 *** 0.02 na
Index + or -
0.02 0.03 0.02 0.04
Adjusted R-squared 0.58 0.30 0.55 0.39
F-statistic 13.75 6.30 16.58 10.62
Durbin-Watson Statistic 1.19 0.88 1.34 0.84
Cross-Sections Included 43 28 45 29
Total Unbalanced Panel 102 136 140 165
Observations
Years Covered 2003-2010 2003-2011 2001-2011 2000-2011
Source: Author’s Estimates, MIX Market Data (http://www.mixmarket.org/)
Note: Italicized numbers refer to the standard deviation. Regression uses White diagonal
standard errors and covariance (degrees of freedom corrected). All p-values of the F-statistic are
very significant or p less than 0.01. p-values used are: *** p less than 0.01, ** p less than 0.05
and greater than 0.01, * p less than 0.15 and greater than 0.05. Swamy and Arora estimator of
component variances.
68
The results of the regressions may indicate that NGOs are devoting resources on
a levelling-off of the cost per dollar of loan as well as transactions cost for rural banks,
their social efficiency index is positively related to cost. This observation may be verified
by the comparison of operational self-sufficiency and the social efficiency index. This
result may suggest that NGOs have to re-think their organization and operations so as to
their attempt to increase the outreach of their social projects might be comprised with less
ratio and the gross loan portfolio over assets. In principle, MFIs should not lend beyond
their level of assets. Thus, more efficient operations may be indicated by a negative
relationship of this indicator with costs. Both MFIs and rural banks seem to reflect this
negative relationship. However, the structure of debt would be indicated by the debt-to-
indicator with costs. However, this behavior can only be observed with rural banks as the
debt-to-equity ratio has a positive relationship with costs for NGOs. This regression
result may verify that NGOs have an extensive source of grants that help cover their
outreach activities. However, such expenses do not seem to allow a healthy level of
operational self-sufficiency and social efficiency index for NGOs. (See Figure 4.5)
69
It can be observed that a social efficiency index which is greater than 100 is likely
to have an operational self-sufficiency that is lower than 1.0. This trend is most observed
with NGOs. The social efficiency index for some rural banks, though, may fall within
the moderate range but would report an operational self-sufficiency level which is lower
than 1.0. Most of these rural banks loan more than 10%, the regulated level by the
The research hypotheses that were tested in the study led to the following results:
1. Hypothesis for rural banks. Operating costs for rural banks have manifested
higher experience or learning curve spillovers and lesser transactions cost than NGOs.
experience, and, their strict observance of industry standards for operational self-
70
sufficiency. With efficiency gains, rural banks are operating at the low marginal cost
levels in the supply curve attributed to the individual lending mode of transactions done
among rural banks involved with MFI operations which follow the traditional or market-
oriented manner of transacting with clients. Lower transactions cost among rural banks
enable them to achieve high operational efficiency. Empirically, the presence of lower
transactions cost denoting high learning or spillover effects have enabled rural banks to
operate efficiently thereby allowing them to perform their outreach activities with more
productivity and lesser cost. The satisfactory level of their social efficiency index
indicates that financial and operational expenses are not compromised with extensive
social outreach. All these indicators seem to precede the eventual occurrence of an
upward sloping marginal cost curve, and thereby, allowing rural banks serving MFI
2. Hypothesis for NGOs. Operating costs for NGOs have manifested lower
experience or learning curve spillovers and have higher transactions cost than rural
banks.
and, the non-regulated nature of their operations. Transactions cost among NGOs are
high and are less likely to attain industry standards for operational self-sufficiency. With
lesser efficiency gains, some NGOs may be experiencing disincentive effects, that is,
being unable to increase their average loans credited to micro-borrowers, and, NGOs
may not yet be operating at low marginal cost levels in the supply curve. This can be
explained by the group lending with individual liability lending mode of transactions
done among NGOs involved with MFI operations which do not follow the traditional or
71
market-oriented manner of transacting with clients. Loan officers and personnel have to
micro-borrowers. While still at the high level of transactions and operating costs, NGOs
into microfinance are not yet in the capacity to operate at the well-behaved portion of the
marginal cost curve, also known as the upward sloping supply curve. More efficient
operations will have to be achieved while they attempt to accomplish their social
outreach. Their social efficiency index seems to denote that financial resources are
In terms of objectives of the study, the results are denoted by Table 4.10. The
downward trend of cost per dollar of loan and transactions cost through time, indicated
by age, establishes the presence of an experience or learning curve spillover for rural
banks and NGOs. (See Figures 4.1 and 4.2) This is the result when the proxy variable in
the scatterplot for cumulated output is time, that is, age upon establishment, per firm
included in the data. When the proxy variable for cumulated output in the scatter plot is
average loan balance per borrower, one can observe a very steep downward sloping
marginal cost curve for NGOs and a U-shaped marginal cost curve for rural banks when
the unit cost used is either cost per dollar of loan or transactions cost. (See Figures 4.3
and 4.4). This result establishes the need for a downward sloping with a levelling-off
trend for cost per dollar of loan and transactions cost, before the marginal cost curve
starts to increase. This phenomenon is observed only among rural banks, and denotes a
downward trend of transactions cost and cost per dollar of loan for both rural banks and
72
NGOs. However, social outreach efficiency, indicated by a low social efficiency index,
as of the moment, does not seem to coincide with the trend observed with costs as the
Table 4.10
Experience or Learning Curve Spillovers, Transactions Cost and a U-Shaped
Supply Curve for Rural Banks and NGOs
Experience or Learning Experience or Learning Curve Spillovers,
MFIs Curves Transactions Cost and a U-Shaped Supply Curve
(Objective 1) (Objective 2)
1. Lower transactions cost, lower cost per dollar of
loan, leading to a U-shaped supply curve
Higher experience or
Rural
learning curve spillovers
Banks 2. Excellent level of the social efficiency index but
translate to faster learning
has a positive relationship to operating and
transactions costs
1. Higher transactions cost and operating
expenses. NGOs still operate at the steep portion
Lower experience or
of the marginal cost curve
learning curve spillovers
NGOs
translate to slower to
2. Poor level of the social efficiency index but has
moderate learning
a positive relationship to operating and
transactions cost
Source: Author’s Regression Results
73
CHAPTER V
The results of the study can be summarized by Table 5.1. The combination of
low operating and transactions costs, due to a fast learning environment due to high
satisfactory or low social efficiency index. This combination of indicators allows the
MFI to reach a minimum level of marginal costs, while at the same time allowing MFIs
to operate efficiently and achieve an appropriate level of outreach. Higher levels of loans
order to properly monitor larger loan portfolios. Only rural banks manifest this trend.
On the other hand, NGOs have to improve learning from the operations of other
moment, with a wide variety of micro-borrowers with very small loans, operational and
transactions costs are still high, although showing a downward or decreasing trend
through time.
The results lead to the following conclusion: high experience or learning curve
spillovers in the microfinance industry allow lenders to learn from the experience of other
MFIs allows the entire industry to reach a low level of operating and transactions costs.
This level of costs, however, enables the MFI to appropriately reach its social outreach
mission while at the same time achieve operational self-sufficiency, the indicator for
financial viability used in the study. This phenomenon, though, is being observed only
74
among rural banks. NGOs are still operating at the steep portion of marginal costs but
operating and transactions costs are showing a decreasing trend through time.
operating costs, transactions costs and social efficiency be verified among a sample of
MFIs so as to tract those costs which allow transactions and negotiations among micro-
borrowers to be costly. Focusing the study on a few MFIs, who would represent a
determine those costs, specifically costs related to human asset specificity, which explain
why NGOs continue to operate at the steep portion of the marginal cost curve. With this
intent, there seems to be a rationale behind the existence of a U-shaped supply curve for
the microfinance industry of the Philippines, and for the microfinance industry, in
general.
significant experience or learning curve spillovers before reaching the minimum level of
marginal costs, may lead to the necessary conditions by which micro-lenders are able to
reach an efficient level of costs and risks. This efficient level of operations, which
combine financial viability and social outreach, may be the starting point through which
the microfinance industry, namely rural banks and NGOs, be included in the financial
sector.
75
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Ahlin, Christian, Jocelyn Lin, Michael Maio 2011 Where does microfinance flourish?
Microfinance institution performance in macroeconomic context. Journal of
Development Economics 95, 105-120.
Akerlof, George A. 1970 The Market For ‘Lemons’: Quality Uncertainty and the Market
Mechanism. Quarterly Journal of Economics 84, 3: 488-500.
Ashta, Arvind 2009 Microcredit Capital Flows and Interest Rates: An Alternative
Explanation Journal of Economic Issues Vol. XLIII No. 3 September, pp. 661-
683 (DOI 10.2753/JEI0021-3624430305. Accessed: September 7, 2013)
Besanko, David, David Dranove, Mark Shanley, Scott Schaefer 2013 Economics of
Strategy. Sixth Edition. New Jersey, USA: John Wiley and Sons. pp. 119-120,
139-141
76
Cull, Robert, Asli Demirgüç-Kunt and Jonathan Morduch 2007 Financial Performance
and Outreach: a Global Analysis of Leading Microbanks Economic Journal 117,
F107-F133, February.
Dacanay, Jovi C. 2012 Can Outreach and Sustainability Co-Exist in the Microfinance
Industry of the Philippines? An NGO and Rural Banks Performance Analysis
Working Paper. Submitted to the Faculty of the Department of Economics for
Workshop in Economics 2. School of Social Sciences, Ateneo de Manila
University, March.
Economic Intelligence Unit (EIU) 2013 Global Microscope on the Microfinance Business
Environment. London, UK: Economic Intelligence Unit
Ghemawat, Pankaj and A. Michael Spence 1985 Learning Curve Spillovers and Market
Performance The Quarterly Journal of Economics Vol. 100 Supplement, pp.
839-852 (http://www.jstor.org/stable/1882926 Accessed: 28/03/2014)
Jimenez, Eduardo C., Pia Bernadette Roman 2011 Case Study on Philippines Electronic
Banking: Delivering Microfinance Services to the Poor in the Philippines”
Working Paper. Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas
Karlan, Dean S. and Jonathan Morduch 2009 Access to Finance” Chapter 2. Handbook of
Development Economics. Dani Rodrik and Mark Rosenzweig (eds). North
Holland: Elsevier Science, Volume 5.
Karlan, Dean S. and Jonathan Zinman 2010 Expanding Credit Access: Using
Randomized Supply Decisions to Estimate the Impacts Review of Financial
Studies 23(1): 433-464
McIntosh, Craig and Bruce Wydick 2005 Competition and Microfinance Journal of
Development Economics 78, 271-298.
MicroRate 2014 The Technical Guide: Performance and Social Indicators for
Microfinance Institutions. www.ada-microfinance.org; www.microfact.org.
(Accessed: April 15, 2014)
Randon, Emanuela, Ahmad Naimzada 2006 Dynamics of the non linear learning curve
with spillovers in a differentiated oligopoly: effects on industry structure” Journal
of Evolutionary Economics 17: 95–106 (DOI 10.1007/s00191-006-0032-6,
Accessed October 20, 2014)
77
Riordan, Michael H., Oliver E. Williamson 1985 Asset Specificity and Economic
Organization International Journal of Industrial Organization 3: 365-378.
Rosenberg, Richard 2002 Microcredit Interest Rates. Consultative Group to Assist the
Poor (CGAP): Washington DC
Rosenberg, Richard, Scott Gaul, William Ford, Olga Tomilova 2013 Microcredit Interest
Rates and Their Determinants 2004-2011 Access to Finance Forum. Report by
the Consultative Group to Assist the Poor (CGAP) and its Partners. No 7 June
Saito KA, Villanueva, DP 1981 Transaction Costs of Credit to the Small-Scale Sector in
the Philippines Economic Development and Cultural Change 29(3):631-640.
Spence, A. Michael 1981 The Learning Curve and Competition The Bell Journal of
Economics Vol. 12 No. 1 (Spring) pp. 49-70 (http://www.jstor.org/stable/3003508
Accessed: 23/03/2014)
Stiglitz, Joseph E. and Andrew Weiss 1981 Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect
Information American Economic Review 71, 3: 393-410.
Thompson, Peter 2010 Learning by Doing Chapter 10. In Handbook of the Economics of
Innovation Volume 1. Edited by Bronwyn H. Hall and Nathan Rosenberg. North
Holland: Elsevier Science, pp. 429-476.
Williamson, Oliver 1975 Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications.
New York, USA: Free Press.
78
APPENDICES
79
Table A.1
Descriptive Statistics (2003 to 2011)
Average Percentage
Selected Gross
Loan Scale Outreach of Women
Descriptive Transactions Operational Number of Loan Portfolio Age
Balance Real (1-Small; (1-Narrow; Borrowers
Statistics with Cost Self- Active Portfolio at Risk (0-Young;
per Yield 2-Medium; 2-Moderate; to Total
common (in US$) Sufficiency Borrowers over (90 days) 1-Mature)
Borrower 3-Large) 3-Broad) Active
samples Assets
(US$) Borrowers
Rural Banks
Mean 48.78 1.16 703.03 24,122 0.25 0.65 0.06 0.93 2.13 1.73 57%
Median 20.48 1.13 472.00 12,007 0.23 0.69 0.05 1 2 2 60%
Maximum 747.31 1.76 5,731.00 311,380 0.67 0.89 0.44 1 3 3 100%
Minimum 3.20 0.48 46.00 208 (0.02) 0.32 0 0 1 1 2%
Std. Dev. 97.66 0.16 745.78 43,471 0.12 0.14 0.07 0.25 0.68 0.73 29%
80
Skewness 5.23 0.23 3.90 4.74 1.19 (0.74) 2.24 (3.42) (0.16) 0.47 (0.20)
Kurtosis 32.87 7.59 24.20 27.97 5.02 2.71 11.69 12.70 2.19 2.01 1.83
Observations 117 117 117 117 117 117 117 117 117 117 117
NGOs
Mean 151.78 1.09 114.52 73,105 0.46 0.71 0.06 0.72 1.82 2.27 93%
Median 77.13 1.09 96.00 25,321 0.45 0.70 0.03 1 2 2 99%
Maximum 1,153.11 1.74 470.00 606,488 0.75 1.19 0.48 1 3 3 110%
Minimum 16.00 0.38 44.00 1,157 0.13 0.42 (0.09) 0 1 1 1%
Std. Dev. 180.98 0.20 68.55 100,502 0.12 0.15 0.09 0.45 0.78 0.76 12%
Skewness 2.68 (0.58) 2.96 2.51 0.17 0.73 2.69 (1.00) 0.33 (0.50) (3.64)
Kurtosis 11.89 6.01 13.91 10.64 2.53 3.58 10.72 2.00 1.72 1.88 24.19
Observations 141 141 141 141 141 141 141 141 141 141 141
Source: MIX Data 2013
Notes: If MFIs intend to fund growth via commercial funds, then the transactions cost should be from US$ 10 to US$ 25; OSS has to be greater
than 1.0 and Portfolio at risk (90 days) should be less than 0.05. Transactions cost is calculated as administrative and personnel expenses
over average loan portfolio per borrower.
Table B.1
Market Share of Selected Rural Banks (2009-2011)
Market Share (in %)
Gross Number
No. Rural Banks into Microfinance Loan of Active Gross Number
Lending Portfolio Borrowers Loan of Active
(in US$) Portfolio Borrowers
1 1st Valley Bank 69,078,307 64,719 13.6 7.1
2 Banco Santiago de Libon 3,397,136 11,407 0.7 1.3
3 Bangko Kabayan 22,397,278 11,394 4.4 1.3
4 Bangko Luzon 7,918,003 9,610 1.6 1.1
5 Bangko Mabuhay 9,191,583 6,715 1.8 0.7
6 Bukidnon Cooperative Bank 5,509,136 1.1
(BCB)
7 Cantilan Bank 16,974,467 21,305 3.3 2.3
8 Center for Agricultural and Rural 38,251,373 240,615 7.5 26.4
Development (CARD Bank)
9 Cooperative Bank of Misamis 11,431,706 24,029 2.2 2.6
Oriental (CBMO)
10 First Agro-Industrial Rural Bank 8,782,969 20,539 1.7 2.3
(FAIR Bank)
11 First Isabela Cooperative Bank 25,260,159 25,072 5.0 2.8
(FICO)
12 First Macro Bank 11,477,170 7,618 2.3 0.8
13 GM Bank 28,798,526 31,932 5.6 3.5
14 Rural Green Bank of Caraga 36,534,854 60,005 7.2 6.6
(Green Bank)
15 Kausawagan Bank (K Bank) 5,410,927 33,815 1.1 3.7
16 Mallig Plains RB 7,454,387 23,133 1.5 2.5
17 New RB of Victorias 1,987,736 2,529 0.4 0.3
18 OMB 5,927,615 31,162 1.2 3.4
19 People's Bank of Caraga (PBC) 20,134,877 55,808 3.9 6.1
20 PR Bank 48,639,582 9.5
21 Progressive Bank 6,902,829 28,210 1.4 3.1
22 RB Bagac 1,041,571 622 0.2 0.1
23 RB Camalig 7,924,049 11,137 1.6 1.2
24 RB Cotabato 432,914 0.1
25 RB Digos 7,815,288 7,921 1.5 0.9
26 RB Dipolog 12,968,218 2.5
27 RB Guinobatan 3,527,309 12,711 0.7 1.4
28 RB Katipunan 15,551,204 36,324 3.1 4.0
29 RB Labason 2,123,021 1,625 0.4 0.2
30 RB Lebak 3,716,046 4,875 0.7 0.5
31 RB Liloy 1,677,402 0.3
81
32 RB Loon 722,513 508 0.1 0.1
33 RB Mabitac 5,273,418 13,037 1.0 1.4
34 RB Makiling 3,650,288 3,005 0.7 0.3
35 RB Montevista 5,667,814 22,399 1.1 2.5
36 RB Oroquieta 4,684,648 4,708 0.9 0.5
37 RB Pagbilao 817,624 705 0.2 0.1
38 RB San Enrique 1,607,953 3,456 0.3 0.4
39 RB Siargao 2,348,886 7,096 0.5 0.8
40 RB Solano 2,859,520 5,146 0.6 0.6
41 RB Talisayan 4,759,958 18,743 0.9 2.1
42 Opportunity
(OK Bank)
Kausawagan Bank 6,155,402 31,162 1.2 3.4
43 Valiant RB 22,992,262 15,567 4.5 1.7
Average/Hirschman-Herfindahl Index 11,855,301 23,957 0.0561 0.0964
Source: MIX Website
82
Table B.2
Market Share of Selected NGOs (2009-2011)
Market Share (in %)
Gross Loan Number
No. NGOs into Microfinance Lending Portfolio of Active Gross Number
(in US$) Borrowers Loan of Active
Portfolio Borrowers
1 ABS-CBN 3,001,218 1.2
2 ARDCI 4,074,446 22,123 1.6 0.9
3 ASA Philippines 24,415,521 298,970 9.8 12.5
4 Ahon sa Hirap, Inc (ASHI) 4,515,103 21,838 1.8 0.9
5 Alalay sa Kaunlaran, Inc. (ASKI) 13,900,604 53,919 5.6 2.2
6 Center for Agricultural and Rural
Development (CARD NGO) 56,508,101 580,999 22.7 24.2
7 Community
(CEVI)
Economic Ventures, Inc. 4,469,872 33,832 1.8 1.4
8 Cebu Micro-Enterprise Development
Foundation, Inc. (CMEDFI) 1,442,999 10,905 0.6 0.5
9 Daan sa Pagunlad, Inc. (DSPI) 3,263,197 54,926 1.3 2.3
10 Ecumenical
(ECLOF - PHL)
Church Loan Fund 2,364,657 5,806 0.9 0.2
11 FCBFI 2,009,112 15,626 0.8 0.7
12 Hagdanan sa Pag-uswag Foundation,
Inc. (HSPFI) 1,693,025 17,814 0.7 0.7
13 Kasagana-Ka
Inc.
Development Foundation, 1,751,571 17,236 0.7 0.7
14 Kazama Grameen, Inc. 3,073,497 27,536 1.2 1.1
15 Kasanyangan-Mindanao
Inc. (KCCDFI)
Foundation, 2,833,290 24,434 1.1 1.0
16 Kabalikat para sa Maunlad na Buhay,
Inc. (KMBI) 13,757,522 222,070 5.5 9.3
17 Life Bank Foundation, Inc. 19,829,145 236,917 7.9 9.9
18 Mentors Philippines 1,282,394 11,268 0.5 0.5
19 MILAMDEC Foundation, Inc. 2,414,600 30,661 1.0 1.3
20 Negros Women for Tomorrow
Foundation, Inc. (NWTF) 10,987,599 93,637 4.4 3.9
21 Pagasa 8,679,634 99,317 3.5 4.1
22 People's Alternative Livelihood
Foundation of Sorsogon, Inc. (PALFSI) 2,027,240 13,834 0.8 0.6
23 RSPI 2,506,870 30,795 1.0 1.3
24 Serviamus 1,057,999 10,452 0.4 0.4
25 Taytay sa Kauswagan, Inc. (TSKI) 22,898,570 183,455 9.2 7.7
26 Tulay sa Pag-unlad, Inc. (TSPI) 32,609,652 278,018 13.1 11.6
27 VEF 2,101,619 1,695 0.8 0.1
Average/Hirschman-Herfindahl Index 9,239,595 92,234 0.1041 0.1173
Source: MIX Website
83
Table C.1
Experience Curve Regression on Cost per Dollar of Loan
Dependent Variable: OPEXPLOAN
Method: Panel EGLS (Cross-section random effects)
Date: 10/17/14 Time: 16:46
Sample (adjusted): 2001 2011
Periods included: 11
Cross-sections included: 45
Total panel (unbalanced) observations: 140
Swamy and Arora estimator of component variances
Effects Specification
S.D. Rho
Weighted Statistics
Unweighted Statistics
84
Table C.2
Experience Curve Regression on Personnel Cost per Dollar of Loan
Dependent Variable: PERSONEXPLOAN
Method: Panel EGLS (Cross-section random effects)
Date: 10/17/14 Time: 16:47
Sample (adjusted): 2003 2010
Periods included: 8
Cross-sections included: 43
Total panel (unbalanced) observations: 102
Swamy and Arora estimator of component variances
Effects Specification
S.D. Rho
Weighted Statistics
Unweighted Statistics
85
Table C.3
U-Shaped Supply Curve Regression on Cost per Dollar of Loan
Dependent Variable: OPEXPLOAN
Method: Panel EGLS (Cross-section random effects)
Date: 10/17/14 Time: 16:48
Sample (adjusted): 2001 2011
Periods included: 11
Cross-sections included: 45
Total panel (unbalanced) observations: 140
Swamy and Arora estimator of component variances
Effects Specification
S.D. Rho
Weighted Statistics
Unweighted Statistics
86
Table C.4
U-Shaped Supply Curve Regression on
Personnel Cost per Dollar of Loan
Dependent Variable: PERSONEXPLOAN
Method: Panel EGLS (Cross-section random effects)
Date: 10/17/14 Time: 16:49
Sample (adjusted): 2003 2010
Periods included: 8
Cross-sections included: 43
Total panel (unbalanced) observations: 102
Swamy and Arora estimator of component variances
Effects Specification
S.D. Rho
Weighted Statistics
Unweighted Statistics
87