3 IGE-text-book
3 IGE-text-book
3 IGE-text-book
GREEN ECONOMY
Edited by Derek Eaton & Fulai Sheng
POLICIES AND PRACTICE
Copyright © Zayed International Foundation for the Environment & Tongji University, 2019
Unless otherwise stated, all content is © Zayed International Foundation for the Environment & Tongji University and is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International License. This means that as
long as the material is used for non-commercial and non-derivative purposes you are free to share the content by copying and distributing. You must give appropriate credit to Zayed International Foundation for the Environment & Tongji University,
provide a link to the report and the licence, and indicate if changes were made.
Every reasonable effort has been made to seek appropriate permission from people identifiable in photographs used throughout the site as well as to trace copyright holders, but we would be pleased to make suitable arrangements to clear
permission for material reproduced in this book with any copyright holders whom it has not been possible to contact.
Disclaimer of liability
The material contained in the report is provided for general purposes only. Although we endeavour to ensure that the content is accurate and up to date, the Zayed International Foundation for the Environment & Tongji University accept no
responsibility for loss arising from reliance on information contained in this website.
Neither the Zayed International Foundation for the Environment & Tongji University nor any of its agents, employees and sub-contractors shall be liable to you or any other party for any claim, loss, demand or damages whatsoever (whether such
claims, loss, demands or damages were foreseeable, known or otherwise) arising out of or in connection with the use of the report or information, content or materials included.
In no event shall the Zayed International Foundation for the Environment & Tongji University or any of its agents, employees or sub-contractors be liable to you for any indirect or consequential loss or damage including, without limitation, any; (1)
loss of actual or anticipated profits (including loss of profits on contracts); (2) loss of revenue; (3) loss of business; (4) loss of opportunity; (5) loss of anticipated savings; (6) loss of good will; (7) loss of reputation; (8) loss or damage to or corruption
of data; (9) loss of use of money or otherwise, and whether or not advised of the possibility of such claim, loss, demand or damages and arising in tort (including negligence), contract or otherwise, to the fullest extent permitted by law.
Links within the report may lead to other websites. They are provided for convenience only. We do not sponsor, nor necessarily endorse or otherwise approve of any information or statements appearing in those websites (or websites referred to or
linked to those websites). The Zayed International Foundation for the Environment & Tongji University accept no responsibility for the privacy practices, nor do we accept any liability in connection with the content of, such websites.
Citation
Eaton, D., & Sheng, F. (Eds.) (2019). Inclusive Green Economy: Policies and Practice. Dubai, Shanghai: Zayed International Foundation for the Environment & Tongji University.
Acknowledgements:
Assistant Editors: Elena Antoni (UN Environment), Verena Balke (former: UN Environment, now: Accenture), Zhengzheng Qu (former: UN Environment, now: Green Climate Fund)
Project Focal Point, Tongji University: Dr. Jing Zhang, Tongji University, College of Environmental Science and Engineering
Project Focal Point, Zayed International Foundation for the Environment: Dr. Meshgan Mohammed Al Awar, Director, Research and Studies Center, Dubai Police Academy, Secretary General Zayed Foundation
Authors: Cameron Allen, Elena Antoni, Meshgan Mohammed Al Awar, Steve Bass, Derek Eaton, Moustapha Kamal Gueye, Haripriya Gundimeda, Guoyong Liang, Gunnar Köhlin, Wilfried Lütkenhorst, Anna
Pegels, José Pineda, Zhengzheng Qu, Jacob Michael Salcone, Kristin Seyboth, Paul Steele, Thomas Sterner, Zhou Xin, Aiora Zabala, Simon Zadek, Eduardo Zambrano, Jing Zhang
Reviewers: Sarwat Chowdhury, Michele Clara, Marcel Crull, Devika Iyer, Joy Kim, Benoît Lallemand, Mireille Martini, Albert Merino-Saum, Bruno Oberli, Sadamitsu Sakoguchi, Tim Scott, Ben Simmons,
Lizhen Xu
Student reviewers: Verena Balke, Jonas Bannert, Patrick Lindner, Nadia Mondini, Kira Lynn Mullally, Jannika Mumme, Carolin Scheil, Kerstin Wonka, Alberto Zambon.
In addition, we would like to thank the following individuals for their contributions, without whom the completion of the book would not have been possible: Stacey Andell, Claudia Assmann, Christy Box, Loreine
Dalmeida, Friederike Doebbe, Mohamed Elharati, Emily Frankling, Abdul-Majeid Haddad, Claire Harasty, Colm Hastings, Cameron Hepburn, Sai Konda, Anna McIntosh, Hannah Parry, Siaka Salami, Olga
Strietskallina, Kiia Strömmer, Halima Tahikheli, Bereket Tsegav, Mito Tsukamoto, Karin Valverde, Dimitri Zenghelis, Yimin Zhou
Special thanks also go to: Mohamed Ahmed Bin Fahad, Zayed International Foundation for the Environment, Asst. Commander, Academic & Training, Dubai Police Gen. H.Q, Fengting Li, Professor, and
Executive Deputy Dean of UN Environment-Tongji Institute of Environment for Sustainable Development, Iyad Abumoghli, Regional Director and Representative of UN Environment in West Asia 2012-2017,
and Steven Stone, Chief of UN Environment’s Resources & Markets Branch (R&M), as well as all other colleagues from UN Environment, Tongji University, and the Zayed Foundation, who have made the
completion of this book possible.
FOREWORD
The United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP) launched a Green Economy Initiative in 2008, which aimed at encouraging investment in improving the
environment as a new engine for economic growth. The initiative resonated with policy makers such that “green economy” was adopted as a major agenda item
for the 2012 United Nations Conference on Sustainable Development.
Governments and businesses are intuitively attracted to the notion that investing in clean technologies, clean water, and clean mobility, etc. can improve the
environment while creating jobs and markets. Some of them acted upon this notion accordingly, such as in China and the United Arab Emirates. For the green
economy model to sustain beyond anecdotal examples, however, it needs a systematic framework that speaks to policy advisers and business executives, as
well as the graduate students who will step into those positions in the coming years.
This textbook attempts to offer that systematic framework for the green economy model. It builds on and extends from the traditional economic growth model by
articulating the contributions to productivity from investing in natural capital, clean technologies, and green skills, enabled by fiscal, finance, trade, and labour
policies. It also addresses the importance of institutions and progress measurement for ensuring that transition towards a green economy is pro-poor, inclusive,
fair, and just. We hope that this textbook will inspire the students of today and prepare them to shape the Inclusive Green Economy of tomorrow.
CHAPTER 7 : INCLUSION, POVERTY REDUCTION & GENDER EQUITY FOR A GREEN ECONOMY
Cameron Allen
LEARNING OBJECTIVES
This chapter aims to enable its readers to: University of New South Wales
Cameron Allen is an international sustainable development expert who worked
• Outline the main challenges facing humanity and analyse their drivers; for several years with the United Nations on inclusive green economy and
the development and implementation of the Sustainable Development Goals
• Articulate how the inclusive green economy model seeks to address these chal- (SDGs).
lenges; and He is currently a consultant and researcher at the University of NSW in
Sydney, where his research focuses on evidence-based approaches to policy
and planning and the application of systems analysis and modelling to support
• Understand the major characteristics that underpin national strategies on national implementation of the SDGs.
inclusive green economy, the related analytical tools, key actors and initiatives He has published a range of academic journal papers in this field, and
as well as the critical role of public policy in turning the inclusive seen economy continues to engage with the UN on a range of projects relating to the inclusive
model into practice. green economy and SDGs.
CHAPTER CONTENTS profound across all dimensions of life. The richest one
per cent of the world’s population now control close Box 1: The planetary boundaries
1. Main challenges and drivers to 50 per cent of global assets, while the poorest half
concept
owns a mere one per cent (Stierli et al., 2014). About
2. The ‘Inclusive Green Economy’ model one in eight people still live in extreme poverty, nearly Considerable research has been done in the past decade to better
understand and measure planetary biophysical limits, with increasing
3. Turning the new model into practice 800 million people suffer from hunger, 1.1 billion people attention towards delineating safer limits or thresholds for human activ-
are living without electricity, some 2.5 billion people lack ity. Among the most comprehensive efforts to delineate such limits is
4. Concluding remarks basic sanitation facilities, and water scarcity affects the work on establishing nine planetary boundaries, which represent a
safe operating space for humanity [zotpressInText item=”{BS33HN7F}”]
5. Appendices more than 2 billion people worldwide (United Nations, (Rockström et al., 2009, Steffen et al., 2015).
2016; World Health Organization & UNICEF, 2013). While The nine planetary boundaries concept, which was introduced in 2009
economic development and globalization have brought and has been influential in global sustainability policy development,
immense progress and advancements, they have also aims to define the environmental limits within which humanity can safely
worldwide (see also Chapter 7) (Felbermayr et al., 2011; Their analysis suggests that humanity has already transgressed three of
1.1 Persistent poverty and inequality Davis & Harrigan, 2011; Lee & Vivarelli, 2006). these boundaries (climate change, biodiversity loss and nitrogen) and is
well on the way to crossing several others.
In the years leading up to 2015, significant progress was In Figure 1, the green zone shows the safe operating space, the yellow
zone is the zone of uncertainty, where risk is increasing, and red rep-
made across a range of development objectives agreed 1.2 Overstepped planetary boundaries resents the high-risk zone. The planetary boundary itself is located at the
under the Millennium Development Goals (MDGs), intersection of the green and yellow zones. The grey wedges represent
including addressing poverty and hunger, education, Economic growth has indeed driven an increase in processes for which global-level boundaries cannot yet be quantified.
gender equality, and health outcomes in the low-income household income in both high- and low-income coun-
world (United Nations, 2015). This progress has taken tries along with a reduction in extreme poverty and
place in the context of a quadrupling of the global pop- expansion of the middle class. This growth, however, has
ulation to well over 7 billion people over the last 100 been accompanied by rapidly changing consumption
years, during which time global economic output (mea- and production patterns, with steeply rising environmen-
sured by GDP) has increased more than 24-fold (UN tal impacts and pollution on a global scale (Figures 1-4,
Environment, 2012; Maddison, 2003; Krausmann et al., over the page). Over the past century, primary energy
2009) (Figures 1 and 2). Continued economic develop- use has increased more than ten-fold, while water use
ment and growth in low-income regions is seen by many has increased more than
as the key mechanism for addressing remaining social Key term:
six-fold (Figure 3). Global
development challenges and leaving no one behind. Primary energy material consumption rose
Energy that has not been to 70 billion metric tonnes
However, despite the gains made, inequalities remain transformed in any way from its
original form. in 2010, with two-fifths of
Figure 6: Key elements for National Green Growth Planning (Green Growth Best Practice, 2014) Figure 7: The steps of a typical green economy policy assessment
ics models), as well as sectoral models which enable a in 2013 reported that at that time there were around 60 • Reegle (REEEP and REN21)
more detailed assessment of a sector of interest (energy, different initiatives globally supporting green economy, • Sustainable Development Knowledge Platform (UN DESA).
agriculture, water etc.) through simulation and optimiza- green growth and low-carbon development, as well as Partnerships
tion at a sectoral level (e.g. partial equilibrium models over 30 donor countries and a broad range of imple-
or systems engineering models). For example, Allen et menting organizations including UN Environment, the • The Global Green Growth Institute, established in 2010,
brings together a range of national governments, research institutes,
al. (2016) reviews 80 different modelling tools that can Global Green Growth Institute, the World Bank, UNDP, intergovernmental organizations and private sector actors
support national policy assessment for the SDGs, many FAO, GEF, UNIDO, IFAD, UNFCCC, OECD, ILO, REEEP • The Partnership for Action on Green Economy (PAGE), established
of which have been applied in the development of green and REN21 (UN DESA, 2013). These actors continue to in 2012, is being led by UN Environment with its partners the
International ILO, UNIDO, UN Institute for Training and Research
economy and low carbon strategies. The LEDS Global provide support for the green economy through a mul- (UNITAR)
Partnership also includes an online toolkit which lists titude of platforms and partnerships (Box 2). Informa-
• The Green Economy Coalition is a global network of organizations
around 80 tools to assess impacts and linkages between tion about many of these initiatives can be located on from NGOs, research institutes, the UN, business and trade unions
national development priorities and low emission devel- the Green Growth Knowledge Platform which provides for information exchange, awareness-raising and research
opment strategies (LEDS Global Partnership, n.d.). a portal to a broad range of research, publications and • The Low Emissions Development Strategies (LEDS) Global
Partnership is coordinated through Open Energy Info (OpenEI).
data on the green economy.
These publications, guidelines and toolkits provide a • International Partnership on Mitigation and Measurement, Reporting
useful starting point for countries and stakeholders who Since 2008 through its Green Economy Initiative and and Verification (MRV), REEEP, and REN21
are embarking on a national green economy planning more recently through PAGE, UN Environment and its • World Bank’s Wealth Accounting and Valuation of Ecosystem
process (see Appendix 2 for a non-exhaustive list of partners (UNITAR, UNDP, ILO and UNIDO) have sup-
Services (WAVES) Partnership, as well as the Economics of
Ecosystems and Biodiversity (TEEB) initiative led by UN Environment
tools). ported the preparation of green economy stocktaking with a range of partners
and scoping studies, national modelling or quantitative
assessments, green fiscal assessments, and national
the Korea Institute for International Economic Policy, the • Chile’s National Green Growth Strategy (2013)
Korea Legislative Research Institute, the European Bank There is also considerable related experience with • Peru’s National Green Growth Strategy (2014)
for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) and UN low-carbon development planning. Based on UNDP esti-
• Kenya’s Green Economy Strategy and Implementation Plan (2015
Environment. mates in 2017, around 88 countries have adopted some
form of LEDS in the context of UNFCCC commitments. • Malta’s Green Our Economy – Achieving a Sustainable Future (2015)
Based on the general framework outlined in its Green Over the past decade, several emerging economies with • Indonesia’s Green Growth Roadmap (2015)
Growth Strategy launched in 2011, the OECD has main- substantial GHG emissions (notably Brazil, China, India, • Fiji’s Green Growth Framework (2015)
streamed green growth into its national and multilateral Indonesia, South Africa and Republic of Korea) have
policy surveillance exercises in order to provide policy developed integrated strategies on climate change and
• Egypt’s Green Economy Strategy (2016)
advice that is targeted to the needs of individual coun- development or low-carbon growth. Moreover, a number • Jordan’s National Green Growth Plan (2017)
tries. These include its Economic Surveys, Environmental of the lowest-income countries have elaborated inte- • Uganda’s Green Growth Development Strategy (2018)
Performance Reviews, Innovation Reviews, and Invest- grated climate and development strategies, for instance
Additional resources
Uncovering Pathways to an Inclusive
Green Economy
The UN’s Sustainable Development
Goals
Re-thinking Progress: The Circular
Economy
Allen, C., Metternicht, G. & Wiedmann, T. (2017). An iterative framework for national scenario Daly, H. E. (2008). A steady-state economy. Opinion Piece for Redefining Prosperity. Sustainable
modelling for the sustainable development goals (SDGs). Sustainable Development. Vol. 25, 5. Development Commission, UK.
372-385. Daly, H. E. & Farley, J. (2011). Ecological economics: principles and applications. Washington, D.C:
Atkisson, A. (2012). Life Beyond Growth. Institute for Studies in Happiness, Economy and Society: Island Press.
Tokyo-ISHES. Davis, D. R. & Harrigan, J. (2011). Good jobs, bad jobs, and trade liberalization. Journal of
Ayres, R. U. & Warr, B. (2010). The economic growth engine: how energy and work drive material International Economics, 84, 26-36.
prosperity. Cheltenham, UK. Northampton, MA, USA: Edward Elgar Publishing. Dietz, R. & O’Neill, D. W. (2013). Enough is enough: Building a sustainable economy in a world of
Barbier, E. (2010). How is the global green new deal going? Nature, 464, 832-833. finite resources. Abingdon, Oxon: Routledge.
Barbier, E. (2011). The policy challenges for green economy and sustainable economic Efken, J., Dirksmeyer, W., Kreins, P. & Knect, M. (2016). Measuring the importance of the
development. Natural Resources Forum, Wiley Online Library, 233-245. bioeconomy in Germany: Concept and illustration. NJAS-Wageningen Journal of Life
Sciences, 77, 9-17.
Boston, J. (2011). Biophysical limits and green growth. Policy Quarterly, 7, 34-42.
El-Chichakli, B. (2016). Five cornerstones of a global bioeconomy. Nature, 535, 221-223.
Boulding, K. E. (1966). The economics of the coming spaceship earth. Environmental Quality Issues
in a Growing Economy. Baltimore: Inc. The John Hopkins Press. Ellis, K., Baker, B. & Lemma A. (2009). Policies for low carbon growth, Overseas Development
Institute, London, UK.
Brand, U. (2012). Green economy–the next oxymoron? No lessons learned from failures of
implementing sustainable development. GAIA-Ecological Perspectives for Science and European Commission (2009). Impact assessment guidelines. Brussels: European Commission.
Society, 21, 28-32. European Sustainable Development Network (2009). Sustainable development strategies beyond
Bringezu, S., Schutz, H., Pengue, W., O’Brien, M., Garcia, F., Sims, R., Howarth, R. W., Kauppi, L., Europe. ESDN Quarterly Report September 2009.
Swilling, M. & Herrick, J. (2014). Assessing global land use: Balancing consumption with Felbermayr, G., Prat, J. & Schemer, H.-J. (2011). Globalization and labor market outcomes: Wage
sustainable supply. Nairobi: United Nations Environment Programme. bargaining, search frictions, and firm heterogeneity. Journal of Economic theory, 146, 39-73.
Cobb, J. B. & Daly, H. E. (1973). Towards a steady state economy. San Francisco: W. H. Freeman Geoghegan, T. (2013). Post-2015: framing a new approach to sustainable development. Policy
and Co. Ltd. Paper [Online], March 2013.
Costanza, R., Cumberland, J. H., Daly, H., Goodland, R., Norgaard, R. B., Kubiszewski, I. & Franco, George, D. A., Lin, B. C.-A. & Chen, Y. (2015). A circular economy model of economic growth.
C. (2014). An introduction to ecological economics. Boca Raton: CRC Press. Environmental Modelling & Software, 73, 60-63.
Pearce, D. W., Markandya, A. & Barbier, E. (1989). Blueprint for a green economy, Abingdon, Oxon: UN Environment (2011a). Decoupling natural resource use and environmental impacts from
Earthscan. economic growth. In: Fischer-Kowalski, M., Swilling, M., Von Weizsackar, E. U., Ren, Y.,
Moriguchi, Y., Crane, W., Krausmann, F., Eisenmenger, N., Giljum, S., Hennicke, P., Romero
Pearce, D. W. & Turner, R. K. (1990). Economics of natural resources and the environment. Lankao, P. & Siriban Manalang, A. (eds.) A Report of the Working Group on Decoupling in the
Baltimore:JHU Press. International Resource Panel. Nairobi: United Nations Environment Programme.
Pirgmaier, E. (2017). The Neoclassical Trojan Horse of Steady-State Economics. Ecological UN Environment (2011b). Towards a green economy: Pathways to sustainable development and
Economics, 133, 52-61. poverty eradication. Nairobi: United Nations Environment Programme.
Pollitt, H., Barker, A., Barton, J., Pirgmaier, E., Polzin, C., Lutter, S., Hinterberger, F. & Stocker, A. UN Environment (2012). Global environmental outlook: Fifth Edition (GEO5). Nairobi: United Nations
(2010). A scoping study on the macroeconomic view of sustainability. Final report for the Environment Programme.
European Commission, DG Environment. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge econometrics.
UN Environment (2014a). A guidance manual for green economy indicators. Nairobi: United Nations
Robins, N., Clover, R. & Singh, C. (2009). A climate for recovery. HBSC Bank Global Research, Environment Programme.
London.
UN Environment (2014b). A guidance manual for green economy policy assessment. Nairobi.:
Schneider, F., Kallis, G. & Martinez-Alier, J. (2010). Crisis or opportunity? Economic degrowth for United Nations Environment Programme.
social equity and ecological sustainability. Introduction to this special issue. Journal of Cleaner
Production, 18, 511-518. UN Environment (2014c). Using models for green economy policymaking. Nairobi: United Nations
Environment Programme.
Shogren, H. & White, P. (2007). Environmental economics in theory and practice. London: Palgrave.
UN Environment (2015). Uncovering pathways towards an inclusive green economy: A summary for
Stahel, W. R. (2016). The circular economy. Nature, 531, 435. leaders. Nairobi: United Nations Environment Programme.
Steffen, W., Richardson, K., Rockstrom, J., Cornell, S. E., Fetzker, I., Bennet, E. M., Biggs, R., UN Environment (2016). GEO-6 regional assessment for Africa. Nairobi: United Nations Environment
Carpenter, S. R., De Vries, W., De Wit, C. A., Folke, C., Gerten, D., Heinke, J., Mace, G. M., Programme.
Persson, L. M., Ramanathan, V., Reyers, B. & Sorlin, S. (2015). Planetary boundaries: Guiding
human development on a changing planet. Science, 347. UN Environment (n.d.). Environment live. Science and data for people.
Stern, N. (2008). The economics of climate change. The American Economic Review, 1-37. UNEP Inquiry (2015). Design of a Sustainable Financial System: The Inquiry’s 3rd progress Report.
Geneva, Switzerland: United Nations Environment Programme.
Stierli, M., Shorrocks, A., Davies, J. B., Lluberas, R. & Koutsoukis, A. (2014). Global Wealth Report
2014. Zurich: Credit Suisse Research Institute (CSRI). United Nations (2015). The Millennium Development Goals Report 2015. New York: United Nations.
Swanson, D. & Bhadwal, S. (2009). Creating adaptive policies - A guide for policy-making in an United Nations (2016). The sustainable development goals report 2016. New York: United Nations
uncertain world. Ottawa: International Institute for Sustainable Development. United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs (2012). A guidebook to the green
Swanson, D., Pinter, L., Bregha, B., Volkery, A. & Jacob, K. (2004). National strategies for sustainable economy - Issue 3: Exploring green economy policies and experiences with national
development – Challenges, approaches and innovations in strategic and coordinated action. strategies. New York: UNDESA.
Winnipeg, Canada:International Institute for Sustainable Development. United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs (2013). A guidebook to the green
Tietenberg, T. H. & Lewis, L. (2016). Environmental and natural resource economics, Abingdon, economy Issue 4: A guide to international green economy initiatives. New York: UNDESA.
Oxon: Routledge. United Nations Development Programme (2011). Preparing low-emission climate-resilient
development strategies. New York: UNDP.
GREEN ECONOMY
Technopolis Group
Dr. Xin Zhou is Leader of the Strategic and Quantitative Analysis Centre at the
• Become aware of the limitations of existing modeling tools in macroeconomics for
Institute for Global Environmental Strategies. She has more than 20 years of
guiding the transition process and short-run macroeconomic policy; and experience in environmental policy analysis. She is now leading a couple of
research projects related to Sustainable Development Goals interlinkages and
• Appreciate the role of economic accounts and statistics in informing policy and, climate policy assessment, etc.
the benefits of developing and adopting extended frameworks of the System of
She led the development of a couple of practical tools supporting integrated
National Accounts. policy making for achieving sustainable development, including the SDG
Interlinkages Analysis and Visualisation Tool. Prior to joining IGES in 2007, she
was Director of Environmental Policy Research at the Policy Research Center
for Environment and Economy.
CHAPTER CONTENTS As is argued in chapter one of this publication, this calls possible implications for specific domains of economic
for a shift from a siloed approach, seeking to maximize policy are clearly articulated. This approach is intended
1. Introduction certain economic benefits, to an integrated approach to provide a unifying departure point for other chapters
covering broader aspects of sustainable development. in this book.
2. Origins of green macro-economic thinking Macroeconomics, the discipline concerned with the
3. The economy in pictures: Stocks and flows study of economy-wide
Key term: phenomenon, has in the
4. Growth Macroeconomics
Macroeconomics is distinguished past concentrated on 2. Origins of green macro-
explaining the dynamics
economic thinking
from microeconomics which con-
5. Growth in a green economy: Towards centrates on specific products,
of inflation, employment,
balanced capital stocks groups of consumers, firms and
markets. Readers wishing to growth, exchange rates, Economics – most broadly defined as the study of
deepen their understanding of
6. Short-run dynamics: Transforming the economics, and the treatment of etc. To guide an integrated “human behaviour as a relationship between given ends
sustainability and inclusion, should approach to policy-mak- and scarce means” (Robbins, 1935) – has a long tradi-
components of aggregate demand consider consulting online CORE
textbook, “The Economy” (CORE
ing towards an inclusive tion of looking at resource and growth concerns. Some
7. Models for policy analysis Team). See also https://www.you- green economy, a tran- classical economists were very much concerned with
tube.com/watch?v=MKO1icFVtDc
sition that affects almost the potential limits to improving people’s living stan-
8. Data and accounting every aspect of production dards, particularly as population increased. Malthus’
9. Conclusion and consumption in the economy, the discipline of mac- (1798) predictions that population growth would diminish
roeconomics itself needs to evolve (see, for example, the benefits of improved agricultural productivity resulted
Vines and Wills, 2018). in economics being labelled “the dismal science”. It is
typically claimed that Malthus failed to foresee the pos-
1. Introduction We argue that a fully suitable macroeconomic framework
sibility that technological change would outpace popu-
for addressing a green economy transition does not yet
The world today faces many unprecedented economic, lation growth and this indeed appears to be the case, at
exist, though there are many useful elements that can
social and environmental challenges. Whereas the spe- least in aggregate, over the past 200 years. Now, with
guide both research and policy. This chapter will review
cific nature of challenges may vary in different countries growing awareness of planetary boundaries, the basic
previous and ongoing efforts from a range of economic
and regions, the degradation of the global environment Malthusian idea is gaining renewed attention (Clark,
paradigms, recognizing their different contributions, as
is affecting all of the world’s regions and interrelates in 2007; Galor and Weil, 2000; Peretto and Valente, 2015).
well as the relevant weaknesses. Thus, our perspective
complex ways with our social and economic systems. is one that openly recognizes ongoing differences and Economists began early to look at the question of
Environmental degradation, as a result of unsustainable debates between competing perspectives on macro- how to optimally use natural resources, including both
lifestyles and systems of production and consumption, economics. The reader should take away an overview
have become an economy-wide phenomenon, with of these frameworks and signposts on where to find
far-reaching consequences on the welfare of the world more in-depth information. In pursuing this objective, the
population. chapter takes a policy perspective which means that the
The emphasis then was on rebalancing the attention and priority given to competing
objectives, or goals. As stated, the nested model in both Figures 2 and 3 emphasizes
that the economy ultimately needs to operate within environmental boundaries, sug-
gesting that there are ways to align economic, social and environmental objectives. This
is the essence of the green economy. Figure 4: ‘The Doughnut’ economy (Raworth, 2017)
being “agnostic about growth”, arguing that resolving and another examining long-term processes of eco- In its most general form, the production function is written mathematically
the debate around growth is less relevant than devoting nomic growth. This latter area studies long-run struc- as:
more attention to such other goals. Ideas and frame- tural change in the economy, through a process called Y=f(K,L,R)
works such as the nesting of SDGs in Figure 3, and ‘capital accumulation’. Economists working on this topic,
Doughnut Economics presented in Figure 4, emphasize Where K represents the stock of physical capital, L the stock of human
attempt to identify specific factors that either promote capital (or labour), R the stock of natural capital (including resources,
the need to assess economic performance in terms of or inhibit growth with a particular focus on institutions though not limited to those), and Y is total production. Thus, in this
other outcomes and indicators. To formulate and guide and policies that concern, for example, education, simple sense, the production function embodies the technological possi-
bilities existing in an economy.
policy, it is also necessary to have frameworks – theo- trade and innovation 13. These determinants of long-
ries and models – that describe the functioning of the run growth have been studied by economists since the The general form of the production function above does not tell us how
much output can be produced. For that purpose, a specific function
economy in these terms. At the very least, frameworks 1950s. The core of this area of macroeconomics has needs to be used. Economists have used a number of different func-
need to integrate outcomes in terms of social and envi- been the aggregate production function, in which labour tions. One of the most popular is termed the Cobb-Douglas function:
ronmental considerations. The following sections will and capital are combined to produce goods and ser-
review long-run and short-run perspectives on the mac- Y=Kα×Lβ×Rγ
vices with the use of some technology, as in the original
roeconomy. It will be seen that there are a few limited Solow growth model (Solow, 1956; see Box 2.2) 14. These This includes three new parameters, or variables (αα,β,γγ), which deter-
macroeconomic frameworks that include some of the goods and services are either consumed or invested in mine how much the additions to the respective capital stocks will
increase production. The nature of the production function also deter-
issues. It should, however, be clear that these remain the production of more physical capital. The model has mines the degree to which capitals can be substituted for each other in
inadequate for the task of policy guidance and remain been used to assess under what conditions an economy the economy. Acemoglu (2009) provides a detailed discussion on the
aggregate production function and its use in economic growth theory.
an open and urgent field for research and development.
13 A comprehensive treatment is found in the leading graduate level textbook by
Acemoglu (2009).
14 The discussion here concentrates on “mainstream” neoclassical macroeconom-
ics. There are various other approaches and lines of research. From a green economy
11 Tily (2015) provides an account of how economic growth as an objective came perspective, “Keynesian” models have recently been developed to incorporate climate
to dominate economic policy making in the 1950s and 1960s. change, as well as income distribution and inequality issues (see, for example, Rezai
12 Hepburn et al., (2018) provide detailed arguments in favour of the green et al., 2013; 2018) and some other approaches have been proposed (Rezai and Stagl,
growth agenda. 2016).
(Romer, 2011) 15. This analysis emphasizes the impor- Some stock of natural capital, for instance. is required assumes that natural capital can generally be substituted for by other forms of capi-
tal, while strong sustainability considers such substitution possibilities as being more
tance of the rate at which technological progress can in order to produce food. This suggests that there may limited. The multi-dimensionality of the concept of natural capital can give rise to
be a critical lower threshold for natural capital, and if such seemingly different perspectives. The possibility of substitutes for specific natural
resources is greater than for ecosystems providing essential life support services.
15 The model is based on work by Nordhaus (1992), as part of a critical review of
crossed, economic production would decline or even 17 In mathematical terms, the technology is represented by the function and its
the revised Limits to Growth modeling (Meadows et al., 1992). specific parameters (see Box 2).
LeBaron, Blake, and Leigh Tesfatsion. 2008. “Modeling Macroeconomies as Open-Ended Dynamic PAGE, 2017a. The Green Economy Progress Measurement Framework – Methodology. Partnership
Systems of Interacting Agents.” American Economic Review 98 (2): 246–50. doi:10.1257/ for Action on a Green Economy.
aer.98.2.246. PAGE, 2017b. The Integrated Green Economy Modelling Framework – Technical Document.
Lequiller, Francois, and Derek Blades. 2014. Understanding National Accounts. Paris: Partnership for Action on a Green Economy.
OECD. 2018. The Bioeconomy to 2030: Designing a Policy Agenda. Paris, France: Organisation for Pearce, D. A., Turner, R. K., 1990. Economics of Natural Resources and the Environment. Baltimore:
Economic Co-operation and Development Johns Hopkins University Press.
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264214637-en. Peretto, Pietro F., and Simone Valente. 2015. “Growth on a Finite Planet: Resources, Technology
and Population in the Long Run.” Journal of Economic Growth 20 (3): 305–31. https://doi.
Lin, Justin Yifu. 2012. The Quest for Prosperity: How Developing Economies Can Take Off. Princeton org/10.1007/s10887-015-9118-z.
N.J.: Princeton University Press. http://press.princeton.edu/titles/9812.html.
Perez, Carlota. 2016. “Capitalism, Technology and a Green Global Age: The Role of History in
Lucas, R. E. J., 1988. “On the mechanics of Economic Development.” Journal of Monetary Helping to Shape the Future.” In Rethinking Capitalism: Economics and Policy for Sustainable
Economics, 22 (1), 3-42. and Inclusive Growth, edited by Michael Jacobs and Mariana Mazzucato, 1 edition, 191–217.
Malthus, R., 1798. An Essay on the Principle of Population. London: J. Johnson, in St. Paul’s Church- Chichester, West Sussex, United Kingdom: Wiley-Blackwell.
Yard.
Raval, Devesh. 2017. “What’s Wrong with ‘Capital in the Twenty-First Century’s’ Model?” In After Samuelson, Paul A. 1948. Economics: An Introductory Analysis. New York: McGraw Hill.
Piketty: The Agenda for Economics and Inequality, edited by Heather Boushey, J. Bradford Smith, A., 1776. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Basel: J.J.
DeLong, and Marshall Steinbaum. Harvard University Press. Tourneisen.
Raworth, Kate. 2017. Doughnut Economics: Seven Ways to Think Like a 21st-Century Economist. Smulders, S., 1994. Growth, Market Structure, and the Environment. Essays on the Theory of
London: Random House Business. Endogenous Economic Growth. Tilburg University.
Rezai, Armon, and Sigrid Stagl. 2016. “Ecological Macroeconomics: Introduction and Review.” Smulders, S., 2005. “Endogenous Technological Change, Natural Resources, and Growth.” In:
Ecological Economics 121: 181–85. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2015.12.003. Simpson, R. D., Toman, M. A., Ayres, R. U. (Eds.), Scarcity and Growth Revisited: Natural
Rezai, Armon, Lance Taylor, and Duncan Foley. 2018. “Economic Growth, Income Distribution, Resources and the Environment in the New Mellennium. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the
and Climate Change.” Ecological Economics 146 (April): 164–72. https://doi.org/10.1016/j. Future.
ecolecon.2017.10.020. Smulders, S., Toman, M., Withagen, C., 2014. “Growth Theory and “Green Growth”. OxCarre
Rezai, Armon, Lance Taylor, and Reinhard Mechler. 2013. “Ecological Macroeconomics: An Research Paper 135. Oxford Centre for the Analysis of Resource Rich Economies.
Application to Climate Change.” Ecological Economics 85 (January): 69–76. doi:10.1016/j. Solow, R. M., 1956. “A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth.” Quarterly Journal of
ecolecon.2012.10.008. Economics, 70 (1), 65-94.
Ricardo, D., 1821. On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation (3rd Edition). London: John Solow, R. M., 1974. “Intergenerational equity and exhaustible resources.” Review of Economic
Murray. Studies (Symposium): 29-46.
Robbins, Lionel. 1935. An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science. London: Stern, David I., Michael S. Common, and Barbier, Edward B., 1996. “Economic Growth and
MacMillan. Environmental Degradation: The Environmental Kuznets Curve and Sustainable Development.”
Rockstrom, Johan, Will Steffen, Kevin Noone, Asa Persson, F. Stuart Chapin, Eric F. Lambin, Timothy World Development 24 (7): 1151–1160.
M. Lenton, et al. 2009. “A Safe Operating Space for Humanity.” Nature 461 (7263): 472–75. Stern, Nicholas. 2007. The Economics of Climate Change: The Stern Review. Cambridge, UK ; New
https://doi.org/10.1038/461472a. York: Cambridge University Press.
Rockström, Johan and Sukhdev, Pavan. 2016. “How food connects all the SDGs”, Blog post, http:// Stiglitz, J. E., 1974. “Growth with Exhaustible Natural Resources.” Review of Economic Studies 41.
www.stockholmresilience.org/research/research-news/2016-06-14-how-food-connects-all-the- Stiglitz, Joseph E. 2018. “Where Modern Macroeconomics Went Wrong.” Oxford Review of
sdgs.html Economic Policy 34 (1–2): 70–106.
Romer, P. M., 1986. “Increasing Returns and Long-run Growth.” Journal of Political Economy, 94 (4), Stiglitz, Joseph E., Amartya Sen, and Jean-Paul Fitoussi. 2009. “Report by the Commission on
1002-1037. Measurement of Economic Performance and Social Progress.” http://www.stiglitz-sen-fitoussi.
Romer, P. M., 1994. “The Origins of Endogenous Growth.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8 (1), fr/en/index.htm.
3-22. Stokey, N., 1998. “Are there limits to growth?” International Economic Review 39 (1): 1-31.
Romer, David. 2011. Advanced Macroeconomics. 4 edition. New York: McGraw-Hill Education.
Thaler, Richard H., and Cass R. Sunstein. 2009. Nudge: Improving Decisions About Health, Wealth, Van den Bergh, Jeroen C. J. M., 2017. “A Third Option for Climate Policy within Potential Limits to
and Happiness. New York: Penguin Books. Growth.” Nature Climate Change 7 (2): 107–12.
Tily, Geoff. 2015. “The National Accounts, GDP and the ‘Growthmen.’” http://www.primeeconomics. Victor, Peter A. 2012. “Growth, Degrowth and Climate Change: A Scenario Analysis.” Ecological
org/e-publications/. Economics, 84 (December): 206–12. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2011.04.013.
Tran-Nam, B., Truong, C. N., 2001. “The Environment, Externalities and Sustainable Growth in an Vines, David, and Samuel Wills. 2018. “The Rebuilding Macroeconomic Theory Project: An Analytical
Overlapping Generations Model.” In: Alan, W., Aldershot, H. W. (Eds.), Economic Theory and Assessment.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy 34 (1–2): 1–42.
International Trade. Hants: Edward Elgar. Voosholz, F., 2014. “A Survey on Modelling Economic Growth: With special interest on natural
United Nations, European Union, Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations., resource use.” CAWM Discussion Paper No. 69.
International Monetary Fund, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development., and Withagen, C., Smulders, S., 2012. “Green Growth: Lessons from Growth Theory.” Policy Research
World Bank. 2014. System of Environmental-Economic Accounting 2012 Central Framework. Working Paper 6230. The World Bank.
ST/ESA/STAT/Ser.F/109. New York: United Nations. Zenghelis, Dimitri. 2017. “The Role of Modelling and Scenario Development in Long-Term
UNEP. 2011. Towards a Green Economy: Pathways to Sustainable Development and Poverty Strategies.” World Resources Institute Long-Term Climate Strategies - Expert Perspectives
Alleviation. Geneva, Switzerland: United Nations Environment Programme. (blog). Accessed January 18, 2019. https://www.wri.org/climate/expert-perspective/role-
UNEP. 2014. A Guidance Manual for Green Economy Policy Assessment. modelling-and-scenario-development-long-term-strategies.
UNU-IHDP, and UNEP. 2012. Inclusive Wealth Report 2012: Measuring Progress Towards Zenghelis, Dimitri. 2016. “Decarbonisation: Innovation and the Economics of Climate Change.” In
Sustainability. Cambridge U.K.: Cambridge University Press. http://www.ihdp.unu.edu/docs/ Rethinking Capitalism: Economics and Policy for Sustainable and Inclusive Growth, edited by
Publications/Secretariat/Reports/SDMs/IWR%20SDM%20Low%20Resolution.pdf Michael Jacobs and Mariana Mazzucato, 1 edition. Chichester, West Sussex, United Kingdom:
Wiley-Blackwell.
CHAPTER 3:
Nature Sustainabiility
NATURAL CAPITAL
Cambridge, UK, for several years. She gained her PhD at Cambridge, after
studying at Oxford University and the Autonomous University of Barcelona. Her
work has been published in Ecological Economics, Global Environmental Change
and Methods in Ecology and Evolution, among others. She is handling editor at
the journal Nature Sustainability, covering social sciences.
This chapter introduces topics and concepts that are essential to further under- United Nations Environment Programme
standing of the current discussions and decision-making that are related to natural
capital. This chapter therefore will enable readers to: Jacob Salcone is an ecological economist consultant for The Economics of
Ecosystems and Biodiversity (TEEB), an initiative of UN Environment. With TEEB,
Jacob helps governments and researchers use microeconomic tools to quantify
• Articulate the concept of natural capital, why it has emerged, its importance, and value the human benefits of ecosystems and natural capital. He holds an
and how it differs from and relates to other relevant ideas; M.S. in Agricultural and Resource Economics from Colorado State University
and a B.A. in International Sustainable Development from the University of
• Describe a range of methodologies for valuing natural capital; California, Santa Cruz. He is currently modelling the land-use change impacts of
payment for ecosystem service programs in Mexico in pursuit of a PhD in Human
• Explain how natural capital is implemented in the public and private sectors; Dimensions of Natural Resources from Colorado State University.
and
• Articulate the importance of the labour market for a green transition and the Haripriya Gundimeda
resulting implications and effects on employment;
Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay
corresponds to non-use value, and estimations of the tion methods are commonly used to estimate values for • ◦Replacement/ substitute costs
value of natural capital tend to underestimate the total cost-benefits analysis • Opportunity costs
economic value (this caveat has led to some of the main Key term: (CBA). Other uses of these
Valuation methods • Damage cost avoided
criticisms of the concept, as explained above in sections A long-standing introductory re- methods are to explore or
2.3 and 3.2). source for such valuation methods project human behaviour B) Non-market and indirect market valuation methods:
is available at https://www.eco-
systemvaluation.org/ by King and and to assess damages in
In the absence of economic valuation, however, busi- Mazzotta. court cases. Valuation is • Revealed preferences (use value)
nesses and policy makers often implicitly assign zero also used to compare or • ▪Travel cost (typically for recreation values)
value to non-market benefits. While monetary esti- monitor changes in stocks
Key term: • Hedonic pricing (typically for property prices)
mates of natural capital may not reflect its full value, the Cost benefit analysis of natural capital, evaluate
process of valuation and integration of natural processes Cost Benefit Analysis is a
trends and steer policies.
• Stated preferences (use and non-use value)
popular approach to make deci-
and economic processes is useful to increase our per- sions about prospective policies or • Contingent valuation
ception of the costs of degrading nature, and to give it projects. In a CBA, the costs and Non-market and indirect • Choice modelling
higher policy priority. An example of this communicative the benefits of an intended policy methods are grouped into
or project are listed and quantified,
and agenda-setting role was the Stern review (Stern, and they require that all costs and two broad categories: C) Benefit transfer (extrapolating values estimated for another similar
entity)
2007), which brought climate change to the forefront of benefits are expressed in monetary revealed and stated pref-
terms.
public and policy attention by estimating the economic erences (see Box 3.3).
costs that climate change would bring to a national The choice
economy. Table 1 summarises the distinct reasons why Key concepts: of a spe- value a place they visit (e.g. a national park), by cal-
Valuation tools
valuation can be useful, in terms of uses that depend on Some examples of valuation web-sites are: cific method culating the costs of travelling from their homes to the
context and policy needs. https://www.evri.ca/Global/Splash.aspx depends on place.
http://www.environment.nsw.gov.au/envalueapp/
http://www2.lincoln.ac.nz/nonmarketvaluation/
the type of
http://www.gevad.minetech.metal.ntua.gr/home.php natural capital Researchers use hedonic pricing to analyse the influ-
4.1 Economic valuation methods http://www.beijer.kva.se/valuebase.htm
or ecosystem ence of natural environments on property prices, for
service to be example, by looking at properties next to urban parks,
A wide variety of economic methods can be used to esti- evaluated, its context and data availability. Revealed and comparing their prices to those of similar properties
mate the economic value of nature, including values not preferences methods estimate the value of a natural but which are located far from green spaces.
represented through market prices. As most of nature’s entity indirectly, through the prices of related items
contributions to humans have no real market, a range observed in real markets. For example, researchers use Stated preference methods ask individuals what they
of indirect or non-market valuation techniques have the travel cost method to estimate how much people would choose or how they would behave in a hypothet-
ical situation. In these methods, since values, expen-
Following a Ph.D. in environmental science, Dr. Jing Zhang has been working
at tongji University since 2010, focusing on low carbon development and
green economy.
Dr. Al Awar has been recognized both locally and internationally as she
has received multiple awards and appointments from various UN bodies,
including UNESCO, UNIDO, ECOSOC, UNOSSC and others. She is also a
certified UNIDO Expert in the use of Contaminated Sites Management Toolkit
for POPs and a Co-Chair in the WISDP initiated by UNESCO Hong Kong
Association.
Circular economy organizes economic activities into a closed-loop, and is based on whole-system thinking. Initially,
circular economy focused predominantly on waste recycling, which did not significantly change the patterns of
consumption and production. However, today’s notion of a circular economy extends far beyond recycling, and Cleaner energy supply technologies
encompasses new modes of production, new business models and new types of lifestyles, embracing innovation.
These practices depart radically from those adopted in a take-make-dispose linear model (UN Environment, 2015). A radical departure from hydrocarbon-based energy
Key term:
In the book Waste to Wealth, Lacy and Rutqvist (2015) introduce ten key technologies that bring disruptive influences Hydropower generation requires a shift towards more environmentally
to the economic system and support the shift towards a circular economy. Those technologies fall into three broad Power sourced from water. The en- friendly energy sources. Currently, the most widely
categories: digital technology, engineering technology, and a blend of these two (Hybrid technologies), such as ergy from flowing water is convert-
Machine to machine communication, 3D printing or advanced recycling technology. ed into electricity. Adapted from:
applied renewable energy sources include solar, wind,
https://www.studentenergy.org hydropower, biomass, and geothermal energy, and
It should be noted that while these technologies present good opportunities by which enterprises can move towards
a circular economy, they cannot be considered inherently green. Innovations beyond technology are therefore while these are gradually substituting coal and oil as an
necessary to optimize their application and to develop their full potential, so as to ensure that they have a positive
Key term:
energy source, they remain a long way from dominating
effect on the environment. This encompasses social and societal innovations, and a shift towards sustainable
consumption and lifestyles. Biomass global energy systems. With the levels of atmospheric
A renewable source of energy, carbon dioxide already at a record high and continuing
There is still a long way to go in the process towards becoming a circular society, with a recent publication reporting organic matter that comes from
that our world has only achieved 9% circularity to date (The Platform for Accelerating the Circular Economy, 2019). plants/animals. Biomass contains to increase, the technology that generates negative
One of the key elements in realizing this shift from a linear economy towards a circular model therefore lies in energy stored from the sun; when emissions, such as carbon capture and storage, could
understanding technology trends, and their potential to disrupt existing value chain, as well as support the creation of it is burned the chemical energy
new ways ones. stored in the biomass is released as play a key role in reducing carbon concentrations in the
heat. Examples include: Wood, ag- atmosphere.
Source: Lacy and Rutqvist, 2015; The Platform for Accelerating the Circular Economy, 2019; UN Environment, 2015. ricultural crops, food, sewage etc.
Adapted from: https://www.eia.gov
Digital technologies provide tools for the precise management of water and nutrients, thereby providing
agricultural products of a better quality. Implementing digital technology in an agricultural system may
take on different forms. For example, cloud-based services enable continuous and real-time monitoring
of production environments, enabling farmers to correct any problems before they become detrimental
to yield. So called ‘Cloud-based nitrogen advisors’, for instance, allow farmers to align nutrient additions
more precisely with crop needs. On-farm experiences of using cloud-based services have thus
highlighted the win-win effect of increased profit and decreased environmental impact.
For example, in Bulgaria, this advanced field equipment has been widely adopted, and associated
products and services are now offered by technical service providers. The increasing use of advanced
digital technologies within the agricultural sector has created opportunities for precise farming practices
and promoted the efficient utilization of natural resources. Digital technologies, such as remote sensors,
are also used to provide information on yield loss and risk management.
to its subsequent diffusion. The Theory of Technology Diffusion identifies three stages: Within the renewable energy sector, the UAE has since made great progress, recording an astounding 29-fold
“invention” – the first technical implementation of an idea; “innovation” – the first increase in renewable energy investment of US$2.2 billion in 2017. This investment was concentrated on two
Photovoltaic (PV) projects, the two largest such projects developed anywhere in the world: Sheikh Mohammed Bin
commercial introduction of a new product or business method; and “diffusion” – the Rashid Al Maktoum Solar Park Phase III installation, at 1.2GW and US$899 million, and the Marubeni JinkoSolar and
gradual adoption of a new way of doing things by multiple actors (Schumpeter, 1942). Adwea Sweihan plant, at 800MW and an estimated US$968 million (FS-UNEP Collaborating Centre, 2018).
At the diffusion stage, technology develops as more users adopt it, as initial previous In order to guide the formulation of its national innovation strategy, as well as the activities of both the private sector
users share information on its existence and its usage. As this process develops, and and civil society in advancing the UAE’s Green Economy transition, a number of initiatives were established. The
UAE Green Business Toolkit is one such example. The Toolkit is intended to inspire the private sector to make their
as new compatible products are developed, the value of the technology increases. businesses eco-friendlier and more socially responsible, and to guide them in this process. The Toolkit provides
These adoption externalities are important to understand the market diffusion process guidelines on how to green existing businesses, or to start your own business as a green entrepreneur, focusing on
three key areas:
of a new product or technology (Jaffe et al., 2005), and Box 4.5 introduces the concept
of diffusion of innovation in greater detail. • Green office: Focusing on typical office uses of energy, water, and other material goods and resources, the
Toolkit presents examples of how to green offices by making small changes in how these goods and resources are
used.
• Green procurement: This area focuses on procurement practices, including improving energy efficiency,
Coordination Failures lowering emissions, avoiding hazardous materials, and increasing recyclability. It also takes social aspects into
account, such as ethical conduct and community development.
Coordination within and across sectors and industries is essential when new
technologies attempt to change entire socio-technical systems. Companies and • Green products: This area focuses on enhancing the sustainability of produced goods and services, through
reducing the use of resource materials, energy, and water at the input stage, and then by minimizing waste and
businesses will not financially commit to major projects unless related investment needs emission outputs (UAE Ministry of Climate Change and Environment, 2018).
can be guaranteed. For instance, the development of offshore wind-farms requires the Dubai, as a leading smart innovative city both within the UAE and the wider Middle East region, has also developed
construction of underwater steel structures, the presence of electricity grids, and a a number of green technology initiatives. For example, in November 2015 His Highness Sheikh Mohammed bin
synchronized outlay of wind turbines. In the absence of such coordination, companies Rashid Al Maktoum, Vice President and Prime Minister of the UAE and Ruler of Dubai launched the US$27 billion
Dubai Green Fund in November 2015, as part of its broader Dubai Clean Energy Strategy 2050. The strategy aims to
and businesses will not commit to investing in the development of the necessary provide 7 per cent of Dubai’s energy mix from clean energy sources by 2020, 25 per cent by 2030 and 75 per cent by
technology (Altenburg & Pegels, 2012). 2050, eventually making it the city with the smallest carbon footprint in the world (UAE Ministry of Climate Change and
Environment, 2017).
In addition to these market failures, environmental externalities (see Chapter 1) also
have the effect of distorting financial markets. In order to achieve a socially optimal
level of green technology development, both kinds of market failures therefore have
to be addressed. While environmental regulation works to internalize the effects of
environmental externalities, policy instruments that promote both the development
This chapter aims to enable its readers to: International Labour Organization
• Articulate the importance of the labour market for a green transition and the Moustapha Kamal Gueye is Coordinator, Green Jobs Programme, at the
International Labour Organization. Previously, Kamal served as Head, Green
resulting implications and effects on employment; and Economy Advisory Services at the UN Environment Programme and as Senior
Programme Manager at the International Centre for Trade and Sustainable
• Formulate strategies and policies to overcome negative developments in the Development in Geneva.
labour market to enable a just transition. Earlier, Kamal spent twelve years across Asia working at the Institute for
Global Environmental Strategies in Japan. He holds a Ph.D. from Nagoya
University, Japan; DEA and LL.M from Dakar University; and Executive
Certificates from the World Bank Institute; Columbia University; Foundation
for Advanced Studies on International Development, Japan; and Integrated
Research and Action for Development, India.
1
This chapter is largely based on an ILO technical paper titled “A just transition to climate-resilient economies and
societies: Issues and perspectives for the world of work”, prepared by the author with contributions from Claire
Harasty, Olga Strietska-Ilina and Mito Tsukamoto (ILO, 2016).
CHAPTER 5: A JUST TRANSITION TO GREEN ECONOMIES: EMPLOYMENT & SOCIAL ISSUES 5.2
CHAPTER CONTENTS workers, the potential for growth in environmental goods It does so by articulating the concept of a ‘just transition’
and services industries can be hampered. as a principle of social justice and a practical guiding
1. Introduction The adjustment parameter reflects policy objectives
framework to connect growth and economic policies with
social objectives.
2. Natural capital degradation: Risks to that recognize that the structural, economic and social
decent work changes that green economies entail will benefit The chapter highlights that while most research
some, while impacting negatively on others. Unless suggests that the potential job creation of a transition
3. Investing in human capital for a just deliberate social policies are put in place to minimize to a greener economy outweighs the risk of job losses,
transition to a greener economy negative social impacts, green economies will not be and positive labour market outcomes can be expected
inclusive or just. Of equal importance, concern about overall, specific policies to ensure an active engagement
4. Conclusions the implications for jobs can be a powerful factor of in the world of work, social dialogue, and social
resistance with far reaching political consequences. In protection are indispensable for a just transition that
some cases, countries have lowered, limited or simply leaves no one behind.
1. Introduction cancelled environmental policies, including international
commitments, on the grounds of the negative effects that
This chapter discusses the importance of human these policies have on employment.
capital and a proactive labour policy in the transition 2. Natural capital degradation:
The chapter sets out by examining the consequences
towards greener economies (ILO, 2016). Human capital
can be defined by a broad interpretation of the labour that degradation or loss of natural capital has on Risks to decent work
stock, which includes skills, knowledge, education employment. It focuses on phenomena such as
The risks arising from environmental degradation, and
and research. In the pursuit of more environmentally climate change, natural disasters and heat waves, as
climate change in particular, range from economic and
sustainable economies and societies, human capital, on environmental impacts that bring shocks to the economy
welfare losses, damage to health and labour productivity,
the one hand, acts as an ‘enabling condition’ and, on the and have immediate consequences for enterprises and
and forced labour migration (Jessoe et al., 2018). The
other hand, as a ‘parameter of adjustment’ to achieve workers.
interrelation of these various types of risk translates into
fair and acceptable social outcomes. Secondly, it discusses how a transition to greener significant challenges for decent work. It is estimated
economies and subsequent structural changes in the that 1.2 billion jobs depend on a stable environment and
The enabling dimension can be thought of as a
economy and technology-related developments will have ecosystem services. Therefore, a healthy planet and
required input in green economic transformation and
various effects on labour markets. The chapter will then a stock of natural capital are necessary conditions for
production processes, whereby its absence can become
discuss four principles channels of change, which may decent work, productive enterprises and sustainable
a constraint for green growth. For example, unless
be observed in the literature and via country experience. livelihoods (ILO, 2018). In many instances, jobs in
investment is made to build skills, retrain and requalify
sectors characterised by informality and deficits in
Finally, the chapter discusses why investing in human decent working conditions are further undermined by
capital is not only a condition for success, but also a climate impacts due to higher vulnerability of workers
required building block in the shift to a greener economy. and communities in sectors such as agriculture.
CHAPTER 5: A JUST TRANSITION TO GREEN ECONOMIES: EMPLOYMENT & SOCIAL ISSUES 5.3
2.1 Economic losses 2.2 Impacts on labour productivity
Current resource and energy-intensive economic growth Box 5.1: Physical impacts of climate Labour productivity is usually understood to mean
models combined with the increased frequency and change on jobs the quantity of production obtained per unit of labour.
intensity of natural disasters have economic costs. Facing an average of 20 typhoons a year, the Philippines is the third This can be represented by the number of hours
Although debates about the scale economy remain most disaster-prone country in the world. Storms have been getting worked or the number of employees. Improving
stronger and more deadly in recent years. In 2014, Typhoon Hagupit,
open, there is growing locally known as Ruby, damaged and interrupted the livelihood of labour productivity has been a key focus of economic
Key term: evidence that uncontrolled 800,000 workers overnight. About 370,000 of these workers were in productivity. Resource productivity measures the
Scale economies vulnerable employment, living in poverty and accepting whatever work
Microeconomic concept that de-
climate change, scarcity was available to them.
efficiency in using natural resources when producing
scribes a reduction of production of vital resources, such as goods and services. A recent study by Stocker (2015)
costs due to an increase in the pro- In response to the impact of Typhoon Hagupit, development cooperation
duced quantity. Adapted from:
fertile land, clean air, and agencies such as the International Labour Organization (ILO) provided
examined the relationship between resource and labour
https://dictionary.cambridge.org water may have negative emergency employment and sustainable livelihood support. Emergency productivity with a conclusion that resource productivity
employment programmes guarantee a minimum wage, extend social
impacts on the economy security, health and accident insurance coverage, and ensure safety at
and employment are strongly linked. High levels of
and jobs. For example, a decade ago, the Stern Review work through the presence of on-site medical support and provision of employment tend to also be accompanied by high levels
(Stern et al., 2006) suggested that in a business-as- personal protective equipment, such as masks, helmets, gloves, boots of resource productivity (Stocker, 2015).
and protective clothing.
usual (BAU) scenario, long-term climate change would
reduce welfare by an amount equivalent to a reduction Apart from bringing much-needed cash into the affected areas, this Studies by the ILO have suggested that the resource-
in consumption per head between 5 and 20 per cent
support helps workers to develop new skills, earn a decent wage and intensive development model of the past will result
access better working conditions, including social protection coverage.
globally. Economic sectors most impacted by climate These are not just labour rights but also basic human rights, which in rising costs, loss of productivity and disruption
change include agriculture, forestry, energy, transport,
need to be taken into account in times of crisis and disaster. Such of economic activity. Estimates based on the ILO
programmes are designed and implemented in close cooperation with
manufacturing and building and construction (Planet national governments, employers’ and workers’ organizations and the Global Economic Linkages (GEL) model suggest that
Forward, 2014). Together, these employ more than half Humanitarian Country Team of the United Nations (ILO Newsroom, productivity levels in 2030 would be 2.4 per cent lower
2014).
of the global workforce. For instance, agriculture alone than today and 7.2 per cent lower by 2050 in a business-
provides jobs to 1.3 billion people, most of them working as-usual scenario. This is in line with the findings of a
poor, which is close to 40 per cent of global employment number of studies, which analyse economic damages
(ILO, 2016). workers, many of whom were forced to migrate (see because of environmental degradation and loss of basic
Box 5.1, right, for more detail). Also, the 2011 drought ecosystem services (ILO & IILS, 2012).
One billion people live and work in low-lying flood in East Africa affected 13 million people, mainly farmers
prone areas directly affected by the rising sea-level and Generally, economics has historically focused on
and pastoralists, with devastating impacts on local improving labour productivity rather than progress
flooding. The World Bank estimates that due to global incomes, jobs and livelihoods (ILO, 2016).
flooding, damage and loss of life will increase from on energy and resource productivity. For example, it
US$6 billion in 2005 to US$52 billion a year by 2050, is estimated that in Europe, over the past 50 years,
causing massive labour migration. For example, in 2014, labour productivity has grown nearly four-fold while
Typhoon Hagupit hit the Philippines, affecting 800,000 energy productivity increased by less than 25 per cent.
Achieving a circular economy will require bridging this
CHAPTER 5: A JUST TRANSITION TO GREEN ECONOMIES: EMPLOYMENT & SOCIAL ISSUES 5.4
gap between labour productivity and resource projected temperature-rise particularly in agriculture,
productivity (see Chapter 1, Annex, for more which can result in several medical conditions, including
information on circular economy). exhaustion and stroke. The report calculates that 2 per
Figure 1. Percentage of working hours lost due to heat stress under a cent of hours worked globally will be lost due to sickness
1.5°C scenario, 1995-2030 One dimension of environmental change, which from heat stress (ILO, 2018).
Note: Due to warming temperatures, some areas will become too hot to work. Under is likely to have significant consequences
a conservative scenario of warming at 1.5 degrees, 1.9 per cent of work hours will be on employment and productivity, although it
lost by 2030 (up from 1.3 per cent in 1995). Agriculture and construction will be hit the
receives little attention in policy and science,
hardest.
is the rise in global temperatures and its
2.3 Employment shifts in the transition
Source: ILO calculations based on ILOStat and HadGEM2-ES and GFDL-ESM2M
climate models. impact on the workforce. Excessive workplace towards a greener economy
heat is a well-known occupational health and A global transition towards a low-carbon and sustainable
productivity danger: high body temperature or economy entails both positive and negative impacts on
dehydration causes heat exhaustion, heat stroke employment. Generally, output and employment in low-
and in extreme cases, death. A worker’s natural carbon industries and services will grow, while energy
protection is to slow down work or limit working and resource-intensive sectors, on the other hand, are
hours, which reduces productivity, economic likely to stagnate or contract. Yet, evidence suggests
output, pay and family income (Kjellstrom et overall job growth resulting from the transition process
al., 2016). The IPCC’s 5th Assessment Report (ILO, 2016).
confirmed that labour productivity impacts could
result in output reductions in affected sectors From a conceptual perspective, employment will be
exceeding 20 per cent during the second half of affected in four different ways as green economy policies
the century. Overall, the global economic cost reorient the economy toward greater environmental
of reduced productivity may be more than US$2 sustainability.
trillion by 2030 (Kjellstrom et al., 2016). As the
IPCC report suggests, “Particularly at risk are Firstly, the expansion of greener products, services, and
agricultural and construction workers as well infrastructure will translate into higher labour demand
as children, homeless people, the elderly, and across many sectors of the economy, thereby leading to
women who have to walk long hours to collect the creation of new jobs (ILO, 2016). Examples include:
water.” (IPCC 2014, p.71) Beyond productivity jobs in renewable energy and energy efficiency (in
losses, there are also impacts on human health. manufacturing, transportation, building construction and
These effects are dominated by malnutrition, operations); organic agriculture; various employment-
diarrhoea, malaria and heat-related cardio- intensive adaptation measures intended to protect
respiratory disease. A more recent study by the and restore ecosystems and biodiversity; and in
ILO found that heat stress would increase with
CHAPTER 5: A JUST TRANSITION TO GREEN ECONOMIES: EMPLOYMENT & SOCIAL ISSUES 5.5
infrastructure and green (public) works, intended to As is the case with job creation, there are indirect and possible through the pursuit of climate policies (ILO &
adapt to climate impacts and build resilience. induced effects. IILS, 2012). Most of the studies indicate net employment
gains of 0.5–2 per cent, or 15–60 million additional jobs
Improving rural infrastructure, through the development Finally, many, and perhaps most, existing jobs (such as globally.
of irrigation schemes, flood prevention measures, plumbers, electricians, metal workers, and construction
soil stabilization, reforestation works, rural transport workers) will simply be transformed and redefined as A more recent study by the ILO examines the potential
maintenance and improved land tenure may enhance day-to-day workplace practices, skill sets, work methods jobs implications of pursuing the goal of the 2015 Paris
agricultural productivity and contribute to the world’s and job profiles are greened. For instance, plumbers agreement on climate change to limit global temperature
food supply and local energy production. In addition and electricians working in the ‘brown economy’ can, in increase (ILO, 2018). The report finds that with the right
to direct jobs are those in the supply chain (indirect principle, be reoriented to carry out similar work in the policies to promote a greener economy in place, 24
jobs). As the incomes generated are spent across the green economy. Automobile workers will produce more million new jobs will be created globally by 2030. In the
economy, they create further employment (induced fuel-efficient (or electric) cars. Farmers will apply more process of limiting global warming to 2 degrees Celsius,
jobs). climate-appropriate agricultural methods, and therefore the report estimates that the jobs created will more than
have a lesser impact upon natural capital such as fresh offset job losses of up to 6 million, and generate a net
Secondly, some existing jobs will be replaced as a result water, or a lesser impact upon global greenhouse gas gain of 18 million jobs globally.
of shifts in the economy from less to more efficient, emissions.
from high-carbon to low-carbon, and from more to The report further projects that, at the regional level,
less polluting technologies, processes, and products. Predictions of positive net effects are often based on changes in the production and use of energy will lead
Examples include a shift from truck-based transportation assumptions of perfect labour markets, where workers to a net job creation in the Americas, Asia-Pacific, and
to rail, from internal combustion engine manufacturing are mobile between jobs and locations and where Europe, representing some 3 million, 14 million, and 2
to electric vehicle production, or from landfilling to there is sufficient supply of labour with the necessary million jobs respectively. However, regional differences
recycling and refurbishing. These shifts can be gradual skills. But this is not the case in the real world. In reality, do exist:, a dependence on fossil fuel and mining may
or sudden, and will likely take place both within and workers are not always mobile and do not necessarily lead to net job losses in the Middle East (-0.48 per cent)
across different industries. have the right skills. Without policies to address these and Africa (-0.04 per cent), if current trends continue
issues, net employment effects of the transition to a (see also Figure 2, overleaf).
Thirdly, certain jobs may be eliminated, phased out green economy may be negative.
or massively reduced in numbers, without direct The energy sector stands out with rising investment
replacement. This may happen where polluting and and falling costs that have been the drivers behind an
energy- and materials-intensive economic activities expansion of renewables, with wind power and solar PV
are reduced or phased out entirely. The continuation of
2.4 Job gains and substitutions being the most dynamic sectors. Global employment in
large-scale mining and the burning of coal, in particular, Most studies that have investigated the net impact on the renewables energy sector has grown substantially in
are both incompatible towards a stable climate. Greater employment of environmental policy measures suggest
energy, materials, and water efficiency (along with it is positive. A review of 30 studies (covering individual
boosts in recycling of materials and reusing of products) countries and economic regions) finds that meaningful
could lead to substantial job losses in the primary sector. employment gains have either been achieved or are
CHAPTER 5: A JUST TRANSITION TO GREEN ECONOMIES: EMPLOYMENT & SOCIAL ISSUES 5.6
Figure 2 – Employment in a green energy scenario, 2030, compared to BAU, by recent years; reaching an estimated 8.1 low-impact (organic) farming methods tend to be more
region (ILO calculations, based on Exiobase and IEA scenarios (ILO, 2018)) million jobs1 in 2015 (IRENA, 2016). labour-intensive than conventional farming, opening
an opportunity for new workers to be absorbed into
Most renewable energy employment agricultural jobs at least in the short to medium term.
is found in China, Brazil, the United At the same time, agriculture and forestry also open
States, India, and members of the EU. up opportunities to build on traditional knowledge and
It is important to note that this growth empower communities that face several socio-economic
has, to date, supplemented jobs in the vulnerabilities, including indigenous and tribal peoples.
fossil fuel sector, due to the additional For example, as part of a global assessment, Herren
energy needs of emerging economies, et al. (2011), ran a macroeconomic model simulating
rather than replacing them. This may green investments in
well change if GHG emissions are cut as Key term: the agriculture sector
strongly as called for by climate science, Macroeconomic model
and concluded that the
in other words, if there is a comprehensive Analytical tool describing the be-
transition to sustainable
haviour and operation of the ag-
transition from fossil fuels to renewables gregate economy within a country agriculture could create
(and to energy efficiency) (UNFCCC, or a region. Adapted from: https://
over 200 million full-time
en.wikipedia.org
2016) jobs across the entire food
The potential for jobs creation is production system by 2050. Another study by (Morison
not confined to the energy sector. et al., 2005), with a sample of 1,144 organic farms in the
Agriculture, the biggest employer in United Kingdom and the Republic of Ireland, concluded
the world, offers many opportunities that organic farms employ 135 per cent more full-time
both in the context of mitigation and equivalent jobs per farm than conventional farms
adaptation to climate change, through
climate smart agriculture. Evidence
from various countries 2.5 Job transformation and redefinition
Key term: strongly suggests that
Climate smart The majority of jobs will neither be lost nor newly created
agriculture
‘Climate smart agriculture’ (CSA)
but redefined in terms of their occupational qualifications
1 The estimates reflect annual
incorporates a combination of data collection efforts based on a and profiles. This highlights that the greening of
traditional and modern techniques,
which is one of the most cited and
wide range of sources, including economies through public and private investment in
government agencies, industry the context of sustainable development and poverty
promoted techniques aimed at
mitigating, and adapting to, climate and NGO studies, academic
reports, and interviews with eradication will rely on a mix of macroeconomic,
change. See FAO: Climate Smart
Agriculture: Sourcebook (Rome, experts. Inevitably, the underlying
2013). methodologies vary, however, and
data gaps remain.
CHAPTER 5: A JUST TRANSITION TO GREEN ECONOMIES: EMPLOYMENT & SOCIAL ISSUES 5.7
industrial, sectoral, labour market, and skills policies 2.6 Job losses
(ILO, 2016).
Box 5.2: Energy efficiency in It is important to note that changes due to greening
One example is the buildings and construction sector, initiatives and climate change policies make up only
which is already experiencing job transformations on buildings in Europe and the United some of the several factors that can lead to job losses. In
a large scale. Buildings are among the biggest users States fact, to date, greening initiatives for example has actually
of energy, water, and materials, and they are the single In the EU, an assessment of the potential impacts of the 2010 been a minor factor (ILO and IILS, 2012). The principal
largest emitter of GHGs. the same time, the sector has Energy Performance of Buildings Directive for the period 2011– causes of declining employment in industries such
2050 concluded that an accelerated pace of renovation could
an enormous potential to improve energy efficiency, generate 0.5–1.1 million jobs annually (Buildings Performance as mining, fossil energy, or iron and steel have been
which lends it a leading role in the green transition (see Institute Europe, 2011). A US study found that energy efficiency relative; absolute price changes, increasing automation,
retrofits of pre-1980 building stock could reduce electricity use
also Box 5.2). Worldwide, building construction employs by 30 per cent and create more than 3.3 million cumulative job- and rising labour productivity have been occurring over
at least 110 million workers in formal jobs, plus an years of employment (Deutsche Bank Climate Change Advisors & several decades. For example, hard coal mining in
unknown but much larger number of informal labourers, Rockefeller Foundation, 2012).
France, Germany, Poland and the UK simply became
including migrant workers (ILO, 2016). The renovation of too costly to be profitable (see Box 5.3).
existing structures and the construction of new energy-
efficient buildings will require a significant number of An expansion of green economy and climate policies
workers with additional new skills in green technology energy-related emissions (IEA, 2014). China’s 13th Five- will need to bring about a fundamental change in the
practices to realize the large potential of economic Year Plan for 2016-2020 seeks a further 18 per cent global energy mix in coming years and decades. The
and employment benefits. For example, the benefits reduction in carbon intensity compared with 2015 levels result will be further job loss in the fossil fuel sector—in
of enhancing skills in plumbing for solar water heater by 2020 (Climate Home, 2016). These measures point to coal mining, exploration and production of oil and gas,
installation, masonry for using alternative construction a growing realization that decoupling economic growth and among fossil fuel-powered power plants. Coal, as
materials (such as compressed earth blocks), and the from pollution is possible the dirtiest and most CO2-intensive fuel, will need to
installation of rooftop photovoltaic panels In addition, Key term: while creating jobs along bear the brunt of the changes to come along with the
building renovation will not only directly create and Decoupling
the way. To achieve high- implementation of the Paris Agreement (see Box 5.3,
The separation of the rate of re-
transform jobs in the construction sector, but also in source productivity from the eco- performance efficiency overleaf).
supplier industries that produce insulation materials and nomic growth rate, meaning that
goals for buildings, The experiences of countries undergoing job retention in
more can be achieved with less
energy efficiency equipment and materials, as well as resources. Adapted from: http:// working conditions the coal sector highlight obstacles but also encouraging
in energy services requiring additional skills (Syndex, S. www.resourcepanel.org and skill levels need policy lessons.
Partner & WMP, 2009; Trabish, 2011). to be improved for the
construction sector to create decent, well-paying jobs
Employment dynamics in the building and construction
(ILO, 2016). 2.7 Job quality
sector are mainly driven by government incentives
and policies. China achieved significant improvement
As noted by the ILO (2016), a dimension that is equally
in energy efficiency leading to important reductions in
important as the number of jobs created, lost, or
CHAPTER 5: A JUST TRANSITION TO GREEN ECONOMIES: EMPLOYMENT & SOCIAL ISSUES 5.8
such risks is the shifting towards renewable energy
which would avoid many of the severe health dangers
Box 5.3: Transition in the coal mining lesson that emerges is that a successful transition takes time, a strong
vision of the future, and adequate resources. Worker co-determination (as
associated with coal mining, even though some new
industry: Germany part of a cooperative tripartite structure) has been an important factor in hazards need particular attention. For example, workers
the coal sector, facilitating solutions that embrace a range of labour market producing solar PV panels are exposed to a number
The case of the German coal mining industry underlines the need for well policies.
planned, well designed and socially fair transition strategies, including of toxic substances and electrical hazards; thin-film
active labour market policies, social protection, retraining efforts, and For instance, for thousands of coal workers an early retirement plan was and emerging nanotech-based solar technologies may
economic diversification of regions most dependent on the coal industry. developed by the state government of North Rhine-Westphalia (NRW) in
Total employment in Germany’s coal mining industry has dropped from 1972, with transition payments for up to 5 years, to bridge the time until prompt health and safety-related concerns that will
about 753,000 in the late 1950s to about 33,500 in 2014, an astounding workers became eligible for pension payments. For younger workers, need to be addressed proactively. (SVTC, 2009 & 2014;
96 per cent decline. From the 1950s to the 1980s, automation eliminated efforts were undertaken to find other jobs, with the help of personnel
jobs even while production held roughly steady. But the plunge in development centres and agencies specializing in employment promotion EASHW, 2011).
production from the 1990s and beyond accelerated job loss (Statistik der and training. As a result, in
Kohlewirtschaft, 2015). establishing higher-education
Key term: institutions and technology
Knowledge-based
Galgóczi (2014) examines the transformation of the Ruhr region, Germany’s economy
centres, the region did manage
to lay the foundations of a
2.8 Drivers of change: Technology and
prime hard coal-producing area, for general lessons in managing the
transition challenges inherent in such a steep drop in coal employment.
Economy that heavily relies on
knowledge and information as cat-
knowledge-based economy other factors
Even though resource depletion, automation, and rising competition from as an alternative to the coal-
alysts for growth and productivity. and steel-centred economy
imports were the main driving factors, the lessons of dealing with this crisis Adapted from: https://www.oecd. (UNFCCC, 2016).
Transitions towards a greener economy are driven by a
are useful to consider in the context of climate-driven transitions. A key org variety of factors. Some drivers relate to environmental
and resource constraints that gradually lead to the
integration of such dimensions in economic and growth
policies. Other drivers are related to innovation and
transformed, concerns the quality of employment. Jobs by migrant workers who lack social protection. There are technological developments that enable economic
that do not offer decent work today, may or may not often complex subcontracting arrangements, particularly growth to continue while the pace and scale of
become more decent or among informal workers, which makes for extremely environmental impacts are minimised. Yet other drivers
Key term: greener with the structural hazardous employment conditions (Poschen, 2015). are purely linked to policy goals and objectives that aim
Decent work
Decent work means opportunities transformation. Again, to redirect investment and growth trajectories towards
policies are critical in this The ILO (2016) also notes that a shift in economic
for everyone to get work that is pro- greater environmental sustainability.
ductive and delivers a fair income,
respect. For instance, practises will affect a variety of areas linked to
security in the workplace and social
protection for families, better pros- construction workers employment, including social protection, safe working Among these drivers, technology plays a central role
pects for personal development
generally face poor conditions, workers rights, and the ability of workers’ in the transition to greener and more resource efficient
and social integration. Adapted
working conditions that to assume a meaningful voice in decision-making. economies (please refer to chapter 4 for a detailed
from https://un.org
are among the most Generally, research indicates that effects will be positive. discussion on the role of innovation and technological
hazardous in terms of work accidents and occupational For example, occupational health and safety risks tend change for a green economy). Digitally enabled
diseases, even in the formal sector. Jobs are often to be lower with a move towards a low-carbon economy automation and artificial intelligence (AI) bring
temporary rather than permanent and frequently filled (Poschen, 2015; Renner et al., 2008). An example of significant benefits in the form of new jobs and increased
CHAPTER 5: A JUST TRANSITION TO GREEN ECONOMIES: EMPLOYMENT & SOCIAL ISSUES 5.9
productivity (McKinsey technology can and will be substituted for human capital been labelled “the Fourth
Key term: Key term:
Digitally-enabled Global Institute, 2017). in the transition to a greener economy. The nature and Techno-pessimism Industrial Revolution,”
automation However, the shift to a scale of the technological development and its impact The overestimation of security (Schwab, 2015) there is an
Digital transformation process threats and risks associated with
which describes the incorporation new economy also calls on employment have been studied for many decades. technological developments. accelerated automation of
of digital innovation and supporting for large-scale reskilling Adapted from https://scholar.har- occupations.
infrastructure within existing busi-
and a socially responsible A common assumption has long been, for the right or vard.edu
ness processes with the purpose of
increasing efficiency. Adapted from transition, which poses the wrong, that technological progress, by gradually A new dimension in
https://www.techradar.com/news/
challenges to employers, leading to a substitution of human labour by machines, the debate on technology and jobs, are environment-
what-is-digital-business-automation will translate into an overall loss in employment. A related technological innovations and their impact on
employees, and policy
makers alike. Among review of the literature (ILO ,2016), reveals that a simple employment. This question may be approached through
Key term: these challenges is the answer does not exist.. The empirical evidence finds that a variety of angles. This chapter considers two aspects:
Artificial intelligence
increased labour market impacts vary, depending on the waves of technological job displacement and job creation.
Simulated intelligence in machines
which are designed to think like polarisation, where low change (see also chapter 4). Based on an extensive
human beings while rationally literature review on technological progress and In South Africa, for example, some 70,000 jobs in the
taking the most plausible actions to and middle-skill jobs are electricity-power generation sector were lost between
achieve a specific target. Adapted more likely susceptible to employment, Nübler (2017) observes that technological
from https://www.investopedia.com change is inevitably a dynamic process, which 1980 and 2000, at the same time electricity generation
automation while digital, increased by more than 60 per cent. Similarly, in the
entrepreneurial skills will involves: (a) both job destruction and creation; and (b)
transforming existing jobs, particularly in how work is European Union, an estimated 300,000 jobs in the
Key term: be in high demand in electricity-power generation sector were cut between
Labour market the labour market of the organized, supporting Schumpeter’s notion of ‘creative
polorization destruction’ (Schumpeter, 1942). 1997 and 2004 (ILO & IILS, 2012). Overall, evidence
Simultaneous increase in high- future. points to the fact that technological innovations have
skilled and low-skilled jobs com-
Digitalisation affects
bined with a decreasing share of Nübler (2017) argues that debates on the impact of played a much more significant role as a driver of job
employment in middle-skilled occu-
existing organisational and technology on jobs, which started as early as 1930 displacement than green-economy-relevant policies (ILO
pations. Adapted from http://blogs.
worldbank.org management structures in when John Maynard Keynes introduced the concept & IILS, 2012).
companies and touches of technological unemployment, are still relevant
today. This is owing to the fact that “unemployment, With regard to job creation, there is also evidence to
on issues related to legal responsibility, data protection suggest that innovation in the environmental sector has
and work safety rules. due to our discovery of means of economising the
use of labour… is…outrunning the pace at which we stimulated job creation. For example, in the case of the
From the perspective of employment, technological can find new uses for labour,” (Keynes, 1930, quoted European Union, ‘eco-industry’ companies were found
change raises many questions that have yet to be in Nübler, 2017) – still persists today. She concludes to employ over 4.2 million people in 2013, a figure well
answered: The first concerns its effect on employment, that historical experience to date tends to discredit above car manufacturing, textile or chemical industries.
of course. Another question relates to its implications arguments of techno-pessimism when it comes to the
considering substitutability with other forms of capital. overall employment outcome. The question that arises,
In particular, a key question that arises is to what extent subsequently, is whether, in the context of what has
CHAPTER 5: A JUST TRANSITION TO GREEN ECONOMIES: EMPLOYMENT & SOCIAL ISSUES 5.10
3. Investing in human capital goods and services sectors, whereas skill shortages or workers and communities that depend on fossil fuels
inadequacy can hamper such expansion (ILO, 2016). in in the United States. They concluded that a rough
for a just transition to a greener high-end estimate for such a programme would
Second, the greening of economies will engender both
economy job creation and job losses, although most studies point
require a relatively modest US$600 million per year, to
pay for income, retraining and relocation support for
The concept of human capital has become an accepted to a net job (ILO & IILS, 2012). However, the picture is workers facing retrenchments; pension guarantees for
concept among economists following early writings by much more complex as a result of factors due to delays employees in affected industries; and effective transition
authors such as Gary Becker (2013). Human capital in time and geographical shifts of industries - new green programs for communities depending on fossil fuels
describes the stock of knowledge and attributes, jobs are not necessarily created where other work is (Pollin & Callaci, 2016).
including creativity, that materialize in the ability to lost, or maybe provided right when new employment
perform labour in order to generate economic value. It opportunities may be required. Responding to the need to identify and create
is also referred to as the stock of skills possessed by the appropriate and integrated solutions for a green
In addition, it is essential to look at the underlying transition, the International Labour Organization (ILO)
labour force encompassing the notion of investments in assumptions that scientific studies employ. Some
people (e.g., education, training, health), which increase has formulated a guiding framework for a just transition,
economic models assume perfect labour market which will be discussed below.
an individual’s productivity (Goldin, 2016). dynamics whereby labour mobility enables those who
lose jobs to immediately enter occupations in growing
green sectors. In reality, transitions in labour markets
3.1 Conceptualising Human Capital in the are more complex than economic models make appear.
3.2 Policies for a just transition
Inclusive Green Economy Environmental Goods and services industries that might A green economy transition implies important structural
be expanding do not necessarily require the same transformations that will affect national economies,
In the context of the green economy transition, two qualifications as declining, ‘brown’ industries, and enterprises, foreign and domestic workers and their
observations can be made. First, the transition to green workers who have lost jobs may have neither the skills communities, thereby inherently creating (new) winners,
economies affects labour as an input to production, nor the means to take up new job opportunities in new but also potential losers. To respond to potential
by way of a change in aggregate demand that leads locations. adverse impacts of the green economy transition on
to more demand for green products. This will require
some, the notion of a ‘just transition’ aims to ensure that
enterprises and a labour force to obtain the right skills Investing in human capital and social policies is
the transition is fair and maximizes opportunities for
and qualifications to deliver such goods and services. essential to bridge this disconnects. Transition policies
economic prosperity, social justice, rights, and social
As discussed in the sub-section on training and skills can support workers and enable them to take advantage
protection for all, and leaves no one behind.
development below, the availability of a skilled workforce of new jobs created. That calls for coordinated and
contributes to the expansion of the environmental integrated approach to a just green transition, which At the International Labour Conference in 2013,
includes social protection measures. This, of course, governments, workers’ and employers’ organizations
relies on appropriate planning and investment of discussed and adopted the key guiding principles for
financial resources. For example, Pollin and Callaci a just transition towards environmentally sustainable
(2016) have estimated costs of a programme to support economies and societies (International Labour
CHAPTER 5: A JUST TRANSITION TO GREEN ECONOMIES: EMPLOYMENT & SOCIAL ISSUES 5.11
tripartite meeting of experts produced draft guidelines to labour market restructuring, communities affected by
for a just transition towards environmentally sustainable climate change and other environmental disasters, and
Box 5.4: Guidelines for a just economies and societies for all, with the ILO Governing population groups disadvantaged by green policies
transition Body successfully adopting a decision on the guidelines (ILO, 2016). According to the ILO (2016), labour market
in November 2015 (ILO Governing Body, 2015). The policies are comprised of regulations and policies
Policy coherence and institutional arrangements for mainstreaming
sustainable development and ensuring stakeholder dialogue and Guidelines cover a broad range of policy areas, as also that influence labour demand and supply, and the
coordination between policy fields; shown in Box 5.4, above. interaction between the two. These regulations and
• Establishing mechanisms for social dialogue throughout policies influence the conditions of the labour market,
policy-making processes at all levels;
The concept of a just transition has been particularly upon which the employment effects of the transition
prominent in the context of global negotiations and to a low-carbon economy depend. Whereas ‘passive’
• Employment-centred macroeconomic and growth policies;
policy addressing climate change. The Paris Agreement labour market policies are concerned with the provision
• Environmental regulations in targeted industries and sectors; on Climate Change adopted in December 2015 of replacement income during periods of transition, i.e.
• Creating an enabling environment for sustainable and recognizes “the imperative of a just transition of the joblessness or the search for employment, ‘active’ labour
greener enterprises; workforce and the creation of decent work and quality market policies refer to labour market integration through
• Skills development to ensure adequate skills at all levels to jobs in accordance with nationally defined development demand- or supply-side measures (Auer et al., 2008).
promote the greening of the economy; priorities”. In addition, the 21st Conference of the Parties Active labour market policies encompass five broad
• Occupational safety and health policies to protect workers (COP21) in Paris, adopted a work programme on the types of measures:
from occupational hazards and risks; impact of the implementation of response measures (to
• Social protection policies to enhance resilience and climate change), comprising two areas: (1) economic (i) Training schemes that consist of vocational and
safeguard workers from the negative; impacts of climate change, diversification and transformation; and (2) just transition on-the-job programmes that target the long-term
economic restructuring and resource constraints;
of the workforce, and the creation of decent work and unemployed, laid-off workers, youth and other
• Labour market policies that actively pursue job creation, limit quality jobs (UNFCCC, 2018). vulnerable groups along with special incentives for
jobs loss and ensure that adjustments related to greening policies
are well managed.
apprenticeships;
In the sub-sections below, a few employment and social
(ILO, 2016) policies based on the ILO Guidelines are discussed with (ii) Job subsidies, which include measures to
illustrative country applications (please note that material protect jobs, such as work-sharing schemes and
not cited specifically is based upon (ILO, 2016). interventions that promote hiring, including social
security exemptions and one-off payments for hiring
long-term unemployed;
Labour market policies
(iii) Public employment programmes that cover not only
Conference, 2013). The conclusions and resolutions on Labour market policies are critical to ensure that the traditional public works programmes, but also the
sustainable development, decent work and green jobs, employment effects of the transition to climate-resilient
adopted by the Conference, lead to a framework that economies are positive for everyone: the workers
could be used by policy-makers. In October 2015, a negatively affected by green economy policies linked
CHAPTER 5: A JUST TRANSITION TO GREEN ECONOMIES: EMPLOYMENT & SOCIAL ISSUES 5.12
new generation of public employment schemes and life). Question and answer sessions were then provided construction and maintenance industry. Around 95 per
employment guarantees; between industry specialists and pupils as well as cent of car industry skills are transferable, which shows
information events within the local schools. Another that building upon existing human capital can be very
(iv) Entrepreneurship incentives that typically consists trend is the emergence of web job platforms for green successful in developing new industries. In this case,
of a combination of entrepreneurship training and industries, such as the renewable energy industry the retraining helped foster the development of a cluster
microcredit; and platform. of industrial maintenance industries in the region (ILO,
(v) Job search 2016).
Key term: Training schemes aim at improving employability and
Microcredit assistance and other reducing skill mismatches between the skills of workers Job subsidies aim at supporting labour demand by
Small financial loans granted to
impoverished borrowers who strive
intermediation services (supply-side) and the requirements of the job market. preventing lay-offs or encouraging hiring. They can be
to start their own business. Adapted that are provided by Whereas such training schemes are important, as they effective in encouraging green job creation in locations
from http://www.businessdictionary.
com
public and private build the human capital required for the transition to be with high levels of unemployment and/or low levels of
employment agencies. successful they must be matched by appropriate short- activity. They are, however, expensive and can have
(ILO, 2016) run support schemes that can support workers in times deadweight/substitution effects.
of crisis (such as passive employment schemes). This
Job search assistance and job counselling aim at may also mean that short-term skill gaps are difficult to Key term: Typical examples of
improving the match between demand and supply address. Whereas longer-term planning would, of course
Deadweight effects those effects include
Cost to society which arises due
of labour and preventing long-term unemployment. be desirable, forecasting job skills which will be needed to an inefficient use of resources. cuts to social security
They are relatively cost-effective, but require efficient in the future is challenging.
Adapted from https://www.investo- contributions for green
pedia.com
employment services, are difficult to implement in times start-ups.
of crisis and are more suitable for formal jobs. Public Generally, however, longer-term trends like an economy-
wide transition from fossil fuels can already be Entrepreneurship incentives aim to promote
employment services (PES) can inform and stimulate entrepreneurship as a way out of under- or
interest in green careers among future workers and the anticipated by regulators and supported. For example,
a number of training centres are delivering vocational un-employment. They are an effective means of targeting
unemployed by providing information on vocational poor, vulnerable groups, however only a minority of
training and study routes, businesses and professions training for workers in targeted green industries, such as
the China Wind Power Center. Dismissed workers from new enterprises are usually successful (Patel, 2015).
in green sectors, as demonstrated by the project In the United States, a growing number of business
“Meine Energie hat Zukunft” (My energy has a future) in disappearing industries are retrained in order to place
them in green industries. This retraining is happening incubators are specifically designed for green start-ups.
Germany [available online]. In this project, the PES of For example, the Green
the German town Bielefeld joined forces with a network at the initiative of local public employment services in
cooperation with local businesses. This was also the Exchange in Chicago
of 120 companies, higher education institutions and Key term:
provides retail, office
learning providers, as well as the Association of German case of the Le Mans region in France where workers, Business incubator
Organisation that aims at boosting
Engineers to lead experiments and workshops on solar who were dismissed from the declining car industry, the growth of start-ups and early
energy, designing virtual wind farms, as well as taster were retrained as mechanics and electro-mechanics stage companies, i.e. through sup-
porting access to capital. Adapted
events in physics (offering an insight into university - so that they could work in the newly created wind from https://www.entrepreneur.com
CHAPTER 5: A JUST TRANSITION TO GREEN ECONOMIES: EMPLOYMENT & SOCIAL ISSUES 5.13
and live-work space as well as a variety of marketing of green technologies through technical education and environment ministries and vice versa, education and
services for green businesses. vocational training (ILO, 2016). training institutions are typically not involved in shaping
climate policies. Safety and health issues are typically
Public Employment Programmes aim to provide income addressed separately, as well.
to the poor/vulnerable while increasing employability Training and skills development
and supporting labour demand by creating direct jobs. Besides the need to ensure that enough labour market
These programmes can be effective in situations of Skill shortages already pose a major problem for the entrants acquire the skills needed in the economy
effective post-crisis, disaster, and measures linked to transition to greener, climate-compatible economies and of tomorrow, retraining of existing workers provides
season-specific risks, to protect incomes and prevent thus for job creation. Moreover, this is a problem that is another challenge. Retraining may be difficult for older
poverty. As such, Public Employment Programmes offer likely to grow in the coming years. Poschen (2015) warns workers and especially for low-skilled workers, or also
indirect benefits to households, but they do not provide that with a lack of skilled and motivated workers in green migrant workers (again linked to skill-level or language),
long-term employment. Green works refer to either growth sectors, hopes for creating a climate-compatible due to their challenge to ‘skill-up’ and compete for new
both infrastructure and related employment-intensive economy may not materialize. Shortages are the result jobs. Another challenge is linked to spatial shifts, in that
approaches that have direct environmental benefits or as of a number of factors, including: underestimation of the green economy jobs may be created in locations very
a response to a specific environmental context, including pace at which certain green sectors grow; a general different from those suffering job losses.
changes in climate and extreme weather events. They shortage of scientists and engineers; a low reputation
focus on forestry, irrigation, soil and water conservation or limited attractiveness of some economic sectors; and National education and training efforts therefore need
and flood protection. shortages of teachers and trainers proficient in fast- to be linked with a regional (development) approach to
growing sectors such as renewable energy and energy ensure a just transition policy. Disadvantaged workers
The transition to low-carbon and climate-resilient efficiency (Strietska-Ilina et al., 2011). and communities require targeted assistance, which
economies and societies is best conceived as a can encompass the integration of skills building,
driver of structural economic change. This process of Strietska-Ilina et al. (2011) explain that “the challenge for vocational training and retraining into regional
structural transformation is likely to involve imbalances skills development policy is to integrate environmental economic development strategies. This also applies
in the number and types of jobs available. Labour awareness and the right technical training for green to larger socio-cultural perceptions and systems of
market policies play an active role in addressing these jobs into education and training provision”. Marrying thought: For instance, with regard to agriculture and
imbalances and ensuring a just transition for all. They these two objectives is essential, but difficult. Country forestry, indigenous peoples’ traditional knowledge
help workers and employers to make the transition with studies compiled by the global report on skills for green is increasingly being recognized for effective climate
a smooth reallocation of jobs revealed that while coordination between climate/ action and livelihood security, but non-recognition of
Key term: workers from declining environment and skills policies can be comprehensive traditional skills continue to be an important challenge.
Eco-innovation
Innovative business approaches to growing firms/sectors, in some country cases, it is fragmented or practically
that foster sustainability along the to reduce the adjustment non-existent in others. One observation made was a lack A number of efforts have targeted the renewable energy
entire life cycle of a product while
costs for displaced of cross-ministerial coordination (for more information sector, motivated by the desire to overcome problems
promoting a company’s competi-
tiveness and overall performance. workers, and to foster eco- on institutional challenges and reform, see Ch.6). linked to the crises in older industries or a lack of
Adapted from: https://www.unenvi-
innovation and diffusion Efforts by educational authorities to anticipate, identify, economic diversification. Examples include the United
ronment.org
and provide skills do not typically include inputs from States, where wind energy development has been
CHAPTER 5: A JUST TRANSITION TO GREEN ECONOMIES: EMPLOYMENT & SOCIAL ISSUES 5.14
seen as a way to inject new life into many abandoned are often inadequate (ILO, sectors such as coal mining, fossil fuel energy
Key term:
“rustbelt” industrial facilities in Pennsylvania and Ohio, Informal employment 2016b). production, industry that currently feature a low-level of
though with somewhat mixed results. Employment in the informal sector energy efficiency, while new green low-carbon sectors
Informality, is common
includes all jobs in informal sector
may benefit. In these cases, formulating accompanying
enterprises or all persons who,
Critical to the success of education and training efforts during a given reference period,
in the majority of the policies through social protection, including
is effective coordination and constructive dialogue sectors most affected by
were employed in at least one infor-
unemployment insurance and benefits, social security
mal sector enterprise, irrespective
between all actors, including the government, trade climate change impacts,
of their status in employment and portability, skills training and upgrading, workforce
unions, and employers. Whereas countries’ education such as agriculture,
whether it was their main or a sec-
redeployment and other appropriate measures to
and training systems in different countries face varying ondary job. Adapted from https://
fisheries, forestry or
www.ilo.org support enterprises
challenges and some may incorporate climate and tourism. Migrant workers Key term: and workers in sectors
environmental considerations into training programmes are overwhelmingly Workforce redeployment
negatively impacted by
more readily than others, a multi-layer approach, with represented in these sectors, as are low-skilled national The act or strategy of reassigning
the transition should be
employees to a new position, for
action taking place at the levels of enterprise, industry, workers, and vulnerable groups, such as indigenous example in another geographical part of the policy mix.
nation and region, is essential for success. and tribal peoples, which makes them exposed to location, within a different work unit
or by changing tasks and responsi-
discrimination and exploitation. This is also a very bilities. Adapted from: Another example where
frequent phenomena in economic sectors that are https://www.ofm.wa.gov social protection policy
Social protection and security essential to achieve a low-carbon development, such is instrumental is in
as waste-management and recycling, construction and the field of fossil fuel
Social protection constitutes one of the pillars of a
small-scale industries in all industrial sectors. Thus, subsidy reform. According to ILO (2016) estimations,
just transition framework. Only around one quarter of
providing access to social protection measures to between 2010 and 2015 overall, 100 governments in
the world’s population has adequate social security
these workers should be an integral part of any climate 78 low-income and 22 high-income countries reduced
coverage and more than half do not have any coverage
change policy. or removed subsidies, predominately on fuel, but also
at all. A majority of the world’s economically active
on electricity, food and agriculture. These adjustment
population do not benefit The fifth IPCC Report (2014) highlights the importance
Key term:
measures were implemented at a time when food and
from any protection in of assessing the synergies between social protection
Economically active energy prices were hovering near record highs; if basic
According to the definitions of the cases of unemployment, policies, social development strategies, disaster risk subsidies are withdrawn from beneficiaries without
International Labour Organisation work-related injury, or reduction strategies and climate policies. In addition,
(ILO) for the purposes of the labour adequate social protection mechanisms in place, this
market statistics people are clas- maternity. Nearly half of all there is a growing body of evidence that linking social can lead to a situation in which food and energy become
sified as employed, unemployed people over pensionable protection and climate change policies plays a double
and economically inactive. The unaffordable for many households, in particular, but not
age do not receive a role of enhancing the resilience of workers and their
economically active population is only, the poorest ones.
the sum of employed and unem- pension, and for those families in times of climate disasters and facilitating the
ployed persons. Inactive persons
are those who, during the reference
who do, pension levels ability to cope with climate consequences. In low and middle-income countries, public and private
week, were neither employed nor financing that supports national public employment
unemployed. Adapted from https:// In addition, mitigation policies may have a negative schemes are not only extending the social protection
ec.europa.eu
impact on businesses and workers in highly emitting
CHAPTER 5: A JUST TRANSITION TO GREEN ECONOMIES: EMPLOYMENT & SOCIAL ISSUES 5.15
floor, but in some cases, they are also contributing to result, where negative to coordination of the implementation of a specific policy,
Key term:
restoring and protecting the productive capacity of Tripartism socio-economic impacts to reaching binding agreements.
lands, building resilient infrastructure, and at the same Refers to a form of economic policy are addressed;
time, creating livelihood and income security for the most
which relies on tripartite collabo- It can be noted that for social dialogue to be effective,
ration between employers, unions
vulnerable often particular at risk of being impacted by (iv) Taxing natural
and the government. Adapted from:
two elements should be developed (ILO, 2016): 1)
climate change. Investment in physical, financial, natural https://en.wikipedia.org resource extraction offers providing technical capacity and adequately updated
and social capital is not only necessary, but also has a great potential for many information to stakeholders taking part in the dialogue
significant potential to contribute to climate resilience developing countries. process; and 2) ensuring that consultations take place
and disaster risk management. Norway’s approach of taxing oil profits and storing on an on-going basis.
To design successful climate related social protection the revenues in the Government Pension Fund
Global is perhaps the best-known case (see Chapter According to the Guidelines for a Just Transition (ILO,
systems, it should be considered that: 2015), governments should actively promote and
8, Section 1.2.2).
(i) Developing a social protection system takes a long engage in social dialogue to discuss the best means to
time, particularly in countries where institutional implement social, economic and environmental goals.
capacity is limited. Therefore, mitigation actions with Consultation and social dialogue The Guidelines also recommend for social partners
potential social impact, “to promote active participation in social dialogue
Key term: Consultation and social dialogue among those who are at enterprise, sectoral and national levels to assess
should only be taken once
Institutional capacity most affected by climate change impacts and policies opportunities and resolve challenges posed by the
Generally referring to the the potential affected
that attempt to tackle these impacts are at the core of transition” (p.10).
capability of institutions to perform population are protected
effectively and efficiently, for in- the just transition framework.
stance through adequate manage- and compensation
ment of shocks or through skills of through adequate social The role of dialogue to reach decision by consensus,
human resources.
protection measures are in
Adapted from: http://www.undp.org
place;
identify new business and employment opportunities,
and the potential challenges, as well as adaptation of
4. Conclusions
current skills and retraining, has placed consultation Natural capital supports jobs in many economic sectors
(ii) The large cost savings resulting from mitigation
and tripartism as an essential element of labour relations such as agriculture, forestry, tourism and industry. The
policies should allow countries and regional bodies
around the world. In the context of climate change, degradation of natural resources and changing climatic
to develop comprehensive social protection systems
social dialogue has been identified as an essential tool and environmental conditions represent threats to
and agreements;
for anticipating and managing the effects of greening on employment, while resource and energy intensive forms
(iii) Mitigation policies may have complex social quality of work and employment (Aumayr-Pintar, 2015). of production will result in declining productivity over
impacts that need to be properly assessed and time. This makes climate change and environmental
Social dialogue can take place at the regional level, at
discussed within the framework of national dialogue. degradation a topic that relates directly to jobs. By
the national level, through cross-industry consultation or
Involving tripartite constituents in the definition tackling these structural problems, a transition to an
at the sectoral and company level. It also varies in terms
and implementation of social protection measures
of the purpose of the dialogue, from merely consultation
is a key element to ensure a fair and efficient policy
CHAPTER 5: A JUST TRANSITION TO GREEN ECONOMIES: EMPLOYMENT & SOCIAL ISSUES 5.16
inclusive green economy can secure and safeguard to manage distributional impacts of green growth and the actors of the world of work to identify new green
jobs. ensure a just and fair transition for all. business and employment opportunities and the means
to address any challenges in the transition process.
More than that, the transition to green economies As noted in the ILO (2016) analysis, for a transition
interacts with jobs and employment policy in various towards greener and climate-resilient economies to Promoting labour market policies is critical to ensure
ways: First, a successful transition relies on the be successful it requires accompanying and enabling that the employment effects are positive for everyone.
availability of a workforce that has the required skills policies that address the social and employment Enhanced training for skills building and retraining,
and qualifications, for example to enable the production dimensions in order to maximise the positive including better management and more efficient use
of environmental goods and services. Labour can thus employment effects of the transition. of energy and material resources, is key in order to
be understood as a required ‘input’ and ‘condition’ fully take advantage of the opportunities presented
for a successful transition to a green and sustainable Assessing the labour market implications at macro through economic and industrial changes and
economic structure. At the same time, green growth by and sector level can provide a very solid knowledge unleash employment potential, notably by supporting
default is not sufficient to deliver social inclusion and base to inform the policy making process. It is essential entrepreneurship development. Besides, social
positive labour market outcomes. Dedicated investment that policy coherence is promoted at all levels so protection policies should not be overlooked as they can
in human capital along with social policies is needed that greening policies are integrated in other policy enhance the resilience of communities most dependent
areas and efforts are coordinated amongst different on natural capital for their livelihoods, and safeguard
stakeholders through effective social dialogue. workers from the negative impacts of environmental
Indeed, social dialogue is a fundamental pillar of the change, economic restructuring and resource
just transition policy framework that brings together constraints.
CHAPTER 5: A JUST TRANSITION TO GREEN ECONOMIES: EMPLOYMENT & SOCIAL ISSUES 5.17
References International Energy Agency. (2014). Global energy-related emissions of carbon dioxide stalled
in 2014. Available online: http://www.iea.org/newsroomandevents/news/2015/march/global-
Aumayr-Pintar, C. (2015). The Greening of Social Dialogue: Ensuring the Quality of Work and energy-related-emissions-of-carbon-dioxide-stalled-in-2014.html
Employment in the Transition to a Green Economy. Presentation at European Parliament International Labour Conference, 102nd Session (2013). Resolution concerning sustainable
Hearing (Brussels). Eurofound. European Observatory of Working Life. Available online: http:// development, decent work and green jobs.
www.europarl.europa.eu/meetdocs/2014_2019/documents/empl/dv/20150324_presentation_
eurofound_/20150324_presentation_eurofound_en.pdf ILO Governing Body (2015, October) GB.325/POL/3 Outcome of the Tripartite Meeting of Experts on
Sustainable Development, Decent Work and Green Jobs, Geneva.
Auer, P., Efendioglu, U., & Leschke, J. (2008), Active Labour Market Policies around the World:
Coping with the Consequences of Globalization, 2nd edition. Geneva: ILO. ILO Newsroom (2014, December 10). Available online: https://www.ilo.org/global/about-the-ilo/
newsroom/news/WCMS_326878/lang--en/index.htm
Becker, Gary (1993). Human capital: a theoretical and empirical analysis, with special reference to
education (3rd ed.). Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. ILO (2018). World employment and social outlook: Greening with jobs. ILO Geneva. Available
online: https://www.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/---dgreports/---dcomm/---publ/documents/
Buildings Performance Institute Europe (2011). Europe’s Buildings under the Microscope. Brussels: publication/wcms_628654.pdf
Climate, Agriculture and the challenges Ahead. (2014). Planet forward. Available online: https://www. ILO and IILS (International Institute for Labour Studies) (2012). Working towards sustainable
youtube.com/watch?v=G0K9sD0vGus development: Opportunities for decent work and social inclusion in a green economy. Geneva:
Climate Home (2016, March 17). China five-year plan hints at deeper carbon cuts. Available online: International Labour Organization.
http://www.climatechangenews.com/2016/03/17/china-five-year-plan-hints-at-deeper-carbon- ILO (2015). Guidelines for a just transition towards environmentally sustainable economies and
cuts/Decision 11/CP.21, Paragraphs 1 and 5 (2015). Forum and work programme on the societies for all.
impact of the implementation of response measures.
ILO (2016b). World Employment Social Outlook: Trends 2016. Geneva, International Labour
Deutsche Bank Climate Change Advisors and Rockefeller Foundation. (2012). United States Organization;
Building Energy Efficiency Retrofits: Market Sizing and Financing Models. New York:
ILO (2015b). Global Flagship Programme on Building Social Protection Floors for All. Geneva,
EASHW (European Agency for Safety and Health at Work). (2011). Foresight of New and Emerging International Labour Organization. Available online: http://www.social-protection.org/gimi/gess/
Risks to Occupational Safety and Health associated with New Technologies in Green Jobs by RessourcePDF.action?ressource.ressourceId=51737
2020: Phase II—Key Technologies. Luxembourg.
ILO (2016). A just transition to climate-resilient economies and societies: Issues and perspectives for
Galgóczi, B. (2014). The long and winding road from black to green: Decades of structural change the world of work. ILO Technical Paper. Available online: http://www.ilo.org/global/topics/green-
in the Ruhr region. International Journal of Labour Research. 6(2), 217–240. jobs/publications/WCMS_536552/lang--en/index.htm
Goldin C. (2016). Human capital. In Handbook of Cliometrics. Heidelberg, Germany: Springer IPCC (Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change) (2014). 5th Assessment Report. Synthesis
Verlag. report. Available online: https://www.ipcc.ch/report/ar5/syr/
Harasty, C., Strietska-Ilina, O., & Tsukamoto, M. (2016). A just transition to climate-resilient IRENA (2016). Renewable Energy and Jobs. Annual Review 2016. Available online: http://www.
economies and societies: Issues and perspectives for the world of work. Available online: se4all.org/sites/default/files/IRENA_RE_Jobs_Annual_Review_2016.pdf
http://www.ilo.org/global/topics/green-jobs/publications/WCMS_536552/lang--en/index.htm
Jessoe, K., Manning, D., Taylor, E. (2018). Climate change: extreme heat will decrease rural
Herren, H., Bassi, A., Tan, B., & Binns, W. (2011). Green Jobs for a Revitalized Food and Agriculture employment and increase migration in Mexico. London School of Economics Business Review.
Sector. Rome: FAO. Available online: https://blogs.lse.ac.uk/businessreview/2018/05/18/climate-change-extreme-
heat-will-decrease-rural-employment-and-increase-migration-in-mexico/
Keynes, J.M. (1930). Economic possibilities for our grandchildren. The Nation Company. New York.
CHAPTER 5: A JUST TRANSITION TO GREEN ECONOMIES: EMPLOYMENT & SOCIAL ISSUES 5.18
Kjellstrom, T., Otto, M., Lemke, B., Freyberg, C., Briggs, D., & Line, L. (2016). Climate change Schumpeter, Joseph. (1942). Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. Harper & Bros, New York.
and labour: Impacts of heat in the workplace. Climate change, workplace environmental Schwab, Klaus. (2016). The Fourth Industrial Revolution. World Economic Forum.
conditions, occupational health risks, and productivity – an emerging global challenge
to decent work, sustainable development and social equity. Geneva: United Nations Statistik der Kohlenwirtschaft (2015). Der Kohlenbergbau in der Energiewirtschaft der
Development Programme. Bundesrepublik Deutschland im Jahre. Herne and Köln.
McKinsey Global Institute. (2017). Digitization, AI, and the future of work: imperatives for Europe. Stern, N., Peters, S, Bakhshi, V., Bowen, A., Cameron, C., Catovsky, S., Crane, D., Cruickshank, S., &
(Briefing note prepared for the European Union Tallinn digital summit). Available online: https:// Dietz, S. (2006). Stern Review: The economics of climate change. London: HM treasury.
www.mckinsey.com/~/media/McKinsey/Featured%20Insights/Europe/Ten%20imperatives%20 Strietska-Ilina, O., Hofmann, C., Durán Haro, M. & Jeon, S. (2011). Skills for Green Jobs. A Global
for%20Europe%20in%20the%20age%20of%20AI%20and%20automation/Digitization-AI-and- View. International Labour Office.
the-future-of-work.ashx
Stocker, A. (2015). The interaction of resource and labour productivity: a scoping study. Sustainable
Meine Energie hat Zukunft. Available online : http://www.meine-energie-hat-zukunft.de/ Europe Research Institute (SERI) bio by Deloitte on behalf of European Commission. DG
Morison, J., Hine, R., & Pretty, J. (2005). Survey and Analysis of Labour on Organic Farms in the UK Environment.
and Republic of Ireland. International Journal of Agricultural Sustainability. SVTC (Silicon Valley Toxics Coalition) (2009). Toward a Just and Sustainable Solar Energy Industry.
Nübler, I. (2017). Technological changes and work in the future: making technology work for all. ILO San Jose, CA.
Briefing Note. SVTC (2014). 2014 Solar Scorecard. San Jose, CA.
Paris Agreement (Dec. 13, 2015), in UNFCCC, COP Report No. 21, Addenum, at 21, U.N. Doc. Syndex S Partner and WMP (2009). Climate Disturbances, New Industrial Policies and Ways Out of
FCCC/CP/2015/10/Add, 1 (Jan. 29, 2016). the Crisis. Brussels: ETUC.
Patel, N. (2015). 90% Of Start-ups Fail: Here’s What You Need To Know About The 10%. Forbes. Trabish, H.K. (2011, October 31). The Multibillion-Dollar Value of Energy Service Companies.
Available online: https://www.forbes.com/sites/neilpatel/2015/01/16/90-of-startups-will-fail- Available online: http://www.greentechmedia.com/articles/read/The-Multi-Billion-Dollar-Value-
heres-what-you-need-to-know-about-the-10/#42453b0a6679 of-Energy-Service-Companies/
Pollin, R., & Callaci, B. (2016). The Economics of Just Transition: A Framework for Supporting Fossil UNFCCC. (2016). Just transition of the workforce, and the creation of decent work and quality jobs.
Fuel–Dependent Workers and Communities in the United States. Labor Studies Journal, Technical paper by the secretariat. Available online: https://unfccc.int/resource/docs/2016/
0160449X18787051. tp/07.pdf
Poschen, P. (2015). Sustainable Development, Decent Work
and Green Jobs. Sheffield, Greenleaf UNFCCC (2018). Overview of the work of the Conference of the Parties and the subsidiary and
Publishing. constituted bodies on the work programme under the Paris Agreement. Available online:
Renner, M., Kubit, J., & Sweeney, S (2008). Green Jobs: Towards Decent Work in a Sustainable, https://unfccc.int/node/28798/
Low-Carbon World. Nairobi: UN Environment.
CHAPTER 5: A JUST TRANSITION TO GREEN ECONOMIES: EMPLOYMENT & SOCIAL ISSUES 5.19
CHAPTER 6: INSTITUTIONAL REFORM FOR
INCLUSIVE GREEN ECONOMIES
CHAPTER 6: INSTITUTIONAL
REFORM FOR INCLUSIVE GREEN
ECONOMIES
This chapter aims to enable its readers to: International Institute for Environment and Development
• Appreciate the institutional challenges of assessing, planning and implementing Steve Bass has worked in sustainable development since 1982, in
inclusive green economy approaches; international policy processes and in developing countries, notably Africa
and South Asia. With natural science degrees from Oxford and Manchester,
• Articulate the institutional spectrum of organizations, rules, and norms that he has held senior roles at DFID (Chief Environment Advisor) and the
International Institute for Environment and Development (Director of Forestry,
are needed to sustain and grow green economies, and the change processes of Programmes, and latterly of Sustainable Markets).
needed to arrive at them; and
Steve co-founded the Green Economy Coalition, chaired the 8-year UK
• Apply practical frameworks to analyse the institutional reforms required for inclu- programme Ecosystem Services for Poverty Alleviation, and is on advisory
boards of the Cambridge Conservation Initiative, Cancer Research UK,
sive green economy. Fundação Amazonas Sustentável, and UN Poverty Environment Initiative.
tions designed specifically for green economy and existing institutions that may evolve Several observations can be made about institutions (defined in the broad sense) that
towards a green economy. are relevant for green economy.
Organizations receive significant attention in discussions on institutional reform toward First, there is no ‘magic bullet’ institutional solution. Institutions are shaped by their his-
a green economy, in part due to the number and variety of organizations involved in torical, geographical, political, cultural and other contexts and can be very diverse. For
the transition process (Wiggins & Davis, 2006, Carter, 2014a). Box 1 provides a list of example, French and British colonial influences remain strong in the institutions of gov-
the most relevant ones. These organizations are shaped by institutions and in return ernment and law in ex-French and ex-British colonies and they are quite distinct from
propose changes to ‘the rules of the game’, thereby influencing institutions. each other. Chinese historical and cultural references are extremely strong in the institu-
tions that are now driving green economy in China – ancient traditions of harmony with
the institutional foundations that have been deployed, 8. Interdisciplinary approach for sustainable science
We explore these further in Section 3 below.
strengthened or built for sustainable development. Build- 9. Recognition of holistic institutions
ing on an earlier twenty-year stock-take of the sustain- 10. Future-facing mechanisms
able development legacy (Bass, 2007), we can point to
11. Development of sustainability networks
3. Institutional progress to green several core institutional innovations leading the way.
Many will prove to be important institutional assets,
economy – baseline, drivers, which will enable countries to develop a green economy.
barriers Firstly, a recognised body of sustainable development
law has been built (see Box 6.2). Brundtland’s report development, and now for an IGE. Among the more influ-
This section takes stock of the ‘meta-institutional’
(1987) identified 22 sustainable development principles, ential examples are legal principles such as Polluter
context, the key institutional components, their readi-
many of which have come to be widely adopted in legal Pays, Precaution, and Free Prior Informed Consent,
ness for the transition to a green economy, the institu-
form. Initially embodied in multilateral environmental which are now applied routinely and effectively.
tional barriers to this transition, and the kinds of institu-
agreements, this body of sustainable development law
tional reform that have already taken place. This section
has come to be interpreted and enacted in most national In addition, some countries have enshrined sustainable
begins by depicting three decades of institutional evolu-
jurisdictions, together development into founda-
tion for sustainable development, followed by the more Key definition: with the three pillars of tional national documents
recent and rapid development of several international Three pillars Key definition:
More properly expressed today as sustainable development Polluter pays (see innovation 2 in Box
initiatives that have been influential in researching, pro- three indivisible, interwoven strands concept, – which offered This principle entails the responsi- 6.2). The 2012 synthe-
moting and planning for a green economy. The extent rather than pillars – reflecting the bility of polluters to pay for the envi-
‘indivisibility’ now asserted by the principles for building ronmental degradation they cause. sis of national reports
to which issues related to green economies have been
SDGs. institutions for sustainable Adapted from: http://www.lse.ac.uk to Rio+12 revealed how
mainstreamed at national and local levels is explored in
Localisation processes: decentralisation, participation, landscape/nexus approaches that highlight cross-issue local realities.
around sector, theme, country, project and best-practice Green Economy Coalition (GEC) To keep people focused on the prize of transition, building a compel-
ling narrative has been central to the GEC’s work with devices such as
bases. GGKP research committees review the evidence GEC is a new kind of institution that is designed to
‘glimpses of a green economy’, ‘stories of change’, and a ‘barometer’ of
progress.
available and identify knowledge gaps, proposing future catalyse the transition to green economies: holistic and
research. Fifty-eight ‘knowledge partners’ have so far inclusive, future-focused and adaptive, values- and
GEC now includes both international members and national NGOs large
and small, forming national hubs that reach out to hear the ‘voices of
joined GGKP (GGKP, 2019). Its institutional model is evidence-based. Established in 2009, initially as a the poor’. It has upheld high aspirations for inclusive GE, conferring the
consistent with the requirements of IGE: it is an acces- time-bound partnership for three years between a few
credibility to critique some of the intergovernmental work (e.g. too many
initiatives were focused on carbon, large companies, big infrastructure
sible, organised platform and network for international founding members (like the GGKP), its membership has and high technology, risking green economy being owned by elites)
green economy research that encourages collaboration grown to include international organizations, business (GEC, 2014). As its work plan and funding expands, the GEC intends not
to build a large central secretariat but to mobilise best-placed members
among actors in generating and using knowledge for the and civil society, as well as large and small organizations to act, increasingly those based in different continents.
green economy transition. across 20 countries. Its role is to facilitate multi-stake-
Stages in institutional Level on integration at this stage Current status Catalysts that help this stage
reform
1. Silos - ‘do nothing’ Separate – institutions work separately; Very few countries are still at this stage. Prevailing institutional incentives – incumbent regimes, profes-
and social, environmental, and economic But prevailing incentives can be hard to shift. sional disciplines and elite bargains maintain (and often robustly
objectives are not integrated in practice. defend) silos.
2. Safeguards - ‘do no Checks and balances – between social, Most countries have achieved this stage, with many provisions in Citizen engagement has often pushed for safeguards.
harm’ environmental, and economic objectives legislation. Tools include: Environmental impact assessment; Social Impact
seek a minimal ‘do no harm’ outcome, with But provisions are often misunderstood and ignored in practice. Assessment; ‘alternative livelihood’ schemes; cash transfers or
minor institutional cooperation. compensation.
Safeguards do not enable the major leaps forward that are
required.
3. Synergies - ‘do good Win-wins – between social, environmental, Many countries are at this stage International engagement has often catalysed win-win strate-
win-wins and co-bene- and economic objectives are sought, but Policy discussion is constructive and focused on integrated gies.
fits are limited in extent – to where current insti- schemes. Tools include: Strategic environmental assessment; Payments
tutional and finance rules allow. for Ecosystem Services and conditional cash transfers; joint env/
But win-wins are elusive – just as important is to consider ‘losers’
as well, with ‘just transition’ (see Chapter 5) or at least compen- social protection schemes e.g. jobs through land restoration;
sation mechanisms. certification of production; and Public expenditure reviews on
environment, climate, sustainable development.
4. System-wide reform Full integration – of sustainability, effi- Few countries are at this stage yet. Multi-stakeholder policy/oversight bodies
- ‘do more by changing ciency, equity and long-term orientation. However, the need for an inclusive green economy is understood Primary empowerment e.g. rights reforms and redistributing
the rules’ A truly inclusive, green economy draws by many – institutionally this means: assets
on relevant concepts of circular economy,
• Much better trade-off decisions – with mechanisms to Inclusive formalisation of informality
bio-economy, etc. Addresses structural
analyse and resolve Fiscal reforms pro-green economy, anti-brown economy
barriers to scaling/speeding up the transi-
tion towards green economies. • Changing economic structures so they are inclusive and Wealth/natural capital accounting and other means for better
green decision-making.
What, then, helps countries or sectors to progress 4.1.2 Stakeholder interactions and leadership: in Table 1. Multi-stakeholder processes (MSPs) provide
between the stages? The following section will elaborate this space. The value of MSPs lies in their potential to
on a number of important factors. Financial, juridical, organizational and mental space achieve consensus and pool the necessary resources
is needed for the kind of adaptive strategy required to for the institutional reform that no one stakeholder alone
drive the transition from siloed organizations to full inte- could achieve (or even envisage). MSPs confer legiti-
gration (GGGI et al., 2016), i.e. from stage 1 to stage 4 macy by virtue of whom they involve and the kinds of
16.3 Promote the rule of law at the national and international levels and 2. Rooted – in local contexts, capabilities and needs. Embracing domestic cultural, politi-
ensure equal access to justice for all;
5. Conclusions cal, economic and social processes that support GE, and thus ‘owned’ by stakeholders.
16.5 Substantially reduce corruption and bribery in all their forms; 3. Future-oriented – clear vision, long horizons. Responsive and adaptive, not only focus-
Although many countries have to date devel- ing on short-term stability but also long-term wellbeing of future generations.
16.6 Develop effective, accountable and transparent institutions at all
levels; oped green economy transition plans, the lack 4. Holistic and systemic – integrated, interdisciplinary, and internalizing externalities.
of efficient, capable institutions is one of the Respecting both ecological and social limits in planning, incentives and implementation.
16.7 Ensure responsive, inclusive, participatory and representative deci-
sion-making at all levels; persistent obstacles to IGE progress. Only 5. Networked – linking actors horizontally and vertically, and across knowledge systems.
transparent, competent, resilient and enabling Supporting coherence, collaboration and coordination, and not overly centralized.
16.8 Broaden and strengthen the participation of low-income countries in
the institutions of global governance; institutions can ensure that sustainable devel- 6. Wealth-building – helping stakeholders to understand, manage, grow and track the
opment is taken into consideration in the deci- capitals needed for inclusive green economy, and make sustainable trade-offs.
16.10 Ensure public access to information and protect fundamental free-
doms, in accordance with national legislation and international agree- sion-making process, and that all societal 7. Resilient – effective means for feedback, learning, adaptation, prioritization and
ments ; groups are represented and participate. grant resourcing.
16.b Promote and enforce non-discriminatory laws and policies for sus- representation and participation to all societal 8. Legitimate and clear mandate – rooted in the constitution and legal regime, accepted
tainable development . groups. Developing such institutions will not as right and proper, reflecting societal demand and consensus, and autonomous from short-
term political pressure and vested interests.
follow a single model in all countries. Institu-
tions are complex and diverse and shaped 9. Upholding the rule of law – protecting rights and fundamental freedoms, reducing
bribery and corruption, and promoting informed consent and the body of sustainable devel-
by their historical, geographical, political and opment law.
Whereas not every characteristic will be a prerequi- cultural contexts. If new institutions gain com-
site for every institution, organization, rule or norm (and mitment from stakeholders, to coordinate effec- 10. Evidence-based and -sharing – founded on sound science and local knowledge;
ensuring access and welcoming and responding to diverse information and learning loops.
instead might pull the former in too many dimensions) – tively among them and to increase cooperation
their absence across the national institutional landscape for an IGE, they will need to be tailored to local 11. Accountable and transparent – institutions are able to account for performance, trans-
parent and open about the quality of that performance, and subject to independent oversight.
can make the reform process very fragile. However, needs and circumstances. They will build on
overall, the outline characteristics remain quite general, what works in context. 12. Competent and adequately resourced – finance and expertise are secure but respon-
sive to need, with mechanisms to mitigate risks and avoid performance dropping off.
and a wide variety of institutions in government, busi-
ness or civil society could achieve and demonstrate This chapter has explored promising institu-
those. Nevertheless, it is useful to emphasize that many tional various reforms and innovative measures
different types of institutions may be selected or devel- in diverse contexts including new regulations
for sustainable development, the establishment
BMWI (Bundesministerium fuer Wirtschaft und Energie). (2018). Erneuerbare Energien. Retrieved GGKP. (2013). Cambodia National Strategic Plan on Green Growth 2013-2020. Available online:
from https://www.bmwi.de/Redaktion/DE/Dossier/erneuerbare-energien.html? http://www.greengrowthknowledge.org/national-documents/cambodia-national-strategic-plan-
green-growth-2013-2030
Buchan, D. (2012). The Energiewende – Germany’s gamble. Oxford.
GGKP. (2018). Green Growth Knowledge. Available online: http://www.greengrowthknowledge.org/
Carter, B. (2014a).Defining institutions. In Governance and Social Development Resource Centre theme/institutions-governance.
(GSDRC). University of Birmingham.
GGKP. (2019). Knowledge Partners. Available online: http://www.greengrowthknowledge.org/
Cashore B, Auld,G. and Newsom, D. (2004). Governing Through Markets: Forest Certification and partners
the Emergence of Non-State Authority. Yale University Press, New Haven and London.
Grove, R. (1990). The GGGI, origins of environmentalism. Nature 345, 11-14.
Confino, J. (2015). Beyond capitalism and socialism: could a new economic approach save the
planet? Available online: http://greeneconomycoalition.org. Helmke, G & Levitsky, S. (2004). Informal Institutions and Comparative Politics: A Research Agenda.
Cambridge Journals.
North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge: UNDP (2017b). SDG Accelerator and Bottleneck Assessment.
Cambridge University Press. UNECA (2016). Enabling measures for an inclusive green economy in Africa.
OECD (2012.) Enhancing capacity: a basis for greening development. UN Environment (2008). Green Economy report.
OECD (2013). South Africa Environmental Performance Review. Paris. UN Environment (2015). Uncovering Pathways Towards An Inclusive Green Economy.
Palwa, K. (2012, June). Social Enterprise for a Green Economy. DevAlt [Newsletter] Available online: UNFCCC. (2016). Climate Action Plan 2050. Available online: https://unfccc.int/files/focus/long-term_
http://www.devalt.org/newsletter/jun12/lead.htm. strategies/application/pdf/161114_climate_action_plan_2050_en_bf.pdf
Wales Government (2015). Well-being of Future Generations (Wales) Act 2015. Wiggins, S. & Davis, J. (2006, July). Economic Institutions [IPPG Briefing paper no. 3].
World Bank (2017). World Development Report 2017: Governance and the Law. Washington DC,
World Bank.
This chapter aims to enable its readers to: International Institute for Environment and Development
• Outline the main challenges facing humanity and analyse their drivers; Paul Steele is Chief Economist at the International Institute for Environment
and Development (IIED) where he focuses on financing for the SDGs and
• Articulate how the inclusive green economy model seeks to address these chal- Incentives for an inclusive, green economy. He spent eight years with the
lenges; and United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) in Bangkok working with
Ministries of Finance in Asia Pacific on climate and development finance.
• Understand the major characteristics that underpin national strategies on For four years he worked with the Department for International Development
inclusive green economy, the related analytical tools, key actors and initiatives (DFID), UK as the only environmental economist and focused on poverty and
as well as the critical role of public policy in turning the inclusive seen economy environment issues in Africa and Asia. He holds an MSc in Environmental
Economics from London University and a BA in Politics, Philosophy and
model into practice. Economics from Oxford University.
CHAPTER 1: INCLUSION, POVERTY REDUCTION AND GENDER EQUITY FOR A GREEN ECONOMY 7.2
CHAPTER CONTENTS gender equality in the context of a green economy tran- For these purposes, inclusion is defined as the pro-
sition (a case which has recently been strengthened by cesses of overcoming social exclusion through poverty
Foreword the Sustainable Development Goals), and examines the reduction, or of addressing discrimination against a dis-
instrumental case for why this transition will improve the advantaged social group, such as women.
1. Poverty, inclusion, and gender equity: sta-tus health, livelihoods, and vulnerability of poor women and
men. Section 3 then presents economic theory, model- At the global level, absolute poverty (using the inter-
and trends national poverty line of US$1.90 per day) has fallen
ling statistics and empirical studies to demonstrate the
2. Why a green economy transition should links between green economy transition and poverty considerably over the past 15 years – both in terms of
numbers, and as a percentage of the world’s popula-
contribute to inclusion, poverty reduction, and reduction, income, and gender equality. Section 4 con-
tion. Almost 1.1 billion people were lifted out of poverty
siders the trade-offs between inclusion and a green
gender equality: Intrinsic versus Instru- economy transition, as well as how these might be between 1990 and 2013. However, still 766 million
mental approach addressed (such as through price increases for fossil of people were living on less than US $1.90 a day in
fuels). 2013, as estimated by World Bank (2017). However,
3. Theory and data of how green economy the remaining poor population is often difficult to reach.
transition matters for inclusion, poverty re- By doing so, the chapter aims to enable the reader to Many of them live in remote rural areas with little access
better reflect upon the fact that a green economy tran- to share the common wealth achieved by their city or
duction and gender equality
sition does not automatically enhance social justice in country. They are frequently living on poor quality land
4. Managing trade-offs : Why inclusion, poverty developing countries. Indeed, social justice cannot be and far from formal markets, generally find themselves to
reduction and gender equality are enhanced unless the transition is complemented by inte- be politically invisible, in some cases. Only a deliberately
grated policies that ensure that the externalised costs of inclusive approach will succeed in reaching them.
not inevitable outcomes of a green economy greening the economy do not fall on those that are living
5. How to increase inclusion, poverty reduc- in poverty. Finally, Section 5 presents illustrative exam- In addition, the advancements to fight poverty have
ples of how inclusion, poverty reduction, and gender been predominately driven by pro-poor growth in both
tion, and gender equity as outcomes of green China, and more recently, in India. Due to the huge size
equality can be improved under a green economy transi-
economy transition tion, focusing on four main approaches: empowerment, of their populations, improvements in these two coun-
tries mask underperformance elsewhere, and particu-
6. Conclusion integrated institutions, inclusive finances, and metrics.
larly in some African countries. In addition, there are still
hundreds of millions of people that continue to live just
Foreword above the official poverty lines with few safety nets, low
This chapter will begin by discussing the status and 1. Poverty, inclusion, and gender job security and limited physical and social infrastruc-
ture. These people therefore remain highly vulnerable
trends of the key aspects of inclusion, focusing on
poverty, equality, and gender equality in developing
equality: status and trends to the effects of conflicts, economic shocks (as in the
2008 global financial crisis), or climate impacts (such as
countries. Section 2 introduces the intrinsic case for This section will examine and review the global status
establishing the links between inclusion, poverty, and and trends on poverty, inclusion, and gender equality.
CHAPTER 7: INCLUSION, POVERTY REDUCTION AND GENDER EQUITY FOR A GREEN ECONOMY 7.1
tries (with some emerging economies experiencing as estimates of female infanticide, gender-based vio-
rapid levels of growth), wealth within most coun- lence, and cases of child marriage, show that women
tries is becoming increasingly concentrated in the and girls still remain seriously vulnerable in many coun-
hands of just a few individuals. Indeed, a recent tries.
study conducted by Oxfam found that just eight
individuals now possess more wealth than the 3.5 Another area of exclusion that has been receiving
billion people living in the “bottom half” of the global increasing recognition is disability. Estimates of its prev-
population (Oxfam, 2017). Rising inequality is often alence are challenging due to the lack of uniform under-
accompanied by polarised levels of education, standing on, or definition of, what disability is, as well as
health, and mobility, each of which further exacer- a lack of national data allowing for international compar-
Figure 1: Paradox of global GDP growth alongside persistent poverty. ison. The most comprehensive estimate of global prev-
(Left-hand figure of World real GDP based on Tani, 2016 and right-hand bate the imbalances of power – fuelling exclusion
figure from Chen and Ravallion, 2012). at the cost of future economic growth. Indeed, the alence is from 2011, when the WHO/World Bank’s World
2013 UNDP Human Development report found that Disability Report synthesized data collected from 59
countries with high inequality suffer from slower countries through the World Health Surveys from 2002 to
floods and droughts), each of which can cause them to 2004, and which was based on a ‘functioning’ approach.
growth rates than countries in which incomes are distrib-
fall back below the poverty line. From this, the 2011 report estimated the global preva-
uted more equally (UNDP, 2013). There is now growing
political momentum in many countries to address lence of disability to be at 16 per cent, with a lower prev-
The geography of poverty is also changing. Already,
inequality, even if it is phrased in more politically accept- alence of 12 per cent in higher income countries and a
more than half of the world’s poor now live in Sub-Saha-
able terms, such as ‘inclusion’. higher prevalence of 18 per cent in lower-income coun-
ran Africa, and this number is set to increase further by
tries (WHO/World Bank, 2011).
2030 (World Bank, 2016). Out of the eighteen countries
Gender inequality also remains a stark global issue. In
in which the number of people living in absolute poverty
this regard, data shows that women complete at least
is rising, fourteen are located in Africa (Kharas et al.,
twice as much unpaid domestic and care work as men.
2018). These countries also represent some of those
most at risk to challenging social and political conflicts,
Even where women provide more agricultural labour, 2. Green economy transition’s
and climate extremes. And, while poverty remains pri-
most agricultural land is still owned by men: in India,
Nepal, and Thailand, for example, less than 10 per cent
contribution to inclusion,
marily rural, urban poverty has now also increased to 20
per cent of the total poor. This is due in part to increas-
of women farmers own the land that they farm, while in poverty reduction & gender
ing rural-urban migration, with it being estimated that up
Kenya this figure is only 1 per cent, despite women pro-
viding 70 per cent of the agricultural labour (IFAD, 2008).
equality: Intrinsic &
to 80 per cent of the total population in some cities now
living in slums (World Bank, 2016).
However, some improvements have been made and instrumental approach
provide hope for the future: 20 per cent of parliamen-
tarians worldwide are women, and many countries now There are both intrinsic (i.e. moral) and instrumen-
The challenge of tackling relative poverty now also
have almost 100 per cent enrolment of girls in primary tal arguments for the transition to a green economy to
takes place in a global context or rising and widespread
address poverty and inclusion issues.
inequality. While wealth is expanding between coun- education (IPU, 2014). However, other indicators, such
CHAPTER 7: INCLUSION, POVERTY REDUCTION AND GENDER EQUITY FOR A GREEN ECONOMY 7.2
• First, the intrinsic argument views inclusion, poverty On the other hand, the instrumental view of the interlink-
reduction, and gender equality as fundamental under- Box 7.1: Selected SDGs will drive some ages between poverty, inclusion, gender, and a green
pinning of a green economy transition. This position is economy transition focuses on ‘cause and effect’. In this
supported by the UN’s Declaration of Human Rights aspects of an inclusive green economy way, the transition to a green economy can contribute to
and many other UN Conventions related to develop- SDG 1: End poverty in all its forms everywhere. the ‘effects’ of poverty reduction, inclusion, and gender
ment and poverty reduction, which explicitly call for SDG 2: End hunger, achieve food security and improved nutrition and equality by first reviewing which environmental issues
these to be prioritised within national policies. promote sustainable agriculture. this transition will ‘cause.’ Then those that are most likely
SDG 5: Achieve gender equality and empower all women and girls. to threaten the health and livelihoods of poor women and
• Second, the instrumental view submits that if comple- men can then be addressed on this basis (DFID et al.,
mented by targeted, integrated policies, the transition SDG 6: Ensure availability and sustainable management of water and
2002).
sanitation for all.
to a green economy will contribute to poverty reduc-
tion and enhance inclusion. SDG 7: Ensure access to affordable, reliable, sustainable and modern
energy for all.
Our focus here is primarily on the instrumental view, as SDG 8: Promote sustained, inclusive and sustainable economic growth.
2.1 Environmental health of poor people
the intrinsic view is determined by definitional consid- and transition to a green economy
SDG 10: Reduce inequality within and among countries.
erations. For instance, if by definition a green economy
is required to contribute to poverty reduction then the SDG 11: Make cities and human settlements inclusive, safe, resilient and While the provision of water and sanitation has improved,
transition will necessarily be inclusive. In this regard, it is sustainable. many poor people still lack regular and safe access. In
important to note that the intrinsic view recognising the SDG 16: Promote peaceful and inclusive societies for sustainable devel- 2012, 89 per cent of the world’s population had access
interlinkages between green economy, poverty, inclusion opment. to an improved drinking water source (up from 76 per
and gender equality has recently been endorsed under cent in 1990), which still left almost 750 million people
the 17 Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs), which exposed to, and relying on, unsafe water sources
were formally agreed and launched by all countries at (UNDP, 2014). And while sanitation coverage increased
The 17 goals and 169 indicators may be complex, but from 49 per cent to 64 per cent over this same period,
the United Nations General Assembly in September sustainable development (SD) is inevitably a multi-di-
2015. over a third of the world’s population, almost 2.5 billion
mensional endeavour, and especially when applied people, continue to live without sanitation, with one
Up to this point, progress on issues of poverty, the to all countries and all people. Importantly, equity and billion of these still forced to resort to open defecation
environment, and economic growth had largely been inclusion are central components to half of the Goals (UNDP, 2014). Moreover, these water and sanitation
pursued independently. Indeed, certain SDGs (see Box shown in the box, and the SDGs commit countries to end metrics are often inadequate, with “improved” water
7.1 below), whilst not being without their critiques, do extreme absolute poverty by 2030: a global commitment sources and sanitation types not reflecting real needs
provide a platform for joint action on poverty reduction, that would have seemed naïve even a decade ago. In observed on the ground — a reflection of the failure to
inclusivity, and environmental sustainability, based on the this regard, the SDGs aim to drive inclusive green growth include people when defining the targets.
high degree of consensus between countries and stake- at the national level, since the 2030 Agenda applies uni-
holders that the SDGs represent. versally and equally to all countries across the globe. In addition, deaths from the effects of air pollution con-
tinue to rise, with indoor air pollution, which affects the
CHAPTER 7: INCLUSION, POVERTY REDUCTION AND GENDER EQUITY FOR A GREEN ECONOMY 7.3
very poorest members of society. In 2012, around 7 dependent on agriculture; 1.6 billion rely on forests; and more traditional resource
Key concept:
million people died as a result of air pollution exposure a further 250 million on fisheries (Lee, 2012). Natural Governing the commons management approaches
– one in eight of total global deaths,: 4.3 million from capital is therefore critical for low-income countries — Good examples from Ostrom’s (such as small-scale irri-
‘Governing the Commons’ (https://
indoor air pollution, mostly resulting from cooking with forming 25 per cent of national wealth, compared to just wtf.tw/ref/ostrom_1990.pdf) are: gation and traditional
biomass, and 3.7 million from other effects of outdoor air two per cent in those countries which are members of Torbel in Switzerland (p. 61), Hira- fishery management
no, Nagaike and Yamanoka villages
pollution (with 1 million deaths being attributed to over- the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Devel- in Japan (p. 65), Spanish Huerta regimes in South Asia),
lapping causes) (WHO, 2014). Of the 4.3 million deaths opment (OECD) (World Bank, 2006). irrigation institutions (p.69) and as well as those that are
irrigation communities in Philippines
attributed to indoor pollution, most of the victims are (p.82). Further resources:
more contemporary (such
women and young girls, who spend most of their time This explains why farming, forestry, and fisheries make https://www.youtube.com/ as community manage-
with the ‘killer in the kitchen.’ (WHO, 2004). up 57 per cent of what has been called ‘the GDP of the watch?v=Qr5Q3VvpI7w
ment forestry in Nepal
poor’ in India, even if they contribute just 7 per cent to Switzerland: https://houseofswitzer-
and elsewhere) (Ghate et
land.org/swissstories/environment/
Since 2012, the proportion of the world’s population India’s formal national GDP. It is also why forest com- swiss-village-changed-ecology- al., 2008). In this respect,
living in slums, and specifically urban residents in devel- munities choose to invest an estimated US$2.5 billion of twice Japan: https://www.youtube.
the adoption of collective
com/watch?v=GFVwm3earxU
oping regions, has fallen from 40 per cent to 33 per cent. their own labour and inputs each year into sustainable Spain: https://dlc.dlib.indiana.edu/ management approaches
However, the rapid rate of urban population growth has forestry — a figure that is higher than the combined dlc/bitstream/handle/10535/10135/
under a green economy
ORTEGA.pdf?sequence=1&isAl-
meant that the actual number of people living in slums yearly contributions of all international organisations put lowed=y Philippines: https://www. transition can contribute
has risen considerably, from 650 million in 1990, to 760 into forestry aid (ITTO & RRI, 2007). youtube.com/watch?v=yNQcOvn-
to poverty reduction by
QY4g
million in 2000, and reaching 863 million in 2012 (UNDP, increasing the social and
2014). These slums are known for having poor environ- In this regard, many poor groups have developed
the skills to successfully manage natural capital, and institutional capital of poor
mental conditions which have a corresponding negative women and men.
impact on human health, such as poor water and sani- numerous examples of community managed natural
tation, indoor air pollution, exposure to vector-borne dis- resources in drylands, croplands, forests, and fisheries
eases (such as dengue fever) from a lack of drainage, have been well-documented by anthropologists. Ini-
and vulnerability to climate change-related flooding. tially, economists focused on the so-called “tragedy of 2.3 Poor people vulnerability and
the commons,” which undermined the effectiveness of transition to a green economy
community management approaches. More recently,
however, this narrative has changed, and the “tragedy Climate change is now almost universally recognized
2.2 Livelihoods of poor people and of open access” now acknowledges the inefficiencies of as posing a huge short-term threat to poor economies,
transition to a green economy open access approaches, with the collective manage- and particularly to the very poorest members of the pop-
ment of natural capital serving to address these. Elinor ulation. This discourse has shifted from concern over
The poorest members of society disproportionately rely impacts on future generations to the realisation that
on available natural assets such as forests, fisheries, Ostrom, the Nobel Prize-winning economist, focused
her work on documenting what made these collective climate change is already having significant impacts –
and farmland for their livelihoods, nutrition, health, and increasing the intensity and frequency of natural disas-
employment, and this is especially the case in rural management schemes successful (Ostrom, 1990), and
her theories have now been applied to both older and ters, the economic damages from which exceeded
areas. Some 2.6 billion people are either partially or fully US$380 billion in 2011 alone. While the financial impacts
CHAPTER 7: INCLUSION, POVERTY REDUCTION AND GENDER EQUITY FOR A GREEN ECONOMY 7.4
of these are greater in emerging economies, the toll on 3. Theory and data of how green 3.1 Theoretical literature on a green
society and human life hits small, low-income countries economy transition in low-income
the hardest (World Bank, 2012a). economy transition matters for
countries
Within this context, evidence increasingly suggests inclusion, poverty reduction and
There is now emerging theoretical literature on the
that women and other excluded groups are particu- gender equality effects of a green economy transition within low income
larly exposed to the effects of climate change. The
Inter-Governmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC, This section presents economic theory and data from and less developed countries. This literature has been
2014) concluded that: “Differences in vulnerability and modelling and empirical studies which consider the links produced both by international organisations such as
exposure arise from non-climatic factors and from mul- between a green economy transition and poverty reduc- the World Bank and the United Nations, and by more
tidimensional inequalities often produced by uneven tion, income, and gender equality: academic economists (Scott et al, 2013; Barbier, 2013;
development processes (very high confidence). These Dercon, 2011; Hallegate et al., 2012). The only applied
Section 3.1 presents the proponents and critics of the work to have been conducted tends to be advocacy
differences shape differential risks from climate change. theoretical linkages between growth and development,
[…] People who are socially, economically, culturally, analysis, made by green growth exponents such as the
in the context of a green economy transition in low New Climate Economy (eg. NCE and GoU, 2016).
politically, institutionally, or otherwise marginalized are income and least developed countries. The proponents
especially vulnerable to climate change and also to of these linkages focus on the instrumental justifications It is submitted that the literature that has been critical
some adaptation and mitigation responses (medium that were briefly introduced in Section 2. Critics of these, of a green economy transition is constrained by seeing
evidence, high agreement). This heightened vulnerability on the other hand, tend to focus on shorter-term green the goals of economic policy (i.e. to deliver growth and
is rarely due to a single cause. Rather, it is the product economy issues, while ignoring the effects of distribu- employment) in the aggregate and over relatively short
of intersecting social processes that result in inequalities tion and equality over time. Section 3.2 presents some of term periods, while generally ignoring the long-term
in socioeconomic status and income, as well as in expo- the data that is available for these linkages, with a focus effects of distributional issues or other social goals. As
sure. Such social processes include, for example, dis- on modelling and some empirical data taken from Ethi- such, some of the critiques in this section are limited and
crimination on the basis of gender, class, ethnicity, age, opia and Uganda. In this regard, the limited observable partial when considering poverty reduction and inequal-
and (dis)ability.” empirical data is highlighted. Section 3.3 then presents ity as explicit long-term goals and objectives.
the linkages between a green economy transition and
Some publications, by international organisations such
income inequality, with a focus on equality of incomes,
as the OECD and World Bank, have argued that a green
natural resource access, and climate vulnerability
economy transition in developing countries is ‘neces-
and emissions. Finally, Section 3.4 considers a green
sary to achieve sustainable development’ (World Bank,
economy transition in the context of gender equality,
2012). This core argument, as Resnick et al. submits, is
and examines both the traditional literature focusing on
based on the evident failings of following the ‘conven-
the unequal burdens of environmental degradation, as
tional development theory’ path (Resnick, 2012). Indeed,
well as a more radical feminist interpretation of a green
upon reviewing publications by the World Bank, ADB,
economy transition being needed to free women from
ESCAP, UN Environment, and OECD, and based on
patriarchal economic systems.
CHAPTER 7: INCLUSION, POVERTY REDUCTION AND GENDER EQUITY FOR A GREEN ECONOMY 7.5
hypothetical and empirical analysis, Scott et al. (2013) A second critique raises the opposite concern – that their comparative advantages and past investments,
argue that green economy can bring ‘poverty reduc- green growth is too closely linked to the earlier eco- economically costly and face popular resistance’.
tion, economic growth, reduced vulnerability to climate nomic models of neoclassical growth (see Chapter 2).
change and natural disasters, greater energy security, For instance, Becher (2012) argues that ‘the assumption This literature also considers the potential impacts a
and more secure livelihoods for those directly dependent underlying economic policies – that growth automatically green economy transition can have on jobs in develop-
on the use of natural resources’. brings prosperity, or for that matter, greater justice – has ing countries. A green economy requires low-carbon
proven to be false’. These arguments similarly oppose climate resilient investments and investments in natural
However, at least two main economic critiques to the the financialization of natural capital, which is framed capital to create green jobs (Bowen & Kuralbayeva,
literature relating to development and poverty reduc- within the traditional neo-liberal economy mode of think- 2015). Green livelihoods therefore depend on the cre-
tion have been put forward. As a sceptic of the green ing (Scott et al., 2013:5; McAfee, 2012). ation of entrepreneurial opportunities and decent jobs,
economy model, the economist Dercon (2012) argues and to this end a green economy can influence the
that ’conventional growth may provide a more rapid The emerging theoretical literature also focuses on two labour market by creating new employment opportu-
route out of poverty.’ Dercon further argues that given necessary components for a green economy transition: nities where previous jobs had been lost (see Chapter
their level of poverty and high dependency on natural state capacity and sufficient finance. A green economy 5 for a full discussion of the impact of Green Economy
resources and natural capital, the ‘poor are likely to often requires, at the initial stage, state structural trans- on labour). In this regard, the proponents of green
suffer most due to their low resources for mitigation and formation and huge capital investment. However, chal- economy argue that the overall net expansion of jobs
for investment in adaptation’ (2011). In addition, con- lenges regarding the ‘absorptive capacity’ for innova- would have a positive effect (OECD, 2013). This is par-
cerns have been raised regarding the trade-offs that tive green technology among developing countries is ticularly important when taking into account the high
must be taken for advancing green economy transitions evident, and the transition may be ‘too costly for LICs youth unemployment rates in most low-income countries.
within national development strategies. As Resnick et and potentially a constraint on their economic develop- However, countering this position, some writers contend
al. (2012:1) argue these pose ‘more trade-offs than is ment’ (Scott et al., 2013:10-12). The question of afford- that the technological advancement and mechanisa-
readily acknowledged’. Here, it is submitted that the ability then, with many developing countries already tion of several economic sectors, as part of a green
focus of green growth strategies essentially remains to facing overstretched public finances, is important. economy transition, can lead to unemployment among
reduce carbon emissions, and that doing so requires the poor who live in both urban and rural areas. These
that countries deviate from both the prescriptions of con- In this regard, there have also been huge disparities economists argue that a green economy is anticipated
ventional development theory, as well as their current between the levels of climate finance awarded to devel- to be highly based on certain technology and industri-
development trajectories. Therefore, while the long-term oping continents, with Asian and Latin American coun- alisation processes, and that these may benefit more
environmental benefits in this context could be size- tries receiving a significantly greater amount than their educated, skilled workers; and this can negatively affect
able, the initial short-term societal and economic costs African counterparts do. It is therefore submitted that, in the millions of poor people whose livelihoods depend on
are likely to be particularly felt by the poorest members Africa, the proposed economic transformation under a labour-intensive employment, especially in agriculture
of society. These trade-offs are explored further in green economy can potentially be an obstacle for growth (Barbier, 2015).
Section 4. and poverty reduction. Indeed, in the cases of Malawi,
Mozambique and South Africa, Resnick et al. (2012) Finally, the literature also speaks about the need to
conclude that green economy ‘may be inconsistent with ensure that natural resource revenues are carefully
CHAPTER 7: INCLUSION, POVERTY REDUCTION AND GENDER EQUITY FOR A GREEN ECONOMY 7.6
managed in order to benefit the poor and to sustain ‘lack of a model’ is indeed creating uncertainty for devel- mation Plan. Our goal is quickly to improve the living
future finance flows — maintaining these as a resource oping countries in pursuing a green economy transition. conditions of our people by reaching a middle-income
‘blessing’ rather than a resource ‘curse’ (Auty, 2001). status by 2025 based on carbon-neutral growth.”
Revenue flows from natural resources — such as min- However, some countries are nevertheless making
erals, land, forests, and fisheries — are more critical to attempts to seize opportunities that might be presented (FDRE, 2011: 5)
low-income than to high-income countries, a depen- by pursuing a green economy transition, and reviewing
some of these national initiatives can provide a basis To this end, it is stated that the CRGE, which deploys
dency that has increased with commodity price booms a ‘sectoral approach’ and identifies more than 60 pri-
(Isham et al., 2005). It is therefore vital that these reve- for developing corresponding activities. Some of the
countries that have taken these steps include Columbia, oritised national initiatives for advancing the green
nues are used in ways that benefit the poor, both through economy transition, can enable Ethiopia to become a
revenue-sharing schemes, and to secure future revenue China, India, Ethiopia, and Uganda. For now, our focus
here is on Uganda and Ethiopia, and the green economy middle-income country ‘while limiting 2030 GHG emis-
streams through the management of the natural resource sions to around today’s 150 Mt CO2e – around 250 Mt
base (Ploeg, 2011; OECD, 2008). transition in an African context. Sub-Saharan Africa had
the biggest group of people in extreme poverty com- CO2e less than estimated under a conventional develop-
pared to other regions in the world in 2015 and the World ment path’ (FDRE, 2011).
Bank (2017) projected the trend to continue until 2030.
3.2 Applied economic literature on a In line with the theoretical literature examined in Section
3.1, these country modelling calculations conducted at
green economy in low-income Advancing the green economy agenda is seen, for gov-
the national level highlight the need for major financing,
countries: Country data ernments of the global south, to be part of their foreign
policy and diplomatic efforts to create a positive state often with huge external investment, to unlock the full
There is limited data from modelling or actual empirical image or brand at the global level (Death, 2011). Ethio- potential of a green economy transition. For instance,
work conducted on the interlinkages between poverty pia, while representing African interests at COP15, took in Uganda it is estimated that an annual investment of
reduction, development, and the transition to a green on a leading role in elaborating the common position of US$1.8 billion is needed until 2020 to meet its green
economy in low-income countries. As Scott et al. (2013) the African countries and, in doing so, served to create a economy objectives (NCE & GoU, 2016). In the case of
pointed out, macro-level ‘research on the costs and ben- new state brand at the global stage. Indeed, while Ethio- Ethiopia, initial estimates for achieving a green economy
efits’ of a green economy transition has not yet been pia is a low-income country, it decided to be a leader in detailed a total expenditure requirement of around
carried out within many developing countries. This lack the global and national greening agenda by launching US$150 billion over the next 20 years, ‘with around US$
of a green economy ‘champion’ for a model transition its Climate Resilient Green Economy (CRGE) Strategy in 80 billion of required funding estimated to be capital
within a developing country context, and the subsequent 2011. The following quote, made by the late Prime Min- investment and the remaining US$70 billion assessed
unproven results (Jacobs, 2013) is creating uncertainty ister Meles Zenawi, reflects the new ambitious direction as being necessary to cover operating and program
and deterring many developing countries from pursuing that the country decided to pursue. expenses’ (FDRE, 2011). The CRGE, recognising this
this approach. Developing countries are struggling to huge financing gap, calls for the mobilization of addi-
find a showcase “green economy country” with a similar “We have therefore embarked upon the development tional resources from both international climate finance
initial level of economic development but reaching a of a CRGE strategy addressing both climate change and the private sector, requiring additional state capac-
high degree of economic growth with the transition. The adaptation and mitigation objectives […] which will be ity and the development of a CRGE Facility to oversee
fully integrated into our five-year Growth and Transfor- this project preparation. To this end, the CRGE Strat-
CHAPTER 7: INCLUSION, POVERTY REDUCTION AND GENDER EQUITY FOR A GREEN ECONOMY 7.7
egy reformed the Environment Protection Authority to ‘boost to economic activity, worth around 10 per cent
give it the status of an executive body with a ministerial Box 7.2: Organic agriculture in Uganda of GDP by 2040 compared to business as usual (BAU)
mandate – making it the Ministry of Environment, For- deliver employment of up to 4 million [green] jobs; and
estry, and Climate Change. Inclusive green economy within the agriculture sector would entail an reduce future greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions by
increase in sustainable farming practices, including organic production,
and an increase in food productivity. Agriculture is a dominant sector in 28 per cent relative to a conventional growth pathway’
However, despite the initial investment required, Ethi- most African economies, accounting for 32 per cent of Africa’s GDP and (Ibid). For instance, Uganda plans to create up to 4
opia’s transition to a green economy is expected to supporting about 65 per cent of the labour force (AGRA, 2013). As such,
million green jobs by 2040 (NCE & GoU, 2016). While
targeted green investment in the sector could yield long-term positive
provide significant positive pay-offs. Indeed, ‘for more results and generate the highest social impacts with regards to the some of these green job opportunities are projected on
than 80 per cent of the abatement potential, abatement economy and food security.
the basis of future initiatives, there is evidence of some
costs are less than US$15 per Mt CO2e. Many of the ini- In Eastern Africa, the amount of land under organic production has progress already being made in Uganda, such as in the
tiatives offer positive returns on investments, thus directly been expanding. Between 2000 and 2012, land under organic produc-
sector of organic agriculture (see Box 7.2).
tion grew more than 20-fold (UNECA, 2016). Uganda currently has the
promoting economic growth and creating additional biggest proportion of land under organic cultivation (Willer and Lernoud,
jobs with high value-added’ (NCE & GoU, 2016). The 2014), and accounts for 16 per cent of Africa’s total. Ethiopia and the To conclude, modelling data is starting to emerge on
United Republic of Tanzania also have significant areas of organic agri-
ambitious strategy to transform Ethiopia to a middle-in- cultural land, with 13 per cent and 12 per cent respectively.
how a green economy can contribute to development
come status, and in a short timeframe, has prioritised in low-income countries, but this is still primarily based
In Uganda, organic products represent an important source of export
the forestry, agriculture, energy, and transport sectors for earnings for the state, and provide revenue for smallholder farmers.
on hypothetical modelling promoted by exponents of
investment. For instance, the huge hydropower poten- Certified organic exports increased from US$3.7 million in 2003-2004 to a green economy transition. Meanwhile, critics of this
tial of the country, demonstrated through megaprojects US$6.2 million in 2004-2005, before jumping to US$22.8 million in 2007- transition focus primarily on the possible imposition of
2008.
like the Renaissance Dam (with about 6,000 megawatt short-term societal and economic costs on the poorest
capacity), is expected to positively contribute towards Through organic farming, Uganda not only gains economically but also members of society. However, it is argued that these
contributes to mitigating the effects of climate change, as greenhouse
the country’s generation of clean energy. emissions per hectare are estimated to be on average 64 per cent lower critics fail to properly consider long-term sustainability of
than emissions produced on conventional farms. In sum, Uganda has traditional growth models, and whether these will lead to
Similarly, Uganda’s national green strategy aims to make taken an apparent liability – limited access to chemical inputs – and
lasting poverty reduction. This dichotomy arises from a
turned this into a comparative advantage by growing its organic agri-
it an upper-middle income country by 2040, and ‘a green culture base, thereby generating revenue and income for smallholder lack of observable empirical data and actual experience
growth leader in the region’ (NCE & GoU, 2016: v-vi). To farmers.
over time. While this section has identified some excep-
this end, its recently developed Green Growth paper, Source: UN Environment, 2010 and UNECA, 2016 tions to this, such as the growth of organic agriculture in
entitled Achieving Uganda’s Development Ambition – Uganda, contributing to poverty reduction in the short-
The Economic Impact of Green Growth: An Agenda for term, generally it will be some time before independent
Action and published in November 2016, aims to accel- and observable macro-economic empirical data will
erate the country’s economic development in a way that Vision 2040 strategy. This strategy estimates that a 3 per allow the impacts and effectiveness of a green economy
ensures ‘growth is socially inclusive and that the protec- cent increase to the annual public budget, financed by transition in low-income countries to be assessed.
tion of the environment is upheld’ (NCE & GoU, 2016). the development and climate communities, will bring
This document is intended to complement and enhance an economic benefit of ‘US$3 for every dollar invested,
Uganda’s Second National Development Plan and its even excluding wider benefits’. With full implementation
of its green strategy, Uganda expects to experience a
CHAPTER 7: INCLUSION, POVERTY REDUCTION AND GENDER EQUITY FOR A GREEN ECONOMY 7.8
3.3 Economic literature on green economy nomic growth and income inequality can be neutral, pos- are very inequitably distributed and controlled by certain
transition and inequality itive or negative (Chen & Guo, 2002), or take the shape elites, the overall economic growth rate is reduced (Auty,
of an inverted U (Kuznets, 1955,). In this regard, the 2001).
Inequality is important because of its fundamental asso- ‘Kuznets Curve’ submits that inequality is low (negative)
ciations with income or wealth, ethnicity, gender, and the at initial levels of growth, increases (positive) as income Increasing evidence also suggests that climate change
power to access or control natural resources. Inequality levels increase, before falling again once an average has a direct ‘cause and effect’ relationship with inequal-
can also determine vulnerability to the effects of climate level of income is reached. Aghion et al. (1999), based ity – that the effects of climate change can be a cause
change, the capacity to respond to green growth ben- on cross-country empirical studies, found a negative for income inequality, while income inequality itself
efits (such as green jobs), and the impacts of green correlation between the average rate of growth and mea- increases vulnerability to climate change, creating a
policies (UNRISD, 2012). More recently, the economist sures of inequality. The compilation of household-level reinforcing circle. Indeed, a recent study in Nature by
Thomas Piketty has argued that inequality is deeply data from developing countries also suggested little or Burke et al. (2015) found that unchecked climate change
rooted politically and thus cannot be determined or no correlation between growth (and indicators of growth is likely to reduce global average incomes per capita by
dealt with by economic mechanisms alone; rather, that promoting policies) and its effects on inequality across roughly 23 per cent by the year 2100, but that this figure
knowledge and skills diffusion are the two converging countries (Ravallion, 2001), and this reaffirmed the will vary considerably depending on where a country
forces essential to economic growth and the reduction of conclusions of Dollar and Kraay (2000) that economic is located. According to Burke et al. (2015), climate
inequality (Piketty, 2014). growth has a low direct impact on inequality (UN Envi- change will reduce average incomes in the poorest
ronment, 2011). countries by 75 per cent in the year 2100, while the
The identifiable links between economic growth and the richest countries may actually experience slight income
social pillars of sustainable development have generally With regards to other aspects of a green economy tran- gains. Climate change is therefore predicted to signifi-
shown to be positive and complimentary (Hallegate et sition, such as access to natural resources and vul- cantly increase global patterns of inequality.
al., 2012; Dollar & Kraay, 2002), and even more so in the nerability to the effects of climate change, the links to
presence of policies that reduce inequality. In economic inequality is much clearer. Firstly, it has been shown In this regard, inequality of income can also exacerbate
theory, wealth inequality is directly related to the capac- that more equal access to natural resources promotes climate change as high-income individuals are much
ity to invest in physical or human capital, which in turn economic growth, and that inequality of access has the more likely to emit greenhouse gases. To this end, a
affects the long-term growth rate (Aghion et al., 1999). opposite effect. High levels of inequality in the distribu- recent article by Piketty and others found that “Global
However, this conclusion has been challenged by recent tion of income and tenure to land appear to slow eco- CO2e emissions remain highly concentrated today: top
‘degrowth’ literature (Jackson, 2017), which argues that nomic growth and restrict the opportunities for pro-poor 10 per cent emitters contribute to about 45 per cent of
beyond a certain level of income, growth may in fact growth (Aghion et al., 1999, Ravallion, 2001). Studies of global emissions, while bottom 50 per cent emitters con-
have negative impacts – in particular, by increasing post-war land reform in Korea and Taiwan, on the other tribute to 13 per cent of global emissions. Top 10 per
inequality, as will be seen below. hand, showed that a reduction in inequality helped to cent emitters live on all continents, with one third of them
foster rapid and broad economic growth. In addition, the from emerging countries” (Chancel & Piketty, 2015).
The question as to whether income growth causes natural resource ‘curse’ (as considered in Section 3.1)
inequality continues to be contested both theoretically submits that where certain natural resources (particularly
and empirically. Theoretical relationships between eco- hydrocarbons, but also hard rock mineral and forests)
CHAPTER 7: INCLUSION, POVERTY REDUCTION AND GENDER EQUITY FOR A GREEN ECONOMY 7.9
indoors. Green economy initiatives that promote the use tion, raise financing, and acquire relevant technology.
Box 7.3: Green economy investments in of cleaner energies can therefore have positive cor- Therefore, it is submitted that gender needs to be central
responding effects on gender equality (see Box 7.3 - in developing ‘environmentally friendly technology’
energy for gender benefits example from Bangladesh). (ENERGIA et al., 2011:3). In many developing countries,
A pioneer in renewable energy production and distribution, Grameen women are often unable to seize the new benefits asso-
Shakti has been operating in Bangladesh for the last 20 years. The not- Another linkage between gender equality and green ciated with green economy, including ‘improved agricul-
for-profit organization provides renewable energy services, such as solar economy relates to job creation. Globally, while the gen-
energy or biogas, to households for electricity generation and cooking. ture management […] due to patriarchal attitudes and
eration of green jobs is expected to create a wide array social conditioning’ (ENERGIA et al., 2011:3). This cri-
This benefits women in two respects: 1) Women are able to reduce of opportunities for women, this can go both ways. As
the time-consuming, tiring, and often unpleasant and even dangerous tique also contends that ‘a gender-equality perspective
work of gathering biomass fuel; and 2) Grameen Shakthi has trained a ENERGIA et al. (2011:2) point out, greening initiatives is still missing from the mainstream understanding of the
growing pool of female energy technicians, allowing women to benefit that aim to generate ‘green jobs’ in the informal sector concept, which is based on a traditional interpretation
from the production side of renewable energy. There is now a network
of ‘Grameen technology centres’ (GTCs), with most of these being can in ‘some cases even be a threat to women’s liveli- of the economy, focusing on growth while ignoring the
managed by women engineers. These GTCs train other women as hoods’. There is also the question as to whether infor- value of care work’ (2012:20). On this basis, it is submit-
technicians through a two-week course, in which they learn to assemble
equipment and how to install and maintain solar home systems. Some mal jobs, such as domestic work and the engagement ted that a green economy transition that fails to value the
women are then given further training on how to repair these. As of 2008, of women in agriculture and food production, can be care and domestic contributions of women does not fully
20 GTCs had trained over 1,000 technicians; with at least 300 of these
technicians working either for the GTCs or on their own. considered ‘decent jobs’ under a green economy transi- depart from conventional economic approaches.
tion. For example, some jobs involve the use of harmful
Source: Ashden, https://www.ashden.org/winners/grameen-shakti
chemicals – ‘women in the flower industry are exposed
to pesticides, and women hairdressers use chemicals
linked to breast cancer,’ meaning that women often ‘have
different health risks from working with chemicals than
4. Managing trade-offs: Why
3.4 Economic literature on green economy inclusion, poverty reduction and
men’ (ENERGIA et al., 2011:5). Green jobs therefore
and gender equality need to be introduced in ways that do not undermine
employment opportunities for women.
gender equality are
The emerging literature on the relationship between a
green economy transition and gender equality high-
not inevitable outcomes of a
Finally, the literature on gender equality and a green
lights the strong linkages between the two. Traditionally, economy transition has given rise to a more radical cri- green economy
this literature has focused on how a green economy will tique: that in order to become more effective within a
provide benefits to poor women in terms of health, live- The previous sections have served to demonstrate that
green economy context, women first need to be freed by placing green growth at the heart of their develop-
lihoods, and vulnerability. For example, in most devel- from current patriarchal systems. This includes eco-
oping countries women bear the principal responsibility ment objectives, governments can generally achieve
nomic, legal, and political constraints which limit their sustainable economic growth and social stability (OECD,
for collecting and then using household forms of energy ability to own and control land and, restrict their rights
– often generated from biomass – and thus spend much 2013) and bring long-term sustainable benefits to the
to access natural resources, and often prevent them poor (Raworth et al., 2014). However, emerging theoreti-
of their time not only travelling to collect the biomass, from obtaining necessary training, to access informa-
but also facing harmful smoke exposure when cooking cal literature by Dercon, Hallegate and Barbier highlight
CHAPTER 7: INCLUSION, POVERTY REDUCTION AND GENDER EQUITY FOR A GREEN ECONOMY 7.10
a number of potential trade-offs to these benefits, as settlements or rural houses in Bangladesh and other of environmental externalities (e.g. through a ‘Carbon
initially considered in the previous section. If not compli- climatically vulnerable locations. This is an area where tax’) may lead to higher energy prices for consumers.
mented by integrated policies, these trade-offs can have further attention is required. They may also have income and distributive effects – a
negative impacts on the poor: ‘Carbon tax,’ for example, is likely to reduce the number
• Moving from labour intensive, more poverty-reducing of jobs in the polluting, fossil fuel industries (Hallegate
• Increases to fossil fuel prices, if not complemented technology to more capital intensive and less poverty et al., 2012). However, green economy policies can
by other policies, can strongly affect those poor con- reducing technology, such as the development of succeed if the external costs of these policies are con-
sumers who have no alternative but to continue to pur- high-tech, clean technology for energy, agriculture, tained, ensuring that they do not disproportionately
chasing fossil fuels. and transport, may potentially reduce job and employ- affect the poorer members of society (Huberty et al.,
ment opportunities for the poor. 2011). For example, removing fossil fuel subsidies and
• The closure of coal mines, often found in the poorer
parts of a country, can have significant impacts on • Green economy initiatives, which carry high health providing direct cash transfers to low-income house-
coal miners who have limited employment alternatives. costs, such as rare earth metal mining (e.g. cobalt) holds (as in the case of Indonesia), or promoting higher
for renewable technologies and batteries, often dis- government spending on other public development
• An increase in biofuel production, intended to reduce proportionately affect the very poorest members of objectives such as health and education (as in the case
greenhouse gas emissions, can displace land for food society. For instance, artisanal miners in many African of Ghana), has shown that such policies can signifi-
crops, negatively impacting poor rural food producers. countries are exposed to serious pollutants on a daily cantly improve the living conditions and wellbeing of the
Indeed, “land grabbing” for biofuel production by cor- basis, as well as the conflict and negative social poorest (OECD, 2013).
porates and state-led mega-investments has, in many impacts experienced in mining regions.
cases, driven Indigenous and rural communities off of To this end, Dercon (2011) conducted a study in 2011
their own land, leading to an increase in conflicts in An IGE does not operate in a vacuum (UNECA, 2016). in which he deployed a number of stylized examples
many communities. The green economy does not automatically increase of green growth initiatives, assessed their effects and
social justice, and must be complemented by inte- impact on the poor. His analysis focused on three main
• The use of scarce natural resources for green, grated policymaking processes and a holistic outcome categories of green growth policies (environmental
non-poverty reducing investments. For instance, framework which combines environmental, social and pricing and regulation, low-carbon investments, and
climate proofing (e.g. protecting against floods and economic objectives, so that the costs of greening the adaptation investment), and he tested these in four
storms) public infrastructure such as roads, ports and economy do not fall on women and men living in poverty spatial and sectoral dimensions. These dimensions are
industrial estates is more likely to benefit the wealthier (Raworth et al., 2014). Thus, as the trade-offs above now crucial in understanding the dynamic relationship
members of society. To this point, the focus of climate serve to illustrate, green economy policies do have the between economic growth and the inclusiveness of
proofing physical infrastructure has generally been for potential to cause inequalities (Barbier, 2015) and their growth in low-income and least developed countries.
the economic benefits to the economy as a whole, with ultimate effect is dependent on them being compli-
only a limited consideration of the distributional and First, he found that environmental pricing and regula-
mented by other integrated policies. tion intended to internalise environmental costs (such
poverty reduction benefits (UNDP, 2011). However,
there are now programmes to climate proof capital that Indeed, green economy policies can have both negative as fuel or water pricing at full cost) might impact poor
are important for poor people, such as low-income and positive impacts – for instance, the internalization people (as consumers and producers) through rising
CHAPTER 7: INCLUSION, POVERTY REDUCTION AND GENDER EQUITY FOR A GREEN ECONOMY 7.11
prices, while the wealthy could circumnavigate envi- costs of coal are included (such as its negative impacts
ronmental regulations by simply displacing pollution Box 7.4: Successful energy subsidy on health and outdoor air pollution), renewables can
to low-income areas. The design and enforcement of be seen to be the more cost-effective option. At the
regulations as part of green growth policies is therefore reforms in Kenya same time, however, increases to fossil fuel prices (e.g.
central to determining whether these will benefit the In Kenya, energy subsidy reforms were made under a new energy policy through the removal of fossil fuel subsidies) could also
in 2004. The policy increased power tariffs in 2005 to reflect long-term
poor. Second, Dercon found that low-carbon and other marginal costs, introduced an automatic pass-through mechanism to
potentially have negative impacts on the poor. As such,
environmentally friendly investment strategies could adjust tariffs for changes in fuel costs, and reconstituted the Electricity it is important for governments to be aware of these tran-
Regulatory Commission as an independent energy regulator.
promote and mobilize investment at a local level (such sition costs and to ensure that they favour the excluded
as by supporting growth-focused on local linkages, such The new policy led to significant improvements in the electricity sector as and poor, as shown by the example of energy subsidy
power generation steadily increased, distribution losses declined, and
as agriculture close to cities). However, such strategies the number of customers served by grid-supplied power expanded sub-
reforms in Kenya (see Box 7.4). This can be achieved by
could also discourage investment in more rural, marginal stantially. In the post-tariff increase period, the average annual increase shifting the savings made by removing fossil fuel subsi-
areas from common shared development as the cost of in national power supply was over 5 per cent. Line losses declined from dies into social programs and initiatives that benefit the
18 per cent in 2005 to 16 per cent in 2011, and the collection rates
long-distance transport could be a factor holding back increased from 85 per cent of total power bills in 2005 to 99 per cent in poor. Such initiatives have been successfully introduced
the investment, which may lead to geographical imbal- 2011. Indeed, electricity access in Kenya increased by almost 140 per in Indonesia, Ghana, Mexico, and Germany, where the
cent between 2005 and 2011.
ance. Finally, his study found that adaptation measures costs under a green economy transition have been
generate the strongest trade-offs for the poor. Instead Political support for the process was achieved through prior consultation cushioned by social protection reforms and programs.
with trade unions, which helped to mitigate potential job losses. On the
of encouraging economic transformation and migration, basis of these reforms, the increase in revenues would also be used to
rural adaptation measures may actually encourage the expand energy access, with the newly reconstituted Electricity Regula- A second, important trade-off is the use of greener,
rural poor to invest in low-return livelihoods. In addition,
tory Commission to promote integrity and more transparent processes. cleaner technology, which can potentially produce
investments in public infrastructure may be centred on Source: IMF (2013) more (energy) outputs while using fewer polluting and/
the most economically valuable assets at the expense or natural capital inputs. However, it will also have
of poor communities based in marginal and unsuitable impacts on other types of assets and may, for example,
areas, making them increasingly vulnerable to climate require more or less labour or capital inputs. Again,
shocks. One common example of a trade-off would be any this may negatively impact poor women and men, and
short-term increases in energy prices before renew- the impacts of these technologies therefore need to
As earlier sections have demonstrated, the medium and able energy prices can compete with the lower market be carefully assessed before being introduced to a
long-term benefits of a green economy transition are rates for fossil fuels. In many cases, this will bring country. Indeed, while internet connectivity and high-
clear and, if implemented correctly, can provide tangible immediate benefits to the poor. First, renewables are tech approaches will always be important aspects of
benefits to the excluded and poor. However, the transi- now price-competitive (half the new energy-generating a green economy transition, it does not require only
tion may also carry many costs, and these are essen- capacity installed in 2014 across the world was renew- imported or high-cost high technology. Instead, an inclu-
tially the costs of moving from unsustainable production able). Second, poor people in remote locations often sive approach to a green economy transition will aim
and consumption processes to ones that are sustain- live too far from the grid to utilize traditional power sup- to identify and support local technical knowledge, as
able. It is therefore vital that these transition costs are not plies, and thus decentralized renewables may represent well as innovations compatible with informal economies.
borne by the excluded and poor. a more convenient option. Finally, when the external Energy-efficient cookers made from local materials,
CHAPTER 7: INCLUSION, POVERTY REDUCTION AND GENDER EQUITY FOR A GREEN ECONOMY 7.12
bicycle-based transportation, and local mobile phone 5. How to increase inclusion, their lack of a political voice on the global stage is seen
apps are good examples of affordable technologies that as being a cause of these wider problems. As such, it
can directly benefit poor groups. In this regard, social poverty reduction, and gender is submitted that a systematic change, with new gover-
enterprises can be good brokers for finding, testing, and equity as outcomes of nance institutions, is required at the global level (Action
extending appropriate technologies that produce the 2). As rights-holders, poor women and men must be
inclusive and green outcomes that are sought by these green economy transition able to hold duty-bearers accountable for their actions
groups. For example, the solar water heater program This final section reviews the existing literature on recom- (MRFCJ, 2015). These duty-bearers are those acting
in Bangladesh, as detailed in Box 7.3, is supported by mendations for advancing a green economy transition at the governmental or state levels, who have a legal
social enterprises and aims to maximize benefits for the that increases inclusion, poverty reduction, and gender obligation to protect, respect, and fulfill the rights of the
excluded and poor: low-income women act as produc- equality. These will be considered under the following rights-holder (UN, 2016). To this end, it is contended that
ers and distributors and, as a result, thousands of female four main areas (which need to be pursued together): an empowerment and human rights-based strategy, con-
jobs have been created. sistent with the UN Declaration of Human Rights, should
(i) Empowerment be pursued as part of the broader SDG implementation
A third and final trade-off may occur when prevailing process at the global level.
governance and fiscal rules for access to and control (ii) Integrated institutions
over natural resources work against the social and In many developing countries, marginalized producers
institutional capital of the poor. It is often mistakenly (iii) Inclusive finance; and who operate through micro/small enterprises within the
assumed that simply increasing the value of natural (iv) Metrics informal economy still form the backbone of that coun-
assets and capital, such as through increasing land try’s economic activity. Smallholder agriculture remains
prices for biofuel production or receiving, will benefit the principal form of employment in many countries,
the excluded and poor. Instead, these higher prices 5.1 Empowerment with women often being the main source of agricultural
may lead to higher demand and ‘land grabs’ and ‘green labor. Meanwhile, the non-agricultural informal economy
grabs’ that subsequently exclude the poor from access- Increase empowerment and rights: recognising, continues to grow and now accounts for 82 per cent of
ing natural capital. Greater resource and tenure rights empowering and engaging poor women and men — the total non-agricultural employment in South Asia, 66
must therefore accompany these increases in natural so that they can be effective agents and rights-hold- per cent in sub-Saharan Africa, and 51 per cent in Latin
resource prices for the poor (Cotula and Mathieu, 2008). ers in their own future America (ILO, 2014). Indeed, the informal economy is
Improvements to land governance are especially import- now encouraging innovative developments in a range of
ant for women who, while often being the primary farm Poor people are actors for, and the holders of, univer- sectors, including energy, water, sanitation and transport
workers, have limited land and tenure rights (Kisambu, sal human rights. They also possess the most credible provision.
2016). voices in terms of drawing the world’s attention to the
poverty, environmental and climate agendas – these are Poor women and men, then, can be a central compo-
all issues that disproportionately affect their livelihoods. nent in advancing the transition to a green economy – as
However, prevailing dialogue and decision-making struc- empowered citizens able to upgrade slums, as custodi-
tures are often closed to this group of population and ans of natural resources, as labour intensive producers,
CHAPTER 7: INCLUSION, POVERTY REDUCTION AND GENDER EQUITY FOR A GREEN ECONOMY 7.13
and as distributors of low carbon technologies and prod- 5.2 Institutions ment and new landscape/spatial modelling providing
ucts. Informal labour markets should therefore be sup- clearer ideas on the consequences of multi-factorial
ported (e.g. to achieve higher wages), and governments Developing integrated, inclusive and transformative decisions – and all increasingly in real time.
should resist attempts to criminalize or close them. institutions — including for collective action on mul- If the work completed to date has focused on integrated
Instead, in those cases where informal labour markets tiple systemic risks and opportunities assessments, plans, and projects, this should now be
do have negative environmental and health impacts on Poverty, environmental and climate issues affect stake- expanded to encompass the development of integrated
the poor (such as in some small-scale mining, and waste holders across a variety of different sectors, and solu- governance frameworks and institutional capacities.
recycling and disposal), the provision of technological tions to these problems accordingly require collection This is certainly an ambitious aim, given that poverty,
and training support can help to shift informality along action from a wide range of organizations. On this basis, environmental and climate problems are themselves the
the spectrum from ‘dirty’ and ‘illegal’, to ‘professional’ the international community needs to build more and result of deep structural failures. So while systematic,
and ‘efficient’. stronger bridges between these individual organisations, institutional reform may at first appear daunting, a lot can
and to promote synergies and collaborative practices, be achieved in smaller steps. Moreover, to begin this
Doing so requires a formal, institutional process and, process, sequencing and priorities should first be deter-
when organized by governments or state/private cor- which benefit the poor. These bridges need to be built
deliberately and systemically — developing integrated mined at the national level, and perhaps in the form of
porations, these can be (inadvertently) exclusionary or a poverty, environment, and climate institutional change
environmentally ineffective. Such processes, if prompted institutions with common rules, knowledge bases, and
norms that achieve a better balance between sustain- roadmap.
by small producers or traders based on their own cap-
itals, knowledge and organization can be more sus- ability, growth, and equity.
tainable; however, these are likely to miss out on other
technological, skills-based and market opportunities.
Two decades of mainstreaming the environmental and 5.3 Finance
climate agendas at the international level have gener-
Instead, through a better understanding of these infor- ated enough theoretical experience to consider how Inclusive finance and business: reforming private
mal actors, as well as the power and agency that they this institutional restructuring may be achieved. On this and public investment — to better engage with the
hold, it is submitted that innovative hybrid approaches basis, three key opportunities may be identified. First, people and environments marginalised by current
can promote rewarding livelihoods and create decent the 2030 Agenda requires governments to generate policy
jobs within these informal environments. In the long-term, national plans for implementing the SDGs within their
education and training programs should complement Together, the 2015 Paris Agreement and 2030 Agenda
respective countries. Second, there is now an increas- for Sustainable Development, promote the need for
these, in order to build a workforce suited and prepared ingly imminent need for the international community
for an inclusive, green future. huge new investments in energy, transport, and urban
to make decisions on issues that will help shape the infrastructure across the world. If done correctly, these
futures, one way or another, for poor people and the investments have the potential to make real progress on
environment (e.g. whether to exploit new fossil discover- poverty, environmental and climate issues.
ies, or where to focus climate change adaptation plans). However, for these investments to achieve the requisite
And third, these decisions are to be facilitated by the scale, the current financial rules need to be changed.
availability of new information and communication tech- These must recognize the interests of all stakeholders
nology and ‘big data,’ with magnified citizen engage-
CHAPTER 7: INCLUSION, POVERTY REDUCTION AND GENDER EQUITY FOR A GREEN ECONOMY 7.14
of innovation, and should prioritize investment quality as
Box 7.5: Social protection schemes well as quantity. Box 7.6: Support for SMMEs in Nepal
starting to address climate and environ- Microfinance, local funds, and social protection schemes In Nepal, the Alternative Energy Promotion Centre has developed a
mental objectives can provide targeted financial instruments that reach targeted subsidy model to enable the most vulnerable households to
adopt renewable energy technologies. Forty per cent of Nepal’s National
those who need it most and so get money to where it Rural Renewable Energy Programme’s US$170 million budget is being
Brazil: The national Bolsa Verde program provides cash payments to
low-income families who adopt practices that conserve trees, fish, and matters (IIED, 2017). Where new finance is brought into disbursed as grants to these households and, depending on the cir-
cumstances, these grants can cover between 30 and 50 per cent of
other natural resources. The scheme targets people in extreme poverty, the economy as a measure to drive green growth, it the cost of buying and installing renewable energy technology (with the
and particularly forest-dependent communities in the Amazon region.
The program distributes more than US$40 million dollars each year to
often fails to consider the benefits that this may provide remainder coming from concessional loans). These grants are delivered
in accordance with Nepal’s Subsidy Policy for Renewable Energy (2013),
more than 69,000 families, and the quarterly payment of 300 Reais that to poor women and men. Indeed in many cases, the which promotes the targeting of poor, vulnerable, and socially marginal-
these receive is nearly double the average quarterly income. poor and excluded are not able to access formal credit ized households.
Ethiopia: The Productive Safety Net Project provides 7 million people, markets, general financial instruments, or even basic Source: Rai et al. (2015) and Steinbach et al. (2015)
who are chronically food insecure, with a predictable transfer of cash or banking loan facilities due to their lack of collateral and
food, in return for labour on schemes that benefit vulnerable communi-
ties. These work schemes include tree planting, water harvesting, and low income earnings, for instance, only a quarter of
the construction of health centres. The project enables vulnerable people adults of sub-Saharan Africa have access to a formal
to resist shocks, accumulate assets and, most importantly of all, to feed
themselves. The project aims to encourage households to engage in bank account (Demirgüç-Kunt el al., 2017). Microfi- Financial mechanisms should also look to prioritize the
production and investment promotes market development by increasing nance, local funds, and social protection schemes can informal economy and Small, Medium and Micro-sized
household purchasing power.
therefore expand this access to financial capital for the Enterprise (SMMEs). In terms of inclusive consumption,
India: Each year, the Mahatma Gandhi National Rural Employment excluded and poor (Steele et al., 2015a). the exploration of major, “bottom of the pyramid” markets
Guarantee Scheme provides tens of millions of people with 100 days of
paid manual work. The scheme creates a legal right to employment, and can better align these mechanisms with the needs of
Social protection can also be designed in a way that
anyone who applies and is not given work within 15 days is entitled to an poor consumers who, as was detailed in Section 5.1,
unemployment allowance. Since 2006, when the scheme began, US$25 is adaptive. In this way, social protection and climate
often operate within informal markets. In order to mobi-
billion has been distributed. Participants work on projects that benefit resilience objectives are linked and targeted towards
their local communities, such as creating infrastructure for water harvest- lize green production, jobs, livelihoods and SMMEs
ing, drought relief, and flood control. those households that are most vulnerable to income
within informal economies should be recognized as
and climate shocks. Other social protection schemes
Source: Steele et al. (2015b) being potential drivers of, IGE growth and especially
are now also starting to address ecological rehabilita-
in those countries where ‘job creation’ represents a
tion through afforestation and water management initia-
primary political concern. Start-up grants provided to
tives (Porras et al., 2016). Examples of these schemes
SMMEs can be a useful tool in this regard (as shown
and not just shareholders, and should consider long- in Brazil, Ethiopia, and India are provided in Box 7.5,
in Box 6), and these work well for projects that may not
term outcomes as well as share prices. There is a need while in South Africa’s “Working for…” programs, public
generate revenue, but are otherwise ideal for promoting
to engage those who, while not having contributed to works schemes for cleaning up the nation’s river basins
green growth. However, these grants should be aligned
these issues, can nevertheless play a powerful role in and water bodies are targeted at single-parent female
with other investments to ensure that first; they do not
addressing them. Finance mechanisms will therefore headed households — including those affected by HIV.
increase government expenditure over investments and,
need to be more accessible, integrated, and supportive second, do not provide false market signals. The long-
CHAPTER 7: INCLUSION, POVERTY REDUCTION AND GENDER EQUITY FOR A GREEN ECONOMY 7.15
term effects of these grants and subsidies should also environment, and climate (such as the judicious use general public to use the system to inform national
be monitored, and subsidies should be phased out once of economic information, but also incorporating ethical decision-making and transparency.
markets have been developed. arguments, people-centred stories of change, ‘wellbe-
ing’ measures, and ways to ‘brand’ poverty, environ- • Today’s ‘data revolution’ provides many opportunities
ment, and climate). that are yet to be harnessed. Information and commu-
nication technology and ‘big data’ can help us build
5.4 Metrics • A conceptual framework that best expresses the links a picture on how poverty and the environment relate
New messages and metrics: improving and aligning between poverty, environment, and climate, and which in specific cases, as well as the effects and impacts
poverty, environment, and climate messages, nar- is scientifically credible, robust to diverse biophysi- that previous interventions have had. This will help the
ratives, and metrics – to inspire widespread under- cal, social, and economic realities, policy-influencing, international community to progress from the drawing
standing of poverty, environment, and climate issues, and can be used throughout the whole policy cycle of crude trade-offs between poverty, environment, and
and to galvanise and measure progress (from assessment to debate, modelling, planning, and climate, to achieving better distributional results and
accounting). This framework could be based on two correlations which can optimize synergies and inte-
A positive narrative promoting the poverty-environ- reviews: gration. In addition, new technology, such as mobile
ment-climate nexus is now needed. A narrative that is phones, can enable poor people to become powerful
based on enduring prosperity, and perhaps on joint • A review of existing frameworks, including the steps data producers and receivers. They can bridge the
human and ecosystem wellbeing, could have increasing countries have taken to implement the SDGs (and disconnect between global and very local, service
political traction as extreme poverty declines but climate especially the nine poverty, environment, and climate providers and service demanders, and thus enhance
change and ecosystem degradation impacts really related SDGs noted in Table 2); learning and accountability.
begin to ‘bite’. New players, such as BRICS (New Devel-
• A review of how the Millennium Ecosystem Assess-
opment) Banks, locally controlled development funds,
ment’s ecosystem service-wellbeing framework has
and domestic markets, now need to work alongside the
been adopted and adapted by different disciplines,
UN and other development agencies that have until now
from economists, to statisticians, to natural scientists. 6. Conclusion
led the poverty, environment, and climate agendas to
establish a clear and coherent set of poverty, environ- • Rolling out the System of Environmental Economic This chapter provided an understanding on the link-
ment, and climate planning and performance standards. Accounts. Under the auspices of the UN Statisti- ages between inclusion, poverty and gender equality,
cal Division, the System of Environmental Economic and the transition to a green economy. It demonstrated
These standards will require cross-disciplinary collabo- that poverty reduction is not an automatic outcome of
Accounts has now been agreed at the international
ration, and must engage multiple stakeholders from all green economy interventions and that trade-offs do
level, with the Wealth Accounting and Valuation of
(and not just developing) countries in order to produce exist. However, the recommendations put forward in this
Ecosystems (WAVES) initiative, led by the World Bank,
a message that is universally acknowledged and chapter can provide a guidance for learners and deci-
providing support to countries for implementation. Yet
accepted. This message should include: sion makers on research, evidence and best practise,
more is still needed to generate the necessary phys-
• Communication strategies that can successfully influ- ical and economic data for the system, and to create and thus help maximising identified links and syner-
ence positive decision making regarding poverty, the necessary demand among policymakers and the gies between inclusion, poverty reduction, and gender
CHAPTER 7: INCLUSION, POVERTY REDUCTION AND GENDER EQUITY FOR A GREEN ECONOMY 7.16
equality. A careful consideration of inclusion, poverty
and gender equality, and their fully integration into pol-
icy-making may thus help ensure that the transition to
a green economy promotes social justice among the
poorest members of society.
CHAPTER 7: INCLUSION, POVERTY REDUCTION AND GENDER EQUITY FOR A GREEN ECONOMY 7.17
REFERENCES Dercon, S. (2011) Is Green Growth Good for the Poor. World Bank. Available at http://www.espa.
ac.uk/files/espa/Greengrowth.pdf
Aghion, P., Caroli, E., & Garcia-Penalosa, C. (1999). Inequality and economic growth: the perspec- DFID (2015) Conceptual framework on agriculture. DFID, London. Available at https://www.gov.uk/
tive of the new growth theories. Journal of Economic literature, 37(4), 1615-1660. government/publications/dfids-conceptual-framework-on-agriculture
Auty, R. M. (Ed.). (2001). Resource abundance and economic development. Oxford University DFID, European Commission, UNDP and World Bank (2002) Linking poverty reduction and environ-
Press. mental management policy challenges and opportunities. The International Bank for Recon-
Barbier, E. (2015) Is Green Growth good for poor economies. Available at http://www.ferdi.fr/sites/ struction and Development/The World Bank, Washington DC. Available at www.unpei.org/sites/
www.ferdi.fr/files/publication/fichiers/p144-ferdi_barbier.pdf default/files/publications/Linking-poverty-red-env.pdf
Bass, S., Wang, S., Ferede, T., & Fikreyesus, D. (2013) Making Growth Green and Inclusive: The Dollar, D., & Kraay, A. (2002) Growth is Good for the Poor. Journal of Economic Growth, September
case of Ethiopia. OECD Green Growth Papers, 2013–07, OECD Publishing, Paris. 2002; 7,3. ABI/INFORM Global, 195. Available at https://hec.unil.ch/docs/files/21/1036/dol-
larkraay02.pdf
Becher, C. (2012) The concept of a ‘green economy’, gender equality and intergenerational solidar-
ity. European Women’s Voice, Spring 2012, 20-22. ENERGIA, Earth Day Network, Global Forest Coalition, VAM, WOCAN, WEDO & WEC (March 2011)
A Gender Perspectives on the ‘Green Economy’: Equitable, healthy and decent jobs and liveli-
Bowen, A., & Kuralbayeva, K. (2015) Looking for green jobs: the impact of green growth on employ-
hoods. Women’s Major Group position paper in preparation for the United National Conference
ment. Available at http://www.lse.ac.uk/GranthamInstitute/wp-content/uploads/2015/03/Look-
on Sustainable Development 2012. Available at http://www.wecf.eu/download/2011/March/
ing-for-green-jobs_the-impact-of-green-growth-on-employment.pdf
greeneconomyMARCH6docx.pdf
Burke, M., Hsiang, S. M., & Miguel, E. (2015). Global non-linear effect of temperature on economic
EU (2010) EU Report on Gender Aspects of the Economic Downturn and Financial Crisis
production. Nature, 527(7577), 235.
(2009/2204) NI), Committee on Women’s Rights and Gender Equality.
Chancel, L., & Piketty, T. (2015) Carbon and inequality: from Kyoto to Paris. Paris School of Econom-
FDRE (2011) The path to sustainable development: Ethiopia’s climate-resilient green economy strat-
ics. Available at http://piketty.pse.ens.fr/files/ChancelPiketty2015.pdf
egy, Federal Democratic Republic of Ethiopia (FDRE). Addis Ababa, Ethiopia.
Cook, S., Smith, K., & Utting, P. (2012) Green economy or green society? Contestation and policies
Fre, Z., Negash, Z., Woldu, G. T., Araya, S. T., Tsegay, B., & Teka, A. M. (2017) Social Protection for
for a fair transition. UNRISD Occasional paper no. 10. Geneva: UNRISD. Available at https://
Inclusive Development in Afar Region: Participatory Rural Appraisal Report’’. SPIDA Working
www.files.ethz.ch/isn/156013/10%20Cook-Smith-Utting.pdf
Paper Series: SPIDA/WP/01/2017, April, 2017.
Cotula, L., & Mathieu, P. (2008) Legal empowerment in practice. Using legal tools to secure land
Ghate, R., Jodha, N., & Mukhopadhyay, P. (Eds.). (2008). Promise, trust and evolution: managing the
rights in Africa. Available at http://pubs.iied.org/12552IIED/
commons of South Asia. Oxford University Press.
Chen, B. & Guo, J. (2002) Is Income Inequality Really Not Harmful for Economic Growth? Available
Guerrero, N., & Stock, A. (2012). Green Economy from a Gender Perspective.
at http://economics.ucr.edu/papers/papers01/01-38.pdf
Hallegatte S., Bangalore M., Bonzanigo L., Fay M., Kane T., Narloch U., Rozenberg J., Treguer D., &
Chen, S., & Ravallion, M. (2012) More relatively poor people in a less absolutely poor world. Policy
Vogt-Schilb A. (2016) Shock waves: managing the impacts of climate change on poverty. The
Research Working Paper, 6114, 37.
World Bank Group, Washington DC.
Death, C. (2011) Leading by Example: South African Foreign Policy and Global Environmental Poli-
Hallegatte, S., Heal, G., Fay, M., & Treguer, D. (2011). From growth to green growth-a framework.
tics. International Relations, 25(4), 455-478, Sage.
The World Bank.
Demirgüç-Kunt, Asli, Leora Klapper, Dorothe Singer, Saniya Ansar, and Jake Hess. 2018. The Global
Hitchen, J., & Branson, N. (2015) Cash Transfers: Indebted to Donors. Africa Research Institute
Findex Database 2017: Measuring Financial Inclusion and the Fintech Revolution. Washington,
(ARI).
DC: World Bank.
CHAPTER 7: INCLUSION, POVERTY REDUCTION AND GENDER EQUITY FOR A GREEN ECONOMY 7.18
Huberty, M., Gao, H., & Mandell, J. (2011) Shaping the green growth economy: a review of the Lee D. (2012) Toward a sustainable future: sustainability: economics, environment and equity. Pre-
public debate and the prospects for green growth. The Berkeley Roundtable on the Interna- sentation at the National Academy of Engineering Regional Symposium, Ithaca, NY, 16 May
tional Economy. 2012.
IIED (2017) Money where it matters: financing the Sustainable Development Goals and Paris Agree- MRFCJ (2015) Zero carbon, zero poverty, the climate justice way. MRFCJ. Available at www.mrfcj.
ment through local finance. International Institute for Environment and Development. Available org/media/pdf/2014/ZeroCarbontheClimateJusticeWay.pdf.
at http://pubs.iied.org/17419IIED/ McAfee, K. (2012). The contradictory logic of global ecosystem services markets. Development and
IFAD (2008) Improving access to land and tenure security. IFAD, Rome. Available at www.cpahq. change, 43(1), 105-131.
org/cpahq/cpadocs/Land Access Rural Communities.pdf. Millenium Institute (MI) (2017) Threshold 21 iSDG. Available at http://www.millennium-institute.org/
ILO (2014) Global employment trends: risk of a jobless recovery? Available at http://www.ilo.org/ integrated_planning/tools/SDG/index.html
global/research/global-reports/global-employment-trends/2014/lang--en/index.htm NCE & Government of Uganda (2016) Achieving Uganda’s Development Ambition, Economic
IPCC (2014) Summary for Policymakers. Climate Change, 2014: Part A, 63. Impact of Green Growth. Available at http://newclimateeconomy.report/workingpapers/wp-con-
IPU (2014) Women in parliament in 2013. IPU, Geneva. Available at www.ipu.org/pdf/publications/ tent/uploads/sites/5/2016/11/Ugandas-development-ambition.pdf
WIP2013-e.pdf Nealon, C. (2017) Big data makes poverty maps more accurate. Futurity, 12/12/2017. Available
Jackson, T. (2017) Prosperity without growth. Available at https://www.cusp.ac.uk/themes/aetw/pwg/ online: https://www.futurity.org/data-poverty-maps-1628812/
Isham, J., Woolcock, M., Pritchett, L., & Busby, G. (2005). The varieties of resource experience: ODI (2015) Zero poverty, zero emissions: eradicating extreme poverty in the climate crisis. ODI,
natural resource export structures and the political economy of economic growth. The World London. Available at https://www.odi.org/publications/9690-zero-poverty-zero-emissions-eradi-
Bank Economic Review, 19(2), 141-174. cating-extreme-poverty-climate-crisis.
ITTO, & RRI (2007) Community forest enterprises in poor nations call for level field in use of forest OECD (2008) Natural Resources and Pro-Poor Growth: the economics and politics. Available at
lands and access to world markets. Press Release from the International Conference on Com- http://www.oecd.org/dac/environment-development/naturalresourcesandpro-poorgrowthth-
munity forest management and enterprises: global issues and opportunities, 16-20 July 2007, eeconomicsandpolitics.htm
Rio Branco, Acre, Brazil.
Jacobs, M. (2012) Green Growth: Economic Theory and Political Discourse. Centre for Climate OECD (2013) Putting green growth at the heart of development. OECD Green Growth Studies,
Change Economics and Policy Working Paper No. 108. Grantham Research Institute on OECD Publishing, Paris. Available at http://www.oecd.org/dac/environment-development/put-
Climate Change and the Environment Working Paper No. 92. ting-green-growth-at-the-heart-of-development-9789264181144-en.htm
Kharas, H., Hamel, K., & Hofer, M. (2018). The start of a new poverty narrative. 19/06/2018. Brook- Oxfam (2017). An economy for the 99%. https://www.oxfam.org/en/research/economy-99
ings. Available at https://www.brookings.edu/blog/future-development/2018/06/19/the-start-of- Ostrom, E. (1990) Governing the Commons: the evolution of institutions for collective action. Avail-
a-new-poverty-narrative/ able at https://wtf.tw/ref/ostrom_1990.pdf
Kisambu, N. (2016) Mainstreaming gender in Tanzania’s local land governance. IIED, London. Avail- Van der Ploeg, F. (2011). Natural resources: curse or blessing?. Journal of Economic Literature,
able at http://pubs.iied.org/12594IIED/ 49(2), 366-420.
Kuznets, S. (1955). Economic growth and income inequality. The American economic review, 45(1), Porras, I., Steele, P., & Mohammed, E. Y. (2016). Upscaling solutions: the role of conditional transfers
1-28. for poverty reduction and ecosystem management. London: IIED.
Li, H., & Zou, H. F. (1998). Income inequality is not harmful for growth: theory and evidence. Review Pokhriyal, N., & Jacques, D. C. (2017). Combining disparate data sources for improved poverty
of development economics, 2(3), 318-334. prediction and mapping. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 114(46), E9783-
E9792.
CHAPTER 7: INCLUSION, POVERTY REDUCTION AND GENDER EQUITY FOR A GREEN ECONOMY 7.19
Pearson, T., & Tabellini, G. (1994). Is inequality harmful for growth? Theory and evidence. American UN (2014a) The Millennium Development Goals report 2014. UN, New York. Available at www.
Economic Review, 84(3), 600-621. un.org/en/development/desa/publications/mdg-report-2014.html.
Ravallion, M. (2001). Growth, inequality and poverty: looking beyond averages. World development, UN (2015b) Sustainable Development Goals. Available at www.un.org/sustainabledevelopment/sus-
29(11), 1803-1815. tainable-development-goals
Resnick, D., Tarp, F., & Thurlow, J. (2012). The political economy of green growth: Illustrations from UN (2016) Human Rights Based Approach. http://hrbaportal.org.
Southern Africa (No. 2012/11). WIDER Working Paper. UNDESA (2014) World urbanization prospects: the 2014 revision, highlights. UNDESA Population
Raworth, K., Wykes, S., & Bass, S. (2014) Securing social justice in green economies: a review and Division. http://esa.un.org/unpd/wup/highlights/wup2014-highlights.pdf.
ten considerations for policymakers. IIED & CAFOD, London. UNDP (2011) Paving the Way for climate resilient infrastructure, http://www.undp.org/content/undp/
Scott, A., McFarland, W., & Seth, P. (2013). Research and evidence on green growth. Report pro- en/home/librarypage/environment-energy/low_emission_climateresilientdevelopment/paving_
duced by Overseas Development Institute for Evidence on Demand. Available at https:// the_way_forclimate-resilientinfrastructure.html
assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/media/57a08a14ed915d622c000551/EoD_HD064_July2013_ UNDP (2014) Towards human resilience: sustaining MDG progress in an age of economic uncer-
GreenGrowth_Final.pdf tainty. UNDP, New York. http://www.undp.org/content/undp/en/home/librarypage/poverty-re-
Shafik, N. (1994). Economic development and environmental quality: an econometric analysis. duction/inclusive_development/towards_human_resiliencesustainingmdgprogressinana-
Oxford economic papers, 757-773. geofeconomicun.html
Steele, P. (2015) Development finance and climate finance: achieving zero poverty and zero emis- UNDP (2013) Human Development Report 2013 – the rise of the South: human progress in a diverse
sions. IIED, London. Available at http://pubs.iied.org/pdfs/16587IIED.pdf world. UN, New York. http://hdr.undp.org/en/2013-report
Steele, P., Neha, R., Walnyki, A., & Nhantumbo, I. (2015) Delivering climate and development (2011) Managing private investment in natural resources: a primer for pro-poor growth and environ-
finance to the poorest: intermediaries that ‘leave no-one behind’. IIED, London. mental sustainability. UNDP-UN Environment Poverty-Environment Initiative. Available at http://
Tani, D. (2016) Global Growth Tracker. Available at https://www.worldeconomics.com/papers/Global- tinyurl.com/hbc2fax.
GrowthMonitor_7c66ffca-ff86-4e4c-979d-7c5d7a22ef21.paper UNDP & UN Environment (2017) Budgeting for sustainability in Africa. UNDP & UN Environment.
Piketty, T. (2014) Capital in the Twenty-First Century. The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press Wandibba, S., Nangendo, S.M., & Mulemi, B.A (2014) Gender Empowerment and Access to Finan-
Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England. cial Services in Machakos County, Eastern Kenya.
Piketty, T. (2015) The Economic of Inequality. Translated by Arthur Goldhammer, Harvard University WCSD (2014) Searching for the Social Engine of the Green Growth. World Centre for Sustainable
Press. Development
UNCSD (2012) The Future We Want. Outcome Document of UNCSD Rio+20 Conference June 20-22 WHO (2004) Indoor Air Pollution-the killer in the kitchen. Available at https://www.who.int/mediacen-
2012, Rio de Janeiro, Brazil. tre/news/statements/2004/statement5/en/
UNECA (2016) Inclusive green economy policies and structural transformation in selected African WHO (2014) 7 million premature deaths annually linked to air pollution. WHO News Release, 25
countries. Available at http://www.greengrowthknowledge.org/resource/inclusive-green-econo- March 2014. Available at www.who.int/mediacentre/news/releases/2014/air-pollution/en.
my-policies-and-structural-transformation-selected-african-countries WHO & World Bank (2011) World Report on Disability. Available at https://www.unicef.org/protection/
UN Environment (2011) Towards a Green Economy: Pathways to Sustainable Development and World_report_on_disability_eng.pdf
Poverty Eradication. World Bank (2006) Where is the wealth of nations? Measuring capital for the 21st century. The Inter-
UNRISD (2012) Social Dimensions of Green Economy. Available at file:///C:/Users/Yodit/Down- national Bank for Reconstruction and Development/The World Bank, Washington DC. Avail-
loads/1068_revisiting_s.pdf able at http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/2005/12/6623427/wealth-nations-measur-
ing-capital-21st-century
CHAPTER 7: INCLUSION, POVERTY REDUCTION AND GENDER EQUITY FOR A GREEN ECONOMY 7.20
World Bank (2016) Poverty and Shared Prosperity. Available at https://openknowledge.worldbank.
org/bitstream/handle/10986/25078/9781464809583.pdf#page=55
The World Bank (2017) Global Extreme Poverty. Available at https://ourworldindata.org/extreme-pov-
erty
CHAPTER 7: INCLUSION, POVERTY REDUCTION AND GENDER EQUITY FOR A GREEN ECONOMY 7.21
CHAPTER 8: FISCAL POLICY FOR AN
INCLUSIVE GREEN ECONOMY
Thomas Sterner
CHAPTER 8: FISCAL POLICY FOR The Environment for Development Initiative and University of Gothenburg
AN INCLUSIVE GREEN ECONOMY Thomas Sterner, a Professor of Environmental Economics focuses on the
design of policy instruments to deal with resource and environmental problems.
Sterner has published more than a dozen books and a hundred articles in
refereed journals, mainly on environmental policy instruments with applications
to energy, climate, industry, transport economics and resource management
in developing countries. With Gunnar Köhlin, he has founded the Environment
for Development Initiative. Sterner is the recipient of the Myrdal Prize and
LEARNING OBJECTIVES
past president for the European Association of Environmental and Resource
Economists. During 2015-16 he was guest professor at the Collège de France.
Independent Consultant
4. Public expenditure reviews Environmental taxes Tradable permits Bans Information disclosure
and charges and rights
5. Concluding remarks User charges International offset Permits and quotas
systems
Key term:
ments, each with its own pros and cons and usefulness in A comprehensive green fiscal policy is therefore an
Taxonomies different contexts. Based on field experience, one useful essential ingredient to ensuring that an appropriate incentive structure is in place to
System according to which things, typology applicable to natural resource management and achieve an inclusive green economy. Through the design of government revenues and
in particular animals and plants,
can be sorted into groups that pollution control (based on World Bank, 1997) breaks expenditures, signals can be given to consumers and producers that ensure efficiency
share similar qualities. Adapted policy instruments into four categories: 1) using markets; in resource use, discourage environmental pollution (static efficiency), and encourage
from https://dictionary.cambridge.
org/ 2) creating markets; 3) environmental regulations; and 4) innovation in new products, processes and technologies (dynamic efficiency). In other
Figure 9: Distributional consequence of a carbon tax on the lowest income group relative to the national average in
low-income countries. Values smaller than one indicate progressive distributional impacts, whereas those greater
than one indicate regressive impacts. Source: Dorband et al., 2018. 3.2 Fuel taxes
As described in Sterner (2011), fuel taxes are often criticized for being
high-income countries. In an overview study of 87 low and middle-income coun- regressive, though a closer look at the empirical results shows that there
tries, Dorband et. al. (2018) found that for countries with per-capita incomes of below are large variations in distributional impacts and effects ranging from regressive to
US$10,000 per year carbon pricing has, on average, progressive distributional effects progressive. The specific regressive effects of fuel taxes are also impacted by country
(see Figure 9). In many low-income countries, energy and transportation access are still and region-specific factors such as distribution of income, energy supply structure and
luxuries and expenditure on energy shares increase with rising income. This is partially energy efficiency characteristics of domestic fuel use, as well as on the specifics of
due to the use of traditional biomass (which is collected rather than purchased) used as the methods used (e.g. whether lifetime or temporary income, or substitution or other
a primary fuel by the very poor. adaptations are allowed for in the analysis) (Ekins, 2011; Sterner and Carlsson, 2012).
Nonetheless, the assertion that fuel taxes are regressive is often used as an argument
The impact of a carbon tax on the distribution of income has been shown to be a fun- against them and can make fuel taxes politically difficult to implement even if untrue.
damental factor in securing public support for such a policy and thereby also politi-
cal acceptability (Baranzini, 1997; Zhang and Baranzini, 2004). There are, of course, In rich countries, fuel taxes may be neutral or weakly regressive, though the picture is
design options that could help to mitigate any regressive distributional impact. Such somewhat mixed. While in Europe (see below), taxes tend to be neutral, in some richer
INVESTMENT
German Development Institute
At DIE, Anna has led several research projects and extensively authored and
edited publications on the question of adequate policy instruments for green
LEARNING OBJECTIVES latecomer development. Her current research concentrates on the transition to
clean energy and a circular economy in developing and emerging countries.
This chapter aims to enable its readers to:
• Outline the main challenges facing humanity and analyse their drivers;
• Articulate how the inclusive green economy model seeks to address these
challenges; and Wilfried Lütkenhorst
• Understand the major characteristics that underpin national strategies on German Development Institute
inclusive green economy, the related analytical tools, key actors and initiatives
After finishing his Ph.D. in economics at Ruhr-University Bochum, Wilfried
as well as the critical role of public policy in turning the inclusive seen economy
joined UNIDO. During three decades, he served as Director for Private Sector
model into practice. Development, Director for Strategic Planning, Chief of Cabinet and Managing
Director of various Divisions – including responsibilities for strategic research,
policy advisory services, resource mobilization, evaluation and advocacy.
From 2013-2017, he was Principal Professor at the School of Economics and
Resource Management, Beijing Normal University.
Competitiveness Global coordination or Compatibility with Trading instruments may fit into Global coordination or Information can be used as a signal
compensation of taxpayer trade rules needs to be framework of international treaties. compensation needed if global to environmentally conscious export
needed if global competition is considered. competition is strong, but may also markets when their standards are
strong. open up new export markets, e.g. adhered to.
organic food.
Employment Effects depend on use of Effects depend on Effects depend on likelihood of Effects can be negative (e.g. if Unlikely to have negative effects.
revenues; can be positive e.g. success in building production relocation to other, compliance costs lead to layoffs)
when ancillary wage costs are new industries versus less regulated countries (“carbon or positive (e.g. if mandating leads
reduced (“double dividend”). negative price effects on leakage”). to efficiency and competitiveness
incumbent industries. gains of regulated firms).
Innovation Send a stable price signal Effects depend on Can have effects similar to taxes, but Can have positive effects (Porter Unlikely to have negative effects.
which, if high enough, can spur the subsidy design. depend on stability and scale of the & van der Linde, 1995), but not Information and nudging can lead to
innovation. Innovation subsidies can price signal. automatically. consumer demand shifts and thus
be mission oriented. spur innovation.
Distribution / poverty Regressive effects of taxes Distributive effects Tradable permits are popular Can have direct effects on Unlikely to have negative distributive
can be mitigated by revenue depend on who receives with polluters if allocated freely distribution when costs are passed effects.
use. Charges may be politically and who pays for the (“grandfathering”), but can lead to on to the consumer.
more palatable. subsidies. price increases (e.g. energy prices)
with subsequent negative distributive
effects.
Technical capabilities Taxes can be easier to establish, Information on appropriate Possible if number of polluters is Voluntary instruments usually require Information disclosure requirements
administer and monitor than, for subsidy level can be sufficient and pollutions sources can relatively little administrative capacity, can be powerful instruments to
example, cap and trade systems. obtained by competitive be monitored, but requires relatively but can be less effective than provide consumers with the basis for
Most governments already have processes, e.g. public high technical capacity. Trading mandating. They can, in a sequenced informed choices, and to increase
tax systems in place in which tendering of renewable schemes often need to be set up from approach, be made mandatory societal pressure on polluters. Nudging
they can use for environmental energy feed-in tariffs. scratch, including institutions to monitor after companies have time to adapt. instruments can also have strong
purposes. Regular tax discussion However, tendering emissions, register allowances, and Mandating is useful if compliance is influence on consumer decisions, at low
and revision in budget cycles requires relatively high keep track of allowance trade. Taxing or observable, the number of regulated cost and with little technical management
enhances transparency and technical capacity. mandating may be preferable if technical agents is small and enforcement requirements. However, they should be
eases policy-learning. capacity to manage the market is can be safeguarded. Requires less tested before implementation to optimise
lacking. technical capacity than many market- intervention design.
based instruments.
Political / rent management Political aspects of monitoring and enforcement need attention, Trading schemes may be used as an Individual negotiation entails risks. Low risk of rent-seeking since rents
capabilities corruption complicates market-based policies. Smaller entry barrier, polluters will lobby for Risk of non-compliance of powerful involved are typically low to non-existent.
numbers of actors can coordinate more easily and thus exert free allocation of permits. Risk of price entities.
pressure to achieve a favourable design of market-based manipulation when the number of market
instruments. participants is too small.
Taxes typically engender Subsidies may be subject
opposition. to lobbying, trigger rent-
seeking and wasteful
activities. Sunset clauses
should be introduced and
communicated from the
beginning.
over time below a certain rate. • Imposing a ban on new coal power plants and designing a concrete
The German energy transition (‘Energiewende’) is a project that aims at • Purchase guarantees decommissioning plan for all existing coal power plants;
radically changing the country’s existing energy system in the direction of Adapted from https://www.thefreed-
for unlimited volumes of energy
renewables and climate sustainability. Similar policy-relevant endeavours ictionary.com produced; • Committing to accompanying policy measures to mitigate the economic and
are seen across different regions and in countries with different economic social costs of structural adjustment. Specifically, this would include a structural
endowments and capabilities (Pegels & Lütkenhorst, 2014; Buchan, 2012; • Grid priority in terms of adjustment fund for affected lignite regions; a close monitoring of energy supply
Matschoss, 2013; Quitzow et al., 2016). Notwithstanding debates on various connection (“feed-in”) and transmission; and security during the transition phase; and special attention to maintaining the
implementation challenges and shortcomings, to date the German energy competitiveness of energy-intensive companies;
transition has consistently enjoyed exceedingly high levels of popular support. • Burden sharing of additional costs by all electricity consumers.
Providing long-term security to both investors and financing institutions, • Ensuring supranational policy alignment through a mechanism to be built into
It can legitimately be considered as a national transformation project that is
the EU ETS that would ensure the automatic withdrawal of certificates released
in line with the country’s generally high public backing of climate change and and remaining open-ended in terms of technology choice, the feed-in tariffs
through the coal phase-out (see also Box 4).
environmental policy objectives (Uekötter, 2014). have triggered the roll out and up-scaling of a whole range of renewable
technologies. However, over the course of time the original feed-in tariff Obviously, this proposal is exceedingly ambitious both in its overall goal and its
The rapidly rising contribution of renewables in Germany’s energy mix is among approach has become the victim of its own success by causing an excessive implementation modalities. Yet Germany does have a track record of reaching
the cornerstones of the energy transition. From around five per cent 15 years expansion of heavily subsidized solar PV deployment – a development that broad-based consensual policy decisions, as was the case, for example, in a
ago, the share of renewables in total electricity consumption has surged to over in recent years has led to a series of policy reforms. The recent reforms have 2007 agreement on the future phase-out of hard-coal mining. Furthermore, the
30 per cent in 2016. resulted in significantly reduced tariff rates in response to unexpectedly steep policy-driven push of renewable energy sources into the market has now been
technological learning curves and decreasing unit costs for renewable energy; pursued for 25 years, bearing in mind that the predecessor law to the EEG
From the outset, the German energy transition has been policy-driven and the introduction of an expansion corridor linking future feed-in tariff reductions went into force back in 1991. Thus, the principal lesson seems to be that policy
constitutes a clear-cut case of deliberately changing the main parameters as to actual capacity expansion (‘flexible ceiling’); and the gradual introduction of coherence over long periods of
well as the long-term price signals for energy markets. Apart from a whole competitive mechanisms, such as competitive bidding procedures. The latter time is not necessarily elusive.
range of conventional promotional instruments (e.g. preferential financing and had been applied before in some emerging economies, such as China, India Key term:
targeted R&D support), the introduction of feed-in tariffs constituted the major and South Africa (for the latter case see Pegels, 2014a), which points to an EEG Source: Authors, partially adapted
and decisive policy innovation, which is characterized by: interesting example of reciprocal inter-country policy learning. German Renewable Energy Sourc- from Deep Decarbonization
es Act – law to promote renewable Pathways Project (DDPP, 2015)
• Guaranteed feed-in tariff levels for 20 years, with initially fixed amounts (for 5-12 Currently, the debate in Germany is moving towards the design of a credible electricity in Germany. Adapted
years) subject to a degressive scale later on; long-term strategy for “moving out of coal”, based on a legally binding from https://www.bmwi.de
roadmap agreed by all societal stakeholders. A proposal by AGORA
Energiewende (2016) includes 11 actionable principles, encompassing:
commensurate policy tools, be they tax or financial At the same time, long-term credibility and pathways and being open to policy learning and adjustments
incentives, standards or regulations. This can be locking in desired policy goals and tools, calls for based on results derived from regular monitoring and
exemplified with the German energy transition and the greater attention to patterns of consumer behaviour that evaluation (see Box 9.7). A compromise needs to be
specific instrument of feed-in tariffs – a case where respond to new technological options. found between, on the one hand, keeping incentives
strong support for renewable energies has created robust and reliable, while, on the other hand, allowing
and scaled up markets beyond a point of no return, While policy credibility and long-term reliability are key for adjustments that must remain possible in the spirit
i.e. rendering this particular industrial policy direction to providing investment certainty, there is a potential of continuous improvement and technological cost
endogenous to the economic system itself (see Box 9.6). conflict between locking in a specific policy path
Mazzucato, M. (2014). The entrepreneurial state: Debunking public vs. private sector myths. OECD (2016). The economic consequences of outdoor air pollution. Paris: Organization for
London: Anthem Press (revised edition). Economic Cooperation and Development. Retrieved 01 February 2017, from http://www.oecd.
org/environment/the-economic-consequences-of-outdoor-air-pollution-9789264257474-en.htm
McGlade, C., & Ekins, P. (2014). Un-burnbable oil: An examination of oil resource utilization in a
decarbonized energy system. Energy Policy 64: 102-112. Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collectiva Action: Public goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge,
MA: Harvard University Press.
Meadows, D.H., Meadows, D.L., Randers, J., & Behrens III, W. (1972). The limits to growth. New
York: Universe Books. Ortiz, J., & Cummings, M. (2011). Global Inequality: Beyond the bottom line. A rapid review of
income distribution in 141 countries. New York: UNICEF (Social and Economic Policy Working
Meinshausen, M., Meinshausen, N., Hare, W., Raper, S. C., Frieler, K., Knutti, R., Frame, D.J., & Paper, April 2011).
Allen, M. R. (2009). Greenhouse gas emission targets for limiting global warming to 2°C.
Nature 458:1158-1162. Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons. The evolution of Institutions for collective action.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Messner, D. (2015). A social contract for low carbon and sustainable development: Reflections on
non-linear dynamics of social realignments and technological innovations in transformation Pegels, A. (ed.) (2014). Green industrial policy in emerging countries. London: Routledge.
processes. Technological Forecasting, & Social Change 98: 260-270. Pegels, A. (2014a): The politics of South African renewable energy support. In Pegels, A. (ed.):
Munasinghe, M. (1999). Is environmental degradation an inevitable consequence of economic Green industrial policy in emerging countries, London: Routledge, 126-147.
growth: Tunneling through the environmental Kuznets curve. Ecological Economics 29(1): Pegels, A. (2014b): Why we need a green industrial policy. In Pegels, A. (ed.): Green industrial
89-109. policy in emerging countries, London: Routledge, 1-8.
Naudé, W. (2010). Industrial policy. Old and new issues. United Nations University. World Institute for Pegels, A., & Becker, B. (2014). Implementing green industrial policy. Green Industrial Policy in
Development Economics Research. Working Paper 2010/106. Helsinki: UNU-WIDER. Emerging Countries. A. Pegels. London: Routledge.
Nordhaus, W. (2013). The climate casino: Risk, uncertainty and economics for a warming world. Pegels, A., & Lütkenhorst, W. (2014). Is Germany’s energy transition a case of successful green
New Haven CT: Yale University Press. industrial policy? Contrasting wind and solar PV. Energy Policy 74: 522-534.
O’Donoghue, T., & Rabin, M. (2000). The economics of immediate gratification, Journal of Behavioral Pegels, A. (2015). Synergies and trade-offs between green growth policies and inclusiveness.
Cedision Making 13: 233-250. Eschborn, GIZ.
OECD (1992). Technology and the Economy: The Key Relationships. Paris: Organization for Pegels, A. (2016). Taxing Carbon as an Instrument of Green Industrial Policy in Developing
Economic Cooperation and Development. Countries. Bonn: Deutsches Institut für Entwicklungspolitik. Discussion Paper 23/2016.
OECD (2007). The Political Economy of Environmentally Related Taxes. Paris: Organization for Pegels, A. (2017). Germany: The energy transition as a green industrial development agenda. In
Economic Cooperation and Development. Altenburg, T., & Assmann, C. (Eds.). (2017). Green Industrial Policy. Concept, Policies, Country
OECD (2010). Linkages between Environmental Policy and Competitiveness. Paris: Organization for Experiences (pp. 166–184). Geneva, Bonn: UN Environment; German Development Institute /
Economic Cooperation and Development. Deutsches Institut für Entwicklungspolitk (DIE).
OECD (2011). Divided we stand: Why inequality keeps rising. Paris: Organization for Economic Pichert, D., & Katsikopoulos, K. V. (2008). Green defaults: Information presentation and pro-
Cooperation and Development. environmental behaviour. Journal of Environmental Psychology 28(1): 63-73.
Quitzow, R., Roehrkasten, S., & Jaenicke, M. (2016). The German energy transition in international Scholz, I. (2012). “Green economy - a promise or a real opportunity for sustainable development?”
perspective. Potsdam: Institute for Advanced Sustainability Studies. The Current Column. Retrieved 30 Jan 2013, from http://www.die-gdi.de/uploads/media/
Column_Scholz.29.05.2012.pdf
Ramanathan, R., He, A., Black, A., Ghobadian, A., & Gallear, D. (2016). Environmental regulations,
innovation and firm performance: A revisit of the Porter hypothesis. Journal of Cleaner Schwarzer, J. (2013). Industrial policy for a green economy. Winnipeg: International Institute for
Production, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2016.08.116 Sustainable Development.
Ranis, G. (2005). The evolution of development thinking: Theory and policy. In: Bourguignon, F. Sedlacek, T. (2011). Economics of good and evil. The quest for economic meaning from Gilgamesch
and B. Pleskovic (eds.) (2005). Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics. to Wall Street. New York: Oxford University Press.
Lessons of experience: 119-140. Washington and New York: The World Bank and Oxford Sheng, F. (2009). What does it take for a transition towards a green economy. In The 3rd OECD
University Press World Forum on “Statistics, Knowledge and Policy” Charting Progress, Building Visions,
Rifkin, J. (2014). The zero marginal cost society: The internet of things, the collaborative commons, Improving Life.
and the eclipse of capitalism, New York: St. Martin’s Press. Sierzchula, W., Bakke, S., Maat, K., & van Wee, B. (2014). The influence of financial incentives and
Rodrik, D. (2007). Industrial policy for the twenty-first century. In: Rodrik, D. One economics - many other Socio-economic factors on electric vehicle adoption. Energy Policy 68: 183-194.
recipes: Globalization, institutions and economic growth. Princeton and Oxford: Princeton Simon, H. A. (1957). Models of man: Social and rational. New York: John Wiley and Sons.
University Press. Sinn, H.-W. (2012). The green paradox: A supply-side approach to global warming. Cambridge:
Rodrik, D. (2014). Green industrial policy. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 30: 469-491. Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
Rodrik, D. (2015). Premature deindustrialization. Princeton: School of Social Science, Institute for Smith, A. (2013). The climate bonus: Co-benefits of climate policy. London: Earthscan/Routledge.
Advanced Study (Economics Working Paper 107). Stern, N. (2007). Stern Review on economics of climate change. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Rodrik, D., & Hausmann, R. (2003). Economic development as self-discovery. Journal of Press.
Development Economics 72(2): 603-633, Stiglitz, J. (1998). More instruments and broader goals: Moving toward the post-Washington
Rodrik, D., & Hausmann, R. (2006). Doomed to choose: Industrial policy as predicament. Retrieved consensus. WIDER Annual Lectures 2. Helsinki: UNU-WIDER.
14 March 2017, from http://j.mp/1MnkYCx. Stiglitz, J., Lin, J., & Monga, C. (2013). Introduction: The rejuvanation of industrial policy. In Stiglitz,
Rozenberg, J., Vogt-Schilb, A., & Stéphane, H. (2013). Efficiency and acceptability of climate J., & Lin, J. (eds.) The industrial policy revolution I: The role of government beyond ideology.
policies: Race against the lock-ins. Review of Environment, Energy and Economics, http:// Basingstoke, UK and New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 1-15.
dx.doi.org/10.7711/feemre3.2013.11.002 Syrquin, M. (2007). Kuznets and Pasinetti on the study of structural transformation: Never the twain
Rubashkina, Y., Galeotti, M., & Verdolini, E. (2015). Environmental regulation and competitiveness: shall meet?. International Centre for Economic Research. Working Paper 46. Retrieved 14
Empirical evidence on the Porter Hypothesis from European manufacturing sectors. Energy March 2017, from http://www.biblioecon.unito.it/biblioservizi/RePEc/icr/wp2007/ICERwp46-07.
Policy 83: 288-300. pdf
• Understand the major characteristics that underpin national strategies on California Polytechnic State University
inclusive green economy, the related analytical tools, key actors and initiatives
Eduardo Zambrano is Professor of Economics at Cal Poly in San Luis Obispo,
as well as the critical role of public policy in turning the inclusive seen economy
California, with research interests in General Equilibrium Theory, Game
model into practice. Theory, Decision Theory, Political Economy and Welfare Economics. He has
published in journals such as Econometrica, Games and Economic Behavior,
Journal of Mathematical Economics, Journal of Health Economics and
Economic Theory, among others.
He obtained his PhD in Economics in 1999 from Cornell University and has
worked since 2010 as a consultant to UNDP, UNEP, and the OECD in matters
regarding the measurement of human development, gender inequality, and
the impact of environmental sustainability on human development.
1. The authors are grateful for the substantive contributions provided by Antonio Villar, from Universidad Pablo de Olavide (Seville) and
the Valencian Institute for Economic Research (Ivie), as well as Carmen Herrero, from University of Alicante and Ivie for this chapter.
Inclusive Wealth Index (IWI) Comments about the adjusted measures Green Growth Indicators
The IWI is designed by the United Nations University The purpose of any dashboard of sustainability indica- The OECD Green Growth Indicators are developed by
International Human Dimensions Programme on Global tors is to track the evolution of key stocks of built, the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Devel-
Environmental Change (UNU-IHDP) and UNEP, in col- human, intellectual, natural, cultural and institutional opment. This dashboard is composed of more than 50
laboration with the UN-Water Decade Programme on capital at the country and at the planetary level, that are indicators and is intended as a guideline for Countries
Capacity Development (UNW-DPC) and the Natural priorities to sustain life on the planet. We explained in that want to assess themselves in terms of green growth.
Capital Project. The IWI measures the wealth of nations Section 2 that in the ideal world such dashboard could The OECD collects data for the 34 OECD countries, as
by carrying out a comprehensive analysis of a coun- contain only a single number: the indicator dV* (t) since, well as Brazil, China, India, Indonesia, the Russian Fed-
try’s productive base. This measure covers 140 coun- as we saw in that Section, if dV* (t) is negative, then eration, and South Africa and the indicators are available
tries over the span of 20 years from 1990 to 2010. The present well-being is not sustainable. It is this theoretical
Despite the fact that the GEP measurement framework does not combine the variables To summarize, when comparing progress based on the GEP index and the dash-
in the dashboard into a single scalar measure, determining the importance levels asso- board, countries will be ranked according to their comparatively least-performing type
ciated with each variable in the dashboard is, of course, relevant. We explain how the of achievements. This approach sends the policy message that a country that is only
GEP measurement framework determines those importance levels in Appendix B2. making substantive achievements or on a few issues (indicators) of an IGE, at the cost
of others, will not necessarily be doing better than one that is making small achieve-
Finally, when desirable policies have been identified and measurable actions are
implemented, indicators can be employed to monitor progress and assess the impact
of policy actions (such as electricity production from renewables or the improvement
in energy efficiency over time). The need to implement other policy interventions or
mitigating actions can be determined through these indicators, thus supporting the
achievement of the desired policy objectives.
Despite the significant efforts that have been done in order to have a common frame-
Figure 2: The production framework for green economy indicators and wealth accounting (GGKP, work (e.g. GGKP (2013)), the reality is that there are a variety of different approaches
2013). Note: Grey ovals represent indicator categories. that work with indicators on green economy, as we already saw on Section 3. In this
Section, we will present a practical application of the GEP measurement framework and
how it compares with alternative methods for measuring green economy progress. In
many cases, the indicators being used in the evaluations convey the same message,
To illustrate some of the main properties of the GEP measurement methodology, Tables
1a-c presents the weights, the slope of relative weights, and the value of progress for of the multidimensionality of an IGE in a way that is useful for setting priorities both at
the 13 indicators used in the GEP index for the case of China, Colombia and Ireland. the national and global level, and to understand the interplay between these two. For
The best way to understand how the weights are useful to set national priorities, is the example, the three countries in Table 1 are exceeding the global threshold for material
construction of the slope (ratio) of weights across indicators. footprint per capita. For this indicator, the initial situation was worse for Ireland, followed
by China and then Colombia. However, China experiences other significant challenges,
The weighting system of the GEP methodology allows us to understand the complexity for example in air pollution, so the slopes of weighting relative to material footprint
Protected areas
Life expectancy
Pension cover-
Environmental
basic services
Mean years of
own caculations, based on PAGE, 2017b)
Material foot-
Air pollution
Green trade
Energy use
Palma ratio
Renewable
The weights in the table are defined as πi=κ∙Importance(i)
Access to
schooling
inequality
patents
Gender
and the slope of indicator i with respect to mfp is Impor-
energy
print
tance(i)/⁄Importance(mfp). See Appendix B1 for details.
age
Weights � 0.0728 0.3303 0.2639 0.0704 0.0085 0.0355 0.0154 0.0360 0.0348 0.0400 0.0365 0.0116 0.0442
indicate that progress on material footprint will be
important but not as important as progress on air Slope with respect to mfp 1.0000 4.5350 3.6214 0.9660 0.1170 0.4881 0.2116 0.4942 0.4779 0.5487 0.5015 0.1597 0.6074
pollution (relative slope of 4.535). So, even though
Progress -3.8662 -0.1587 0.0387 0.5196 0.2306 0.4183 -0.5050 -0.1856 1.4626 0.6365 0.3624 0.6614 0.4121
the first weight indicates that it will be more import-
ant that China makes progress on material footprint
than Colombia, the analysis of the slopes incorpo-
Colombia
Protected areas
Life expectancy
rates information on the other indicators for each
Pension cover-
Environmental
basic services
Mean years of
Material foot-
Air pollution
Green trade
country, making it clear that progress on material
Energy use
Palma ratio
Renewable
Access to
schooling
inequality
footprint is of higher relative priority for Colombia
patents
Gender
energy
and progress on air pollution is of higher relative
age
priority to China (relative slope of 4.535 vs 0.4317
for China and Colombia, respectively). In the case Weights � 0.1222 0.0527 0.1334 0.0406 0.0520 0.0820 0.0218 0.1416 0.0878 0.0675 0.0709 0.0399 0.0874
of protected areas, another indicator for which all
Slope with respect to mfp 1.000 0.4317 1.0921 0.3325 0.4256 0.6710 0.1784 1.1592 0.7188 0.5524 0.5805 0.3269 0.7156
three countries are exceeding the global threshold,
the comparison of the relative slopes indicates that, Progress -1.6227 -0.1889 0.1015 0.4568 -0.1547 0.4070 -0.1194 0.2291 0.3021 0.1972 0.2914 0.1621 0.3635
in the case of China and Colombia, protected areas
are higher priorities than material footprint while for
the case of Ireland material footprint is the highest Ireland
Protected areas
Life expectancy
Pension cover-
Environmental
basic services
priority. In this way, the flexibility of the weighting
Mean years of
Material foot-
Air pollution
Green trade
Energy use
Palma ratio
Renewable
system allows for better articulation and action on
Access to
schooling
inequality
patents
national and global priorities based on when the
Gender
energy
print
global and national priorities coincide and when
age
they differ.
Weights � 0.3896 0.0414 0.1619 0.0269 0.0198 0.0397 0.1814 0.0470 0.0200 - 0.0250 - 0.0473
Another important advantage of the GEP weight-
ing system is that it helps to know if progress is Slope with respect to mfp 1.0000 0.1063 0.4156 0.0690 0.0509 0.1020 0.4657 0.1205 0.0513 - 0.0642 - 0.1214
happening where it is most needed. One way to Progress 0.2588 -1.3650 0.2872 0.5965 0.0965 0.5188 1.1076 0.4897 0.6252 - 0.4115 - 0.5137
5. Concluding remarks
In this Chapter, some of the main methodological and practical aspects to consider
when working with green economy indicators were presented. The discussion in Sec-
tions 6 and 7 from Chapter 2 was built on and an extensive list of the main approaches
for the measurement of green economy was presented, and some of the challenges we
face to achieve a unified framework was discussed. Particular focus was on the green
economy measurement framework, recently developed by PAGE, since it is an example
of a comprehensive methodology for the monitoring of progress towards key social,
economic and environmental goals, integrating key theoretical aspects to its methodol-
ogy and application. The GEP measurement framework follows an extraordinarily prag-
Figure 5: Rank differential of GEP+ vs GDP growth. (Source: Authors’ calculations based on PAGE matic approach, guided by theory.
(2017b)
An effort to focus on measurement instruments that will be a practical guide to policy
at the country level was made. This allows for tracking their performance in key stocks
such as material footprint, rising emissions and increased freshwater withdrawal, while
at the same time ensuring that further development is not put at risk, economic oppor-
tunities are created, ecosystem services are preserved, and social inclusiveness is pro-
moted. Towards the end of the chapter, the results from the GEP framework was com-
pared with other well-known indices measuring green economy, the EPI and the GGEI,
to illustrate the implications of using different indicators, discussing their main results
Leadership & Climate Climate Change Performance (50%) International Energy Agency (IEA), Climate Change Per-
Agriculture (5%) Agricultural subsidies (50%) Subsidies are expressed in price of their Change (25%) formance Index (CCPI)
product in the domestic market (plus any
International Climate Forums (20%) Climate Action Network (ECO) reporting scored by Dual
direct output subsidy) less its price at the Citizen LLC on scale of 0-10
border, expressed as a percentage of the
Head of State (20%) Google Analysis scored by Dual Citizen LLC on scale of
border price (adjusting for transport costs 0-10
and quality differences)
Media Coverage (10%) Google Analysis scored by Dual Citizen LLC on scale of
Pesticide regulation (50%) Scoring of whether countries have signed 0-10
on to the Stockholm Convention and allow, Efficiency Sectors (25%) Buildings (25%) LEED certification as reported by the U.S. Green Building
restrict, or ban the “dirty dozen” POPs that Council (USGBC)
are common agricultural pesticides Transport (25%) International Energy Agency (IEA)
Water resources Wastewater management Wastewater treatment level weighted by con-
(25%) (100%) nection to wastewater treatment rate Tourism (25%) Scored by Dual Citizen LLC on scale of 0-10
Markets & Investment Renewable Energy Investment (25%) Renewable Energy Country Attractiveness Index (RECAI,
(25%) Ernst & Young)
Green Investment Promotion & Facili- Scored by Dual Citizen LLC on scale of 0-10
tation (25%)
Environment & Natural Agriculture (17%) Environmental Performance Index 2014 (Yale University)
Capital (25%)
Air quality (17%)
Water (17%)
Fisheries (17%)
Forests (17%)
Additional sources:
Ecorys (2012). Survey of green growth / environmental sustainability accounting and indicators. Technical paper.
World Bank (2018). Data. Adjusted net savings, including particulate emission damage (% of GNI).
Moulin, H. (1998). Axioms of Cooperative Decision Making. Cambridge: Cambridge Univ. Press. University of the United Nations / International Human Dimensions Programme on Global
Environmental Change, United Nations Environment Programme (UNU-IHDP/UNEP) (2014).
OECD (2011). “Towards Green Growth: Monitoring Progress”. Inclusive Wealth Report. Measuring progress toward sustainability. Cambridge: Cambridge
PAGE (2017a). The Green Economy Progress Measurement Framework – Methodology. University Press.
PAGE (2017b). The Green Economy Progress Measurement Framework – Application. Villar, A. (2011). Who Meets the Standards: A Multidimensional Approach, Modern Economy, 2(4):
614-624.
Pearce, David and Giles D. Atkinson (1993). Capital theory and the measurement of sustainable
development: an indicator of “weak” sustainability. Ecological Economics, 1993, vol. 8, issue 2,
103-108.
Simon Zadek
LEARNING OBJECTIVES
This chapter aims to enable its readers to: Project Catalyst and Singapore Management University
• Outline the main challenges facing humanity and analyse their drivers; Simon Zadek is currently Principal of Project Catalyst, an initiative by UNDP,
Senior Advisor to UN Environment on sustainable finance, and Visiting
• Articulate how the inclusive green economy model seeks to address these Professor at Singapore Management University.
challenges; and He was until recently Senior Advisor on Finance in the Executive Office of the
UN Secretary-General, and Co-Director of the UN Environment’s Inquiry into
• Understand the major characteristics that underpin national strategies on Design Options for a Sustainable Financial System.
inclusive green economy, the related analytical tools, key actors and initiatives
He is on the Advisory Board of the leading sustainability investment fund,
as well as the critical role of public policy in turning the inclusive seen economy Generation Investment Management.
model into practice.
reduces the impact of natural catastrophes on people Interventions in the financial system may also be war- financial decision-makers do not have the data to understand social and
environmental factors. Short-termism can deter financing from sustain-
could reduce the numbers displaced from their homes, ranted. Here, the focus is on four specific circumstances able investments that tend to be more capital intensive with associated
currently an average of 26.4 million people every year. (Robins & Zadek, 2015; Zadek, 2016; see also Exhibit 2): lower operating costs. Mispricing environmental risk can deter green
financing and encourage investment in pollution-intensive assets.
Thus, green finance in this context can also be seen as a (i) Valuing externalities: Action may be justified where Sources: G20 Green Finance Study Group, 2016; UN Environment &
financing for overall sustainable development more gen- financial markets systematically misprice the impact Smith School, 2014; Zadek & Robins, 2016
erally. of externalities on financial returns, and thereby
create negative spill-over impacts on third parties or
society in general.
1.2 Why intervene in the financial system? (iv) Ensuring policy coherence: Action may be justified to
(ii) Promoting innovation: Action may be justified to stim-
Conventional wisdom among economists suggests ulate “missing markets”, generating positive spill- ensure that the rules governing the financial system
that the ‘first best’ solution to real economy externali- overs, for example, through common standards for are consistent with wider government policies.
ties would be to intervene in the real economy. Pricing financial instruments that improve liquidity in embry- These four reasons are, in the main, first-best solutions
the negative effects of greenhouse gas emissions into onic areas. to providing public goods. The first three, in particular,
markets for products and services is without a doubt key
(iii) Managing systemic risks: Action may be justified which focus on ensuring markets effectively handle risk
to addressing climate change (see also Ch.8 on fiscal
where the stability of parts of the financial system pricing, innovation and financial stability, are central to
policy). In some instances, this is a matter of correcting
may be affected by environmental impacts, or the role of financial policy makers and regulators, as
policy failures. The IMF, for example, calls for an end to
by associated policy, technological and social well as standard-setters. From this perspective, these
energy subsidies that it estimates at US$5.3 trillion annu-
responses. reasons for intervening need not concern any direct
ally, or about 6.5 per cent of global GDP (Coady et al.,
policy or principled interest in advancing an inclusive
2015). Such subsidies, the IMF highlights, are made up
green economy.
of a combination of policy and market failures – policy
has enhanced environ- • China has introduced a comprehensive set of guidelines to establish a
green financial system, including for banking, capital markets, insurance,
mental and societal considerations in financial market Considerable progress has been made in advancing local finance and international cooperation (PBoC, 2016).
decision-making, at times together with public actors green finance at the national level. As early as 2007, for
• France’s implementation of new reporting requirements for corporate, as
through enabling frameworks and public finance. example, the China Banking Regulatory Commission well as more specific reporting from institutional investors, and ongoing
An example of market action are green bonds (UN established the Green Credit Guidelines, which over work on the assessment of climate-related risks in the banking sector
are a key part of its low carbon transition strategy (Institute for Climate
Environment, 2015), new stock market indices, risk the subsequent period have evolved into an annual Economics, 2015).
modelling, advances in credit ratings (PRI, 2016) and assessment of each bank’s progress in greening its • India’s securities regulator has introduced green bond requirements to
remuneration and voluntary disclosure arrangements. balance sheet. Building on this development, the Peo- boost financing, particularly for renewable energy (UN Environment &
FICCI, 2016).
An example of blended action is development banks, ple’s Bank of China and UN Environment established a
which have taken a lead in blending public finance to Green Finance Task Force in mid-2014. This task force • Kenya is building on its global leadership in promoting financial inclusion
by developing a plan to mobilize green finance and position itself as a
leverage more private capital, and, in some instances, produced recommendations that informed the decisions regional hub (UN Environment & IFC, 2015).
tax credits are used domestically with the same aim in made by the State Council in August 2016, to advance • The Netherlands central bank has assessed the implications of climate
mind, notably in the US (Usher et al., 2016). the greening of China’s financial system. change for its financial system (Sustainable Finance Lab, 2015; De Ned-
erlandsche Bank, 2016).
• Targeted Rule-Making: specific non-market mea- As Box 11.2 suggests, Kenya’s advance of green • The Philippines has developed a public-private disaster insurance pool
sures have been taken by financial institutions, finance began with its digital efforts to increase finan- that will make disaster insurance compulsory for homeowners and SMEs
(Halle, Forstater & Zadek, 2015).
policy makers, regulators, standard setters and other cial inclusion (UN Environment & IFC, 2015). Indeed, by
• Switzerland has undertaken a comprehensive roadmap of the opportu-
non-market actors, or market makers such as stock 2014, Kenya had the world’s highest use of mobile pay- nities for the Swiss financial community in developing a green finance
exchanges, to embed aspects of sustainable devel- ments. Building on the dominant mobile payments plat- expertise and reputation (Swiss Federal Office of the Environment & UN
Environment, 2015).
opment in financial system decision making. UN form, M-PESA, a number of additional financial services
Environment has identified over 200 of these ‘green/ have been added. Notable has been M-KOPA, which • The UK has launched a green finance initiative focused on advancing
the City of London as a global green finance hub (McDaniels & Robins,
social’ targeted financial system reform and develop- uses the platform to enable poorer people to pay for 2016).
ment innovations, highlighting the leadership taken by renewable energy supplied by distributed solar technol-
developing countries in banking regulatory innovations ogy. Other examples include the Swedish start-up, Trine,
and the developed country leadership in the area of that has added crowd-sourcing in Sweden to this tech-
institutional investor (Robins & Zadek, 2016). nological eco-system to pay for the initial capital costs. SolarCoin from the US is experimenting with blockchain
and crypto-currencies to further enhance its offering.
G20 Green Finance Study Group (2016). G20 Green Finance Synthesis Report. G20 Green Finance OJK (2014). Roadmap for Sustainable Finance Indonesia 2015-2019, Otoritas Jasa Keuangan,
Study Group Available online: http://unepinquiry.org/wp-content/uploads/2016/09/Synthesis_ Jakarta.
Report_Full_EN.pdf OECD (2016). The Economic Consequences of Outdoor Air Pollution, Organisation for Economic
Goldstuck, A., & Naidoo, S. (2016). The Experience of Governance Innovations in South Africa. UN Co-operation and Development, Paris.
Environment and Global Green Growth Institute, Geneva. Available online: http://unepinquiry. People’s Bank of China & UN Environment (2015). Greening China`s Financial System, UN
org/publication/south-africa-3/ Environment, Geneva.
Sustainable Finance Lab (2015). Design of a Sustainable Financial System: Input to UN Environment Usher, E., Yasui, Y., & Yacob, L. (2016). Connecting Financial System and Sustainable Development:
Inquiry, UN Environment, Geneva. Available online: http://unepinquiry.org/wp-content/ Market Leadership. UN Environment Finance Initiative, Geneva. Available online: http://www.
uploads/2015/10/Design_of_a_Sustainable_Financial_System_Netherlands_Input_to_the_ unepfi.org/wordpress/wp-content/uploads/2016/11/MKT-LEADERSHIP-REPORT-AW-WEB.pdf
UNEP_Inquiry.pdf V20 (2016). V20 Press Release – October 6th, 2016, V20, Washington DC. Available online:
Swiss Federal Office of the Environment & UN Environment (2015). Design of a Sustainable Financial http://www.thecvf.org/wp-content/uploads/2016/10/V20-Press-Release-3rd-Ministerial-
System: Input to UN Environment Inquiry, FOEN, Berne. Available online: http://unepinquiry. Dialogue-06-10-2016.pdf
org/wp-content/uploads/2015/04/Design_of_a_Sustainable_Financial_System_Swiss_Team_ Zadek, S. (2016) Imagining a Sustainable Financial System, in Dominic Barton et al. (2016)
Input_into_the_UNEP_Inquiry.pdf Re-Imagining Capitalism, Oxford University Press, Oxford: 193-206.
TCFD (2017). Recommendations of the Task Force on Climate Related Disclosures, Task Force on Zadek, S. & Robins, N. (2016). Financing Sustainable Development: Moving from Momentum
Climate Related Financial Disclosures, TCFD, Basel. to Transformation in a Time of Turmoil (with Foreword by Peter Thomson, President of the
UNCTAD (2014). World Investment Report 2014 - Investing in SDGs. Geneva: UNCTAD. UN General Assembly), UN Environment, Geneva. Available online: http://unepinquiry.org/
publication/financing-sustainable-development/
Zheng, Z. (2015). Demand for Green Finance, in Greening China’s Financial System. People`s Bank
of China and UN Environment
CHAPTER 12: INTERNATIONAL Trade and Development (UNCTAD) in Geneva. As a major author of World
Investment Report, a flagship UN publication, he has rich experience in
economic research, intergovernmental process and technical assistance.
DIMENSIONS OF GREEN ECONOMY Dr. Liang has published widely with a focus on international economic issues,
playing an active role in public policy making in trade, investment and related
areas. His recent book Chinese Economy 2040 is an influential work on the
new landscape of globalization and its implications for China’s development.
Zhengzheng Qu
LEARNING OBJECTIVES
Green Climate Fund
This chapter aims to enable its readers to:
Ms. Zhengzheng Qu is the Project Preparation Specialist with the Green
• Outline the main challenges facing humanity and analyse their drivers; Climate Fund (GCF). She coordinates the daily operations of the Project
Preparation Facility, including application reviews and further design of the
facility.
• Articulate how the inclusive green economy model seeks to address these
challenges; and Prior to the GCF, Zhengzheng worked for the United Nations Environment
Programme as a Research Analyst focused on green economy related policy
• Understand the major characteristics that underpin national strategies on research and projects, as well as for the United Nations Conference on Trade
inclusive green economy, the related analytical tools, key actors and initiatives and Development (UNCTAD). Zhengzheng has a master’s degree on Banking
and Finance from Monash University in Australia.
as well as the critical role of public policy in turning the inclusive seen economy
model into practice.
Elena Antoni
3. Trade & inclusive green economy economy linkage. Sections 5 and 6 bring foreign direct The relationship between the two is of growing
investment and technology transfer into the discussions. significance, and in constant flux. Recent events such
4. Liberalising trade in environmental goods Section 7 summarises the major points of this chapter. as the creation of the World Trade Organisation and
& services renewed imperatives for the Non-Aligned Movement
add to the kaleidoscope of movements, motivations,
5. Foreign direct investments and inclusive
interests and objectives. Meanwhile, the distinct and
green economies 2. Trade and Environment perceptibly fixed interests of North and South remain,
6. Green technology transfer & knowledge The discussion of the relationship between trade and buttressing a framework that changes only piecemeal
green economy invariably covers the complex links if at all.
flows
between trade and the environment. Complexities (...) The two polar extremes of (voracious) unbridled
such as the environment-trade debate over the past free trade and rampant (protecto-)environmentalism
1. Introduction decade that has often been marked by mutual distrust are still very much in play: growth at all costs,
and a lack of mutual understanding: On the one hand, regardless of environmental decay or some irreparable
This chapter extends the green economy analysis from the environmentalist community has been critical consequence; and restrictive- punitive legislation
the national to international level with a primary focus towards free trade and wary about the effects of a ostensibly for environmental protection, but which is
on trade, but also covers foreign direct investment and more open trading system on the environment. On the certain to restrict trade and punish foreign traders
technology transfer. By way of globalisation of economic other hand, the trade community has been concerned — while affording disguised protectionism to
activities in the past decades, trade has become an that environmental protection would be utilised as a domestically-based transnational corporations. The
ever greater and more important part of economic disguised means of market protectionism. As Copeland two ends of this continuum have drifted further apart,
activity. This makes it also increasingly relevant from an and Taylor (2004) note in their review on Trade, growth and in doing so have created more grey areas in the
environmental and green economy perspective. and the environment, “The debate has often been widened spectrum between them.”
unproductive because the parties differ greatly in their
The chapter is organised as follows. Section 2 discusses Nagara (1994)
trust of market forces and typically value the environment
the relationship between trade and environment, which
differently”. Nagara (1994) elaborates this point by
has been extensively researched 1. Section 3 explores Nevertheless, the research interest on the interlinkages
stating that….
the relationship between trade and green economy, between environment and trade since the 1990’s has
“The debate over linkage between trade and the contributed to a better understanding of the channels by
1 See, for example, Copeland & Taylor (2004) for an overview of literature on the
environment continues unabated. The entire complex which trade liberalisation and economic growth affect
environmental consequences of economic growth and international trade. the environment. An example of this interlinkage can
EGS trade conclusion of the current full WTO EGA list can bring a • A better data system would need to ensure environmental credibility
of defined ESTs, address the issue of dual-use, improve classification
Key negotiations for liberalising and facilitating trade EUR 21 billion increase for global trade (Monkelbaan, of environmental services, capture the relationship between
environmental goods and services, and promote standardisation and
in EGS have been taking place at the multilateral 2017). Various studies show that a more liberal trade harmonisation of data collection.
level. In the WTO’s Doha Ministerial Declaration in in EGS may also benefit countries that currently do not
• At the country level, policy measures could be taken to promote and
2001, members agreed to the reduction, or if deemed have a sufficiently high level of production and services encourage trade and investment in EST sectors, build productive
appropriate, the elimination of tariff and non-tariff barriers capacities (Bucher et al. 2014), if embedded in a capacity, improve the skills of the labour force, ensure coherence
between environment and trade policies, and effectively assess
to EGS. However, due to the stall of the Doha round, holistic approach policy-making (see also box 12.4). impacts of EST trade based on comprehensive sustainability
assessments.
negotiations were not finalised. Taking up this issue later, However, some countries have expressed concerns that
14 WTO members released a joint statement in Davos liberalising the trade of these goods and thus facilitating Source: Entirely based on UN Environment (2018), Key findings
on 24 January 2014 and pledged to launch negotiations the import of EGS would make their own industry less
to liberalise global trade in environmental goods. The competitive or might hinder them from developing such
Environmental Goods Agreement (EGA) negotiations an industry in the future, which may partially explain their
hesitance to engage in negotiations. and soil, as well as problems related to waste, noise
were then formally launched on 8 July 2014 in Geneva and eco-system”. This includes cleaner technologies,
The EGA is a plurilateral agreement, which means that Besides concerns over competitiveness, the products, and services that reduce environmental risk
it is covering a group of WTO Members, rather than all negotiations on the EGA have been slowed down due and minimise pollution and resource use (OECD &
members of the WTO. WTO Member States negotiation to technical difficulties. One such difficulty has been on Eurostat, 1999). However, some countries have adopted
participants have grown to 18 by 2018, representing 46 what can and should be considered an ‘environmental’ a definition based on their own scope and criteria. For
WTO members and accounting for 86% of the global good (or service). According to the definition proposed example, Canada, Japan and the United States have
trade in environmental goods. Negotiations are in theory by Eurostat and OECD (1999), the environmental adopted a broad definition, thus encompassing a wider
open to all WTO members and outcomes will extend to goods and services industry consist of “activities which range of goods; while Italy, Germany and Norway’s
all WTO members on a ‘most favoured nation’ basis. This produce goods and services to measure, prevent, limit, definitions are rather narrow and focused on pollution
means that tariff reductions negotiated as part of the minimize or correct environmental damage to water, air
potential of cross-border technology transfer for its • Movement of people. International movement of people, in particular
the inward movement of green technology professionals and experts
own technological learning and industrial development into the country, is another channel for international transfer of green
(Assman and DIE, 2017). In addition to adequate technologies. This is related to the domestic delivery of environmental
In that case, building up national production capacity for and/or green technological services. According to the definition of the
absorptive capacities, an enabling environment for WTO, a supplier of one Member in the territory can deliver services
green technologies is challenging, as it would take more cross-border flows of technology at the macro level internationally to any other Member through the presence of natural
persons. Domestic companies relate this to the employment of
time and money to generate the same technologies is essential. For example, for attracting low-carbon foreign professionals and experts, as well as returnees. For both, the
already available in some other places. Here, technology technologies some countries have established low- international movement of people is crucial.
transfer becomes central, in particular for many carbon special economic zones, others provide
developing economies, as a way to access advanced specific incentives (UNCTAD, 2010). The effectiveness
green technologies. In reality, today, the production of and efficiency of the transfer of green technologies
sophisticated environmental technologies is organised are also affected by the national system of innovation
in complex regional or global value chains of production,
Brander, J. A. and B.J. Spencer (1985) “Export subsidies and international market share rivalry,” George, C. (2014) “Environment and regional trade agreements: emerging trends and policy
Journal of International Economics, 18(1-2): 83-100. drivers”, OECD Trade and Environment Working Papers, 2014/02, OECD Publishing, Paris.
Brander J. A. and M. S. Taylor (1997) “International trade between consumer and conservationist Griffith, R., Redding, S. and Van Reenen, J., 2003. R&D and absorptive capacity: theory and
countries,” Resource and Energy Economics, 19: 267-297. empirical evidence. Scandinavian journal of Economics, 105(1), pp.99-118.
Bucher, H., Drake-Brockman, J., Kasterine, A., and M. Sugathan (2014). Trade in Environmental Hindelang, S. and M. Krajewski (2015). Shifting Paradigms in International Investment Law - More
Goods and Services: Opportunities and Challenges. International Trade Centre Technical Balanced, Less Isolated, Increasingly Diversified. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Paper, Geneva. Holzer, K., 2014. Carbon-related border adjustment and WTO law. Edward Elgar Publishing.
Bulte, E. H., and E. B. Barbier (2005) “Trade and renewable resources in a second-best world: An Grossman, G.M., and Krueger, A.B. (1991) “Environmental Impacts of a North American Free Trade
overview”, Environmental and Resource Economics, 30 (4): 423–63. Agreement”. Conference on the US-Mexico Free Trade Agreement.
Cosbey, A (n.d.), The Environmental Goods Agreement and Its Regional Impact. Available at: http:// ICTSD (2014) A conversation on green goods trade with Ronald Steenblik and Grant Ferrier.
www19.iadb.org/intal/icom/en/notas/39-12/ Biores, Volume 8-Numer 1. Available at: https://www.ictsd.org/bridges-news/biores/news/a-
conversation-on-green-goods-trade-with-ronald-steenblik-and-grant-ferrier.