My Thesis
My Thesis
My Thesis
INTRODUCTION
Paddy is originated in the Southeast Asia. Rice is staple food for 6000 years in
this region. It is staple food and daily diet in Myanmar too. People consume various
kinds of traditional snacks made of rice, broken rice and sticky rice. Per capita
attempted to develop the country rice economy to provide sufficient rice for domestic
consumption in line with food security for increasing population, and enhancing
income by rice export. It is noted that these successive governments have one main
interest to produce rice in surplus though they did not have same political, economical
self-sufficiency for rice and other crops and for getting personnel goods. Barter
system was practiced. Myanmar kings encouraged the agricultural cultivation and
took appropriate measures, and constructed new reservoirs, lakes, canal and
maintained the old irrigation network. Starting from 1824, the British colonialists
occupied Burma for three times, and the country fell in 1885. In this era, they
established the colonial capitalist economic system. Rice area was expended to 5.07
million hectares and around 3 million tons of rice was exported from 1923 to 1940.
The highest production of paddy was over 8 million tons during this era. In December
1
1941, the Second World War II was spread into Burma, and Japanese occupation
started. Up to 1941, Burma exported 3.4 million tons of rice products annually. Burma
was not able to export rice and paddy due to SWW II, and consequently, the price of
paddy dropped sharply due to the halt of export of rice. It was estimated that only
2.63 million hectares of paddy areas were cultivated in 1944-45. When the SWW II
ended in 1945, British government took power again because they won in the war.
government took place in. During this time, rice sown area had increased to 3.83
million hectares and it was produced 5.6 million metric tons of paddy in 1951-52. Over
government tried to regain the previous sown area, and implemented Eight-year
Pyidawtha Plan from 1952-53 to 1959-60. At that time, the highest level of rice export
was recorded at 1.8 million tons. In 1961-62, paddy sown area was reached 4.6
million hectares, and it was produced 6.8 million metric tons of paddy. The country’s
annual rice export was over 1 million ton. On March 2, 1962, the Revolutionary Council,
otherwise military men, took the responsibility of the state. Then rice marketing was
nationalized. No traders were not allowed to carry out purchase, storage, marketing,
milling and distribution of rice and rice products, and later on the business was
become SOE. In 1964-65, 5.11 million hectares of land was cultivated for paddy,
surpassing 5.07 million hectares of the highest sown area in 1940-41. In that year,
over 1 million ton of rice was exported and total paddy production was 8.5 million
metric tons.
During 1960’s, the Green Revolution was introduced by the world research
communities. High yielding varieties such as IR 8 and IR 5 were introduced into Burma
to increase rice production. Since that time, the Revolutionary Council adopted the
new state constitution on January 3, 1974 the state came to be known as the Socialist
unattractive (fixed) prices set by the government through its agencies. Food security
2
was a case to feed its increasing population. To overcome this problem, the
fertilizers, agricultural loans, etc. The country’s paddy production reached over 14
million metric tons, and the average annual rice export during that time was 0.5
economy for several reasons. The State Law and Order Restoration Council (SLORC),
otherwise military regime, assumed the responsibilities of the state in 1988, and
Myanmar Agricultural Produce Trading (MAPT) was responsible for marketing of rice
and paddy. From 1988 to 2002, the SLORC carried out to sell rice to the specific
groups at reasonable price, to provide rice to the victims of natural disasters free of
charge and to reserve rice that may need in times of military, political and economic
emergencies, and to export the surplus rice to earn foreign exchange. In November
1997, the SLORC changed its name as State Peace and Development Council (SPDC).
The SPDC continued to practice as under the SLORC. MAPT disbursed advanced
payments to farmers under contracts as in the previous years. This system had been
practiced up to April 22, 2003. The SPDC announced an issue on April 23, 2003, that
it would end direct purchase of paddy from farmers beginning from fiscal 2003-2004,
and would adopt the new rice marketing policy allowing free marketing of the paddy,
rice and rice commodities. Unexpectedly, it declared that rice export is not allowed for
successive era. Rice dominates the agriculture sector, and shares 49 percent of the
total crop sown area. Paddy production of different regions for 2003-04 in Myanmar is
shown in Table 1.1. Delta region shares 63 percent of total sown area and 69 percent
of the country’s rice production. It is well known as the country’s rice bowl. Although
Myanmar is rice-surplus country, and can sufficiently provide rice for domestic
3
consumption and export, the central dry zone region, Tanintharyi division in coastal
region, and Shan, Kachin, Chin states in mountainous regions are still rice deficit
areas. The average rice yield in delta region is over 3 metric tons per hectare, and that
of the rest ones range from 1.7 to 2.94 metric tons per hectares.
Source: MAS
Most of the government of every country has intervened in the market pricing
of food grains to promote price stability. A number of stabilization schemes has used
some form of control over prices and trade in commodity through its agency, Myanmar
Agricultural Produce Trading (MAPT). Government intervention policies could not fit to
the welfare of poor in Myanmar. The government announced it would end a 40 year
policy and permit rice to be sold privately via “free trade” in April 2003. But it was not
longer and it was revoked in 2004, it might be, not to be happen some political riot
Dorosh and Shahabuddin (2002) pointed out that “domestic rice procurement
4
involved only a small percentage farmers, and incurred excessive costs following
successful harvests because of procurement prices set far in excess of market prices
in Bangladesh”. Nielsen (2003) showed that the export quota has been a very
restrictive policy tool that has kept Vietnamese rice production and exports well below
potential.
There are two major components in intervention: (1) price intervention, and
(2) institutional intervention. A set of direct policy interventions may distort prices
such as export taxes, import tariffs, trade quotas, and domestic producer and
consumer taxes and subsidies. It is relevant to examine the selected policy goals, and
1. What were the costs and benefits associated with given policies and
price policy. The partial equilibrium models equate supply and demand in one or more
markets clear at their equilibrium price levels. This makes prices endogenous. Partial
economy, nor do they attempt to capture all of the economy’s markets and prices. The
approach allows the analyst to trace the impact of changes in one market on other
markets, but it only captures such changes in the markets included in the model.
Partial equilibrium models are best suited to analyzing sector reforms that are less
(1) To describe the present status of physical, economic structure and paddy/rice
5
(3) To examine the welfare of consumers and producers of paddy/rice, and
1.4 Methodology
A variety of methods is used to examine the various research tasks. These are
demand and supply elasticities. Each method will be further explained in the following
chapters. Data were collected both published and unpublished data from the following
Agricultural Produce Trading (MAPT), Ministry of Commerce, and Other related local
1.5 Organization
analysis.
Chapter 4 studies the rice production and supply. It focuses on rice production
consumption and econometric analysis of rice demand based on HIES carried out by
CSO.
6
Chapter 6 uses the partial equilibrium model to evaluate the effects of pricing
policy in Myanmar rice economy. Firstly it develops the methodology. The elasticity of
rice demand and supply is used in the model. This involves comparing the volume of
production, consumption and export evident at intervention prices with those that are
pricing policy and simulation, and some recommendations are made with regard for
other studies.
7
CHAPTER 2
THE PHYSICAL AND ECONOMIC STRUCTURE
2.1 Geography
Myanmar is geographically located between 9 Degree 58' to 28 Degree 31' N
and 9 Degree 29' to 10 Degree 10' E. Bounded by land on the northeast, north, east
and the remaining sides by sea, it stretches for about 1275 miles from north to south
and 582 miles from east to west, while approximating 261228 square miles, in total
area. Myanmar is situated in Southeast Asia and is bordered on the north and
northeast by China, on the east and southeast by Laos and Thailand, on the south by
the Andaman Sea and the Bay of Bengal and on the west by Bangladesh and India
(Figure 2.1). Myanmar's coastline defines the eastern shore of the Bay of Bengal,
running from the Bangladesh border in the down to the Malay Peninsula and Thai
territory in the southeast. Southern Myanmar consists largely of the broad river valley
of the Ayeyarwaddy. The Ayeyarwaddy rushes down through great mountain gorges in
northern Myanmar before spreading out into one of the largest river delta in Asia. Both
of Myanmar's principal cities- Yangon and Mandalay- are situated along the
Ayeyarwaddy, and 1600km river is navigable for almost two thirds of its length. The
vast majority of Myanmar's people live in the lowland regions of this river valley in the
Ayeyarwaddy basin. This fertile expense, which sits within the tropical monsoon belt,
Kachin, Kayah, Kayin, Chin, Mon, Rakhine, Shan States and Sagaing, Tanintharyi,
districts which comprise 324 townships and 13745 village tracts in the rural areas and
8
Figure 2.1 Union of Myanmar
2.3 Climate
Myanmar has two distinct dry and wet seasons. The dry season runs from
mid-October to mid-May and the rest being the wet season. Myanmar has the effect of
monsoon in different parts of the country. Temperature varies from 38˙C to 19˙C,
humidity from 82.8 percent to 66 percent. The precipitation depends on the locality,
9
elevation and months. The climatological data by regions is given in Table 2.1. The
Source: CSO
agroclimatic conditions; namely, Delta, Coastal, Central dry zone and Mountainous
regions. The Delta region has the highest population density, highest land productivity
(mostly alluvial soil), moderately high rainfall, generally flat topography, and excellent
conditions for growing rice. The Coastal region can be characterized with small land
area, highest annual rainfall exceeding 4000mm per annum, and highly suitable for
growing perennial crops. The Central dry zone has lowest annual rainfall, sandy soils,
and the second highest population density. The Mountainous region has the largest
area comprising dense forest, poor road infrastructure, and low population density.
Myanmar is rich in natural resources. More than half of the area of the country
is covered by dense forest which can produce valuable hard woods. Myanmar's teak is
famous in the world and in addition other varieties of hard wood are available in
abundance. Myanmar also has well-known gems, and being produced 36 types of
precious stones and gems. Production of mineral resources such as gold, silver, copper,
10
lead, tin and nickel are being carried out by private firms and SOEs. Myanmar with a
coastal line of 2832 km is also rich in marine resources. It has been estimated one
basis. Many foreign companies are investing to explore oil and gas. Presently, 7
companies had signed 12 contracts for onshore blocks and another 7 companies had
signed 8 contracts for offshore blocks. Most of Myanmar's natural resources are still
Myanmar.
As for water resources, there are four major river basins; namely, The
Ayeyarwaddy, the Chindwin, the Sittaung, and the Thanlwin. These are flowing
north to south into the Andaman Sea. The Ayeyarwaddy basin creates a vast fertile
delta region.
Myanmar can be classified into different types in various parts of the country. Different
rural area and depends mainly on agriculture. The country's active labour force is
17.23 millions, and 65 percent engage in agriculture sector (Figure2.2). Delta region
to the official estimate. In FY2003, Myanmar faced sanctions from US and EU that
constrained growth and hurt international trade and investment in Myanmar. Troubles
11
Table 2.2 Different soil types in Myanmar
Fodder, Vegetables
Ferrosol Rhodic 9971 14.7 Forest, Rubber, Pineapple, Horticulture, Mango, Tea
Coffee
Ferrosol Xanthic 8363 12.4 Forest, Rubber, Pineapple, Horticulture, Mango, Tea
Coffee
Mango, Pineapple
12
(Chin hill)
35%
65%
such as sown land area, use of fertilizer, pesticides, and crude oil have been flat or
The fiscal deficit, which is largely financed through central bank credit
creation because of low level of revenues, hit 4.1 percent of GDP (ADB). More than 60
percent of the overall deficit was caused by the deficits of State Owned Enterprises
to price increases. Government keeps nominal interest rate and monetizing the
data, the balance of payment was in surplus by $49.3 million in FY2002. But it was
deficit again by $38 million in the first 6 months of FY2003. In Myanmar, the parallel
13
market exchange rates co-exist with official rate with a difference over 154 times in
start of 2003 (Table 2.3). The Government of Myanmar (GOM) once tried to solve dual
exchange rate by issuing FEC and adopting the devalued customs valuation rates.
Finally this system leaded to decline in FE reserves after the Asian currency crisis
because the GOM has reinforced exchange controls by regulating foreign remittances.
Trade sanctions have been lessened because of stronger demand from neighbouring
2.6.3 Investment
People's saving was increased from 1980 to January 2003. After that it was
declined because of trouble in banking crisis dramatically as shown in the Table 2.4.
FDI of permitted enterprises from various countries up to the end of 2002 is shown in
Figure 2.3. In 2003, investment represents 25 percent of total GDP. Among various
14
Table 2.4 People's saving
FY Total saving(million)
1998-1999 162609
1999-2000 236383
2000-2001 352347
2001-2002 465005
2002-2003 415183
2003-2004 408098
2003
January 526918
February 440533
March 415183
April 391668
May 375104
June 370790
July 378643
August 380872
September 392239
October 381736
November 375739
December 380012
2004
January 374839
February 378379
March 408098
April 269034
May 451829
June 484293
15
Figure 2.3 FDI from various countries
1800
1600
1400
1200
million $
1000 No of enterprises
800 Investment value
600
400
200
0
Thailand
Germany
Israel
Canada
China
Indonesia
Panama
India
Malaysia
Australia
Austria
Srilanka
Republic of Korea
Netherlands
Denmark
United States
Philippines
Hong Kong
France
Macau
Japan
Singapore
Britain
Bangladesh
Figure 2.4 Government Investment at various sectors in capital
14% Agriculture
13%
Energy
7% Construction
2.6.4 Trade
GOM has supported private exporters and importers recognizing that private
sector as a prime mover of the market mechanism and pays great attention to its
development. As private sector has been in place, it could seen the volume of external
16
trade has increased in absolute terms and reached K35509 millions in 2001 (Figure
40000
35000
Value (million MMK)
30000
25000
20000 Total trade
15000
10000
5000
0
20 0
5
5
00
-9
-9
-9
-9
-9
-0
-0
-0
-0
-0
-2
94
95
96
97
98
00
01
02
03
04
99
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
20
19
Year
Myanmar has 67.7 million hectares of total land area of which 10 million
hectares is utilized for crop cultivation. The forest area contributes 49 percent of
country's total land area. Extendable land area is approximately 7.28 million hectares,
which can be brought under crop cultivation and livestock farming (Table 2.5).
Table 2.5 Land utilization ('000ha)
17
2.6.6 The Role of Agriculture in Myanmar Economy
There are four economic objectives laid down by the government, and the
first objective is to develop agriculture as the base and all round development of other
sectors. In this regard, the MOAI set the following policies and strategies for the
seasonal crops and perennial crops and distribution of farm machineries and other
inputs.
achieved an annual growth rate of 5.6 percent (Table 2.6), and contributes about 42.7
percent to GDP (at the 1985-86 constant prices) indicating the dominant position in
the national economy. Fishery and forestry sector also achieved considerable increase
Particulars 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001
Goods 2.6 11 6 6.9 6.7 6.4 5.1 4.9 12.1 13.5 9.7
L&F -0.6 4.5 4.8 6 3 11.9 7.1 9.3 16.8 17.8 11.3
Forestry 8.3 -3.3 1 -14.3 -4.5 2.7 2.8 3.2 4.6 3.3 10
Mining -1.2 26.3 16.2 14.8 27.4 11.6 29.7 7 30 25.5 -7.8
E power 5 31.1 24.4 4.8 6.6 10 17.8 -5.4 14.2 13.9 -5.5
Constrn 35.8 11.2 11.7 15.7 27.2 24.6 9.8 6.3 4.4 11.9 29.2
Services 4.2 6.1 8 10 9.3 8.2 8.8 7.8 8.8 13.2 15.7
GDP 2.8 9.7 6 7.5 6.9 6.4 5.7 5.8 10.9 13.6 10.5
Source: CSO
18
CHAPTER 3
LITERATURE REVIEW
incentives are an integrating theme of food policy analysis (Timmer and others 1983).
Streeten (1987) stated that food policy is that between food prices high
enough to encourage agricultural production and low enough to protect poor food
buyers. Anderson (1986) pointed out that policies that attempt to strengthen
incentives to expand food production through higher food prices may result in reduced
incomes and severe hardships for the poor. To implement price policies government
Deaton (1989) found that higher prices for rice are likely to bring benefits to
rural households at all levels of living in Thailand, and there were marked regional
variations depending on the importance of the rice crop, but there is no systematic
pattern whereby higher prices favour the rural rich at the expense of the rural poor.
Malaysia, Morocco, and Indonesia. The results exposed the fatal flaws of narrowly
will fail when they do not recognize the interdependence of the three criteria of
Ramaswami and Balakrishnan (2002) studied the food prices and the
differences between public and private grain supply. As both qualities were procured
19
at similar prices, the lower quality of public grain marked the inefficiency of
prices and hurt the poor even when they are not major recipients of the subsidy.
food aid policy has three key findings: (1) There is a consistent relationship between
commodity producer interests and US food aid policy, (2) there is a strong relationship
between commodity stocks and food aid shipments, especially during the years when
stocks were the greatest, (3) US food aid policy-making is highly incremental.
sellers or buyers, and, for many others, net sales or marketable surplus is fairly small.
The roughly one-third of rice farmers who fall below the poverty line have substantial
net purchases of rice. More variable rice prices induced by economic reforms likely
Smith (1997) pointed out that an important stimulus for cereal sector has
been the massive fiscal costs of many state procurement and intervention agencies.
This has led to policies to minimize their role in the future through rapid market
liberalization and a substantially increased role for the private sector. There were
private sector is not fully developed, public sector agencies can potentially play an
services.
mean and variance of food prices vary substantially by commodity, region and season.
In the long term, liberalization increases both the mean and the variance of food
differences in mean food prices and a sharp increase in price auto-correlation. Real
20
exchange rates have pronounced positive effects on mean food prices, but these
effects emerge indirectly, rather than directly, through induced changes to border
parity prices.
Schultz (1978) said that price distortions against agriculture have been blamed for the
stagnation of agriculture in LDCs. Sah and Stiglitz (1984) blamed that for the squeeze
on agricultural incomes.
Currie, Murphy, and Schmitz (1971) pointed out that the concept of consumer
surplus provides a measure of consumer welfare as the excess of the price the
consumer would be willing to pay for each unit consumed over the price which is
actually paid.
The supply and demand functions represent only part of the reaction to a
change in the price of the commodity being considered and so are referred to as
partial equilibrium models. When the commodity is important to the entire economy,
as a staple food grain or major export crop inevitably is to a developing country, these
partial equilibrium adjustments provide only an initial glimpse of the full adjustments
Myoung and Lee (1988) evaluated the Korean market intervention system by
using partial equilibrium model. They estimated the elasticities for rice demand and
supply and calculated nominal protection coefficients (NPC), and were used to
calculate trade levels under the no intervention scenario. Then they compared actual
trade levels with those generated by the model. They found that producer welfare
overall loss of US$3945.2 million, and the net social welfare loss amounted to
21
US$418.4 million.
Using partial equilibrium model, Tamin and Meyanathan (1988) studied rice
market intervention system in Malaysia. They placed the demand and supply
elasticities at 0.2 and 0.3 respectively. They found that with the exception of 1974 and
1975 ‘no intervention’ supply balances show a decrease while consumption would
have increased (except 1974 and 1981). Efficiency losses generated by the system of
controls (deadweight losses) stood at M$141 million in 1974 and have tended to rise
over the 1980s. The foreign exchange cost to the nation (compared to intervention)
has been reduced by about M$190 million over 1980-86 due to the measures
enforced.
benefits and costs of intervention using the partial equilibrium analysis approach.
They explored the adverse impact of higher food grain prices on the real incomes and
nutritional status of the poor, within the context of the macro-economic model of the
Bangladesh economy. Their results indicated that worker households carry most of
the burden of adjustment while large farmers enjoy the major income games.
However, the persistence of a downward trend in world grain prices has softened the
1982 to 1985.
intervention policies in Andhra Pradesh, India. They constructed variant of the partial
prices would fall from Rs.2910 to Rs.2400 per ton, while production within Andhra
Pradesh would fall by about half a million tons. The consequent loss in producer
revenue of Rs.6172 millions per year would be more than offset, though, by a cut in
consumers.
imperfectly markets in Sri Lanka. A partial equilibrium model was developed for the
22
paddy market in Sri Lanka, under oligopsony. Results revealed that losses to paddy
eliminated simultaneously.
level of demand for the commodities an individual consumes given the structure of
relative prices faced, real income, and a set of individual characteristics such as age,
nutritional impact and would require much larger transfers to achieve a quantum of
nutritional improvement. Behrman and Deolalikar (1990) argued this debate that
increases in income will not result in any significant improvements in nutrient intakes.
However, Strauss and Thomas (1990), and Subramanian and Deaton (1992) showed
that calorie elasticity is indeed lower than expenditure elasticity, but nevertheless
significantly positive.
is one consumed in large quantities by the poor and little by those with adequate diets,
thus minimizing leakages toward the latter (Timmer, Falcon, and Pearson, 1983).
Minot and Goletti (2000) estimated the linear approximation of the Almost
Ideal Demand System for Vietnamese urban and rural households by using regression
analysis. Their food system included the 14 food categories, and regression equations
explained between 54 and 71 percent of the variation in the budget share of rice
across households. They found that rice consumption is largely determined by the
23
Weerahewa (2004) developed a demand function for cereals representing
rice, wheat and millet that are used in Sri Lanka diet. It was assumed that the utility
of cereal consumption is weakly separable from the utility derived from other
commodities. The results showed that all the elasticity estimates of demand with
respect to own prices have the expected negative sign and they are statistically
technological relation that exists between any particular combination of inputs and
the resulting levels of outputs; this is represented by the production function. The
other is the producer’s behaviour in choice of inputs, given the level of market prices
for a commodity and factors that can be traded, and the availability of fixed factors
whose quantity cannot be altered in the period of analysis (Sadoulet and Janvry
1995).
Nerlove (1956 and 1958) developed the supply response model, and called
Nerlovian Supply Response Model. He formulated the model in terms of yield, area, or
output response of individual crops, for instance, the desired area to be allocated to a
crop in period t is a function of expected relative prices and a number of shifters such
as private and public fixed factors and truly exogenous variables such as weather.
Cuddihy (1980) estimated a model of area response for the five major crops
of Egyptian agriculture: Egyptian clover, cotton, wheat, maize and rice. It was used
revenue per feddan (1 feddan=1.035 acres) of each crop deflated by a real wage
index. It was assumed that price and yield expectation are exogenous. The data had
coefficients are significantly different from zero at the 5 percent level, and the
For the analysis of rubber supply in Sri Lanka, Hartley, Nerlove, and Peters
24
(1987) focused on the uprooting and replanting of trees as opposed to new plantings.
They specified a three equation model with replanting, production, and new plantings.
Haughton and et al (2004) estimated the rice supply for Vietnam in their
study of “the effects of rice policy on food self-sufficiency and on income distribution
in Vietnam” using Cobb-Douglas production function including sown area, the number
of labour used in cultivation and other variables such as the intensity of agricultural
extension activities, or the educational level of farmers. They found that the most
important determinant of rice output is the area of land cultivated. Their estimation
results indicated that if the wage rate rises by the equivalent of 1 kg of paddy rice per
day, or about 10 percent, then the quantity of rice will fall by 14 kg per household
(about 7 percent).
25
CHAPTER 4
RICE PRODUCTION AND SUPPLY
Myanmar is able to grow over more than 60 different crops since its
prevalence of different agroecological zones within the country. Among various crops,
cereal crops are main important crops constituting 50 percent of the total crop sown
area of 16.7 million hectares in 2003-04 (Figure 4.1). Rice as a national crop is grown
widely all over the country and throughout the year because of its adaptability to a
wide range of agroclimatic conditions. It could be divided into two rice cultivation
methods: dry upland and wet cultivation. The method for former one generally
practiced on the hillsides especially in the forest area. Shifting cultivation on the
hillside is almost replaced by dry land crop rotation system for subsistence production.
4% 1%
6%
Cereals
18% Oil crops
Peas and Beans
50%
Industrial Crops
Food crops
Plantation crop
21%
water submerged rice. Rice production in dry season is generally not feasible without
irrigation. Generally, little work and care is needed for rice cultivation in monsoon
26
season. The current major rice ecosystems include the traditional rain-fed that is
grown in monsoon season, deep water submerged rice, irrigated lowland rice and
rain-fed upland rice. Rain-fed lowland and deep water rice are mostly produced in the
lower delta region (Ayeyarwaddy and Bago), and the coastal region (Rakhine).
Irrigated rice is grown where irrigation system exists. It is not surprising that
the GOM is giving priority in constructing new dams, reservoirs and weirs in every
parts of the country where it is able to construct these because of the successful of its
irrigation. Net sown area and irrigated area in Myanmar is given in Table 4.1.
1991-92 8.34 1 12
Source: DAP
27
three distinct programs launched by the MOAI: summer paddy production program,
expansion of HYVs, and paddy-fish integrated farming system. About two-thirds of the
The widely used and accepted method in Myanmar is the classification of five
rice groups, based on length/breadth ratio of rice grains (Table 4.2). Another
classification is based on life period from seeding to maturity. This system is adopted
ratio ratio
Emata (A) type 9.41 and over 3.3 and over 7 and over 3 and over
Source: MAS
since inception of favourable price incentives for some crops especially pulses and
increasing availability of water resources (Table 4.3). Cropping intensity of all field
28
crops with rice increased gradually from 107 percent in 1961-62 to 150 percent in
2003-04.
Source: DAP
It could be noted that the factors contributed to higher cropping intensities are as
follows:
- Increased irrigation
- Higher crop prices, e.g. pulses, to make double cropping more profitable.
29
- Growing a pre-monsoon crop before the main crop in rice growing area (jute,
cotton, sesame)
- Growing of some suitable crops after rice (summer paddy, groundnut, sunflower,
- Growing of two suitable crops in successive on dry land with or without irrigation
- Mixed cropping of two crops with different life periods in the same field (sesame
In fact, rice can be grown and harvested somewhere every month of the year.
As shown in Table 4.4, December is largest harvest (about 39 percent of total), and
195 kg per capita, the rice deficit can be estimated on a monthly basis, shown in last
column of Table 4.4. The December generates a surplus of about 4.56 million tons,
while the months of February to October are the lean months. The largest deficit
30
September 103712 62227.2 0.44 -766.52
Note: National rice gap refers to the gap between monthly production and monthly consumption, assuming
Myanmar farms are relatively larger than other ASEAN countries (Vietnamese
average farm size is just 0.49 ha, Minot and Goletti 2000). The average agricultural
household has 2.3 ha of agricultural land (Table 4.5). According to agricultural census
in 1993 the number of rural households with no agricultural land is about 7 percent.
Out of total agricultural area (nearly 11 million ha), rice sown area is about 53 percent
Source: SLRD
31
4.5 Cost of Production
The data for cost of production was obtained from MAS. The cost of
production will differ depending on the season and region. Among the purchased input,
urea is the most important, accounting for nearly 18 percent of total production. The
labour intensity of rice production also reflects variation in population densities. In the
table 4.6 for Ayeyarwady division (delta region), rice cultivation takes 153 man-days
per acre per season or more than 300 man days per hectare per season. It is relatively
higher than other ASEAN countries (Red River Delta in Vietnam has 246 man days per
hectare per season Pingali et al., 1998). That is because of farmers usually practice
transplant rice seedlings rather than broadcasting seeds to tolerate heavy rain. It,
Ayeyarwady division use 150 kg urea per hectare. The usage is relatively lower than
when comparing to Vietnam (more than 180 kg per hectare Minot and Goletti, 2000).
Also farmers in that region use FYM and bio composer to improve soil fertility.
Table 4.6 Cost of production for monsoon rice per acre for Ayeyarwady division (2003)
Source: MAS
32
Ayeyarwady division has the highest profit than other states and divisions, and rice
The GOM is continually facing the problem of scarce public and private capital.
So, the GOM cut off the fertilizer subsidies to farmers in 1994. As Soe (1994a)
maintain security and national stability and to support the subsidies of government
employees is considered highly unlikely in the immediate future was now become real
case in Myanmar. However, paddy production was increased although GOM has
Because of these limitations, imported farm inputs such as fertilizer were inadequate
to the use of improved technology. The considerable another constraint might be the
overvalued official exchange rate for private investment particularly when imported
On the other hand, the GOM also opened local markets for paddy farmers
after fulfilling compulsory delivery system to MAPT. So from 1990 onwards, it could be
seen farmers’ response to paddy price. In 2003, the GOM announced trade
liberalization in paddy/rice sector. But it was no longer, and again revoked the export
of rice. In respect of these factors, it’s still in question whether Myanmar rice sector
will grow rapidly or not although the country has rich capacity to potentially increase
rice production.
S r
= S r ( A,Y )
33
Where S r
= quantity of rice supply
___
Y = rice yield
From this equation, it could be obtained the price elasticity of output by summarizing
the elasticity of area and elasticity of yield with respect to price. Rice sown area is
A = A (P , P , A
r r t −1 f
)
t −1
P t −1
= lagged rice price of paddy
P f
= Price of fertilizer
A t −1
= lagged rice sown area
Hypothesis 2: If the input price (fertilizer) is increased, rice sown area will be
Hypothesis 3: Present rice sown area depends on the lagged rice sown area.
34
The expected yield depends on the following factors:
Y = Y ( P , P , MV )
r r t −1 f
Where Y r
= the expected yield of rice
P t −1
= lagged price of rice
P f
= price of fertilizer
Hypothesis 1: The expected yield of rice is depends on the lagged price of rice. If the
well their rice fields, consequently yield might be increased and vice
versa.
farmers may use lower rate of fertilizer and consequently yield may be
Hypothesis 3: It could be expected if farmers use modern or hybrid rice varieties, yield
In this section, regression analysis is used to examine the area response and
Where At is the rice sown area, Pt −1 is the lagged price of paddy, Pf is the
35
Yield response function is as follows:
fertilizer, MVt is the area for modern varieties hybrid varieties, and vt is the
disturbance term.
To estimate the elasticity for area response, yield response and supply, data
were collected from CSO, MAS and DAP. Price data were deflated by the general
consumer price index based on 1986 price. Supply elasticity is approximated with the
R2 0.96 0.87
(0.26) (0.224)
(0.029) (0.037)
At −1 0.513*** 0.513
(0.106)
(0.064)
standard errors.
36
the summation of the elasticity of area response and yield response.
R 2 indicates that the model is fit both in area response and yield response.
It is 0.96 for area response and 0.87 for yield response. The estimated price elasticity
for area response function is significant at 5 percent level though its value is very
small (0.053). It could be said that there is a little response by farmers to price
changes after 1990. Hossain and Oo (1995) found that the regression coefficient of
rice price with respect to area and yield is not significant in their analysis from 1960 to
1991. Here the estimated price elasticity for yield response is not significant in this
analysis too.
The regression results indicate that paddy production is much depends on the
lagged area and the use of modern varieties or hybrid varieties. The elasticity lagged
area is 0.513 and it is strongly significant at 1 percent level. That means the
expansion of rice area much depends on the government’s program for the
agricultural development, not on the price. The elasticity for modern varieties is 0.18
the rice production potential with increased technology (the use of MV and HYV).
It is found that the elasticity for main input (urea price) is significant both in
area response and yield response functions. It is -0.13 for area response and -0.067
for yield response, and both are significant at 5 percent level. Thus from 1990
37
CHAPTER 5
PADDY/RICE MARKETING AND DEMAND
urban consumption. Per capita consumption of rice is 129 kg in urban area, and 152
kg in rural area (CSO, 2001). Rice is consumed not only as rice, but also in the form
CSO, average per capita consumption is 159 kg. Monsoon rice in Delta region is
harvested from November to January, and summer rice is harvested from May to July.
In Central Dry zone, planting time depends on the feasibility of irrigation. Supply of
rice is related to the planting time and harvesting time. Marketing surplus of rice is
estimated based on CSO survey (Table 5.1). Though paddy is surplus for the whole
country, some regions such as Magway and Mandalay in the Central dry zone,
Tanintharyi division in Coastal region, and Shan state in the Mountainous region are
rice deficit areas. Thus rice is marketed from surplus to deficit areas.
mt)
38
Note: Marketable surplus is calculated based on 60 percent milling capacity and 14 percent for seed and
losses.
covers from farm level marketing to retail market and exports (Figure 5.1 and 5.2).
Farmers mostly sell their paddy in their own villages or in their fields
or farms just after harvesting. But in some cases, a few farmers mill part of their
paddy using a small mill in their villages. Then, they consume themselves or sell rice
to traders or retailers or consumers in the nearby markets. Some farmer store their
crops as an expectation to get higher price and sell just before next season harvesting
time especially when the price is highest. But it depends on their financial situation
and expected price. Collectors purchase paddy from farmers starting from October to
January for monsoon paddy, and from May to July for summer paddy. Most of primary
collectors sell to millers but some sell to township wholesalers. Before 2003, farmers
Three types of private mills can be categorized by small, medium and large.
Small mills with a capacity of 0.6 to 0.8 ton per hour are found in the rural areas and
play an important role. All private rice mills need to be registered with MAPT if they
have capacity of 0.6 metric ton per hour or more. Most private commercial mills have
a paddy milling capacity of 50 metric ton per day with a maximum of 70 metric ton per
Because of new rice trading policy, government owned rice mills, storage
facilities, and lands can be rented by charges. Most millers buy paddy from farmers,
39
Figure5.1: Paddy-Rice Marketing Channels from 1990 to 2002
Farmers
Traders (small
traders, retailers,
shopkeepers)
Domestic consumers
Remarks: Prices at the MAPT channels were at government determined prices, and
prices at private channels were at market prices.
40
Figure5.2: Paddy-Rice Marketing Channels from 2003
Farmers
Wholesalers
Traders
Domestic consumers
Government
procurement for
target groups
41
collectors, and sell the milled rice to traders. According to MAS, the average milling
capacity is nearly 60 percent. Before 2003, MAPT purchase paddy directly from
farmers with advanced payment or at government determined price for milling, and to
distribute target groups as milled rice and export surplus. But from 2004 harvest,
MAPT did not purchase directly from farmers. According to MAPT, there were 2189
registered mills with an estimate milling capacity of 50000 tons per day (Table 5.2).
Among this milling capacity, about 54 percent of milling capacity is used to process
rice at the farm level.
Source: MAPT
42
5.2.5 Export marketing
Government’s new rice trading policy has two-folds: removal of compulsory
quota delivery system for farmers and its replacement of purchasing paddy or rice
from millers or traders at prevailing market price, and lifting the ban on private export
of rice under certain circumstances. So, private traders can export rice if there is
surplus in the country. MAPT exported 0.1 million metric ton (approximately 60
percent of its purchase) in 2001-2002. According to MAPT estimates, it will purchase
around 70 percent of current volumes in future of which 40 percent will be reserved
for domestic sales and the other 30 percent reserved for buffer stock. MAPT will no
longer be in exporting rice in the future.
43
5.3 Rice Demand
There are several reasons to get information on food and calorie consumption
patterns for the analysis of rice price policy. First, government intervention in food
income and price elasticities is essential for the simulation of impact of policy changes
relationship between foreign exchange earning from rice export and rice consumption
is imminent debate to be sustainable for long term. Finally, there is a hot controversy
about the magnitude of the income elasticity of calorie intake compared with income
consumption.
This chapter first describes the pattern in rice consumption. Then trend in rice
consumption and purchases across regions and household types are expressed.
Finally, an econometric analysis of rice demand and the effects of price and income
Rice consumption was measured at the household level carried out by CSO
for the household income and expenditure survey (HIES) in 1997 as nation-wide scale.
estimated that rice per capita monthly consumption to be about 11 kg for urban and
13 kg for rural Myanmar. Thus, per capita monthly consumption of rice for rural
Myanmar is more than 2 kg per month that of urban or 24 kg per year. Table 5.3 shows
44
It was estimated that in all urban areas, per capita monthly consumption of
rice is more than 10 kg, the highest in Rakhine state about 15 kg, and the lowest in
Shan state about 11 kg. But in rural areas, per capita monthly consumption of rice is
more than 14 kg except Chin state about 11 kg, the highest in Rakhine state about 18
kg and the lowest in Chin state about 11 kg. Per capita monthly consumption of rice
for Yangon city is about 11 kg which is lower than that of Mandalay city about 13 kg.
Table 5.3 Monthly per capita consumption of rice in states and divisions
Urban Rural
Source: CSO
45
Table 5.4 Apparent rice consumption in Myanmar 1989-2002
Source: FAO
The only data on Myanmar rice consumption available for various years is
apparent rice consumption per capita (Table 5.4) from FAO, defined as net production
minus net exports minus losses, seed and feed divided by population. This rough data
stable from 1989 to now. According to official data, per capita GDP increased about 7
46
percent annually over this period, it implies that the income elasticity of rice demand
is close to zero.
rice among Myanmar households. The log linear approximation of the rice demand
function is used to estimate the own price elasticity and income elasticity of rice. Thus,
x
log Qr = α 0 + α 1 log Pr + α i log Pi + β log + ut
p
Pr = price of rice
Pi = price of other foods
X = the value of consumption expenditure per person
ut = disturbance term.
The derivation of the demand function is given in appendix B. There is a series
of price for 6 food categories including rice described in Table 5.5. The independent
variables include per capita consumption expenditure (x/p), food prices ( Pi ) and price
of rice ( Pr ). The community prices are used for the heterogenous group of foods.
analysis, the quantity of rice consumed is used as a dependent variable, and the price
of rice, the price of meat, the price of fish, the price of cooking oil and fats, the price
of fruits and vegetables and the community price of other foods are dependent
variables.
47
Table 5.5.Dependent and Independent variables in model of rice demand
2
The value of R is 0.96, and it indicates that the regression equation
x
q r = 2.8 − 0.1 log p1 + 0.2 log p 2 − 0.2 log p 3 − 0.04 log p 4 − 0.04 log p 5 − 0.05 log p 6 + 0.12 log
( 0.21) ( 0.02 ) ( 0.06 ) ( 0.07 ) ( 0.02 ) ( 0.03) ( 0.02 ) ( 0.05 ) p
Figures in parentheses are standard errors. The own-price elasticity of rice demand
(-0.1) indicates that there is a very little response to the rice price and little
substitutability between rice and other foods. According to the regression result, it is
strange that there is a positive relationship between the price of meat and the
quantity of rice consumed. It might be because of the very low income of people, and
consumers want to choose meat rather than fish if the price of meat and fish would be
the same. The expenditure elasticity is statistically significant at 5 percent level and it
48
CHAPTER 6
EVALUATION OF PRICING POLICY
Timmer (1987) noted that “When it comes to the price of a basic necessity such as
food, few governments are willing to accept the outcome of a freely competitive
Myanmar liberalized rice marketing both in domestic and international trade after its
intervention in rice marketing for a 40 years period. Thus, this paper focuses on the
evaluation of pricing policy in Myanmar from 1989 to 2003, and the impact of trade
liberalization though it is a short period. This has two interests: presently the
total farms.
pricing policy. Elasticity of rice supply and demand is used in the model. This involves
prices with those that are consistent with a hypothetical no intervention outcome, and
evaluation of welfare for producers, consumers and government net gain from
intervention. Finally a brief epilogue is discussed for the initial impact of rice market
liberalization.
involved rice marketing for several years through its agency (MAPT). MAPT’
49
involvement in trade and distribution to target groups is given in Appendices. GOM
procured 10 to 15 baskets from farmers at fixed price (lower than market price) on
production side, and on the consumption side, food subsidies to selected consumers
food prices are debated political issues in Myanmar. This section examines the effects
of these price distortions by using partial equilibrium model. The model can be
explored as follows:
large amount and the average volume of rice export is very small though export
intervention and no export, the price ( Pni ) will be determined at the intersection of
the national supply and demand schedules (Qni ) as in figure 6.1.
Supply
pb
p ni
Demand
q ni qb
elastic world market. Then production will expand to qb , and at the same time the
50
domestic prices will be raised and the domestic demand will suffer a considerable fall.
that ( pb − p d ) , to increase consumers’ welfare and its revenue, the producers will
adjust to the new price p d by reducing output to q d (Figure 6.2). Consequently,
producers will suffer a welfare loss of producers’ surplus. It includes payment of the
tax on the new level of output (rectangle a in Fig. 6.2) plus the deadweight loss
(triangle e in Fig. 6.2). Deadweight loss can be termed as the “efficiency” or “net
W p = qb ( p d − pb ) − NSL p
Supply
pb
a e
pd
Demand
qd qb
The implicit tax on producers and the consequent reduction of the price will
6.3). It includes welfare gain for consumers (rectangle b in Fig. 6.3) plus the
consumer surplus (triangle c in Fig. 6.3). It could be termed as net social loss in
consumption ( NSLc ) which affects both domestic producers and foreign consumers.
51
Thus, consumers’ welfare could be calculated as follows:
Wc = c d ( pb − p d ) − NSLc
Supply
pb
b
c
pd
Demand
cb cd
foreigners (qb − q d ) , and the loss of foreign exchange earnings for the quantity
diverted to domestic consumption (c d − cb ) . Thus it can be expressed as:
Change in FE = − p b (q b − q d + c d − cb )
new level of exports (after an implicit tax) with the unit tax rate ( pb − p d ) . It could be
calculated as:
summation of NSL p and NSLc (Figure 6.6). Therefore, how much on the magnitude
52
of the net social loss from the market distortion of paddy/rice commodity depends on
Supply
pb
pd
Demand
cb cd qd qb
Supply
pb
d
pd
Demand
cd qd
53
Supply
pb
c e
pd
Demand
cb cd qd qb
pb = border price
qb = quantity produced at the border price
cb = quantity consumed at the border price
E S = elasticity of supply
E D = elasticity of demand
Imposition of an export tax (implicit) changes the domestic price level and
Then, the net social loss in production ( NSL p ), equal to triangle e in Fig. 6.2, can be
measured as:
54
1
NSLP = (qb − q d )( pb − p d )
2
1 q − qb pb qb
NSL p = − ( d ) ( p d − pb )( pb − p d )
2 p d − pb qb pb
1 p − pb 2
= ES ( d ) pb qb
2 pb
1
= E S t 2 pb qb
2
Where, t = NRP = NPC − 1 = ( p d / pb ) − 1
In a similar fashion, it could be obtained net social loss in consumption:
1
NSLc = − E D t 2 pb cb
2
In this section, it is analyzed the effects of price intervention that can distort
producer incentives and influence the efficiency of resource allocation. The task
by eliminating of price distortions. Firstly, border prices are set as reference points
which are the international prices of a tradable commodity at the country’s border.
Second, by using the border prices it is calculated welfare effects of price intervention
distortion that is equal to the ratio of the domestic price of a commodity to its border
price. NPC greater than one means producers are protected and consumers are taxed,
less than one means producers are taxed and consumers are subsidized, and unity
means the protection is neutral. Otherwise, NPC which is greater than unity implies
that protective measures have been applied to encourage the domestic production of
the commodity, while NPC smaller than unity means that taxation measures
55
Table 6.1.Market exchange rate, consumers and producer price series (1990-2004)
Year Market exchange Producer price (A) Consumer Price (B) B/A
2004
There are two kinds of NPCs depending upon which domestic prices are used.
If farm-gate prices are used to calculate, it would be NPC for producers, and if the
wholesale prices are used, it would be NPC for consumers. Subtracting 1 from NPC
yields a nominal protection rate (NPR). NPR greater than zero means producers are
protected and consumers are taxed; NPR less than zero means that producers are
taxed and consumers are subsidized. Thus, if NPC greater than one or NPR greater
than zero implies that producers receive a price which, after direct interventions, is
above the border price, giving producers incentives to produce more of the commodity
Table 6.1 gives the market exchange rate, producer prices and consumer
56
price series from 1990 to 2004. There are two parallel markets for exchange rate in
Myanmar; official and unofficial (market exchange rate) rates. In this analysis, market
exchange rate is used because of the official exchange rate is extremely overvalued.
FOB export prices are used as border prices for Myanmar since Myanmar is exporting
country. Producer, consumer and border prices of rice are presented in Table 6.2.
producers consumers
2004
Note: Border price to consumers is the border price to producer plus a 15 percent mark-up for
The resulting NPC and NPR for producers and consumers are given in Table
6.3. The developed countries such as US and EEC have paid their producers as much
as five times the world price for sugar; and Japan pays on average about 2 and 1/2
times the world price (Tyres and Anderson, 1986). Since Myanmar is a developing
57
country, with NPCs less than one or (negative NPRs) not uncommon. For example, the
NPC in 1995 is 0.21, and it implies that the commodity is taxed at a 79 percent rate.
onwards, but it is still in a higher tax rate position. For example, NPC for 2003 is 0.60
subsidized fertilizers up to 1994 at a rate less than market price. So higher tax rate for
this period is acceptable while 1994 onwards it was an unreasonable policy. One
utilization.
2004
58
6.2.2 Partial equilibrium analyses of rice market intervention
government intervention on the rice market have been derived. To calculate trade
levels under the ‘no intervention scenario’, the computed NPC p , NPC c and the
estimated elasticities for national rice demand and supply are used. Then the
apparent effects of intervention are determined by comparing actual trade levels with
those generated by the model. In Myanmar, consumer price is always greater than
producer price. Border price is greater than that both of producer and consumer prices
except in 1993, 1995 and 2003 for which that of consumer price is higher than border
price.
The overall results of the partial equilibrium analyses are shown in Table 6.4
and 6.5 from 1990 to 2004. It has been evaluated the price intervention effects
government revenue and expenditures, net social efficiency losses, and changes in
the foreign exchange balance. The welfare trade-off depends on the intervention and
border prices of rice using the price elasticities of national demand and supply. The
decrease in price distortion though it is still high. From 1990 onwards even though the
producer loss is decreasing, the welfare for producer loss in 2002 is US$ 1029.95
million. In that year the government gained US$ 523.35 million as a result of
intervention. Consumers also gained US$ 372.98 million. The net social welfare loss
(total deadweight loss) amounted to US$ 76.38 million. But in 1993 and 1995 in which
the consumer price was higher than that of border price, both of consumers and
producers suffered losses. For producers it was US$ 1310.19 million and for
consumers it was US$ 113.29 million in 1993; and it was US$ 1777.03 million and
US$ 334.23 million for producers and consumers, respectively. But the government
gained US$ 1242.23 million in 1993 and US$ 1852.77 million in 1995. For the overall
study period from 1990 to 2003, net social loss summed up to US$ 4.31 billion.
59
6.2.3 Simulations
To quantify the effects of a few likely scenarios and policy changes because
the government of Myanmar liberalized the rice market from 2003, though it was
revoked for the export market, but in a nearly future it is expected to open the
international market like as domestic market_ the base case model is calibrated for
three cases from 2006 to 2010. These are summarized in scenarios 1-3.
(1) Production increase by 1 percent per annum over the 2003 level of 13.9
(3) FOB price of Myanmar rice to be maintained at US$ 130 per metric ton.
The resulting outcomes are shown in Table 6.6. In this analysis, it was assumed for
the year of 2004 and 2005 is the same as 2003 because of getting data is difficult.
Under such assumptions, consumers continue to gain but the magnitude of the gain
($ 206 million) is less than before 2002 except in 2003, 2004 and 2005. Producers are
still to be lost on the other hand but its magnitude in lost is much lower than before
2002. The net gain for government is about $ 207 million. Total deadweight loss
(1) Production increase by 1.5 percent per annum over 2003 level of 13.9
(3) Myanmar’s FOB price of rice to be maintained at US$ 130 per metric ton.
60
2010. However, consumers will be lost on the other hand by about $ 190 million in
2010. Net effect expected to be declined to $ 1 million comparing to the previous case.
(1) Production increase by 2 percent per annum over 2003 level of 13.9
million tonnes.
(3) Myanmar’s FOB price of rice to be maintained at US$ 130 per metric ton.
Different from the previous two scenarios, producers expected to be gained in this
case. Producers will be gained about $ 300 million in 2010. Consumers expected to be
lost about $ 600 million on the one hand. Conversely change in foreign will be started
to declined in this case. Total deadweight lost is expected to be greater than scenario
61
Table 6.4.Partial equilibrium effects of rice price intervention in Myanmar (1990-1996)
Production ('000 mt) 8428.98 7795.74 8761.8 9897 11109.42 10601.76 10438.2
Net Export ('000 mt) 216 199 201 265 1025 358 93
Apparent Domestic Consumption ('000 mt) 8212.98 7596.74 8560.8 9632 10084.42 10243.76 10345.2
Border price to producer (Pb) US$/mt 186 199 181 147 163 178 194
Producer price (Pp) US$/mt 22.56 22.56 22.56 33.6 33.6 36.92 45.77
Consumer price (Pc) US$/mt 46.6 51 89.8 158.8 148.2 210.58 161.68
Shift to No Intervention
Movement from Pp to Pb (%) 733.33 809.09 733.33 334.78 376.19 376.19 316.67
Movement from Pc to Pb (%) 354.55 354.55 132.56 6.38 26.58 -2.91 38.89
Increase/Decrease in output ('000mt) 6181.25 6307.46 6425.32 3313.34 4179.26 3988.28 3305.43
Increase/Decrease in consumption ('000mt) -2911.87 -2693.39 -1134.80 -61.48 -268.07 29.84 -402.31
Intervention outcome
62
Demand ('000mt) 8212.98 7596.74 8560.80 9632.00 10084.42 10243.76 10345.20
Results
Producer gain ($ million) -1882.76 -1931.92 -1897.23 -1310.19 -1707.96 -1777.03 -1792.24
Consumer gain ($ million) 941.93 925.01 729.00 -113.29 147.27 -334.23 327.86
Government Exp/Rev ($ million) 172.52 192.26 570.81 1242.23 1257.97 1852.77 1206.89
Change in foreign exchange ($ million) 1691.32 1791.17 1368.38 496.10 724.91 704.60 719.30
Efficiency loss in production ($ million) 505.13 556.44 509.01 187.87 270.40 281.33 244.98
Efficiency loss in consumption ($ million) 202.96 199.31 51.75 -0.36 1.98 0.49 6.50
Total deadweight loss ($ million) 708.09 755.76 560.76 187.50 272.38 281.82 251.48
Production ('000 mt) 9834.72 10084.68 11884.8 12592.14 12941.52 13083 13881.6
Apparent Domestic Consumption ('000 mt) 9805.72 9962.68 11829.8 12338.14 11992.52 12173 13837.6
Border price to producer (Pb) US$/mt 194 199 169 151 139 128 128
Producer price (Pp) US$/mt 77.13 49.71 45.79 41.62 25.17 54.36 76.33
Consumer price (Pc) US$/mt 113.68 113.05 137.14 106.13 65.22 96.55 129.5
63
NPCp 0.4 0.25 0.27 0.28 0.18 0.42 0.6
Shift to No Intervention
Movement from Pp to Pb (%) 150.00 300.00 270.37 257.14 455.56 138.10 66.67
Movement from Pc to Pb (%) 96.08 104.08 40.85 63.93 143.90 51.52 13.64
Increase/Decrease in output ('000mt) 1475.21 3025.40 3213.30 3237.98 5895.58 1806.70 925.44
Increase/Decrease in consumption ('000mt) -942.12 -1036.93 -483.19 -788.83 -1725.75 -627.09 -188.69
No Intervention outcome
Intervention outcome
Results
Producer gain ($ million) -1235.59 -1731.37 -1662.28 -1554.41 -1808.68 -1029.95 -741.17
Consumer gain ($ million) 749.76 811.73 369.20 535.91 821.15 372.98 -20.61
Government Exp/Rev ($ million) 357.13 628.28 1083.92 800.92 448.29 523.35 738.15
Change in foreign exchange ($ million) 468.96 808.40 624.71 608.05 1059.37 311.53 142.61
Efficiency loss in production ($ million) 86.20 225.83 197.96 177.09 335.55 66.52 23.91
Efficiency loss in consumption ($ million) 37.84 44.56 7.70 17.70 63.66 9.86 -0.14
Total deadweight loss ($ million) 124.04 270.39 205.65 194.78 399.21 76.38 23.77
64
Table 6.6.Scenario 1
Production ('000 mt) 13881.6 13881.6 14020.42 14160.62 14302.23 14445.25 14589.7
Apparent Domestic Consumption ('000 mt) 13837.6 13837.6 13837.6 13837.6 13837.6 13837.6 13837.6
Border price to producer (Pb) US$/mt 128 128 130 130 130 130 130
Producer price (Pp) US$/mt 76.33 76.33 100 100 100 100 100
Consumer price (Pc) US$/mt 129.5 129.5 115 115 115 115 115
Shift to No Intervention
Movement from Pp to Pb (%) 66.67 66.67 29.87 29.87 29.87 29.87 29.87
Movement from Pc to Pb (%) 13.64 13.64 13.64 13.64 13.64 13.64 13.64
Increase/Decrease in output ('000mt) 925.44 925.44 418.79 422.98 427.21 431.48 435.80
Increase/Decrease in consumption ('000mt) -188.69 -188.69 -188.69 -188.69 -188.69 -188.69 -188.69
No Intervention outcome
Intervention outcome
65
Demand ('000mt) 13837.60 13837.60 13837.60 13837.60 13837.60 13837.60 13837.60
Results
Producer gain ($ million) -741.17 -741.17 -426.89 -431.16 -435.48 -439.83 -444.23
Consumer gain ($ million) -20.61 -20.61 206.15 206.15 206.15 206.15 206.15
Government Exp/Rev ($ million) 738.15 738.15 207.56 207.56 207.56 207.56 207.56
Change in foreign exchange ($ million) 142.61 142.61 78.97 79.52 80.07 80.62 81.18
Efficiency loss in production ($ million) 23.91 23.91 6.28 6.34 6.41 6.47 6.54
Efficiency loss in consumption ($ million) -0.14 -0.14 1.42 1.42 1.42 1.42 1.42
Total deadweight loss ($ million) 23.77 23.77 7.70 7.76 7.82 7.89 7.95
Table 6.7.Scenario 2
Apparent Domestic Consumption ('000 mt) 13837.6 13837.6 13837.6 13837.6 13837.6
Border price to producer (Pb) US$/mt 130 130 130 130 130
66
Shift to No Intervention
No Intervention outcome
Intervention outcome
Results
67
Table 6.8.Scenario 3
Apparent Domestic Consumption ('000 mt) 13837.6 13837.6 13837.6 13837.6 13837.6
Border price to producer (Pb) US$/mt 130 130 130 130 130
Shift to No Intervention
68
No Intervention outcome
Intervention outcome
Results
69
CHAPTER 7
CONCLUSIONS
Historically Myanmar rice sector showed rather complex. The results indicate
that rice production responded to the 1990s contract system and advanced payment
the production area was increased under the government program for area expansion.
the government set a price (predetermined price) well below the market price. On the
consumption side, some target group of consumers were subsidized. This intervention
system made the government to use huge amount of government budget. All
combined forces in the economy pushed the government to liberalize the rice market
eventually in 2003. But this was not longer. It was revoked in 2004 for export market
So what has been the effect of this intervention system? It is usually argued
about liberalization but not on the previous history. From 1990 onward who bear the
burden of government policy testing? Who gained in the government’s game? There
were no clear estimates of these effects over time. This study uses a partial
particular on the effects of welfare for producers and consumers from 1990 to 2003.
The results indicate that producers are losers and hurt the rural people who especially
grow rice. At the same time consumers get benefit from the intervention almost every
year except in 1993, 1995 and 2003. The model also highlights that the impact of
70
heavy tax on producers. For example NPC in 1995 is 0.21 means that the commodity
(rice) is taxed at a 79 percent rate. Even in 2003, NPC for producers (0.66) indicate
that producers are still heavily taxed of 34 percent. NPC is the simplest indicator of
government pricing policy distortion. It could be imagined how much burden of lost
Moreover the study evaluates the welfare for producers, consumers, net
treasury gain for the government, change in foreign exchange and deadweight loss by
intervention and border prices of rice using the price elasticity of national demand and
supply. It was found that NPC is declining (price distortion is decreasing) from 1990
gradually though the protection rate is still higher even in 2003. The welfare for
producer loss in 2003 is US$ 741 million. Consumers gained from intervention except
in 1993, 1995 and 2003 on the other hand. For the study period from 1990 to 2003,
Policy Implication
GOM is now moving to liberalize rice markets. In April 2003 restrictions on the
internal movement of rice and export market were opened. Unexpectedly, however,
export market was revoked again in 2004. So the impact of trade liberalization is still
unclear. It is heard that military is now closed the movement of rice from Ayeyarway
and Bago divisions (main rice growing regions) for the sake of military stock while it is
writing this conclusion (beginning of 2006). So its policy context is rather complex. Its
71
decision seems to be irrational. But from the study point, the following implications
would be suggested. According to the simulation results, the future growth of rice
sector depends on the rice export. In turn effective marketing system with
order to develop such a system private sector’s participation is important. But there
will be some constraints of credit and information. More generally, support from the
carried out other research for regional and distributional dimensions in the analysis of
quantify the trade-off between regions and groups. For all round development of
agriculture sector it is better to study a chain of policy rather than only focusing on
food policy.
72
References
Anderson, Kym. Hayami, Yujiro, and others. 1986. The Political Economy of
Barrett, C.B. and Dorosh, P.A. 1996. Farmers’ Welfare and Changing Food Prices:
Barrett, C.B. 1997. Liberalization and Food Price distributions. ARCH-M evidence from
Behrman, Jere, and Anil Deolalikar. 1990. The Intrahousehold Demand for Nutrients in
Rural South India: Individual estimates, Fixed effects, and Permanent Income.
Cuddihy, William. 1980. Agricultural Price Management in Egypt. Staff working paper
Currie, J. John Murphy, and Andrew Schmitz. 1971. The Concept of Economic Surplus
analysis. The Economic Journal, Vol. 99, No. 395, Supplement: Conference Papers
1989, 1-37.
Diven, P.J. 2001. The Domestic Determinants of US Food Aid Policy. Food Policy 26,
2001: 455-474.
Dorosh, Paul, and Shahabuddin, Quazi. 2002, Rice Price Stabilization in Bangladesh:
Hartley, Micheal, Marc Nerlove, and Kyle Peters. 1987. Analysis of Rubber Supply in
Haughton, J., and et al. 2004. The Effects of Rice Policy on Food Self-sufficiency and on
73
Income Distribution in Vietnam. Department of Economics, Suffolk University, Boston,
USA.
Hossain, Mahabub, and Marlar Oo. 1995. “Myanmar Rice Economy: Policies,
Medium and Long-Term Rice Supply and Demand Project, Beijing, China.
Minot, N, and Goletti, F. 2000. Rice Market Liberalization and Poverty in Vietnam.
Morrisson and et al. 1991. Poverty and Income Distribution during Adjustment: Issues
and evidence from the OECD project. World Development Volume 19, Issue 11,
Myoung, Kwang-Sik, and Lee, Jun-Hwam, 1988. Evaluation of the Korean Market
Nielsen, Chantal Pohl. 2003. Vietnam’s Rice Policy: Recent Reforms and Future
Pingali, P. L., V-T. Xuan, N. T. Khiem, and R. V. Gerpacio. 1998. Prospects for sustaining
in India: The case of Andra Pradesh. Asian Development Bank: 1988. PP. 237-321.
74
Rahman, A, and Mahmud, W. 1988. Rice Market Intervention in Bangladesh. Asian
Ramaswami, B, and Balakrishnan, P. 2002. Food Policies and the Efficiency of Public
Intervention: The case of the public intervention system in India. Food Policy 27.
2002. 419-436.
Sadoulet, E, and Janvry, A.D. 1995. Quantitative Development Policy Analysis. The
Sah, Raaj, and Joseph Stiglitz. 1984. The Economics of Price Scissors. American
Smith, L.D. 1997. Price Stabilization, liberalization and Food Security: Conflicts and
Soe, Tin. 1994a. Economic environment of Myanmar agriculture: Markets and prices,
Myanmar Business and Economic Review, Ministry of Trade, Yangon, pp. 21-23.
Strauss, John, and Duncan Thomas. 1990. The Shape of the Calorie Expenditure
Curve. Economic Growth Centre Discussion paper no. 595. New Haven: Yale
University.
Streeten, P. 1987. What Price Food? Agricultural Price Policies in Developing Countries.
London: Macmillan.
Subramanian, Shankar, and Angus Deaton. 1992. The Demand for Food and Calories:
Scope, Effects and the Need for Reform. Asian Development Bank. 1988. 91-150.
75
Timmer, C.P., Falcon, W.P., and Pearson, S.R. 1983. Food Policy Analysis, Johns
Timmer, C.P. 1986a. Getting Prices Right: The Scope and Limits of Agricultural Price
Paddy/Rice Sector in Sri Lanka. MTID Discussion paper no. 70. IFPRI.
76
Appendices
(million (million
tons) tons)
Source: MAPT
77