2009 Warren Buffet Black-Scholes and Long Dated Options

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 13

First draft: May 2009

Current version: June 2009

Warren Buffett, Black-Scholes and the Valuation of Long-dated Options

BRADFORD CORNELL
CALIFORNIA INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY
PASADENA, CA 91125
626 564-2001
bcornell@hss.caltech.edu

I would like to thank Jaksa Cvitanic and Levon Goukasian for helpful comments.
Warren Buffett, Black-Scholes and the Valuation of Long-dated Options

Abstract

In his 2008 letter to Berkshire shareholders, Warren Buffett presented a critique of

the Black-Scholes option pricing model as a tool for valuing long-dated options, including

options that Berkshire had written. Given Mr. Buffett’s track record, it worth investigating

precisely why he thinks that the Black-Scholes model fails to provide a fair value for long-

dated options. Unfortunately, the alleged deficiencies in the model are not transparent

because Mr. Buffett’s letter fails to develop his viewpoint in terms of option pricing

theory. This short article fills the gap by interpreting Mr. Buffett’s argument in the context

of option pricing theory. It turns out that Mr. Buffett is really making a statement about

political economics more than option pricing.


Introduction: Warren Buffett on long-dated options

Despite referring to derivatives as weapons of mass financial destruction,

Warren Buffett has not been shy about investing in derivatives. In his 2008 letter to the

shareholders of Berkshire Hathaway, Mr. Buffett explains that that Berkshire will enter

into derivatives transactions if prices are sufficiently favorable. With respect to the

investments already made, he states, “I believe each contract we own was mispriced at

inception, sometimes dramatically so.”

In light of their reported poor performance, some Berkshire derivative contracts

have attracted particular attention. The source of the most controversy has been long

dated put options that Berkshire wrote on major stock market indexes, primarily the S&P

500. Using the required mark-to-market accounting, in 2008 Berkshire reported losses

exceeding $5 billion on these contracts. In light of the reported losses, Mr. Buffett went

to some lengths to explain why he thought the long-dated options were good investments.

His explanation was premised on the view that the Black-Scholes option pricing model

was a poor tool for valuing long-date equity index put options. Referring to the Black-

Scholes model, Mr. Buffett went so far as to say that “If the formula is applied to

extended periods, however, it can produce absurd results.” The purpose of this short

paper is to explore exactly why Mr. Buffett believes the Black-Scholes model leads to

absurd results by analyzing example calculations he presented in his shareholder letter.

II. Buffet’s Argument and the Black-Scholes Option Pricing Model

Rather than directly analyzing the Black-Scholes model, Mr. Buffett frames his

-1-
critique of the model in terms of example calculations. In deference to Mr. Buffett, and

to avoid mischaracterization, here is his entire explanation from the shareholder letter.

It’s often useful in testing a theory to push it to extremes. So let’s

postulate that we sell a 100- year $1 billion put option on the S&P 500 at a

strike price of 903 (the index’s level on 12/31/08). Using the implied volatility

assumption for long-dated contracts that we do, and combining that with

appropriate interest and dividend assumptions, we would find the “proper”

Black-Scholes premium for this contract to be $2.5 million.

To judge the rationality of that premium, we need to assess whether the

S&P will be valued a century from now at less than today. Certainly the dollar

will then be worth a small fraction of its present value (at only 2% inflation it

will be worth roughly 14¢). So that will be a factor pushing the stated value of

the index higher. Far more important, however, is that one hundred years of

retained earnings will hugely increase the value of most of the companies in the

index. In the 20th Century, the Dow-Jones Industrial Average increased by

about 175-fold, mainly because of this retained-earnings factor.

Considering everything, I believe the probability of a decline in the index

over a one-hundred-year period to be far less than 1%. But let’s use that figure

and also assume that the most likely decline – should one occur – is 50%.

Under these assumptions, the mathematical expectation of loss on our contract

would be $5 million ($1 billion x 1% x 50%).

But if we had received our theoretical premium of $2.5 million up front,

we would have only had to invest it at 0.7% compounded annually to cover this

-2-
loss expectancy. Everything earned above that would have been profit. Would

you like to borrow money for 100 years at a 0.7% rate?

Let’s look at my example from a worst-case standpoint. Remember that

99% of the time we would pay nothing if my assumptions are correct. But even

in the worst case among the remaining 1% of possibilities – that is, one

assuming a total loss of $1 billion – our borrowing cost would come to only

6.2%. Clearly, either my assumptions are crazy or the formula is inappropriate.

When Mr. Buffett refers to a $1 billion put option in the example, he means that

$1 billion is the maximum loss if the index were to go to zero. Given the hypothetical

index level of 903, this implies that the put options are effectively written on 11,074,200

units of the index. To use the Black-Sholes model to price European put options on an

index three inputs are required – the dividend yield, the risk-free rate and the volatility.

At the time that Mr. Buffett published his letter reasonable approximations for each of

these were 3%, 4.8% and 18%, respectively. The 3% dividend yield is both the

approximate yield on the date of Mr. Buffet’s letter and the approximate average payout

rate over the prior fifty years. The 4.8% risk-free rate is somewhat greater than the yield

on 30-year Treasury bonds because at the time of the Berkshire letter disruptions in the

financial market led many analysts, including Mr. Buffett, to believe that Treasury yields

were artificially low. The 18% is based on estimates of the long-run historical standard

deviation of nominal returns for the S&P 500. These assumptions are evidently quite

close to those used by Mr. Buffett because when they are substituted into the Black-

Scholes model the estimated value of the put position is found to be $2.46 million, within

rounding error of the $2.5 million figure that Mr. Buffett refers to in his letter.

-3-
Mr. Buffett clearly states that this value is much too high, but does not explicitly

explain why the model fails to give the appropriate value. One thing he points to is

inflation. Over the course of 100 years, depreciation in the purchasing power of the

dollar will tend to increase nominal stock prices. Although Mr. Buffett is right to stress

the impact of inflation, the Black-Scholes model takes account of this factor through the

use of the nominal risk-free rate. As long as the inflation rate impounded in the risk-free

rate is a reasonable estimate of long-run inflation, there will be no inflation bias in the

model’s estimate of value.

Although Mr. Buffett bases his example calculations on the future earnings

Berkshire could achieve by investing the option premiums, those potential earnings are

explicitly accounted for in the Black-Scholes model through the inclusion of the long-

term risk-free rate in the model. Consequently, when Mr. Buffett speaks of the

deficiencies of the model, he could not be referring to the failure to adequately account

for the time value of money.

It should be noted, however, that a long-horizon makes estimated option values

highly sensitive to the choice of the risk-free rate and the associated inflation rate that

underlies it. For example, if the risk-free rate is dropped to 3.8% the estimated value of

Mr. Buffett’s hypothetical option position rises almost fivefold to $11.1 million, whereas

if the rate is increased to 5.8% the estimated value falls by more than a factor of five to

only $0.45 million. Nonetheless, Mr. Buffett does not appear to be arguing that the

source of the mispricing is the failure to use a proper risk-free rate. The problem must lie

elsewhere.

-4-
The estimated value of long dated puts is also highly sensitive to the choice of the

dividend yield. Here, however, it is hard to quarrel with the choice of 3% because it

represents both the approximate current yield on the S&P 500 and, serendipitously, the

long-term average yield. Furthermore, Mr. Buffett does not claim in his letter that the

failings of the model are somehow tied to use of an improper dividend yield.

The final factor to consider, other than the form of the model itself, is the long-

term volatility. To review, the standard Black-Scholes model assumes that returns follow

a lognormal diffusion. This implies that the time T distribution of the stock price, or

index, is given by1

Ln ST ~ Normal [Ln S0 + ( – 2/2)*T, 2*T] . (1)

In equation (1), S0 is the current stock price, ST is the stock price at the date of expiration,

T,  is the drift which equals the expected return on the index minus the dividend yield,

and  is the volatility.

To apply equation (1) an estimate of  is required. Without reliving the extensive

debate on the equity risk premium, the risk-free rate is selected as an estimate of for .2

This implies that the equity premium equals the dividend yield. Given this assumption,

in addition to those previously discussed, equation (1) implies that the probability that ST

will be less than S0 100 years hence comes to about 4%, a number greater than the 1%

probability that Mr. Buffet claims is much too large. This means that Buffett has two

1
See, for example, Hull (2009)
2
See, for example, Cornell (1999).

-5-
possible beefs. First, the equity premium, and therefore, the drift should be larger.

Second, something is wrong with the volatility.

The culprit is unlikely to be the drift. Although variation in the drift does impact

the probability that the index will be below its initial level at expiration, it does not affect

the estimate of value produced by the Black-Scholes model. Because Mr. Buffett’s

ultimate view is that the model overvalues the puts, his main criticism cannot be based to

any meaningful extent on the drift term.

The final candidate, other than the arbitrage argument on which the model is

based, is the volatility. If Mr. Buffett is criticizing the use of the lognormal diffusion

assumption when pricing long-term options, he is not alone. Recall that the lognormal

assumption implies that volatility increases linearly with respect to the horizon over

which it is measured as shown in equation (1). There is empirical evidence which

indicates that the linearity assumption fails to hold at long horizons. For example, Siegel

(2008) reports that the variance of real returns on the S&P 500 historically have failed to

rise linearly with the horizon. If the long-run volatility is lower, the value of long-term

put options will be less. For instance, a volatility of 15%, instead of 18%, reduces the

estimated value of Mr. Buffett’s hypothetical put position to $1.5 million. It also reduces

the probability that the index will be lower at expiration than at initiation.

The assumption that volatility fails to rise linearly with the horizon of which it is

measured is not without controversy. First, the reduction that Siegel points to is less true

of nominal returns than real returns. Whereas Siegel (2008) reports that historical

volatility at 20-year horizons is about 25% below the prediction of the lognormal

diffusion model for real returns, the number using nominal returns is less than 12%. In

-6-
addition, the conclusion is sample dependent. At horizons of 10 years the lognormal

model essentially matches the historical data. Furthermore, some scholars, including

Pastor and Stambaugh (2009), argue that return volatility as a function of the horizon

may actually increase more than the lognormal assumption predicts.

In any event, the evidence regarding the volatility of nominal returns over the

long run is not strong enough to support Mr. Buffett’s contention that the Black-Scholes

model produces absurd results. He must have had something else in mind. It is unlikely

that Mr. Buffett put billions of dollars of Berkshire’s capital at risk on the basis of an

academic debate regarding the historical estimation of stock price volatility.

More fundamentally, the debate over historical estimation of volatility is

ultimately irrelevant because the model requires an estimate of future volatility. The

Black-Scholes model will produce “absurd results” if it is based historical estimates of

volatility that have become outdated. It is here, I believe, that Mr. Buffett parts ways

with the application of the Black-Scholes model on which Berkshire’s mark-to-market

accounting is based.

As Mr. Buffett notes, the value of long-dated put options is derived from the

extreme right hand tail of the distribution of outcomes for which the ending index value

is less than the strike price. Historically, this has been the result of a combination of two

factors – negative real stock returns and falling prices. For example, the worst period in

the history of the American stock market was from 1929 through 1932 when real returns

fell and there was significant deflation making nominal returns even more negative. The

value of long-dated puts is based on the likelihood that such events will occur again with

a likelihood that is determined largely by the volatility parameter. The key question,

-7-
therefore, is whether the assumption of lognormal diffusion assumption accurately

approximates the likelihood of such recurrences. Clues elsewhere in his letter suggest

that Mr. Buffett believes that it does not.

Early on in his letter, Mr. Buffett observes, with respect to the current economic

crisis, that

This debilitating spiral has spurred our government to take massive

action. In poker terms, the Treasury and the Fed have gone “all in.” Economic

medicine that was previously meted out by the cupful has recently been

dispensed by the barrel. These once-unthinkable dosages will almost certainly

bring on unwelcome aftereffects. Their precise nature is anyone’s guess, though

one likely consequence is an onslaught of inflation.

Mr. Buffett’s observations regarding response of the government to the current

crisis suggest that he believes a repeat of the 1930s is not possible. The reason being that

governments will respond strongly and aggressively to prevent downturns, even deep

downturns, from turning into deflationary spirals by providing whatever liquidity is

needed to halt deflation. If this is so, then the assumption that nominal stock returns

follow a lognormal diffusion over the long term with a volatility that can be estimated

from historical data is not realistic. Instead, the lower tail of the probability distribution

will be impacted by something akin to a soft reflecting barrier induced by the inflationary

reactions of governments and central banks to economic crises. Cornell, Cvitanic and

Goukasian (2009) show that the existence of such limitations on possible stock price

paths, compared with the assumption of a lognormal diffusion, has a significant impact

on option prices. In this case, the impact of inflationary government responses would be

-8-
to markedly reduce the estimated value of long-dated put options. Depending on the

aggressiveness of the governmental response to potential deflation, the values for long-

dated puts given by the standard Black-Scholes model using historical volatility can turn

out to be “absurdly high” as Mr. Buffett asserts.

There is one final clue that supports the foregoing interpretation of Mr. Buffett’s

investment in long-dated index puts. Remember that Mr. Buffett states that “if the

formula is applied to extended time periods, however, it can produce absurd results.”

This implies that over shorter time intervals Mr. Buffett believes that the formula yields

more reasonable results. Such reasoning is consistent with the political economics

interpretation of Mr. Buffett’s critique presented previously. During normal times, when

aggressive injection of liquidity is not required, the lognormal approximation is

reasonable. Where it breaks down is near the left-hand tail when extensive government

intervention is required to prevent deflation. But it is precisely that tail from which long-

dated puts derive their value. In the short-run, the probability of reaching the tail is too

small to be meaningful. But if volatility grows linearly with time, eventually the left-

hand tail becomes important. Government policies which cut off that tail, therefore, have

a dramatic impact on the value of long-dated puts but have little impact on short-dated

contracts except possibly during times of crisis.

In conclusion, although Mr. Buffett’s critique of the Black-Scholes model might

appear to be another attack on “geeks bearing formulas,” it is better seen as a statement

about the changing nature of America’s political economy. If threat of severe recession

and deflation cause governments to respond with massive injections of liquidity, then

naïve application of the Black-Scholes model will produce absurd results for long-dated

-9-
options if it is based on standard assumptions and historical data. The problem, however,

is not the theory on which the model is based, but that government intervention implies

that the long-run distribution of returns will not be lognormal. In particular, the left-

hand tail will be truncated, sharply reducing the value of long-dated put options. If this is

so, Mr. Buffett has made another wise investment even if his rationalization of it

somewhat misses the mark.

II. Conclusion

In his 2008 letter to Berkshire shareholders, Warren Buffett criticizes the Black-

Scholes option pricing model arguing that it can produce “absurd” values for long-dated

put options. Though Mr. Buffett does not explicitly say so, a careful analysis of his

viewpoint reveals that his criticism boils down to the belief that future nominal stock

prices are not well approximated by a lognormal distribution with a volatility estimated

from historical data. Instead, Mr. Buffett apparently believes that inflationary policies of

governments and central banks will limit future declines in nominal stock prices

compared with those predicted by an historically estimated lognormal distribution. If Mr.

Buffett is right on this point, then the Black-Scholes model will indeed significantly

overvalue long-dated put options.

- 10 -
REFERENCES

Buffett, Warren., 2009, Letter to the Shareholders of Berkshire Hathaway,

http://www.berkshirehathaway.com/letters/2008ltr.pdf.

Cornell, Bradford, 1999, The Equity Risk Premium and the Long-run Future of the Stock

Market. John Wiley and Sons, New York, NY.

Cornell, Bradford, Jaksa Cvitanic and Levon Goukasian, 2009, Beliefs regarding

fundamental value and optimal investing, unpublished working paper, California

Institute of Technology.

Hull, John C., 2009, Options, Futures and Other Derivative Securities, Seventh Edition,

Prentice-Hall, New York.

Pastor, Lubos and Robert F. Stambaugh, 2009, Are stocks really less volatile in the long

run?, unpublished working paper, Booth School of Business, University of Chicago.

Siegel, Jeremy, 2008, Stocks for the Long Run, McGraw-Hill, New York.

- 11 -

You might also like