Exam MFE/3F Sample Questions and Solutions: April 6, 2010
Exam MFE/3F Sample Questions and Solutions: April 6, 2010
Exam MFE/3F Sample Questions and Solutions: April 6, 2010
April 6, 2010
1
1. Consider a European call option and a European put option on a nondividend-paying
stock. You are given:
(A) 0.039
(B) 0.049
(C) 0.059
(D) 0.069
(E) 0.079
2
Solution to (1) Answer: (A)
The put-call parity formula (for a European call and a European put on a stock with the
same strike price and maturity date) is
C P F0,PT ( S ) F0,PT ( K )
F0,PT ( S ) KerT
= S0 KerT,
because the stock pays no dividends
Remark 1: If the stock pays n dividends of fixed amounts D1, D2,…, Dn at fixed times t1,
t2,…, tn prior to the option maturity date, T, then the put-call parity formula for European
put and call options is
C P F0,PT ( S ) KerT
S0 PV0,T(Div) KerT,
n
i 1
Remark 2: The put-call parity formula above does not hold for American put and call
options. For the American case, the parity relationship becomes
S0 PV0,T(Div) K ≤ C P ≤ S0 KerT.
This result is given in Appendix 9A of McDonald (2006) but is not required for Exam
MFE/3F. Nevertheless, you may want to try proving the inequalities as follows:
For the first inequality, consider a portfolio consisting of a European call plus an amount
of cash equal to PV0,T(Div) + K.
For the second inequality, consider a portfolio of an American put option plus one share
of the stock.
3
2. Near market closing time on a given day, you lose access to stock prices, but some
European call and put prices for a stock are available as follows:
After reviewing the information above, John tells Mary and Peter that no arbitrage
opportunities can arise from these prices.
Mary disagrees with John. She argues that one could use the following portfolio to
obtain arbitrage profit: Long one call option with strike price 40; short three call
options with strike price 50; lend $1; and long some calls with strike price 55.
Peter also disagrees with John. He claims that the following portfolio, which is
different from Mary’s, can produce arbitrage profit: Long 2 calls and short 2 puts
with strike price 55; long 1 call and short 1 put with strike price 40; lend $2; and
short some calls and long the same number of puts with strike price 50.
4
Solution to (2) Answer: (D)
The prices are not arbitrage-free. To show that Mary’s portfolio yields arbitrage profit,
we follow the analysis in Table 9.7 on page 302 of McDonald (2006).
Time T
Time 0
ST < 40 40≤ ST < 50 50≤ ST < 55 ST 55
Buy 1 call 11 0 ST – 40 ST – 40 ST – 40
Strike 40
Sell 3 calls + 18 0 0 3(ST – 50) 3(ST – 50)
Strike 50
Lend $1 1 erT erT erT erT
Buy 2 calls 6 0 0 0 2(ST – 55)
strike 55
Total 0 erT > 0 erT + ST – 40 erT + 2(55 ST) erT > 0
>0 >0
Remarks: Note that Mary’s portfolio has no put options. The call option prices are not
arbitrage-free; they do not satisfy the convexity condition (9.17) on page 300 of
McDonald (2006). The time-T cash flow column in Peter’s portfolio is due to the identity
max[0, S – K] max[0, K – S] = S K
(see also page 44).
In Loss Models, the textbook for Exam C/4, max[0, ] is denoted as +. It appears in the
context of stop-loss insurance, (S – d)+, with S being the claim random variable and d the
deductible. The identity above is a particular case of
x x+ (x)+,
which says that every number is the difference between its positive part and negative
part.
5
3. An insurance company sells single premium deferred annuity contracts with return
linked to a stock index, the time-t value of one unit of which is denoted by S(t). The
contracts offer a minimum guarantee return rate of g%. At time 0, a single premium
of amount is paid by the policyholder, and π y% is deducted by the insurance
company. Thus, at the contract maturity date, T, the insurance company will pay the
policyholder
π (1 y%) Max[S(T)/S(0), (1 + g%)T].
Determine y%, so that the insurance company does not make or lose money on this
contract.
6
Solution to (3)
Now, Max[0, 103 – S(1)] is the payoff of a one-year European put option, with strike
price $103, on the stock index; the time-0 price of this option is given to be is $15.21.
Dividends are incorporated in the stock index (i.e., = 0); therefore, S(0) is the time-0
price for a time-1 payoff of amount S(1). Because of the no-arbitrage principle, the time-
0 price of the contract must be
(/100)(1 y%){S(0) + 15.21}
= (/100)(1 y%) 115.21.
Remarks:
(i) Many stock indexes, such as S&P500, do not incorporate dividend reinvestments.
In such cases, the time-0 cost for receiving S(1) at time 1 is the prepaid forward
P
price F0,1 ( S ) , which is less than S(0).
7
4. For a two-period binomial model, you are given:
Calculate the price of an American call option on the stock with a strike price of 22.
(A) 0
(B) 1
(C) 2
(D) 3
(E) 4
8
Solution to (4) Answer: (C)
First, we construct the two-period binomial tree for the stock price.
32.9731
25.680
20 22.1028
17.214
14.8161
The calculations for the stock prices at various nodes are as follows:
Su 20 1.2840 25.680
Sd 20 0.8607 17.214
Suu 25.68 1.2840 32.9731
Sud Sdu 17.214 1.2840 22.1028
Sdd 17.214 0.8607 14.8161
9
Remark: Since the stock pays no dividends, the price of an American call is the same as
that of a European call. See pages 294-295 of McDonald (2006). The European option
price can be calculated using the binomial probability formula. See formula (11.17) on
page 358 and formula (19.1) on page 618 of McDonald (2006). The option price is
2 2 2
er(2h)[ p *2 Cuu + p * (1 p*)Cud + (1 p*)2 Cdd ]
2 1 0
0.1 2
= e [(0.4502) 10.9731 + 20.45020.54980.1028 + 0]
= 2.0507
10
5. Consider a 9-month dollar-denominated American put option on British pounds.
You are given that:
11
Solution to (5)
Each period is of length h = 0.25. Using the first two formulas on page 332 of McDonald
(2006):
u exp[–0.010.25 0.3 0.25 ] exp(0.1475) 1.158933,
d exp[–0.010.25 0.3 0.25 ] exp(0.1525) 0.858559.
Using formula (10.13), the risk-neutral probability of an up move is
e 0.010.25 0.858559
p* 0.4626 .
1.158933 0.858559
The risk-neutral probability of a down move is thus 0.5374. The 3-period binomial tree
for the exchange rate is shown below. The numbers within parentheses are the payoffs of
the put option if exercised.
2.2259
(0)
1.9207
(0)
1.6573 1.6490
(0) (0)
1.43 1.4229
(0.13) (0.1371)
1.2277 1.2216
(0.3323) (0.3384)
1.0541
(0.5059)
0.9050
(0.6550)
The payoffs of the put at maturity (at time 3h) are
Puuu 0, Puud 0, Pudd 0.3384 and Pddd 0.6550.
Now we calculate values of the put at time 2h for various states of the exchange rate.
12
Now we calculate values of the put at time h for various states of the exchange rate.
Remarks:
e( r ) h e( r ) h h 1 e h 1
(i) Because , we can also
e( r ) h h
e e h e h
( r ) h h
1 e h
calculate the risk-neutral probability p* as follows:
1 1 1
p* 0.46257.
0.15
1 e h 1 e0.3 0.25 1 e
1 e h 1
(ii) 1 p* 1 .
h h h
1 e 1 e 1 e
p* ½ 1 – p*.
13
6. You are considering the purchase of 100 units of a 3-month 25-strike European call
option on a stock.
(A) 0.04
(B) 1.93
(C) 3.50
(D) 4.20
(E) 5.09
14
Solution to (6) Answer: (C)
C ( S , K , , r , T , ) Se T N ( d 1 ) Ke rT N ( d 2 ) (12.1)
with
1
ln(S / K ) (r 2 )T
d1 2 (12.2a)
T
d 2 d1 T (12.2b)
Because S = $20, K = $25, = 0.24, r = 0.05, T = 3/12 = 0.25, and = 0.03, we have
1
ln(20 / 25) (0.05 0.03 0.242 )0.25
d1 2 = 1.75786
0.24 0.25
and
d2 = 1.75786 0.24 0.25 = 1.87786
15
7. Company A is a U.S. international company, and Company B is a Japanese local
company. Company A is negotiating with Company B to sell its operation in
Tokyo to Company B. The deal will be settled in Japanese yen. To avoid a loss at
the time when the deal is closed due to a sudden devaluation of yen relative to
dollar, Company A has decided to buy at-the-money dollar-denominated yen put of
the European type to hedge this risk.
16
Solution to (7)
Let X(t) be the exchange rate of U.S. dollar per Japanese yen at time t. That is, at time t,
¥1 = $X(t).
We are given that X(0) = 1/120.
Thus, Company A purchases 120 billion units of a put option whose payoff three months
from now is
$ Max[1201 – X(¼), 0].
The exchange rate can be viewed as the price, in US dollar, of a traded asset, which is the
Japanese yen. The continuously compounded risk-free interest rate in Japan can be
interpreted as the dividend yield of the asset. See also page 381 of McDonald (2006)
for the Garman-Kohlhagen model. Then, we have
r = 0.035, = 0.015, S = X(0) = 1/120, K = 1/120, T = ¼.
Because the logarithm of the exchange rate of yen per dollar is an arithmetic Brownian
motion, its negative, which is the logarithm of the exchange rate of dollar per yen, is also
an arithmetic Brownian motion and has the SAME volatility. Therefore, {X(t)} is a
geometric Brownian motion, and the put option can be priced using the Black-Scholes
formula for European put options. It remains to determine the value of , which is given
by the equation
1
= 0.261712 %.
365
Hence,
= 0.05.
Therefore,
(r 2 / 2)T (0.035 0.015 0.052 / 2) / 4
d1 = = = 0.2125
T 0.05 1 / 4
and
17
In Exam MFE/3F, you will be given a standard normal distribution table. Use the value
of N(0.21) for N(d1), and N(0.19) for N(d1).
Remarks:
(i) Suppose that the problem is to be solved using options on the exchange rate of
Japanese yen per US dollar, i.e., using yen-denominated options. Let
$1 = ¥U(t)
at time t, i.e., U(t) = 1/X(t).
Because Company A is worried that the dollar may increase in value with respect to
the yen, it buys 1 billion units of a 3-month yen-denominated European call option,
with exercise price ¥120. The payoff of the option at time ¼ is
¥ Max[U(¼) 120, 0].
To apply the Black-Scholes call option formula (12.1) to determine the time-0 price
in yen, use
r = 0.015, = 0.035, S = U(0) = 120, K = 120, T = ¼, and 0.05.
Then, divide this price by 120 to get the time-0 option price in dollars. We get the
same price as above, because d1 here is –d2 of above.
The above is a special case of formula (9.7) on page 292 of McDonald (2006).
18
8. You are considering the purchase of a 3-month 41.5-strike American call option on
a nondividend-paying stock.
0.15 x 2 / 2
(A) 20 – 20.453 e dx
0.15 x 2 / 2
(B) 20 – 16.138 e dx
0.15 x 2 / 2
(C) 20 – 40.453 e dx
0.15 x 2 / 2
(D) 16 .138 e dx 20 .453
0.15 x 2 / 2
(E) 40 .453 e dx – 20.453
19
Solution to (8) Answer: (D)
Since it is never optimal to exercise an American call option before maturity if the stock
pays no dividends, we can price the call option using the European call option formula
C SN ( d 1 ) Ke rT N ( d 2 ) ,
1
ln(S / K ) (r 2 )T
where d1 2 and d 2 d1 T .
T
Because the call option delta is N(d1) and it is given to be 0.5, we have d1 = 0.
Hence,
d2 = – 0 .3 0 .25 = –0.15 .
To find the continuously compounded risk-free interest rate, use the equation
1
ln(40 / 41.5) (r 0.32 ) 0.25
d1 2 0,
0.3 0.25
which gives r = 0.1023.
Thus,
C = 40N(0) – 41.5e–0.1023 × 0.25N(–0.15)
= 20 – 40.453[1 – N(0.15)]
= 40.453N(0.15) – 20.453
40.453 0.15 x 2 / 2
= e
2
dx – 20.453
0.15 x 2 / 2
= 16 .138 e dx 20 .453
20
9. Consider the Black-Scholes framework. A market-maker, who delta-hedges, sells a
three-month at-the-money European call option on a nondividend-paying stock.
If, after one day, the market-maker has zero profit or loss, determine the stock price
move over the day.
(A) 0.41
(B) 0.52
(C) 0.63
(D) 0.75
(E) 1.11
21
Solution to (9)
According to the first paragraph on page 429 of McDonald (2006), such a stock price
move is given by plus or minus of
S(0) h ,
where h 1/365 and S(0) 50. It remains to find .
Because the stock pays no dividends (i.e., 0), it follows from the bottom of page 383
that N(d1). By the condition N(d1) = 0.6179, we get d1 0.3. Because S K and
0, formula (12.2a) is
(r 2 / 2)T
d1
T
or
d
½2 – 1 + r 0.
T
With d1 0.3, r 0.1, and T 1/4, the quadratic equation becomes
½2 – 0.6 + 0.1 0,
whose roots can be found by using the quadratic formula or by factorization,
½( 1)( 0.2) = 0.
We reject = 1 because such a volatility seems too large (and none of the five answers
fit). Hence,
S(0) h = 0.2 50 0.052342 0.52.
Remarks: The Itô’s Lemma in Chapter 20 of McDonald (2006) can help us understand
Section 13.4. Let C(S, t) be the price of the call option at time t if the stock price is S at
that time. We use the following notation
2
CS(S, t) = C ( S , t ) , CSS(S, t) = C ( S , t ) , Ct(S, t) = C ( S , t ) ,
S S 2 t
t = CS(S(t), t), t = CSS(S(t), t), t = Ct(S(t), t).
At time t, the so-called market-maker sells one call option, and he delta-hedges, i.e., he
buys delta, t, shares of the stock. At time t + dt, the stock price moves to S(t + dt), and
option price becomes C(S(t + dt), t + dt). The interest expense for his position is
[tS(t) C(S(t), t)](rdt).
Thus, his profit at time t + dt is
t[S(t + dt) S(t)] [C(S(t + dt), t + dt) C(S(t), t)] [tS(t) C(S(t), t)](rdt)
= tdS(t) dC(S(t), t) [tS(t) C(S(t), t)](rdt). (*)
22
Because dS(t) = S(t)[ dt + dZ(t)], it follows from the multiplication rules (20.17) that
[dS(t)]2 = [S(t)]2 2 dt, (***)
which should be compared with (13.8). Substituting (***) in (**) yields
dC(S(t), t) = t dS(t) + ½t [S(t)]2 2 dt + t dt,
application of which to (*) shows that the market-maker’s profit at time t + dt is
{½t [S(t)]2 2 dt + t dt} [tS(t) C(S(t), t)](rdt)
= {½t [S(t)]2 2 + t [tS(t) C(S(t), t)]r}dt, (****)
which is the same as (13.9) if dt can be h.
Now, at time t, the value of stock price, S(t), is known. Hence, expression (****), the
market-maker’s profit at time t+dt, is not stochastic. If there are no riskless arbitrages,
then quantity within the braces in (****) must be zero,
Ct(S, t) + ½2S2CSS(S, t) + rSCS(S, t) rC(S, t) = 0,
which is the celebrated Black-Scholes equation (13.10) for the price of an option on a
nondividend-paying stock. Equation (21.11) in McDonald (2006) generalizes (13.10) to
the case where the stock pays dividends continuously and proportional to its price.
Although (***) holds because {S(t)} is a geometric Brownian motion, the analogous
equation,
[S(t + h) S(t)2 = [S(t)2h, h > 0,
which should be compared with (13.8) on page 429, almost never holds. If it turns out
that it holds, then the market maker’s profit is approximated by the right-hand side of
(13.9). The expression is zero because of the Black-Scholes partial differential equation.
23
10. Consider the Black-Scholes framework. Let S(t) be the stock price at time t, t 0.
Define X(t) ln[S(t)].
n
(iii) lim
n
[ X ( jT / n) X (( j 1)T / n)]2 = 2 T.
j 1
24
Solution to (10) Answer: (E)
(i) is true. That {S(t)} is a geometric Brownian motion means exactly that its logarithm is
an arithmetic Brownian motion. (Also see the solution to problem (11).)
(ii) is true. Because {X(t)} is an arithmetic Brownian motion, the increment, X(t + h)
X(t), is a normal random variable with variance 2 h. This result can also be found at the
bottom of page 605.
n
2T 2 / n + 2T/n) [Z(T) Z(0)] + [ Z ( jT / n) Z (( j 1)T / n)]2 .
j 1
As n , the first two terms on the last line become 0, and the sum becomes T
according to formula (20.6) on page 653.
25
motion. This result is a reason why the true stock price process (20.25) and the risk-
neutral stock price process (20.26) must have the same . A discussion on realized
quadratic variation can be found on page 755 of McDonald (2006).
A quick “proof” of the quadratic variation formula (20.6) can be obtained using
T 2
the multiplication rule (20.17c). The left-hand side of (20.6) can be seen as 0 [dZ (t )] .
Formula (20.17c) states that [dZ (t )]2 = dt. Thus,
T 2 T
0 [dZ (t )] 0 dt T.
26
11. Consider the Black-Scholes framework. You are given the following three
statements on variances, conditional on knowing S(t), the stock price at time t.
d S (t )
(ii) Var S (t ) 2 dt
S (t )
27
Here are some facts about geometric Brownian motion. The solution of the stochastic
differential equation
dS (t )
dt + dZ(t) (20.1)
S (t )
is
S(t) S(0) exp[( – ½2)t + Z(t)]. (*)
Formula (*), which can be verified to satisfy (20.1) by using Itô’s Lemma, is equivalent
to formula (20.29), which is the solution of the stochastic differential equation (20.25). It
follows from (*) that
S(t + h) = S(t) exp[( – ½2)h Zt + h) Z(t)]], h 0. (**)
From page 650, we know that the random variable Zt + h) Z(t)] has the same
distribution as Z(h), i.e., it is normal with mean 0 and variance h.
d S (t )
(ii) is true: Var S (t ) = Var[dt + dZ(t)|S(t)]
S (t )
= Var[dt + dZ(t)|Z(t)],
because it follows from (*) that knowing the value of S(t) is equivalent to knowing the
value of Z(t). Now,
Var[dt + dZ(t)|Z(t)] = Var[ dZ(t)|Z(t)]
= Var[dZ(t)|Z(t)]
= Var[dZ(t)] independent increments
= 2 dt.
dS (t )
Remark: The unconditional variance also has the same answer: Var 2 dt.
S (t )
28
(iii) is true because (ii) is the same as
Var[dS(t) | S(t)] = S(t)2 2 dt,
and
Var[dS(t) | S(t)] = Var[S(t + dt) S(t) | S(t)]
= Var[S(t + dt) | S(t)].
We can also show that (iii) is true by means of the formula for the variance of a
lognormal random variable (McDonald 2006, eq. 18.14): It follows from formula (**) on
the last page that
Var[S(t + h) | S(t)] = Var[S(t) exp[( – ½2)h + Zt + h) Z(t)]] | S(t)]
= [S(t)]2 exp[2( – ½2)h] Var[exp[Zt + h) Z(t)]] | S(t)]
= [S(t)]2 exp[2( – ½2)h] Var[exp[Z(h)]]
Thus,
Var[S(t + dt) | S(t)] = [S(t)]2 × 1 × 1 × (dt × 2),
which is (iii).
29
12. Consider two nondividend-paying assets X and Y. There is a single source of
uncertainty which is captured by a standard Brownian motion {Z(t)}. The prices of
the assets satisfy the stochastic differential equations
dX (t )
= 0.07dt 0.12dZ(t)
X (t )
and
dY (t )
= Adt + BdZ(t),
Y (t )
where A and B are constants.
Determine A.
(A) 0.0604
(B) 0.0613
(C) 0.0650
(D) 0.0700
(E) 0.0954
30
Solution to (12) Answer: (B)
If f(x) is a twice-differentiable function of one variable, then Itô’s Lemma (page 664)
simplifies as
df(Y(t)) f ′(Y(t))dY(t) + ½ f ″(Y(t))[dY(t)]2,
because f (x ) = 0.
t
1 1 1
d[ln Y(t)] = dY(t) [dY (t )]2 . (1)
Y (t ) 2 [Y (t )]2
It is pointed out in Section 20.4 that two assets having the same source of randomness
must have the same Sharpe ratio. Thus,
(0.07 – 0.04)/0.12 = (A – 0.04)/B = (A – 0.04)/0.085
Therefore, A = 0.04 + 0.085(0.25) = 0.06125 0.0613
31
13. Let {Z(t)} be a standard Brownian motion. You are given:
t
(iii) W(t) t2 Z(t) 2 sZ ( s)ds
0
32
Solution to (13) Answer: (E)
33
14. You are using the Vasicek one-factor interest-rate model with the short-rate process
calibrated as
dr(t) 0.6[b r(t)]dt dZ(t).
For t T, let P(r, t, T) be the price at time t of a zero-coupon bond that pays $1 at
time T, if the short-rate at time t is r. The price of each zero-coupon bond in the
Vasicek model follows an Itô process,
dP[r (t ), t , T ]
[r(t), t, T] dt q[r(t), t, T] dZ(t), t T.
P[r (t ), t , T ]
34
Solution to (14)
For t < T, (r, t, T) is the time-t continuously compounded expected rate of return
on the zero-coupon bond that matures for 1 at time T, with the short-rate at time t being r.
Because all bond prices are driven by a single source of uncertainties, {Z(t)}, the
(r , t , T ) r
no-arbitrage condition implies that the ratio, , does not depend on T. See
q(r , t , T )
(24.16) on page 782 and (20.24) on page 660 of McDonald (2006).
In the Vasicek model, the ratio is set to be , a constant. Thus, we have
(0.05, 1, 4) 0.05 (0.04, 0, 2) 0.04
. (*)
q (0.05, 1, 4) q(0.04, 0, 2)
To finish the problem, we need to know q, which is the coefficient of −dZ(t) in
dP[r (t ), t , T ]
. To evaluate the numerator, we apply Itô’s Lemma:
P[r (t ), t , T ]
dP[r(t), t, T] Pt[r(t), t, T]dt Pr[r(t), t, T]dr(t) ½Prr[r(t), t, T][dr(t)]2,
which is a portion of (20.10). Because dr(t) a[b r(t)]dt dZ(t), we have
[dr(t)]2 = 2dt, which has no dZ term. Thus, we see that
q(r, t, T) = Pr(r, t, T)/P(r, t, T) which is a special case of (24.12)
= lnP(r, t, T)].
r
In the Vasicek model and in the Cox-Ingersoll-Ross model, the zero-coupon bond
price is of the form
P(r, t, T) A(t, T) eB(t, T)r;
hence,
q(r, t, T) = lnP(r, t, T)] = B(t, T).
r
In fact, both A(t, T) and B(t, T) are functions of the time to maturity, T – t. In the Vasicek
model, B(t, T) [1 ea(T t)]/a. Thus, equation (*) becomes
(0.05, 1, 4) 0.05 (0.04, 0, 2) 0.04
.
a ( 4 1)
1 e 1 e a ( 2 0)
Because a = 0.6 and (0.04, 0, 2) = 0.04139761, we get (0.05, 1, 4) = 0.05167.
35
Remarks:
(i) The second equation in the problem is equation (24.1) [or (24.13)] of MacDonald
(2006). In its first printing, the minus sign on the right-hand side is a plus sign.
(ii) Unfortunately, zero-coupon bond prices are denoted as P(r, t, T) and also as
P(t, T, r) in McDonald (2006).
(iv) If the zero-coupon bond prices are of the so-called affine form,
P(r , t, T) A(t, T) eB(t, T)r ,
where A(t, T) and B(t, T) are independent of r, then (24.12) becomes
q(r, t, T) σ(r)B(t, T).
Thus, (24.17) is
(r , t , T ) r (r , t , T ) r
(r, t) = ,
q (r , t , T ) (r ) B(t , T )
from which we obtain
(r, t, T) = r (r, t)(r) B(t, T).
In the Vasicek model, σ(r) σ, (r, t) , and
(r, t, T) = r + σB(t, T).
r
In the CIR model, σ(r) σ r , (r, t) , and
(r, t, T) = r + rB (t , T ) .
In either model, A(t, T) and B(t, T) depend on the variables t and T by means of their
difference T – t, which is the time to maturity.
where the asterisk signifies that the expectation is taken with respect to the risk-
neutral probability measure. Under the risk-neutral probability measure, the expected
rate of return on each asset is the risk-free interest rate. Now, (24.13) is
36
dP[r (t ), t , T ]
[r(t), t, T] dt q[r(t), t, T] dZ(t)
P[r (t ), t , T ]
Then, applying
~
Z (t ) = dZ(t) [r(t), t]dt (***)
to (**) yields
dP[r (t ), t , T ] ~
r(t)dt q[r(t), t, T]d Z (t ) ,
P[r (t ), t , T ]
which is analogous to (20.26) on page 661. The risk-neutral probability measure is
~
such that Z (t ) is a standard Brownian motion.
Applying (***) to equation (24.2) yields
dr(t) a[r(t)]dt σ[r(t)]dZ(t)
~
a[r(t)]dt σ[r(t)]{d Z (t ) [r(t), t]dt}
~
{a[r(t)] σ[r(t)][r(t), t]}dt σ[r(t)]d Z (t ) ,
which is (24.19) on page 783 of McDonald (2006).
37
15. You are given the following incomplete Black-Derman-Toy interest rate tree model
for the effective annual interest rates:
16.8%
17.2%
12.6%
9% 13.5%
9.3% 11%
Calculate the price of a year-4 caplet for the notional amount of $100. The cap rate
is 10.5%.
38
Solution to (15)
First, let us fill in the three missing interest rates in the B-D-T binomial tree. In terms of
the notation in Figure 24.4 of McDonald (2006), the missing interest rates are rd, rddd, and
ruud. We can find these interest rates, because in each period, the interest rates in
different states are terms of a geometric progression.
0.135 0.172
rdd 10.6%
rdd 0.135
ruud 0.168
ruud 13.6%
0.11 ruud
2
0.11 0.168
rddd 8.9%
rddd 0.11
The payment of a year-4 caplet is made at year 4 (time 4), and we consider its discounted
value at year 3 (time 3). At year 3 (time 3), the binomial model has four nodes; at that
time, a year-4 caplet has one of four values:
Then, we calculate the caplet’s value in each of the two nodes at time 1:
Remarks:
(i) The discussion on caps and caplets on page 805 of McDonald (2006) involves a loan.
This is not necessary.
(ii) If your copy of McDonald was printed before 2008, then you need to correct the
typographical errors on page 805; see
http://www.kellogg.northwestern.edu/faculty/mcdonald/htm/typos2e_01.html
(iii)In the earlier version of this problem, we mistakenly used the term “year-3 caplet” for
“year-4 caplet.”
39
Alternative Solution: The payoff of the year-4 caplet is made at year 4 (at time 4). In a
binomial lattice, there are 16 paths from time 0 to time 4.
For the uuuu path, the payoff is (16.8 – 10.5)+
For the uuud path, the payoff is also (16.8 – 10.5)+
For the uudu path, the payoff is (13.6 – 10.5)+
For the uudd path, the payoff is also (13.6 – 10.5)+
:
:
We discount these payoffs by the one-period interest rates (annual interest rates) along
interest-rate paths, and then calculate their average with respect to the risk-neutral
probabilities. In the Black-Derman-Toy model, the risk-neutral probability for each
interest-rate path is the same. Thus, the time-0 price of the caplet is
1
16
{ 1.09 1(16.126.8 10 .5)
1.172 1.168
+
(16.8 10.5)
1.09 1.126 1.172 1.168
+
(13.6 10.5)
1.09 1.126 1.172 1.136
+
(13.6 10.5)
1.09 1.126 1.172 1.136
+ ……………… }
=
1
8
{ 1.09 1(16.126.8 10 .5)
1.172 1.168
+
(9 10.5)
1.09 1.093 1.106 1.09
} = 1.326829.
Remark: In this problem, the payoffs are path-independent. The “backward induction”
method in the earlier solution is more efficient. However, if the payoffs are path-
dependent, then the price will need to be calculated by the “path-by-path” method
illustrated in this alternative solution.
40
16. Assume that the Black-Scholes framework holds. Let S(t) be the price of a
nondividend-paying stock at time t, t ≥ 0. The stock’s volatility is 20%, and the
continuously compounded risk-free interest rate is 4%.
You are interested in contingent claims with payoff being the stock price raised to
some power. For 0 t T, consider the equation
Ft P,T [ S (T ) x ] S (t ) x ,
where the left-hand side is the prepaid forward price at time t of a contingent claim
that pays S (T ) x at time T. A solution for the equation is x 1.
(A) 4
(B) 2
(C) 1
(D) 2
(E) 4
41
Solution to (16) Answer (B)
Remarks:
(i) McDonald (2006, Section 20.7) has provided three derivations for (20.30). Here is
another derivation. Define Y = ln[S(T)/S(t)]. Then,
Ft ,PT [S(T)x] = E t [er(Tt) S(T)x] Prepaid forward price
42
17. You are to estimate a nondividend-paying stock’s annualized volatility using its
prices in the past nine months.
Calculate the historical volatility for this stock over the period.
(A) 83%
(B) 77%
(C) 24%
(D) 22%
(E) 20%
43
Solution to (17) Answer (A)
This problem is based on Sections 11.3 and 11.4 of McDonald (2006), in particular,
Table 11.1 on page 361.
Let {rj} denote the continuously compounded monthly returns. Thus, r1 = ln(80/64),
r2 = ln(64/80), r3 = ln(80/64), r4 = ln(64/80), r5 = ln(80/100), r6 = ln(100/80),
r7 = ln(80/64), and r8 = ln(64/80). Note that four of them are ln(1.25) and the other four
are –ln(1.25); in particular, their mean is zero.
Remarks: Further discussion is given in Section 23.2 of McDonald (2006). Suppose that
we observe n continuously compounded returns over the time period [, + T]. Then,
h = T/n, and the historical annual variance of returns is estimated as
1 1 n 1 n n
h n 1 j 1
(r j r ) 2 =
T n 1 j 1
(r j r ) 2 .
Now,
1 n 1 S ( T )
r =
n j 1
r j = ln
n S ()
,
44
18. A market-maker sells 1,000 1-year European gap call options, and delta-hedges the
position with shares.
Under the Black-Scholes framework, determine the initial number of shares in the
delta-hedge.
(A) 586
(B) 594
(C) 684
(D) 692
(E) 797
45
Solution to (18) Answer: (A)
By formula (14.15) in McDonald (2006), the time-0 price of the gap option is
Cgap = SN(d1) 130N(d2) = [SN(d1) 100N(d2)] 30N(d2) = C 30N(d2),
where d1 and d2 are calculated with K = 100 (and r = δ = 0) and T = 1, and C denotes the
time-0 price of the plain-vanilla call option with exercise price 100.
1 x2 / 2
Remark: The formula for the standard normal density function, e , can be
2
found in the Normal Table distributed to students.
46
19. Consider a forward start option which, 1 year from today, will give its owner a
1-year European call option with a strike price equal to the stock price at that time.
Under the Black-Scholes framework, determine the price today of the forward start
option.
(A) 11.90
(B) 13.10
(C) 14.50
(D) 15.70
(E) 16.80
47
Solution to (19) Answer: (C)
Let S1 denote the stock price at the end of one year. Apply the Black-Scholes formula to
calculate the price of the at-the-money call one year from today, conditioning on S1.
d2 d1 T d1 0.117
Thus, the time-0 price of the forward start option must be 0.157 multiplied by the time-0
price of a security that gives S1 as payoff at time 1, i.e., multiplied by the prepaid forward
price F0P,1( S ) . Hence, the time-0 price of the forward start option is
0.157 F0P,1( S ) = 0.157e0.08 F0,1( S ) = 0.157e0.08100 14.5
Remark: A key to pricing the forward start option is that d1 and d2 turn out to be
independent of the stock price. This is the case if the strike price of the call option will
be set as a fixed percentage of the stock price at the issue date of the call option.
48
20. Assume the Black-Scholes framework. Consider a stock, and a European call
option and a European put option on the stock. The current stock price, call price,
and put price are 45.00, 4.45, and 1.90, respectively.
Investor A purchases two calls and one put. Investor B purchases two calls and
writes three puts.
The current elasticity of Investor A’s portfolio is 5.0. The current delta of Investor
B’s portfolio is 3.4.
(A) –0.55
(B) –1.15
(C) –8.64
(D) –13.03
(E) –27.24
49
Solution to (20) Answer: (D)
Applying the formula
portfolio portfolio value
S
to Investor B’s portfolio yields
3.4 2C – 3P. (1)
Remarks:
(i) If the stock pays no dividends, and if the European call and put options have the
same expiration date and strike price, then C P = 1. In this problem, the put
and call do not have the same expiration date and strike price; so this relationship
does not hold.
(ii) If your copy of McDonald (2006) was printed before 2008, then you need to replace
the last paragraph of Section 12.3 on page 395 by
http://www.kellogg.northwestern.edu/faculty/mcdonald/htm/erratum395.pdf
The ni in the new paragraph corresponds to the i on page 389.
(iii) The statement on page 395 in McDonald (2006) that “[t]he elasticity of a portfolio
is the weighted average of the elasticities of the portfolio components” may remind
students, who are familiar with fixed income mathematics, the concept of duration.
Formula (3.5.8) on page 101 of Financial Economics: With Applications to
Investments, Insurance and Pensions (edited by H.H. Panjer and published by The
Actuarial Foundation in 1998) shows that the so-called Macaulay duration is an
elasticity.
(iv) In the Black-Scholes framework, the hedge ratio or delta of a portfolio is the partial
derivative of the portfolio price with respect to the stock price. In other continuous-
time frameworks (which are not in the syllabus of Exam MFE/3F), the hedge ratio
may not be given by a partial derivative; for an example, see formula (10.5.7) on
page 478 of Financial Economics: With Applications to Investments, Insurance and
Pensions.
50
21. The Cox-Ingersoll-Ross (CIR) interest-rate model has the short-rate process:
dr (t ) a[b r (t )]dt r (t ) dZ (t ) ,
where {Z(t)} is a standard Brownian motion.
For t T, let P(r, t , T ) be the price at time t of a zero-coupon bond that pays $1 at
time T, if the short-rate at time t is r. The price of each zero-coupon bond in the
CIR model follows an Itô process:
dP[r (t ), t , T ]
[r (t ), t , T ]dt q[r (t ), t , T ]dZ (t ) , t T.
P[r (t ), t , T ]
(A) 0.042
(B) 0.045
(C) 0.048
(D) 0.050
(E) 0.052
51
Solution to (21) Answer: (C)
As pointed out on pages 782 and 783 of McDonald (2006), the condition of no riskless
arbitrages implies that the Sharpe ratio does not depend on T,
(r , t , T ) r
(r , t ). (24.17)
q(r , t , T )
(Also see Section 20.4.) This result may not seem applicable because we are given an
for t = 7 while asked to find an for t = 11.
Remarks: (i) In earlier printings of McDonald (2006), the minus sign in (24.1) was
given as a plus sign. Hence, there was no minus sign in (24.12) and would be a
negative constant. However, these changes would not affect the answer to this question.
(ii) What McDonald calls Brownian motion is usually called standard Brownian motion
by other authors.
52
22. You are given:
(iii) g(r, t) denotes the price of an interest-rate derivative at time t, if the short-
rate at that time is r. The interest-rate derivative does not pay any
dividend or interest.
(A) (r 0.09)g
(B) (r 0.08)g
(C) (r 0.03)g
(D) (r + 0.08)g
(E) (r + 0.09)g
53
Solution to (22) Answer: (D)
is the stochastic differential equation for r(t) under the true probability measure, while
formula (24.19),
dr (t ) a(r (t )) (r (t )) (r (t ), t ) dt (r (t ))dZ (t ) ,
is the stochastic differential equation for r(t) under the risk-neutral probability measure,
where (r, t) is the Sharpe ratio. Hence,
(r) = 0.3,
and
0.15 – 0.5r = a(r)r)(r, t)
= [0.09 – 0.5r(r)(r, t)
= [0.09 – 0.5r](r, t).
Thus, (r, t) = 0.2.
Now, for the model to be arbitrage free, the Sharpe ratio of the interest-rate derivative
should also be given by (r, t). Rewriting (iv) as
dg (r (t ), t ) μ(r (t ), g (r (t ), t ))
dt 0.4dZ (t ) [cf. equation (24.13)]
g (r (t ), t ) g (r (t ), t )
and because there are no dividend or interest payments, we have
(r , g (r , t ))
r
g (r , t )
= (r, t) [cf. equation (24.17)]
0.4
= 0.2.
Thus,
(r, g) = (r + 0.08)g.
54
23. Consider a European call option on a nondividend-paying stock with exercise date
T, T 0. Let S(t) be the price of one share of the stock at time t, t 0. For
0 t T , let C(s, t) be the price of one unit of the call option at time t, if the stock
price is s at that time. You are given:
dS (t )
(i) 0.1dt dZ (t ) , where is a positive constant and {Z(t)} is a
S (t )
Brownian motion.
dC ( S (t ), t )
(ii) ( S (t ), t )dt C ( S (t ), t )dZ (t ), 0t T
C ( S (t ), t )
(iii) C(S(0), 0) 6.
(iv) At time t 0, the cost of shares required to delta-hedge one unit of the call
option is 9.
(A) 0.10
(B) 0.12
(C) 0.13
(D) 0.15
(E) 0.16
55
Solution to (23) Answer: (C)
Because
S (0) ( S (0), 0) 9
1.5 ,
C ( S (0), 0) 6
we have
(S(0), 0) 0.04 + 1.5 × (0.1 0.04) 0.13
(which is the time-0 continuously compounded expected rate of return on the option).
Remark: Equation (21.20) on page 687 of McDonald (2006) should be the same as
(12.9) on page 393,
option = || × ,
and (21.21) should be changed to
r option r
= sign() × .
option
Note that , option, and option are functions of t.
56
24. Consider the stochastic differential equation:
dX(t) = [ – X(t)]dt dZ(t), t ≥ 0,
where and are positive constants, and {Z(t)} is a standard Brownian motion.
The value of X(0) is known.
Find a solution.
t (t s )
(E) X(t) X(0) et (1 – et) 0e dZ ( s )
57
Solution to (24) Answer: (E)
The given stochastic differential equation is (20.9) in McDonald (2006).
Rewrite the equation as
dX(t) X(t)dt = dt dZ(t).
If this were an ordinary differential equation, we would solve it by the method of
integrating factors. (Students of life contingencies have seen the method of integrating
factors in Exercise 4.22 on page 129 and Exercise 5.5 on page 158 of Actuarial
Mathematics, 2nd edition.) Let us give this a try. Multiply the equation by the integrating
factor et, we have
et dX(t) + etX(t)dt etdt et dZ(t). (*)
We hope that the left-hand side is exactly d[etX(t)]. To check this, consider f(x, t) = etx,
whose relevant derivatives are fx(x, t) = et, fxx(x, t) = 0, and ft(x, t) = etx. By Itô’s
Lemma,
df(X(t), t) et dX(t) + 0 + et X(t)dt,
which is indeed the left-hand side of (*). Now, (*) can be written as
d[esX(s)] esds esdZ(s).
Integrating both sides from s = 0 to s = t, we have
t t t
e t X (t ) e 0 X (0) e s ds e s dZ (s ) (e t 1) e s dZ (s ) ,
0 0 0
or
t
etX(t) X(0) (et – 1) e s dZ (s ) .
0
which is (E).
58
Remarks: This question is the same as Exercise 20.9 on page 674. In the above, the
solution is derived by solving the stochastic differential equation, while in Exercise 20.9,
you are asked to use Itô’s Lemma to verify that (E) satisfies the stochastic differential
equation.
If t > 0, we differentiate (E). The first and second terms on the right-hand side are not
random and have derivatives X(0)et and et, respectively. To differentiate the
stochastic integral in (E), we write
t (t s ) t
0 e dZ (s ) = e t es dZ (s ) ,
0
0
X (0)e t e t e s dZ (s ) dt e t dt dZ (t )
t
0
[ X (t ) (1 e t )]dt e t dt dZ (t )
[ X (t ) ]dt dZ (t ),
which is the same as the given stochastic differential equation.
59
25. Consider a chooser option (also known as an as-you-like-it option) on a
nondividend-paying stock. At time 1, its holder will choose whether it becomes a
European call option or a European put option, each of which will expire at time 3
with a strike price of $100.
The stock price is $95 at time t = 0. Let C(T) denote the price of a European call
option at time t = 0 on the stock expiring at time T, T 0, with a strike price of
$100.
Determine C(3).
(A) $ 9
(B) $11
(C) $13
(D) $15
(E) $17
60
Solution to (25) Answer: (B)
Let C(S(t), t, T) denote the price at time-t of a European call option on the stock, with
exercise date T and exercise price K 100. So,
C(T) C(95, 0, T).
Similarly, let P(S(t), t, T) denote the time-t put option price.
Thus,
C(3) 20 (4 + 5) 11.
61
26. Consider European and American options on a nondividend-paying stock.
You are given:
You are interested in the graph for the price of an option as a function of the current
stock price. In each of the following four charts IIV, the horizontal axis, S,
represents the current stock price, and the vertical axis, , represents the price of an
option.
I. II.
III. IV.
Match the option with the shaded region in which its graph lies. If there are two or
more possibilities, choose the chart with the smallest shaded region.
62
26. Continued
(B) II I IV III
(D) II II IV III
(E) II II IV IV
63
Solution to (26) Answer: (D)
Thus, the shaded region in II contains CAm and CEu. (The shaded region in I also does,
but it is a larger region.)
For a European put, we can use put-call parity and the inequality S(0) CEu to get a
tighter upper bound,
PV0,T(K) PEu.
Thus,
PV0,T(K) PEu Max[0, PV0,T(K) S(0)],
64
Remarks:
(i) It turns out that II and IV can be found on page 156 of Capiński and Zastawniak
(2003) Mathematics for Finance: An Introduction to Financial Engineering,
Springer Undergraduate Mathematics Series.
(ii) The last inequality in (9.9) can be derived as follows. By put-call parity,
CEu PEu F0P,T ( S ) erTK
F0P,T ( S ) erTK because PEu 0.
We also have
CEu 0.
Thus,
CEu Max[0, F0P,T ( S ) erTK].
(iii) An alternative derivation of the inequality above is to use Jensen’s Inequality (see,
in particular, page 883).
CEu E* e Max(0, S (T ) K )
rT
(iv) That CEu CAm for nondividend-paying stocks can be shown by Jensen’s Inequality.
65
27. You are given the following information about a securities market:
(iv) There are three possible outcomes for the prices of X and Y one year from
now:
Outcome X Y
1 $200 $0
2 $50 $0
3 $0 $300
Calculate PY C X .
(A) $4.30
(B) $4.45
(C) $4.59
(D) $4.75
(E) $4.94
66
Solution to (27) Answer: (A)
B: e.1 1
200
X: 100 50
Y: 100 0
300
?? 95
0
The time-1 payoffs come from:
(95 – 0)+ (200 – 95)+ = 95 – 105 = 10
(95 – 0)+ (50 – 95)+ = 95 – 0 = 95
(95 – 300)+ (0 – 95)+ = 0 – 0 = 0
So, this is a linear algebra problem. We can take advantage of the 0’s in the time-1
payoffs. By considering linear combinations of securities B and Y, we have
Y
B : e 0.1 1 3 1
300
67
Y
We now consider linear combinations of this security, B , and X. For replicating
300
the payoff of the put-minus-call security, the number of units of X and the number of
Y
units of B are given by
300
1
200 1 10
.
50 1 95
Thus, the time-0 price of the put-minus-call security is
1
200 1 10
0.1
(100, e 3 ) 1
.
50 1 95
Applying the 2-by-2 matrix inversion formula
1
a b 1 d b
c d ad bc c a
to the above, we have
1 1 1 10
(100, e 0.1 1 3 )
200 50 50 200 95
1 105
(100, 0.571504085)
150 19500
= 4.295531 4.30.
Remarks:
(i) We have priced the security without knowledge of the real probabilities. This is
analogous to pricing options in the Black-Scholes framework without the need to
know , the continuously compounded expected return on the stock.
(ii) Matrix calculations can also be used to derive some of the results in Chapter 10 of
McDonald (2006). The price of a security that pays Cu when the stock price goes
up and pays Cd when the stock price goes down is
1
uSe h erh Cu
( S 1) h
dSe erh Cd
1 e rh e rh Cu
( S 1)
uSe ( r ) h dSe ( r ) h dSe
h
uSe h Cd
1 C
( r ) h
(e rh de h ue h e rh ) u
(u d )e Cd
e ( r ) h d u e ( r ) h Cu
e rh ( )
ud ud Cd
C
e rh ( p * 1 p *) u .
Cd
68
(iii) The concept of state prices is introduced on page 370 of McDonald (2006). A state
price is the price of a security that pays 1 only when a particular state occurs. Let
us denote the three states at time 1 as H, M and L, and the corresponding state prices
as QH, QM and QL.
QH 0
QM 1
QL 0
Hence,
1
1 200 0
(QH QM QL ) (e0.1 100 100) 1 50 0 ( 0.4761 0.0953 0.3333) .
1 0 300
69
28. Assume the Black-Scholes framework. You are given:
(ii) S(0) 10
At time t 0, you write a one-year European option that pays 100 if [S(1)]2 is
greater than 100 and pays nothing otherwise.
Calculate the number of shares of the stock for your hedging program at time t 0.
(A) 20
(B) 30
(C) 40
(D) 50
(E) 60
70
Solution to (28) Answer: (A)
Note that [S(1)]2 100 is equivalent to S(1) 10. Thus, the option is a cash-or-nothing
option with strike price 10. The time-0 price of the option is
100 × erT N(d2).
To find the number of shares in the hedging program, we differentiate the price formula
with respect to S,
100e rT N ( d 2 )
S
d 1
= 100e rT N ( d 2 ) 2 = 100e rT N (d 2 ) .
S S T
0.02 e0 / 2 1
100e
2 2
50e0.02
2
19.55.
71
29. The following is a Black-Derman-Toy binomial tree for effective annual interest
rates.
6%
5%
r0 rud
3%
2%
Compute the “volatility in year 1” of the 3-year zero-coupon bond generated by the
tree.
(A) 14%
(B) 18%
(C) 22%
(D) 26%
(E) 30%
72
Solution to (29) Answer: (D)
According to formula (24.48) on page 800 in McDonald (2006), the “volatility in year 1”
of an n-year zero-coupon bond in a Black-Derman-Toy model is the number such that
y(1, n, ru) = y(1, n, rd) e2,
where y, the yield to maturity, is defined by
n 1
1
P(1, n, r) = .
1 y (1, n, r )
Here, n = 3 [and hence is given by the right-hand side of (24.53)]. To find P(1, 3, ru)
and P(1, 3, rd), we use the method of backward induction.
P(2, 3, ruu)
P(1, 3, ru)
P(1, 3, rd)
P(2, 3, rdd)
1 1
P(2, 3, ruu) = ,
1 ruu 1.06
1 1
P(2, 3, rdd) = ,
1 rdd 1.02
1 1 1
P(2, 3, rdu) = ,
1 rud 1 ruu rdd 1.03464
1
P(1, 3, ru) = [½ P(2, 3, ruu) + ½ P(2, 3, rud)] = 0.909483,
1 ru
1
P(1, 3, rd) = [½ P(2, 3, rud) + ½ P(2, 3, rdd)] = 0.945102.
1 rd
Hence,
y (1,3, ru ) [ P (1,3, ru )]1/ 2 1 0.048583
e = = = ,
y (1,3, rd ) [ P (1,3, rd )]1/ 2 1 0.028633
resulting in = 0.264348 26%.
Remarks: (i) The term “year n” can be ambiguous. In the Exam MLC/3L textbook
Actuarial Mathematics, it usually means the n-th year, depicting a period of time.
However, in many places in McDonald (2006), it means time n, depicting a particular
instant in time. (ii) It is stated on page 799 of McDonald (2006) that “volatility in year 1”
is the standard deviation of the natural log of the yield for the bond 1 year hence. This
statement is vague. The concrete interpretation of “volatility in year 1” is the right-hand
side of (24.48) on page 800, with h = 1.
73
30. You are given the following market data for zero-coupon bonds with a maturity
payoff of $100.
A 2-period Black-Derman-Toy interest tree is calibrated using the data from above:
Year 0 Year 1
ru
r0
rd
Calculate rd, the effective annual rate in year 1 in the “down” state.
(A) 5.94%
(B) 6.60%
(C) 7.00%
(D) 7.27%
(E) 7.33%
74
Solution to (30) Answer: (A)
Year 0 Year 1
ru rd e 2 1
r0
rd
In a BDT interest rate model, the risk-neutral probability of each “up” move is ½.
Because the “volatility in year 1” of the 2-year zero-coupon bond is 10%, we have
1 10%.
We are given P(0, 1) 0.9434 and P(0, 2) 0.8850, and they are related as follows:
Thus,
1 1 2 0.8850
1.8762,
1 rd e 0.2
1 rd 0.9434
or
2 rd (1 e 0.2 ) 1.8762[1 rd (1 e0.2 ) rd 2 e 0.2 ],
which is equivalent to
1.8762e 0.2 rd 2 0.8762(1 e 0.2 ) rd 0.1238 0.
The solution set of the quadratic equation is {0.0594, 0.9088}. Hence,
rd 5.94%.
75
31. You compute the current delta for a 50-60 bull spread with the following
information:
How much does delta change after 1 month, if the stock price does not change?
76
Solution to (31) Answer: (B)
Assume that the bull spread is constructed by buying a 50-strike call and selling a 60-
strike call. (You may also assume that the spread is constructed by buying a 50-strike put
and selling a 60-strike put.)
(delta for the 50-strike call) – (delta for the 60-strike call).
(You get the same delta value, if put options are used instead of call options.)
1
ln(S / K ) (r 2 )T
Call option delta N(d1), where d1 2
T
50-strike call:
1
ln(50 / 50) (0.05 0.2 2 )(3 / 12)
d1 2 0.175 , N(d1) N(0.18) 0.5714
0.2 3 / 12
60-strike call:
1
ln(50 / 60) (0.05 0.2 2 )(3 / 12)
d1 2 1.6482 , N(d1) N(–1.65)
0.2 3 / 12
1 – 0.9505 0.0495
Delta of the bull spread 0.5714 – 0.0495 0.5219.
60-strike call:
1
ln(50 / 60) (0.05 0.2 2 )(2 / 12)
d1 2 2.0901 , N(d1) N(–2.09)
0.2 2 / 12
1 – 0.9817 0.0183
Delta of the bull spread after one month 0.5557 – 0.0183 0.5374.
77
32. At time t 0, Jane invests the amount of W(0) in a mutual fund. The mutual fund
employs a proportional investment strategy: There is a fixed real number , such
that, at every point of time, 100% of the fund’s assets are invested in a
nondividend paying stock and 100% in a risk-free asset.
d W (t )
(A) = [ + (1 – )r]dt + dZ(t)
W (t )
(B) W(t) = W(0)exp{[ + (1 – )r]t + Z(t)}
(C) W(t) = W(0)exp{[ + (1 – )r – ½2]t + Z(t)}
(D) W(t) = W(0)[S(t)/S(0)] e(1 – )rt
(E) W(t) = W(0)[S(t)/S(0)] exp[(1 – )(r + ½2)t]
78
Solution to (32) Answer: (E)
A proportional investment strategy means that the mutual fund’s portfolio is continuously
re-balanced. There is an implicit assumption that there are no transaction costs.
At each point of time t, the instantaneous rate of return of the mutual fund is
d W (t ) dS (t )
= + (1 – )rdt
W (t ) S (t )
= [dt + dZ(t)] + (1 – )rdt
= [ + (1 – )r]dt + dZ(t). (1)
We know
S(t) = S(0)exp[( – ½2)t + Z(t)]. (2)
The solution to (1) is similar,
W(t) = W(0)exp{[ + (1 – )r – ½(2]t + Z(t)}. (3)
Remarks:
(i) There is no restriction that the proportionality constant is to be between 0 and 1. If
0, the mutual fund shorts the stock; if > 1, the mutual fund borrows money to
buy more shares of the stock.
(ii) If the stock pays dividends continuously, with amount S(t)dt between time t and time
t+dt, then we have equation (20.25) of McDonald (2006),
dS (t )
= (dt + dZ(t),
S (t )
whose solution is
S(t) = S(0)exp[( ½2)t + Z(t)]. (5)
Since
d W (t ) dS (t )
= dt + (1 – )rdt
W (t ) S (t )
= [ + (1 – )r]dt + dZ(t),
formula (3) remains valid. Raising equation (5) to power and applying it to (3)
yields
W(t) = W(0)[S(t)/S(0)] exp{[(1 – )r – ½(2 + ½2)]t}
= W(0)[S(t)/S(0)] exp{[(1 – )(r ½2)]t}. (6)
79
Note that as in (4), Z(t) and do not appear explicitly in (6). As a check for the
validity of (6), let us verify that
F0,Pt [W(t)] = W(0). (7)
Since
F0,Pt [W(t)] = W(0)S(0)exp{[(1 – )(r ½2)]t} F0,Pt [S(t)],
equation (7) immediately follows from (20.30) of McDonald (2006).
80
33. You own one share of a nondividend-paying stock. Because you worry that its
price may drop over the next year, you decide to employ a rolling insurance
strategy, which entails obtaining one 3-month European put option on the stock
every three months, with the first one being bought immediately.
Your broker will sell you the four options but will charge you for their total cost
now.
Under the Black-Scholes framework, how much do you now pay your broker?
(A) 1.59
(B) 2.24
(C) 2.85
(D) 3.48
(E) 3.61
81
Solution to (33) Answer: (C)
The problem is a variation of Exercise 14.22, whose solution uses the concept of the
forward start option in Exercise 14.21.
Let us first calculate the current price of a 3-month European put with strike price being
90% of the current stock price S.
With K = 0.9×S, r = 0.08, = 0.3, and T = ¼, we have
ln( S / 0.9S ) (r ½2 )T ln(0.9) (0.08 ½ 0.09) ¼
d1 = 0.9107
T 0.3 ¼
d2 = d1 – T d1 – 0.3 ¼ 0.7607
N(–d1) N(–0.91) = 1 – N(0.91) 1 – 0.8186 0.1814
N(–d2) N(–0.76) = 1 – N(0.76) 1 – 0.7764 0.2236
For the rolling insurance strategy, four put options are needed. Their costs are
0.0159S(0) at time 0, 0.0159S(¼) at time ¼, 0.0159S(½) at time ½, and 0.0159S(¾) at
time ¾. Their total price at time 0 is the sum of their prepaid forward prices.
82
34. The cubic variation of the standard Brownian motion for the time interval [0, T] is
defined analogously to the quadratic variation as
n
lim {Z [ jh] Z [( j 1)h]}3 ,
n
j 1
where h T/n.
83
Solution to (34) Answer: (A)
Alternative argument:
n T
lim {Z [ jh] Z [( j 1)h]}3 [dZ (t )]3 .
n 0
j 1
84
35. The stochastic process {R(t)} is given by
t
R(t ) R(0)et 0.05(1 et ) 0.1 e s t R( s)dZ ( s),
0
Find dX(t).
0.1 X (t ) 2 X (t ) dt 0.2 X (t ) 4 dZ (t )
3
(A)
0.11 X (t ) 2 X (t ) dt 0.2 X (t ) 4 dZ (t )
3
(B)
0.12 X (t ) 2 X (t ) dt 0.2 X (t ) 4 dX (t )
3
(C)
0.1 2 R (0) e t
3
(E) X (t )dt 0.2[ X (t )] 4 dZ (t )
85
Solution to (35) Answer: (B)
t t
e R( s )dZ ( s ) as et e s R( s)dZ ( s ) .
s t
To find dR(t), write the integral
0 0
Then,
t
dR(t ) R(0)e t dt 0.05e t dt 0.1e t dt e s R ( s)dZ ( s ) 0.1e t et R (t )dZ (t )
0
Thus,
[dR(t)]2 [0.1 R(t ) ] 2 dt = 0.01R(t)dt,
and
dX (t ) 2 R(t ){[0.05 R(t )]dt 0.1 R(t )dZ (t )} 0.01R(t )dt
{0.11R(t ) 2[ R(t )]2 }dt 0.2[ R(t )]3/ 2 dZ (t )
0.11 X (t ) 2 X (t ) dt 0.2[ X (t )]3/ 4 dZ (t ).
Answer is (B).
86
36. Assume the Black-Scholes framework. Consider a derivative security of a stock.
You are given:
Find k.
(A) 0.04
(B) 0.05
(C) 0.06
(D) 0.07
(E) 0.08
87
Solution to (36) Answer: (E)
We are given that the time-t price of the derivative security is of the form
V[S(t), t] [S(t)]a,
where a is a negative constant.
The function V must satisfy the Black-Scholes partial differential equation (21.11)
V V 1 2 2 2V
( r δ) S S rV .
t s 2 s 2
Here, 0 because the stock does not pay dividends.
1
0 (r 0) S aS a 1 2 S 2 a(a 1) S a 2 rS a ,
2
or
1
ra 2 a(a 1) r ,
2
which is a quadratic equation of a. One obvious solution is a 1 (which is not negative).
The other solutions is
2r
a 2 .
Consequently, k 2r 2(0.04) 0.08.
Alternative Solution:
Let V[S(t), t] denote the time-t price of a derivative security that does not pay dividends.
Then, for t ≤ T,
V[S(t), t] Ft P,T (V [ S (T ), T ]) .
In particular,
V[S(0), 0] F0,PT (V [ S (T ), T ]) .
We are given that V[S(t), t] [ S (t )]a , where ak2. Thus, the equation above is
[ S (0)]a F0,PT ([ S (T )]a )
erT [ S (0)]a exp{[a(r – ) + ½a(a – 1) 2]T}
by (20.30). Hence we have the following quadratic equation for a:
r + a(r – ) + ½a(a – 1)2 0.
whose solutions, with 0, are a 1 and a 2r/ 2.
88
Remarks:
(ii) For those who know martingale theory, the alternative solution above is equivalent
to seeking a such that, under the risk-neutral probability measure, the stochastic
process {ert[S(t)]a; t ≥ 0} is a martingale.
(iii) If the derivative security pays dividends, then its price, V, does not satisfy the
partial differential equation (21.11). If the dividend payment between time t and
time t dt is (t)dt, then the Black-Scholes equation (21.31) on page 691 will need
to be modified as
Et [dV + (t)dt] V × (rdt).
See also Exercise 21.10 on page 700.
89
37. The price of a stock is governed by the stochastic differential equation:
d S (t )
0.03dt 0.2dZ (t ),
S (t )
where {Z(t)} is a standard Brownian motion. Consider the geometric average
(A) 0.03
(B) 0.04
(C) 0.05
(D) 0.06
(E) 0.07
90
Solution to (37) Answer: (D)
Remarks:
(i) Consider the more general geometric average which uses N equally spaced stock
prices from 0 to T, with the first price observation at time T/N,
1/ N
G = j 1 S ( jT / N )
N
.
Then,
1 N 2 N
Var[ln G] = Var ln S ( jT / N ) 2
Var Z ( jT / N ) .
N j 1 N j 1
91
N N
Z ( jT / N ) ( N 1 j ) Z j .
j 1 j 1
2 N
T
N 2 ( N 1 j)
j 1
2
N
2 N ( N 1)(2 N 1) T
N2 6 N
( N 1)(2 N 1) T
2
,
6N 2
which can be checked using formula (14.19) on page 466.
1 N
(ii) Since ln G ln S ( jT / N ) is a normal random variable, the random variable G is
N j 1
a lognormal random variable. The mean of ln G can be similarly derived. In fact,
McDonald (2006, page 466) wrote: “Deriving these results is easier than you might
guess.”
(iv) The determination of the distribution of an arithmetic average (the above is about the
distribution of a geometric average) is a very difficult problem. See footnote 3 on
page 446 of McDonald (2006) and also #56 in this set of sample questions.
92
38. For t T, let P(t, T, r ) be the price at time t of a zero-coupon bond that pays $1 at
time T, if the short-rate at time t is r.
(i) P(t, T, r) A(t, T)×exp[–B(t, T)r] for some functions A(t, T) and B(t, T).
(ii) B(0, 3) 2.
(A) 1.0240
(B) 1.0408
(C) 1.0416
(D) 1.0480
(E) 1.0560
93
Solution to (38) Answer: (B)
The term “delta-gamma approximations for bonds” can be found on page 784 of
McDonald (2006).
By Taylor series,
1 1
P(t, T, r0 + ) P(t, T, r0) + Pr(t, T, r0) + Prr(t, T, r0)2 + … ,
1! 2!
where
Pr(t, T, r) –A(t, T)B(t, T)e–B(t, T)r –B(t, T)P(t, T, r)
and
Prr(t, T, r) –B(t, T)Pr(t, T, r) = [B(t, T)]2P(t, T, r).
Thus,
P (t , T , r0 )
1 – B(t, T) + ½[B(t, T)]2 + …
P (t , T , r0 )
and
PEst (0,3, 0.03)
= 1 – (2 × –0.02) + ½(2 × –0.02)2
P (0,3, 0.05)
= 1.0408
94
39. A discrete-time model is used to model both the price of a nondividend-paying
stock and the short-term (risk-free) interest rate. Each period is one year.
At time 0, the stock price is S0 100 and the effective annual interest rate is
r0 5%.
At time 1, there are only two states of the world, denoted by u and d. The stock
prices are Su 110 and Sd 95. The effective annual interest rates are ru 6% and
rd 4%.
Let C(K) be the price of a 2-year K-strike European call option on the stock.
Let P(K) be the price of a 2-year K-strike European put option on the stock.
(A) 2.85
(B) 2.34
(C) 2.11
(D) 1.95
(E) 1.08
95
Solution to (39) Answer: (B)
We are given that the securities model is a discrete-time model, with each period being
one year. Even though there are only two states of the world at time 1, we cannot assume
that the model is binomial after time 1. However, the difference, P(K) – C(K), suggests
put-call parity.
Thus, the problem is to find P(0, 2), the price of the 2-year zero-coupon bond:
1
P(0, 2) p * P (1, 2, u ) (1 p*) P (1, 2, d )
1 r0
1 p * 1 p *
= .
1 r0 1 ru 1 rd
96
40. The following four charts are profit diagrams for four option strategies: Bull
Spread, Collar, Straddle, and Strangle. Each strategy is constructed with the
purchase or sale of two 1-year European options.
Portfolio I Portfolio II
15 15
One Year
10 Six Months 10
Three Months
Expiration
5 5
P rofit
P rofit
0 0
30 35 40 45 50 55 60 30 35 40 45 50 55 60
-5 -5
One Year
Six Months
-10 -10
Three Months
Expiration
-15 -15
10 10
8
8 One Year
Six Months
6
Three Months
6 Expiration
4
4
2
P rofit
P rofit
0
2
30 35 40 45 50 55 60
-2
0
30 35 40 45 50 55 60
-4
One Year -2
-6
Six Months
Three Months
-8 Expiration -4
97
Solution to (40) Answer: (D)
Profit diagrams are discussed Section 12.4 of McDonald (2006). Definitions of the
option strategies can be found in the Glossary near the end of the textbook. See also
Figure 3.17 on page 87.
98
41. Assume the Black-Scholes framework. Consider a 1-year European contingent
claim on a stock.
payoff
42
S(1)
42
(A) 0.24
(B) 0.29
(C) 0.34
(D) 0.39
(E) 0.44
99
Solution to (41) Answer: (C)
We have d1 0.56 and d2 0.31, giving N(d1) 0.2877 and N(d2) 0.3783.
ln V
Elasticity =
ln S
V S
=
S V
S
= V
V
S
= Put .
V
S (0)
Time-0 elasticity = e T N (d1 )
V (0)
45
= e 0.03 0.2877
36.9099
= 0.34.
100
42. Prices for 6-month 60-strike European up-and-out call options on a stock S are
available. Below is a table of option prices with respect to various H, the level of the
barrier. Here, S(0) 50.
60 0
70 0.1294
80 0.7583
90 1.6616
4.0861
H1 Hit
H1 Not Hit
H2 Not Hit H2 Hit
0 2 max[S(0.5) – 60, 0] max[S(0.5) – 60, 0]
(A) 0.6289
(B) 1.3872
(C) 2.1455
(D) 4.5856
101
Solution to (42) Answer: (D)
Let the price of the ordinary call with strike 60 be p (actually it is 4.0861),
then the price of the UIC (H1 = 70) is p – 0.1294
and the price of the UIC (H1 = 80) is p – 0.7583.
The price of the “knock-in, knock out” call is 2(p – 0.1294) – (p – 0.7583) 4.5856 .
Alternative Solution:
Let M(T) max S (t ) be the running maximum of the stock price up to time T.
0t T
Let I[.] denote the indicator function.
For various H, the first table gives the time-0 price of payoff of the form
I [ H M (½)] [ S (½) 60] .
Thus, the time-0 price of this payoff is 4.0861 2 0.1294 0.7583 4.5856 .
102
43. Let x(t) be the dollar/euro exchange rate at time t. That is, at time t, €1 = $x(t).
Let the constant r be the dollar-denominated continuously compounded risk-free
interest rate. Let the constant r€ be the euro-denominated continuously
compounded risk-free interest rate.
Let y(t) be the euro/dollar exchange rate at time t. Thus, y(t) 1/x(t).
dy (t )
(A) (r€ r)dt dZ(t)
y (t )
dy (t )
(B) (r€ r)dt dZ(t)
y (t )
dy (t )
(C) (r€ r ½2)dt dZ(t)
y (t )
dy (t )
(D) (r€ r ½2)dt dZ(t)
y (t )
dy (t )
(E) (r€ r 2)dt – dZ(t)
y (t )
103
Solution to (43) Answer: (E)
By Itô’s Lemma,
dy(t) df(x(t), t)
ftdt fxdx(t) ½fxx[dx(t)]2
0 [x(t)2]dx(t) ½[2x(t)3][dx(t)]2
x(t)1[dx(t)/x(t)] x(t)1[dx(t)/x(t)]2
y(t)[(r – r€)dt dZ(t)] y(t)[(r – r€)dt + dZ(t)]2
y(t)[(r – r€)dt dZ(t)] y(t)[2dt],
rearrangement of which yields
dy (t )
(r€ r + 2)dt – dZ(t),
y (t )
which is (E).
Remarks:
The equation
dx (t )
(r – r€)dt + dZ(t)
x (t )
can be understood in the following way. Suppose that, at time t, an investor pays $x(t) to
purchase €1. Then, his instantaneous profit is the sum of two quantities:
(1) instantaneous change in the exchange rate, $[x(t+dt) – x(t)], or $ dx(t),
(2) € r€dt, which is the instantaneous interest on €1.
Hence, in US dollars, his instantaneous profit is
dx(t) + r€dt × x(t+dt)
dx(t) + r€dt × [x(t) + dx(t)]
dx(t) + x(t)r€dt, if dt × dx(t) 0.
104
Under the risk-neutral probability measure, the expectation of the instantaneous rate
of return is the risk-free interest rate. Hence,
E[dx(t) x(t)r€dt | x(t)] x(t) × (rdt),
from which we obtain
dx(t )
E x(t ) (r r€)dt.
x(t )
Furthermore, we now see that {Z(t)} is a (standard) Brownian motion under the
dollar-investor’s risk-neutral probability measure.
105
where
(t) exp[)Z(t) – ½()2t] exp[Z(t) – ½2t].
Because
y(t) y(0)exp[(r€ r + ½2)t – Z(t)],
we see that
exp(r€t)y(t)(t) y(0)exp(rt).
Since x(0)y(0) 1, we indeed have the identity
x(0)E€[exp(r€t) y(t)W] E[ert W].
106
For Questions 44 and 45, consider the following three-period binomial tree model for a
stock that pays dividends continuously at a rate proportional to its price. The length of
each period is 1 year, the continuously compounded risk-free interest rate is 10%, and the
continuous dividend yield on the stock is 6.5%.
585.9375
468.75
375 328.125
300 262.5
210 183.75
147
102.9
44. Calculate the price of a 3-year at-the-money American put option on the stock.
(A) 15.86
(B) 27.40
(C) 32.60
(D) 39.73
(E) 57.49
45. Approximate the value of gamma at time 0 for the 3-year at-the-money American
put on the stock using the method in Appendix 13.B of McDonald (2006).
(A) 0.0038
(B) 0.0041
(C) 0.0044
(D) 0.0047
(E) 0.0050
107
Solution to (44) Answer: (D)
108
46. You are to price options on a futures contract. The movements of the futures price
are modeled by a binomial tree. You are given:
Let CI be the price of a 1-year 85-strike European call option on the futures
contract, and CII be the price of an otherwise identical American call option.
(A) 0
(B) 0.022
(C) 0.044
(D) 0.066
(E) 0.088
109
Solution to (46) Answer: (E)
By formula (10.14), the risk-neutral probability of an up move is
1 d 1/ d 1
p* .
u d u / d 1
Substituting p* 1/3 and u/d 4/3, we have
1 1/ d 1
.
3 4 / 3 1
Hence, d 0.9 and u (4 / 3) d 1.2 .
The two-period binomial tree for the futures price and prices of European and American
options at t 0.5 and t 1 is given below. The calculation of the European option prices
at t 0.5 is given by
e 0.050.5 [30.2 p * 1.4(1 p*)] 10.72841
e 0.050.5 [1.4 p * 0 (1 p*)] 0.455145
Remarks:
(i) C I e 0.05 0.5 [10.72841 p * 0.455145(1 p*)] 3.78378.
C II e 0.05 0.5 [11 p * 0.455145(1 p*)] 3.87207.
(ii) A futures price can be treated like a stock with = r. With this observation, we can
obtain (10.14) from (10.5),
e ( r ) h d e ( r r ) h d 1 d
p* .
ud ud ud
Another application is the determination of the price sensitivity of a futures option
with respect to a change in the futures price. We learn from page 317 that the price
sensitivity of a stock option with respect to a change in the stock price is
C Cd C Cd
e h u . Changing to r and S to F yields e rh u , which is the same
S (u d ) F (u d )
as the expression e rh given in footnote 7 on page 333.
110
47. Several months ago, an investor sold 100 units of a one-year European call option
on a nondividend-paying stock. She immediately delta-hedged the commitment
with shares of the stock, but has not ever re-balanced her portfolio. She now
decides to close out all positions.
(ii)
Several months ago Now
The put option in the table above is a European option on the same stock and
with the same strike price and expiration date as the call option.
(A) $11
(B) $24
(C) $126
(D) $217
(E) $240
111
Solution to (47) Answer: (B)
Let the date several months ago be 0. Let the current date be t.
Delta-hedging at time 0 means that the investor’s cash position at time 0 was
100[C(0) C(0)S(0)].
After closing out all positions at time t, her profit is
100{[C(0) C(0)S(0)]ert – [C(t) C(0)S(t)]}.
Alternative Solution: Consider profit as the sum of (i) capital gain and (ii) interest:
(i) capital gain 100{[C(0) C(t)] C(0)[S(0) – S(t)]}
(ii) interest 100[C(0) C(0)S(0)](ert – 1).
Now,
capital gain 100{[C(0) C(t)] C(0)[S(0) – S(t)]}
100{[8.88 14.42] [40 – 50]}
100{5.54 + 7.94} 240.00.
To determine the amount of interest, we first calculate her cash position at time 0:
100[C(0) C(0)S(0)] 100[8.88 400.794]
100[8.88 31.76] = 2288.00.
Hence,
interest = 2288(1.09435 – 1) = 215.87.
Thus, the investor’s profit is 240.00 – 215.87 = 24.13 24.
Third Solution: Use the table format in Section 13.3 of McDonald (2006).
112
Remark: The problem can still be solved if the short-rate is deterministic (but not
t
necessarily constant). Then, the accumulation factor ert is replaced by exp[ r ( s )ds ] ,
0
which can be determined using the put-call parity formulas
T
C(0) – P(0) = S(0) – K exp[ r ( s )ds ] ,
0
T
C(t) – P(t) = S(t) – K exp[ r ( s )ds ] .
t
If interest rates are stochastic, the problem as stated cannot be solved.
113
48. The prices of two nondividend-paying stocks are governed by the following
stochastic differential equations:
dS1 (t )
0.06dt 0.02d Z (t ),
S1 (t )
dS 2 (t )
0.03dt k d Z (t ),
S 2 (t )
The current stock prices are S1(0) 100 and S2 (0) 50.
You now want to construct a zero-investment, risk-free portfolio with the two
stocks and risk-free bonds.
If there is exactly one share of Stock 1 in the portfolio, determine the number of
shares of Stock 2 that you are now to buy. (A negative number means shorting
Stock 2.)
(A) –4
(B) –2
(C) –1
(D) 1
(E) 4
114
Solution to (48) Answer: (E)
The problem is a variation of Exercise 20.12 where one asset is perfectly negatively
correlated with another.
The no-arbitrage argument in Section 20.4 “The Sharpe Ratio” shows that
0.06 0.04 0.03 0.04
=
0.02 k
or k = 0.01, and that the current number of shares of Stock 2 in the hedged portfolio is
S ( 0) 0.02 100
1 1 = = 4,
k S 2 ( 0) (0.01) 50
which means buying four shares of Stock 2.
The portfolio is risk-free means that N(t) is such that (t) = 0. Since I(t) 0, the no-
arbitrage condition and the risk-free condition mean that we must also have (t) 0, or
0.02 S1 (t )
N (t ) .
0.01S 2 (t )
In particular,
0.02 S1 (0) 2
N ( 0) 4.
0.01S 2 (0) 0.5
Remark: Equation (21.20) on page 687 of McDonald (2006) should be the same as
(12.9) on page 393,
option || × .
Thus, (21.21) should be changed to
r option r
sign() × .
option
115
49. You use the usual method in McDonald and the following information to construct
a one-period binomial tree for modeling the price movements of a nondividend-
paying stock. (The tree is sometimes called a forward tree).
At the beginning of the period, an investor owns an American put option on the
stock. The option expires at the end of the period.
Determine the smallest integer-valued strike price for which an investor will
exercise the put option at the beginning of the period.
(A) 114
(B) 115
(C) 116
(D) 117
(E) 118
116
Solution to (49) Answer: (B)
u e( r ) h h
e rh h
e(0.04 / 4) (0.3/ 2) e0.16 1.173511
d e( r ) h h e rh h e(0.04 / 4)(0.3 / 2) e 0.14 0.869358
S initial stock price 100
Because the RHS of (1) is nonnegative (the payoff of an option is nonnegative), we have
the condition
K S 0. (2)
We now investigate whether there is any K, S K Su, such that inequality (3) holds. If
Su K, then Max(K Su, 0) 0 and inequality (3) simplifies as
K S erh × (1 p*) (K Sd),
or
1 e rh (1 p * )d
K S. (4)
1 e rh (1 p * )
1 e rh (1 p * )d
The fraction can be simplified as follows, but this step is not
1 e rh (1 p * )
necessary. In McDonald’s forward-tree model,
1 p* p*× e h
,
from which we obtain
1
1 p* .
h
1 e
117
1 e rh (1 p * )d 1 e h e rh d
Hence,
1 e rh (1 p * ) 1 e h e rh
1 e h e h
because 0
h rh
1 e e
1
.
h rh
1 e e
Therefore, inequality (4) becomes
1
K S
1 e h e rh
1
S 1.148556×100 114.8556.
0.15
1 e e 0.01
Thus, the answer to the problem is 114.8556 115, which is (B).
Alternative Solution:
u e( r ) h h
e rh h
e(0.04 / 4) (0.3 / 2) e0.16 1.173511
d e( r ) h h e rh h e(0.04 / 4)(0.3 / 2) e 0.14 0.869358
S initial stock price = 100
1 1 1 1
p* = 0.3/ 2
0.15
= 0.46257.
1 e h 1 e 1 e 1+1.1618
Then, inequality (1) is
K 100 e0.01[0.4626 × (K 117.35)+ 0.5374 × (K 86.94)+], (5)
and we check three cases: K ≤ 86.94, K ≥ 117.35, and 86.94 K 117.35.
For K ≤ 86.94, inequality (5) cannot hold, because its LHS 0 and its RHS 0.
For K ≥ 117.35, (5) always holds, because its LHS K 100 while
its RHS e0.01K 100.
For 86.94 K 117.35, inequality (5) becomes
K 100 e0.01 × 0.5374 × (K 86.94),
or
100 e 0.01 0.5374 86.94
K 114.85.
1 e 0.01 0.5374
Third Solution: Use the method of trial and error. For K 114, 115, … , check whether
inequality (5) holds.
118
50. Assume the Black-Scholes framework.
You are given the following information for a stock that pays dividends
continuously at a rate proportional to its price.
Calculate the upper limit of the 90% lognormal confidence interval for the price of
the stock in 6 months.
(A) 0.393
(B) 0.425
(C) 0.451
(D) 0.486
(E) 0.529
119
Solution to (50) Answer: (A)
U
We are to seek the number S0.5 such that Pr( S0.5 S0.5
U
) = 0.95.
Remark The term “confidence interval” as used in Section 18.4 seems incorrect, because
St is a random variable, not an unknown, but constant, parameter. The expression
Pr( StL St StU ) 1 p
gives the probability that the random variable St is between S tL and StU , not the
“confidence” for St to be between S tL and StU .
120
51. Assume the Black-Scholes framework.
Month Price
1 54
2 56
3 48
4 55
5 60
6 58
7 62
121
Solution to (51) Answer: (E)
This problem is a modification of #34 in the May 2007 Exam C. Note that you are given
monthly prices, but you are asked to find an annual rate.
1 n 1 S (tnh ) 1 62
r =
n j 1
r j = ln
n S (t0 )
= ln
6 54
= 0.023025.
1 n 1 n 1 6
n 1 j 1
( r j r ) 2
= ( r j ) nr
n 1 j 1
2 2
= ( r j ) 2 6r 2 = 0.01071.
5 j 1
122
Remarks:
(i) Let T = nh. Then the estimator of ½ is
r 1 S (T ) ln[ S (T )] ln[ S (0)]
= ln = .
h nh S (0) T 0
This is a special case of the result that the drift of an arithmetic Brownian motion is
estimated by the slope of the straight line joining its first and last observed values.
Observed values of the arithmetic Brownian motion in between are not used.
(iii) An important result (McDonald 2006, p. 653, p. 755) is: With probability 1,
n
lim
n
{ln[ S ( jT / n) / S (( j 1)T / n)]}2 = 2T,
j 1
showing that the exact value of can be obtained by means of a single sample path
of the stock price. Here is an implication of this result. Suppose that an actuary
uses a so-called regime-switching model to model the price of a stock (or stock
index), with each regime being characterized by a different . In such a model, the
current regime can be determined by this formula. If the price of the stock can be
observed over a time interval, no matter how short the time interval is, then is
revealed immediately by determining the quadratic variation of the logarithm of the
stock price.
123
52. The price of a stock is to be estimated using simulation. It is known that:
(i) The time-t stock price, St, follows the lognormal distribution:
S
ln t N (( ½ 2 )t , 2t )
S0
124
Solution to (52) Answer: (C)
U Uniform (0, 1)
N1(U) N(0, 1)
a + bN1(U) N(a, b2)
The random variable ln(S2 / 50) has a normal distribution with mean
(0.15 ½ 0.32 ) 2 0.21 and variance 0.32 × 2 = 0.18, and thus a standard deviation of
0.4243.
The three uniform random numbers become the following three values from the standard
normal: 2.12, 1.77, 0.77. Upon multiplying each by the standard deviation of 0.4243
and adding the mean of 0.21, the resulting normal values are 1.109, 0.541, and 0.537.
The simulated stock prices are obtained by exponentiating these numbers and multiplying
by 50. This yields 151.57, 29.11, and 85.54. The average of these three numbers is
88.74.
125
53. Assume the Black-Scholes framework. For a European put option and a European
gap call option on a stock, you are given:
(iii) The gap call option has strike price 45 and payment trigger 40.
Consider a European cash-or-nothing call option that pays 1000 at time T if the
stock price at that time is higher than 40.
(A) 5
(B) 2
(C) 2
(D) 5
(E) 8
126
Solution to (53) Answer: (B)
Let I[.] be the indicator function, i.e., I[A] = 1 if the event A is true, and I[A] = 0 if the
event A is false. Let K1 be the strike price and K2 be the payment trigger of the gap call
option. The payoff of the gap call option is
[S(T) – K1] × I[S(T) K2] [S(T) – K2] × I[S(T) K2] (K2 – K1) × I[S(T) K2].
Because differentiation is a linear operation, each Greek (except for omega or elasticity)
of a portfolio is the sum of the corresponding Greeks for the components of the portfolio
(McDonald 2006, page 395). Thus,
Gap call gamma Call gamma (K2 – K1) Cash-or-nothing call gamma
As pointed out on line 12 of page 384 of McDonald (2006), call gamma equals put
gamma. (To see this, differentiate the put-call parity formula twice with respect to S.)
Remark: Another decomposition of the payoff of the gap call option is the following:
See page 707 of McDonald (2006). Such a decomposition, however, is not useful here.
127
54. Assume the Black-Scholes framework. Consider two nondividend-paying stocks
whose time-t prices are denoted by S1(t) and S2(t), respectively.
(iv) The correlation between the continuously compounded returns of the two
stocks is –0.40.
(vi) A one-year European option with payoff max{min[2S1(1), S2(1)] 17, 0} has
a current (time-0) price of 1.632.
Consider a European option that gives its holder the right to sell either two shares of
Stock 1 or one share of Stock 2 at a price of 17 one year from now.
(A) 0.66
(B) 1.12
(C) 1.49
(D) 5.18
(E) 7.86
128
Solution to (54) Answer: (A)
At the option-exercise date, the option holder will sell two shares of Stock 1 or one share
of Stock 2, depending on which trade is of lower cost. Thus, the time-1 payoff of the
option is
max{17 min[2S1(1), S2(1)], 0},
which is the payoff of a 17-strike put on min[2S1(1), S2(1)]. Define
M(T) min[2S1(T), S2(T)].
Here, K = 17 and T = 1. It is given in (vi) that c(17, 1) 1.632. F0P,1 ( M ) is the time-0
price of the security with time-1 payoff
Since max[2S1(1) S2(1), 0] is the payoff of an exchange option, its price can be obtained
using (14.16) and (14.17):
Thus,
P P
F0,1 ( M ) 2 F0,1 ( S1 ) 2.856 2 10 2.856 17.144
and
p(17, 1) 1.632 17.144 17e0.05 0.6589.
Remarks: (i) The exchange option above is an “at-the-money” exchange option because
2S1(0) = S2(0). See also Example 14.3 of McDonald (2006).
(ii) Further discussion on exchange options can be found in Section 22.6, which is not
part of the MFE/3F syllabus. Q and S in Section 22.6 correspond to 2S1 and S2 in this
problem.
129
55. Assume the Black-Scholes framework. Consider a 9-month at-the-money European
put option on a futures contract. You are given:
If three months later the futures price is 17.7, what is the price of the put option at
that time?
(A) 2.09
(B) 2.25
(C) 2.45
(D) 2.66
(E) 2.83
130
Solution to (55) Answer: (D)
ln( F / K ) ½ 2T
where d1 , and d 2 d 1 T .
T
½2T
With F K, we have ln(F / K) 0, d1 ½ T , d 2 ½ T , and
T
P Fe rT [ N (½ T ) N ( ½ T )] Fe rT [2 N (½ T ) 1] .
N(d1) 0.7224
d 2 d 1 T 0.5904 0.254 0.5 0.7700
N(d2) 0.7794
131
Remarks:
(i) A somewhat related problem is #8 in the May 2007 MFE exam. Also see the box
on page 299 and the one on page 603 of McDonald (2006).
(ii) For European call and put options on a futures contract with the same exercise date,
the call price and put price are the same if and only if both are at-the-money
options. The result follows from put-call parity. See the first equation in Table 9.9
on page 305 of McDonald (2006).
(iii) The point above can be generalized. It follows from the identity
[S1(T) S2(T)]+ + S2(T) = [S2(T) S1(T)]+ + S1(T)
that
(See also formula 9.6 on page 287.) Note that F0,PT (( S1 S2 ) ) and
F0,PT (( S2 S1) ) are time-0 prices of exchange options. The two exchange options
have the same price if and only if the two prepaid forward prices, F0,PT ( S1 ) and
132
56. Assume the Black-Scholes framework. For a stock that pays dividends
continuously at a rate proportional to its price, you are given:
Calculate Var[A(2)].
(A) 1.51
(B) 5.57
(C) 10.29
(D) 22.29
(E) 30.57
133
Solution to (56) Answer: (A)
2
1
Var[A(2)] = {E[(S(1) + S(2))2] (E[S(1) + S(2)])2}.
2
S (1)
2
S (1) S (1) 2
0.05
E 1 1 2E E S (0) 1 2e e0.14 .
S (0) S (0)
Hence,
E[(S(1) + S(2))2] 52 × e0.14 × (1 2e0.05 e0.14) 122.29757.
Finally,
Var[A(2)] ¼×{122.29757 [5(e0.05 e0.1)]2} 1.51038.
Alternative Solution:
Because S(t) is a lognormal random variable, the two variances can be evaluated using
the following formula, which is a consequence of (18.14) on page 595.
Var[S(t)] = Var[S(0)exp[( ½2)t Z(t)]
= S2(0)exp[2( ½2)t]Var[eZ(t)]
= S2(0)exp[2( ½2)t]exp(2t)[exp(2t) 1]
= S2(0) e2( )t [exp(2t) 1].
(As a check, we can use the well-known formula for the square of the coefficient of
variation of a lognormal random variable. In this case, it takes the form
Var[S (t )] 2
= e t 1.
{E[S (t )]}2
This matches with the results above. The coefficient of variation is in the syllabus of
Exam C/4.)
135
To evaluate the covariance, we can use the formula
Cov(X, Y) = E[XY] E[X]E[Y].
In this case, however, there is a better covariance formula:
Cov(X, Y) = Cov[X, E(Y | X)].
Thus,
Cov[S(1), S(2)] = Cov[S(1), E[S(2)|S(1)]]
= Cov[S(1), S(1)E[S(2)/S(1)|S(1)]]
= Cov[S(1), S(1)E[S(1)/S(0)]]
= E[S(1)/S(0)]Cov[S(1), S(1)]
= e Var[S(1)].
Hence,
Var[S(1) S(2)] = (1 + 2e )Var[S(1)] + Var[S(2)]
2 2
= [S(0)]2[(1 + 2e )e2( )( e 1) + e4( )( e 2 1)]
= 25[(1 + 2e0.05)e0.1(e0.04 1) + e0.2(e0.08 1)]
= 6.041516,
and
Var[A(2)] = Var[S(1) S(2)]/4
= 6.041516 / 4
= 1.510379.
136
57. Michael uses the following method to simulate 8 standard normal random variates:
Step 1: Simulate 8 uniform (0, 1) random numbers U1, U2, ... , U8.
Step 2: Apply the stratified sampling method to the random numbers so that Ui
and Ui+4 are transformed to random numbers Vi and Vi+4 that are uniformly
distributed over the interval ((i1)/4, i/4), i 1, 2, 3, 4. In each of the four
quartiles, a smaller value of U results in a smaller value of V.
i 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8
Ui 0.4880 0.7894 0.8628 0.4482 0.3172 0.8944 0.5013 0.3015
Find the difference between the largest and the smallest simulated normal random
variates.
(A) 0.35
(B) 0.78
(C) 1.30
(D) 1.77
(E) 2.50
137
Solution to (57) Answer: (E)
Since the smallest Z comes from the first quartile, it must come from U1 or U5.
Since U5 U1, we use U5 to compute the smallest Z:
1 1 0.3172
V5 0.0793,
4
Z5 N1(0.0793) N1(0.9207) = 1.41.
Since the largest Z comes from the fourth quartile, it must come from U4 and U8.
Since U4 U8, we use U4 to compute the largest Z:
4 1 0.4482
V4 0.86205 0.8621,
4
Z4 N1(0.8621) = 1.09.
The difference between the largest and the smallest normal random variates is
Z4 Z5 1.09 (1.41) 2.50.
Remark:
The simulated standard normal random variates are as follows:
i 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8
Ui 0.4880 0.7894 0.8628 0.4482 0.3172 0.8944 0.5013 0.3015
no stratified
–0.030 0.804 1.093 –0.130 –0.476 1.250 0.003 –0.520
sampling
Vi 0.1220 0.4474 0.7157 0.8621 0.0793 0.4736 0.6253 0.8254
Zi –1.165 –0.132 0.570 1.090 –1.410 –0.066 0.319 0.936
Observe that there is no U in the first quartile, 4 U’s in the second quartile, 1 U in the
third quartile, and 3 U’s in the fourth quartile. Hence, the V’s seem to be more uniform.
138
For Questions 58 and 59, you are to assume the Black-Scholes framework.
Let C ( K ) denote the Black-Scholes price for a 3-month K-strike European call option on
a nondividend-paying stock.
Let Cˆ ( K ) denote the Monte Carlo price for a 3-month K-strike European call option on
the stock, calculated by using 5 random 3-month stock prices simulated under the risk-
neutral probability measure.
You are to estimate the price of a 3-month 42-strike European call option on the stock
using the formula
C*(42) Cˆ (42) + [C(40) Cˆ (40) ],
where the coefficient is such that the variance of C*(42) is minimized.
139
Solution to (58) Answer: (B)
For a pair of random variables X and Y, we estimate the ratio, Cov[X, Y]/Var[X], using the
formula
n n
( X i X )(Yi Y ) X iYi nXY
i 1 i 1 .
n n
( X i X )2 X i2 nX 2
i 1 i 1
We now treat the payoff of the 40-strike option (whose correct price, C(40), is known) as
X, and the payoff of the 42-strike option as Y. We do not need to discount the payoffs
because the effect of discounting is canceled in the formula above.
Remark: The estimate for the minimum-variance coefficient can be obtained by using
the statistics mode of a scientific calculator very easily. In the following we use TI–30X
IIB as an illustration.
140
[ENTER][DATA] 0 0 0 0 0.35 0 3.65 1.65 8.9 6.9 [Enter]
Step 4: Press [2nd][STATVAR] and select “Y” to exit the statistics mode.
n n
You can also find X , Y , X Y , X
i 1
i i
i 1
i
2
etc in [STATVAR] too.
Step 3: Select L1 and L2 for x and y data. Then select Calc and [ENTER]
The plain-vanilla Monte Carlo estimates of the two call option prices are:
141
60. The short-rate process {r(t)} in a Cox-Ingersoll-Ross model follows
where {Z(t)} is a standard Brownian motion under the true probability measure.
For t T , let P(r , t , T ) denote the price at time t of a zero-coupon bond that pays 1
at time T, if the short-rate at time t is r.
1
(ii) lim ln[ P ( r , 0, T )] 0.1 for each r 0.
T T
(A) 0.02
(B) 0.07
(C) 0.12
(D) 0.18
(E) 0.24
142
Solution to (60) Answer: (E)
Let y(r, 0, T) be the continuously compounded yield rate of P(r, 0, T), i.e.,
ey(r, 0, T)T = P(r, 0, T).
Then condition (ii) is
ln P ( r , 0, T )
lim y ( r , 0, T ) lim 0.1.
T T T
Hence,
2(0.1)(0.11)
0 .1 .
0.1 (0.1 ) 2 2(0.08) 2
We now solve for :
(0.1 ) (0.1 ) 2 2(0.08) 2 0.22
(0.1 ) 2 0.44(0.1 ) 0.0484 (0.1 ) 2 0.0128
0.44(0.1 ) 0.0356
0.01909
Condition (i) is
(r , t ) c r .
Thus,
c /
0.01909 / 0.08
0.2386.
143
Remarks: (i) The answer can be obtained by trial-and-error. There is no need to solve
the quadratic equation.
(ii) If your textbook is an earlier printing of the second edition, you will find the
corrected formulas in
http://www.kellogg.northwestern.edu/faculty/mcdonald/htm/p780-88.pdf
(iii) Let
1
y (r , t , T ) ln P (r , t , T ) .
T t
We shall show that
2ab
lim y (r , t , T ) .
T a (a ) 22 2
Under the CIR model, the zero-coupon bond price is of the “affine” form
P(r, t, T) A(t, T)e–B(t, T)r.
Hence,
1 r
y(r , t , T ) ln A(t , T ) B (t , T ) . (1)
T t T t
Observe that
1 2ab 2 γe ( a γ )(T t ) / 2
ln A(t , T ) 2 ln
T t (T t ) (a γ)(e γ (T t ) 1) 2 γ
2ab ln 2γ a γ ln[(a γ)(e γ (T t ) 1) 2γ]
2
T t 2 T t
where 0. By applying l’Hôpital’s rule to the last term above, we get
γ(a γ)
lim
T ( a γ)(1 e γ(T t ) ) 2γe γ(T t )
γ(a γ)
(a γ)(1 0) 2γ 0
γ.
So,
1 2ab a γ ab(a γ)
lim ln A(t , T ) 2 0 γ .
T T t 2 2
145
61. Assume the Black-Scholes framework.
(A) 0.030
(B) 0.035
(C) 0.040
(D) 0.045
(E) 0.050
146
Solution to (61) Answer: (D)
Let , , and be the stock’s expected rate of (total) return, dividend yield, and
volatility, respectively.
From (ii), 0.01.
From (iii), 0.05; hence, 0.06.
Also from (iii), 0.25.
According to Section 20.5 in McDonald (2006), the stochastic process {Z (t )} defined by
Z (t ) Z (t ) t (2)
is a standard Brownian motion under the risk-neutral probability measure; see, in
particular, the third paragraph on page 662. Thus,
~
E* [ Z (t )] 0 , (3)
where the asterisk signifies that the expectation is taken with respect to the risk-neutral
probability measure.
Remark In Section 24.1 of McDonald (2006), the Sharpe ratio is not a constant but
depends on time t and the short-rate. Equation (2) becomes
~ t
Z (t ) = Z(t) 0 [r(s), s]ds. (5)
{Z(t)} is a standard Brownian motion under the true probability measure, and {Z (t )} is a
standard Brownian motion under the risk-neutral probability measure. Note that in (5)
there is a minus sign, instead of a plus sign as in (2); this is due to the minus sign in
(24.1).
147
62. Assume the Black-Scholes framework.
Let S(t) be the time-t price of a stock that pays dividends continuously at a rate
proportional to its price.
(ii) for 0 t T, the time-t forward price for a forward contract that delivers the
square of the stock price at time T is
Calculate .
(A) 0.01
(B) 0.04
(C) 0.07
(D) 0.10
(E) 0.40
148
Solution to (62) Answer: (A)
The time-t prepaid forward price for the forward contract that delivers S2 at time T is
Ft ,PT ( S 2 ) er(T t)Ft,T(S 2) S 2(t)exp[(0.18 r)(T – t)].
The prepaid forward price is the price of a derivative security which does not pay
dividends. Thus, it satisfies the Black-Scholes partial differential equation (21.11),
V V 1 2 2 2V
( r δ) s s rV .
t s 2 s 2
The partial derivatives of V(s, t) = s2exp[(0.18 r)(T – t)], t ≤ T, for the partial
differential equation are:
Vt (r 0.18)V(s, t),
2V ( s, t )
Vs 2s×exp[(0.18 r)(T – t)] ,
s
2V ( s, t )
Vss 2exp[(0.18 r)(T – t)] .
s2
Substituting these derivatives into the partial differential equation yields
2V ( s, t ) 1 2 2 2V ( s, t )
(r 0.18)V ( s, t ) ( r δ) s s rV ( s, t )
s 2 s2
(r 0.18) 2(r δ) 2 r
0.18 2
r = = 0.01.
2
149
Remarks:
(i) An easy way to obtain (20.31) is to use the fact
F0,T(Sa) = E *[[ S (T )]a ] ,
where the asterisk signifies that the expectation is taken with respect to the risk-neutral
probability measure. Under the risk-neutral probability measure, ln[S(T)/S(0)] is a
normal random variable with mean (r – – ½2)T and variance 2T. Thus, by (18.13)
or by the moment-generating function formula for a normal random variable, we have
F0,T(Sa) = E *[[ S (T )]a ]
[ S (0)]2 exp[a(r – – ½2)T + ½×a22T],
which is (20.31).
(ii) While the prepaid forward price satisfies the partial differential equation (21.11), the
forward price satisfies the partial differential equation (21.34). In other words,
substituting V(t, s) = s2exp[0.18(T – t)] and its partial derivatives into (21.34) is a way to
obtain r − . Equation (21.34) is not in the current syllabus of Exam MFE/3F.
(iii) Another way to determine r − is to use the fact that, for a security that does not pay
dividends, its discounted price is a martingale. Thus, the stochastic process
{e rt Ft P,T ( S 2 );0 t T } is a martingale. Because
e rt Ft P,T ( S 2 ) [ S (t )]2 e 0.18t e rT ,
the martingale condition is that
[ S (0)]2 e0 = E *[[ S (t )]2 e0.18t ]
= e0.18t E *[[ S (t )]2 ] ,
e0.18t [ S (0)]2 exp[2(r – – ½2)t + ½×222t].
Thus, the martingale condition becomes
0 = −0.18t + 2(r – – ½2)t + ½×222t,
which again leads to
0.18 2
r = .
2
This method is beyond the current syllabus of Exam MFE/3F.
150
63. Define
(i) W(t) t 2.
(ii) X(t) [t], where [t] is the greatest integer part of t; for example, [3.14] 3,
[9.99] 9, and [4] 4.
(iii) Y(t) 2t 0.9Z(t), where {Z(t): t 0} is a standard Brownian motion.
Let VT2 (U ) denote the quadratic variation of a process U over the time interval
[0, T].
Rank the quadratic variations of W, X and Y over the time interval [0, 2.4].
151
Solution to (63) Answer: (A)
For a process {U(t)}, the quadratic variation over [0, T], T 0, can be calculated as
T
0
[dU (t )]2 .
(i) Since
dW(t) 2tdt,
we have
[dW(t)]2 4t2(dt)2
which is zero, because dt dt 0 by (20.17b) on page 658 of McDonald (2006).
2.4
This means V22.4 (W ) = 0
[dW (t )]2 0 .
(ii) X(t) 0 for 0 t < 1, X(t) 1 for 1 t < 2, X(t) 2 for 2 t < 3, etc.
For t ≥ 0, dX(t) = 0 except for the points 1, 2, 3, … . At the points 1, 2, 3, … , the
square of the increment is 12 1. Thus,
2
V2.4 ( X ) = 1 + 1 = 2.
152
64. Let S(t) denote the time-t price of a stock. Let Y(t) [S (t)]2. You are given
dY (t )
1.2dt − 0.5dZ(t), Y(0) 64,
Y (t )
where {Z(t): t 0} is a standard Brownian motion.
Find U.
(A) 27.97
(B) 33.38
(C) 41.93
(D) 46.87
(E) 53.35
153
Solution to (64) Answer: (C)
For a given value of V(0), the solution to the stochastic differential equation
dV (t )
dt + dZ(t), t ≥ 0, (1)
V (t )
is
V(t) V(0) exp[( – ½2)t + Z(t)], t ≥ 0. (2)
That formula (2) satisfies equation (1) is a consequence of Itô’s Lemma. See also
Example 20.1 on p. 665 in McDonald (2006)
154