Ch06 Nondemocratic Regimes
Ch06 Nondemocratic Regimes
Ch06 Nondemocratic Regimes
KEY CONCEPTS
! Nondemocratic regimes are often divided between authoritarianism and total-
itarianism.
! As with democracy, there are various and competing theories for the emer-
gence and perseverance of nondemocratic regimes.
! The general trend worldwide has been away from nondemocratic regimes,
though illiberal regimes seem to be growing in importance.
In the modern world, only communist North Korea can still properly be
described as totalitarian, dominated by an elaborate ideology that covers all
aspects of life and is backed by violence, widespread fear, and the absence of
even small personal freedoms. By way of comparison, a country such as Iraq
under Saddam Hussein, although highly oppressive, could not be described
as totalitarian because it lacked a strong ideology and in many ways was less
centralized than outsiders imagined. Saddam Hussein’s primary goal as Iraq’s
leader was to maintain and expand his own political power as an end in itself.
In spite of this, critics often described Iraq as a totalitarian society. Similarly,
Iran is frequently described as a totalitarian system, but though one might
describe the current regime as embodying a “totalist” ideology, large swaths of
the state, society, and economy function with varying degrees of independence.
To sum up, nondemocratic rule is a political regime in which power is
exercised by a few, unbound by public or constitutional control. The public
lacks not only the right to choose its own leaders but also other personal lib-
erties that those in power may see as a threat, such as freedom of speech or
assembly. Totalitarianism, as a particular form of nondemocratic rule, is dis-
tinguished from other forms of nondemocratic rule by its totalist ideology that
seeks the fundamental transformation of most domestic institutions and the
potential use of violence toward that end.
Recall that one of the central assertions of the behavioral revolution was that
with modernization, societies would become more urban, educated, and polit-
ically sophisticated, creating the basic conditions that would catalyze democ-
racy. And indeed, there is a strong correlation between societies that lack
modern institutions and nondemocratic rule. Societies that are poor and
poorly developed are less likely to have democracy for a number of reasons,
which we noted in Chapter 5. First, such societies are more likely to be highly
146 CH. 6 NONDEMOCRATIC REGIMES
chapter, however, we noted that modernization theory has found new life in
the idea that democratization may be more likely under conditions where
there is not simply economic development but also a relatively equitable dis-
tribution of those resources. Elites may be more willing to share power when
they have fewer fears of losing economic opportunities in the process. Accord-
ingly, highly unequal societies will reinforce nondemocratic rule, and in fact,
the longevity of nondemocracy may be precisely due to the fact that rivals for
power seek control specifically so that they can enrich themselves. The state
under these conditions becomes a tool to siphon off resources and maintain
control. Given these higher levels of inequality, those in power may be par-
ticularly loath to surrender power, not only because they may be forced to
give up their assets but because they may lose their lives as well. The threat
of revolution may make these systems particularly unlikely to provide much
in the way of participation, competition, or liberty.
One particular variant of this argument that has gained currency of late is
what is referred to as the “resource trap” theory of development. The resource
being referred to here is natural resources, such as oil, gas, or minerals. While
these might be a source of great wealth, the puzzle is why so many resource
rich countries are development or democracy poor. According to this theory,
the existence of natural resources acts as a barrier to modernization and democ-
racy, for several related reasons. First, resources in the ground give leaders the
wealth necessary to run the state without taxation. This means those in power
need not bother themselves with the taxation and representation trade-off; since
they do not need to tax the people, they can also effectively ignore their polit-
ical demands. Even worse, natural resources tend to stunt the development of
a modern economy and middle class, since neither is of concern to those in
power (and in fact may represent a threat). The result is that wealth is highly
concentrated in the hands of those in power. Under these conditions, nonde-
mocratic rule can effectively subsidize itself, so long as the resources last and
have a market. Oil is clearly the most obvious example of a resource trap, but
diamonds, gold, or timber could also serve this function.
This discussion returns us to the idea of civil society. Recall that we defined
civil society as a fabric of organizations created by people to help define their
own interests. These are not necessarily political, and in fact, the vast major-
ity of them have no specific political content. Sports groups, collectors and
enthusiasts, religious and other organizations all form civil society. It is com-
monly argued that civil society is crucial to democratic life because it allows
individuals to organize, articulate their preferences, and form networks that
cross normal economic, social, or political divides. Civil society is thus com-
148 CH. 6 NONDEMOCRATIC REGIMES
monly viewed as a crucible for democratic action, laying the groundwork for
democratic institutions.
Conversely, many authoritarian systems are characterized by the absence
of civil society. This can be the specific result of those in power, who have
taken steps to harass, absorb, monitor, or destroy any form of independent
action outside of the state and those in power. Civil society may also have lit-
tle precedent in society or be hindered by significant ethnic or other societal
divisions that dissuade people from forming organizations across these insti-
tutional barriers. The result can be a society that is more familiar with view-
ing the state as a primary arena for social organization, or that thinks
of association more in terms of mass movements and protest. Sometimes
both of these go hand in hand in what is known as populism. Populism is
not a specific ideology and in fact draws much of its power from an anti-
institutional approach. But generally, populism carries within it the view that
elites and established institutions do not fully represent the will of the peo-
ple and that a new movement, free from ideology and often led by a charis-
matic leader, can usher in a new order. Where civil society is weak, populism
may find more fertile ground.
Finally, it is also possible that civil society may emerge alongside a non-
democratic regime but may itself take on nondemocratic tendencies, espe-
cially where more democratic forms have been repressed by the state. Across
parts of the Middle East there are strong civil society movements rooted in
Islamic fundamentalism, but these organizations, while opposed to current
nondemocratic regimes, wish to take their place, not democratize them.
Cold War, both the Soviet Union and the United States backed authoritarian
rulers against democratic forces in order to maintain or expand their influ-
ence. The United States played a significant role in overthrowing the demo-
cratically elected government in Iran in 1953, fearing that the prime minister
was tilting toward the Soviet Union. The Soviet Union crushed revolts in Hun-
gary in 1956 and Czechoslovakia in 1968. With the rise of China and the move
away from democracy in Russia, these two countries have become important
supporters of nondemocratic regimes in Africa and the Middle East through
investment and diplomatic support in the international community. Iran and
Venezuela, too, have sought to use their oil wealth to support like-minded
regimes.
Let us return to the idea of political culture, which argues that there are dif-
ferences in societal institutions—norms and values—that shape the landscape
of political activity. In the previous chapter we discussed the controversial
idea that there may be a culture of democracy or liberty that must be a pre-
condition for institutionalized democracy, and that certain cultures may, for
whatever reason, hold these values while others do not. By way of extension,
it could be argued that there are nondemocratic political values as well. If we
return to our map of political culture in Chapter 3, we can see an array of
countries whose cultural values tend more toward authority over individual
freedom. This may be a function of modernization or something more fixed
in the cultural landscape of these societies, raising the controversial question
of modernization versus Westernization. In contrast to modernization theory,
which essentially views “Western” and “modern” concepts as the same, cul-
ture is much more fixed, according to some scholars; they believe that mod-
ernization will not necessarily lead to Westernization, meaning the adoption
of such values as secularism, individualism, and liberal democracy. Nonde-
mocratic rule in this view is not the absence of democracy—it is its own set
of values.
Let’s look at some specific examples. A common argument is that democ-
racy is a unique product of interconnected historical experiences in Europe,
such as Christianity (particularly Protestantism), the emphasis on individual-
ism and secularism, the development of the nation-state, ideology, early indus-
trialization, and the development of capitalism, among others. These factors,
the argument goes, allowed for the creation of democracy as a regime built
on liberal values that emphasize freedom—what we typically call “Western”
societies. In contrast, some have asserted that under Islam, political power
and religious power are one and the same: laws are seen not as societal insti-
tutions to protect or advance individual rights, but as codes handed down by
150 CH. 6 NONDEMOCRATIC REGIMES
100
80
Percentage of countries
60
40
20
0
Sub- Middle Asia Americas Europe World
Saharan East & Pacific
Africa North
Africa
Allah that are to be observed and defended, and democracy is essentially anath-
ema to the will of God. Cultural arguments can also be found in what has
been called the “Asian values” debate. Proponents of the idea of Asian values
argue that Asia’s cultural and religious traditions stress conformity, hierar-
chy, and obedience, which are more conducive to a political regime that lim-
its freedom in order to defend social harmony and consensus. The philosophy
of Confucianism is frequently cited in this regard, with its emphasis on obe-
dience to hierarchy and its notion of a ruler’s “mandate from heaven.” The
ruling elite stands as a parental figure over the people, acting in the public’s
best interest but not under its control. As the former Malaysian prime min-
ister Mahathir Mohamad, one of the major proponents of “Asian values,” has
put it, “When citizens understand that their right to choose also involves lim-
its and responsibilities, democracy doesn’t deteriorate into an excess of free-
dom. . . . These are the dangers of democracy gone wrong, and in our view
it is precisely the sad direction in which the West is heading.”5
As you might imagine, there are many both inside and outside societies
with Islamic or Confucian traditions who reject the idea that these or any
other cultures create a culture of nondemocratic rule. These countries and
Nondemocratic Regimes and Political Control 151
the peoples within them are far too diverse to speak of one set of values.
Differences in history, religion, social structure, and other institutions have
led to an array of different and overlapping ideas that are in a continuous
process of interaction and reinterpretation. Confucian thought, just like the
Bible in the West or the Koran in Islamic countries, can be interpreted in
very different ways. Recall that in the previous chapter we noted that not
long ago, it was asserted that certain forms of Christianity created cultures
more amenable to authoritarian rule. Roman Catholicism emphasized hier-
archy and the power of organized religion over the state, while Orthodox
Christianity in Eastern and Southern Europe fused religious and political
authority in a single head. Yet nondemocratic rule in societies with these reli-
gious traditions has also given way since the 1970s. Cultural arguments may
inform the content of nondemocratic or democratic institutions, but we should
be wary of making sweeping arguments about culture and regime type.
Let’s sum up. There are numerous explanations for nondemocratic rule,
and these arguments are contingent on time and space—what might be the
explanation for one country at one point in time may be irrelevant in another.
The lack of modernization or its disruptive nature may reinforce nondemo-
cratic rule. Elite strategies and the fear of sharing power can also help sup-
port nondemocratic rule, especially when natural resources are in play. A weak
civil society at home and support abroad can also play an important role.
Finally, culture can be a factor in shaping the contours of nondemocratic insti-
tutions, but whether this can explain authoritarianism itself is much more
questionable and contentious. The intersection of these forces can explain how
and why nondemocratic rule comes to power.
One feature that we initially, and perhaps primarily, associate with nonde-
mocratic regimes and especially with totalitarianism is the use of coercion.
Coercion can be defined as compelling individuals by threatening harm to
their lives or livelihoods. Compliance and obedience with regime goals are
often enforced through the threat or use of force against the population, send-
ing a clear signal that those who oppose the regime or government will be
dealt with harshly: loss of job or access to certain resources, arrest, detention
without trial, torture, death. In an extreme example, in the 1970s several non-
democratic regimes in Latin America used “death squads” made up of police
or military troops to target individuals suspected of harboring political views
opposed to the regime. These individuals were abducted by the death squads
and murdered, frequently after torture. In some cases, their bodies were
dumped in the open as a warning to others who dared to question the regime;
in other cases, the victims simply joined the thousands of the “disappeared,”
individuals abducted and never seen again.
In other regimes, violence has been used even more indiscriminately. When
Stalin consolidated his totalitarian rule in the Soviet Union in the 1930s he car-
ried out what are known as “purges,” widespread arrests that decimated the
ranks of the Communist Party and the state bureaucracy. Former leaders of the
1917 revolution, city mayors and local party bosses, high-ranking officers in the
army and navy, university professors, scientists, diplomats, and many others were
detained, tortured, coerced into confessing during “show trials,” forced to impli-
cate others in their supposed crimes, and either sent to forced labor camps or
executed. The targets of the purges were not limited to the party or the state;
writers, artists, students, farmers, and workers were also among those accused
of political sabotage and anti-Soviet views. It is not known how many died in
these purges; estimates range from 5
million to 20 million. Undoubtedly, in
IN FOCUS the vast majority of these cases, the
Nondemocratic Means of Control
victims were innocent; yet this was
unimportant to Stalin’s regime. By
• Coercion: public obedience is enforced through violence making everyone fear that he or she,
and surveillance. too, can be arrested, the public can be
• Co-optation: members of the public are brought into a controlled and even turned against
beneficial relationship with the state and government, itself, with all fearing that they will be
often through corporatism or clientelism. denounced by someone else. The use
• Personality cult: the public is encouraged to obey the of arbitrary arrests, torture, disap-
leader based on his or her extraordinary qualities and pearances, and murder continues to
compelling ideas. be common in many nondemocratic
regimes.
Nondemocratic Regimes and Political Control 153
CLIENTELISM A less structured means by which states may co-opt the pub-
lic is through clientelism, whereby the state co-opts members of the public
by providing specific benefits or favors to a single person or small group in
return for public support (such as voting in elections). Unlike corporatism,
clientelism relies on individual patronage rather than organizations that serve
a large group of people, and it is more ad hoc than corporatism. Clientelism
does not require a set of sanctioned and licensed organizations but can tar-
get and respond to individuals and groups as those in power see fit, trading
benefits for particular forms of support.
In both corporatism and clientelism, the state has a number of perquisites
it can use in co-opting individuals. Jobs within the state or in state-run sec-
tors of the economy, business contracts or licenses, public goods such as roads
or schools, kickbacks and bribes are a few of the tools in its arsenal. Such
largesse often leads to rent seeking, a process in which political leaders essen-
Nondemocratic Regimes and Political Control 155
tially rent out parts of the state to their supporters, who as a result control
public goods that would otherwise be distributed in a nonpolitical manner.
For example, leaders might turn over control of a nationalized industry, pro-
viding supporters with jobs and the ability to siphon off public funds from
that branch of the state.
In general, co-optation may be much more successful than coercion at
maintaining nondemocratic regimes, since many in the public may actively
support the regime in return for the benefits they derive. Political opposition
is dealt with not through repression and violence but by incorporating one’s
opponents into the system and making them dependent on it, or withholding
such largesse. Such a regime, however, faces limitations. Corporatist and clien-
telist institutions can run out of benefits with which to pacify the public;
national industries or resources can drag on the economy, run out, or decline
in value. In addition, in a regime where economic resources are doled out for
political reasons, problems may emerge as productive resources are siphoned
off to secure the acquiescence of the public. At its worst, such a regime can
decline into a kleptocracy (literally, “rule by theft”), where those in power seek
only to drain the state of assets and resources. As these resources dry up, co-
optation can quickly unravel.
Personality Cults
the power of the leader, and mistakes are blamed on the mortal flaws of the
public or on external enemies. Cults of personality may also be coupled to
coercion; the public may not believe the praise, but no one is willing to say
so. This is especially the case where charismatic power has faded over time
to become little more than a facade, held up only by force. Under these con-
ditions, there is always the chance that the cult will crack, leading to a rapid
political decompression. This occurred in Romania in 1989, when Nicolae
Ceauşescu, the self-styled “conductor” of his country, was shown on national
television reacting in a stunned and confused manner when attendees at a
public rally he was addressing suddenly grew hostile. Within hours, revolu-
tion had swept the country, and within three days, Ceauşescu and his wife
had been executed by firing squad.
Personality cults may also take a weaker but still powerful form. In Iran,
the image of Supreme Leader Ayatollah Khamenei adorns shops and bill-
boards around the country, and he is viewed as a conduit to God. Yet in spite
of his power, few Iranians would view him as a kind of deity in his own right
or believe that has superhuman powers. In recent years, Latin America has
produced a number of populist leaders whose personal charisma and sym-
bolic power are significant. Most notable of these is Hugo Chávez in
Venezuela, known for his regular presence in the media, including unscripted
speeches on national television that can last for several hours. His personal
popularity is strong and amplified by the state-run media, but it would be a
stretch to call this a personality cult. Chávez remains, in the eyes of the pub-
lic and in his own political communication, an exceptional, but still flawed,
human being.
Looking back over what we have discussed so far, we find that nonde-
mocratic regimes come to power and stay in power in various ways: some of
these ways are “carrots” (reward for compliance and support), others “sticks”
(threatened or actual punishments). It also follows that some people, perhaps
even a majority, may therefore view the regime as legitimate. They may agree
with the regime’s ideology, be direct beneficiaries of its rule, venerate its lead-
ers, or simply fear political change. The idea of nondemocratic legitimacy may
be hard for us to accept. Particularly in Western democracies, there is the
assumption that in every nondemocratic regime, the people are simply wait-
ing for the chance to install democracy. This belief is an exaggeration. Non-
democratic regimes can be just as institutionalized and stable and legitimate
as any democratic regime, enjoying some, or even a great deal of, public sup-
port, especially if benefits are widespread enough, coercion limited, and polit-
ical change viewed as fraught with risk. Many, for example, would suggest
that the current Chinese regime enjoys widespread public support and that
the public has little interest in democratization, which it views as potentially
undoing the economic progress of the last twenty years.
Models of Nondemocratic Rule 157
Personal and monarchical rule is what usually comes to mind when people
think of nondemocratic rule, perhaps because long before modern politics,
states, or economies came into being, people were ruled by powerful figures—
kings and Caesars, emperors and sultans, chiefs and caudillos. Drawing from
charismatic or traditional legitimacy, personal and monarchical rule often
rests on the claim that one person alone is fit to run the country, with no clear
regime or roles to constrain that person’s rule. Under this form of rule, the
state and society are commonly taken to be possessions of the leader, to be
dispensed with as he (or, occasionally, she) sees fit. The ruler is not a subject
of the state; rather, the state and society are subjects of the ruler. Ideology
may be weak or absent, as the ruler justifies his control through the logic that
he alone is the embodiment of the people and therefore uniquely qualified to
act on the people’s behalf. This claim may be coupled with a strong person-
ality cult or a reliance on the traditional authority of bloodlines.
In some cases, personal or monarchical rule relies less on charismatic or
traditional authority than on a specific form of co-optation known as patri-
monialism. Patrimonialism can be seen as a form of clientelism, in that those
158 CH. 6 NONDEMOCRATIC REGIMES
Military Rule
forces take control of the government by force. In some cases, military actors
may claim that they have seized control only reluctantly, promising to return
the state and government to civilian rule once stability has been restored. This
was the case in Thailand in 2006 when the military deposed the prime min-
ister, but then returned the country to democratic rule in 2007. In recent years,
the Turkish military has similarly threatened military action against the rul-
ing Islamist party, claiming that its religious orientation conflicts with the
country’s secular constitution. Often, under military rule, political parties and
most civil liberties are restricted; civilian political leaders or opponents of mil-
itary rule are arrested and may be killed or disappear. The use of coercion is
a common aspect of military rule, since by their nature, militaries hold an
overwhelming capacity for violence.
Military rule typically lacks a specific ideology, although some military
leaders espouse radical or reactionary political attitudes. Military rule also
tends to lack any charismatic or traditional source of authority, meaning that
if the military seek legitimacy in the eyes of the people, they often must fall
back on rational authority. One particular variant of military rule that reflects
this logic is known as bureaucratic authoritarianism, a regime in which the
state bureaucracy and the military share a belief that a technocratic leader-
ship, focused on rational, objective, and technical expertise, can solve the prob-
lems of the country—as opposed to “emotional” or “irrational” ideologically
based party politics. Public participation, in other words, is seen as an obsta-
cle to effective and objective policy making and so is done away with. In the
1960s and 1970s, bureaucratic authoritarian regimes emerged in a number of
less-developed countries as rapid modernization and industrialization gener-
ated a high degree of political conflict. State and industry, with their plans
for rapid economic growth, clashed with the interests of the working class
and peasantry, who sought greater political power and a larger share of the
wealth. This increasing polarization in politics often led business leaders and
the state bureaucracy to advocate military rule as a way to prevent the work-
ing class and the peasantry from gaining power over the government.7
Over the past thirty years, many bureaucratic authoritarian regimes have
transitioned to democracy. However, there remain some noteworthy exam-
ples. Russia now might be viewed as a bureaucratic authoritarian regime,
where those in power have tended to come from within the secret service or
military, including Vladimir Putin. Supporters of military rule believe that dis-
pensing with democracy can help facilitate modernization and development;
they point to cases like South Korea, Taiwan, and Chile as success stories.
But this is a problem of selection bias, where we have only looked for cases
of economic success. If we concentrate instead on military rule, we can find
many more cases that led to instability, the loss of life, and poor economic
development, such as much of Central America.
160 CH. 6 NONDEMOCRATIC REGIMES
One-Party Rule
that they cannot challenge the current regime. For many years, this was the
case in Mexico, which was dominated by the Institutional Revolutionary Party,
or PRI. Cuba, North Korea, China, Vietnam, and Laos are other examples of
one-party regimes, each controlled by a single communist party.
Theocracy
IN FOCUS
Types of Nondemocratic Rule
other faiths or sects within Islam are brought under strict control or banned
outright. Many have suggested that other countries in the Middle East, such as
Iraq or Egypt, could eventually move toward a theocracy; surveys, however, pro-
vide a more mixed picture of the public’s desire to fuse religion and state.8 As
with fundamentalism, we should not confuse religiosity, or even greater reli-
gion in politics, with a desire for theocracy. In fact, many of the strongest crit-
ics of Iran’s theocracy are some of its most prominent religious leaders.
Illiberal/Hybrid Regimes
Our last example is perhaps the most important for us to consider, since it
seems to be growing in prominence around the world. In fact, Figure 6.1,
Models of Nondemocratic Rule 163
shown earlier, includes a large group of countries that are categorized as nei-
ther “free” nor “not free,” but as “partially free,” falling somewhere between
democratic and nondemocratic regimes. Examples would include Venezuela,
Turkey, and Thailand. These regimes go by a number of names, such as semi-
democratic regimes, quasi-democratic regimes, or electoral democracies. They
are what we will term illiberal or hybrid regimes; scholars use both of these
terms to mean the same regime type, though each term captures a different
aspect of this particular form. By illiberal, we mean that they do not fully
institutionalize liberty, while the idea of a hybrid speaks to a combination of
democratic and nondemocratic institutions and practices. We will use the
terms illiberal and hybrid interchangeably.
What do illiberal or hybrid regimes have in common? These regimes fea-
ture many of the familiar aspects of democracy, though with important qual-
ifications. As a starting point, while the rule of law may be in place, it is weak.
As a result, all the democratic institutions that rest upon the rule of law are
weakly institutionalized and respected. Thus, executives, legislatures, and judi-
ciaries have their respective arenas of authority; the public enjoys the right
to vote; elections take place on a regular basis; and political parties compete.
But these institutions and processes are circumscribed or unpredictable in
ways inconsistent with democracy. Executives typically hold an overwhelm-
ing degree of power. This power is often concentrated in a presidency of a
semipresidential system that limits the ability for removal. Moreover, presi-
dents in illiberal systems often rely on referenda to bypass the state and con-
firm executive power. Legislatures in turn are less able to check the power of
the executive, and judicial institutions such as constitutional courts are often
packed with the supporters of those in power. In addition, while political com-
petition may exist on paper, parties and groups are restricted or harassed.
Government monopolies over print and electronic media are used to deny the
opposition a public platform while the judicial system is used to harass them.
The military or state-run industries can also be used by those in power to
compell their members to vote and act as instructed. Elections are manipu-
lated through changing electoral rules, barring candidates from running, vote-
buying, or intimidation.
Illiberal regimes in many ways represent a gray area between nondemoc-
ratic and democratic rule. Although these regimes look much like democra-
cies on paper, they are much less so in practice. The big question here is
whether illiberal regimes are transitional, in the process of moving from non-
democratic to democratic rule (or vice versa), or a new form of nondemoc-
racy that uses the trappings of democracy to perpetuate its control.
Increasingly we are seeing more of the latter: the spread of democratic insti-
tutions but with circumscribed participation, competition, and liberty.9
164 CH. 6 NONDEMOCRATIC REGIMES
I N S T I T U T I O N S I N
ACTION
POPULISM IN AN ILLIBERAL
REGIME: HUGO CHÁVEZ
AND VENEZUELA
The rise to power of Hugo Chávez in Venezuela has been an interesting example
for political scientists who study the intersection among populism, illiberalism, and
natural resources. A former army officer jailed for a failed coup in 1992, he was
elected president in 1998 by a strong majority of the vote. Since then, Chávez has
sought to carry out dramatic change in the country through means that have polar-
ized the international and domestic community. Many of these changes are rooted
in socialist or at least populist ideas, concentrating on the needs of the poor over
the wishes of the elites; they have included increased education and health care in
what is a highly unequal society. At the same time, the president has asserted greater
control over the country’s oil industry, which provided the means by which the pres-
ident can influence domestic and international affairs. The media, once strongly crit-
ical of Chávez, has been stifled by laws that prohibit slandering elected officials and
the refusal to relicense one of the largest private television stations known for its
hostility to Chávez. Chávez has also been given the power to rule by decree in cer-
tain areas, effectively bypassing the legislature, and he has sought to ban members
of the opposition from running in local elections. In the international arena, Chávez
has combined his political platform and oil revenues to forge ties with such coun-
tries as Cuba and Iran, and with other populist leaders in Latin America.
But to illustrate the complexity of illiberal regimes, Chávez does not enjoy
unchecked political power. His presidency has been hindered by term limits, which
require that he step down in 2013. In 2007, Chávez called for a national referendum
to eliminate term limits but it was defeated in the polls; a decree to increase the
powers of the intelligence services was rescinded after a public outcry, and mem-
bers of the military have criticized what they see as the politicization of the military.
At the same time, a second referendum to eliminate term limits passed in 2009,
which may pave the way for more nondemocratic actions by the president. A clear
transition to a fully democratic or authoritarian regime is probably the least likely
result.
100
80
Percentage of countries
60
40
20
0
1977 1987* 1997 2007
Year
NOTES
1. See the Freedom House website at www.freedomhouse.org.
2. For an excellent discussion of the bewildering varieties of nondemocratic rule, see
Juan Linz, Totalitarian and Nondemocratic Regimes (Boulder: Lynne Rienner, 2000).
This work was originally published in Fred I. Greenstein and Nelson W. Polsby,
eds., Handbook of Political Science (Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley, 1975).
3. Linz, Totalitarian and Nondemocratic Regimes.
4. Hannah Arendt, Totalitarianism (New York: Harcourt, Brace and World, 1951).
5. Mahathir Mohamad and Shintaro Ishihara, Voice of Asia: Two Leaders Discuss the
Coming Century (Tokyo: Kodansha International, 1996), p. 82.
6. For details, see Michael Bratton and Nicholas Van de Walle, “Neopatrimonial
Regimes and Political Transitions in Africa,” World Politics, 46, no. 4 (1994), pp.
453–489.
7. Guillermo O’Donnell, Modernization and Bureaucratic Non-democratic Regimes:
Studies in South American Politics (Berkeley: Institute of International Studies,
1973).
8. See “Iraqi Public Rejects Iranian Model but Wants Major Role for Islam in Gov-
ernment,” Program on International Policy Institute, 14 June 2005, www.pipa.org;
also “Iranians Egyptians, Turks: Contrasting Views on Sharia,” Gallup, 10 July
2008, www.gallup.com.
9. Marina Ottaway, Democracy Challenged: The Rise of Semi-Authoritarianism (Wash-
ington, DC: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, 2003); Arch Pudding-
ton, “Findings of Freedom in the World 2008—Is the Tide Turning?” Freedom in
the World Report 2008, www.freedomhouse.org
10. Oswald Spengler, The Decline of the West (New York: Knopf, 1928), p. 347.