Econ 209 Notes
Econ 209 Notes
Econ 209 Notes
Start-Up
What is ‘Macroeconomics’?
Potential output (Y*): Real GDP if all resources employed at normal intensity of use
Often called full-employment output
The upward trend in Y* is caused by growth in the economy’s productive capacity (labour force,
capital stock, technological change)
Output gap is the difference between potential & actual output and actual output
Output Gap = Y – Y*
Y < Y* a recessionary gap
Y > Y*, an inflationary gap
Potential GDP and the Output Gap, 1985-2017
Stats Can’s monthly rate is seasonally adjusted – i.e., compensated for normal (average)
changes over the years
Long-term trend: employment has grown roughly in line with the growth in the labour
force
Been large short-term fluctuations in U rate from 3.4% in 1966 to 12% in 1982
Some U is desirable: e.g., frictional reflects time needed for workers & firms to “find” each
other – so good matches are made
Some U associated with human hardship: e.g., structural is longer-term U (usually long-term)
caused by mismatch between skills of Ued & those required to fill vacancies – not in demand
by firms
Note: A 3% increase in real GDP with a 4% increase in population gives reduction in the average
S of L.
CPI is based on the price (i.e., cost) of a typical “consumption basket” relative to its base year
price
Assume there are only 2 goods, a and b. the P and Q are prices and quantities, and the number
1 indicates the base year. The CPI in the base year is:
In year 2, Pa rise from $10 50 $11 (a 10% rise), Pb rises from $5 to $6 (a 20% rise). The P index
for year 2 is:
12% is a weighted average – rise in Ps of G & S weighted by the relative importance of each
good in the average consumer’s spending.
Importance of Inflation
The purchasing power of money is negatively related to the price level. So inflation:
Hurts people on fixed incomes (Rules of 72)
Reduces real value of things with a fixed price
Creates expectations of further inflation, which affects other behaviour (e.g., US house
prices & savings rate)
Interest Rates
The interest rate is the price of “credit” flow of credit crucial to firms and households in a
modern economy
The effects of inflation on borrowers & lenders depends on the real interest rate. In real terms,
unanticipated inflation
Hurts the lender
Benefits the borrower
For Canada, exports and imports are both very large – roughly 35% of GDP – but the balance of
trade is usually small.
Balance of payments always sums to zero.
If someone sells a Canadian dollar, someone else must buy it.
How much can government actions affect the economy’s LR growth rate? Much debate
Short-term fluctuations
Different views on effectiveness of monetary and fiscal policy to influencing these fluctuations.
Some economists argue governments should not attempt “fine-tuning” despite the “power” of
policy to affect the economy
Step 2: Firms cut investment spending: less intermediate capital goods are produced. Some
workers are laid off.
Step 3: Laid-off workers buy less consumer goods & services. And increased fear of lay-off cause
other households to increase saving and reduce spending.
Step 4: Firms reduce production of final consumer goods. The cycle continues into recession.
Result: Expectations seem to have been correct. But only correct because of how economy
reacted to expectations.
To organize our thinking about macroeconomics, we must develop some tools. These will
include:
Discussing measurement of national income
Building a simple model of the economy
Modifying the model to make it more realistic
Using our model to analyze some pertinent economic issues
Production stages:
Intermediate products
Final products (G & S)
GDP = value of final G & S produced in the domestic economy
Includes additions to inventory (produced that year)
Includes exports to intermediate goods – ‘final’ sales domestically
Excludes imported final goods – not domestic production
Problem: distinguishing between final goods and intermediate goods (e.g., what is milk?)
Double counting avoided by value added
Each firm’s value added:
= revenues – cost of intermediate goods
= incomes to factors of production (at the firm)
Total value added gives Gross Domestic Product (GDP)
Note: Even if total output unchanged, moving some prodn from government to private sector
could increase GDP! Why?
*Because now valued at market value instead of at cost*
b. Non-factor payments:
Indirect maxes minus subsidies (gives true market values)
o Example: firm revenues = $10 000 of which $2000 is a government subsidy. So
market value = $8000
Depreciation (of existing K)
o Physical capital depreciates as it helps produce current output. So even though
the K was produced in previous years, is creating income/output in current year
o Measured by Capital Consumption Allowance in taxes
Changes in GDP deflator not necessarily same as changes in CPI (Consumer Price Index)
Measuring different things:
Change in CPI reflects the change in the average price of goods consumed in Canada
(including imports)
Change in GDP deflator reflects the change in the average price of goods produced in
Canada (including exports)
No ‘right’ base year – but % change in GDP between years are same regardless of which base
year chose
Example: would the ‘importance’ of a barrel of albert’s oil be the same at 1995 prices and 2015
prices?
Note of Caution: Non-market activities and econ bads can be a problem when comparing
different countries
Example: Non-market activities more prevalent in rural settings?
Econ bads are more prevalent in urban settings?
AE = C + I
Assume Ps constant – no inflation
Investment is autonomous (for the moment)
Highly unrealistic – but introduction to many of the interlinkages & ‘tools’ needed for more
realistic economy
Simple C function:
Changes in Sales
Higher is level of production & sales, larger is desired inventory level:
Changes in sales can cause temporary changes in investment in inventories (change
stops when get to new desired level)
Business Confidence
When business confidence improves, firms want to invest now in response to incentive for
higher future profits.
Business confidence and consumer confidence may feed off of one another.
The economy is in equilibrium when desired aggregate expenditure equal actual national
income.
In equilibrium:
Y = AE = C + I But: C + Y – S
Y=Y–S+I Y–Y+S=I
S=I
In this simple model, you recall, we kept the price level constant
This would mean that as the economy wishes to consume more, it will be provided (i.e.,
produced) without any change in price.
That is, none of our increased demand for output will be ‘squeezed out’ by higher prices.
So, production (aggregate supply of output) in this highly simplified economy is demand
determined.
The Multiplier
The multiplier measures ∆ in equilibrium Y resulting from ∆ in autonomous expenditure. In this
simplest of macro models, in equilibrium:
Y = AE = C + I = a + bY + I = (a + I) + bY
Y = A + bY (1 – b)Y = A Y = A/(1 – b)
∆Y/∆A = 1/(1-b)
The multiplier exceeds one
[b < 1 so 1/(1-b) > 1]
Example:
Finding the Simple Multiplier
AE = C + I = a + bY + I
AE = a + I + bY
= A + bY
In equilibrium, AE = Y
Y = 600 +0.8Y
(1 – 0.8)Y = 600
Y = 600/0.2
Y = 1/0.2 600 = 5(600) = 3000
∆Y/∆A = 1/(1 – z) = 1/0.2 = 5
Chapter 22: Adding Government and Trade to the Simple Macro Model
Government Purchases
Government purchases of G & S (G) are part of desired AE
Not including transfer payments
All levels of government – federal, provincial, territorial municipal
Net Exports
Two assumptions:
Canada’s exports are autonomous with respect to Canadian GDP
Canada’s imports rise as Canadian GDP rises
o IM = mY
o Where m is the marginal propensity to import
Thus, net exports are given by: NX = X – mY
Example: a fall in our exchange rate (i.e., an increase in the value the C$)
Increase the foreign price of our exports, and (so X falls)
Reduces the C$ price of our imports (so IM rise)
The AE Function
Expand the AE function:
AE = C + I + G + NX
AE = a + b(1 – t)Y + I + G + X – mY
AE = [a + I + g + X] + b(1 – t)Y – mY
AE = A + [b(1 – t) – m)]Y = A + zY
Slope of the AE function is the marginal propensity to spend out of national income – we call
this z
In this model, we get:
Z = MPC(1 -t) – m z = b(1 – t) – m
Clearly, t > o and m > 0 lead to a lower value of z
Fiscal Policy
Refers to government spending and tax policies (which influence the budget deficit or surplus)
Any policy to keep Y at or near Y* is called stabilization policy
Y < Y* suggests increase G and/or reduce T
Y > Y* suggests reduce G and/or increase T
Often is clear direction for fiscal policy, but its less clear how much adjustment is needed
AE = A = [b(1-t) – m)]Y = A + zY
Contractionary: reduce G (∆G < 0)
In AE = A + zY, A falls. Equilibrium Y falls by ∆Y
∆Y = ∆G x simple multiplier
∆Y = [1/(1-z)]
AE = A + [b(1-t)-m]Y = A + zY z = b(1-t) – m
There’s an equal increase in government injections and withdrawals, but for the economy the
increase in injections exceeds the increase in withdrawals
The increase in T reduces YD
The fall in YD reduces S
The net change in withdrawal = increase T minus decrease S
Although increase G = increase T, increase G > increase T+S so increase injection > increase
withdrawals
The net injection means consumption (C = f(YD) doesn’t fall by the full rise in T
Caveat: raising taxes can’t go on and on, continually stimulating output higher and higher taxes
would eventually cause a big enough reduction incentive to work that GDP would fall
Our simple macro model (chapters 21 and 22) is based on three central concepts:
Equilibrium national income
The simple multiplier
Demand-determined output
Demand-determined output is implicit in the assumption that firms will produce all that is
demanded at the current (i.e., constant) price level
Both simple multiplier and demand-determined output are closely connected to the
assumption of a constant price level, determined exogenously
The next chapter brings supply side of the economy because of the interactions between
aggregate demand and aggregate supply. The price level and inflation to be determined
endogenously.
Chapter 23: Real GDP and the Price Level in the Short Run
Issue:
How much of the shift in AD gets ‘translated’ into
o Increases in output (Y)
o Increase in price level (P)
Answers depends on slope of aggregate supply curve (AS)
So, our next step is to examine the supply side of the economy
Having done that, well put the demand & supply sides together
A Word of Warning
Many economic events (especially changes in the world prices of raw materials) cause both AD
and AS shocks – complex shocks
The overall effect on the economy depends on the relative importance of the two separate
effects
Chapter 24: From Short Run to Long Run- the Adjustment of Factor Prices
When Y > Y*, the demand for labour (and other factor services) is relatively high
An inflationary output gap
During an inflationary output gap there are high profits for firms and unusually large demand
for labour
Wages and unit costs tend to rise
When Y < Y*, the demand for labour (and other factor services) is relatively low
Recessionary output gap
During a recessionary gap there are low profits for firms and low demand for labour (AS shifts
down, economy moves down along AD curve)
Wages and unit costs tend to fall*
*assuming no productivity growth
Adjustment asymmetry:
Inflationary output gaps typically raise wages rapidly
Recessionary output gaps often reduce wages only slowly (i.e., a downward stickiness in
money wages)**
This is general adjustment process – from output gaps to factor prices (specifically, wages) – is
summarized by the Phillips curve
The Phillips Curve shows how adjustment speed/pressures differ depending on the size of and
direction of the output gap
**Actually, money wage seldom fall. Real wages fall, however, if prices rise more than money
wages. We’ll use money wages for simplicity
The Phillips curve shows a negative relationship between U rate & the rate of change of ∆ in
nominal Wage rates*
Y > Y* excess D for L W rise quickly
Y < Y* excess S of L W fall slowly
Y = Y* no excess supply/demand Ws constant
Emphasis:
‘Adjustment asymmetry’ and ‘downward stickiness of money wages’ means ‘adjustment
pressures differ depending on whether it’s an inflationary gap (Y>Y*) or a recessionary gap
(Y<Y*)
If Y<Y* but wages are sticky downwards, what other pressures can help the economy to adjust
to reduce the recessionary gap?
a. Expectations of recovery can raise stock prices, which increases wealth which increases
consumption
b. Replacement of ‘worn-out’ durables can raise confidence further increasing investment
and therefore employment
These may play an even larger role than falling wages in closing a recessionary gap (but well
continue to use falling wages)
And downward rigidity of W can makes other forces more powerful than W in getting out of a
recessionary gap.
Repeat: Don’t necessarily need fall in money W. If % increase P > % increase W, then still have
real wages
Long-Run Equilibrium
The economy is in a state of long-run equilibrium when factor prices are no longer adjusting to
output gaps:
Y = Y*
The AS is a vertical line at Y* -- sometimes called:
The long-run aggregate supply curve, or
The classical aggregate supply curve
In the long run there is no relationship between the price level and potential output
In LR
Y* determines Y, and
AD determines only P
LR growth in Y* can come from:
Growth in amount of factors of production
Improved productivity via technological change
With no change in AD curve, LR growth in Y* reduces P level
Canadian data confirm that positive output gaps tend to drive wages and costs upward.
The motivation for fiscal stabilization policy is to reduce the volatility of aggregate outcomes.
When an AD or AS shock pushes Y away from Y* the alternative are:
Use fiscal stabilization policy (via ∆s in budget deficit/surplus)
Not use – wait for the recovery of private sector demand - a shift in the AD curve
Not use – wait for the economy’s S-side adjustment process - a shift in the AS curve
A recessionary gap may be closed by a (possibly slow) rightward shift in the AS curve or by a
rightward shift in AD.
Summary: Fiscal stabilization policy will generally have consequences for economic growth
1. An increase in G:
- Increases Y in the short run
- In the long run the rate of growth if Y* may be influence by effect of increase on G
private sector investment:
o Lower if private investment is lower in the new long-run equilibrium
o Higher if G increases the productivity of private-sector production (e.g., via
infrastructure)
2. A reduction in t:
- Demand stimulus in SR
- If LR growth is increased, no obvious trade-off between SR & LR – e.g., cut in corporate
tax rates can be SR & LR stimulus (if causes big rise in I hence in Y*)
- And, S-siders argue get even higher tax revenues from combination of the lower t and
higher Y* (e.g., Thatcher, George W. Bush)
Final Note
In theory, seems no obvious trade-off between SR & LR effects of cutting tax rates –
seem OK for SR & LR
But in practice would this be an illusion if LR effect of lower t included a fall in revenues,
causing:
o Lower productivity in private sector by less government spending on R&D &
infrastructure?
o On other goods/services of social value (R&D, health care, national parks etc.)
that either:
Can’t be counted for National Accounts (GDP) or
Counted only at cost rather than societal value?
Recent years – biggest growth in income in many developed countries been going to top
part of the income distribution
Rising average income has come with rising income inequality
Policy issue: What to do about it? How to do it?
The “quick and dirty: explanation: falling supply of natural resources cause their prices to rise,
which gives incentives for two things:
More exploration to find more of the same resource
The development of new substitute resources
Note: Texts says it’s not the same question as for Global Warming – see later in “are there limits
to growth?”
The figure shows a positive relationship between investment rates and growth rates, as
predicted by our model
What’s left? Neoclassical growth model requires technological change for sustained growth in
living standards
Note: Technological change is not directly observable, so its impact is difficult to measure. This
becomes even more apparent when recognize it can arise in different ways.
Disembodied: Not contained within new capital but comes from newly generated sources. For
example:
New materials
New products
New production processes
New managerial techniques
Embodied: Contained within the new capital equipment etc. (higher quality and more
productive)
Even replacement investment contains embodied technological change, and disembodied can
soon become embodied
Note: technological change can also be ‘embodied’ within the work force (L) and well as K)
Investment in Human Capital – more & better skills
The information Technology (IT) ‘revolution’ likely improved both physical & human capital
productivity. For example, better
Information flows
Management techniques
Quality of learning etc.
To repeat:
In Neoclassical growth theory, increases in Y* are inextricably linked to investment in new,
more productive K.
IT revolution likely improved both physical & human capital – e.g. better information flows,
management techniques, quality of learning etc.
How much of an increase in GDP results from tech change & how much from other things?
Cannot measure this directly
Resort to indirect measurement
How is Technological Change Measured?
The ‘Solow residual’
Robert Solow (MIT): in his “growth accounting” he
Estimates what part of the growth in GDP can be explained by growth in quantities of
capital stock or the labour force, and
The ‘residual’ – the part of growth in GDP that’s not explained by changed in quantities
of inputs – is by implication, explained by technological change
Note: May see Solow Residual called rate of growth of Total Factor Productivity (TFP)
Market-Development Costs
The initial R & D & marketing costs are one-time ‘fixed costs’
Subsequent investment built upon the initial R & D can give increasing marginal returns in other
ways. Some examples:
Creates benefits for other firms & industries by:
o Creating new skills that becomes available to them
o Resolving practical problems of use, so making the new investment even more
profitable
o Using the new technology creates the infrastructure for more and more efficient
use
Creates new attitudes among consumers:
o Consumers become more receptive of new products (obvious example is
internet)
o The number of new consumers grows and grows once they see the advantages
for others using the innovation (Facebook?)
The Knowledge Element
‘New Growth Theories’ place much more emphasis on the economics of ideas
Knowledge is a public good. Is non-diminishable and (mostly) non-excludable
The property of non-diminishing means the marginal cost (MC) of others using the ideas
is zero
So, knowledge need not be subject to diminishing marginal returns, as may be the case
with other capital
The current emphasis is on such knowledge-driven growth
Rate at which we are acquiring knowledge seems to be rising
Resource Exhaustion
Current technology and resources could not support the entire world’s population at
Canada’s average standard of living
Does this imply absolute limits to growth?
o Technology is constantly improving
o New resources are being ‘discovered’ & ‘invented’
But while we can have expectations about what might happen in the future, we don’t
know what technological change will happen
Must use caution as economic growth continues
Conclusion
Economic growth may help the world with many problems
But it new must be sustainable growth – based on knowledge-driven technological
change
And there’s the issue of ‘equity’ for developing countries especially as the world
population rises
Has the world already passed the point of no return?
Most environmentalists say ‘No’ – but must act now
Chapter 26: Money and Banking
Origins of Money
Money has evolved over time, taking various different forms:
Metallic money:
At first, market value of the metal = face value of the coin
Led to debasing & clipping (note milled edges), so
Inflation as value of precious metal in coin fell
The ‘good money’ drops out of circulation (people keep it)
o Gresham’s Law – Bad Money Drives Out Good
Paper money:
Was initially fully backed by precious metal, convertible on demand
Often referred to as bank notes (issued by banks)
Fractionally backed paper money:
Goldsmiths and banks issued more notes than amount of gold in their vaults
Was possible because only small % want to redeem their notes at the same time
Sometimes caused loss of confidence – ‘run’ on banks
Fiat money:
Not backed & not convertible into anything else
Decreed by the government to be legal tender
o Note: see writing on $20 bill
Today, almost all currency is fiat money
Reserves
Banks’ cash reserves are normally quite small because only a small fraction of depositors want
their money at any time
A bank’s reserve ratio is the fraction of its deposits liabilities that it actually holds as reserves
Either vault cash or deposits with the central bank
A bank’s target reserve ratio is the fraction of its deposits it wishes to hold as reserves
The Canadian banking system is a fractional-reserve system
In March 2006 commercial banks in Canada held less than 1% of their deposits in
reserves
In March 2018 they had 2.5% of their deposits in reserves
Reserves greater than target reserves are excess reserves
Financial institutions make money by lending out (& ‘investing’) their excess reserves,
which
Become the basis for creating more deposit money
A new deposit of $100 raises the bank’s reserve ratio to 27 percent = (300/1100) x 100
∆Deposits = (1/v)∆Reserves
In our example, with v=0.2, $500 = 1/0.2(4100) = 5($100)
See that the sum of the additions to reserves in any round is 20% of the sum of the new
deposits created that round
For all rounds together, the banking system’s expansion of deposits is 5 times the first deposit
of new currency
Conclusion: Money supply and deposit expansion per $ of change in total cash (currency) in the
economy will be greater
The smaller the target reserve ratio of commercial banks, and
The smaller the public’s cash drain from the banking system
The money supply is the total quantity of money that is in the economy at any time
In general terms: Money supply = Currency (held by public) + Deposits
Specifically, there are several definitions of “money”
Kinds of Deposits
The long-standing distinction between money and other highly liquid assets used to be:
Money was a medium of exchange that did not earn interest
Other assets earned interest but were not a medium of exchange
Today, distinction between what is and is not a medium of exchange is very blurred. Transfers
between different types of accounts can be made extremely quickly.
Choosing a Measure
There is no single timeless or best definition of money
New financial assets are continually being developed that serve some of the function of money
Chapter 27
Part A: The Demand for Money
Perspective
1. Classical view:
Dichotomy between Monetary & Real sectors of the economy:
In real sector, resources allocated among production of various goods & services by
relative prices
“the neutrality of money” – change in quantity of money affect only the P level (not
relative Ps), so has no effect on allocation of resources & output level
Economy adjusts so quickly to an output gap that even SR classical AS curve vertical
at Y*, so any change in AD simple changes P level
2. Modern view:
Agree that money is “neutral” in long run
But not accept that is neutral in short run
Where are we going?
So far, our model has treated investment as autonomous. But
Investment is negatively related to rate of interest, and
Changes in D or S of money affect the rate of interest, so
Money affects the ‘real’ sector by affecting the rate of interest, which then affects
investment, which then affects AD and output
For simplicity, we assume that people have two types of financial assets:
Money (earns no interest)
Bonds (earn interest)
First need to understand relationship between interest rate & ‘price’ of bonds
Summary
MD = MD (i, Y, P) – (negative, positive, positive)
Reserved for D to hold bonds – Descision to hold money is a decision not to hold bonds
Graphing It
Change in r of I – along MD
Change in Y or P – shift MD
Side note: MD curve is liquidity preference function
Next Steps
1. Determining equilibrium in the monetary sector (MD = MS)
2. Understanding how changes in monetary sector of the economy are transmitted to the
real sector – the “transmission mechanism” of monetary policy
Monetary Equilibrium
Occurs when the quantity of money demanded equals the quantity of money supplied:
Equilibrium interest rate
The Money Transmission Mechanism
Connects changes in MD and/or MS with aggregate demand
Three stages:
1. ∆MD or ∆MS - ∆ in equilibrium interest rate
2. ∆I - ∆ in desired investment expenditure
3. ∆ID - ∆ in AD
Stage 1: Shifts in the MS or MD curves cause the equilibrium interest rate to change
The Effects of Changes in the Money Supply on Desired Investment Expenditure
Stage 2: Changes in the equilibrium interest rate lead to changes in desired investment
Step 2: demand for bonds rises, pushing up the P of bonds and lowering the rate of interest
Step 3: Bond holders want to sell Canadian bonds to invest abroad at the now higher interest
rates
Note: that this selling of bonds to invest abroad prevents the P of bonds from rising as much as
they would in a closed economy – and prevents rate of interest falling as much
So the capital outflow in an ‘open’ economy actually weakens the impact of monetary policy
through the interest rate channel
But while weakening the effect on interest rates, the capital outflow also creates a new channel
for the transmission mechanism of monetary policy (Steps 4 & 5)
Step 4: the capital outflow increases the supply of Canadian money on the international
currency markets, reducing its price (i.e., its value depreciates)
Step 5: the depreciation of the Canadian money makes exports less expensive and imports
more expensive. NX rises, and this too shifts the AD curve to the right
The net effect of (i) weakening the effect on AD through the interest rate & investment channel
and (ii) creating the new channel through imports & exports is too strengthen monetary policy
All three effects are caused by ∆P, so creating movement along AD curve, not a shift
So whether ∆I & ∆NX show as a shift of or movement along the AD curve depends on what
causes them:
If the cause is ∆P, it’s a movement along
For any other cause, it’s a shift
Example 2: a fall in NX
If the cause is a rise in the domestic P level (increasing the price of exports), the effect is
shown as a move along AD
If the cause is a fall in MS, which
o Raises I which
Induces a capital inflow, which
Reduces exchange rate, which
o Reduces NX, which
Shifts the AD curve
27.4 – The Strength of Monetary Forces
Example: if U in recession causes a deterioration of skills (a fall in HC) through lack of use, then
workers are less productive after recession than before it, so Y* will be lower
Been some empirical support for hysteresis in Western Europe, but the weight of evidence is
against it for Canada
Still debatable – but let’s see what happens to productivity after the long-duration
unemployment of many workers because of COVID-19
Across many countries over long periods of time, the rate of inflation and the growth rate of
the money supply are highly correlated
Much empirical support for the idea that the money demand curve is not flat:
Changes in money supply do lead to changes in the equilibrium interest rate, so
Monetary policy can be effective
There is much less compelling evidence regarding the slope of the investment demand curve
Practical Problem: Separating the effect of expectations from the effect of interest rates
Example: assume the central banks expects an inflationary gap to open in the near future and
uses contractionary monetary policy to increase interest rates
Then suppose that, shortly afterwards, there is a small reduction in investment. Would this
imply that the investment D curve is quite steep?
Not necessarily…
Suppose that a higher I alone would cause big fall in desired investment – i.e., a move along
quite flat investment D curve,
But at the same time the private-sector’s expectations of a ‘boom’ shifts the investment
demand curve to the right
The resulting ‘small’ reduction in investment would be the net effect of two opposing forces,
not the result of investment being quite insensitive to the rate of interest (i.e., not a steep
investment demand curve)
Example 1: Canadian dollar appreciation caused by increase in foreign D for Canadian exports:
Increases AD
Creates Y>Y* (inflationary gap)
Appropriate response is contractionary monetary policy
Example 2: Canadian dollar appreciation caused by increase in foreign D for Canadian monetary
assets (e.g., bonds)
Reduces NX (X fall & IM rise)
Reduces AD
Creates Y < Y* (recessionary gap)
Appropriate response us expansionary monetary policy
Appropriate monetary policy response to change rate change differs by cause of the change
Keynesians: Reverse it: Fall in MS a result of the downturn in the real sector. Follow the process:
A big drop in output & employment in construction, combined with
A stock market crash, together
Reduced wealth, which
Caused drop in consumption spending, causing
Drop in demand for deposit money, causing
Fall in MS
Political Difficulties?
Lags mean monetary policy must be forward-looking
Policy may seem inconsistent with current state of economy – tightened now because of
expected future inflation
Expectations
Some Ws raised in anticipation of inflation. So, 2 forces:
Change in Money Wages = Output-gap effect + Expectational effect
If the economy remains at Y* there’s no output gap effect on prices. The only influence on
inflation, therefore, is expectations
To ‘validate’ expectations of (say) 5% inflation the monetary authorities must increase the MS
by 5%
If MS were increased by more than 5% an inflationary output gap would open, Y > Y*,
inflation would rise above 5%.
If MS were increased by less than 5% a recessionary gap would open, Y > Y*, inflation
would fall below 5%.
So, to keep Y = Y* (i.e. prevent an output gap from opening), then
o the rate of increase of MS must equal the expected inflation rate
Here we see it. Continual validation keeps AD curve moving up at the same rate as the AS curve,
no output gap opens up, and actual inflation remains equal to expected inflation.
Demand Inflation
Demand shock (e.g., rise in NX) increases AD from AD0 to AD1
Rate of increase of W rises costs of production go up, & if AD remains at AD 1 (i.e. no validation)
the output gap is eroded until GDP back at Y*
Without further validation, inflation come to a halt
So, inflation was only temporary
But with continuing monetary validation of inflation at Y1:
AD keeps increasing, which
Keep inflationary gap open, which
Keeps both pressures (output gap + expectations) on inflation, which
Causes accelerating inflation
Initially the upward pressure on Ws from expectations exceed the downward pressure from the
recessionary output gap, so there’s both rising prices and falling output. This is called
‘stagflation’ (i.e., stagnation with inflation).
Because of these opposing forces, inflation declines. Thus the level of expected inflation falls. As
this continues, the effect of the output gap will become equal the effect of expectations and the
reduction in AS will stop (AS1 in the diagram) And inflation comes to a halt
Thereafter the effect of the output gap on prices exceeds the effect of expectation on prices, AS
shifts to the right, inflation falls, the output gap closes, and eventually the economy returns to
Y*
Conclusion: With Y < Y* & no monetary validation Y returns to Y* – but only slowly because
wage rates are downwardly ‘sticky’. Again, inflation without monetary validation is temporary
Phase 2: Stagflation
At Y* expectations are still increasing wages
Stagflation as AS keeps shifting via expectations
Recessionary gap opens – downward pressure on W via output gap effect (Y < Y*)
At E3 the 2 pressures offset each other AS stops shifting, inflation stops
Breaking inflationary expectations has been a slow process
Phase 3: Recovery
Eventually, recovery takes output to Y*, and P is stabilized. Two ways for this to happen.
Either wait for wages fall, bringing the AS curve back to AS 2…
… or the central bank increases the money supply sufficiently to shift the AD curve to AD 2
It’s a trade-off: (i) faster return to Y*, but (ii) possibility of creating new inflationary
expectations
Productivity
Productivity: output per unit of input
The productivity of labour is the relevant one here
Usually measured as (real) GDP per worker
Or (real) GDP per hour of work
The latter is a more accurate definition of labour productivity, but harder to collect data which
to measure it
Increases in productivity is probably the single largest cause of LR increases in the average
Standard of Living*
The major causes of increased productivity are
New and better technology
Improvement in skills (education among them)
*Note: A 3% increase in real GDP with a 4% increase in population gives reduction in the
average S of L
A: Market-Clearing Theories
Economy adjust so rapidly that output gaps don’t exist
So GDP always = Y*, and U rate always = U*
And at Y* there is no cyclical unemployment – all U* is frictional or structural
The labour market is always in equilibrium (Qd = Qs). Thus, there is never any excess supply of
labour – i.e., nobody who wants to work isn’t working. So, no unemployment
B: Non-Market-Clearing Theories
Like market-clearing theories, in the long run U=U* (the NAIRU) since Y=Y*
Unlike the market-clearing theories, the non-clearing theories recognize that there are output
gaps in the short run. So, in the short run:
The economy can be where Y does not equal Y*, and U does not equal U*
Ws do not adjust quickly (i.e., are ‘sticky’)
There is a cyclical and involuntary U
Recessions:
Excess S of Labour (U > U*)
Cyclical U of (L’1-L1)
Ws ‘sticky’ downwards, so the labour market does not clear quickly. (L’-L 1) persists
Booms:
Ws increase flexible
Excess D for L (U < (or equal) U* of (L’2 – L2)
Ws flexible upwards, so market clears quicker than in recession
Results:
Union wages are ‘sticky’
U of union members in recessions is higher than it would have been with flexible wages
5. Government Policies
Do they affect labour market flexibility?
Use EI (Employment insurance) as an example
Do the EI benefits increase workers’ time between jobs?
Benefits reduce the opportunity cost of staying unemployed for longer. How does the
unemployed worker react?
Do benefits harm market-clearing by reducing regional mobility? They reduce
unemployed workers’ (financial) incentive to move to where firms are hiring. Do they
respond to that incentive?
But also, social and economic benefits:
Do they promote longer search time, raising efficiency by creating a better match
between skills for jobs & skills for workers?
Social benefits created by redistributing income to reduce hard ship
Cyclical Component
Difference between the actual deficit & the structural deficit
(Y < Y*), actual deficit > structural deficit
(Y > Y*), actual deficit < structural deficit
NB: if Y* were at Y**, have negative structural deficit – i.e. a surplus = S
∆d = x + (r – g) x d
∆d = ∆[D/GDP] = change in D/GDP ratio
X = (G – T)/GDP = the rise in D/GDP caused by primary budget deficit
r x d = (r x D)/GDP = the rise in D/GDP ratio caused by debt service payments
g x d = D/(g x GDP) = fall in D/GDP ratio caused by rate of growth of GDP
∆d = x + (r – g) x d
Three cases:
Case 1: r = g
(r – g) x d = Zero
So any change in D/GDP ratio (∆d) must be caused by x i.e. by (G-T)/GDP
Primary deficit (G.T) increases D/GDP ratio
Primary surplus (G<T) reduces D/GDP ratio
Balanced primary budget (G=T), no change
∆d = x + (r – g) x d
Case 2: r > g
(r – g) x d > 0, which by itself would increase the D/GDP ratio
But it isn’t ‘by itself’ – there’s also X
1) If X is positive (i.e. primary deficit) it would also increase D/GDP, so combining the two
means D/GDP must rise
2) 2) If X is negative (i.e. primary surplus) it’s pushing D/GDP in the opposite direction, so
there are two opposing forces on D/GDP
a. D/GDP will fall if the primary surplus is big enough to dominate effects of the
debt service payments
b. D/GDP will rise if it isn’t
∆d = x + (r – g) x d
Case 3: r < g
(r – g) x d < 0
1) If X is negative (primary surplus) D/GDP must fall
2) If X is positive (primary deficit) then D/GDP ratio
a. Will fall if primary deficit not big enough to offset effects of the debt service
payments
b. Will rise primary deficit is large enough
2. Fiscal Policy:
Very high D/GDP ratio may severely restrict ability to use counter-cyclical fiscal policy
Debt service payments are high % of tax revenue, which
o May restrict ability to use fiscal policy, since
Less ‘room’ for debt-financed
So may be unable to have stabilizing fiscal policy (especially in recessions when need/want
deficit)
∆d = x + (r – g) x d
G = % increase in GDP, which alone reduces D/GDP
Can have budget deficit with no rise in D/GDP
- With r < g, can have deficit and falling D/GDP
First develop an alternative way of specifying the current account surplus (CA). We’ll do it using
injections & withdrawals
At equilibrium, injections = withdrawals: G + I + X = S + T + M
Rearrange: (X – M) = S + (T – G) – I
(X – M) = NX + CA surplus
CA + S + (T – G) – I (Note S + (T – G) is National Savings
If PPP worked, the actual e and the ePPP would move closely together
Advocates of a flexible exchange rate argue that, compared to a fixed rate, it gives flexibility to
the economy and reduces the impact of negative ‘shocks’ on the economy. The emphasize the
“Shock Absorber” effect of a flexible exchange rate.
The fall in D exports also reduces the demand for C$ on foreign exchange markets. With a
flexible rate the C$ depreciates, which lowers the foreign price of our exports and increases the
domestic price of imports
The resulting effect on net exports reduces the negative effects of the initial fall in D exports, so
GDP & employment do not fall as much as they would under a fixed exchange rate.
A fixed rate would have prevented the description of the $C thereby eliminating the ‘shock-
absorber’ effect on GDP & employment