The Evolution of Corporate Bankruptcy
The Evolution of Corporate Bankruptcy
The Evolution of Corporate Bankruptcy
.1.1.473.
Neetu Yadav
Mon ey
Bankruptcy Law in India &
Fin a n ce
1
NIMRIT KANG AND NITIN NAYAR OCT. 0 3 M A R . 0 4
Abstract
The Indian post-independence industrial policies, such as import
substitution, industrial licensing, and limited private ownership, fostered a
breed of inefficient and uncompetitive companies. Deregulation, foreign
competition and financial reform led many financially unviable firms to
consider exit or restructuring options. H owever, the existing legal, political
and social system did not provide the appropriate framework for efficient and In so far as the
equitable resolution of insolvency cases, thus dramatically slowing the pace of
the much needed industrial restructuring. This paper shows that there is no objective of a well
single comprehensive and integrated policy on corporate bankruptcy in India
comparable with the bankruptcy code in the US. Instead, there are a number functioning
of legislative acts and special provisions, which provide procedural guidance
on the liquidation or reorganisation process and there is an involvement of bankruptcy system
different agencies, having overlapping jurisdiction, which creates systemic
delays and complexities in the process. In so far as the objective of a well
is to promote
functioning bankruptcy system is to promote economic efficiency by
economic efficiency
maximising the total value of assets, the Indian system fails, as under this
system, liquidation or reorganisation is extremely time and resource costly; the by maximising the
system does not encourage optimal valuation outcomes; and creates incentives
for managers or stockholders to take actions that generate private benefits at total value of assets,
the expense of firm value. The paper evaluates the existing corporate bank-
ruptcy system; and the incentives and biases it has created, given the Indian the Indian system
socio-political context and economic goals. It assesses the new Companies
(Second Amendment) Act, 2002, and the possibility of its success in streamlin- fails, as under this
ing and correcting the shortcomings of the existing process.
system, liquidation
The Protectionist Past
or reorganisation is
After its independence from British rule in 1947, India adopted
a socialistic and state dominated economic system and over the next extremely time and
four decades aggressively pursued a series of protectionist policies
designed to develop and promote the domestic industrial base. Policies resource costly.
such as import substitution, industrial licensing, limited private owner-
ship, and price fixing gave rise to a new breed of Indian companies that
1 The authors are recent graduates from H arvard Business School and
A Changing Context
India is paying a
A few shocks, such as the fiscal and balance-of-payment crisis
huge opportunity of 1991, triggered a move towards privatisation and rapid dismantling
of these protectionist policies through the 1990s. Deregulation and
cost for not being introduction of foreign competition coupled with financial reform have
exposed the vulnerabilities (financial and business) of the incumbent
able to redeploy this firms, forcing many of them to consider exit or restructuring options.
H owever, the current legal, political and social system have lagged
capital towards its behind in providing the appropriate forum or policy framework for
efficient and equitable resolution of insolvency cases, thus dramatically
ambitious goals for slowing the pace of a much needed industrial shakeout. Also, as much
of public sector and institutional credit is locked up in these poor
economic investments, India is paying a huge opportunity cost for not being able
to redeploy this capital towards its ambitious goals for economic
development; hence
development; hence a growing consensus for development of a robust
a growing bankruptcy system. As of M arch 2001, there were 3,317 financially
distressed large and medium sized firms with an unpaid debt of Rs. 258
consensus for billion (or US$5.4 billion at the 2001 exchange rate), roughly 2 per
cent of 2001 gross domestic product (GDP) or 10 per cent of the total
development of a outstanding industrial credit provided by banks in 2001. These “ sick”
loans have been growing faster than GDP at an annual rate of about 10
robust bankruptcy per cent over the last 10 years (M itra, 2001).
This paper will focus on (1) evaluation of the corporate bank-
system. ruptcy system that had existed until very recently (referred to as the exist-
ing system in this paper) until a new amendment was passed in January
2003, the incentives and systemic biases it has created, given the Indian
social and political context and the goals for economic development;
and (2) assessment of the suitability of the recently passed amendment
(new system) in correcting the shortcomings of the existing system.
3 The SIC Act defines net worth as the sum of paid up capital and “ free
reserves” ; free reserves include all reserves from profits and share premium account
by maximising the
Company under Financial Distress
this score.
Voluntarily Liquidate
Reorganise Reorganise Recommend Liquidate
Liquidation
N otes: The bold lines indicates the actual process pursued in majority of the cases of
financial distress.
such as India.
The commonly cited reasons for the delays include sheer
workload (~40 cases are reviewed each month), dilatory tactics used by
the management and workers such as litigating the BIFR decision and
not providing appropriate financial records, and lack of cooperation
from creditors when asked to make concessions.
The process of liquidation under the jurisdiction of the Compa-
nies Act, 1956, is also a cumbersome process riddled with endless loops
of procedural delays. O nce a recommendation for liquidation is made
by the appropriate agency, the process of disposing of assets and
42 settling claims is very lengthy because of the involvement of the
government and the judicial system. For example, the O fficial Liquida- ICRA BULLETIN
recommendations
TABLE 2
Years taken in the OL liquidation process for companies (3/ 12/ 1999) made by the BIFR.
Years 0-5 5-10 10-15 15-20 20-25 >25 Total
Active Cases 1065 603 482 321 251 473 3195
% of Total 33% 19% 15% 10% 8% 15%
43
ICRA BULLETIN Bias against Restructuring & Liquidation
The definition of sickness proposed by the Sick Industrial
Mon ey
Companies Act (1993) prevents any intervention by the BIFR until the
& accumulated losses have completely wiped out equity and reserves,
Fin a n ce which is simply too late for any meaningful rehabilitation of the
company’s financial condition. In the words of a previous chairman of
OCT. 0 3 M A R .. 0 4
the BIFR, “ We find typically that in a sick unit…the entire net worth has
been eroded, the working capital has all but disappeared, there are no
stocks, and the unit is characterised by very low levels of capacity
utilisation…. For all practical purposes, the sorts of cases that come
before BIFR are almost mortuary cases” (M itra, 2001). The absurdity
An intrinsic bias
of the definition of sickness is evident in the data reported by the BIFR
among the at the end of 2002: for 4,318 registered cases, cumulative net worth
was Rs. 468 billion and the accumulated losses were almost twice the
management and net worth at Rs. 891 billion. H ence, although the BIFR has the author-
ity to propose a wide range of remedial reorganisation plans, the SIC
creditors to file for Act’s sickness definition and its corresponding selectivity bias towards
the worst possible cases explain the high proportion of liquidation
restructuring rather recommendations made by the BIFR (of 1,711 active cases at end of
2002, 63 per cent were recommended for liquidation, 22 per cent were
than outright reorganised successfully, 5 15 per cent were still under rehabilitation 6 ).
If we think of the Companies Act as analogous to Chapter 7
liquidation might be and the SIC Act to Chapter 11, then the numbers in Table 3 imply that
an overwhelming number of firms chose to file for restructuring even if
due to the social
it may not have been a viable option, since a majority of these cases
pressure to preserve ended up being recommended for liquidation eventually. Thus volun-
tary liquidation (Chapter 7) is a rare occurrence in the Indian land-
jobs, which tends to scape. H ence, the system has created an interesting mismatch whereby
the right policy prescriptions are available to the wrong candidates and
be driven by the vice versa, causing widespread scepticism and disappointment on the
part of all involved. An intrinsic bias among the management and
elevated status of creditors to file for restructuring rather than outright liquidation might
be due to the social pressure to preserve jobs, which tends to be driven
the local businesses by the elevated status of the local businesses as social benefactors
within their communities.
as social
O ther barriers to restructuring include the land and labour
benefactors. regulations mentioned above which make it much harder to consoli-
date, merge and redeploy labour and physical assets. For example, “ a
sick firm like the N ational Textile Corporation sits on land potentially
worth hundreds of crores, 7 but it is an encumbered asset since state
governments would not give permission to sell that land” (Kapur and
Ramamurti, 2002).
was implemented.
6 Reorganisation plan has been implemented but net worth is still negative
44 7 1 crore = 10 million.
ICRA BULLETIN
TABLE 3
Annual Outcomes via Legislative Process
Mon ey
Com panies A ct, 1956 SIC A ct data from BIFR w ebsite &
Voluntary L iquidations R eorganisation L iquidation D ism issed i Fin a n ce
L iquidations under Court R ecom m ended R ecom m ended
O rder OCT. 0 3 M A R . 0 4
1996 13 39 29 85 25
1997 14 42 13 85 22
1988 19 81 13 50 36
1999 35 102 13 65 70
2000 34 52 10 153 158 For sick companies,
i Cases where management had a false case (i.e. accounting manipula-
tion, etc.). since liquidation
Source: Department of Company Affairs A nnual R eport, 2001.
will wipe out equity,
The 2002 Securitisation Bill (a descendant of the Financial the debtor-in-
Recovery due to Banks and Financial Institutions Act) has further comp-
licated the process, by allowing banks and financial institutions to seize possession and
assets if a borrower defaults on a repayment and fails to respond within
60 days of a notice issued by the creditors. A Supreme Court ruling automatic stay
establishes that when statutes conflict with each other, such as the 2002
Securitisation Bill and the 1985 SIC Act, the more recent statute
further create
overrides the older one.8 This would imply that secured creditors could
incentives for the
seize assets of sick companies, violating the automatic stay provided by
the 1985 SIC Act. The 2002 Securitisation Bill is still being challenged promoters to delay
in courts, 9 but there have been numerous cases of a mad rush among
creditors to take control of the assets although an interim injunction the process and
prevents them from disposing of the assets. This represents an appalling
example of the system’s bias towards sub-optimal outcomes. siphon off value in
8 View taken by the Supr eme Court in A llahabad Bank v. Canara Bank .
Interview with Gunjan Shah, Lawyer, Amarchand M angaldas, a N ew Delhi law firm.
9 In M ardiya Chem icals v. ICICI and others. Interview with Ashish Rana,
A sia Pulse, January 20, 2003, available on Lexis N exis Academic, http://www.lexis-
nexis.com.
14 “ Companies (Amendment) Bill 2001,” US India Business Council
Information Sheet. 47
ICRA BULLETIN guidelines will limit the restructuring or liquidation process to
about two years. The Tribunal would institute monitoring
Mon ey
mechanisms throughout the restructuring process to prevent
& management from engaging in rent-seeking behaviour.
Fin a n ce • Introduction of a Rehabilitation and Revival Fund: A tax will
be levied on revenues of all Indian companies to build a Fund
OCT. 0 3 M A R .. 0 4
that will compensate displaced workers of sick companies. This
fund would enable the Tribunal to restructure or liquidate
distressed companies without penalising labour.
Redefining “Sickness”
The definition of
The definition of “ Sickness” in the 1985 SIC Act had been
“ Sickness” in the considered restrictive by the Eradi Committee, in that by the time a
company had accumulated losses equal to or exceeding its entire net
1985 SIC Act had worth, chances of recovery were remote. The requirement that firms
must be registered for at least five years further limited the scope of
been considered companies covered by the Act. Given that the 1985 SIC Act was the
only means by which a firm could restructure under the aegis of the
restrictive by the courts, such a restrictive definition ensured few companies would
actually be restructured. The 2002 Act redefines a “ Sick Company” as
Eradi Committee, in one:
that by the time a (a) which has accumulated losses in any financial year equal to 50
per cent or more of its average net worth during four years
company had immediately preceding the financial year in question, or
(b) which has failed to repay its debts within any three consecutive
accumulated losses quarters on demand for repayment by its creditors (Gupta, 2001).
equal to or The 2002 Act also lifts the five-year registration restriction on
industrial companies (Rana, 2003).
exceeding its entire
Establishment of a National Company Law Tribunal
net worth, chances The 2002 Act establishes the N ational Company Law Tribunal
(the Tribunal) to consolidate the powers and jurisdictions of the Com-
of recovery were pany Law Board (CLB), the BIFR, and various offices of the H igh
Courts that deal with affairs surrounding company insolvency. The
remote.
BIFR and the CLB now cease to exist. “ The multiplicity of litigations
before various bodies for revival or rehabilitation or merger or amal-
gamation or winding up of companies will be avoided and the Tribunal
will hear and decide these matters” (Rana, 2003). The Tribunal, like its
predecessor bodies, adjudicates on plans offered by creditors and
management, or proposes a plan itself (unlike Chapter 11 of the US
Bankruptcy Code, where creditors and management negotiate and vote
on an appropriate plan that is sanctioned by the Court). The Tribunal is
headquartered in N ew Delhi and has 10 branches throughout the
country in the H igh Court offices. Appeals against the Tribunal are
heard by the Appellate Tribunal, and appeals contesting the Appellate
48 Tribunal judgements will be heard in the Supreme Court.
The 2002 Act recommends that the Tribunal “ should be headed ICRA BULLETIN
bankruptcy regime, for example, between the H igh Courts and tribu-
Mon ey
nals such as the BIFR and the CLB, or between the 1956 Act and the
1985 Act, has been a source of considerable delay. The 2002 Act &
eliminates this dualism by transferring all cases managed by the Fin a n ce
Courts, the BIFR, and the CLB to the Tribunal. O ne benefit of removing
OCT. 0 3 M A R . 0 4
this dualism is that once the Tribunal decides a company must be
liquidated, it need not refer the case to the H igh Court as the BIFR once
did. H owever, this streamlining could itself cause additional delays.
For example, although the Tribunal has 10 branches throughout the
country, there is only one Appellate Tribunal in N ew Delhi, in contrast
When it comes to
to the 10 Appellate Courts, each of which would handle appeals
relating to decisions made by the corresponding H igh Court (Datar, executing a
2001). The two judiciaries were often located in the some building. It
remains to be seen whether the Appellate Tribunal will be clogged with restructuring plan,
appeals relating to decisions made by the 10 Tribunals.
however, the
Will the Right Companies be Restructured and Liquidated?
An efficient bankruptcy system ensures that companies whose Tribunal may face
going-concern value is less than liquidation value are liquidated, while
those whose going-concern value is greater than liquidation value are the same source of
restructured. Under the bankruptcy system embodied in the 1956 and
1985 Acts, there existed some companies that should have been restruc-
delay as faced by
tured or liquidated, but would be permitted to continue as going
the BIFR, viz., the
concerns. A common example would be state-owned enterprises, which
would simply receive additional funding from the government, without 1947 Industrial
being restructured or liquidated when necessary.
Table 5, a variation of Gilson’s schematic framework for Disputes Act.
comparing alternative bankruptcy systems (Figure 10.1, Gilson, 1994),
illustrates potential outcomes of the previous bankruptcy system, given
that a firm should be restructured or liquidated. Each box lists possible
reasons why these sub-optimal outcomes might occur. Sub-optimal
outcomes (e.g., firm that should be restructured is allowed to continue
as a going concern because it does not meet the definition of “ sickness”
outlined by the BIFR) are shaded in grey. By tackling specific root
causes relating to sub-optimal outcomes, such as the government’s
inability to retrench workers, exemption of state enterprises, etc., the
2002 Act can limit the type of sub-optimal outcomes that might occur.
The 2002 Act has attempted to remedy the underlying issues
behind these sub-optimal outcomes. For example, “ sickness” has been
redefined to include non-payment of debt as a contributing factor,
thereby enabling creditors to force companies to restructure. Broader
powers have been conferred upon the O fficial Liquidator to accelerate
the liquidation process. The dualism inherent in the system as a result
of two legislations addressing the issue of corporate bankruptcy has
been removed; now one Act and one agency will handle all aspects of
the corporate bankruptcy process. A set restructuring timeframe has 53
ICRA BULLETIN been introduced to reduce the time taken to 12–14 months for the
agency to decide on either a restructuring plan or a liquidation plan.
Mon ey
Creditors are now able to petition the Tribunal to initiate restructuring
& proceedings and submit plans while previously they could only restruc-
Fin a n ce ture out of court or force liquidation. M anagement fraud is addressed
by appointing Directors, auditors, and O As to oversee the restructuring
OCT. 0 3 M A R .. 0 4
process.
TABLE 5
An analysis of which sub-optimal outcomes might occur under the previous
bankruptcy system. Each of the shaded boxes represents a sub-optimal outcome
The dualism
w hat should happen to the firm
inherent in the firm should be liquidated firm should be restructured
w h at firm • government unwilling to • definition of sick is too
system as a result of continues retrench workers narrow
as going • O fficial Liquidator powerless • government unwilling to
two legislations concern • conflicting labour or land retrench workers
• State enterprises exempt • conflicting labour and land
addressing the issue • State enterprises exempt
• Creditors unable to initiate
restructuring proceedings
of corporate
does restructure • government unwilling to • takes too long
retrench workers
bankruptcy has been • wrong agency handles case
• management fraud under
removed; now one BIFR umbrella
happen liquidate • takes too long • wrong agency handles case
Act and one agency • restructuring plan poorly
executed—firm
will handle all subsequently liquidated
aspects of the
The Central Government, with the introduction of the RRF,
corporate also hopes to mitigate the apprehension that restructuring and liquida-
tion are against “ public interest” because workers will be worse off.
bankruptcy process. The RRF enables the Tribunal to focus solely on maximisation of
distressed assets, as the fund will compensate displaced workers and
ensure that the restructuring process does not go against public interest.
Critics worry, however, that the funds in the RRF may be appropriated
for other purposes, or that the Tribunal would have trouble accessing
proceeds of the RRF (Rana, 2003). Because the tax is levied on com-
pany turnover, not profit, even firms that are incurring losses will have
to contribute to the RRF (Rana, 2003). Critics also assert that wages
offered to displaced workers “ should not be used as a dole for the
displaced employees but should be used to retrain them so that they are
able to face up to the challenges of a competitive environment” .20
bankruptcy system, despite the positive strides taken through the 2002
Mon ey
Act. For example, the Tribunal cannot recommend a state industrial
enterprise be restructured or liquidated without the consent of the &
relevant state government. The RRF, however, may encourage lay-off- Fin a n ce
conscious state governments to reform their industrial enterprises,
OCT. 0 3 M A R . 0 4
whose losses are contributing towards an ever-increasing proportion of
their budget deficits. India’s consolidated budget deficit, including
central and state governments and state-owned businesses, is 11 per
cent of GDP21 . O ne piece of legislation, the 2002 Securitisation Bill (if
it eventually makes it through the Courts), could enhance the rights of
External forces will
secured creditors to seize the assets against non-performing loans,
especially if fraud is involved on the part of the borrower.22 Because the still influence the
2002 Companies Act was instituted after the approval of the 2002
Securitisation Bill, the Tribunal will be able to override provisions of effectiveness of
the Securitisation Bill whenever it believes the Bill is acting against the
interests of creditors as a whole. It is possible that this Bill, in conjunc- India’s bankruptcy
tion with the new definition of “ sickness” , will spur more voluntary
out-of-court settlements or referrals to the Tribunal. The recent amend- system, despite the
ment to the 1947 Industrial Disputes Act is also a positive sign.
A more fundamental issue regarding whether the right compa- 2002 Act. For
nies will be restructured or liquidated is whether a system of “ restruc-
turing by tribunal,” embodied by the 1956 Act, the 1985 Act, and the
example, the
2002 Act, is superior to a system of negotiated settlements by creditors
Tribunal cannot
and management, akin to Chapter 11 in US corporate bankruptcy law.
The BIFR, according to one author, “ prolongs the inevitable liquidation recommend a state
of the company. If there is scope for rehabilitation, banks and financial
institutions are competent enough to assess the possibility” (Datar, industrial enterprise
2001). This author envisages that “ a substantial part of the Tribunal’s
time and energy is going to be wasted on rehabilitation schemes which be restructured or
will seldom be implemented” (Datar, 2001). In its analysis of bank-
ruptcy laws in 2001, the Reserve Bank of India (RBI), India’s central liquidated without
bank, urged the Central Government to scrap the command-approach
to resolving bankruptcies: the consent of the
The Advisory Group is of the opinion that the formalistic design or relevant state
facility created for parties to restructure and renegotiate must have a
veil of juristic neutrality, that is, absence of any privilege or favour to government.
any of the parties. The formalistic procedure of restructuring, as for
example, Chapter 11 restructuring of the US Code, is a simple
creation of neutral environment for the parties to renegotiate. It is
Financial Ex press, N ovember 7, 2002, available from Lexis N exis Academic, http://
www.lexis-nexis.com. 55
ICRA BULLETIN only an additional opportunity for voluntary re-negotiation for
reorganisation of the borrower institution. Any effort for restructur-
Mon ey
ing must be based on a voluntary effort of all creditors, secured and
& unsecured, the members of the company, its promoters and manage-
Fin a n ce ment. There is no place for any command. In case the parties want,
the Trustee can provide expert’s advice either from in-house or from
OCT. 0 3 M A R .. 0 4
external expert agencies, hiring the services of such agencies. 23
is paramount, the Will Managers and Stockholders Still Game the System?
The 2002 Act institutes a number of provisions designed to
government may address concerns that under Indian bankruptcy laws, “ bankrupt compa-
nies rot in government-sponsored rehabilitation, their assets tied up,
simply not trust their creditors unpaid but their promoters often richer by raiding
retirement funds and pocketing primary and secondary investors’
creditors and money” . 24 The Act removes the automatic stay against creditors except
when explicitly sanctioned by the Tribunal. There are stringent controls
managers to on management with the appointment of a Director representing the
Tribunal to sit on the company’s Board of Directors and with the
formulate an
appointment of O perating Agencies and the enhanced powers of the
outcome in “ public O fficial Liquidator. A team of auditors verifies the accounts of the
company when it applies to the Tribunal, to ensure management is not
interest” . manipulating its financial statements for the sole purpose of seeking
protection against creditors. A defined timeframe will limit opportuni-
ties for management to engage in perverse behaviour.
It is interesting to note that two hallmarks of Chapter 11 in the
US, the automatic stay and control of assets by the management team
during the restructuring process, have both been curbed in the 2002
Act. Similar provisions of the Indian bankruptcy system led to rent-
seeking behaviour on behalf of both management and public officials.
This misbehaviour may not have been solely a result of the automatic
stay or debtor control of assets, but it may reflect structural flaws in the
25 Ahluwalia, 2002. 57
ICRA BULLETIN References
Ahluwalia, M ontek Singh, 2002, “ Financial Sector Reform: An Assessment,”
Mon ey presented at the Conference on Financial R eform A cross A sia, Center for
Business and Government, H arvard Business School, December 10-11.
& Ahluwalia, M ontek S., 2002, “ Economic Reforms in India Since 1991: H as Gradual-
ism Worked?” Journal of Econom ic Perspectives, 16:3 Summer 2002, p.
Fin a n ce 86-87.
OCT. 0 3 M A R .. 0 4 Board for Financial and Industrial Reconstruction published statistics, available
from BIFR, http://bifr.nic.in/geninfo.htm.
Business Line, 2000, “ Eradi panel proposals on insolvency law—Core Group to
examine changes in Companies Act,” Business L ine Internet Edition,
September 3, 2000, available on http://www.blonnet.com/businessline/.
Companies (Amendment) Bill 2001, US India Business Council Information Sheet,
December 6, 2001, available on http://www.usibc.com.
Datar, Arvind P., 2001, “ India: Energize the Courts,” Business L ine, September 27,
2001, available from Lexis N exis Academic, http://www.lexis-nexis.com.
Department of Company Affairs Annual Report, 2001, available from Department
of Company Affairs, http://dca.nic.in/report/ar2k12k2/main.htm.
Federation of Andhra Pradesh Chambers of Commerce and Industry (FAPCCI)
Review, September 17, 2002.
Gilson, Stuart, 1994, “ M ethodological Issues in Cross Country Comparisons of
Commercial Bankruptcy Law: Comment on Papers by Eisenberg-Tagashira
and Rajak,” Current D evelopm ents in International and Com parative
Corporate Insolvency L aw , Jacob S. Z iegel, Chapter 10, O xford:
Clarendon Press.
Goswami, O mkar, 1996, Corporate Bank ruptcy in India, A com parative perspective,
O ECD, Paris.
Gupta, S. M ., 2001, “ Salient Features of the Companies (Amendment) Bill, 2001,”
Com pany L aw Info, available on http://www.companylawinfo.com.
Justice V.B. Eradi Committee Report on Law Relating to Insolvency of Companies,
July 2000, available from D epartm ent of Com pany A ffairs, http://
www.dca.nic.in/comp/insolv-comp.html.
Kapur, D. and R. Ramamurti, 2002, “ Privatization in India: The Imperatives and
Consequences of Gradualism,” W ork ing Paper N o. 142, Stanford Center
for International Development, July 2002.
M itra, N . L., 2001, “ Report of The Advisory Group on Bankruptcy Laws,” M ay 9,
2001, available from the Reserve Bank of India, http://www.rbi.org.in/
sec21/20811.pdf.
Rana, Ashish, 2003, “ The Companies (Amendment) Bill 2001,” L egal Service India,
January 11, 2003, available on http://legalserviceindia.com,
The Companies (Second Amendment) Act, 2002, Government of India, M inistry of
Law and Justice, January 14, 2003, p. 18, available from the Government
of India Department of Company Affairs, http://www.dci.nic.in.
Wadia, N .N ., “ Unshackling the Indian Industry,” April 2000, available from Prime
M inister’s Council on Trade and Industry, http://www.nic.in/pmcouncils/
reports/unshack/.
58