Velde
Velde
Velde
net/publication/5040934
CITATIONS READS
7 9,731
1 author:
Francois Velde
74 PUBLICATIONS 1,114 CITATIONS
SEE PROFILE
Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:
All content following this page was uploaded by Francois Velde on 17 February 2016.
François R. Velde
2 Economic Perspectives
tendency to become partly fiduciary; The commodity money system delivers a
the peculiar difficulty of enforcing nominal anchor for the price level. The mecha-
contracts involving promises to pay nism by which this takes place can be described
that serve as medium of exchange in the context of a profit-maximizing mint, which
and of preventing fraud in respect to was how coins were produced in the Middle
them; the technical monopoly character Ages and later.2 Suppose there is a way to convert
of a pure fiduciary currency which goods into silver and silver into goods at a con-
makes essential the setting of some stant cost (in ounces of silver per unit of goods),
external limit on its amount; and finally, which can be thought of as either the extraction
the pervasive character of money which cost of silver and the industrial uses of the metal
means that the issuance of money has or the “world price” of silver in a small country
important effect on parties other than interpretation. Silver is turned into coins by the
those directly involved and gives spe- mint; the mint (which really represents the pri-
cial importance to the preceding fea- vate sector) also decides when to melt down
tures. ... The central tasks for govern- existing coins.
ment are also clear: to set an external The government’s role is limited to two
limit to the amount of money and to pre- actions. It specifies how much silver goes into
vent counterfeiting, broadly conceived. a coin, and it collects a seigniorage tax3 on all
new minting.
This article will find much to validate this When the mint is minting new coins, its costs
view. It turns out that the problem of counter- are the cost of the silver content, the seigniorage
feiting, identified as central by Friedman, pro- tax, and the production cost;4 its revenues are the
vided obstacles that were overcome only when market value of the coins, which is the inverse of
the appropriate technology became available. the price level. Similarly, when the mint is melt-
As technology changed and offered the possibility ing down coins, its costs are the market value of
of implementing a form of fiduciary currency, the coins, and its revenues are the value of the silver
various incomplete forms of currency systems contained in them.
were tried, with significant effects on the price Whether the mint will produce new coins
level. These experiments led to the recognition or melt down existing coins will thus depend
that quantity limitation was crucial to maintaining on how the price level relates to the parameters:
the value of the currency. The need for a govern- silver content of the coins, production costs, and
ment monopoly, however, does not emerge from seigniorage rate. The price level cannot be too
our reading of the historical record, and we will low (or the purchasing power of the coins too
see that the private sector also came up with its high) or the mint could make unbounded profits
own solutions to the problem of small change, by minting new coins and spending them. Simi-
thereby presenting alternatives to the monetary larly, the price level cannot be too high (or the
arrangements we have adopted. 1 purchasing power of the coins too low), or the
mint would make profits by melting down the
Commodity money and price stability coins. The absence of arbitrage for the mint places
Among the desirable features of a monetary restrictions on the price level, which is contained
system, price stability has long been a priority, as in an interval determined by the minting point
far back as Aristotle’s discussion of money in Ethics. and the melting point (figure 1).
In the words of the seventeenth century Italian This system, which prevailed until the late
monetary theorist Gasparo Antonio Tesauro (1609), nineteenth century, has some noteworthy fea-
money must be “the measure of all things” (rerum tures. The quantity of money is not controlled
omnium mensura) (p. 633). Aristotle also noted that directly by the government; rather, additions to
commodity money, specifically money made of or subtractions from the money stock are made
precious metals, was well suited to reach that goal: by the private sector, on the basis of incentives
“Money, it is true, is liable to the same fluctuation given by the price level. The incentives operate
of demand as other commodities, for its purchas- so as to make the system self-regulating. If coins
ing power varies at different times; but it tends become too scarce, their value increases and the
to be comparatively constant” (Aristotle, Ethics, price level falls until it reaches the minting point,
1943 translation). when more coins are added to the stock. If coins
4 Economic Perspectives
consisted of silver and bronze coins, which were of counterfeiting.10 While nowadays counterfeiting
token. The government’s willingness to peg, say, may seem to be a significant but not overwhelm-
the silver quarter at 1/40 of a gold eagle was ing nuisance, which suitable technology can
implemented by the U.S. Treasury.8 always remedy (such as that embodied in the
Thus, in the standard formula, tokens play recently issued $100 and $50 bills), in the past it
the same role as convertible notes issued by the presented an insuperable obstacle to the develop-
central bank. As with notes, a mechanism serves ment of the standard formula.
to regulate the quantity outstanding: Excess quan- One way to prevent counterfeiting is to impose
tities of token quarters are turned in at the treasury high costs of entry to counterfeiters. Law enforce-
in exchange for gold eagles, while needed tokens ment provides a second method; as the Italian
are sold by the mint.9 economist Montanari wrote in 1683, “A die which
The advantages of a token coinage are the costs the prince 3 to make, will cost a counterfeiter
same as the advantages of a representative money 8 or 12; because he who works at the mint does
system, as pointed out by a long line of writers, not risk his life, and receives only the wage com-
including Adam Smith, John M. Keynes, and mensurate to his activity; but if a goldsmith has
Milton Friedman. Resources that had been spent to make a coin at the risk of his whole being, he
forming and maintaining that part of the stock of will not be persuaded if not with a lot of gold.”
metallic currency were freed up for other purposes. The death penalty11 for counterfeiters adds a risk
To quote the French monetary official Henri premium to the counterfeiters’ wage costs, which
Poullain, writing in 1612: “In a card game, where may or may not be sufficient to wipe out their
various individuals play, one avails oneself of potential profits. A third method is to make the
tokens, to which a certain value is assigned, and government currency difficult to imitate, for ex-
they are used by the winners to receive, and by ample, if it is produced with a technology that is
the losers to pay what they owe. Whether instead not accessible to the private sector in some way;
of coins one were to use dried beans and give either the government can make better coins or
them the same value, the game would be no less the same coins more cheaply.
enjoyable or perfect” (Poullain, 1709, p. 68). If such a cost or technology advantage is not
Another advantage, from the point of view available to the government, then attempts at
of the government, is that the issue of tokens is issuing token coinage will be plagued by coun-
quite profitable. To the extent that tokens circulate terfeiting or competition from neighboring curren-
for more than their intrinsic value plus the costs cies. Ultimately, the gross seigniorage rate will
of minting, they represent a pure profit, the be driven down to the production costs (common
seigniorage in the medieval and modern sense to both government and counterfeiters). Thus,
of the word. without the appropriate technology, only full-
These two advantages (social savings and bodied coins can be used for small denominations.
government revenues) have been understood
for centuries, and, as Friedman points out, have The big problem of small change
provided impetus for the development of money This seemingly trifling aspect of the monetary
away from a strict, full-bodied commodity version. system turns out to have bedeviled Western soci-
However, these two motivations do not determine eties for centuries. Nowadays, the only problem
clearly in which direction money will develop; most people see with small change is that we
perhaps, in fact, each pushes in a different direc- have too many pennies around, but for students
tion. The tension will be illustrated in the historical of monetary history, the “big problem of small
process I describe. change” (a phrase coined by Carlo Cipolla in 1956)
refers to recurrent coin shortages that were preva-
Prerequisites of a token coinage lent before the adoption of token coinage. The last
Whatever its advantages, the implementation time the U.S. experienced a shortage of small
of the standard formula depended on some pre- change was in 1965–66, when quarters and dimes
requisites. With a token coinage, the profits to the still contained silver; the Coinage Act of 1965
issuer are large, and, as Friedman says (1960, p. 6), made them completely token (Spengler, 1966).
“In fraud as in other activities, opportunities for
profit are not likely to go unexploited.” The gov- Full-bodied small change
ernment’s ability to maintain its monopoly on The medieval technology for making coins
token issue is thus dependent on the prevention was very simple. Metal was melted and beaten
6 Economic Perspectives
denomination, but not fast enough. Figure 3 plots the total money stock M = M1+ eM2 (where M is
the production costs as a function of coin size for the total stock in dollars, M1 is the number of
various European countries. dollar coins, e is the market exchange rate, and
This technological constraint presented the M2 is the number of pennies). As long as there
mints with a dilemma: provide only full-bodied are enough pennies to carry out small transac-
coins and see pennies never minted, or offer the tions (not just in the physical sense M2 but in
same price for bullion in pennies or in dollars and terms of their total value eM2), there can be more
face the risk of seeing the price level increase and or fewer pennies or they can be worth more or
large coins disappear. Thus, the commodity less. If, for some reason, the relative share of
money system with full-bodied denominations small transactions changes and more pennies
has the potential for either shortages or gluts of are needed, more pennies will be provided only
small change. if the minting points are lined up correctly and
In fact, shortages of small change were a the price level falls enough. But for the general
common complaint, running through centuries price level to fall, the shock must affect the volume
of monetary history all over Europe and also of all transactions, and it is not hard to imagine
(in the early nineteenth century) in the U.S. The situations where the existing stock of pennies is
above argument, although limited to the supply insufficient, yet no new pennies are minted.
side, shows how vulnerable the commodity These shortages of small change have a curi-
money system was to such shortages, given the ous feature: In a decentralized economy, agents
technology available. An analysis of the demand choose how many pennies to hold. In order for
side reveals even more trouble. them to hold too few pennies, there needs to be
If we think of pennies and dollars as required a price incentive for them to economize on pen-
for consumption purchases (a feature called a nies. This occurs through a rate of return domi-
cash-in-advance constraint), but we assume that nance, that is, the return on holding pennies is
large coins cannot be used in small transactions, lower than the return on holding dollars. In other
whereas small coins can be used in large trans- words, the market exchange rate, e (in dollars
actions, it emerges that, within the overlapping per pennies), falls. But this means that the share
intervals of figure 2, there is a certain indetermi- of pennies in the total stock of coins shrinks fur-
nacy of the exchange rate between dollars and ther, accentuating the shortage of small change.
pennies or the ratio at which pennies enter into Furthermore, a fall in the exchange rate shifts
the lower interval of figure 2 to the left,
making it likelier that the price level
FIGURE 3 will hit the upper bound of the interval
Production costs of coins in late medieval for pennies, the melting point.
Europe, 1350–1500 Thus, shortages of small change
costs/content (percent of face value)
push the economy in a vicious cycle,
50 by making the shortage even more
severe through a depreciation of the
smaller denominations, and ultimately
40
bringing about a melting down of
pennies, once they have depreciated
30 to the value of their intrinsic content.
Within the confines of the available
20 technology, one partial remedy is for
the government to counteract the left-
ward shift of the interval due to the fall
10
in e by reducing the intrinsic content of
pennies, which shifts the interval to the
0 right. Figure 4 plots the evolution of the
10 1 10 2 10 3 10 4 10 5
mg silver
mint equivalent (the inverse of the intrin-
Note: Production costs were calculated by the percent of the face value
sic content) for two medieval Florentine
of the coin as a function of the coin size in milligrams of silver. silver coins, the picciolo (a penny, or 1d)
Source: T. Sargent and F. Velde, 1997, The evolution of small change,
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, working paper, No. WP-97-13. and the grosso (worth 4d), during the
8 Economic Perspectives
With the appearance of larger denomination with leather money that he redeemed into gold
coins and the existence of time-varying rates of after the successful conclusion of the siege. D’Isernia
exchange between denominations, the legal argued that, under the specific circumstances al-
problems grew more challenging, and jurists ready identified by the current doctrine, money
began to diverge in their answers. A distinction could be made of worthless material, like lead or
was made between the “intrinsic quality” of a leather, as long as it was redeemed after the end
coin (its metal content) and the “extrinsic quality,” of the emergency into good money. This was the
taken to mean either its purchasing power (the basis for the concept of deficit financing, which
inverse of the price level) or its rate of exchange would play an important role in the development
with other coins. The general consensus prevail- of fiat money. By the late sixteenth century, these
ing in the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries called notions were commonly held. The widely cited
for adjusting debt repayments for variations in René Budel (1591) held it “to be indubitable that
the intrinsic quality, but ignoring variations in a Prince in the midst of costly wars, and therefore
extrinsic quality; and small coins were considered in great necessity, can order that money be made
legal tender to the degree that they were full-bodied out of leather, bark, salt, or any material he wants,
and interchangeable with large coins. if he is careful to repair the loss inflicted thereby
However, jurists also observed the existence on the community with good and better money”
of positive seigniorage rates (the width of the (Budel, 1591, chapter 1, paragraph 31).
interval in figure 1), and realized that money’s In other words, the intrinsic content could
purchasing power could be greater than its intrinsic be set to 0, as long as some measure of convert-
value. In other words, they discovered that the ibility, either immediate or in the near future,
price level could move above the minting point. was implied. In 1481, a small town in Catalonia
One strand of the legal literature insisted that carried out an experiment to solve its problem
seigniorage should be set close or equal to 0. of small change: it was authorized by the king
Others, who argued that precious metals as bullion of Aragon to issue pure copper coins, 14 whose
and in the form of coins should afford the same intrinsic value was about 25 percent of their face
utility, recommended that the state subsidize the value, as long as “the city be known to pledge,
mint completely (in particular, the jurist Bartolo and effectively pledge to receive said small money
da Sassoferrato, 1313–1357). As jurists, they tried from those who might hold it, and to convert it
to define rules for repayment of monetary debts. and return for it good money of gold or silver,
They correctly perceived that their proposal would whenever and however much they be asked”
eliminate some fluctuations in the standard of value. (in Botet y Sisó, 1911, p. 328). This experiment
In practice, the jurists realized that govern- was imitated by a number of other Catalonian
ments were unwilling to subsidize mints and cities, although they were plagued by counter-
were tempted to increase seigniorage revenues feiting, which the state of technology made rela-
as much as they could. A small tax was considered tively easy.
acceptable and a larger tax under very specific
circumstances, such as a fiscal emergency (paying Technological change and
for a sudden war or the king’s ransom). Some policy experiments
even argued that, in the words of Gabriel Biel These developments in monetary doctrine,
(d. 1495) a large seigniorage rate “is the easier and the early Catalonia experiment, show that
way to collect quickly the required funds with- technology remained the real barrier to the imple-
out fraud and undue exactions from the subjects. mentation of a standard formula for small change.
It is, moreover, felt less and for this reason more The technology did change, in two major waves;
easily borne without protest and without the and each wave opened up new possibilities that
danger of a rebellion on the part of the people. governments exploited.
It is the most general form of taxation embracing Recall that the standard formula incorporates
all classes, clergy, laity, nobility, plebeians, rich several ingredients: monopolization of coinage,
and poor alike” (Biel, 1930 translation, p. 35). issue of tokens, and convertibility of the tokens.
Some jurists like d’Isernia even went further. The ingredients are logically distinct. The period
D’Isernia probably observed episodes such as between the first and the second wave of techno-
the siege of Faenza in 1241, when the Emperor logical change (1550 to 1800) saw a wide variety
Frederic II ran out of money and paid his troops of experiments, in which some but not always
10 Economic Perspectives
FIGURE 5 the manipulations, which were less suc-
cessful as balances of vellón fell over time.
Nominal and real values of vellón, The Spanish experience unleashed
1595–1680
unprecedented “man-made” inflation,
million ducats
40 which made the Price Revolution of the
sixteenth century (price level increases
due to the inflow of American gold and
30 silver) look tame. It was among the first
large-scale experiments in inconvertible
Nominal value
fiat currency (although the coins were
20 accepted at face value in payment of taxes).
It demonstrated the ease with which
token coinage could overtake the money
10 stock, the workings of the quantity theory,
Real value the need for the issuer of inconvertible
(in silver equivalent) token coinage to restrain issues, and the
0 strength of the temptation created by high
1600 1620 1640 1660 1680
seigniorage rates for a government un-
Source: F. Velde and W. Weber, 1997, Fiat money inflation in 17th century
Castile, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, manuscript. willing or unable to raise other taxes.
The Spanish experiment was not the
only one at the time. During the Thirty
Years War, which started in 1618, many German
progressive displacement of M1 by vellón is con-
states concurrently debased their small denomi-
sistent with no change in e, and, other things
nations (all the while maintaining silver coinage
being equal, an unchanged money stock will
intact) and issued large amounts of copper coin-
correspond to a constant price level. However,
age to raise revenues through seigniorage. The
once M1 has disappeared, the money stock con-
results are shown in figure 6, which tracks the
sists only of copper coins M2, and all further
exchange rate between large denomination
increases in M2 result in increases in the price
coins and small denomination coins and makes
level, as is apparent in figure 5. Once the figure
it clear why the Germans called this die große
of about 20 million ducats was reached, nominal
Inflation (the great inflation), at least until a simi-
and real balances diverged, and inflation set in
lar experiment exactly 300 years later (the famous
with a vengeance. The disappearance of
silver released the price level from the
constraints imposed by the melting/mint- FIGURE 6
ing points for the dollar interval, and un-
Prices of the gold florin and silver thaler,
leashed the quantity theory with copper in Bavarian kreutzers
as the determinant of the price level.
index, 1608=1
The only way to return the price level 8
to its bounds was to engineer a reappear- Thaler
ance of the silver coins, either by decreasing Florin
M2 or by decreasing e. The Castilian gov- 6
ernment toyed with the idea of decreasing
M2 by an open-market operation (selling
bonds to buy back the copper coinage), 4
but in the end decided to halve e over-
night, in 1628.
The rest of the movements in vellón 2
balances are due to repetitions of the ear-
lier operations of vellón issue, restamp-
ing (multiplying the face value of existing 0
1610 1615 1620 1625
coins by N and extracting a seigniorage of
Source: H. Altmann, 1976, Die Kipper- und Wipperinflation in Bayern, München:
(N–1)/N) and overnight devaluations. As Neue Schriftenreihe des Stadtarchivs München, pp. 272273.
figure 5 shows, Castilians grew weary of
12 Economic Perspectives
insufficiently, until 1754. Although mechaniza- and the nineteenth century U.S. One of the ingre-
tion had been adopted in 1660, England remained dients of the standard formula is monopolization
committed to full-bodied copper coinage.17 of coinage; it is not clear, on theoretical or histori-
The laisser-faire regime (mid-sixteenth cen- cal grounds, that this ingredient is needed if the
tury to 1613, 1644 to 1672, and the late eighteenth other two (issue and convertibility of tokens) are
century) was characterized by the absence of present. Of the two advantages of the token coinage
government-issued small denominations and system, social savings and government revenues,
by the issue of tokens by private parties or local the latter clearly provides an impulse toward
governments. In the late sixteenth century, up to monopolization that the former does not.
3,000 London merchants issued tokens. In the
period from 1644 to 1672, over 12,700 different The steam engine and the gold standard
types of tokens have been catalogued, issued in The second major technological innovation
1,700 different English towns. From the 1740s following the mechanization of minting around
on, trade tokens took over when official coinage 1550 was the adaptation of the steam engine to
ceased. Some of these issues were authorized by minting. In 1787, Matthew Boulton, partner of
government. The city of Bristol sought and secured James Watt, produced trade tokens for the Angle-
permission to issue farthings in 1652, and went sey Copper Company. A few years later he was
through three different issues over the next 20 producing copper coins for private issuers across
years. The Bristol farthings, furthermore, were England and even in France. In Paris, the most
officially convertible into large denominations. popular token coins in 1790–92, issued by the firm
They are also known to have been counterfeited. of Monneron, were minted in Birmingham by
The government put an end to the laisser-faire Boulton’s steam presses. The British government
regime twice, in 1672 and by the Act of Suppression contracted with him to produce official copper
in 1817; each time, it did so immediately after coinage in 1797, then bought the technology, and
adopting a new technology. in 1817 eliminated its competitors by making
France’s experiences were somewhat parallel. private coins illegal. The new steam-driven
In the early seventeenth century, private monop- presses were used to mint the new silver coins,
olies were instituted for brief periods of time. which, under the Coinage Act of 1816, were for
France also had a brief experience with free to- the first time issued as partly fiduciary coins,
ken issue in 1790–92. The government had decided whose intrinsic value was significantly lower
in September 1790 to issue substantial amounts than their face value. It took a decade and a half
of large-denomination paper currency backed before an implicit agreement was reached between
by a land sales scheme. Soon, thousands of private the Bank of England and the Treasury for the
and municipal banks emerged to intermediate convertibility of the silver coinage into gold
the government’s notes with their own small upon demand. By 1830, the standard formula
denomination notes and, in some cases, coins. had been fully implemented.
Initially, the government abstained from regulat- England’s implementation of the standard
ing the industry, which operated on fractional formula in 1816 applied both to bronze or copper
or 100 percent reserves, depending on the insti- coinage and to silver coins, leaving gold as the
tution. But soon the government moved to elim- single anchor for the price level (the gold stan-
inate its competitors in the business of issuing dard) and officially abandoning bimetallism.
currency. The government decided to issue It took other countries some time to follow suit:
medium-sized notes (equivalent to silver coins) Germany in 1871, France and the Latin Monetary
in June 1791, followed in December 1791 by small- Union (Belgium, Switzerland, Spain, and Italy)
denomination notes. Technical difficulties post- in 1873, the Netherlands in 1875, and the U.S.
poned the first issue of small notes to August 1792. in 1873–79 (the so-called Crime of 1873). Recently,
The government could now impose a monopoly. researchers (Friedman 1990 and Flandreau
Within a few weeks, all private banks were for- 1997) have argued that this abandonment was
bidden to issue their notes and private coins a mistake, and bimetallism was better suited to
were outlawed, amid unproven allegations of stabilizing the price level than the gold standard.
wildcatting and fraud. Nevertheless, there was no substantial differ-
These episodes present parallels with the ence between applying the standard formula to sil-
Free Banking Eras of eighteenth century Scotland ver and applying it to copper coinage, and the
14 Economic Perspectives
NOTES
1
Much of the material presented here derives from the work in 10
Note that the ability to maintain a monopoly on full-bodied
Sargent and Velde (1997a, 1997b). coinage is dependent on the same.
2
The model sketched here is developed fully in Sargent and 11
The punishment for counterfeiters was particularly severe. In
Velde (1997a). medieval France, they were boiled alive (not poached). A doc-
ument from 1311 details the costs of executing two counterfeit-
3
Seigniorage is literally the lord’s right to collect a tax, and is ers, including the price of a large cauldron and the cost of
derived from the French term for lord,seigneur. adding iron bars to the cauldron, a detail that suggests a rather
long process (Saulcy, 1879–92, Vol. 1, p. 180).
4
This cost is exclusive of the coin’s content. It represents the
costs of transforming metal into coins, and is to some degree in- 12
An anthology of their writings is in Velde (1997).
dependent of the content.
13
This did not preclude the denomination of many prices in
5
The equation is pY = vM, where p is the price level,Y is in- terms of the gold coin and fictitious subdivisions thereof.
come or the volume of transactions, v is velocity, and M is the
quantity of money. 14
Interestingly, the coins were modeled on a currency issued
some years earlier as emergency money during a siege and lat-
6
The optimal denomination structure is an unstudied problem; er left in circulation.
however, see Telser (1995).
15
A mixture of silver, to give value, and copper, to give bulk,
7
In the numismatic sense, token means something that is not of- commonly used for small denominations.
ficially money, but used as money; numismatists will speak of
full-bodied tokens. From an economic viewpoint, the distinc- 16
Another famous proponent of similar arguments was the Scot
tion between official and unofficial money is somewhat arbi- John Law (1671–1729), whose experiment in setting up a paper
trary. currency in France went spectacularly awry in 1720, during the
Mississippi Bubble.
8
Act of June 9, 1879: “Be it enacted ... that the holder of any of
the silver coins of the United States of smaller denominations 17
The proclamation of 1672 stated that small coins “cannot well
than one dollar, may, on presentation of the same in sums of be done in silver, nor safely in any other metal, unless the in-
$20, or any multiple thereof, at the office of the Treasurer or any trinsic value of the coin be equal, or near to that value for
assistant treasurer of the United States, receive therefor lawful which it is made current.” Sir Isaac Newton, master of the mint,
money of the United States” (Statutes at Large 21 [1879]: 7). wrote in 1720: “Halfpence and farthings (like other money)
should be made of a metal whose price among Merchants is
9
The status of silver dollars remained uncertain between the known, and should be coined as near as can be to that price, in-
Bland–Allison Act of 1878 and the final defeat of the pro-sil- cluding the charge of coinage. ... All which reasons incline us
ver forces after 1896. Only after 1900 did the silver dollar be- to prefer a coinage of good copper according to the intrinsic
come no different in nature from other subsidiary coins. value of the metal” (Shaw, 1896, pp. 164–165).
REFERENCES
Altmann, Hans Christian, 1976, Die Kipper- und Cipolla, Carlo M., 1956, Money, Prices and Civili-
Wipperinflation in Bayern, München: Neue zation in the Mediterranean World, Fifth to Seven-
Schriftenreihe des Stadtarchivs München. teenth Century, New York: Gordian Press.
Aristotle, 1943, Ethics, H. Racham (trans.), Cam- D’Isernia, Andrea, 1541, Commentaria in Usus Li-
bridge, MA: Harvard University Press. brum Feudorum, Lyon, France: J. Giunta.
Biel, Gabriel, 1935, Treatise on the Power and Utili- Flandreau, Marc, 1997, “The gradient of a river:
ty of Money, Robert B. Burke (trans.), Philadel- Bimetallism as an implicit fluctuation band,”
phia, PA: University of Philadelphia Press. Paris: l’Observatoire Français des Conjonctures
Economiques, manuscript.
Botet y Sisó, Joaquim, 1911, Les Monedes Catalans,
Vol. 2, Barcelona: Institut d’Estudis Catalans. Friedman, Milton, 1990, “The crime of 1873,”
Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 98, December,
Budel, René, 1591, De Monetis et Re Numaria, pp. 1159-1194.
Book 1, Cologne: Schann Nackel.
Mariana, Juan de, 1994, De Monetae Mutatione, Jo- Spengler, Joseph J., 1966, “Coin shortage: Mod-
sef Falzberger (ed.), Heidelberg: Manutius Verlag. ern and premodern,” National Banking Review,
Vol. 3, pp. 201–216.
Mill, John Stuart, 1857, Principles of Political Econ-
omy, Fourth Edition, London: John W. Parker Stampe, Ernst, 1928, “Das Zahlkraftrecht der
and Son. Postglossatorenzeit,”Abhandlungen der Preußis-
chen Akademie der Wissenschaften, philosophisch-
Montanari, Geminiano, 1804, “Della moneta: historische, Klasse 1, Berlin: Verlag der
Trattato mercantile,” in Scrittori Classici Italiani di Akademie.
Economia Politica, parte antica, Vol. 3, Milan:
G.G. Destefanis. Telser, Lester G., 1995, “Optimal denominations
for coins and currency,” Economic Letters, Vol. 49,
Poullain, Henri, 1709, Traité des Monnoies, Paris: pp. 425–427.
Frédéric Léonard.
Tesauro, 1609, “Tractatus de monetarum augmen-
Rivero, Casto Maria del, 1919, El Ingenio de la to et variatione,” in De Monetarum Augmento Vari-
Moneda, Revista de Archivos, Bibliotecas y Mu- atione et Diminutione Tractatus Varii, Turin, Italy.
seos, Vol. 40.
Velde, François R., 1997, “An anthology of writ-
Sargent, Thomas J., and François R. Velde, ings on money, 12th–17th century,” Federal Reserve
1997a, “The big problem of small change,” Fed- Bank of Chicago, manuscript.
eral Reserve Bank of Chicago, working paper,
No. WP-97-8. Velde, François R., and Warren E. Weber, 1997,
“Fiat money inflation in 17th century Castile,”
, 1997b, “The evolution of small Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, manuscript.
change,” Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
working paper, No. WP-97-13.
16 Economic Perspectives