Tdrbpconf9l1 en
Tdrbpconf9l1 en
Tdrbpconf9l1 en
1
United Nations Conference Distr.: Limited
on Trade and Development 18 September 2020
Original: English
GE.20-12115(E)
TD/RBP/CONF.9/L.1
A. Introduction
1. Chapter III of the UNCTAD Model Law on Competition recommends the prohibition
of restrictive agreements or arrangements. The articles were drafted based on section D,
paragraph 3, of the United Nations Set of Multilaterally Agreed Equitable Principles and
Rules for the Control of Restrictive Business Practices, as follows:
Enterprises, except when dealing with each other in the context of an economic
entity wherein they are under common control, including through ownership, or
otherwise not able to act independently of each other, engaged on the market in rival
or potentially rival activities, should refrain from practices such as the following
when, through formal, informal, written or unwritten agreements or arrangements,
they limit access to markets or otherwise unduly restrain competition, having or being
likely to have adverse effects on international trade, particularly that of developing
countries, and on the economic development of these countries:
(a) Agreements fixing prices, including as to exports and imports;
(b) Collusive tendering;
(c) Market or customer allocation arrangements;
(d) Allocation by quota as to sales and production;
(e) Collective action to enforce arrangements, e.g. by concerted refusals to
deal;
(f) Concerted refusal of supplies to potential importers;
(g) Collective denial of access to an arrangement, or association, which is
crucial to competition.
2. The current wording of chapter III, namely, “agreements between rival or potentially
rival firms”, suggests that the prohibition of anticompetitive agreements concerns only
horizontal agreements. However, taking into account that many competition laws prohibit
2
TD/RBP/CONF.9/L.1
both horizontal and vertical anticompetitive agreements, the commentaries on chapter III also
deal with vertical agreements.
B. Agreements or arrangements
1 United States of America Supreme Court Interstate Circuit v. United States, Case No. 306 US208,
1939; United States Court of Appeals for the Second Circuit, United States v. Apple, Case No. 791
F.3d 290, 2015.
2 United States Court of Appeals for the Ninth Circuit, Esco v. United States, 340 F.2D 1000, 1965.
3 United States Supreme Court, Texaco v. Dagher, Case No. 547 US1, 2006; European Court of
Justice, Third Chamber, Akzo Nobel and Others v. Commission of the European Communities,
Case No. C-97/08, 2009, para 58.
4 R Whish and D Bailey, 2018, Competition Law, ninth edition (Oxford University Press, Oxford).
5 United States Supreme Court, Theatre Enterprise v. Paramount Film Distributing,
Case No. 346 US537, 1954.
6 H Hovenkamp, 2016, Federal Antitrust Policy: The Law of Competition and Its Practice, fifth edition
(West Academic Publishing, Saint Paul, United States).
3
TD/RBP/CONF.9/L.1
Table 1
Alternative approaches in existing legislation: Notion of agreement
Jurisdiction
China Article 13 of the Antimonopoly Law states that monopoly agreements include
“agreements, decisions and other concerted conducts designed to eliminate or
restrict competition”.
India The Competition Act states that “‘agreement’ includes any arrangement or
understanding or action in concert, (a) whether or not such arrangement,
understanding or action is formal or in writing; or (b) whether or not such
arrangement, understanding or action is intended to be enforceable by legal
proceedings”.
Jamaica The Fair Competition Act states that agreement “includes any agreement,
arrangement or understanding whether oral or in writing or whether or not it
is intended to be legally enforceable”.
European Article 101 (1) of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union refers
Union to “agreements between undertakings, decisions by associations of
undertakings and concerted practices”.
11. While most competition laws prohibit both horizontal and vertical anticompetitive
agreements, jurisdictions often take different approaches to formulating the prohibition. In
many competition law regimes, a general provision of anticompetitive agreements covers
both horizontal and vertical agreements. For example, in the United States, the Sherman
Antitrust Act of 1890 contains a broad prohibition of anticompetitive agreements, so that
4
TD/RBP/CONF.9/L.1
both horizontal and vertical agreements can be challenged under the same provision.
Alternatively, some competition laws, for example in Costa Rica, Indonesia and South
Africa, have separate provisions for horizontal and vertical agreements. Competition laws
may contain general provisions that apply only to horizontal agreements, leaving vertical
agreements to be covered by a number of individual provisions dealing with resale price
maintenance, exclusive dealing, tying and bundling, etc. It should be noted that the
prohibition of the abuse of dominance can also apply to vertical agreements when one party
to the vertical agreement holds a dominant position and abuses this position by imposing
anticompetitive terms and conditions.
12. A related issue is whether to explicitly specify types of prohibited conduct in the law
or to draft a broad prohibition covering various forms of anticompetitive agreements. Some
competition laws only contain a broad prohibition against anticompetitive agreements,
leaving specific conduct prohibited by the law to be determined at the enforcement stage.
While this approach allows for flexibility in enforcement, it may provide little guidance for
the public and for competition authorities without a strong competition law capacity, in
particular in young competition law regimes where public awareness about the unlawfulness
of anticompetitive agreements is relatively low. An alternative is to include a list of examples
of prohibited conduct in the relevant competition law provision. Many jurisdictions, such as
Chile, China and the European Union, take an approach whereby a broad prohibition of
anticompetitive agreements is followed by a non-exhaustive list of categories considered
violations. This approach provides a great deal of flexibility, while also giving guidance on
enforcement priorities (see table 2).
Table 2
Alternative approaches in existing legislation: Formulating the prohibition of
anticompetitive agreements
Jurisdiction
Australia Section 45 of the Competition and Consumer Act contains a general provision
that covers both horizontal and vertical agreements. The Act also contains
provisions governing horizontal and vertical agreements separately, including the
prohibition of making or giving effect to cartel provisions. Cartel provisions are
provisions of a contract, arrangement or understanding between firms in a
horizontal relationship, which has any of the purposes or effects enumerated in
section 45AD of the Act. Other provisions apply to vertical agreements, such as
section 47 on exclusive dealing and section 48 on resale price maintenance.
5
TD/RBP/CONF.9/L.1
Jurisdiction
(f) Other monopoly agreements confirmed as such by the authority for
enforcement of the Antimonopoly Law under the State Council.”
A similar provision in article 14 addresses vertical agreements.
Republic of Korea Article 19 (1) of the Monopoly Regulation and Fair Trade Act states as follows:
“No enterpriser shall agree with other enterprisers by contract, agreement,
resolution or any other means to jointly engage in an act, or let others do this
kind of activity, falling under any of the following subparagraphs, that unfairly
restricts competition (hereafter referred to as “improper concerted acts”):
(1) An act fixing, maintaining or changing prices;
(2) An act determining terms and conditions for transactions of goods or services,
or payment of prices thereof;
(3) An act restricting production, delivery, transportation or transaction of goods
or services;
(4) An act limiting the territory of trade or customers;
(5) An act preventing or restricting the establishment or extension of facilities or
the installation of equipment necessary for the production of goods or the
rendering of services;
(6) An act restricting the types or specifications of goods or services in producing
or transacting goods or services;
(7) An act of jointly carrying out and managing the main parts of a business or
establishing a company, etc. to jointly carry out and manage the main parts of a
business; or
(8) Any practice that substantially lessens competition in a particular business
area by means, other than those under subparagraphs 1 to 7, of interfering with or
restricting the activities or contents of business.”
South Africa Paragraph 4 (1) (b) of the Competition Act states as follows:
“An agreement between, or concerted practice by, firms or a decision by an
association of firms is prohibited if it is between parties in a horizontal
relationship and if... it involves any of the following restrictive horizontal
practices:
(a) Directly or indirectly fixing a purchase or selling price or any other trading
condition;
(b) Dividing markets by allocating customers, suppliers, territories or specific
types of goods or services; or
6
TD/RBP/CONF.9/L.1
Jurisdiction
(c) Collusive tendering.”
Paragraph 5 (1) of the Competition Act states that an “agreement between parties
in a vertical relationship is prohibited if it has the effect of substantially
preventing or lessening competition in a market”.
United States The Sherman Antitrust Act states that “every contract, combination in the form
of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the
several States, or with foreign nations, is declared to be illegal”.
European Union Article 101 (1) of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union states as
follows:
“1. The following shall be prohibited as incompatible with the internal market:
all agreements between undertakings, decisions by associations of undertakings
and concerted practices which may affect trade between Member States and
which have as their object or effect the prevention, restriction or distortion of
competition within the internal market, and in particular those which:
(a) Directly or indirectly fix purchase or selling prices or any other trading
conditions;
(b) Limit or control production, markets, technical development, or investment;
(c) Share markets or sources of supply;
(d) Apply dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions with other trading
parties, thereby placing them at a competitive disadvantage;
(e) Make the conclusion of contracts subject to acceptance by the other parties of
supplementary obligations which, by their nature or according to commercial
usage, have no connection with the subject of such contracts.”
13. Among horizontal agreements, a distinction between hard-core cartels and other types
of horizontal agreements can be useful for setting enforcement priorities and standards of
analysis. The agreements listed in chapter III of the Model Law of Competition constitute
hard-core cartels, which have proven to be particularly harmful to competition. It is widely
accepted that hard-core cartels are always anticompetitive and can reasonably be presumed
to be illegal without further inquiry.7 For this reason, a large number of competition law
regimes prohibit them outright, as per se violations of the law or anticompetitive by object.
14. As opposed to hard-core cartels, other types of horizontal agreements may produce
some benefits or procompetitive effects. For example, joint marketing that enables products
to reach customers more quickly can produce some efficiency gains. However, these types
of agreements may also harm competition by reducing the ability or incentive of participating
firms to compete independently or by entailing or facilitating anticompetitive agreements
between them. The overall effect on competition varies case by case, depending on the nature
of the agreement and the market circumstances. Therefore, these types of potentially
anticompetitive agreements require more careful treatment and are therefore commonly
subject to the rule of reason approach under which competition authorities must demonstrate
7 The United States Supreme Court has held that there are “agreements whose nature and necessary
effect are so plainly anticompetitive that no elaborate study of the industry is needed to establish their
illegality – they are ‘illegal per se’” (United States Supreme Court, National Society of Professional
Engineers v. United States, Case No. 435 US679, 1978). In addition, the United States Supreme Court
has held that under the Sherman Antitrust Act “a combination formed for the purpose and with the
effect of raising, depressing, fixing, pegging or stabilizing the price of a commodity in interstate or
foreign commerce is illegal per se” (United States Supreme Court, United States v. Socony-Vacuum
Oil, Case No. 310 US150, 1940).
7
TD/RBP/CONF.9/L.1
the harmful effect of alleged cartel conduct.8 Given the recent trend of criminalization of
hard-core cartels, the distinction between the two types of horizontal agreements becomes
even more important. In some jurisdictions, hard-core cartels are considered to be a criminal
offence and are punishable by imprisonment, while other types of horizontal agreements are
subject to civil or administrative sanctions only.
E. Hard-core cartels
2. Collusive tendering
17. Collusive tendering allows conspiring competitors to effectively raise prices in
situations in which business contracts are awarded by means of soliciting competitive bids.
Competitors agree in advance who will win the bid and at what price, thereby undermining
the purpose of inviting tenders, which is to procure goods or services at the most favourable
price. Collusive tendering may take many forms. Competitors may agree to take turns being
the winning bidder, which is referred to as bid rotation. Some competitors may agree to
submit unacceptable bids to cover up a bid-rigging scheme. In other cases, competitors may
simply agree to refrain from bidding or withdraw a submitted bid. In addition to the bid
submission or non-submission itself, a bid-rigging scheme must also have some way to
compensate the apparent losers. Such agreements may involve subcontracting parts of the
main contract to the losing bidders in exchange or making payments to the other members of
the cartel. Collusive tendering is illegal in most countries. Even countries that do not have a
relevant competition law often have special legislation on tenders. Most countries treat
collusive tendering more severely than other horizontal agreements, because of its fraudulent
8 “The true test of legality is whether the restraint is such as merely regulates, and perhaps thereby
promotes, competition, or whether it is such as may suppress or even destroy competition. To
determine this question, the court must ordinarily consider the facts peculiar to the business, its
condition before and after the restraint was imposed, the nature of the restraint, and its effect, actual
or probable” (United States Supreme Court, Chicago Board of Trade v. United States,
Case No. 246 US231, 1918).
8
TD/RBP/CONF.9/L.1
aspects and its adverse effect on government purchases and public spending in particular (see
table 3).9
Table 3
Alternative approaches in existing legislation: Collusive tendering
Country
Kenya Section 21 (9) of the Competition Act states that collusive tendering is
considered a criminal offence punishable by imprisonment for a term of
up to five years or a fine not exceeding K Sh10 million or both.
South Africa Paragraph 4 (1) (b) (iii) of the Competition Act prohibits bid-rigging.
9 Chile Competition Court, National Economic Prosecutor Office v. Fresenius and Others,
Case No. 165-2018, 2018.
10 United States Supreme Court, United States v. Topco Associates, Case No. 405 US596, 1972; United
States Supreme Court, Palmer v. BRG of Georgia, Case No. 498 US46, 1990.
11 Whish and Bailey, 2018.
9
TD/RBP/CONF.9/L.1
10
TD/RBP/CONF.9/L.1
Table 4
Alternative approaches in existing legislation: Boycotts
Country
United States Cases related to boycotts have generally been analysed by the courts
under the per se approach. However, the Supreme Court has held that
not all horizontal concerted refusals to deal warrant per se treatment.17
22. Horizontal agreements other than hard-core cartels are often qualified as
anticompetitive because of their effects or subject to the rule of reason. These types of
agreements typically include joint marketing, joint purchasing, research and development
joint ventures and, sometimes, information-sharing agreements. In many competition law
regimes, these types of agreements are subject to the rule of reason, reflecting the fact that
competitors sometimes need to collaborate or cooperate in strategic alliances or joint ventures
and that such collaboration can be not only benign but also procompetitive. In addition, in
some jurisdictions, competition authorities must be notified of such agreements before their
implementation, in compliance with a merger and acquisitions control regime.19 However,
simply labelling an arrangement as a joint venture is not enough to avoid per se liability if
participants use the joint venture as a device to raise prices or restrict output.
Joint marketing
23. Joint marketing may involve an agreement to jointly sell, distribute or promote goods
or services. Such agreements can be procompetitive when a combination of complementary
assets can generate cost savings and other efficiencies. However, marketing collaborations
can involve agreements on price, output or other competitively significant variables, resulting
in competitive harm. Whether there will be a net public benefit from an arrangement is a
17 The defendant in one case, a purchasing cooperative, had expelled a member without providing either
an explanation or a procedural means to challenge the expulsion. The Supreme Court found that such
cooperatives were typically designed to increase economic efficiency and held that unless the
cooperative possessed market power or exclusive access to an element essential for effective
competition, the expulsion of the member should be judged under the rule of reason and therefore
might well be lawful (United States Supreme Court, Northwest Wholesale Stationers v. Pacific
Stationery and Printing, Case No. 472 US284, 1985).
18 United States Supreme Court, Associated Press v. United States, Case No. 326 US1, 1945.
19 For further information, see the commentaries on chapter V of the Model Law on Competition.
11
TD/RBP/CONF.9/L.1
matter for the competition authority to decide in the light of the particular circumstances in
each case.
Joint purchasing
24. Joint purchasing involves an agreement to jointly purchase necessary inputs. Such
agreements are often procompetitive, since joint purchasing can allow participants to achieve
greater discounts from suppliers, reflecting, for example, lower supply costs; or to save on
delivery and distribution costs. However, such agreements can lessen competition if they
facilitate collusion through the standardization of participants’ costs. For example, in
Germany, the Act against Restraints on Competition has been amended to allow for a general
exemption for small and medium-sized enterprises and trade associations, for certain
agreements that do not restrain competition and that improve the competitiveness of small
and medium-sized enterprises.
Information-sharing agreements
26. Agreements may involve a considerable degree of information exchanges between
competitors. While the sharing of information can be necessary to achieve procompetitive
collaboration, it can sometimes increase the possibility of collusion. In particular, exchanging
information on pricing, costs, transaction terms, marketing strategies or other significant
competitive variables may raise competition-related concerns and is therefore considered per
se anticompetitive in some jurisdictions. Competitors may facilitate collusion through the
sharing of competitively sensitive information.20
G. Vertical agreements
27. Vertical agreements are those between firms at different levels of the production
and/or distribution chain. Since the firms are often not in direct competition with one another,
the balance of the effects of such agreements is more towards greater efficiency than
substantially lessening competition. Chapter III of the Model Law of Competition does not
refer to vertical agreements, yet some types of vertical agreements that may be
anticompetitive are mentioned in chapter VI, which deals with the abuse of a dominant
position. From a systematic perspective, it may be more appropriate to deal with vertical
agreements under the prohibition of anticompetitive agreements.
28. There are two types of vertical restraints, namely, intrabrand and interbrand.
Intrabrand restraints are agreements between firms at different levels of a production chain
through which some kind of limitation is imposed on the distribution of a manufacturer’s
products, such as a minimum or maximum resale price maintenance or a territorial restraint.
Interbrand restraints are agreements that impose limitations on or affect the distribution of a
rival firm’s products, for example, exclusive dealing or tying.
29. In many jurisdictions, vertical restraints are subject to the rule of reason, which
reflects the fact that such restraints are not always harmful and may actually be beneficial in
certain market structures. Competition authorities rarely oppose vertical restraints that are
not related to price. Vertical agreements that typically raise competition concerns include
those related to resale price maintenance, exclusive dealing, exclusive territory or territorial
20 United States Supreme Court, American Column and Lumber v. United States, Case No. 257 US377,
1921.
12
TD/RBP/CONF.9/L.1
(geographical) market restrictions on distributors and tying arrangements. The first has
remained controversial among economists, while exclusivity practices raise fewer concerns.21
Exclusive dealing
31. Exclusive dealing agreements are interbrand restraints through which a restriction is
placed on a firm’s choice of buyers or suppliers, that is, a buyer is required to purchase all of
its requirements from only one seller or a seller is required to sell its products to only one
firm. Nearly all franchise agreements contain provisions of this nature, prohibiting
franchisees from purchasing inputs, or at the least inputs characteristic of the brand, from
anyone other than the franchisor. The competition-related concern with regard to exclusive
dealing is that it may foreclose a market. For example, if a large fraction of the retailers of a
particular type and quality in a geographical region have entered into an exclusive dealing
agreement with one manufacturer, then another manufacturer may not have a sufficiently
large distribution network available to sell in the market. Exclusive dealing is forbidden only
if it substantially lessens competition in a market.
21 For further information on all four, see the commentaries on chapter IV of the Model Law on
Competition.
22 “Vertical restrictions promote interbrand competition by allowing the manufacturer to achieve certain
efficiencies in the distribution of his products” (United States Supreme Court, Continental TV v. GTE
Sylvania, Case No. 433 US36, 1977); “The justifications for vertical price restraints are similar to
those for other vertical restraints. Minimum resale price maintenance can stimulate interbrand
competition... This is important because the antitrust laws’ ‘primary purpose... is to protect interbrand
competition’ (United States Supreme Court, Leegin Creative Leather Products v. PSKS, Case No. 551
US877, 2007).
13
TD/RBP/CONF.9/L.1
14
TD/RBP/CONF.9/L.1
Table 5
Alternative approaches in existing legislation: Authorization or exemption
Country
Australia The Trade Practices Act specifies when the Australian Competition and Consumer
Commission may grant an authorization. Broadly, conduct may be authorized if the
public benefit outweighs any public detriment. The Act contains two different tests for
authorizing different types of conduct. Under the first test, the Commission may not
grant authorization for making or giving effect to proposed or existing contracts,
arrangements or understandings that might contain cartel provisions, might substantially
lessen competition or involve exclusive dealing (other than third-line forcing), unless it
is satisfied in all circumstances that the agreement or conduct is likely to result in a
public benefit that outweighs the likely public detriment constituted by any lessening of
competition. Under the second test, the Commission may not grant authorization to
proposed exclusionary provisions (primary boycotts), secondary boycotts, third-line
forcing and resale price maintenance unless it is satisfied in all circumstances that the
proposed provision or proposed conduct is likely to result in such a benefit to the public
that the provision should be permitted to be made or the conduct should be allowed to
take place.
15
TD/RBP/CONF.9/L.1
Country
Kenya Articles 25 and 26 of the Competition Act provide for the granting of exemptions from
the restrictive agreements, practices and decisions and restrictive trade practices
applicable to trade associations, if undertakings and/or associations of undertakings
apply and submit the required information that the Authority will require. After
considering the application, the authority may: (a) grant the exemption; (b) refuse to
grant the exemption and notify the applicant accordingly; or (c) issue a certificate of
clearance stating that in its opinion, on the basis of the facts in its possession, the
agreement, decision or concerted practice or the category of agreements, decisions or
concerted practices does not constitute an infringement of the prohibitions in the Act.
Article 26 (2) provides that the authority may grant an exemption for exceptional and
compelling reasons of public policy as to why the agreement, decision, concerted
practice or category of the same ought to be excluded from the prohibitions contained in
the Act. Article 26 (3) provides that in making a decision related to public policy, the
authority shall take into account the extent to which the agreement, decision or
concerted practice or the category thereof contributes to, or results in, or is likely to
contribute to or result in: (a) maintaining or promoting exports; (b) improving or
preventing a decline in the production or distribution of goods or the provision of
services; (c) promoting technical or economic progress or stability in any industry; (d)
obtaining a benefit for the public which outweighs or would outweigh the lessening in
competition that would result, or would be likely to result, from the agreement, decision
or concerted practice or the category of agreements, decisions or concerted practices.
Singapore The Competition Act states that undertakings “entrusted with the operation of services
of general economic interest or having the character of a revenue-producing monopoly”
may be excluded from the prohibition of anticompetitive agreements and that the
minister may also exempt agreements for reasons of public policy. In addition,
agreements that produce a net economic benefit are excluded from the prohibition of
anticompetitive agreements.
South Africa Paragraph 10 (3) of the Competition Act states that the Competition Commission may
grant an exemption if an agreement is required to attain or contributes to “any of the
following objectives: (a) maintenance or promotion of exports; (b) promotion of the
ability of small businesses, or firms controlled or owned by historically disadvantaged
persons, to become competitive; (c) change in productive capacity necessary to stop
decline in an industry; or (d) the economic stability of any industry designated by the
minister, after consulting the minister responsible for that industry”.
16
TD/RBP/CONF.9/L.1
Country
Viet Nam Article 14 (1) of Competition Law No. 23/2018/QH14 states that anticompetitive
agreements “shall be granted exemption for a definite term if they meet one of the
following conditions and benefit consumers:
a) Promoting technical and technological advances, raising the quality of goods,
services;
b) Increasing the competitiveness of Vietnamese enterprises on international market;
c) Promoting the single application of quality standards and technical norms of product
categories;
d) Agreeing on conditions for contract performance, goods delivery and payment, which
are not related to prices and price elements”.
17