SSRN Id724166
SSRN Id724166
SSRN Id724166
2005
Dan Crane
Assistant Professor of Law
Benjamin N Cardozo School of Law
55 Fifth Ave.
New York , NY 10003
United States
(212) 790-0379 (Phone)
(212) 790-0205 (Fax)
<dcrane@yu.edu >
This paper can be downloaded free of charge from the Social Science Research Network at
http://ssrn.com/abstract=724166
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
Daniel A. Crane*
ABSTRACT
i
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
TABLE OF CONTENTS
Abstract ...................................................................................................................i
Table of Contents ...................................................................................................ii
Introduction............................................................................................................1
Conclusion ........................................................................................................... 64
ii
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
INTRODUCTION
The Supreme Court has repeatedly worried that the existence of the
predatory pricing offense may perversely chill vigorous price competition. It has
noted that “the mechanism by which a firm engages in predatory pricing –
lowering prices – is the same mechanism by which a firm stimulates
competition,” and that “mistaken inferences . . . are especially costly, because
they chill the very conduct the antitrust laws are designed to protect.”5 The Court
has commented that “[i]t would be ironic indeed if the standards for predatory
pricing liability were so low [that antitrust suits themselves] became a tool for
3
Probabilistic harm in time two – to the degree of a “dangerous probability” –
suffices. See generally III Phillip E. Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, ANTITRUST LAW:
AN ANALYSIS OF ANTITRUST PRINCIPLES AND THEIR APPLICATION ¶ 726 (1996).
4
Such actions would need to be brought by competitors rather than consumers, since
consumers that enjoyed lower prices in time one without ever getting to the recoupment
era in time two would lack any viable claim of antitrust injury.
5
Brooke Group v. Brown & Williamson, 509 U.S. 209, 226 (1993) (quoting
Matsushita Elec. Industrial Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574, 594 (1986); see also
Cargill, Inc. v. Montfort of Colorado, Inc., 479 U.S. 104, 122 n.17 (1986) (same).
1
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
keeping prices high.”6 Seeking to avoid this irony, the Court has set high the bar
that predatory pricing plaintiffs must hurdle.
6
Brooke Group, 509 U.S. at 226-27.
7
Avishalom Tor, Illustrating a Behaviorally Informed Approach to Antitrust Law:
The Case of Predatory Pricing, 18 Fall-Antitrust 52 (2003); Aaron S. Edlin, Stopping
Above-Cost Predatory Pricing, 111 Yale L. J. 941 (2002); Patrick Bolton, Joseph F.
Brodley & Michael H. Riordan, Predatory Pricing: Strategic Theory and Legal Policy,
88 Geo. L. J. 2239 (2000); Jonathan B. Baker, Predatory Pricing After Brooke Group:
An Economic Perspective, 62 Antitrust L. J. 585 (1994).
8
United States v. AMR Corp., 335 F.3d 1109, 1115 (10th Cir. 2003). Despite
approaching predatory pricing claims with less incredulity, the court affirmed the district
court’s grant of summary judgment against the United States finding that none of the four
alternative cost-revenue models advanced by government showed pricing below
incremental cost.
9
Three times, the Supreme Court has declined to decide what is the appropriate
measure of cost below which prices must be set in order to be condemned as predatory.
Brooke Group, 509 U.S. at 223 n. 24; Cargill, 479 U.S. at 117-118 n.12; Matsushita, 475
U.S. at 585 n.8.
2
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
plaintiff has won a jury verdict since Brooke Group,10 plaintiffs have recently
won some predatory pricing cases11 and procured substantial settlements in
others.12 Additionally, regardless of their low probability of success, plaintiffs
continue to file a significant number of federal predatory pricing cases,13
suggesting that predatory pricing complaints may afford plaintiffs strategic
advantages whether or not they ultimately prevail.
10
See Edlin, supra n. ___ at 941; Herbert Hovenkamp, Post-Chicago Antitrust: A
Review and Critique, 2001 Colum. Bus. L. Rev. 257, 312 (2001); Bolton, Brodley &
Riordan, supra n. ___ at 2258-59; see also David Close, Don’t Fear the Reaper: Why
Transferable Assets and Avoidable Costs Should Not Resurrect Predatory Pricing, 88
Iowa L. Rev. 433, 447 (2003).
11
On September 27, 2002, a San Antonio jury awarded Kinetic Concepts, Inc. and
Medical Retro Design, Inc. $173.6 in damages, before trebling, in their federal predatory
pricing suit against Hillenbrand Industries and Hill-Rom, its subsidiary. Kinetic
Concepts, Inc. v. Hillenbrand Industries, Inc., 262 F.Supp.2d 722, 725-26 (W.D. Tex
2003). The case was subsequently settled before appeal. See infra n. ____. Further,
LePage’s won a $68,486,697 jury verdict against 3M in a monopolization case based on
3M’s bundled discounts and rebates to retailers. LePage's Inc. v. 3M, 324 F.3d 141 (3rd
Cir. 2003) (en banc). The original Third Circuit panel majority and the en banc
dissenting judges saw LePage’s claims as being essentially ones for predatory pricing.
Judge Sloviter’s en banc majority opinion rejected that characterization. See Daniel A.
Crane, Multiproduct Discounting: A Myth of Non-Price Predation, ___ U. Chi. L. Rev.
___ (2005).
12
See infra text accompany notes ___.
13
See infra n. ___ for cases.
3
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
Part I of this Article considers the most obvious way in which predatory
pricing law could adversely affect market pricing: If rival firms strategically
misuse predatory pricing law to discourage price-cutting behavior, then predatory
pricing law could have strong effects antithetical to its purposes. Firms may
strategically misuse predatory pricing law in several different ways. Less
efficient firms may use the threat of a predation lawsuit to raise their rivals’ costs
and thereby overcome efficiency deficits. Equally efficient firms may use
predatory pricing litigation to help organize or stabilize a tacit agreement on
pricing. Part I concludes by considering whether there is evidence that firms in
fact use predatory pricing litigation for strategic purposes, and concludes that
there is some evidence that suggests that they do.
Part II considers the incentives that predatory pricing law creates for
firms to deviate from socially optimal pricing, particularly in comparison to the
incentives that firms would face in an unregulated state. Since both the existence
of predatory pricing law and the absence of such a prohibition would induce or
permit deviations from optimal pricing, some comparison of the likely effects of
weak and strong predatory pricing regimes on pricing behavior is necessary in
formulating the optimal legal rules. I argue that a number of remedial features of
antitrust law – including the treble damages remedy, fee-shifting, and liberality in
proof of damages – coupled with behavioral influences on management decision
making – such as risk aversion under conditions of significant uncertainty –
suggest that predatory pricing law may induce a substantial amount of deviation
from optimal pricing. Part II concludes by reporting the results of an informal
study of in-house lawyers that I conducted to understand the extent to which
predatory pricing law influences firms’ pricing behavior in non-litigation
contexts.
A mainline view among legal scholars today is that the Supreme Court’s
decisions in Matsushita and Brooke Group have made it virtually impossible for
4
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
14
See Bolton, Brodley & Riordan, supra n. ___ at 2258-60; Hovenkamp, supra n.
___ at ___.
15
See supra n. ___.
16
The following are reported federal cases involving a complaint alleging
predatory pricing filed after 1993. The list including primary line price discrimination
under the Robinson-Patman Act, but does not include claims under state antitrust statutes
or anti-dumping statutes. Covad Commun. Co. v. BellSouth Corp., 374 F.3d 1044 (11th
Cir. 2004); Beech-Nut Nutrition Corp. v. Gerber Products Company, 69 Fed. Appx. 350
(9Th Cir. 2003); Michigan Paytel Joint Venture v. City of Detroit, 287 F.3d 527 (6th Cir.
2002); Bailey v. Allgas, Inc., 284 F.3d 1237 (11th Cir. 2002); Lycon, Inc. v. Juenke, 250
F.3d 285 (5th Cir. 2001); Taylor Pub. Co. v. Jostens, Inc. 216 F.3d 465 (5th Cir. 2000);
Acoustic Systems, Inc. v. Wenger Corp., 207 F.3d 287 (5th Cir. 2000); Western Parcel
Exp. v. United Parcel Service, 190 F.3d 974 (9th Cir. 1999); Stearns Airport Equipment
Co. v. FMC Corp., 170 F.3d 518 (5th Cir. Tex.); National Parcel Services, Inc. v. J.B.
Hunt Logistics, Inc.; 150 F.3d 970 (8th Cir. 1998); Kentmaster Mfg. Co. v. Jarvis Prods.
Corp., 146 F.3d 691 (9th Cir. 1998); C.B. Trucking, Inc. v. Waste Management, Inc., 137
F.3d 41 (1st Cir. 1998 ); Springfield Terminal Ry. Co. v. Canadian Pacific Ltd., 133 F.3d
103 (1st Cir. 1997); Queen City Pizza, Inc. v. Domino's Pizza, Inc., 124 F.3d 430 (3rd Cir.
1997); Creative Copier Servs. v. Xerox Corp., 2004 WL 2600436 (D. Conn., Nov. 15,
2004); Linens of Europe, Inc. v. Best Mfg., Inc., 2004-2 Trade Cases P 74,548 (S.D.N.Y.
2004); Alcorn v. BP Products North America, Inc., 2004-2 Trade Cases P 74,505 (D.
Minn. 2004); Nobody in Particular Presents, Inc. v. Clear Channel Communs., 311
F.Supp. 2d 1048 (D. Colo. 2004); Specialty Minerals, Inc. v. Pleuss-Stauffer AG, 2004
WL 42280 (S.D.N.Y. Jan 7, 2004); El Aguila Food Prods., Inc. v. Gruma Corp., 301 F.
Supp. 2d 612 (S.D.Tex. 2003); Leopoldo Fontanillas, Inc. v. Luis Ayala Colon Sucesores,
Inc., 283 F. Supp. 2d 579 (D. Puerto Rico 2003); E-Z Bowz, L.L.C. v. Professional Prod.
Research Co., 2003 WL 22068573 (S.D.N.Y. Sept. 5, 2003); Blanchard & Co, v. Barrick
Gold Corp., 2003-2 Trade Cases P 74,172 (E.D. La. 2003); Masco Contractor Servs.
East, Inc. v. Beals, 279 F. Supp. 2d 699 (E.D. Va. 2003); McKenzie-Willamette Hosp. v.
Peacehealth, 2003 WL 23537980 (D. Or. Aug. 15, 2003); Kinetic Concepts, Inc. v.
Hillenbrand Indus., Inc., 262 F.Supp.2d 722 (W.D. Tex. 2003); Kuligowska v. GNC
Franchising, Inc., 2002 WL 32131024 (W.D. Pa. Nov. 25, 2002); Berlyn, Inc. v. Gazette
Newspapers, Inc., 223 F. Supp. 2d 718 (D. Md. 2002); DJ Mfg. Corp. v. Tex-Shield, Inc.,
275 F.Supp.2d 109 (D. Puerto Rico 2002); Tate v. Pacific Gas & Elec. Co., 230
F.Supp.2d 1072 (N.D. Cal. 2002); Mathiowetz Const. Co. v. Minnesota Dept. of Transp.,
2002 WL 334394 (D. Minn. 2002); ASM America, Inc. v. Genus, Inc., 2002-1 Trade
5
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
suits have probably have been filed as well.17 Are all of these plaintiffs Don
Quixotes tilting at windmills? It is unlikely that they are litigating costly,
resource-intensive predatory pricing cases merely for sport. If an ultimate money
judgment is doubtful in light of Matsushita and Brooke Group, predatory pricing
plaintiffs may have objectives other than simply exacting money from a
________________________________________________________
Cases P 73,573 (N.D. Cal. 2002); Coventry Health Care of Kansas, Inc. v. Via Christi
Health Sys., Inc., 176 F. Supp. 2d 1207 (D. Kan. 2001); Lee v. General Nutrition Cos.,
Inc., 2002-2 Trade Cases P 73,777 (C.D. Ca. 2001); Yellow Page Solutions, Inc. v. Bell
Atlantic Yellow Pages Co., 2002-1 Trade Cases P 73,556 (S.D.N.Y. 2001); Eon Labs
Mfg. Inc. v. Watson Pharm., Inc., 164 F. Supp. 2d 350 (S.D.N.Y. 2001); Mathias v. Daily
News, L.P., 152 F. Supp. 2d 465 (S.D.N.Y. 2001); United Magazine Co. v. Murdoch
Magazines Dist., Inc.,146 F. Supp. 2d 385 (S.D.N.Y. 2001); Peerless Heater Co. v.
Mestek, Inc., 2000-1 Trade Cases P 72,917 (E.D. Pa. 2000); Act, Inc. v. Sylvan Learning
Systems, Inc., 2000 WL 34031484 (N.D. Iowa, May 8, 2000); J & S Oil, Inc. v. Irving Oil
Corp., 63 F.Supp.2d 62 (D. Me. 1999); Cohabaco Cigar Co. v. U.S. Tobacco Co., 1998
WL 773696 (N.D. Ill. Oct. 30, 1998); CSY Liquidating Corp. v. Harris Trust and Sav.
Bank, 1998 WL 157065 (N.D. Ill. March 31, 1998); Malek Wholesaler, Inc. v. First Film
Extruding, Ltd., 1998 WL 142385 (N.D. Ill. March 20, 1998); Bushnell Corp. v. ITT
Corp., 175 F.R.D. 584 (D. Kan. 1997); L&W/Lindco Products, Inc. v. Pure Asphalt Co.,
979 F.Supp. 632 (N.D. Ill. 1997); Anti-Monopoly, Inc. v. Hasbro, Inc., 958 F.Supp. 895
(S.D.N.Y. 1997); Cardinal Industries, Inc. v. Pressman Toy Corp., 1997-1 Trade Cases P
71,738 (S.D.N.Y. 1996); Clark v. Flow Measurement, Inc., 948 F.Supp. 519 (D.S.C.
1996); Hahn v. Rifkin/Narragansett, 941 F.Supp. 1196 (S.D. Fla. 1996); Aurora Gas Co.
v. Presque Isle Electric & Gas, 1996 WL 627399 (E.D. Mich. 1996); Barge v. Daily
Journal Corp., 1996-2 Trade Cases P 71,541 (S.D.N.Y. 1996); Westbank Yellow Pages v.
BRI, Inc., 1996-1 Trade Cases P 71,448 (E.D. La. 1996); AD/SAT, a Div. of Skylight, Inc.
v. Associated Press, 920 F.Supp. 1287 (S.D.N.Y. 1996); Keller's Radiator Warehouse,
Inc. v. Go/Dan Indus., 1996-1 Trade Cases P 71,318 (D. Kan. 1996); Storis, Inc. v. GERS
Retail Systems, Inc., 1995 WL 337100 (D.N.J. May 31, 1995); Bonollo Rubbish Removal,
Inc. v. Town of Franklin, 886 F.Supp. 955 (D. Mass. 1995); MCI Telecommunications
Corp. v. Graphnet, Inc., 881 F.Supp. 126 (D.N.J. 1995).
17
Only about ten to fifteen percent of federal district court decisions are
published in the Westlaw database, which was searched to generate these statistics.
William A. Hilyerd, Using the Law Library: A Guide for Educators—Part I: Untangling
the Legal System, 33 J. L. & Educ. 213, 221 (2004). But it would not be safe extrapolate
from the 58 reported decisions that there have been 387 to 580 federal predatory pricing
cases filed since 1993. Antitrust cases, which often involve large amounts in controversy
and sophisticated counsel, are likely to be reported disproportionately to many more
mundane matters, such as prisoner pro se filings and federally-backed student loan
foreclosure actions. Further, the ten to fifteen statistic concerns the number of decisions
that are published, not the total number of cases in which some written decision gets
reported. A particular case may involve multiple written decisions, some reported and
some not.
6
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
There are two distinct ways in which firms may strategically misuse
predatory pricing law. In the first model, a less efficient rival might use a
predation lawsuit to raise its rival’s costs or threaten the possibility of a large
money judgment in order to overcome an efficiency deficit. In the second model,
a firm might use a predation lawsuit to send price signals, conduct information
exchange, and otherwise facilitate the formation or maintenance of a consciously
18
R. Preston McAfee & Nicholas V. Vakkur, The Strategic Abuse of the Antitrust
Laws, Working Paper, on file with author (2004); Edward A. Synder & Thomas E.
Kauper, Misuses of the Antitrust Laws: The Competitor Plaintiff, 90 Mich. L. Rev. 551
(1991); William J. Baumol & Janusz A. Ordover, Use of Antitrust to Subvert Competition
, 28 J. L. & Econ. 247 (1985); Frank H. Easterbook, The Limits of Antitrust, 63 Tex. L.
Rev. 1 (1984). See also Edward D. Cavanagh, De-Trebling Antitrust Damages: An Idea
Whose Time Has Come?, 61 Tul. L. Rev. 777, 814 (1987). On the more general
proposition that antitrust law has been systematically misused for rent-seeking purposes,
see THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF ANTITRUST: THE PUBLIC CHOICE PERSPECTIVE
(Fred S. McChesney & William F. Shughart II eds., 1995).
19
See Baumol & Ordover, supra n. ___ at 255 (noting that less efficient firms
“advocate their costing approach as a device to limit the price-cutting opportunities of
rivals rendered more efficient by economies of scale or scope, by superior management,
or by other legitimate sources of superiority”).
7
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
parallel pricing scheme. A strategically thinking firm need not adopt only one
model. Elements of both models could be used at the same time to discourage a
rival’s price competition.
20
E.g., Morgan v. Ponder, 892 F.2d 1355, 1363 (8th Cir. 1989) (holding that
predatory pricing plaintiff must show that defendant’s price would have excluded an
equally efficient competitor); Barry Wright Corp. v. ITT Grinnell Corp., 724 F.2d 227,
232 (9th Cir. 1983) (discussing effect of below-marginal-cost pricing on equally efficient
competitors); MCI Communications Corp. v. AT&T, 708 F.2d 1081, 1113 (7th Cir. 1983)
(defending price cuts by dominant firms as incapable of excluding equally efficient
firms); Einer Elhauge, Why Above-Cost Price Cuts to Drive Out Entrants Are Not
Predatory – And the Implications for Defining Costs and Market Power, 112 Yale L. J.
682, 711 (2003) (analyzing what sort of price cuts are capable of driving out equally
efficient firms); Edlin, supra n. ___ (proposing imposition of price-cut freeze on
dominant incumbent firms to enable less efficient new entrants to reach efficient scale);
Richard A. Posner, ANTITRUST LAW 215 (2d ed. 2001) (arguing that above-cost pricing
should not be unlawful because it cannot exclude an equally efficient competitor); Phillip
Areeda, Monopolization, Mergers, and Markets: A Century Past and the Future, 75 Cal.
L. Rev. 959, 968 (1987) (defending Areeda-Turner marginal cost test for predation on
ground that prices above marginal cost cannot exclude an equally efficient competitor).
21
But see Edlin, supra n. ___ (proposing imposition of price-cut freeze on
dominant incumbent firms to enable less efficient new entrants to reach efficient scale);
LePage’s v. 3M, 324 F.3d at 173 (Greenberg, J., dissenting) (discussing LePage’s
apparently successful argument that it did not need to show that it was as efficient in the
8
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
market rivals in predatory pricing cases assumes that each firm’s efficiency is
endogenously created – that each firm brings to the market whatever productive
capacity it has attained on its own. But firms can also affect one another’s
efficiency, incidentally22 or deliberately.23 When an efficiency gap exists
between rival firms, predatory pricing law may enable the less efficient firm to
coerce its rival to price in manner consistent with the less efficient firm’s
productive limitations.24
Suppose that a new entrant is less efficient than the dominant incumbent.
The incumbent may drop its price in response to the new entry, threatening the
new entrant’s survival. The new entrant may threaten to file a predatory pricing
suit – or actually file one – to force the incumbent to soften its price-cutting. The
incumbent firm might quite reasonably anticipate that whatever profits it would
forgo by yielding to the threatened predatory pricing suit and raising its price
(thus yielding market share to the new entrant) would be more than offset by
savings from not having to litigate a predatory pricing case. The incumbent
might therefore shade its prices in the market to appease the litigious rival.
Firms, of course, prefer not to face the cost of litigation. But it is not
sufficient that the aggressor firm threaten to raise its rival’s costs through
predatory pricing litigation. In order for the threat to be credible and force the
incumbent to cease its price discounting even if the incumbent believes the
predatory pricing claim would be highly unlikely to succeed, the incumbent must
believe that the predatory pricing lawsuit would cost it more than it would cost
the new entrant.25 Otherwise, there would be no obvious advantage to the new
entrant from filing the lawsuit since it would harm the new entrant as much as the
incumbent (putting aside the possibility that the new entrant would actually
prevail and recover a substantial judgment, which is discussed in the next
________________________________________________________
production of transparent tape as 3M in order to challenge 3M’s bundled discounts and
rebates as exclusionary).
22
Elhauge, supra n. ___ (explaining how new entrant can decrease incumbent’s
efficiency by creaming the most lucrative business and thereby undermining incumbent’s
price-discrimination scheme).
23
Tom Krattenmaker & Steven Salop, Anticompetitive Exclusion: Raising Rival’s
Costs to Achieve Power Over Price, 96 Y ale L. J. 209, 223 -24 (1986); Steven Salop &
David T. Scheffman, Raising Rival’s Costs, 73 AM. ECON. REV. 267 (1983). On
predatory litigation, see Gary Myers, Litigation as a Predatory Practice, 80 KY. L.J. 565
(1992).
24
See Oliver E. Williamson, Predatory Pricing: A Strategic and Welfare Analysis,
87 Yale L. J. 284, 287 (1977) (noting possibility that predatory pricing law could be used
as a “shelter against inefficiency”).
25
See generally, Krattenmaker & Salop, supra n. ___.
9
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
26
A threat by the new entrant to raise both firms’ costs by an equal amount could
potentially be credible if the new entrant had greater or cheaper access to capital than the
incumbent.
27
See Daniel Kahneman, Jack L. Knetsch, and Richard H. Thaler, Experimental
Tests of the Endowment Effect and the Coase Theorem, in Cass R. Sunstein, ed.,
BEHAVIORAL LAW AND ECONOMICS (2000); Richard Thaler, Toward a Positive Theory of
Consumer Choice, 1 J. Econ. Behav. & Org. 3 (1979).
28
Differences between plaintiff and defendant’s preferences with respect to losses
and gains may not only affect the amount of each side’s litigation expenditures but also
the dynamics of settlement negotiations. If defendant’s aversion to large losses exceeds
plaintiff’s preference for large gains, the likelihood increases that defendant would be
willing to make a larger settlement payment to avoid the risk of a substantial adverse
judgment in a predatory pricing case. This could increase the attraction of predatory
pricing litigation as a strategic threat by plaintiffs to coerce defendants to lessen price
competition.
29
Cindy R. Alexander, On the Nature of Reputational Penalty for Corporate Crime:
Evidence, 42 J.L. & Econ. 489 (1999) (reporting that firms convicted of anticompetitive
10
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
________________________________________________________
collusion paid a relatively small reputational price); see also Michael K. Block, Optimal
Penalties, Criminal Law and the Control of Corporate Behavior, 71 B.U. L. Rev. 395,
400, 409 (1991); William L. Silber & Lawrence J. White, Market Reaction to the Filing
of Antitrust Suits: An Aggregate and Cross-Sectional Analysis; Review of Econ. &
Statistics 64 (1982).
30
Keith N. Hylton, Welfare Implications of Costly Litigation Under Strict Liability,
4 Am. L. & Econ. Rev. 18, 37 (2002); Robert G. Bone & David S. Evans, Class
Certification and the Substantive Merits, 51 Duke L. J. 1251, 1299 n.182 (2002); Chris
Guthrie, Framing Frivolous Litigation: A Psychological Theory, 67 U. Chi. L. Rev. 163,
207 n. 203 (2000); Murray L. Schwartz and Daniel J.B. Mitchell, An Economic Analysis
of the Contingent Fee in Personal-Injury Litigation, 22 Stan L Rev 1125, 1125 (1970).
31
Eric Helland & Alexander Tabarrok, Contingency Fees, Settlement Delay, and
Low-Quality Litigation: Empirical Evidence from Two Datasets, 19 J. Law, Econ, &
Org. 517 (2003) (reporting that contingency fee structure tends to decrease the average
quality of lawsuits as compared to hourly fee structure).
11
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
discovery costs are likely to be less than the defendant’s.32 Since “defendant is
apt to be larger, with more files to search, and to have control of more pertinent
documents than plaintiff,”33 the incumbent may perceive the threatened lawsuit to
be a more costly enterprise to itself than to the new entrant.
Once a jury finds the defendant liable for predatory pricing, proving
damages is typically not that hard. The tendency of courts in antitrust cases is to
be strict with respect to proof of causation and antitrust injury, but much more
lenient in proof of the amount of damages once those elements are shown.34 This
32
Frank Easterbrook, The Limits of Antitrust, 63 Tex. L. Rev. 1, 34 (1984).
33
Id.
34
See generally Story Parchment Co. v. Paterson Parchment Paper Co., 282 U.S.
555, 562-63 (1931) (“It is true that there was uncertainty as to the extent of the damage,
but there was none as to the fact of damage; and there is a clear distinction between the
12
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
________________________________________________________
measure of proof necessary to establish the fact that petitioner had sustained some
damage and the measure of proof necessary to enable the jury to fix the amount. . . .
Where the . . . [wrongful act] itself is of such a nature as to preclude the ascertainment of
the amount of damages with certainty, it would be a perversion of fundamental principles
of justice to deny all relief to the injured person, and thereby relieve the wrongdoer from
making any amend for his acts . . . . [T]he risk of the uncertainty should be thrown upon
the wrongdoer instead of upon the injured party”); J. Truett Payne v. Chrysler Motors
Corp., 451 U.S. 557, 566 (1981) (holding that some uncertainty in proving damages in
antitrust cases must be tolerated because the “vagaries of the marketplace usually deny us
sure knowledge of what plaintiff's situation would have been in the absence of the
defendant's antitrust violation”); Roger D. Blair & Jeffrey L. Harrison, Antitrust Policy
and Monopsony, 76 Cornell L. Rev. 297, 338 n.221 (1991) (“Traditionally, courts have
been lenient about the degree of certainty required to prove the amount of damage in an
antitrust case.”); Jeffrey L. Harrison, The Lost Profits Measure of Damages in Price
Enhancement Cases, 64 Minn. L . Rev. 751, 756-58 (1980) (discussing relaxed
requirements for proving amount of antitrust damages once antitrust injury is shown).
35
See II Phillip E. Areeda, Roger D. Blair & Herbert Hovenkamp, ANTITRUST LAW:
AN ANALYSIS OF ANTITRUST PRINCIPLES AND THEIR APPLICATION ¶ 396g (2000)
(discussing damages models in predatory pricing cases).
36
Id. at 580.
37
Id. at 580-81.
38
Bigelow v. RKO Radio Pictures, Inc., 327 U.S. 251, 265-66 (1946).
13
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
39
15 U.S.C. § 15. Cases holding that juries are not to be informed that damages will
be trebled pursuant to statute include HBE Leasing Corp. v. Frank, 22 F.3d 41, 45-46 (2d
Cir. 1994); Copper Liquor, Inc. v. Adolph Coors Co., 506 F.2d 934, 955 (5th Cir. 1975);
Semke v. Enid Auto. Dealers Ass’n, 456 F.2d 1361, 1370 (10th Cir. 1972).
40
15 U.S.C. § 15.
41
See Posner, supra n. ___ at 214-15 (describing tendency of judges and juries to
misinterpret “metaphors of coercion that are compelling evidence of predatory intent to
the naïve”); A.A. Poulty Farms. Inc. v. Rose Acre Farms, Inc., 881 F.2d 1396, 1402 (7th
Cir. 1989) (Easterbrook, J.) (describing tendency of plaintiff’s lawyers in predatory
pricing cases to “rummage through business records” for evidence of “greed-driven
desire to succeed and glee at a rival’s predicament” which influences juries “to penalize
hard competition”).
42
See infra text accompanying notes ___ - ____ .
43
See Bolton, Brodley & Riordan, supra n. ___ (noting that, before the current wave
of defendant-friendly predatory pricing precedents, juries often awarded
disproportionately large amounts in predatory pricing cases).
44
Bolton, Brodley, and Riordan, supra n. ___ at 2254-55.
14
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
45
MCI Communications Corp. v. American Tel. and Tel. Co., 708 F.2d 1081, 1092
th
(7 Cir.1983).
46
See supra n. ____.
47
The case was settled before an appeal was taken. See note ___ infra.
48
Hillenbrand Industries’ 2002 SEC Form 10-K at 15.
49
Id.
50
Kinetic Concepts, 262 F. Supp. 2d at 725.
51
Brunswick to Settle Pricing Suits for $65 Million, N.Y. Times Dec. 23, 1999 at C4
(reporting that “[t]he Brunswick Corporation said Dec 22, 1999 that it had agreed to pay
$65 million to settle two class-action suits in which boat builders accused it of using
predatory pricing to drive competitors out of business”).
52
Harlan S. Byrne, In a Real Fix: The Corporate and Human Toll of Price-fixing
Cases an Be High, Barrons Oct. 2, 1995 at 16 (reporting that after state court awarded
Thermex Engergy $488 million in predatory pricing suit against Dyno Industries and ICI
Explosives, ICI settled with an offer of $36 million and Dyno settled on undisclosed
terms).
53
Vicki Vaughn, Family feud - Centeno heirs battle to control ruins of bankrupt
grocery chain, San Antonio Express-News June 2, 1996 (reporting that regional grocery
store H-E-B Co. paid Centeno Super Markets $6.5 million to settle predatory pricing
suit).
15
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
The previous section described the ways in which a firm might use the
threat of a predatory pricing suit to overcome an efficiency deficit and coerce
another firm to soften its price competition. To be successful, such a strategy
requires that one firm force a second firm to abandon an otherwise more
profitable pricing strategy in order to avoid costly litigation. There is another
strategic use to which threats of predatory pricing litigation could be put that
would not require that the threatening firm threaten to increase the other firm’s
costs or coerce the other firm to abandon a more profitable pricing scheme.
Threats of predatory pricing litigation, or litigation itself, may be an ideal tool to
create the necessary conditions for tacit price collusion among oligopolists, a
market condition that could increase the profits of both the threatening firm and
the threatened, to the detriment of consumers.
54
See generally Donald F. Turner, The Definition of Agreement Under the Sherman
Act: Conscious Parallelism and Refusals to Deal, 75 Harv. L. Rev. 655 (1962).
55
See Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission 1992 Horizontal
Merger Guidelines, 57 Fed. Reg. 41,552, 41,558, § 2.1 (Sept. 10, 1992) (discussing
theory of coordinated interaction among oligopolists resulting form increase in market
concentration); FTC v. Arch Coal, Inc., 329 F. Supp. 2d 109, 131 (D.D.C. 2004) (noting
that “antitrust policy seeks particularly to inhibit ‘the creation or reinforcement by merger
of . . . oligopolistic market structures in which tacit coordination can occur”); Hospital
Corporation of America v. FTC, 807 F.2d 1381 (7th Cir. 1986) (Posner, J.) (“When an
economic approach is taken in a section 7 [Clayton Act] case, the ultimate issue is
whether the challenged acquisition is likely to facilitate collusion.”).
56
Brooke Group, 509 U.S. at 228.
57
Even overt cartels are known to face policing difficulties, as was shown in two
empirical studies of the Joint Executive Committee, an 1880s U.S. railroad cartel. See
Glenn Ellison, Theories of Cartel Stability and the Joint Executive Committee, 25 RAND
J. Econ. 37, 37-38 (1994) (noting that the cartel suffered occasional price wars); Robert
H. Porter, A Study of Cartel Stability: The Joint Executive Committee, 1880-1886, 14 Bell
16
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
Threats of predatory pricing litigation and actual predatory pricing litigation may
help to solve these collective action problems by signaling pricing levels,
facilitating information exchange, and providing state-sanctioned cartel policing.
________________________________________________________
J. Econ. 301, 312- 13 (1983) (noting “reversions to noncooperative behavior . . . with a
significant decrease in market price in these periods”).
58
Joseph Katten, Beyond Facilitating Practices: Price Signaling and Price
Protection Clauses in the New Antitrust Environment, 63 Antitrust L. J. 133 (1994);
Michael D. Blechman, Conscious Parallelism, Signalling and Facilitating Devices: The
Problem of Tacit Collusion Under the Antitrust Laws, 24 N.Y.L. Sch. L. Rev. 881
(1979); Kestenbaum, What is “Price Signalling” and Does It Violate the Law?, 49
Antitrust L.J. 911 (1980).
59
See Thomas A. Piraino, Jr., Regulating Oligopoly Conduct Under the Antitrust
Laws, 89 Minn. L. Rev. 9, 59 n.203 (2004) (collecting cases where the Federal Trade
Commission charged that price signaling was an illegal facilitating practice under Section
5 of the FTC Act).
60
Beech-Nut Nutrition Corporation v. Gerber Products Company, Complaint for
Damages and Injunctive Relief, CIV-S 01-1920 (Oct. 16, 2001) (on file with author).
17
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
61
Brooke Group, 509 U.S. at 222 (“First, a plaintiff seeking to establish competitive
injury resulting from a rival’s low prices must prove that the prices complained of are
below an appropriate measure of its rival’s costs.”).
62
Supra n. ___.
63
American Column & Lumber Co. v. United States, 257 U.S. 377 (1921) (finding
that American Hardwood Manufacturers’ Association information-sharing plan was an
unlawful restraint of trade that contributed to a significant increase in prices); United
States v. Container Corp., 393 U.S. 333 (1969) (finding that informal arrangement
among corrugated container manufacturers to share bid information on specific customer
contracts was an unlawful restraint of trade); Todd v. Exxon Corp., 275 F.2d 191 (2d Cir.
2001) (holding that employee stated a cause of action where employer-defendants
allegedly agreed to exchange information about employee compensation).
64
It is also the case, of course, that in litigation one party to the information
exchange is an unwilling party. Litigation involves coerced information exchange, but it
is not necessarily surprising that one party would need to coerce its rival to do something
that could ultimately accrue to the benefit of both firms. The dominant firm may have
disincentives to share information with a rival. See Amitai Aviram & Avishalom Tor,
Overcoming Impediments to Information Sharing, 55 Ala. L. Rev. 231 (2004).
65
United States v. Gypsum Co., 438 U.S. 422, 441 n.16 (1978) (“Exchanges of
current price information, of course, have the greatest potential for generating
anticompetitive effects and although not per se unlawful have consistently been held to
violate the Sherman Act.”).
66
E.g., T.W.A.R., Inc. v. Pacific Bell, 145 F.R.D. 105 (N.D. Cal. 1992)
(compelling defendant to produce contemporaneous business documents where plaintiff
argued that such documents were relevant to its claim for injunctive relief in predatory
18
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
67
See Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission Antitrust Guidelines
for Collaborations Among Competitors § 3.34(e) (April 2000) (expressing concern over
information sharing as to competitor’s “input requirements”).
68
See Daniel A. Crane, Exit Payments in Settlement of Patent Infringement
Lawsuits: Antitrust Rules and Economic Implications, 54 Fla. L. Rev. 747, 759 (2002)
(arguing that protective orders are insufficient to assure that competition will not be
harmed by information exchange in discovery between horizontal competitors); Alan
Lawrence, The Value of Copyright law as a Deterrent to Discovery Abuse, 138 U. Pa. L.
Rev. 549, 565 (1989) (arguing that protective orders are “highly unreliable” for the
protection of trade secrets because they may be subject to modification or complete
withdrawal by courts, and breaches are difficult to police and punish); Omri Ben-Sharar
& Lisa Bernstein, The Secrecy Interest in Contract Law, 109 Yale L. J. 1885, 1922
(2000) (arguing that protective orders do not ensure secrecy between contractual parties
because it is difficult to predict when such orders will be granted).
69
E.g., American Building Prods., L.L.C. v. Ashley Aluminum, Inc., 1997 WL
610877 (E.D. La. 1997) (ordering defendant to return its prices to August 1, 1997 levels,
with allowance only for fluctuation in raw materials markets, pending final adjudication
of case); Advantage Publications, Inc. v. Daily Press, Inc., 1993 WL 1829, at *9 (E.D.
Va. 1983) (ordering defendant to hold its advertising rates at specified levels, without
“discounts, bonuses, rebates, pick-ups, tie-ins, or any other arrangements with
advertisers” pending final adjudication).
19
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
Even if plaintiff ultimately loses the predatory pricing lawsuit at a full trial or on
appeal, the plaintiff may have realized significant pricing benefits in the interim.
Milder forms of policing short of direct judicial coercion are also possible.
Plaintiffs may raise defendant’s ongoing pricing behavior in motions, briefs, or
hearings hoping to elicit cautionary comments from the court.
Airlines
Since deregulation in 1978,71 the airline industry has seen several high-
profile charges of oligopolistic collusion. A well-known episode of attempted
price-fixing involved a 1982 price-war between American Airlines and Braniff in
which the Justice Department obtained a tape recording of a conversation
between John Crandall, CEO of American, and Howard Putnam, CEO of Braniff,
70
Edlin, supra n. ___ at 962; Herbert Hovenkamp, Post-Chicago Antitrust: A
Review and Critique, 2001 Colum. Bus. L. Rev. 257, 316 (2001); Bolton, Brodley &
Riordan, supra n. ___ at 2267-68.
71
Airline Deregulation Act of 1978, 49 U.S.C. § 41713.
20
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
During the same period that the airline industry has ostensibly been a
hotbed of oligopolistic cooperation to price at supracompetitive levels, different
airlines have allegedly been engaged in predatory pricing.76 American has faced
predatory pricing claims by Continental and Northwest in 199277 and the Justice
Department in 1999.78 Virgin Atlantic sued British Airways on what amounted
to predatory pricing charges in 1993.79 Other post-deregulation predation suits
include Laker against Sabena and KLM in 198380 and Laker against PanAm in
1985.81 Further, several low-cost carriers have reportedly complained to the
72
United States v. American Airlines, Inc., 743 F.2d 1114, 1116 (5th Cir. 1984)
(reporting transcript of Crandall/Putnam call).
73
United States v. Airline Tariff Publ'g Co., 1994-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) P 70,687
(D.D.C. 1994).
74
Id.
75
Petition of the United States for an Order to Show Cause Why Respondent
American Airlines, Inc. Should Not Be Found in Civil Contempt, Supplemental to Civil
Action N. 92-2854 (D.D.C. Aug. 6, 2004), available at
www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/f204900/204943.htm.
76
See generally Stephen P. Brady & William A. Cunningham, Exploring Predatory
Pricing in the Airline Industry, 41 Transp. J. 515 (2001).
77
Continental Airlines, Inc. v. American Airlines, Inc., 1993 WL 379396 (S.D. Tex.
Aug. 10, 1993).
78
AMR, 335 F.3d 1109.
79
Virgin Atlantic Airways Ltd. v. British Airways PLC, 257 F.3d 256 (2nd Cir.
2001).
80
Laker Airways Ltd. v. Sabena, Belgian World Airlines, 731 F.2d 909 (D.D.C.
1984).
81
Laker Airways Ltd. v. Pan American World Airways, 607 F.Supp. 324 (S.D.N.Y.
1985). It is unlikely that either of the Laker actions involved strategic use of predatory
21
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
What is interesting about the airline cases is that at least one of the
alleged dates of predatory pricing corresponded with periods in which the
predator and prey were supposedly engaged in oligopolistic collusion. The
Government’s 1992 price signaling case against American, Continental, and
Northwest (and others) concerned the same time period as American’s alleged
predatory pricing campaign against Continental and Northwest.83 For both of
these allegations to be true, American would have to be predating against
Contintental and Northwest at the same time as it was colluding with them.
Although a predatory pricing campaign to discipline rivals into collusion may
plausible,84 the Justice Department charged that American, Continental, and
Northwest were already colluding at the time that Continental and Northwest
alleged that American launched its new, allegedly predatory, pricing scheme.
American cannot have been both predating against, and colluding with, the same
competitors at the same moment, since predation involves pricing below cost and
collusion involves pricing at supracompetitive levels.85
It is possible that one or both of the claims were mistaken – indeed, the
jury found that American was not predating.86 It is also possible that the
________________________________________________________
pricing law, since Laker was in liquidation in the United Kingdom at the time of the
actions.
82
James L. Gattuso, Don’t Outlaw Cheap Airfares, Wall St. J. S5 (4/8/98).
83
The Government’s complaint alleged that the “Coordination Facilitating Device”
that enabled oligopoly pricing began in April of 1988 and continued to the date of the
Complaint, December 21, 1992. See Complaint, United States v. Airline Publishing
Company, Civil Action No. 92-2854 (Dec. 21, 1992), available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/f4700/4796.pdf (¶ 31 p. 10). American’s alleged act of
predatory pricing was its Value Pricing plan, announced on April 9, 1992. Continental
Airlines, Inc. v. American Airlines, Inc., 824 F. Supp. 689, 692
(S.D. Tex. 1993).
84
See n. ___ supra.
85
It is theoretically possible that American was colluding with Northwest and
Continental on some routes and trying to drive them from other routes through predation
but that possibility seems to be factually foreclosed since American’s Value Pricing plan
was a general restructuring of its fare system across all routes. See Continental Airlines,
824 F. Supp. at 692-93.
86
Continental Airlines, Inc. v. American Airlines, Inc., 1993 WL 379396 (Aug. 10,
1993).
22
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
allegations of collusion were correct and that the predatory pricing case itself
reinforced a tacit collusive scheme. Northwest and Continental may have
facilitated a resumption of consciously parallel, lockstep pricing by using the
predatory pricing lawsuit as a price signal and information exchange device,
combined with a punitive raising of American’s costs through expensive
litigation.
87
Continental Airlines, Inc. v. American Airlines, Inc., 824 F. Supp. 689, 692
(S.D. Tex. 1993).
88
Lauren R. Rublin, The Trader, Barrons April 27, 1992 at 53.
89
Ron Hutcheson, Airlines Take Dogfight to Congress, Ft. Worth Star-Telegram
June 11, 1992; Northwest Sues American, Alleging Unfair Pricing Policy, Dallas
Morning News June 13, 1992 at 14F.
90
Northwest Air Plans to Raise U.S. Fares 10%, Wall St. J. June 17, 1992 at B1.
91
Air Fares Set to Increase 4.4 Percent, Associated Press July 7, 1992.
92
Id.
93
Continental, Other Major Airlines Ready to Increase Fares, Houston Chronicle
Dec. 24, 1992.
94
William Terdoslavich, Airlines Agree on Fare-Increase Date, Tour & Travel
News September 14, 1992 at 2.
23
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
There is little doubt that the airline fare war that began with American’s
price-cuts in April ended within weeks after Northwest and Continental filed
their predatory pricing suits. How significant a role the predatory pricing suit
played in deterring aggressive price competition and restoring lockstep price
increases is uncertain. The predatory pricing lawsuit was not the only strategic
tool available or utilized by competitor airlines. The competitors also took their
complaint to the Senate Transportation Committee95 and engaged in unabashed
price signaling through the media. The predatory pricing lawsuit, however, may
have offered a unique combination of coercive opportunities to complement other
strategic tools, including raising rival’s costs through litigation expense, the
threat of a substantial adverse judgment, and detailed information exchange in
discovery. And the predatory pricing case may have taught American a lesson.
After the jury returned a verdict for American in the predatory pricing case in the
summer of 1993, American CEO Robert Crandall – the same CEO caught on
tape encouraging Braniff to raise its prices – stated publicly that American
“probably won’t be attempting that type of leadership again.”96
Even in cases where no private predatory pricing lawsuit was filed but
one airline complained to the Department of Transportation or Justice
Department about another’s fares, the predatory pricing complaint may have
worked as a price signal. The complaint was bound to get back from the
government to the ostensible predator in short order. Complaining to the
government about a competitor’s low prices may be one of the cheapest and most
effective ways of organizing a tacit cartel, even if a government suit is relatively
unlikely.97 The complaint is privileged from antitrust scrutiny unless blatantly
fraudulent98 and is therefore a much safer way of sending a message than direct
communication, as American Airlines learned after the Crandall/Putnam debacle.
95
Ron Hutcheson, Airlines Take Dogfight to Congress, Ft. Worth Star-Telegram
June 11, 1992.
96
James L. Gattuso, Don’t Outlaw Cheap Airfares, Wall St. J. April 8, 1998 at S5.
Doubtlessly, the Department of Justice that sued American for predatory pricing in 1999
would disagree that American learned its lesson from the Continental/Northwest
litigation, although American prevailed in the Justice Department lawsuit as well. AMR
Corp., 335 F.3d at 1109.
97
See James C. Miller III, Comments on Baumol and Ordover, 28 J. L. & Econ. 267
(1985). Miller, Chairman of the Federal Trade Commission, commented in reference to
Baumol and Ordover’s article on the strategic misuse of antitrust law and particularly on
their comments about predatory pricing cases. Miller reported that he frequently saw
competitor firms engaging in rent-seeking at the FTC.
98
Eastern RR Presidents Conf. v. Noerr Motor Freight Co., 365 U.S. 127 (1961);
California Motor Transport Co. v. Trucking Unlimited, 404 U.S. 508 (1972).
24
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
Tobacco
Like the airline industry, the tobacco industry has seen repeated
allegations of both collusion and predatory pricing in the last twenty years.99 The
Brooke Group case, involving the generic cigarette market, turns on allegations
of both predation and collusion and provides useful factual detail to consider the
relationship between oligopolistic pricing and predation claims. Plaintiff Liggett
theorized that Brown & Williamson used predatory pricing to try to achieve
oligopoly pricing. It alleged that Brown & Williamson sought to punish
Liggett’s price-cutting in the generic cigarette segment through below-cost
volume rebates to Liggett wholesalers.100 Justice Kennedy’s Supreme Court
majority opinion rejected Liggett’s arguments on the grounds that Brown &
Williamson would have been unable to recoup its below-cost pricing through
subsequent supracompetitive pricing, since Brown & Williamson’s 11-12% share
of the cigarette market would have required its predation to generate around $9 in
supracompetitive profits for every dollar invested in the scheme, just for Brown
& Williamson to break even.101 The majority dismissed the arguments that actual
recoupment had taken place, finding that the claims of post-predation price
increases were either empirically unsupported or not causally linked to the
allegedly predatory scheme.102 The dissent – and the jury – believed that actual
recoupment had taken place in the form of semi-annual, lock-step price increases
following Brown & Williamson’s below-cost pricing.103
A third possibility is that the oligopolistic pricing did emerge from the
events at issue but that it was precipitated more by the predatory pricing lawsuit
than by the alleged predatory pricing. Consider the sequence of events. Brown
& Williamson started the price war in July of 1984 at the time it was introducing
its own black and white cigarettes.104 Liggett immediately sued alleging
trademark infringement and unfair competition.105 On February 5, 1985, Liggett
amended its complaint to add Robinson-Patman Act claims of predatory
pricing.106 In June of 1985, after it had been litigating its predatory pricing
99
See generally, Daniel A. Crane, Harmful Output in the Antitrust Domain: Lessons
From the Tobacco Industry, __ Ga. L. Rev. ___, ___ (2005).
100
509 U.S. at 217.
101
Id. at 228.
102
Id. at 235-37.
103
Id. at 249-50 (Stevens, J., dissenting).
104
Id. at 214-16.
105
Id. at 216.
106
1988 WL 161235.
25
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
claims for about four months, Liggett raised its prices.107 Brown & Williamson
followed suit in October of 1985.108 By the end of the year, the price war was
over.109 By the middle of 1986, the generic segment had settled into a
comfortable pattern of semi-annual lockstep price increases in line with patterns
in the branded cigarette market.110
Assuming that the lock-step pricing in the generic market reflects at least
non-competitive oligopoly pricing, who is to blame – Liggett or Brown &
Williamson? Perhaps the answer is neither, since oligopoly pricing in the generic
segment was inevitable given that the same four or five firms already marched in
lock-step in the branded cigarette segment.111 But tacit collusion takes some
subtle organizing. Who was the organizer? Liggett blamed Brown &
Williamson because it started the price war, but the evidence suggests that Brown
& Williamson’s price strategy was profit-maximizing without any expectation of
recoupment through oligopoly pricing. The amount of supracompetitive profits
the generic segment would have needed to have generated in order to offset the
costs of a predatory scheme were unattainable.112 Liggett, on the other hand,
could help to organize lock-step pricing by filing a predatory pricing lawsuit – an
expensive venture but far less so than pricing below cost across the substantial
generic cigarette market for 18 months.113 Having laid out its predation theory,
exchanged documents in discovery, and perhaps signaled a truce, Liggett then
took the lead in raising prices. The industry soon followed. The evidence in
Brooke Group is consistent with the proposition that Liggett used its predatory
pricing case to facilitate a pattern of oligopoly pricing. On balance, this
proposition seems far more plausible than the proposition that Brown &
107
509 U.S. at 217.
108
Liggett Group Inc. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 964 F.2d 335, 338 (4th
Cir. 1992).
109
509 U.S. at 243 (Stevens, J., dissenting) (characterizing price war as lasting for 18
months, from July of 1984 to end of 1985).
110
Id. at 218. The majority believed that these price increases may have been offset
by coupons, stickers, and give-aways, id. at 236, although at least one witness testified
that the consumer promotions did not nearly offset the price increases. Id. at 250 n.12
(Stevens, J., dissenting) (citing testimony by Liggett’s expert economist to the effect that
“the promotional activity has been far outstripped by the list price increases).
111
509 U.S. at 213.
112
Id. at 228.
113
Liggett, of course, hoped to gain from the predatory pricing lawsuit even if it did
not help to facilitate cartel pricing. It won an $148.8 judgment, although the district court
ultimately vacated it. 509 U.S. at 218.
26
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
Williamson used a predatory pricing scheme to try to discipline Liggett into tacit
collusion.
The airlines and tobacco case share a common pattern of events: One
firm initiated a price war; its rival(s) sued for predatory pricing; shortly after the
filing of the predatory pricing lawsuit the plaintiff raised its prices; shortly
thereafter the defendant followed suit; oligopoly pricing discipline was restored;
the court or jury ultimately found the predatory pricing lawsuit to be without
merit. In both of these examples, it is quite possible that predatory pricing law
facilitated the high prices predation law was meant to deter.
114
Snyder & Kauper, 90 Mich. L. Rev. 551.
115
The Georgetown Private Antitrust Litigation Project was a 1983 study of private
antitrust litigation sponsored by Georgetown Law School. See Lawrence J. White, The
Georgetown Study of Private Antitrust Litigation, 54 Antitrust L. J. 59 (1985); PRIVATE
ANTITRUST LITIGATION: NEW EVIDENCE, NEW LEARNING (Lawrence J. White ed.,
1988); Symposium, Private Antitrust Litigation, 74 Geo. L. J. 999 (1986).
116
Snyder & Kauper, supra n. ___ at 563-67.
117
Id. at 564.
27
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
share and barriers to entry necessary to make the predation claim plausible.118
Although Snyder and Kauper did not articulate any separate conclusion on the
predatory pricing cases, their overall conclusion that few of the competitor cases
exhibited much merit and that many of the plaintiffs were “object[ing] to actions
that represent[ed] increases in competition”119 would appear to apply to the
predation cases also.
118
Id. at 572-73.
119
Id. at 576.
120
See Bailey v. Algas, Inc., 284 F.3d 1237, 1250 (11th Cir. 2002) (finding that
defendant’s market share of 35-40% was insufficient in predatory pricing case); Western
Parcel Express v. United Parcel Service, 190 F.3d 974, 975 (9th Cir. 1999) (rejecting
plaintiff’s predatory pricing theory on grounds that barriers to entry were not
demonstrated); Stearns Airport Equipment Co. v. FMC Corp., 170 F.3d 518, 530 (5th Cir.
2002) (same); Springfield Terminal Ry. Co. v. Canadian Pacific Ltd., 133 F.3d 103, 107-
8 (1st Cir. 1997) (rejecting predatory pricing theory where defendant’s market share was
about 10%); Queen City Pizza, Inc. v. Domino’s Pizza, Inc., 124 F.3d 430 (3rd Cir. 1997)
(rejecting predatory pricing theory on grounds that plaintiff failed to show defendant had
market power); El Aguila Food Prods., Inc. v. Gruma Corp., 301 F. Supp. 2d 612 (S.D.
Tex. 2003) (rejecting predatory pricing theory where defendant lacked market power);
Masco Contractor Servs. East Inc. v. Beals, 279 F. Supp. 2d 699 (E.D. Va. 2003)
(dismissing predatory pricing claim based on absence of barriers to entry); Berlyn, Inc. v.
Gazette Newspapers, Inc., 223 F. Supp. 2d 718, 734-35 (D. Md. 2002) (rejecting
predatory pricing case where defendant lacked market power); Coventry Health Care of
Kansas, Inc. v. Via Christi Health Sys., Inc., 176 F. Supp. 2d 1207, 1233 (D. Kan. 2001)
(denying preliminary injunction against predatory pricing partly on grounds defendant
lacked market power and barriers to entry were low); Yellow Page Solutions, Inc. v. Bell
Atlantic Yellow Pages Co., 2002-1 Trade Cases ¶ 73,556 (S.D.N.Y. 2001) (dismissing
predatory pricing claims because plaintiff failed to plead market power or high entry
barriers); United Magazine Co. v. Murdoch Magazines Dist., Inc., 146 F. Supp. 2d 385
(S.D.N.Y. 2001) (dismissing predatory pricing claim where plaintiff failed to show that
defendant had market power); Peerless Heater Co. v. Mestek, Inc., 2000-1 Trade Cases ¶
72,917 (E.D. Pa. 2000) (granting summary judgment against plaintiff on predatory
pricing claim where plaintiff’s growing market share precluded any inference that
plaintiff was in danger of being driven from the market); J & S Oil, Inc. v. Irving Oil
Corp., 63 F. Supp. 2d (D. Me. 1999) (granting defendant’s motion for summary judgment
where defendant had low market share and barriers to entry were low); Malek
Wholesaler, Inc. v. First Film Extruding, Ltd., 1998 WL 142385 (N.D. Ill. March 31,
28
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
not deterred continuation of some of the misuses of predatory pricing theory that
occurred during the 1973-1983 time-period of the Georgetown Study.121
But this does not necessarily demonstrate that predatory pricing plaintiffs
are using antitrust law strategically. Synder and Kauper’s market screen analysis
is useful in discovering whether the predation lawsuits had merit, but it is only
tangentially relevant in determining whether predatory pricing plaintiffs are
seeking to use antitrust law to chill price competition or invite a program of tacit
collusion. Frivolous lawsuits could be filed to extort a favorable settlement, out
of a misunderstanding of the governing legal rules, or even out of less efficient
firm’s misguided sense of injustice at being excluded from the market.122 All of
these motivations may induce socially costly and undesirable litigation and
provide a sufficient basis for curtailing the predatory pricing cause of action, but
they do not demonstrate that firms use predatory pricing law strategically to
increase prices.
One way to study the possibility that many predatory pricing plaintiffs
have strategic motivations independent of the ultimate success of the lawsuit is
to examine the compensation structure of the plaintiffs’ attorneys. The
compensation structure of plaintiffs’ attorneys in predatory pricing cases also
provides a relevant check on Bolton, Brodley, and Riordan’s assertion that
Brooke Group and Matsushita have created very high barriers for predatory
pricing plaintiffs.123 Plaintiff’s lawyers should only agree to a contingency fee
arrangement if they believe that there is a reasonable likelihood that the predatory
pricing lawsuit will result in a financial payment from defendant to plaintiff,
either through a money judgment or through a settlement. If a predatory pricing
case was very unlikely to result in a money judgment or settlement but might still
bring financial benefits to the plaintiff by chilling price competition, one would
________________________________________________________
1998) (dismissing predatory pricing claim where plaintiff failed to allege that defendant
had market power); Bushnell Corp. v. ITT Corp., 175 F.R.D. 584 (D. Kan. 1997)
(dismissing predatory pricing case where defendant’s market share was 30%); Anti-
Monopoly, Inc. v. Hasbro, Inc., 958 F. Supp. 895 (S.D.N.Y. 1997) (granting summary
judgment for defendant where plaintiff failed to show high barriers to entry); Clark v.
Flow Measurement, Inc., 948 F. Supp. 519 (D.S.C. 1996) (granting summary judgment
for defendant where defendant’s market share was small); AD/SAT v. Associated Press,
920 F. Supp. 1287 (S.D.N.Y. 1997) (granting summary judgment for defendant where
barriers to entry were low).
121
White, The Georgetown Study of Private Antitrust Litigation, 54 Antitrust L. J. at
60 (describing the time-period during which cases were examined).
122
See Russell Korobkin & Chris Guthrie, Psychology, Economics and Settlement:
A New Look at the Role of the Lawyer, 76 Tex. L. Rev. 77 (1997); J. Rachlinski, Gains,
Losses, and the Psychology of Litigation, 70 S. Cal. L. Rev. 113 (1996); Peter H. Huang,
Emotional Responses in Litigation, 12 Int'l. Rev. L. & Econ. 31 (1992).
123
Bolton, Brodley & Riordan, supra n. ___.
29
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
expect to see an hourly fee structure. Further, the predatory pricing theory
assumes that the plaintiff is financially constrained, indeed that its ability to
survive in the market is jeopardized by a lack of funds necessary to weather the
defendant’s below-cost pricing.124 Such firms are unlikely to be able to pay for
expensive predatory pricing litigation on an out-of-pocket basis. One plaintiff’s
attorney involved in at least three recent predatory pricing cases reported that
“antitrust litigation on an hourly basis is something that 99% of the injured
businesses in the U.S. cannot afford.”125
124
Bolton, Brodley & Riordan, supra n. ___ at 2286-87; Paul Milgrom & John
Roberts, New Theories of Predatory Pricing, in INDUSTRIAL STRUCTURES IN THE NEW
INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS 112, 116-18 (Giacomo Bonanno & Dario Brandolini eds. 1990).
125
E-mail from Carl Person to Daniel Crane on January 6, 2004 (on file with author;
used with permission of Mr. Person).
126
Supra n. ___.
127
Several of the responding attorneys were or had been involved in more than one
of the predatory pricing cases listed in footnote ___.
30
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
that the “kicker” cases are largely hourly fee cases and the “up-front fee” cases
are largely contingency cases, this yields a 14-10 split in favor of hourly fees.
128
Very few cases in which predatory pricing is alleged involve solely a predatory
pricing case. Often, the predatory pricing claims appears to be the principal complaint
but the plaintiff pleads other antitrust wrongs as well, perhaps in an effort to avoid the
strictures on predatory pricing theories imposed by Chicago-school-era case law.
129
There is reason to believe that a full census of predatory pricing cases would
show that a higher percentage of cases are brought on an hourly rate basis than the 23
cases on which data were collected would suggest. Many of the attorneys who declined
to respond work for large, corporate law firms that are relatively unlikely to take matters
on contingency.
130
See supra text accompanying notes ____.
131
Estimates of the costs of predatory pricing lawsuits vary considerably. In 1981,
Joshua Greenberg estimated the mean litigation cost of a predation case to be $30 million
and, in the same conference, Frank Easterbrook estimated it at $3 million. Easterbrook,
supra n. ___ at 335 n. 157 (citing Joshua Greenberg in roundtable discussed, in
STRATEGIC PREDATION AND ANTITRUST ANALYSIS (Steven Salop, ed., 1981)).
31
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
war, it is unclear where the firm finds the funds to finance predatory pricing
litigation on an out-of-pocket basis. Conversely, the fact that many firms engage
in predatory pricing litigation on an hourly fee basis is consistent with the theory
that some firms use predatory pricing cases strategically to chill price
competition even in cases that have relatively little chance of resulting in a
plaintiff’s verdict or monetary settlement.
The courts have accepted as a given that predatory pricing law would be
socially costly if it elevated prices above competitive levels.132 Conversely, if it
were possible to detect and deter with precision those instances where a dominant
firm sought to cut prices to levels that could exclude or discipline equally
efficient competitors and facilitate supracompetitive pricing, social welfare
would be best served by detecting and deterring such behavior. Both of these
propositions share the common assumption that social welfare is optimized if
prices are established by competitive market forces and not by monopolistic
coercion by dominant firms or misguided invocation of governmental coercion in
predatory pricing litigation. Structuring predatory pricing law thus requires a
comparison of the likely costs of deviating from a competitive market model
through monopolistic coercion or through misguided state coercion.
132
See supra text accompanying notes ____.
32
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
B presents the theoretical model of deviation from the norm caused by the
existence of predatory pricing law and compares the likely costs of monopolistic
predation to the likely costs of diminished price competition resulting from the
threat of liability for predatory pricing. Part C reports the results of a survey of
in-house counsel that I conducted to explore the degree to which predatory
pricing law influences pricing behavior by business executives.
133
F.M. Scherer & David Ross, INDUSTRIAL MARKET STRUCTURE AND ECONOMIC
PERFORMANCE 19-20 (3rd ed. 1990); Bork, supra n.1 at 97; Williamson, supra n. ___ at
290; Phillip Areeda & Donald F. Turner, Predatory Pricing and Related Practices Under
Section 2 of the Sherman Act, 88 Harv. L. Rev. 697, 711 (1975).
134
Areeda & Turner, supra n. ___ at 709-712.
135
Id. at 711.
136
Id. at 716.
137
F.M. Scherer, Predatory Pricing Under Section 2 of the Sherman Act, 89 Harv. L.
Rev. 868, 883-84 (1976). See also Areeda and Turner’s response to Scherer, Phillip
Areeda and Donald F. Turner, Scherer on Predatory Pricing: A Reply, 89 Harv. L. Rev.
891 (1976), and Scherer’s sur-reply to Areeda and Turner. F.M. Scherer, Some Last
Words on Predatory Pricing, 89 Harv. L. Rev. 901 (1976).
33
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
which Areeda and Turner refer,”138 but worried that Areeda and Turner’s
proposed legal rule would immunize short-term predatory price-cuts that would
lead to later supracompetitive pricing.139 Baumol similarly agreed with the
underlying premise that marginal cost pricing optimizes social welfare, but added
the further caveat that marginal cost pricing is “chimerical” in most real markets
since “pricing at marginal cost will not produce revenues equal to total
production costs.”140 Where marginal cost pricing is unsustainable in the long
run, Baumol would institute Ramsey pricing as the optimal deviation from
marginal cost that predatory pricing law should seek to attain.141 Under Ramsey
Pricing, prices deviate from marginal cost only so much as to make continued
production remunerative and deviations from marginal cost are distributed to
products with the least elastic demand so as to minimize deadweight losses.142
Thus, despite differences over the legal standards that should govern predatory
pricing claims, there is substantial agreement that more closely pricing
approximates marginal cost in a sustainable manner, the more that efficiency is
optimized.143
138
Williamson, supra n. ___ at 290.
139
Id. at 290, 340.
140
William J. Baumol, Quasi-Permanence of Price Reductions: A Policy for
Prevention of Predatory Pricing, 89 Yale L. J. 1, 21 (1979).
141
Id. at 20-22.
142
Frank Ramsey, A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation, 37 Econ. J. 47 (1927);
Baumol, supra n. ___ at 22; William J. Baumol, Ramsey Pricing, in 4 THE NEW
PALGRAVE: A DICTIONARY OF ECONOMICS 49, 49-51 (John Eatwell et al. eds., 1987); W.
Kip Viscusi, John M. Vernon & Joseph E. Harrington, Jr., ECONOMICS OF REGULATION
rd
AND ANTITRUST 350-53 (3 ed 2000).
143
See also Joskow & Klevorick, supra n. ___ at 223 (noting that any predatory
pricing standard that would forces prices to be kept above long-run marginal cost runs the
risk of preserving inefficient firms); Edlin, supra n. __ at 951 (“If the monopoly charges
a price in excess of its marginal cost, the monopoly creates an inefficiency compared to
an ideal world because output is restricted.”).
34
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
never created higher prices, nor a dangerous probability of higher prices.144 Such
non-predatory below-cost pricing is allocatively inefficient, even if it does not
lead to, or threaten, later supracompetitive pricing, because it induces the
consumption of goods by some consumers who value them at less than their cost
of production.145
144
Attempted monopolization through unsuccessful predatory pricing is sanctioned
in order to deter such conduct. See supra text accompany note ___. The probabilistic
harm in such cases justifies the invocation of legal sanctions to deter it. A separate issue
arises when an attempt to monopolize through predatory pricing has no significant
likelihood of succeeding and leads to lower prices. Such instances of “stupid predation”
might still be thought to cause resource misallocation because they would lead to the
consumption of the goods by some consumers who valued the goods at less than their
cost of production.
145
Scherer, supra n. ___ at 883. (“Resource misallocation occurs when there is a
divergence between the cost of additional output and the value of that output to
consumers. Output is too low when production stops short of the level at which price
equals marginal cost; it is too high when marginal cost exceeds the price.”); Joskow &
Klevorick, supra n. __ at 224 n. 31 (“If price is less than short-run marginal cost, and if
demand is at all elastic, the price will not give consumers the proper signal about the
scarcity value of the good. Thus, consumers will purchase too much of the good and as a
result, resources will be devoted to producing the particular good in the short run.”).
146
See Joseph F. Brodley, The Economic Goals of Antitrust: Efficiency, Consumer
Welfare, and Technological Progress, 62 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 1020, 1032 (1987)
(differentiating between allocative efficiency and consumer welfare).
147
Williamson, supra n. ___ at 291.
148
See Richard G. Lipsey & Kevin L. Lancaster, The General Theory of the Second
Best, 24 Rev. Econ. Stud. 11 (1956).
35
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
36
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
might still be optimized, given the constraint that firms need to cover total costs.
Typically, however, it will be difficult to determine whether a particular firm
accused of predation has engaged in Ramsey pricing since the focus of the
predatory pricing litigation is the product competitive with the plaintiff’s product
and not demand elasticities for all products in the defendant’s product
portfolio.149 Any claim that predatory pricing law achieved the social optimum
by forcing a firm to price above marginal cost and therefore ensured that equally
efficient competitor firms, pricing at the same level, could cover a pro rata share
of joint and common costs is generally unverifiable in the context of predatory
pricing litigation.150
Even conceding that some pricing floor above marginal cost would be
optimal in some cases, there remains the fact that predatory pricing law may set
the price floor above the optimal level. Conversely, the absence of predatory
pricing law could result in prices falling temporarily below the Ramsey-optimal
level and even below marginal cost, creating an initial allocative inefficiency due
to overconsumption, and ultimately resulting in monopoly pricing after weaker
firms are excluded from the market, creating an even greater long-run allocative
inefficiency due to deadweight losses. The optimal pricing point is a generally
unknowable abstraction that can rarely be pinpointed in actual cases, but,
wherever that point resides, it is clear that both the presence of predatory pricing
law and the absence of predatory pricing law would exert an upward pull away
from the optimal pricing point.
149
The process of adjudicating predatory pricing cases differs considerably from
establishing optimal prices for regulated industries. See Kenneth E. Train, OPTIMAL
REGULATION: THE ECONOMIC THEORY OF NATURAL MONOPOLY 115-40 (1991)
(discussing Ramsey Pricing solutions for regulated industries); Jerry Hausman & Howard
Shelanski, Economic Welfare and Telecommunications Regulation: The E-Rate Policy
for Universal-Service Subsidies, 16 Yale J. Reg. 19, 34-36 (1999) (discussing Ramsey
Pricing solutions for telecommunications regulation). In a predatory pricing case, the
court is not called upon to determine the optimal pricing in the relevant market given
elasticities of demand in all other affected markets, but only focuses on the single market
under consideration.
150
See Bolton, Brodley, & Riordan, supra n. ___ at 2272 (noting that allocating joint
and common costs is an “undertaking that lacks a precise methodology and is particularly
unsuited to jury resolution”). The difficulty of discovering the socially optimal pricing
point goes beyond merely finding out a rational way to allocate joint and common costs.
Ramsey pricing requires allocation of the joint and common costs by reference to the
demand elasticities of the various products in the firm’s portfolio.
37
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
If predatory pricing law exists at all, it will inevitably exert a pull away
from optimal pricing. If the predation cause of action were abolished, the
absence of predatory pricing law would also induce a deviation from optimal
pricing. Ideally, one would like to know whether the existence of predatory
pricing law or the absence of predatory pricing law would exert a greater
deviation. To study that empirically, however, one would need to examine an
economy in which predation was perfectly legal and compare it to one in which it
was illegal. The incidence and costs of predatory pricing in a regime without any
predatory pricing prohibition has been the matter of considerable academic
controversy, but remains highly speculative.154 It is unlikely to be ascertained
empirically except by reference to historical case studies of particular firms from
151
Joskow & Klevorick, supra n. ___ at ___.
152
Joskow and Klevorick acknowledge the possibility of “harassing litigation” by
“competitors seeking to protect themselves” but believe that these costs would be
minimized by the types of per se rules they reject. Id. at 242
153
Easterbrook, supra n. ___ at 322.
154
Compare Bork, supra n. ___ at 144 (arguing that unsophisticated theories of
predation have to “drastic overestimations of its likelihood”) and Easterbrook, supra n.
___ at 264 (opining that predatory pricing strategies are as common – and fictional – as
theories about dragons) with Bolton, Brodley & Riordan, supra n. ___ at 2241 (arguing
that predatory pricing is significantly more common than Chicago School proponents
have argued).
38
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
the time period before the adoption of the Sherman Act155 since predatory pricing
has long been illegal in the United States and in most other countries with similar
economic cultures.156 Any studies of business behavior today are affected by the
fact that predatory pricing is illegal.157
155
In particular, there has been a well-known debate over whether Standard Oil
engaged in predatory pricing in the pre-Sherman Act period. Compare John S. McGee,
Predatory Price Cutting: The Standard Oil (N.J.) Case, 1 J.L. & Econ. 137 (1958)
(arguing that Standard Oil did not engage in predatory pricing) with Elizabeth Granitz &
Benjamin Klein, Monopolization by “Raising Rivals’s Costs: The Standard Oil Case, 39
J.L. & Econ. 1 (1996) (arguing that Standard Oil’s conduct was predatory).
156
See Elhauge, supra n. ___ at 264 (discussing European Commission approach to
predatory pricing); Norman W. Hawker, Predatory Pricing Law in the United States and
Canada, 7 U. Miami Bus. L. Rev. 201 (1999) (discussing Canadian approach to
predatory pricing law); Ross Jones, An International Perspective on Anti-Competitive
Pricing Practices by Dominant Carriers & Regulatory Rules to Facilitate Competitive
Entry – Australia, 14 De Paul Bus. L. J. 243 (2002) (discussing Australian approach to
predatory pricing law).
157
See, for example, Roland H. Koller, The Myth of Predatory Pricing: An
Empirical Study, 4 Antitrust Law & Econ. Rev. 105 (1971) (examining litigated cases of
alleged predatory pricing and determining that they did not in fact involve predation);
Synder & Kauper, supra n. ___ at 572-73 (same).
39
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
Scenario A, the firm’s intentions are predatory and the price-cut will only be
profitable if it succeeds in excluding the new entrant and permitting the firm to
price above competitive levels. In Scenario B, the price-cut is not predatory and
is profit-maximizing simply as a response to new competition.
158
See Easterbrook, supra n. ___ at 330.
159
See Bolton, Brodley & Riordan, supra n. ___ at 2299-2320; Alvin K. Klevorick,
The Current State of the Law and Economics of Predatory Pricing, 83 Am. Econ. Rev.
162, 163 (1993); Yun Joo Jung, John H. Kagel & Dan Levin, On the Existence of
Predatory Pricing: An Experimental Study of Reputation and Entry Deterrence in the
Chain-Store Game, 25 RAND J. Econ. 72 (1994); John Roberts, A Signaling Model of
Predatory Pricing, 38 Oxford Econ. Papers 75 (1986); Paul Milgrom & John Roberts,
Predation, Reputation and Entry Deterrence, 27 J. Econ. Theory 280 (1982); David
Kreps & Robert Wilson, Reputation and Imperfect Information, 27 J. Econ. Theory 253
(1982).
160
Bolton, Brodley & Riordan, supra n. ___ at 2299-2320.
161
Id. at 2318.
162
Id. at 2320
163
Id.
40
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
followed by realization too late” story may account for the success of predation
schemes in some cases, but it does not provide a basis to believe that many
predation schemes ultimately go undetected. Once the prey learns of the
concealed predation scheme during the recoupment era, nothing prevents it from
acting on that knowledge and bringing a predatory pricing suit.
Predatory pricing is not like a back-room cartel agreement that will often
escape notice and therefore requires a heightened sanction to deter its
commission.164 In most cases, it will work only if rivals observe it and
understand it as a predatory commitment that the predator is willing to replicate
in the future. Predator firms should expect that their conduct will not go
unnoticed. And, if the conduct is observed, it is likely that a competitor will sue,
which will subject the predator to expensive predatory pricing litigation
regardless of the outcome. As to factor (i) in the predator’s calculus, then, the
likelihood of detection must be considered to be high.
164
See generally, Gary Becker, Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach, 76
J. Pol. Econ. 169 (1968). On the reasons for the treble damages multiplier, see Richard
Craswell, Deterrence and Damages: The Multiplier Principle and its Alternatives, 97
Mich. L. Rev. 2185 (1999); Robert H. Lande, Are Antitrust “Treble” Damages Really
Single Damages?, 54 Ohio St. L. J. 115 (1993); A. Mitchell Polinsky, Detrebling Versus
Decoupling Antitrust Damages: Lessons from the Theory of Enforcement, 74 Geo. L. J.
1231 (1986); Steven C. Salop & Lawrence J. White, Treble Damages Reform:
Implications of the Georgetown Project, 55 Antitrust L. J. 73 (1986); TREBLE-DAMAGES
REMEDY, ABA Section of Antitrust Law Monograph 13 (1986); Edward D. Cavanagh,
Detrebling Antitrust Damages: An Idea Whose Time Has Come?, 61 Tul. L. Rev. 777
(1987); William M. Landes, Optimal Sanctions for Antitrust Violations, 50 U Chi. L.
Rev. 652 (1983);
165
See supra text accompanying notes ___.
41
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
Given the legal status quo, unless the substantive legal standards are
substantially off the mark or the adjudication system is systematically biased in
favor of false negatives, predatory pricing would seem to be generally
unprofitable conduct. It is thus not surprising that so few plaintiffs prevail in
predatory pricing cases.166 There probably are not very many cases of bona fide
predatory pricing given the structure of incentives created by the Sherman Act
and the courts. Even if Chicago School adherents like Bork, Easterbrook, and
McGee are wrong to suppose that predatory pricing would occur rarely if ever in
an unregulated state, predatory pricing is unlikely to occur frequently given the
likelihood of detection and suit and the treble damages remedy.
As to factors (ii) and (iii), the costs of false positives to the defendant are
high – treble damages after leniency in proof of damages and attorney’s fees.169
By lowering its price, the defendant will only obtain profits at a competitive rate
of return since the price-cut is not one that creates monopoly power. In order for
166
See Bolton, Brodley, & Riordan supra n. ___ at 2258 (discussing poor success
rate of predatory pricing cases in last decade).
167
Bolton, Brodley & Riordan, supra n. ___ at 2259-60.
168
Edlin sees the incumbent firm’s greater economies of scale as a reason to prohibit
price-cuts for 12 to 18 months following the new firm’s entry. See Edlin, supra n. ___ .
Elhauge responds that the incumbent’s price-cuts may be justified as a response to the
fact that the new entry disrupts optimal price-discrimination schemes and lowers the
incumbent firm’s efficiency. Elhauge, supra n. ___.
169
See supra text accompanying notes ____.
42
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
the price cut to create an expectation of profits, the expected profits from the
increase in sales must exceed the expected probability of the suit times the cost of
defending the suit plus the probability-adjusted costs of an adverse judgment.
Since defense of litigation costs and the costs of an adverse judgment are many
times larger than the profits from the price cut, even relatively small likelihoods
of suit and of an adverse judgment can give the price cut a negative expected
value.
These two scenarios suggest that, given the current legal status quo,
predatory pricing is highly unlikely to occur and predatory pricing law is likely to
chill procompetitive price cutting in many cases. It remains to be examined
whether firms’ preferences with respect to risk, the uncertainty of adjudication,
and the presence of systematic directional biases in the adjudication of predatory
pricing cases ameliorate or aggravate predatory pricing law’s tendency to create
deviations from socially optimal marginal cost pricing.
170
Brooke Group, 509 U.S. at 222-23.
171
Areeda & Turner, supra n. ___.
172
Philip Areeda, Antitrust Law as Industrial Policy, in ANTITRUST, INNOVATION,
AND COMPETITIVENESS 29, 42 (Jorde & Teece, eds. 1992).
173
William J. Baumol, Predation and the Logic of the Average Variable Cost Test,
39 J. L. & Econ. 49 (1996) (affirming that the average variable cost test is optimal, if
variable costs are understood as avoidable costs).
174
McGahee v. Northern Propane Gas Co., 858 F.2d 1487, 1504 n. 38 (11th Cir.
1988) (“When average variable cost is appropriate to use, as well as determining what
costs are variable, is an issue of fact requiring expert testimony.”); Broadway Delivery
43
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
predatory pricing claims tend to be even more complex and create even greater
adjudicatory uncertainty.175
175
For example, Edlin defends his proposed test requiring the incumbent firm not to
cut its prices for 12 to 18 months following entry by a new firm that prices at least 20%
below the incumbent’s price on the grounds that it eliminates complex price/cost
comparisons and would be more easily administrable. Edlin, supra n. ___ at 949.
Elhauge shows that Edlin’s rule would create significant new complexities and
difficulties of administration. Elhauge, supra n. ___ at 808-21.
176
See generally, John E. Calfree & Richard Craswell, Some Effects of Uncertainty
on Compliance with Legal Standards, 70 Va. L. Rev. 965 (1984).
177
There may be circumstances where vagueness in liability rules or remedial
schemes are more efficient than predictable rules because of their superiority in deterring
undesirable conduct. Tom Baker, Alon Harel & Tamar Kugler, The Virtues of
Uncertainty in Law: An Experimental Approach, 89 Iowa L. Rev. 443 (2004). Predatory
pricing is not one of them, because the undesirable conduct is so intertwined with highly
desirable conduct. See generally Richard A. Posner, ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF LAW 242-
50 (5th ed. 1998) (discussing optimal deterrence schemes).
178
See Harry S. Gerla, The Pyschology of Predatory Pricing: Why Predatory
Pricing Pays, 39 Southwestern L. J. 755, 760-65 (1985).
44
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
Are the corporate managers for dominant firms – the ones mostly likely
to engage in predatory pricing or be chilled by predatory pricing law from cutting
prices – likely to be significantly risk-averse? Dominant firms are generally
diversified and therefore unlikely to be institutionally risk-averse.180 But pricing
decisions for particular products are often made by managers with responsibility
for only the particular products at issue, not the firm’s overall portfolio. Those
managers are likely to be risk-averse with respect to pricing decisions that affect
their personal compensation and reputation within the firm. The firm may try to
overcome this agency cost by aligning the managers’ interests with those of the
firm by giving the managers stock options and long-term employment contracts.
Whether such compensation structuring occurs at a sufficient level to overcome
individual managers’ risk aversion is uncertain. John Lott’s empirical study
found no significant difference in the executive compensation structure of firms
accused of predation as compared to comparable firms not accused of
predation.181 Lott also found that firms do not structure compensation packages
to reward managers for predatory behavior.182 By the same token, there is no
179
Harry Gerla argues that managers facing new entry may see not engaging in
predatory pricing as a risky strategy because taking no action will result in a loss of
market share. Gerla, supra n. ____ at 760; see also Chris Guthrie, 97 Nw. U. L. Rev.
1115, 1154-55 (2003); Harry S. Gerla, A Micro-Microeconomic Approach to Antitrust
Law; Games Managers Play, 86 Mich. L. Rev. 892, 906 n.69 (1988). But, in analyzing
manager’s incentives in considering price-cuts, it is not sufficient to focus on gains or
losses in the market. Expected gains or losses arising by virtue of predatory pricing law
itself must also be considered in formulating an optimal legal regime with respect to
predatory pricing.
180
Robert S. Pindyck & Daniel L. Rubinfeld, MICROECONOMICS 558-59(6th ed.
2005) (discussing risk preferences and corporate diversification strategies).
181
John R. Lott, ARE PREDATORY COMMITMENTS CREDIBLE: WHO SHOULD THE
COURTS BELIEVE? 36-49 (1999).
182
Id. at 49.
45
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
reason to believe that dominant firms provide their executives with strong
incentives to engage in non-predatory, but nonetheless legally risky, price-cuts.
183
Arthur Austin, The Jury System at Risk from Complexity, the New Media and
Deviancy, 73 Denv. U. L. Rev. 51, 52-59 (1995).
184
Id. at 54.
185
Id. at 56.
186
Posner, supra n. ___ at 215.
46
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
This leaves, finally, the question whether U.S. courts – the Supreme
Court in particular – exhibit any systematic, directional bias in the creation of the
liability rules governing predatory pricing. It is difficult to answer this question
without engaging the substance of the highly contested debate over what should
count as predatory or non-predatory, because one’s view of the Court’s
directional bias will be largely informed by whether one thinks that the Court’s
precedents have generally been correct or incorrect. Further, if there is a
directional bias toward underinclusion, this may be an artifact of judicial concern
that the predatory pricing cause of action could chill vigorous price competition
and be strategically misused by competitors.190 It is possible that the courts are
quite unbiased in their diagnosis of what conduct is predatory and non-predatory
but deliberately tend in the direction of underinclusion following crude intuitions
about the likely effects on price competition of more or less stringent predation
rules. If so, then the observed bias against predation claims should not count as
“error” but rather as a deliberate structuring of predatory pricing law to minimize
social costs by allowing some marginal cases of predation to go unremedied.
187
475 U.S. 574.
188
See generally Wesley J. Liebeler, Whither Predatory Pricing: From Areeda and
Turner to Matsushita, 61 Notre Dame L. Rev. 1052 (1986); James L. Warren & Mary B.
Cranston, Summary Judgment After Matsushita, 1 Sum-Antitrust 12 (1987).
189
Advo, Inc. v. Philadelphia Newspapers, Inc., 51 F.3d 1191, 1196 (3d Cir. 1995)
(Supreme Court precedent “creates a legal presumption, based on economic logic, that
predatory pricing is unlikely to threaten competition”); Stitt Spark Plug Co. v. Champion
Spark Plug Co., 840 F.2d 1253, 1255 (5th Cir. 1988) (Supreme Court creates “a
presumption that an allegation of such behavior is implausible”).
190
See supra text accompanying notes ___-____.
47
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
How far from the socially optimal pricing point – marginal cost or
Ramsey pricing – does the existence of predatory pricing law induce market
pricing to stray? Taken together, the various factors discussed above suggest that
predatory pricing law induces a substantial deviation from optimal pricing. To
summarize, predation is likely to be detected if it occurs and antitrust law, with
the treble damages remedy, fee-shifting, and liberality in proving damages,
provides a heavy sanction if it is. The incentives to engage in predatory pricing –
monopoly profits – would have to be enormous to overcome these disincentives
to predate. On the other hand, the strategic benefits to plaintiffs of predatory
pricing litigation and the magnitude of recoverable damages induce many
plaintiffs to file meritless predation suits. Even if the plaintiff’s likelihood of
success is small, the defendant has strong incentives to forgo price-cutting
because the costs of defending a meritless suit are large and even a small
probability of an adverse judgment translates into a significant expected cost
given the magnitude of possible damages. Predicting the outcome of a predatory
pricing lawsuit is difficult given the inherent complexity in the legal standard and
adjudication. Adjudicatory uncertainty coupled with risk aversion may lead
potential predators to forgo predation and potential innocent price-cutters to
forgo price cuts. Finally, there is almost certainly a systematic jury bias against
dominant firms that engage in aggressive price-cutting, which may or many not
be sufficiently corrected by the Matsushita gatekeeping function of the courts.
48
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
191
Lawrence J. White, Microeconomics and Antitrust in MBA Programs: What’s
Thought, and What’s Taught, 47 N.Y. L. School L. Rev. 87, 92-93 (2003).
192
Many smaller corporate law departments probably have no one with antitrust
expertise, particularly if the firm seldom faces antitrust matters.
49
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
Seventy in-house attorneys sent back the questionnaire. All but two
identified themselves as individuals responsible for antitrust matters and
provided useable responses. While this 8% response rate is low and places limits
on the conclusions that can be drawn from the responses, there is reason to
believe that the respondents represent a more significant proportion of the in-
house attorneys with exposure to predatory pricing matters than the general pool
of all in-house lawyers. The majority of the respondents work for manufacturing
(51%), wholesale (8%), or retail (4%) companies, which are generally more
likely than firms in other industries to face predatory pricing issues because of
their industry cost structures.193 Further, the majority of the respondents work for
large corporations – 59% had over $1 billion in annual revenues and 26% had
between $200 million and $1 billion in annual revenues. The attorneys who
responded were probably more willing than the general population of in-house
attorneys to fill out the questionnaire because their firms did face predatory
pricing matters. This probable response bias suggests that the survey results
provide little information on the effects of predatory pricing law on corporations
generally,194 but may more accurately reflect the situation in large corporations of
the kind that are likely to affected by predatory pricing law.
193
See Richard Craswell & Mark R. Fratrik, Predatory Pricing Theory Applied: The
Case of Supermarkets v. Warehouse Stores, 36 Case W. Res. L. Rev. 1, 47-48 (discussing
susceptibility of manufacturing and retail industries to predation).
194
Indeed, the vast majority of corporations are unlikely ever to confront a predatory
pricing issue because there is no dominant firm in the market or because the industry cost
structure does not lend itself to predation or predation claims.
195
Predatory pricing was defined in the questionnaire to include “any claim that a
price was too low and therefore exclusionary of competition.” International dumping
claims were excluded. In order to exclude responses concerning the pre-Matsushita and
Brooke Group era, respondents were instructed to limit their responses to matters that
were true within the past 15 years.
50
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
interested to learn the extent to which in-house lawyers provide advice on the
appropriate measure of cost below which prices should not be set. Of the firms
that have an antitrust compliance manual with a provision about predatory
pricing, only 27% contained information about what measure of cost should be
considered in setting prices. Of those, three firm policy manuals establish “cost”
without further description as the measure, three establish “average variable cost”
as the appropriate measure, and two adopt some other, unspecified measure of
cost. When the lawyers gave direct advice to business executives on predatory
pricing, as opposed to merely including it in a policy manual, the lawyers were
more likely to give instruction on the appropriate measure of cost. 79% of the
time they provided counsel on the appropriate measure of cost. 42% advised that
“cost” without further description was the appropriate measure, 29% advised that
“average variable cost” was appropriate, and the remainder advised that some
other measure of cost was appropriate.
196
A further series of questions sought information on the outcome of the litigation if
it did occur. In the six cases where private litigation occurred, defendant won summary
judgment four times, one case ended in a settlement, and the other case resulted in some
other, unspecified, outcome.
51
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
other seven chose “differently.”197 The respondents were also asked whether
they believed that predatory pricing law had any effect on the way in which their
competitors priced. Only two respondents said yes; the others split between “no”
(58%) and “don’t know” (38%).
Although the poor response rate and small response pool limits the
conclusions that can be drawn, the responses suggest the following tentative
observations: At least some rudiments of predatory pricing law are broadly
communicated to executives in large corporations involved in pricing decisions
in manufacturing, retail, and wholesale industries – industries in which predation
is likely to arise as an issue. Not surprisingly given the division among lower
courts on the appropriate measure of cost governing predation claims, the advice
given to corporate executives often does not include specification of a particular
cost threshold below which revenues must not fall. Although some firms have
adopted average variable cost as the presumptive standard, the advice usually
appears to be more general and non-specific. Competitor complaints about
aggressive pricing are not pervasive but occur with some regularity. They result
in litigation only about half of the time, but may occasionally have effects on
pricing even when litigation does not occur. Finally, it is difficult for in-house
lawyers to find a direct causal relationship between predatory pricing law and
higher prices. Pricing decisions are complex and multifaceted, and even when
predatory pricing law induces a firm to change its pricing structure, it will not
always be clear that a net price increase results.
Missing from this survey is one critical question that the respondents
would not have been in a position objectively to answer: whether their firms had
ever considered or actually engaged in predatory pricing. If so, the competitor
threats that never resulted in litigation may count as a virtue and the counseling
about predatory pricing may have beneficial effects. This question is hard to
answer so long as the very definition of predation remains murky and indistinct
and the economic attributes of exclusion and recoupment highly contested. The
most that surveys of this kind can tell us is that predatory pricing law has a high
or low degree of influence on business behavior. Whatever the answer to that
question, one must still determine what degree of influence on pricing behavior is
optimal given the constraints inherent in adjudication. To that question we turn
in the final Part.
197
The implications of the “differently” response are uncertain. Most likely,
respondents who chose this category were unwilling to commit to the view that their
firms had charged higher prices as a result of predatory pricing law, although they had
seen evidence that the firm had restructured some pricing scheme – for example, by
eliminating a price discrimination mechanism or a bundled rebate program – in response
to predatory pricing law.
52
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
Although much has been written about predatory pricing law and the
courts have developed a complex body of governing law, many of the hardest,
and most fundamental questions await conclusive answers. Are predation
theories available only to equally or more efficient competitors, or can less
efficient competitors whose efficiency development was stymied by predation
also assert claims?198 What is the appropriate measure of cost below which
prices cannot be set?199 Does predation necessarily entail the sacrifice of short-
run profits, or is predation without sacrifice possible?200 Do the same predation
rules apply to multi-product discounting as to single product discounting?201
These questions were largely unanswered in the first wave of predatory pricing
scholarship in the 1970s and early 1980s and the Supreme Court decisions of the
late 1980s and early 1990s that adopted the Chicago School perspective that
predation was rare and predation theory a threat to robust price competition.202
Answers to these questions are being, and will continue to be, given in the courts
and in legal scholarship in a second wave of predatory pricing conceptualization.
The second wave of scholarship and judicial development is likely to draw on
advances in economic theory, particularly in behavioral economics and game
198
See supra note ___.
199
See supra note ___.
200
In this regard, there appears to be an emerging divergence between the accepted
wisdom in the courts and the analytical perspective of commentators. Compare Barr
Laboratories, Inc. v. Abbott Laboratories, 978 F.2d 98, 109 (3d Cir. 1992) (holding that
“predatory intent reflects a competitor's willingness to sacrifice present revenues in order
to achieve monopoly profits in the future”); Northeastern Telephone Co. v. AT&T, 651
F.2d 76, 86 (2d Cir. 1981) (holding that predatory pricing is “the deliberate sacrifice of
present revenues for the purpose of driving rivals out of the market and then recouping
the losses through higher profits earned in the absence of competition.” ) and AD/SAT v.
Associated Press, 920 F. Supp. 1287, 1301 (S.D.N.Y. 1996)(citation omitted), aff'd, 181
F.3d 216 (2d Cir. 1999) (asserting that predatory pricing requires “the deliberate sacrifice
of present revenues for the purpose of driving rivals out of the market and then recouping
the losses through higher profits earned in the absence of competition”) with Edlin, supra
n. ___ at 945, (describing theory of predation without sacrifice of short-run profits); Einer
Elhauge, Defining Better Monopolization Standards, 56 Stan. L. Rev. 253, 272 (2003)
(criticizing reliance on sacrifice notions to define predation); Andrew I Gavil,
Exclusionary Distribution Strategies by Dominant Firms: Striking a Better Balance, 72
Antitrust L.J. 3, 56 (2004) (criticizing sacrifice theory of predation).
201
See Crane, supra n. ___.
202
See supra text accompanying notes ___.
53
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
theory,203 and these influences may push courts in a direction more receptive to
predation claims.
A. Decisional Rules
203
See generally Bolton, Brodley & Riordan, supra n. ___; Tor, supra n. ___.
204
See generally Meir Dan-Cohen, Decision Rules and Conduct Rules: On Acoustic
Separation in Criminal Law, 97 Harv. L. Rev. 625 (1984).
54
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
being overinclusive.”205 Edlin further argues that “[t]he probabilities of these two
types of errors depend . . . upon the underlying plausibility of predatory
pricing.”206 But underinclusion need not be an error at all, even if predatory
pricing is plausible and frequent. Herbert Hovenkamp aptly notes that “[u]ntil
antitrust tribunals are able to identify above cost prices as anticompetitive in a
reliable manner, a consumer-oriented antitrust policy has no choice but to adhere
to the admittedly underdeterrent below cost pricing requirements of the Areeda-
Turner or some similar rule.”207 Underinclusion – prohibiting less conduct than
all predatory and socially costly conduct – could be an optimal decisional
strategy if prohibiting the marginal instances of predation would invite greater
strategic misuse of predatory pricing law or self-policed failures to engage in
innocent price cuts. Further, the Supreme Court has quite reasonably justified its
current approach to predatory pricing as deliberately underinclusive, even
without regard to the possibility of false positives, because above-cost “predatory
pricing schemes [are] ‘beyond the practical ability of a judicial tribunal to
control.’”208 Even if the exact line separating predation from beneficial price cuts
could be identified with analytical precision, courts would be ill-advised to draw
the legal line in the same place as the analytical line if the collateral costs to the
legal line-drawing were great.
205
Edlin, supra n. ___ at 953.
206
Id.
207
Hovenkamp, supra n. ___ at 314-15.
208
Verizon Communications Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S.
398, 414 (2004) (citing Brooke Group, 509 U.S. at 223); see also Joseph F. Brodley,
Antitrust Standing in Private Merger Cases: Reconciling Private Incentives and Public
Enforcement Goals, 94 Mich. L. Rev. 1, (1995) (noting that predatory pricing plaintiffs
“must overcome deliberatively underinclusive liability rules”).
55
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
socially beneficial price-cuts, given the risk of adjudicatory error,209 the costs of
defending even a successful suit to conclusion, and the disproportionate costs in
the event of an adverse judgment. Further, setting the liability rule at exactly x
would provide greater opportunities for firms to use predatory pricing law
strategically to organize tacit collusion schemes than if the liability rule were set
at (x + y). Thus, even if a court were absolutely confident in x as the correct
analytical line, setting the substantive liability rule at (x + y) would produce a
more efficient outcome.
As discussed in Part II, Matsushita suggests that the solution to juror bias
is for courts carefully to scrutinize the soundness of predation theories at the
summary judgment stage. While this may work out to a mandate of deliberate
adjudicatory underinclusion of what cases may be given to juries, there are more
explicit ways to achieve the same result. For example, standards establishing the
necessary quantum of evidence can operate optimally to calibrate social behavior
when adjustments in the liability rule are inadvisable.210 If there are expressive
or operational constraints on deliberate underinclusion in the specification of the
liability rule for predatory pricing, then the costs of maintaining a prohibition on
predatory pricing could be minimized by requiring plaintiffs to prove predation
by a some heightened quantum of proof – for example, clear and convincing
209
Ex ante, the perceived risk of adjudicatory error simply cannot be eliminated by
courts, even if courts have a high degree of confidence in the correctness of the
substantive liability rule.
210
Richard A. Bierschbach & Alex Stein,Overenforcement, 93 Geo. L. J. 6 (2005).
56
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
211
Id. at ___.
212
See n. ___ supra.
213
For example, in Brooke Group the parties agreed that average variable cost was
the appropriate measure, as one would expect given that Phillip Areeda represented
Liggett and Robert Bork represented Brown & Williamson. 509 U.S. at 211.
214
See Rebel Oil Co., Inc. v. Atlantic Richfield Co., 146 F.3d 1088 (9th Cir.), cert.
denied, 525 U.S. 1017 (1998); International Travel Arrangers v. NWA, Inc., 991 F.2d
1389 (8th Cir.), cert. denied, 510 U.S. 932 (1993).
57
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
limited to the question of the appropriate cost measure. The Court recently
denied certiorari in a case involving the appropriate treatment of bundled rebates
– a form of multi-product price discounting – after the Solicitor General, Justice
Department, and Federal Trade Commission advised that it would be better to
deny certiorari because the issues presented were “novel and difficult” and
because the Third Circuit’s en banc “ruling does not conflict with the decisions
of any other court of appeals.”215
Given the uncertainty costs of predation law and the glacial pace of
Supreme Court rule-making in antitrust, it is doubtful that the creation of
predation liability rules through incremental common law development is
desirable. Agency rule-making of prospective pricing rules would be superior,
although neither the Justice Department nor the Federal Trade Commission
currently has the statutory authority to make predation rules that would apply to
private predation lawsuits, the primary source of concern.217 If the predatory
pricing cause of action is to be maintained, Congress should consider delegating
such rule-making authority to the FTC.
215
Brief of the United States as Amici Curiae, 2004 WL 1205191, at 8 (May 28,
2004).
216
Thomas A. Lambert, Evaluating Bundled Discounts, forthcoming Minn. L. Rev.
(2005).
217
The FTC has the authority to promulgate substantive competition rules, National
Petroleum Refiners Ass'n v. FTC, 482 F.2d 672 (1973), although any such rules would
not apply to private lawsuits under the Sherman Act.
58
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
B. Remedial Rules
Much of the reason that predation law exerts a pull away from optimal
pricing, requiring the suggested adjustments to liability and adjudicatory rules
suggested above, has to do with the remedial structure of U.S. antitrust law. In
particular, the treble damages remedy, unilateral fee-shifting, competitor
enforcement, and liberal discovery rules provide opportunities for abuse.
Alterations of some of these features of antitrust law in predatory pricing cases
could have significant positive effects without losing the primary deterrent value
of predatory pricing law.
218
Baumol & Ordover, supra n. ___ at 263 (“One should consider both the use of a
multiple smaller than three, at least in those types of cases, such as predatory pricing . . .
and in some types of cases one might even consider [single damages].”); Easterbrook,
supra n. ___ at 329-30.
219
Easterbrook, supra n. ___ at 327.
220
Id.
59
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
then little more incentive is necessary to deter predation given the small
likelihood that it will not be detected. Eliminating the trebling rule for predation
cases would be a simple way of minimizing the costs of predatory pricing law.
The chilling effects of predation law do not arise exclusively from the
fact that competitors are the primary enforcers, but almost so. Virtually every
private predatory pricing case is brought by a competitor, and competitors have
unique incentives to misuse predatory pricing law to chill price competition.
Competitors want to see higher prices both in the short run and in the long run.
The law tolerates their complaint that prices were too low because of their further
allegation that the low prices would eventually lead to higher prices. But the law
does not require proof of actual higher prices. In an attempted monopolization
through predatory pricing case, it is sufficient to prove that defendant’s low
prices created a dangerous probability of subsequent higher prices.221 Thus,
competitor-plaintiffs are often in the position of asserting that defendant’s prices
were anticompetitively low merely based on the speculation that, left unchecked,
defendant would have driven plaintiff from the market and raised its prices –
even though that never actually happened.
Giving firms the standing to challenge their rivals’ prices as too low on
the theory that higher prices might eventually emerge is like asking the fox to
guard the henhouse. Consumers – the intended beneficiaries of antitrust law –
have exactly the opposite incentives as competitors. They prefer sustainably low
prices, and therefore make far better-intentioned predation enforcers than
business rivals of the “predator.” If predatory pricing were a frequent and
successful enterprise, one would expect to see many class action lawsuits by
overcharged consumers.222 Such lawsuits are extremely rare,223 which is probably
more a testament to the absence of successful predation schemes than to
221
See supra n. ___.
222
See Herbert Hovenkamp, Tying Arrangements and Class Actions, 36 Vand. L.
Rev. 213, 236 (1983) (discussing possibility of class action lawsuits for overcharges
following predatory pricing and recoupment).
223
Such a class action case is pending against 3M following a jury verdict by 3M’s
rival, LePage’s, in case involving allegedly exclusionary bundled rebates. See supra n.
___. The case has a number of difficulties. At least one of 3M’s ostensibly injured
customers and plaintiff class members – Staples – joined an amicus curiae brief urging
the Supreme Court to reverse LePage’s jury verdict. See Brief of The Boeing
Corporation; Brunswick Corp., Caterpillar Inc., Honeywell International Inc., Northwest
Airlines Inc., Staples, Inc., and Xerox Corp. as Amici Curiae in Support of Petition, 2003
WL 22428377. Further, since 3M never succeeded in driving LePage’s from the market,
the customers were beneficiaries of the allegedly predatory prices without having to
endure a period of recoupment.
60
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
224
Easterbook, supra n. ___ at 331.
225
Id.
226
Theoretically, consumers could sue for an injunction against attempted
monopolization through predation, but the likelihood that consumers would seek
equitable remedies in cases without damages is remote.
227
As discussed in the text accompanying notes ___, competitors can strategically
misuse even government-enforced predation law and, even if consumers had exclusive
61
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
3. Bilateral Fee-Shifting
________________________________________________________
private standing, competitors could manipulate their customers for anticompetitive ends.
However, eliminating competitor standing would substantially reduce the incidence of
strategic misuse by taking away a firm’s right to seek treble damages and attorney’s fees
for injuries resulting from its competitor’s low prices.
228
See supra text accompanying notes ___-____.
62
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
229
Western Parcel Exp. v. United Parcel Service of America, Inc., 190 F.3d 974, 975
(9th Cir 1999) (reporting that defendant prevailed on summary judgment after initial
phase of discovery, limited by stipulation of the parties to issue of defendant’s market
power).
230
Rebel Oil Co., Inc. v. Atlantic Richfield Co., 133 F.R.D. 41, 45 (D. Nev.1990)
(limiting discovery to facts concerning barriers to entry and not permitting discovery as
to pricing matter relevant to predatory pricing claims until plaintiff established the
existence of barriers to entry).
231
See supra. n. ____.
63
Predatory Pricing – Crane – April 2005 Draft
CONCLUSION
64