"Unfair Methods of Competition" Rulemaking
"Unfair Methods of Competition" Rulemaking
"Unfair Methods of Competition" Rulemaking
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
The University of Chicago Law Review is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and
extend access to The University of Chicago Law Review
A key feature of antitrust today is that the law is developed entirely through
adjudication. Evidence suggests that this exclusive reliance on adjudication has
failed to deliver a predictable, efficient, or participatory antitrust regime. Antitrust
litigation and enforcement are protracted and expensive, requiring extensive discov-
ery and costly expert analysis. In theory, this approach facilitates nuanced and fact-
specific analysis of liability and well-tailored remedies. But in practice, the exclusive
reliance on case-by-case adjudication has yielded a system of enforcement that gen-
erates ambiguity, drains resources, privileges incumbents, and deprives individuals
and firms of any real opportunity to participate in the process of creating substantive
antitrust rules. It is difficult to quantify this harm.
This Essay argues that rulemaking under § 5 of the Federal Trade Commis-
sion Act should supplement antitrust adjudication, and that this institutional shift
would lower enforcement costs, reduce ambiguity, and facilitate greater democratic
participation. We build on existing scholarship to debunk the view that the Federal
Trade Commission (FTC) does not have competition rulemaking authority pursuant
to the Administrative Procedure Act conferring Chevron deference, and trace legis-
lative history to underscore how Congress designed the FTC to play a unique insti-
tutional role.
We close by outlining an initial set of factors that should weigh in favor of
rulemaking: when there is significant learning from past enforcement and when pri-
vate litigation would be unlikely. Finally, we pose questions in the context of the
FTC’s recent hearings to prompt further discussion on where this unused tool would
be most useful.
† Commissioner, Federal Trade Commission. The views expressed here are Com-
missioner Chopra’s and do not necessarily reflect those of the Commission or any other
individual Commissioner.
†† Academic Fellow, Columbia Law School; Counsel, Subcommittee on Antitrust,
Commercial, and Administrative Law, US House Committee on the Judiciary; former Le-
gal Fellow, Federal Trade Commission. This Essay reflects Ms. Khan’s views and not those
of the US House Committee on the Judiciary or any of its members. For thoughtful en-
gagement and comments, we are grateful to Scott Hemphill, William Kovacic, Fiona Scott
Morton, Nancy Rose, Jonathan Sallet, Carl Shapiro, Sandeep Vaheesan, and Joshua
Wright, as well as staff at the FTC and participants in the Symposium on Reassessing the
Chicago School of Antitrust Law at The University of Chicago Law School. We also thank
the editors of The University of Chicago Law Review for careful editing.
357
INTRODUCTION
Open, competitive markets are a foundation of economic lib-
erty. A lack of competition, meanwhile, can enable dominant
firms to exercise their market power in harmful ways. In uncom-
petitive markets, firms with market power can raise prices for
consumers, depress wages for workers, and choke off new en-
trants and other upstarts, undermining innovation and business
dynamism.
Given these far-reaching effects, the Federal Trade Commis-
sion (FTC)’s mandate to promote fair competition is critical. The
Commission’s recent hearings provided an important opportunity
for it to reflect on ways to increase the effectiveness of the Com-
mission’s enforcement of the antitrust laws. This is especially im-
portant given that these hearings came against the backdrop of
concerns about increasing concentration and declining competi-
tion across sectors of the US economy.
When establishing the FTC over a century ago, Congress
sought to harness the value of an expert administrative agency to
collect market data, analyze it rigorously, and use this analysis
to inform enforcement and policymaking. As the FTC reflects on
how the agency advances its competition policy and enforcement
goals, a key aim of this exercise should be to examine its full set
of tools and authorities—not only those that the Commission has
traditionally relied upon.
The Commission should approach this inquiry with three
goals in mind:
(1) Reduce ambiguity around what the law is, enhancing
predictability;
(2) Reduce the burdens of litigation and enforcement,
enhancing efficiency; and
(3) Reduce opacity and certain undemocratic features of
the current approach, enhancing transparency and
participation.
In this Essay, we begin by explaining how the current ap-
proach to antitrust has delivered a regime that generates ambi-
guity, drains resources, and deprives individuals and firms of any
real opportunity to participate in the process of creating substan-
tive antitrust rules. Second, we explore how the FTC can bolster
antitrust enforcement through participatory rulemaking. We close
by identifying two factors to guide when participatory rulemaking
might be especially apt: in situations where (1) there exists an
1 Richard D. Cudahy and Alan Devlin, Anticompetitive Effect, 95 Minn L Rev 59, 87
(2010). See also Maurice E. Stucke, Does the Rule of Reason Violate the Rule of Law?, 42
UC Davis L Rev 1375, 1440 (2009).
2 C. Scott Hemphill, An Aggregate Approach to Antitrust: Using New Data and Rule-
making to Preserve Drug Competition, 109 Colum L Rev 629, 674 (2009).
3 Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc v PSKS, Inc, 551 US 877, 917 (2007) (Breyer
dissenting) (“One cannot fairly expect judges and juries in such cases to apply complex
economic criteria without making a considerable number of mistakes, which themselves
may impose serious costs.”).
4 See, for example, id at 916 (“How easily can courts identify instances in which the
benefits are likely to outweigh potential harms? My own answer is, not very easily.”); FTC
v Actavis, 570 US 136, 173 (2013) (Roberts dissenting) (“[T]he majority declares that such
questions should henceforth be scrutinized by antitrust law’s unruly rule of reason. Good
luck to the district courts that must, when faced with a patent settlement, weigh the ‘likely
anticompetitive effects, redeeming virtues, market power, and potentially offsetting legal
considerations present in the circumstances.’”).
11 Michael R. Baye and Joshua D. Wright, Is Antitrust Too Complicated for General-
ist Judges? The Impact of Economic Complexity and Judicial Training on Appeals, 54 J L
& Econ 1, 2 (2011).
12 Rebecca Haw, Adversarial Economics in Antitrust Litigation: Losing Academic
Consensus in the Battle of the Experts, 106 Nw U L Rev 1261, 1263 (2012).
13 Id at 1261.
14 Jesse Eisinger and Justin Elliott, These Professors Make More Than a Thousand
Federal Trade Commission Expert Witness Services *3 (Nov 14, 2019), archived at
https://perma.cc/UA8A-2FUS (“During FY 2015 and FY 2016, [The Bureau of Competition]
obligated an average $9.3 million on expert services and this spending continues to in-
crease. In FY 2017, spending totaled over $10.7 million and approached $14.9 million in
FY 2018.”).
16 The FTC Office of Inspector General identified soaring expert costs as one of the
two top management challenges facing the Commission in 2019. Federal Trade Commis-
sion Office of Inspector General, Management Challenges Facing the Federal Trade Com-
mission (Sept 27, 2019), archived at https://perma.cc/23VE-ETX5.
17 See, for example, Kevin Caves and Hal Singer, When the Econometrician Shrugged:
Identifying and Plugging Gaps in the Consumer Welfare Standard, 26 Geo Mason L Rev 395,
424 (2019) (“[I]t is unlikely that the slow pace of antitrust enforcement could keep up with
the fast pace of high-tech markets.”).
18 Verizon Communications, Inc v Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 US 398,
414 (2004).
democratic participation or oversight, see generally Harry First and Spencer Weber Waller,
Antitrust’s Democracy Deficit, 81 Fordham L Rev 2543 (2013).
25 See Appendix.
26 Daniel A. Crane, Debunking Humphrey’s Executor, 83 Geo Wash L Rev 1835,
1859 (2015).
27 Daniel A. Crane, The Institutional Structure of Antitrust Enforcement 130 (Oxford
2011) (“The FTC was designed as a complement to, not as a substitute for, the Justice
Department. The FTC Act’s legislative history evidences a Congressional intent that ‘[f]ar
from being regarded as a rival of the Justice Department . . . the [FTC] was envisioned as
an aid to them.’”).
Federal Trade Commission Act28 (FTC Act) and (2) extensive au-
thority to collect confidential business information and conduct
industry studies, as established by § 6(b) of the FTC Act.29
By designing the Commission this way, Congress sought to
create a regime where the law developed not just through the ju-
diciary but also through an expert agency. Congress envisioned
that the Commission’s data collection from market participants
would ensure that the agency stayed abreast of evolving business
practices and market trends, and that it would use this expertise
to establish market-wide standards clarifying what practices con-
stituted an “unfair method of competition,” even as the market
evolved. This unique role would complement adjudication pur-
sued by the Attorney General, state attorneys general, and pri-
vate parties.30 Indeed, Congress expected that federal judges and
other policymakers would defer to the Commission on competition
matters because it would “serve as an indispensable instrument
of information and publicity, as a clearinghouse for the facts by
which both the public mind and the managers of great business
28 15 USC § 45(a). Judicial decisions that have reviewed the legislative history con-
firm that the Commission enjoys flexibility in determining which specific acts or practices
constitute “unfair methods of competition.” Senator Francis Newlands, the statute’s chief
sponsor, said that § 5 would “have such an elastic character that it [would] meet every
new condition and every new practice that may be invented with a view to gradually bring-
ing about monopoly through unfair competition.” Federal Trade Commission Act, 63d
Cong, 2d Sess in 51 Cong Rec 12024 (July 13, 1914). See also, for example, Atlantic Refin-
ing Co v FTC, 381 US 357, 367 (1965) (“The Congress intentionally left development of the
term ‘unfair’ to the Commission rather than attempting to define ‘the many and variable
unfair practices which prevail in commerce . . . .’ In thus divining that there is no limit to
business ingenuity and legal gymnastics the Congress displayed much foresight.”); FTC v
Standard Education Society, 86 F2d 692, 696 (2d Cir 1936):
The Commission has a wide latitude in such matters; its powers are not confined
to such practices as would be unlawful before it acted; they are more than pro-
cedural; its duty in part at any rate, is to discover and make explicit those unex-
pressed standards of fair dealing which the conscience of the community may
progressively develop.
29 15 USC § 46(b). Section 6(b) of the FTC Act authorizes the Commission to require
the Commission could “provide clear rules and direction for business that courts had been
incapable of providing.” Crane, 83 Geo Wash L Rev at 1859 (cited in note 26), referencing
Woodrow Wilson, Address to a Joint Session of Congress on Trusts and Monopolies (Amer-
ican Presidency Project, Jan 20, 1914), archived at https://perma.cc/683G-WWVS (“And
the business men of the country desire something more than that the menace of legal
process in these matters be made explicit and intelligible. They desire the advice, the def-
inite guidance and information which can be supplied by an administrative body, an in-
terstate trade commission.”).
by enforcing the antitrust and consumer protection laws as a plaintiff, no more expert than
the executive branch agencies doing the same thing.”).
36 Jan M. Rybnicek and Joshua D. Wright, Defining Section 5 of the FTC Act: The
Failure of the Common Law Method and the Case for Formal Agency Guidelines, 21 Geo
Mason L Rev 1287, 1304 (2014).
37 Id at 1288.
38 60 Stat 237 (1946), codified as amended in various sections of Title 5.
39 We are not the first to suggest that the Commission engage in competition rule-
making. See, for example, Rebecca Haw, Amicus Briefs and the Sherman Act: Why Anti-
trust Needs a New Deal, 89 Tex L Rev 1247, 1288–89 (2011); Hemphill, 109 Colum L Rev
at 673–82 (cited in note 2); Justin Hurwitz, Chevron and the Limits of Administrative
Antitrust, 76 U Pitt L Rev 209, 250–52 (2014); Sandeep Vaheesan, Resurrecting ‘A Com-
prehensive Charter of Economic Liberty’: The Latent Power of the Federal Trade Commis-
sion, 19 U Pa J Bus L 645, 651–57 (2017).
40 The Supreme Court weighed in on the relative benefits and drawbacks of adjudi-
cation and rulemaking in SEC v Chenery Corp, 332 US 194 (1947). For representative
scholarship, see generally David L. Shapiro, The Choice of Rulemaking or Adjudication in
the Development of Administrative Policy, 78 Harv L Rev 921 (1965); J. Skelly Wright, The
Courts and the Rulemaking Process: The Limits of Judicial Review, 59 Cornell L Rev 375
(1974); Glen O. Robinson, The Making of Administrative Policy: Another Look at Rulemak-
ing and Adjudication and Administrative Procedure Reform, 118 U Pa L Rev 485 (1970);
M. Elizabeth Magill, Agency Choice of Policymaking Form, 71 U Chi L Rev 1383 (2004);
William T. Mayton, The Legislative Resolution of the Rulemaking Versus Adjudication
Problem in Agency Lawmaking, 1980 Duke L J 103; Richard K. Berg, Re-examining Policy
Procedures: The Choice Between Rulemaking & Adjudication, 38 Admin L Rev
149 (1986).
favorable settlements using “strong-arm” tactics without even defining what § 5 is. See
Hurwitz, 76 U Pitt L Rev at 262 (cited in note 39) (“The FTC has shown an alarming
willingness in recent years to threaten litigation under Section 5 without feeling the need
to define its understanding of Section 5’s contours. It has leveraged the uncertain bounds
of Section 5 to demand extrajudicial settlements from numerous firms, especially in high-
tech industries.”).
44 5 USC § 553(b)–(c). The requirement under § 553 to provide the public with ade-
quate notice of a proposed rule is generally achieved through the publication of a notice of
proposed rulemaking in the Federal Register. The APA requires that the notice of pro-
posed rulemaking include “(1) a statement of the time, place, and nature of public rule
making proceedings; (2) reference to the legal authority under which the rule is proposed;
and (3) either the terms or substance of the proposed rule or a description of the subjects
and issues involved.” 5 USC § 553(b)(1)–(3).
45 5 USC § 553(d).
tal principle in our legal system is that laws which regulate per-
sons or entities must give fair notice of conduct that is forbidden
or required.”46 Clear rules also help deliver consistent enforce-
ment and predictable results. Reducing ambiguity about what the
law is will enable market participants to channel their resources
and behavior more productively and will allow market entrants
and entrepreneurs to compete on more of a level playing field.
Second, establishing rules could help relieve antitrust en-
forcement of steep costs and prolonged trials. Identifying ex ante
what types of conduct constitute “unfair method[s] of competition”
would obviate the need to establish the same exclusively through
ex post, case-by-case adjudication. Targeting conduct through
rulemaking, rather than adjudication, would likely lessen the
burden of expert fees or protracted litigation, potentially saving
significant resources on a present-value basis.47
Moreover, establishing a rule through APA rulemaking can
be faster than litigating multiple cases on a similar subject mat-
ter. For taxpayers and market participants, the present value of
net benefits through the promulgation of a clear rule that reduces
the need for litigation is higher than pursuing multiple, pro-
tracted matters through litigation. At the same time, rulemaking
is not so fast that it surprises market participants. Establishing
a rule through participatory rulemaking can often be far more ef-
ficient. This is particularly important in the context of declining
government enforcement relative to economic activity, as docu-
mented by the ABA.48
And third, rulemaking would enable the Commission to es-
tablish rules through a transparent and participatory process, en-
suring that everyone who may be affected by a new rule has the
opportunity to weigh in on it, granting the rule greater legiti-
macy.49 APA procedures require that an agency provide the public
with meaningful opportunity to comment on the rule’s content
through the submission of written “data, views, or arguments.”50
46 FCC v Fox Television Stations, 567 US 239, 253 (2012). See also FTC v Colgate
Palmolive Co, 380 US 374, 392 (1965) (noting that FTC orders “should be clear and precise
in order that they may be understood by those against whom they are directed”).
47 To be sure, the agency may face litigation challenges to the rule itself, though these
risks can be mitigated through the development of a clear record of empirical evidence.
48 ABA Section of Antitrust Law, Controlling Costs at *1 (cited in note 9).
49 See David Fontana, Reforming the Administrative Procedure Act: Democracy Index
Rulemaking, 74 Fordham L Rev 81, 102–03 (2005) (observing that greater public partici-
pation in notice-and-comment rulemaking can generate greater public support for the rule
that the process ultimately delivers).
50 5 USC § 553(c).
The agency must then consider and address all submitted com-
ments before issuing the final rule. If an agency adopts a rule with-
out observing these procedures, a court may strike down the rule.51
This process is far more participatory than adjudication. Un-
like judges, who are confined to the trial record when developing
precedent-setting rules and standards, the Commission can put
forth rules after considering a comprehensive set of information
and analysis.52 Notably, this would also allow the FTC to draw on
its own informational advantage—namely, its ability to collect
and aggregate information and to study market trends and indus-
try practices over the long term and outside the context of litiga-
tion.53 Drawing on this expertise to develop rules will help anti-
trust enforcement and policymaking better reflect empirical
realities and better keep pace with evolving business practices.
Given that the FTC has largely neglected this tool, some may
question the Commission’s authority to issue competition rules
and the legal status these rules would have.54 Indeed, a common
misconception is that this authority is extremely limited because
FTC rulemaking is subject to the extensive hurdles posed by the
Magnuson-Moss Warranty–Federal Trade Commission Improve-
ments Act55 (“Magnuson-Moss”). In reality, Magnuson-Moss gov-
erns only rulemakings interpreting “unfair or deceptive acts or
practices.”56 For rules interpreting “unfair methods of competi-
tion,” the FTC has authority to engage in participatory rulemak-
ing pursuant to the APA. Several antitrust scholars have affirmed
51 Those affected by the rule may challenge it on several grounds, including it being:
“(A) arbitrary, capricious, an abuse of discretion, or otherwise not in accordance with law;
(B) contrary to constitutional right, power, privilege, or immunity; (C) in excess of statu-
tory jurisdiction, authority, or limitations, or short of statutory right; (D) without ob-
servance of procedure required by law.” 5 USC § 706(2).
52 In adjudication, outside observers may be limited to participation through the fil-
ing of amicus briefs.
53 Hemphill, 109 Colum L Rev at 633 (cited in note 2).
54 The FTC has issued an antitrust rule only once in its history. Discriminatory Prac-
tices in Men’s and Boys’ Tailored Clothing Industry, 16 CFR Part 412 (1968). This past
December, however, the FTC issued an announcement that seemed to acknowledge its
legal authority to do engage in competition rulemaking. See Federal Trade Commission,
FTC to Hold Workshop on Non-Compete Clauses Used in Employment Contracts (Dec 5,
2019), archived at https://perma.cc/8ERZ-7HNZ (“Should the FTC consider using its rule-
making authority to address the potential harms of non-compete clauses, applying either
UMC or UDAP principles?”).
55 Pub L No 93-637, 88 Stat 2183 (1975), codified as amended at 15 USC § 2301
et seq.
56 15 USC § 57(a)(1)(A).
57 See, for example, Crane, 83 Geo Wash L Rev at 1862 (cited in note 26); Hurwitz,
76 U Pitt L Rev at 250–52 (cited in note 39); Vaheesan, 19 U Penn J Bus L at 651–57 (cited
in note 39). See also Appendix.
58 Tim Wu, Antitrust via Rulemaking: Competition Catalysts, 16 Colo Tech L J 33,
35 (2005) (observing that with several exceptions, the antitrust regime “remains rooted in
the adjudication model”).
59 Notably, other agencies do engage in competition rulemaking. See id at 34–35.
60 Maureen K. Ohlhausen, Section 5: Principles of Navigation *12 (Federal Trade
63 15 USC § 15(a) (“[A]ny person who shall be injured in his business or property by
reason of anything forbidden in the antitrust laws may sue . . . and shall recover threefold
the damages by him sustained.”).
64 It is worth noting again that rulemaking can also serve to provide certainty about
the bounds of § 5 in a manner that is more durable than FTC Enforcement Policy state-
ments, such as the one adopted by the Commission in 2015. See Federal Trade Commis-
sion, Statement of Enforcement Principles Regarding “Unfair Methods of Competition”
Under Section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act, 80 Fed Reg 57056, 57056 (2015).
(2019); Notice of Voluntary Dismissal with Prejudice, Federal Trade Commission v Allergan
PLC et al, No 17-cv-00312-WHO, *2 (ND Cal filed Feb 22, 2019); Joint Motion for Entry of
Stipulated Revised Order for Permanent Injunction and Equitable Monetary Relief, Fed-
eral Trade Commission v Cephalon, Inc, No 2:08-cv-2141-MSG, *1–3 (ED Pa filed Feb 19,
2019).
67 Hemphill, 109 Colum L Rev at 673–75 (cited in note 2) (explaining that courts
have struggled to understand and apply the agency’s deep expertise in this area, while
rulemaking would likely provide clearer guidance).
68 Evan Starr, J.J. Prescott, and Norman Bishara, Noncompetes in the U.S. Labor
Force *17 (U Mich L and Econ Research Paper No 18-013, Aug 30, 2019), archived at
https://perma.cc/2UTG-RWCB.
69 In 2018, a 5–4 majority of the Supreme Court upheld the validity of class action
waivers in employment contracts. Epic Systems Corp v Lewis, 138 S Ct 1612, 1632 (2018).
See also Alexander J.S. Colvin, The Growing Use of Mandatory Arbitration *5 (Economic
Policy Institute, Sept 27, 2017), archived at https://perma.cc/724B-BZDZ (noting that
roughly sixty million workers are subject to mandatory arbitration terms).
CONCLUSION
The choice between adjudication and participatory rulemak-
ing is neither strictly binary nor categorical. The Federal Trade
Commission can pursue each in the appropriate circumstances.
As the Commission undertakes a period of reflection in a time of
scarce agency resources, we encourage interested parties to ex-
plore whether and how rulemaking might lead to antitrust policy
that is more predictable, efficient, and participatory.
70 221 US 1 (1911).
71 Id at 53–55, 64.
72 62d Cong, 1st Sess in 47 Cong Rec 1225 (May 16, 1911).
73 Neil W. Averitt, The Meaning of “Unfair Methods of Competition” in Section 5 of
There are many forms of combination, and many practices in business which
have been so unequivocally condemned by the Supreme Court that as to them
and their like the statute is so clear that no person can be in any doubt respect-
ing what is lawful and what is unlawful; but as the statute is now construed
there are . . . many other practices that seriously interfere with competition, and
are plainly opposed to the public welfare, concerning which it is impossible to
predict with any certainty whether they will be held to be due or undue re-
straints of trade.
79 Cummins Report, 62d Cong, 3d Sess at 12 (cited in note 75).
80 Federal Trade Commission, S Rep No 597, 63d Cong, 2d Sess 13 (1914).
81 FTC v R.F. Keppel & Brothers, Inc, 291 US 304, 314 (1934):
[The FTC] was created with the avowed purpose of lodging the administrative
functions committed to it in a ‘body specially competent to deal with them by
reason of information, experience and careful study of the business and economic
conditions of the industry affected,’ and it was organized in such a manner, with
respect to the length and expiration of the terms of office of its members, as
would ‘give to them an opportunity to acquire the expertness in dealing with
these special questions concerning industry that comes from experience.
82 See Daniel A. Crane, The Institutional Structure of Antitrust Enforcement 13
(Oxford 2011); Daniel A. Crane, Antitrust Antifederalism, 96 Cal L Rev 1, 2 (2008).
83 Federal Trade Commission, 63d Cong, 3d Sess, in 51 Cong Rec 13047 (1914).
84 15 USC § 46(g).
85 United States v Mead, 533 US 218, 234–35 (2001).
hold that under the terms of its governing statute, 15 U.S.C. § 41 et seq., and under Sec-
tion 6(g), 15 U.S.C. § 46(g), in particular, the Federal Trade Commission is authorized to
promulgate rules defining the meaning of the statutory standards of the illegality the
Commission is empowered to prevent.”).
89 Id at 681.
90 Hurwitz, 76 U Pitt L Rev at 234 (cited in note 39).
91 15 USC § 57.
92 Hurwitz, 76 U Pitt L Rev at 234–35 (cited in note 39) (citations omitted).
93 Pub L No 96-252, 94 Stat 374 (1980), codified as amended at 15 USC § 57.