Global Financial Systems Stability and Risk by Danielsson
Global Financial Systems Stability and Risk by Danielsson
Global Financial Systems Stability and Risk by Danielsson
Global Financial Systems: Stability and Risk is an innovative textbook that explores the ‘why’ behind
global financial stability, providing insightful discussions on the international financial system and the
contemporary issues of today. Drawing on economic theory, finance, mathematical modelling and risk
theory, this book presents a comprehensive, coherent and current economic analysis of the inherent
instabilities of the financial system, and the design of optimal policy response.
Key features
• Up-to-date and thorough analysis of the 2007/08 financial crisis.
• Case studies and practical examples illustrate key arguments and apply the theory to the
real world.
• End-of-chapter questions provoke discussion and critical thinking, and provide
opportunities to test your understanding.
• Accompanied by instructor resources including PowerPoint slides, plus an author-hosted
website featuring regular updates on current events in the global financial system and links
to useful websites.
www.pearson-books.com
Global Financial
SYSTEMS
i
Global Financial
Systems
Stability and Risk
Jon Danielsson
Director, Systemic Risk Centre
London School of Economics
PEARSON EDUCATION LIMITED
Edinburgh Gate
Harlow CM20 2JE
United Kingdom
Tel: +44 (0)1279 623623
Web: www.pearson.com/uk
The right of Jon Danielsson to be identified as author of this work has been asserted by him in accordance
with the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988.
The print publication is protected by copyright. Prior to any prohibited reproduction, storage in a retrieval
system, distribution or transmission in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, recording or
otherwise, permission should be obtained from the publisher or, where applicable, a licence permitting
restricted copying in the United Kingdom should be obtained from the Copyright Licensing Agency Ltd,
Saffron House, 6–10 Kirby Street, London EC1N 8TS.
The ePublication is protected by copyright and must not be copied, reproduced, transferred, distributed,
leased, licensed or publicly performed or used in any way except as specifically permitted in writing by the
publishers, as allowed under the terms and conditions under which it was purchased, or as strictly permitted
by applicable copyright law. Any unauthorised distribution or use of this text may be a direct infringement of
the author's and the publishers' rights and those responsible may be liable in law accordingly.
All trademarks used herein are the property of their respective owners. The use of any trademark in this text
does not vest in the author or publisher any trademark ownership rights in such trademarks, nor does the use
of such trademarks imply any affiliation with or endorsement of this book by such owners.
Pearson Education is not responsible for the content of third-party internet sites.
10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1
16 15 14 13
Author’s acknowledgements xi
Publisher’s acknowledgements xii
Introduction xiii
1 Systemic risk 1
1.1 Case study: the 1914 crisis 2
1.2 The concept of systemic risk 4
1.3 Who creates systemic risk? 9
1.4 Fundamental origins of systemic risk 11
1.5 Summary 17
References 18
3 Endogenous risk 39
3.1 Millennium Bridge 41
3.2 Dual role of prices 43
3.3 Risk 46
3.4 Dynamic trading strategies 48
3.5 Actual and perceived risk and bubbles 53
3.6 The LTCM crisis of 1998 56
3.7 Conclusion 59
References 60
4 Liquidity 61
4.1 The liquidity crisis of 1998 62
4.2 What is liquidity? 65
4.3 Liquidity models 70
4.4 Policy implications 73
4.5 Summary 75
References 76
v
Contents
vi
Contents
vii
Contents
14 Bailouts 261
14.1 Successful and unsuccessful bailouts 263
14.2 The historical origins of lending of last resort (LOLR) 265
14.3 What are bailouts? 267
14.4 Alternatives to bailouts 272
14.5 Bailouts in the crisis starting in 2007 273
14.6 Bailouts, moral hazard and politics 278
14.7 Model of asset bubbles 279
14.8 Summary 283
References 284
viii
Contents
Glossary 391
Bibliography 393
Index 399
ix
Author’s Acknowledgements
This book is based on my lecture notes for my LSE course ‘Global Financial Systems’. The
course was originally developed by Hyun Song Shin, who taught it from 2001 until 2004
and generously gave me access to his lecture notes which formed the skeleton for the first
time I taught the course in 2008.
I was fortunate to be able to employ two exemplary students, Jacqueline Li and Jing
Zeng, who took the course in 2008, to work with me in the summer of 2009 to help me
to develop the lecture material into what became this book. Their assistance was invalu-
able, and they made significant contributions both to the book version of the lecture
notes and to the slides. Their ability to master the computational aspects of the course
material (latex, mercurial, R) and the economic topics was impressive, as was the appar-
ent ease with which they mastered all the technicalities. Their work was generously
funded by the LSE Teaching Development Fund and the Department of Finance.
I was equally fortunate during the summer of 2010 to employ three former students of
the course, Georgia Lv, Eric Pashman and Nick Zeifang. Since then, Kyounghwan Lee has
been very helpful in developing some of the material. Several students have made valu-
able contributions, including Fan Gao, Radhika Saini, Yong Bin Ng, Murathan Kurt, Basak
Yeltekin, Janis Sussick and Stefan Doykin.
Several friends made invaluable contributions to the book. Robert Macrae of Arcus
Investment read the manuscript twice, and made innumerable comments. His insight into
the subject matter and his keen understanding of financial markets from an investor’s
point of view made the book much better than it otherwise would have been.
Con Keating of EFFAS read the whole manuscript, and by identifying the places where
my analysis and logic fell short, significantly improved the book.
Giovanni Bassini read the chapters on financial regulations and pointed out the most
up-to-date developments. David Schraa from IIF read the chapter on future developments
in regulations and gave me very useful insights into the fine points of the ongoing regula-
tory debate.
I would like to thank my wife Sigrun for her shrewd comments, her honest observations
and, above all, her patience.
Without all of these people, this book would not have seen the light of day. Any inac-
curacies and errors that remain in the book are the result of my not paying enough atten-
tion to their comments.
xi
Publisher’s Acknowledgements
Logos
Logo on page xi from Economic and Social Research Council.
Tables
Table 5.1 from On the measurement of Zimbabwe’s hyperinflation, Cato Journal, Vol. 29,
No. 2, 356 (Hanke, S. H. and Kwok, A. K. F. Spring/Summer 2009), Copyright © Cato
Institute. All rights reserved; Tables 6.1, 6.2 after http://data.worldbank.org/, World Bank;
Table 11.2 from Forty Years’ Experience with the OECD Code of Liberalisation of Capital
Movements, OECD Publishing. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264176188-en.
Photographs
The publisher would like to thank the following for their kind permission to reproduce
their photographs:
In some instances we have been unable to trace the owners of copyright material, and we
would appreciate any information that would enable us to do so.
xii
Introduction
The focus of this book is on how the world’s financial system functions, the various policy
choices governments have, and how the system has built-in vulnerabilities which lead to
crises. Financial crises have been our constant companion from the very first time human
beings created a financial system. This means that over time, we have accumulated deep
knowledge and understanding of the economic forces enabling such crises. This experi-
ence shows that financial crises are all fundamentally the same, only the details differ. This
is why financial crises are so hard to prevent and so costly to fight. Every time, we are faced
with new details that enforce age-old vulnerabilities.
The various types of financial-system fragilities are systematically analysed in this book,
lessons from past crisis events are used to study recent crises, and up-to-date research is
employed for the analysis of crises long past. In doing so, we make use of the rich body
of research that has emerged with the continuous crisis from 2007.
The focus of the book is on policy issues. It uses a number of case studies, aiming to
create a unified theme linking all the cases. It is written from a point of view of economics,
but does have relevance in other policy-oriented fields such as government, political sci-
ence and law.
The target level is intermediate to advanced undergraduate students and masters stu-
dents. Some knowledge of economics and financial markets is helpful but not essential.
Most of the chapters are non-mathematical, a few make some use of mathematics and
one is essentially dedicated to formal models. It is an open question what is the best way
to incorporate the technical material. It is quite helpful for students with the right back-
ground, but can be skipped by others.
The first part of the book presents basic concepts in financial stability, such as systemic
risk, endogenous risk, the fundamental role of the central bank and the multi-faceted
concept of liquidity. These chapters provide a foundation for more specialised analysis
later in the book. One important case study is contained in this first part, the Great
Depression of the 1930s, which is the worst financial and economic crisis we have ever
seen and, hence, has had a huge impact on financial and economic policy. The response
to the ongoing crisis is significantly shaped by the Great Depression.
After this, we provide more specific analysis of the various parts of the financial system,
and how they relate to financial stability. We start with a detailed case study of the Asian
crisis of 1997 which clearly demonstrates the various dimensions of modern financial
crises. This is followed by discussion of banking crises and bank runs. Thereafter the book
focuses on financial markets, speculation, trading and the market for credit. The final part
of the financial system that is discussed is currency markets, which are the focus of two
chapters, the first focused on policy issues and the second currency crisis models.
Governments have various ways of intervening in financial markets, and the next chap-
ters in the book discuss financial regulations and bailouts. Financial regulation is a rich
topic that is easily the subject of its own book, but here we limit the discussion to the
xiii
Introduction
main arguments for regulating, some of the challenges faced by the authorities and finally
international regulations on bank capital. The last part of the book focuses on the
ongoing crisis from 2007, starting with the dangerous financial instruments that were one
of the factors that enabled excessive risk-taking to take place out of sight. Failures in
financial regulation and risk management also played a role and are the subject of the
following chapter. After this, we bring together the main lessons from the book into
a three-chapter discussion on the ongoing crisis, first the credit phase from 2007 until
2009, then how the crisis is shaping financial regulations, and finally sovereign debt cri-
ses, both generally and with specific reference to the ongoing European sovereign debt
crisis. Because this crisis is ongoing, we maintain a final chapter online at www.
GlobalFinancialSystems.org addressing day-to-day developments in the crisis. This chap-
ter is updated regularly to reflect new information.
xiv
1 SysTemic risk
The world’s economy was on the brink of collapse in the autumn of 2008. Confidence,
the lifeblood of the financial system, was evaporating at an alarming rate, financial
institutions refused to do business with each other, people took their money out
of banks and it looked like the real economy might be heading for a second Great
Depression. Then, just as suddenly as the crisis materialised, it seemed like it was over.
What we experienced was a near-miss systemic crisis, generally defined as the col-
lapse of the entire financial system, followed by an economic depression. The full
crisis was only averted thanks to the swift actions of the authorities.
Over the past half-century, until a few years ago, systemic risk had been the pur-
view of a few academics and policy makers, very much a backwater discipline. The
prevailing approach was to study the risk of the individual parts of the financial sys-
tem separately, not in aggregate, since the objective of interest was the institution,
not the system. An example is how the Basel Accords – the main body of international
financial regulations – focus on individual prudential behaviour instead of the finan-
cial system in its entirety. The series of crises that started in 2007 demonstrated the
folly of such thinking.
2007 was not the first time we faced systemic risk; it has been present ever since
the first financial system was created, and is an inevitable part of any market-based
economic system. It was a real and recognised danger during the era of the first
globalism – 1873 to 1914. In the highly regulated financial world after the Second
World War (WWII), systemic crises were a relatively remote eventuality, only to
re-emerge with the collapse of the Bretton Woods system in the early 1970s.
Chapter 1 SysTemic risk
Systemic risk is most damaging for advanced financial markets; after all, a country
with a small and underdeveloped financial system is much more resilient to problems
in the financial sector. The key question for policy makers in countries with advanced
financial markets is how to limit the build-up of systemic risk and contain crisis events
when they happen. To answer this we need to identify and understand the different
aspects of systemic risk and the tools available to policy makers.
Key concepts
■ Systemic risk
■ Moral hazard
■ Liquidity
■ Bank runs
■ Pro-cyclicality
■ Firesale externality
2
1.1 Case study: The 1914 crisis
40 million
30 million
20 million
10 million
0 million
Jan Feb Mar Apr May Jun Jul Aug Sep Oct Nov Dec
Figure 1.1 Amount of foreign loans made in the City of London in 1914 (in sterling)
Data source: Brown (1940)
3
Chapter 1 SysTemic risk
A general moratorium was issued on banker acceptances, lasting for two months. The
Bank of England (BoE) made further advances of £200 million to the money markets, and
on 13 August obtained a government guarantee to discount bills in the market without
recourse, whilst also allowing for delays in repayments. The London Stock Exchange was
only reopened on 4 January 1915.
Analysis
It does not take all that much for a panic to happen when confidence evaporates. Even
rumours that a large institution might fail can cause panic. In 1914, it was clear that some
institutions were heavily exposed to cross-border lending and would fail in case of war.
That was enough to trigger the crisis. We did not need the actual event of a war to make
this happen; the expectation of a war was sufficient.
The authorities played a clear role, similar to what they did at the height of the crises
from 2007 but on a much larger scale. The BoE resorted to what now would be called
quantitative easing (QE), literally printing money. In the 10 days to 1 August, the Bank
made securitised loans, worth £31,700,000, to discount houses and the Stock Exchange,
most of which had to be paid back one year after the war. The bank rate jumped from 3%
to 10% in three days in order to prevent the gold bleeding to France. On 1 August, the Peel
Act was suspended and the Bank was allowed to issue notes in excess of its gold holdings.
The policy intervention was successful and the City of London did survive, even if not
unscathed. A systemic crisis was averted. By comparison, events during the crises that
started in 2007 are quite mild.
There are two main lessons to be taken from these events. First, in a crisis, the authori-
ties have no choice but to take extreme measures if they want to save their economies.
Secondly, because decisions have to be taken rapidly it is much better if the authorities
are prepared. In 1914 the BoE did follow the established practice of lending of last resort
(LOLR), developed half a century earlier.
4
1.2 The concept of systemic risk
We need to make a distinction between the term systemic and systematic. Systematic
risk relates to non-diversifiable risk factors that affect everybody and is always present,
perhaps the stock market, whilst systemic risk pertains to the danger of the entire finan-
cial system collapsing.
The consequences of a systemic crisis in the financial sector are more devastating com-
pared to other economic sectors. Suppose a firm making chocolate goes bust: the share-
holders and employees suffer, but competing chocolate firms will benefit. There is no
significant damage to the economy, and such developments may even be positive, as
argued by Joseph Schumpeter (1942) with his notion of creative destruction. By contrast,
if a bank collapses, it may well lead to the seizure of the entire financial system, crippling
the real economy.
‘the disruption to the flow of financial services that is (i) caused by an impairment
of all or parts of the financial system; and (ii) has the potential to have serious nega-
tive consequences for the real economy.’
Definition 1.1 Systemic risk The risk that the entire financial system may fail,
causing a general economic collapse, as opposed to risk associated with an individual part
of the system.
Systemic risk arises from the interlinkages present in the financial system, where the failure
of an individual institution may cause spillovers and even cascading failures, amplified by
the inherent pro-cyclicality of banking and regulations.
The conditions for systemic risk tend to be created when all outward signs point to
stability and low risk.
There are few or no recorded instances of a systemic event according to this strict defi-
nition. We have seen events that got close in their severity, and other events that, if left to
fruition, might have ended up as a systemic event.
It is important to recognise that there is no single generally accepted definition of sys-
temic risk. Some commentators have a much looser definition than the one above, often
considering a severe crisis, and even a routine crisis, to be a systemic event. However, the
most common usage is similar to Definition 1.1.
5
Chapter 1 SysTemic risk
Romania All
Poland Domestic
Bulgaria
Slovakia Upper column 2007
Lithuania
Lower column June 2011
Czech Republic
Hungary
Slovenia
Latvia
Finland
Italy
Greece
Estonia
Portugal
Germany
Spain
Sweden
France
Denmark
Austria
United Kingdom
Belgium
Netherlands
Cyprus
Ireland
Malta
Luxembourg
Figure 1.2 EU banking system, total assets/GDP ratio in 2007 and June 2011, ordered
by size of banking system in 2007
Data source: ECB and Eurostat
6
1.2 The concept of systemic risk
foreign banking, albeit for different reasons. For the small banking countries regular banks
are owned by foreigners, whilst for the large banking countries the foreign-owned banks
mostly service foreign clients. These countries export banking services, produced by
foreign-owned banks.
This reduces vulnerability. For example, even if the assets of the Luxembourg banks
exceed its GDP 20 times, Luxembourg is relatively insulated because the failure of a bank
would not directly involve taxpayers’ money in most cases. Of course, if a number of the
banks failed, the Luxembourg government might find itself short of funds from taxes, so it
is directly connected to the banks. This threat is, however, less direct than if Luxembourg
would be called on to bail out the banks. This suggests that in a country like Ireland or
Cyprus, even if their banks are relatively smaller than the banks in Luxembourg, bank fail-
ures pose a much bigger danger.
The large banking countries are also at risk of Dutch disease,1 where the banks become
the dominating part of the economy, crowding out other economic activity.
200 Finance
Whole economy
150 Manufacturing
100
1
Dutch disease arises when a new large profitable economic sector, traditionally exploiting natural resources,
causes a decline in the manufacturing sector. This happens because the new revenue from natural resources
strengthens the currency, making the manufacturing sector less competitive. It is used here in a more
general sense where one sector crowds out other sectors.
7
Chapter 1 SysTemic risk
8
1.3 Who creates systemic risk?
The current financial crisis gives us a good example of the challenge facing the authori-
ties. The failure of individual institutions like Bear Stearns, Lehman Brothers and AIG
caused serious disruptions. Deciding on whether these institutions should have been
bailed out is a clear example of the risk–return trade-off we have discussed here.
That task is made easier by the observation that most crises are fundamentally similar,
even if the details differ. For example, the 1914 crisis and the ongoing crisis have strong
commonalities — financial institutions building up risk in good times, as if a crisis could
never happen, only to see confidence and liquidity evaporate suddenly, causing cascad-
ing failures. The authorities reacted similarly by providing liquidity injections. This sug-
gests that policymakers should be well prepared and know their history. Getting caught
short in 2007 did not reflect well on many policymaking institutions.
‘The received wisdom is that risk increases in recessions and falls in booms. In con-
trast, it may be more helpful to think of risk as increasing during upswings, as finan-
cial imbalances build up, and materialising in recessions.’
In other words, when looking for the origins of systemic risk one should not focus on
current events; decisions made long ago are usually to blame.
This leaves open the question of who is responsible for a crisis episode. The public
media and affiliated pundits delight in blaming the target of the day, whether the greedy
bankers, incompetent politicians, pernicious academics or some other easy scapegoat.
The reality is more nuanced. It is the interplay between the various parties that creates
conditions for systemic risk, with no key players blameless. It is equally difficult to identify
what is the real problem when confronted by the news of the day.
9
Chapter 1 SysTemic risk
financial institutions have a tendency to extrapolate stability into infinity, investing in ever
more risky debt structures that ultimately undermine stability. At some point, a disrup-
tive event occurs, and markets go through an abrupt correction — the further along in the
cycle, the more violent the repricing.
A clear example of such mechanisms occurred prior to 2007, when the financial indus-
try, and almost everybody else, were blind to the hidden risk being created. The pre-crisis
period was even labelled the ‘great moderation’.
This also demonstrates the double-edged nature of otherwise useful risk control meth-
ods such as mark-to-market accounting, which enable financial institutions to realise prof-
its up-front. This makes the banks even more profitable when things are good, but at the
expense of larger losses when the markets take a turn for the worse — a clear example of
pro-cyclicality.
10
1.4 Fundamental origins of systemic risk
‘When you hear the government talking about systemic risk, hold on to your wallet!
It means that they want you to pay more taxes for more regulations, which are likely
to create systemic risk by interfering with private contracting . . . In sum, when you
think about systemic risks, you’ll be close to the truth if you think of the govern-
ment as causing them rather than protecting us from them.’
Types of money
It is useful to classify money into several different categories, or monetary aggregates as
they are technically known, as illustrated by Figure 1.4.
M0, also known as monetary base, or high-powered money, consists of paper money in
circulation and reserves at the central bank. M1 is known as narrow money, and consists
10
M3−M2
8
USD trillions
M2−M1
6 M1−M0
4 M0
2
0
M0 M1 M2 M3
Figure 1.4 United States (US) monetary aggregates at end of 2005. Identifies unique
components of each aggregate, and labels the main component
Data source: Federal Reserve Board. Data ends 2005 since that is the last full year when M3 was published
11
Chapter 1 SysTemic risk
of M0 plus current (checkable) accounts, in essence funds that are readily accessible for
spending — liquid funds. M2 is M1 plus savings accounts and represents money and close
substitutes for money. It is a key indicator for inflation forecasting. M3 is the broadest
measure of money, including M2 plus large time deposits, institutional money market
funds, short-term repurchase and other larger liquid assets. The higher forms of money
are created out of the lower forms, typically by means of fractional reserve banking.
Reserve requirements
Today, most banking systems use fractional reserve banking which is an arrangement
whereby most of the money is created by the banks; subject to a particular limitation —
the reserve requirement, d — banks are required to hold a certain fraction of deposits on
account with the central bank. Fractional reserve banking expands money supply beyond
what it would otherwise be, as seen by the following example:
Person X deposits $100 (M0) into bank A. d is 10% so the bank lends $90 to per-
son Y who deposits $90 at bank B which keeps fraction d and lends out $81 and so
on. Hence, in the limit M1 = 100 + 90 + 81 + c = 1/d = 1000. The relationship
between M1 and the monetary base can be expressed as:
1
M1 = g * M0 = * M0
d
g is the money multiplier, which tells us how much the money supply changes for a given
change in the monetary base. If the reserve requirement is 10%, every dollar in the form
of deposits uses up only 10 cents of high-powered money, or each dollar of high-powered
money held as reserves can support $10 of deposits. Hence, the higher the required reserve
ratio, the lower the money multiplier. We see in Figure 1.5 how fractional reserve banking
aids the expansion of credit.
Fragilities
The fractional reserve banking system is inherently fragile and hence is a cause of systemic
risk. The reason is that when depositors put money into a bank, creating M1 from M0, the
bank then turns around and lends most of it out, keeping a small fraction as reserves. The
fragility arises because deposits generally are of short maturities, and some can be with-
drawn whenever the depositor wants — demand deposits — whilst the loans tend to be of
longer maturities. If a sufficiently large number of depositors want their money, the bank
will run out of cash, because it cannot similarly call on its own borrowers to repay their
loans. We call such an event a bank run. Bank runs are contagious and can spread quickly
throughout the financial system. The reason is that the banking system is built on trust,
so if depositors lose confidence in banks, they flock to withdraw their deposits as cash.
12
1.4 Fundamental origins of systemic risk
Money supply
$500
$250
2 4 6 8 10 12 14
Number of iterations
Figure 1.5 Credit expansion of $100 under fractional reserve banking and various
reserve ratios
1.4.2 Pro-cyclicality
A process that is positively correlated with the economic cycle is described as pro-cyclical.
Bank capital and leverage are two examples of pro-cyclical processes in which risks build
up during stable periods. Banks tend to have surplus capital when the economy is boom-
ing, whilst capital levels drop during recessions. Likewise, economic agents have a ten-
dency to borrow too much during good times, and borrow too little in downturns.
Pro-cyclicality is often created by the various amplification mechanisms built into the
financial system, and is encouraged by risk-weighted capital, mark-to-market accounting
and the fact that the strength of financial regulations tends to erode in boom times and
come back with a vengeance during crises.
Amplification mechanisms
Financial crises often seem to be triggered by relatively small events. This is not dissimilar
to what chaos theorists mean when they say that a butterfly in Hong Kong causes a hur-
ricane in the Caribbean. Many such butterfly effects exist in the financial system.
The main enabling factor is leverage, whereby a bank borrows money to make investments.
High degrees of leverage enable a bank to multiply profits when investments are success-
ful. For this reason, banks remain highly leveraged. Unfortunately, rapid de-leveraging
amplifies losses, perhaps resulting in bank failures and causing firesale externalities.
Firesale externalities
Firesale externalities (see, e.g., Kashyap et al., 2008) arise when financial institutions need
liquidity and aim to convert risky assets into cash. At that time, there are many sellers and
few buyers of risky assets. That means prices collapse, making it even harder to raise cash
and forcing institutions to sell even more risky assets, in what has become a vicious cycle
(Figure 1.6). It is the individual self-preservation behaviour of each institution that causes
negative externalities for the rest of the financial system. Such behaviour can cause a rela-
tively innocuous shock to become a full-blown crisis.
13
Chapter 1 SysTemic risk
External
shock
Prices Risk
Firesale
fall increases
Forced
sales
8%
4%
Asset growth
Asset growth
4%
2%
0%
0%
−4%
−1.0% 0.0% 1.0% −25% 0% 25%
Leverage growth Leverage growth
(a) Households (b) Commercial banks
Asset growth
6%
Asset growth
20%
4%
0%
2%
0% −20%
Figure 1.7 Asset growth and leverage growth, with a regression line
Data source: Adriam and Shin (2010)
14
1.4 Fundamental origins of systemic risk
For households, the relationship is negative: the richer we become the less leverage we use.
If a household owns a house financed by a mortgage, leverage falls when the house price
increases, since the equity of the household is increasing at a much faster rate than assets.
Similarly, most people pay back their mortgages over time, reducing leverage. For corporations
and commercial banks there is little correlation, but for the broker–dealers it is highly positive.
For such firms, leverage is pro-cyclical, increasing when balance sheets are expanding
and decreasing when balance sheets are shrinking. The slope is close to 1 for broker–dealers,
suggesting that equity is increasing at a constant rate on average.
This result is counter-intuitive in light of standard theories in corporate finance, where
it should not make a difference how a firm is financed. Here, the willingness to use bor-
rowed funds to increase leverage is a key factor in firm growth.
From the point of view of systemic risk, this suggests that broker–dealer type institu-
tions have a tendency to continually increasing leverage. The owners of these institutions
might be rewarded by higher profits when things go well, but at the expense of increased
systemic risk.
1.4.4 Interdependence
The financial system consists of a network of interwoven obligations that during normal
times significantly increases the efficiency of financial markets. This means a financial
institution can have an indirect exposure to another financial institution without any
15
Chapter 1 SysTemic risk
Bank B
Bank C
direct dealings with it. This can be quite dangerous during crises, most obviously because
of interlocking exposures, which create the potential for one institution’s failure to have
‘knock-on’ effects on the financial health of other institutions. At any given time, a finan-
cial institution simultaneously owes money to other institutions and is owed money often
from the very same institutions. These linkages make the financial system fragile.
For example, consider the situation depicted in Figure 1.8, where we have four banks
A, B, C and D. A borrows and lends from B and C, which also borrow and lend from D.
Suppose A suffers a negative shock, and needing funds calls in a loan to B and C. They
now need funds, and in turn may call in their loans to the hitherto healthy bank D. The
difficulties facing A have now been transferred to D, even if A and D have no direct busi-
ness relationships. This is exactly the situation in the 1914 example discussed above.
Because banks have only a limited amount of liquid funds, even a relatively small but
immediate demand for cash, or an interruption in the flow of funds, can cause serious dif-
ficulties and even failure. This means that if financial institutions suspect others may be in dif-
ficulty, their natural instinct is to withdraw, spreading a crisis throughout the financial system.
We see a particularly damaging example of this in the interbank market during the crisis
from 2007. The proliferation of derivatives, in particular structured credit products such as
structured investment vehicles (SIVs), credit default swaps (CDSs) and collateralised debt
obligations (CDOs), has been increasing the interdependence between financial institu-
tions, in turn increasing the fragility of the financial system.
16
1.5 Summary
This can have the unfortunate outcome that a badly run bank actually has a lower
cost of funding than a well-managed bank because only one of them would be bailed
out. Ultimately, this means banks have incentives to become as big, interconnected and
dangerous as possible in order to maximise the chance of a bailout. A particularly inter-
esting example can be seen by the supposedly expressed desires by some hedge funds to
become ‘banks’ in order to enjoy low-cost government guarantees of funding.
There are many other types of perverse incentives. For example, lenders who ultimately
intend to securitise their loan books do not have proper incentives to monitor the quality
of their loans. In addition, the presence of financial instruments, such as CDSs, may create
incentives for some market participants to increase instability.
1.5 Summary
Systemic risk has always been a part of the financial system, and many crisis events of the
past are quite similar to modern crises, for example, that of 1914.
There are many definitions of systemic risk, but most emphasise the risk of widespread
failures in the financial system, caused by the interlinkages between financial institutions,
eventually resulting in a severe economic downturn.
Systemic risk is the inevitable result of having a market-based economy and is not eas-
ily eliminated or reduced significantly without unduly restricting risky activities, adversely
affecting the real economy. This means that the authorities need to balance the various
pros and cons in their approach to systemic risk policies, doing cost–benefit analysis.
Stated differently, the authorities have to find the appropriate risk–return combination,
similar to what investors do for their own portfolios.
Although any sector of the economy may be subject to systemic risk, it is especially relevant
for the financial sector, because it is uniquely dependent on the interplay between confidence
and network effects. The failure of a single institution quickly spreads to other banks, even if
they have been prudently run. The damage caused by even relatively small events in the mar-
kets can be amplified into systemic proportions because of the inherent pro-cyclicality in the
financial system, perhaps aided by the perverse incentives of market participants.
3 What does it mean when we say that systemic risk builds up out of sight, and what
could that mean for the government’s formulation of financial stability policies?
4 How does the European country with the largest banking system relative to GDP man-
age to be mostly unaffected by the banking crisis whilst other countries with relatively
smaller banking system suffer serious banking crises?
5 Do you think it would be prudent for the British government to reduce the size of its
banks in order to reduce systemic risk?
17
Chapter 1 SysTemic risk
6 Can you think of some systemic events in the past, anywhere in the world, excluding
what has been happening since 2007?
References
Adrian, T. and Shin, H. S. (2010). Liquidity and leverage. J. Finan. Intermed., 19: 418–37.
Bandt, D. and Hartmann, P. (2000). Systemic risk: a survey. Working paper no. 35, European
Central Bank.
Black, F. (1995). Hedging, speculation, and systemic risk. J. Derivatives, 2: 6–8.
Brown, W. A. (1940). The international gold standard reinterpreted, 1914–1934. Technical
report, National Bureau of Economic Research.
Crockett, A. (2000). Marrying the micro- and macro-prudential dimensions of financial stabil-
ity. The General Manager of the Bank for International Settlements, www.bis.org/review/
rr000921b.pdf.
Ferguson, N. (2008). The Ascent of Money. The Penguin Group.
International Monetary Fund, Bank for International Settlements, Financial Stability Board
(2009). Report to G20 finance ministers and governors. Guidance to assess the systemic
importance of financial institutions, markets and instruments: initial considerations.
Technical report.
Kashyap, A. K., Rajan, R. G., and Stein, J. C. (2008). Rethinking capital regulation. http://online.
wsj.com/public/resources/documents/ Fed-JacksonHole.pdf.
Kaufman, G. G. (1996). Bank failures, systemic risk, and bank regulation. Cato J., 16(1): 17–46.
Kindleberger, C. P. (1996). Manias, Panics, and Crashes: a History of Financial Crises, 3rd edition.
John Wiley & Sons.
Merton, R. (1995). A functional perspective of financial intermediation. Financial Management,
24: 23–41.
Minsky, H. (1992). The financial instability hypothesis. Working paper. Mimeo, Yale University.
Reinhart, C. M. and Rogoff, K. (2009). This Time Is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly.
Princeton University Press.
Schumpeter, J. (1942). Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. Harper, New York.
18
2 The Great Depression, 1929–1933
The Great Depression, 1929–1933, was the largest worldwide economic catastrophe
the world has ever seen. A Wall Street crash in 1929 was followed by the collapse of
financial institutions and an implosion of activity on financial markets, soon spilling
over to Main Street. This happened because of vicious feedback loops between con-
tracting economic activity, financial crises and government mistakes.
The Depression shaped economic policy long after it ended. While its impact had
been diminishing, that all changed with the crises from 2007, and over the past few
years, the lessons from the Depression have significantly impacted on policy. The
reason why events in the fall of 2008 did not lead to another depression is because
policymakers had learned the lesson of the Great Depression and acted correctly. The
continuing influence of the Great Depression on government policy make it a worth-
while subject in studies of financial stability in the twenty-first century.
The Depression came after one of the longest expansion periods in history, the
roaring twenties, with rapid economic growth and rampant stock market speculation,
when many investors were highly leveraged, buying stocks on the margin. Underneath
were significant frictions. The First World War (WWI) fundamentally affected the
international order, and universal suffrage – for both women and the poor – altered
political power structures as did the emergence of labour unions. Extreme politi-
cal ideologies, communism and fascism, gained a significant foothold, not least as a
result of the economic turmoil marking those years.
International trade patterns were altered considerably, as non-combatants prof-
ited and extended their global reach. Many countries attempted export-led growth,
typically via agricultural products, leading to overproduction and price deflation. And
Chapter 2 The Great Depression, 1929–1933
finally, disputes over war debt, and the determination in some countries to extract
reparations from the losing Central Powers, poisoned international relations and acted
to prevent effective crisis resolution once the Depression was underway.
The first sign of the problems leading to the Great Depression emerged in the agri-
cultural sector and industries dependent on agriculture such as banks and insurance
companies, spreading economic turmoil from the farm to the city. This was followed
by widespread bank collapses, contraction in money supplies, with surpluses, liquid-
ity crises, exchange rate depreciations and trade restrictions, all acting in a vicious
feedback loop, compounding the problems.
Note that it can be difficult to assess the costs of the Great Depression because only
limited data exists and it is often contradictory. This especially applies to national
accounts, as global standards for the calculation of GDP were only determined in the
late 1940s, so comparisons before that time are difficult.
Key concepts
■ Deflation
■ Trade policy
■ Monetary policy
■ Bank runs
■ International coordination
■ Firesale externality
20
2.1 Build-up to a depression
for example, the United Kingdom (UK) was no longer the world’s superpower, yielding
to the United States (US).
Following the war, what would now be called significant global imbalances built up,
with resentment and conflict resulting. Many countries accumulated large debts, with the
largest creditor being the US.
Japan 27
Norway 18
Venezuela 17
Uruguay 14
Germany 13
Sweden 12
Argentina 11
France 10
Denmark 7
Australia 5
United Kingdom 4
Netherlands 3
Switzerland 2
United States 1
Figure 2.1 1929 GDP per capita in constant 1990 dollars and global rank out of
52 countries
Data source: www.ggdc.net/MADDISON/oriindex.htm
21
Chapter 2 The Great Depression, 1929–1933
The policy of extracting very large reparations from the losers was quite popular right
after the war, but opinion soon changed as it was recognised that the amounts demanded
were simply too large. Some voices, most importantly Keynes (1920), warned against the
consequences of treating the losers that way. In order to pay reparations, Germany began
a credit-fuelled period of growth, ending in hyperinflation in 1923.
22
2.1 Build-up to a depression
These problems are not dissimilar to the problems currently affecting the euro zone
and the European exchange rate mechanism (ERM) before that. A monetary policy appro-
priate for a leading country in a boom is likely to be too strict for other countries facing
recessions. This leaves the weaker countries with only two options, either to implement
an internal devaluation or to devalue their currency, with neither choice palatable.
200
Wheat
Depression
150 Cotton
Great
100 Sugar
Rubber
50
0
1920 1925 1930 1935
23
Chapter 2 The Great Depression, 1929–1933
Currency in 1926: ‘It should not be overlooked that one of the greatest menaces to the
trade of this country is depreciating foreign exchange.’
Effectiveness
Surprisingly, the devaluations were not all that effective in helping the producers. When
a country devalues, two things happen: the local currency price of exports increases and
the foreign currency price falls. Elasticities determine which effect ends up dominating.
For a small country with no impact on world prices, local currency prices will increase.
For a major exporter facing an inelastic demand, prices abroad will fall. For example,
when Argentina devalued in the 1930s, local currency prices did not increase but foreign
prices fell, exacerbating that country’s difficulties. The experience of other major agricul-
tural exporters, like Australia, was similar.
Deflation
The falling agricultural prices hit sectors that depended heavily on credit especially hard,
because deflation erodes the price of commodities while increasing the real value of debt.
Throughout the 1920s farm debt was increasing, in the US from $3.3 billion in 1910 to
$9.4 billion in 1925.
One might expect the ever falling prices of commodities to stimulate global spend-
ing and prosperity. This did not happen because the response of countries facing the
improved terms of trade (lower import prices) is slow, as it takes time to realise that real
incomes increased, permitting an increase in spending. The adverse impact on producers
is more immediate.
This is similar to how financial crises reallocate wealth: the losers scream immediately,
but the winners are harder to identify and don’t really notice for a while, and hence delay
spending their newfound wealth.
The end result is a deflationary cycle, as seen in Figure 2.3: prices fall, causing difficul-
ties for debtors, who in turn curtail consumption. Creditors realise they will get more for
their money in the future and also delay spending. This causes demand to contract and
prices to fall further.
Prices
fall
Demand falls
Creditors Debtors in
prosper difficulty
Both delay
spending
24
2.2 The Great Depression
10.0 bn
7.5 bn
5.0 bn
2.5 bn
0.0 bn
−2.5 bn
−5.0 bn
1920 1925 1930 1935
(a) Net capital formation in constant prices
120 bn GNP
Unemployment
Unemployment 20%
100 bn 15%
GNP
80 bn 10%
60 bn 5%
25
Chapter 2 The Great Depression, 1929–1933
Capital markets
The collapse of the stock market caused large losses to individual investors, and affected
firms that relied on capital markets for liquidity, conspiring to create a liquidity crisis
which soon spread to other sectors of the economy such as mortgages. At the time, mort-
gages were normally unamortised three-year obligations, rolled over every three years.
Because of the liquidity crisis, homeowners were unable to refinance, leading to wide-
spread foreclosures and a large drop in house prices. All these factors fed on themselves,
in an example of an endogenous risk feedback loop.
Schadenfreude
Initially, the crash led to widespread schadenfreude – the satisfaction or pleasure felt at
someone else’s misfortune – as people blamed the depression on greedy speculators. It
was felt that banks got what they deserved and should rightly suffer. In the words of the
treasury secretary Andrew Mellon:
‘It will purge the rottenness out of the system. High costs of living and high living
will come down. People will work harder, live a more moral life.’
350
250
150
50
1926 1928 1930 1932 1934 1936
26
2.2 The Great Depression
While such views were common, others, such as Keynes, worried about the adverse
impact of falling markets, arguing that a more useful policy would be for the authorities to
prevent the extreme price drops.
Austria
Austria was the first country to experience a general economic crisis. The balance sheet
of its largest bank, Credit-Anstalt, equalled total government expenditure. In May 1931,
bank officers informed the government that deteriorating loan performance had com-
pletely wiped out its capital. It was bankrupt. The authorities and some private financial
institutions attempted to mount a rescue, but were unable to secure the necessary loans
in time. In response to the crisis, Austria went off the gold standard and imposed capital
controls.
Credit-Anstalt had a controlling interest in Budapest’s largest bank, and as soon as the
crisis erupted in Vienna, foreign investors withdrew their deposits from this and other
Hungarian institutions. By 15 May, bank runs in Budapest were underway.
Germany
The crisis in Austria provoked immediate withdrawals in Berlin. There were worries that
if Austria could freeze foreign deposits so could Germany. In July a fully-fledged banking
panic erupted, starting with Danat Bank, the financier of a failed textile firm, Nordwolle.
As the German government was dependent on foreign creditors for its own financing,
the crisis caused a sudden stop in lending, triggering a run on the mark. The German cen-
tral bank, the Reichsbank, lost $250 million in gold and was forced to ration credit to the
banking system.
US president Herbert Hoover announced the so-called Hoover Moratorium in June,
which called for a one-year moratorium on debt arising from WWI. Whilst quite unpopu-
lar, especially in France, it got support from 15 major nations and Congress. The Hoover
Moratorium was not effective in engineering an international support operation, and
Germany was forced to abandon the gold standard.
27
Chapter 2 The Great Depression, 1929–1933
deposits, whilst earnings from services declined and capital income from abroad col-
lapsed. Unemployment exceeded 20% and foreign banks were unwilling to provide credit.
As the domestic currency denominated assets were converted into foreign exchange,
the BoE, committed to pegging the exchange rate, was haemorrhaging gold. To defend
the gold parity, the Bank raised interest rates and restricted credit, aggravating the bank-
ing crisis.
Eventually, this forced the BoE to abandon the gold standard in September 1931. In
retrospect, this was the right decision as the British economy quickly recovered, and the
impact of the Great Depression was not as big in the UK as in some other countries.
The decision to abandon the gold standard in 1931 resonates strongly in the ongoing
crisis. Because it was key to economic recovery, it has been used to justify subsequent
policies of devaluing sterling, in particular quantitative easing (QE). Similarly, many com-
mentators maintain that the gold standard has strong parallels with the euro, and if only
countries like Spain could devalue, their economies would recover.
28
2.3 Causes of the Great Depression
support to reopen. This was enough to restore confidence, and as the banks reopened, long
lines of depositors formed outside the reopened banks, waiting to put their money back in.
By the end of the week, a total of $1 billion had been redeposited in the banks.
Double dip
While the worst of the Great Depression occurred at the beginning of 1933 and the US
economy recovered significantly in the subsequent years, the crisis returned in 1937.
There are several reasons why that happened. The surviving banks had massive amounts
of cash on reserve with the Fed, both as insurance and also because of lack of demand.
The Fed worried about inflation and tightened monetary policy. Inevitably, this led to a
contraction in lending. At the same time, taxes were on the increase. All these factors left
the economy fragile and susceptible to a double dip in 1937.
In retrospect, a looser fiscal and monetary policy in the years immediately after the
main crisis year of 1933 might have prevented the double dip. That was of course not
known to the policymakers at the time. Eventually, it was the rapidly increased govern-
ment spending with the onset of the Second World War (WWII) that pulled the US out of
the recession.
29
Chapter 2 The Great Depression, 1929–1933
export subsidies and the manipulation of exchange rates. Policymakers at the time were
aware of pitfalls in using trade restrictions, and many attempts were made to discour-
age their use, for example in the World Economic Conference of 1927, but overall such
attempts were not effective.
Trade restrictions were seen much more favourably than today, and both mainstream
political parties and well-known economists like Keynes advocated their use. One reason
is that governments were prevented from employing other measures to stimulate their
economies because of the gold standard and the prevailing orthodoxy that government
should run balanced budgets, even in downturns.
Smoot–Hawley Act
The most infamous example of trade restrictions is the Smoot–Hawley Act of 1930 that
significantly raised US average tariffs. Even before the Act became law, France, Italy, India
and Australia increased their tariffs in response. Once it became law, it let loose a wave
of retaliation. Spain sharply increased its tariffs in July 1930, Switzerland boycotted US
exports, Canada raised tariffs three times, and there were similar tariff increases in many
other countries, such as Cuba, Mexico, France, New Zealand and Australia.
In his 1932 presidential campaign, Roosevelt attacked the Smoot–Hawley Act as a
cause of the Depression. He claimed that when other countries ran out of gold, they paid
their debts by sending more goods, which meant that tariffs had the effect of lowering
prices rather than raising them.
Collapse in trade
As a consequence of the Smoot–Hawley Act, and the various other similar initiatives in
other countries, global trade seized up, with countries experiencing serious difficulties
because they could not export, and frequently defaulting. The severity of the collapse
of trade during 1929–1933 can be seen in the list below and in Figure 2.6, the numbers
being taken from Kindleberger (1986). Globally, trade was reduced by more than two-
thirds. The impact on a sample of countries can be seen in the following list.
30
2.3 Causes of the Great Depression
January
r 2998 Fe
be bru
em 2739 ary
c
De
1839
r
be
Ma
em
rch
v
1206
No
October 992
1932
1931
1930
1929
April
r
be
Ma
m
pte
y
Se
st Ju
gu ne
Au
July
60
50 M0 M1 M2
USD billions
40
30
20
10
0
1926 1928 1930 1932 1934 1936 1938 1940
(a) Money
60%
45%
30%
M0/M2
15%
M1/M2
0%
1926 1928 1930 1932 1934 1936 1938 1940
(b) Ratios of M0 and M1 to M2
31
Chapter 2 The Great Depression, 1929–1933
cycle, with the reduction in money supply leading to deflation, further restricting the money
supply and contributing to a liquidity trap.
Post-Depression analysis is mostly unanimous in identifying the contraction of the money
supply in the US as a major cause of the Depression, in no little measure due to one of the
most influential economic studies ever made, by Friedman and Schwartz (1963) in their
book A Monetary History of the United States: 1867–1960, where they argued that it was the
Fed that was primarily responsible for turning the crisis of 1929 into the Great Depression.
1 The Fed did too little to counteract the credit contraction caused by failing banks. If
banks fail, money supply (credit) contracts, therefore the Fed should have increased
the money supply to counteract the reduction.
2 The Fed actually reduced credit between December 1930 and April 1931. This led to
more and more banks being forced to sell assets at firesale prices, and to deteriorating
liquidity conditions.
3 When the UK abandoned the gold standard in September 1931, the Fed raised dis-
count rates in anticipation of a rush to convert dollars into gold. This did stop the drain
of gold but drove yet more banks into insolvency. But the Fed was in no immediate
danger of running out of gold, since it held 40% of global gold reserves and had more
than enough to meet its legal requirements.
4 Only under enormous political pressure did the Fed start undertaking open market
operations in April 1932. Unfortunately, this was too little, too late, and failed to pre-
vent a wave of bank failures in the last quarter of 1932.
5 When rumours that the incoming Roosevelt administration would devalue the dol-
lar led to a renewed flight from dollars into gold, the Fed once again raised the
discount rate.
According to Friedman and Schwartz, the Fed should have aggressively injected liquid-
ity into the banking system from 1929 onwards, using open market operations on a large
scale, and encouraging lending through the discount window. Gold outflows should not
have been such a priority consideration.
It is still a matter of debate why the Fed reacted the way they did. Friedman and
Schwartz argued that it was the death in 1928 of Benjamin Strong, the Governor of the
NYFed, which caused the deterioration in Fed performance.
An alternative explanation by Epstein and Ferguson (1984) and Anderson et al. (1988)
maintains that this was a deliberate act by the Fed to protect the interests of member
commercial banks rather than the general economy, and that the Fed was content with
seeing non-member banks fail, so that the relative importance of the Fed would increase.
The conclusion of Friedman and Schwartz that the collapse in money supply was a major
factor in causing the Great Depression has significantly influenced policymaking in the ongo-
ing crisis, and is a key reason why central banks have provided significant amounts of QE.
32
2.3 Causes of the Great Depression
US France Germany
UK Argentina Japan
7000
5000 x
x
x x
x
3000
x
1000
1925 1930 1935 1940
Figure 2.8 GDP per capita in constant 1990 dollars, and year of going off gold
Data source: www.ggdc.net/MADDISON/oriindex.htm
33
Chapter 2 The Great Depression, 1929–1933
Abandoning the gold standard was successful. Once prices started rising, the real value
of debt was reduced, making businesses more willing to borrow and consumers more
ready to spend.
This happened after a long period of little or no investment and sharply reduced
personal consumption, meaning there was significant pent-up demand for both indus-
trial goods and consumer goods. Once consumers and companies realised that there
was less benefit in holding onto savings because prices were rising sharply, they were
encouraged to spend, thereby stimulating the economy. Note the difference between
the global abandonment of the gold standard and the piecemeal approaches discussed
in Section 2.1.4. There, an individual country in difficulty devalued whilst the major
industrialised nations, and the main importers of agricultural goods, did not. In this
case, it was the industrialised countries that allowed their money supply to expand,
resulting in prices increasing across the board.
34
2.4 Implications for future policy
‘Almost all the great powers have been negotiating for months about how many
billions a year should be paid until 1966, and thereafter until 1988, by a country
that is not even in a position to pay its own civil servants’ salaries the next day.’
35
Chapter 2 The Great Depression, 1929–1933
Comparisons
The 1920s enjoyed rapid economic growth, with The boom prior to 2007 was based on new
new technology, silent films and the Model T technology like the Internet, and the renewed
Ford, and the beginnings of radio and prominence of financial markets. The financial
commercial air services. Stock market speculation system used high levels of leverage, with strong
was rampant, leverage was high and capital capital flows to financial markets.
flowed to Wall Street.
Financial markets
Rapid development of financial markets, with Financial innovation, with new forms of real-
ordinary citizens for the first time having access estate financing, like subprime, emerged, and a
to financial services such as mortgages and stock rapid increase in homeownership and low-cost
market investments bought on the margin. A mortgages fuelled a real-estate boom. The market
stock market and real-estate boom ensued, boom led to the belief that prices could rise
creating the feeling that prices could rise indefinitely. New financial practices like structured
indefinitely, leading to reckless risk taking. credit and shadow banking enabled risk taking
out of the view of supervisors and the market.
US bailouts
RFC TARP
In 1931, President Hoover set up the RFC, making The main bailout programme was the Troubled
loans to financial institutions of all types, with Asset Relief Program (TARP), authorised at
$500 million outright, and the possibility of $700 billion, but total disbursements were only
issuing up to $1.5 billion in government debt (1% $431 billion, 4.8% and 3% of GDP respectively.
to 3% of GDP respectively). The RFC is seen as a
failure, not least because the bailouts were public.
Short selling
President Hoover compelled the New York Stock The Bush administration temporarily imposed
Exchange to curb short selling. restrictions on short selling of shares in some
financial institutions.
LOLR
The US did not do LOLR until Roosevelt took Various large-sized LOLR-type credit and
office in March 1933. liquidity facilities were provided.
Trade
The Smoot–Hawley Act and various other trade No restrictions on trade have yet been imposed.
restrictions reduced global trade by more than
two-thirds.
Money and liquidity
The US authorities allowed the money supply to Significant QE was provided and deflation was
shrink and deflation to set in. prevented.
36
2.5 Summary
Lesson learned
Generally, it seems that the policy response in the fall of 2008 was the right one, and
the authorities did not repeat the mistakes made in the Great Depression. Deflation
was avoided, widespread bank failures were prevented, trade remained free and global
authorities actively cooperated in their crisis response. These measures seemed successful
in preventing the crisis from turning into another Great Depression.
2.5 Summary
The biggest economic crisis the world has ever seen is the Great Depression. The causes of
the Depression are varied and remain controversial, though they include war reparations,
agricultural overproduction, inappropriate monetary policies (too loose and too strict),
competitive devaluations and trade restrictions.
When the crisis was underway, the policy response could not have been worse; coun-
tries focused on narrow national interests, trade collapsed by more than two-thirds,
37
Chapter 2 The Great Depression, 1929–1933
liquidity (money supply) was allowed to contract and deflation to set in, and banking
systems were allowed to fail in some countries.
The causes of the Great Depression, as well as the needed policy response, have been
extensively studied. The world authorities facing a new global crisis in 2007 effectively
prevented a new Great Depression from emerging by explicitly avoiding the mistakes
made before and during the Great Depression.
The European authorities fighting the European sovereign debt crisis have not been as willing
to take on board Great Depression lessons, especially problems arising from the gold standard.
References
Ahamed, L. (2009). Lords of Finance, The Bankers Who Broke the World. The Penguin Group.
Anderson, G. M., Shughart, W. F., II., and Tollison, R. D. (1988). A public choice theory of the
great contraction. Public Choice, 59: 3–23.
Bernanke, B. (1995). The macroeconomics of the Great Depression: a comparative approach.
J. Money Credit and Banking, 27(1): 1–28.
Eichengreen, B. (1996). Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919–1939.
Oxford University Press.
Eichengreen, B. and Irwin, D. (2009). The slide to protectionism in the Great Depression: who
succumbed and why? NBER Working Paper 15142.
Epstein, G. and Ferguson, T. (1984). Monetary policy, loan liquidation, and industrial conflict:
the Federal Reserve and open market operations of 1932. J. Econ. Hist., 44: 957–83.
Ferguson, N. (2008). The Ascent of Money. The Penguin Group.
Friedman, M. and Schwartz, A. (1963). A Monetary History of the United States: 1867–1960.
Princeton University. Press.
Keynes, J. M. (1920). The Economic Consequences of the Peace. Harcourt Brace, New York.
Keynes, J. M. (1924). A Tract on Monetary Reform. Macmillan.
Kindleberger, C. (1986). The World in Depression, 1929–1939, 2nd edition. University of California Press.
38
3 Endogenous risk
finally market crashes. This creates risk that is hidden until it is too late, providing a
false sense of stability, while the market is really heading for the precipice.
Such spirals of coordinated selling need to be strong enough to overcome the usual
stabilising forces in markets such as arbitrageurs, hedge funds, sovereign wealth funds
and the like that could be expected to step in and buy the cheap assets, putting a
floor under prices.
Financial markets are subject to both exogenous and endogenous risk, but it is the
latter that is more damaging. It is behind some of the biggest financial crisis episodes
in history, while being much harder to model than exogenous risk. For a single bank,
most risk is exogenous. For the financial system, risk is almost entirely endogenous,
even if not to a high degree most of the time. As an approximation, those concerned
with financial risk might not be too far off by assuming risk is exogenous 99.9% of the
time. It is, however, the other 0.1% when endogenous risk becomes a serious concern.
That is when economic agents become harmonised in behaviour, and the conditions
are ripe for a crisis to emerge.
Endogenous risk has direct implications for financial models, since most such mod-
els assume risk is exogenous. This suggests that the models may work well 99.9% of
the time, but fail when needed the most — at times of extreme market turmoil. In
turn, this leads to direct policy conclusions on financial stability, the use of risk mod-
els by bank supervisors and the wisdom of prudential regulations.
The concept of endogenous risk directly relates to other economic theories, such
as the beauty contest in Keynes (1936). It also connects to Minsky (1992) who argued
that economies have either stable or unstable financial regimes; even if the economy
starts out stable, continued prosperity paves the way for an unstable system.
Similarly, endogenous risk impacts on policies towards financial stability. For
example, prudential banking regulations aim at ensuring that each and every finan-
cial institution behaves properly, avoiding excessive risk. Endogenous risk analysis
predicts that such prevention regulations are directly destabilising, because as banks
act prudently in a crisis, their very acts of self-preservation cause them to dispose of
the same risky assets and buy the same safe assets, amplifying price movements and
distress. This suggests that any financial stability policies explicitly need to consider
the potential for endogenous feedbacks.
Key concepts
■ Endogenous risk
■ Firesale externality
■ Trading strategies
■ Actual and perceived risk
■ Dual role of prices
40
3.1 Millennium Bridge
A Value of assets
C Cash
D Debt
d Change operator
E Equity
f Option price
L Leverage
n indicates iteration
P Prices
Q Quantity (units of assets held)
X Strike price
∆ Option delta from the Black–Scholes equation
E Random number
L Price impact factor
S Standard deviation
1
See http://news.bbc.co.uk/hi/english/static/in_depth/uk/2000/millennium_bridge/default.stm and www.
youtube.com/watch? v=eAXVaXWZ8.
41
Chapter 3 Endogenous risk
to break step when crossing bridges. This happens because marching soldiers generate
harmonised frequencies that can create a feedback between the internal frequency of a
bridge and the soldiers’ steps, leading to a collapse. However, the people crowded on the
Millennium Bridge on the opening day were not soldiers, but people of all walks of life.
The chance of them spontaneously marching was considered next to impossible.
Diagnosis
Every bridge is designed to move with the elements, and the Millennium Bridge was sup-
posed to sway gently in response to the Thames breeze. A gust of wind – an exogenous
shock – hit the bridge, causing it to move sideways and wobble. When this happens a
natural reaction is to adjust one’s stance to regain balance. By doing so, the bridge gets
pushed back, making it sway even more, causing people to adjust their stance yet again –
more and more at the same time – this time pushing the bridge in the opposite direction.
As an ever increasing number of pedestrians started to adjust their stance simultaneously,
the bridge moved more and soon almost all the pedestrians joined in. This created a
mutually reinforcing feedback loop between the synchronised adjustments of the pedes-
trians’ stance and the bridge’s wobble,2 shown in Figure 3.1.
We cannot identify the endogeneity of the Millennium Bridge by considering either the
properties of the bridge or the crowd in isolation; they have to be studied jointly. This is
what makes endogenous risk problems hard.
Wider lessons
The wobble of the bridge was created by people reacting to a gust of wind pushing the
bridge. The wobble continued and intensified even though the initial gust of wind had
long passed. This is a concise example of how a relatively small exogenous shock (the gust
of wind) causes a large endogenous response. It is a clear example of endogenous risk in
action, unlike, for example, an earthquake which is an exogenous shock. The ultimate les-
son from the Millennium Bridge is that it is not the shock that matters but the feedback
mechanism that allows a small shock to be amplified into a large event.
Pedestrians
adjust
stance
Bridge
Bridge
gets
moves
pushed
People further
adjust their
stance
2
For more information, see www.arup.com/millenniumbridge/challenge/results.html.
42
3.2 Dual role of prices
The financial system is replete with analogous processes, whereby an innocuous shock
has the potential to trigger a systemic crisis. Financial markets are examples of environ-
ments whereby individuals not only react to events around them, but also by their actions
directly affect market outcomes, because of balance sheet adjustments. The pedestrians
on the Millennium Bridge were like traders reacting to price changes, and the movement
of the bridge was like price moves in markets. Consequently, the notion of endogenous
risk provides a clear mechanism for analysing feedbacks in financial systems.
43
Chapter 3 Endogenous risk
example below demonstrates that constraints can lead to upward-sloping demand func-
tions for regular assets.
Setup
Suppose a bank’s leverage (L) is restricted to 5. In other words, the ratio of assets (A) to
equity (E) has to be 5:
A
L = = 5
E
We set the initial price of the asset, P, to $10, where the bank holds Q = 100 units of the asset,
and has debt of D = +800. This means that the value of its portfolio is A = Q * P = +1000,
and its equity is E = A - D = +200. The initial balance sheet is therefore:
Assets Liabilities
A = 1000 E = 200
D = 800
and the bank meets its leverage constraint. Suppose the asset is hit by a negative exog-
enous shock, causing its price to fall to P = +9. This price drop directly affects equity and
the balance sheet becomes:
Assets Liabilities
A = 900 E = 100
D = 800
Leverage is now 9 = 900>100, and the bank needs to take action to meet the constraint.
The most direct way is to reduce debt by selling assets.
Consider two different cases. In the first case, the bank is a price taker, meaning that
no matter how much it buys or sells, prices remain unaffected. Prices are exogenous. In
the second case the bank exerts a significant market power, so that its buying or selling
decisions cause prices to move. Prices are endogenous. The former case corresponds to a
small individual trader, whilst the latter case reflects a large bank or fund.
D1 - D0 = P1Q1 - Q02
D1 = D0 + PQ1 - PQ0 (3.1)
A1 PQ1
L = =
E1 PQ1 - D1
44
3.2 Dual role of prices
PQ1
L =
PQ0 - D0
D0
Q1 = L a Q0 - b (3.2)
P
In our example, the bank should now hold 500/9 units of the asset. By selling 100 - 500>9
units, the target leverage ratio is reached and the bank needs to do nothing further. Its
balance sheet becomes:
Assets Liabilities
A = 500 E = 100
D = 400
This means that in order to meet the leverage constraint, the bank had to sell $400 worth
of the asset. This happened because prices dropped, so the demand function is upward
sloping. If the price shock had been positive, the bank would have bought the asset. We
show the demand function in Figure 3.2.
Pn - Pn - 1 = lPn - 11Qn - 1 - Qn - 22
l is known as the price impact factor, with Pn - 11Qn - 1 - Qn - 22 the amount the bank wants
to sell, in our case $400.
Because prices fall in response to the sale, the bank will not be meeting the leverage
constraint even after selling the same amount as in the exogenous case above. It will have
to sell more assets. That in turn triggers a further price drop, and so forth, until we get
convergence. The process to compute the variables is as follows:
1 Pn = Pn - 1 + lPn - 11Qn - 1 - Qn - 22
2 Qn = L1Qn - 1 - Dn - 1 >Pn2
3 An = PnQn
4 En = An >L
5 D n = A n - En
Let the price impact factor be l = 0.001. We then repeatedly apply (3.2) until we get
convergence, with the results of 10 rounds shown in Table 3.1.
45
Chapter 3 Endogenous risk
Iteration Q P A
The initial sale was for 44.444 units of the asset, but as we keep on iterating we get
further sales of 12.6 units, causing prices to drop further to $8.492.
Exogenous
Endogenous
Final change
50
in quantity
−50
The x-axis shows the initial price change, with our $1 price drop from above on the extreme
left. We then go all the way to a $1 price increase on the right. The y-axis shows the final
change in the bank’s holding of the asset. On the extreme left we get 55.55 for the exogenous
case and 42.93 in the endogenous case. This demonstrates the upward-sloping demand
functions and shows that when prices are endogenous, the impact is much stronger.
In this case, the price impact was quite small, 0.001, and we still manage to get a sizable
endogenous change in prices and quantity. This succinctly demonstrates how a small exoge-
nous shock can trigger a large outcome, where the constraints dictate a ‘sell cheap, buy dear’
strategy that generates precisely the kind of vicious feedback loops that destabilise markets.
3.3 Risk
There is no single way to define risk. A basic textbook definition is the volatility of returns,
but that is only a complete description if financial returns are normally distributed, with
constant unchanging volatility. Neither assumption is true in reality. This means that any
46
3.3 Risk
‘The riskiness of an investment is not measured by beta [a Wall Street term encom-
passing volatility and often used in measuring risk] but rather by the probability –
the reasoned probability – of that investment causing its owner a loss of purchasing
power over his contemplated holding period. Assets can fluctuate greatly in price
and not be risky as long as they are reasonably certain to deliver increased purchas-
ing power over their holding period. And as we will see, a nonfluctuating asset can
be laden with risk.’
Financial regulations employ Value-at-Risk (VaR) (see the appendix to Chapter 13) as a
preferred way to quantify market risk. This is based on the risk of daily outcomes (linearly
scaled to 10 days) that happen with 1% probability, so once every five months. In most
cases, the VaR is calculated by volatilities. It therefore falls under Buffett’s criticism.
Risk-free
Some assets have such low risk that they are referred to as risk-free. This is typically a short-
term obligation of sovereigns considered extremely unlikely to default, like the United
States (US), United Kingdom (UK) and Switzerland. Even in that case, the investment is
not totally risk-free because it involves putting money into a local currency which is at risk
from inflation. Some governments offer inflation-linked bonds which come close to being
risk-free.
Gold is, however, often considered a good hedge against inflation, and one might be
tempted to invest in an asset like gold in order to avoid risk, but it is far from risk-free, as
can be seen in Figure 3.3.
2000
1500
1000
500
47
Chapter 3 Endogenous risk
3.3.1 Dependence
Correlations between asset returns are often higher when the markets are falling, even
tending to 1 in a market crash. An increased level of correlations is often a sign of market
turmoil. While the theoretical analysis above focused on the interaction between market
and funding liquidity for a single security, it also has implications for how multiple asset
prices move together in times of stress.
Danielsson et al. (2012b) demonstrate that a chain of events like that described in
Figure 4.4 in Chapter 4 also affects the dependence between assets. In normal times,
dependence between assets is generally based on the inherent properties of the assets
themselves, with similar assets tending to move in similar ways.
In a crisis, the situation changes, and is much more affected by the liquidity positions
of the banks that trigger the crisis. This can happen because if a bank suffers from a lack of
funding liquidity, it may be forced to sell its assets across the board, adversely impacting
on the price of each and every one. This is manifested in higher correlations.
Forced selling in a firesale externality scenario tends to create new forms of depend-
ence between assets held by similar investors. This leads to the empirical prediction that
correlations increase sharply in times of market turmoil, and especially in crises.
2600
2400
2200
2000
1800
48
3.4 Dynamic trading strategies
The postmortem analysis by the US government, the Brady Commission (1988) report,
found that the main underlying cause was the use of an automatic trading strategy called
portfolio insurance.
Portfolio insurance
Portfolio insurance is a trading strategy whereby an investor wishes to hedge downside
risk by dynamically replicating a put option. In principle, the investor could just buy the
put option, but it may not be available for the particular asset, or be illiquid and/or too
expensive. Under the assumptions of the option pricing model of Black and Scholes
(1973b), there should be no difference between the price of an option bought outright
and a dynamically replicated option.
Option price f
pa
yo
pa
ff a
yo
f fp
te
rio
xp
r to
ira
exp
i
t
rati
ion
∆ on
X Stock price P
49
Chapter 3 Endogenous risk
Simulation
The realised return from day t - 1 to day t is
1 + et + 1At - At - 12 (3.3)
where et is the exogenous random return and At - At - 1 the purchase (or sale) of the stock.
First week. The trader starts with no funds. The initial stock price is 100. The trader
shorts the stock by ∆ units, and from the Black–Scholes equation we find that
∆ = -0.14. This gives the trader 14.3 in cash. We assume this is the same in both the
endogenous and exogenous price cases in order to start both off in the same place.
Exogenous prices
Second week. We start by drawing a random shock,
0.252
P ∼n a 0, b
52
resulting in -0.016 in this particular case, so the price falls to 98.4, and ∆ becomes
-0.17. As a consequence, we sell more of the stock, increasing the cash balance to 16.8.
T - t e P P* ∆ ∆* C C*
50
3.4 Dynamic trading strategies
We continue repeating this until at expiration, when T - t = 0, the price of the stock
ends up in the money at 84.2, the price where we have to buy it back, while the final cash
position is 87.6. This means that the final payoff is
87.6 - 84.2 = 3.4
If we had instead bought a put option at the Black–Scholes price of $0.80, the payoff
would have been
So why the discrepancy? If we had delta hedged continuously, as assumed by the Black–
Scholes model, the outcomes would have been identical. However, with one week pass-
ing between re-hedging, the error becomes non-trivial.
Endogenous prices
Third week. We start by drawing a random shock,
0.252
P ∼n a 0, b
52
resulting in 0.022. In the exogenous case this would make the price rise to 100.6; how-
ever, we sold at the end of the previous week and (3.3) indicates that the price falls
further to 98.1.
This continues for a few weeks, but it is really by the eighth week that things heat up
and the downward spiral begins to gather momentum.
Eighth week. The random shock is -0.085, coming after a price drop of 6.6 over the
previous week, resulting in a large negative price movement, all the way to 52.6. Delta
is on its way to become -1, which is obvious from Figure 3.5 since we are so deep in
the money.
This continues on in the following week, slightly reversing in the last week. At that
time, the actual price has fallen to 24.8 and the cash balance is 71.5. This means the profit
from the strategy is
71.5 - 24.8 = 46.7
If we had instead purchased a put option, and the prices had followed the same pattern,
the profit would have been
Here the difference between the dynamic trading strategy and an outright purchase of the
option is much larger than in the exogenous case. This is not surprising, since it follows
from Figure 3.5 that if prices move a lot, the delta approximation becomes less accurate.
This is an illustration that the Black–Scholes formula is underpricing the put option when
there is feedback.
Analysis
We summarise these results in Figure 3.6 which shows the two price columns from Table 3.2.
The dynamic strategy amplifies the price movements, both going up and going down.
If the price shocks are small, it doesn’t make much difference, but by the middle of the
51
Chapter 3 Endogenous risk
100
80 Theoretical price
Actual price
60
40
9/10 8/10 7/10 6/10 5/10 4/10 3/10 2/10 1/10 0/10
T−t
Price falls
∆ falls, sell
period we get a few small but negative price shocks in a row. Initially, it does not matter
much, but all of a sudden the endogenous shock kicks in and prices fall sharply over the
span of two weeks. This is captured in Figure 3.7. This is exactly how many market crashes
happen, and demonstrates the importance of considering endogenous feedback.
Trading rules
The stock market crash of 1987 is a classic example of the destabilising feedback effect
on market dynamics of concerted selling pressure arising from certain mechanical trading
rules, like the sell-on-loss considered here.
What is especially striking in this example is that the underlying destabilising behav-
iour is completely invisible so long as trading activity remains below some critical but
unknown threshold. It is only when this threshold is exceeded that the endogenous risk
52
3.5 Actual and perceived risk and bubbles
becomes apparent, causing a market crash. This clearly demonstrates the difference
between perceived risk and actual risk.
Perceived risk
The two risk lines are even more interesting. The red line labelled perceived risk shows
how market participants view risk when using typical risk forecast models used by the
industry. As the prices increase, perceived risk falls.
When market participants observe increasing prices and falling risk they are encouraged
to continue buying, an example of a momentum strategy. In the short run, this becomes a
virtuous cycle of ever increasing prices and lower risk.
9 Prices
Perceived risk
7 Actual risk
1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19
53
Chapter 3 Endogenous risk
Eventually, the bubble bursts. It is as if somebody yells ‘the Emperor has no clothes’
with traders realising there is nothing fundamental behind these high prices. This prompts
them all to sell at the same time, causing prices to collapse. Because the fall in prices
makes perceived volatility increase, risk forecast models will report sharply increasing risk.
Actual risk
What happens to the actual risk? We show that in the green line. Actual risk builds up
before market prices shoot up, eventually indicating a constant high probability of a crash
in the near future. Eventually, as the market collapses, so does actual risk.
This means that perceived risk sends the wrong signals in all states of the world. Before
the crisis, it is biased downwards, giving a too optimistic view of the world, and after the
main crisis event, it becomes too high, making us too pessimistic. This is one manifesta-
tion of pro-cyclicality.
This is one of the main explanations for the phenomenon observed by Andrew Crockett
(2000), mentioned earlier:
‘The received wisdom is that risk increases in recessions and falls in booms. In
contrast, it may be more helpful to think of risk as increasing during upswings, as
financial imbalances build up, and materialising in recessions.’
0.5
Risk level targeted
Risk of very large
risk management
and uncommon
outcomes
0.4
by active
Distribution of risk
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
−3 −2 −1 0 1 2
Market outcomes
54
3.5 Actual and perceived risk and bubbles
day-to-day risk, whilst the red line shows what happens when they do. The impact is to
reduce the probability of uncommon events, shown by the red line being below the blue
line in the sides of the distribution, but at the expense of the red line being higher in the
tails, signalling the higher probability of extreme outcomes. Keep in mind that the area
under both functions must be 1 because these are probability distributions.
10%
200
8%
Case−Shiller
Case−Shiller
Delinquency
180
160 Delinquency 6%
rate
140 rate
4%
120
2%
100
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012
55
Chapter 3 Endogenous risk
‘LTCM would make money by being a vacuum sucking up nickels that no one else
could see.’
LTCM operated with high leverage, at around 30. It drove very hard bargains on financ-
ing and was able to get low rates and special deals because its prime brokers did not
want to get left out of LTCM business and were prepared to cut corners both on the rates
charged and on the amount of collateral demanded.
Trading strategies
The mainstay of LTCM’s trading strategies was convergence or relative value trades, in
which a long position in one asset is hedged by a matching short position. The under-
lying principle is that two fundamentally identical assets should have identical prices,
otherwise there is an arbitrage opportunity. Their VaR in 1998 indicated that it would
take a 10s event for it to lose all capital in a single year. Since it makes sense to analyse
sigma events only under the normal distribution, this implies a probability of default
of 7.6 * 10-23 . By comparison, the Earth is 4.5 * 109 years old and the Universe is
1.3 * 1010 years old.
LTCM’s very success attracted copycats. As more and more players with similar trading
strategies crowded into the market, spreads narrowed, eroding profit margins.
3
The events are well summarised in two official reports by the Bank for International Settlements (BIS)
(Committee on the Global Financial System, 1999) and the International Monetary Fund (IMF) (1998).
The first is at www.bis.org/publ/cgfs12.htm, and the second in Chapter III of www.imf.org/external/
pubs/ft/weo1298/index.htm.
56
3.6 The LTCM crisis of 1998
A perfect storm
In May and June 1998 fund returns were -6.42% and -10.14% respectively, reducing LTCM’s
capital by $461 million. This was further aggravated by the Russian financial crises in August
and September 1998, when the Russian government defaulted on their government bonds
on 17 August. This triggered a panic: investors sold Japanese and European bonds to buy US
30
10
Jan 1990 Jan 1992 Jan 1994 Jan 1996 Jan 1998
(a) 1990 to June 1998
40
30
20
4
Vega is the sensitivity of the Black–Scholes price of an option with respect to volatility, that is, the first
derivative of the Black–Scholes equation with respect to volatility.
57
Chapter 3 Endogenous risk
Treasury bonds (flight to quality), and hoped-for profits from convergence trades became
large losses, as the value of the bonds diverged. Meanwhile, credit spreads widened, volatil-
ity shot up to 45%, and correlations went to 1, as usually happens in crises.
In the first three weeks of September, LTCM’s equity tumbled from $2.3 billion to $600
million, leading to a sharp increase in its already high leverage, further increasing its fra-
gility. Eventually, it had to unwind the convergence trades, sell the long positions, and
buy back the short positions. This caused an adverse price shock for all other traders with
similar positions and for some triggering margin calls. A vicious feedback loop was set in
motion in which adverse price moves led to liquidations, which further fed adverse price
moves. Schematically, this can be seen in Figure 3.12.
Realising the potentially disastrous consequences of letting LTCM fail, the New York
Federal Reserve Bank (NYFed) organised a bailout of $3.625 billion by the major credi-
tors of LTCM to avoid a wider collapse in the financial markets. In return, the participat-
ing banks got a 90% share in the fund and a promise that a supervisory board would be
established. After the bailout, the panic abated, and the positions formerly held by LTCM
were eventually liquidated at a small profit to the new owners.
Analysis
What befell LTCM was a classic example of endogenous risk. The owners of LTCM main-
tained that it was quite safe as perceived risk was low. Investors could expect losses in
excess of 20% in one year out of 50.
One LTCM partner said that ‘what happened to LTCM was a perfect storm – a
100-year flood’. But does that stand up to scrutiny? The endogenous risk analysis
above suggests otherwise: the unprecedented price movements in the summer of
1998 were not the results of extremely bad luck, in the same way that the Millennium
Bridge did not wobble because of bad luck. Instead, it was only a matter of time
before a small exogenous shock would hit LTCM, triggering its failure. Once the bub-
ble started collapsing, the internal dynamics of the feedback loop took hold with a
vengeance. Under the right conditions, the crisis was a near certainty, with endog-
enous risk doing the harm, because of the endogenous feedback loops between mar-
gin calls and distress.
Deleveraging
Margin calls
Adverse price move
Distress
58
3.7 Conclusion
Irrationality of markets?
LTCM invested in a mean reverting asset whose value was far away from the long-run
mean. We would expect that given time, the VIX would eventually fall, bringing signifi-
cant profits to LTCM. Indeed, profits were made, but only by those who bailed LTCM out.
So why did LTCM not profit from this? The explanation is provided by an observation
often attributed incorrectly to Keynes, who supposedly said ‘The market can stay irra-
tional longer than you can stay solvent.’ The very high levels of VIX were explicitly caused
by the uncertainty created by LTCM’s existence. That meant that a necessary condition for
the VIX to return to its long-run mean was the failure of LTCM.
3.7 Conclusion
Most risk models and pricing models used by the financial industry and financial supervisors
assume risk to be exogenous, that is, risk arrives to the markets from outside but is not endog-
enously generated within the financial system. While this assumption is clearly incorrect, it is
usually accepted as a necessary evil because modelling endogenous risk is very hard.
The concept of endogenous risk is not confined to finance. For example, the Millennium
Bridge wobbled when it was opened in 2000 because of endogenous feedbacks.
One reason why endogenous feedbacks are so prevalent within the financial system is
the constraints imposed on market participants, like leverage constraints. Endogenous risk
is also created when a substantial number of market participants mechanistically follow
the same trading rules, which is exactly what caused the biggest stock market crash in
history in 1987.
The most infamous hedge fund failure in history, that of LTCM, happened because
the managers of the fund did not understand the endogenous risk it created, and naively
assumed that in essence it could not fail. That led them to take ever more risk, ensuring
the fund’s eventual failure.
2 The former general manager of the BIS, Andrew Crockett stated in 2000:
‘The received wisdom is that risk increases in recessions and falls in booms. In con-
trast, it may be more helpful to think of risk as increasing during upswings, as finan-
cial imbalances build up, and materialising in recessions.’
How does his view on risk relate to endogenous risk, and what is the implication for
governments’ policies on financial stability?
3 It has been said that financial risk models are least reliable when needed the most.
Do you agree?
4 Discuss financial bubbles, considering both prices and risk, from the point of view of
endogenous and exogenous risk, using the terminology of actual and perceived risk.
59
Chapter 3 Endogenous risk
5 To what extent can crisis events from 2007 be explained by the notion of endogenous
risk?
6 To what extent is the sovereign debt crisis an endogenous risk story, and to what extent
is it not?
7 Suppose a hedge fund operates with four times leverage (assets over equity), where its
equity is worth $10 and the current price of the asset it holds is $5.
(a) Suppose the fund is currently meeting its leverage constraint. How many units of
the asset does it told?
(b) Suppose the price of the asset increases to $6 and the fund is a price taker. How
does it respond?
(c) Suppose instead the fund exerts a price impact, whereby the price of the asset
moves by 0.1% of the amount the fund trades. How does it react to the price
increase?
References
Black, F. and Scholes, M. (1973b). The valuation of option contracts and a test of market effi-
ciency. J. Finance, 27: 399–418.
Brady Commission (1988). Report of the presidential task force on market mechanisms.
Technical report, Government Printing Office, Washington DC.
Buffett, W. (2012). Why stocks beat gold and bonds. Fortune, 27 February.
Committee on the Global Financial System (1999). A review of financial market events in
autumn 1998. Technical report, Bank for International Settlements.
Crockett, A. (2000). Marrying the micro- and macro-prudential dimensions of financial stabil-
ity. The General Manager of the Bank for International Settlements, www.bis.org/review/
rr000921b.pdf.
Danielsson, J. and Shin, H. S. (2003). Endogenous risk. In Modern Risk Management – a History.
Risk Books, London. www.riskresearch.org.
Danielsson, J., Shin, H. and Zigrand, J.-P. (2012a). Endogenous and systemic risk. In Haubrich,
J. G. and Lo, A. W., editors, Quantifying Systemic Risk. University of Chicago Press for NBER;
www.riskresearch.org.
Danielsson, J., Shin, H. and Zigrand, J.-P. (2012b). Endogenous extreme events and the dual
role of prices. Ann. Rev. Econ., 4(1): 111–29; www.riskresearch.org.
Danielsson, J., Shin, H. and Zigrand, J.-P. (2012c). Procyclical leverage and endogenous risk.
Mimeo, LSE, www.riskresearch.org.
International Monetary Fund (1998). World economic outlook and international capital mar-
kets: Interim assessment. Financial turbulence and the world economy. Technical report.
www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/ weo/weo1298/ index.htm.
Keynes, J. M. (1936). The General Theory of Interest, Employment and Money. Macmillan.
Lowenstein, R. (2000). When Genius Failed – the Rise and Fall of Long-Term Capital Management.
Random House, New York.
Minsky, H. (1992). The financial instability hypothesis. Working paper. Mimeo, Yale University.
Shin, H. S. (2010). Risk and Liquidity. Clarendon Lectures in Finance. Oxford University Press.
60
4 Liquidity
Liquidity is essential for the functioning of the economy. It increases the efficiency
of markets, makes individual assets more attractive to investors, enables financial
institutions to withstand maturity mismatches and gives central banks the ability to
conduct monetary policy. Unfortunately, liquidity is transient and has a tendency to
evaporate suddenly.
It is quite easy to miss the importance of liquidity. When it is ample, which is usu-
ally the case, markets function well. Herein lies a hidden danger. When market par-
ticipants and governments take liquidity for granted, they assume more risk than is
prudent. This means that over time hidden liquidity risk builds up. Eventually, the risk
becomes so high that a crisis is inevitable. When it finally happens, liquidity becomes
of paramount importance. Unfortunately, when liquidity hits the newspaper head-
lines it is too late: a crisis is already under way.
It is easier to talk informally about the importance of liquidity than to formally
conceptualise it, making it hard to measure and manage. Many a disagreement has
arisen because different problems are analysed under the mistaken assumption that
they are the same. This is no wonder, since the notion of liquidity is elusive and poorly
understood both in the economic literature and by practitioners.
ongoing crisis: 2007–2009 phase) and Chapter 19 (sovereign debt crises). Liquidity
also impacts on the ongoing developments in financial regulation as described in
Chapter 18.
Key concepts
■ Market liquidity and funding liquidity
■ Limit order markets
■ Feedback loops
■ Cash-in-hand pricing
Chain of events
From the mid-to late 1990s, the bond and equity markets of the United States (US) expe-
rienced a long bull run, growth was steady and inflation low. This was sometimes referred
to as ‘a new era of high productivity’, a phrase that was echoed a decade later in the ‘great
moderation’. Spreads were falling, and the issuance of debt securities saw strong growth,
reflecting a move away from more traditional bank lending.
The Asian crisis which started in July 1997 had initially little effect on OECD countries
until it become apparent in July 1998 that recovery would take longer than expected.
Banks with exposure to the Asian markets saw their share prices drop and corporate bond
spreads widened in the first half of August 1998 on concerns about US growth, a sign of
the impending flight to quality and liquidity.
The trigger for a major crisis was when Russia declared a moratorium on its sovereign
debt and devalued the rouble on 17 August. This accelerated the repricing of emerg-
ing market risk and led to large-scale deleveraging. A flight to quality caused yields on
62
4.1 The liquidity crisis of 1998
US government bonds to fall and spreads on less safe bonds to increase, reaching an
eight-year peak. Figure 4.1 reveals how sudden these events were; issuance of new
debt fell from $228 billion to negative $156 billion, signalling very severe and rapid
deleveraging.
It was then that LTCM ran into trouble. The uncertainty created by its pending col-
lapse, and the resulting impact on the markets, triggered a global collapse in liquidity
which was the motivation for its bailout, organised by the New York Federal Reserve Bank
(NYFed).
The stable pre-crisis environment resulted in low margin requirements and the increase
of leverage. It was not surprising, therefore, that highly leveraged investors suffered heavy
losses during the crisis. They had to meet margin calls, further aggravating the crisis, in an
example of an endogenous risk feedback loop.
A clear example of the liquidity problems can be seen Figure 4.2 which shows the rapid
increase in spreads as the crisis unfolded. This parallels the impact on volatility (VIX) we
saw in Figure 3.11. The crisis spread to even supposedly safe assets, like US Treasuries, as
investors cared only about investments that could be monetised quickly. This rejection of
even the safest of assets is a typical characteristic of liquidity crises.
200 bn
100 bn
0 bn
−100 bn
150
Spread (bp)
100
50
0
Q3/97 Q4/97 Q1/98 Q2/98 Q3/98 Q4/98
On−off the run Treasuries CDs
Commercial paper Corporate bonds
Figure 4.2 Spreads of various debt instruments (bp = basic point, one-hundredth of a
percentage)
Data source: Bank for International Settlements (BIS)
63
Chapter 4 Liquidity
As the International Monetary Fund (IMF) (1998) noted, ‘... markets became one-sided
until prices declined enough to bring buyers back ...’. The Wall Street Journal reported that
market makers ‘cut back on the size of the trades, quoted wider bid–offer spreads or did
not quote at all’ (as noted by Davis, 1999), further contributing to the general illiquidity.
The crisis finally ended when LTCM collapsed and the Fed, along with other major cen-
tral banks, lowered interest rates, increasing liquidity. The pace of recovery did surprise
many commentators at the time. However, for a pure liquidity crisis, where no productive
resources are destroyed, that is to be expected.
Analysis
The 1998 liquidity crisis highlights the common features of all liquidity crises, and many
a banking crisis. Securities markets usually help investors and borrowers to engage in
maturity transformations and help in ensuring against idiosyncratic liquidity shocks. One
criterion in investors’ decisions is based on the convertibility of assets into cash, that is
liquidity. The more liquid an asset, the less it yields, other things being equal. If investors
fear a liquidity crisis, their rational response is to sell before anybody else. If everybody
thinks the same, the result is a rush to sell, ending in a crisis.
Before a crisis, financial institutions often seem to assume that liquidity is infinite, that
they can always execute their trading strategies and borrow what is needed. Unfortunately,
these assumptions hold only when things are good, at the time when increasing prices
create an illusion of credit-worthiness, resulting in seemingly infinite liquidity. However,
during crises, such virtuous feedback loops suddenly turn vicious, causing distress.
64
4.2 What is liquidity?
banking crisis of the early 1990s. Regulators worked to prevent those from happening
again, for example, by further developing prudential regulations and in the US prompt cor-
rective action.
The 1998 crisis happened elsewhere. It was a conjunction of several events, most
importantly the Asian crisis, the Russian crisis and LTCM. Therefore, it is not surprising
that decision makers were caught off guard. Once the problem was identified, the NYFed
acted decisively and correctly to address the problem.
This left us with the view that the next crisis would involve hedge funds. Many safe-
guards to prevent hedge fund crises were put into place, and the role of the prime broker
(the hedge fund bankers) was beefed up. However, the crisis that started in 2007 hap-
pened elsewhere, in the most regulated part of the financial system, banking, which had
been thought to be kept safe thanks to the Basel Accords.
Funding liquidity refers to the ready availability of cash to finance day-to-day opera-
tions, and market liquidity to the ease of buying and selling securities at a fair price.
These two notions of liquidity are of course highly interdependent. When things are
going well, cash is ample and trading is easy, whilst during market turmoil and especially
crises, financial institutions simultaneously will find access to cash curtailed and trading
difficult. Therefore, market liquidity and funding liquidity impact on each other, either
virtuously or viciously.
Regardless, policy initiatives directed at liquidity often focus exclusively on fund-
ing liquidity, ignoring market liquidity. One reason is that risks associated with funding
65
Chapter 4 Liquidity
illiquidity have been acknowledged for several hundred years, but market liquidity is a
newer topic and perhaps harder to understand.
66
4.2 What is liquidity?
67
Chapter 4 Liquidity
Definition 4.2 Limit order A limit order is an order that specifies an offer to buy or to
sell the security, the volume to be bought or sold and a price at which to execute a transaction.
Definition 4.3 Market order A market order specifies buying or selling immediately
at the best price.
Market orders usually execute immediately upon entry, provided there are existing limit
orders in the system. By contrast, limit orders are executed only if they are hit by a market order.
There is not a single price for a security in limit orders markets, but two: one price at
which you can buy a security, called the ask or offer, and another, lower price at which
you can sell the security, called the bid.
Almost all exchanges now use limit order books. This includes assets such as foreign
exchange, equities and many of the more common forms of derivatives. A more traditional
form of exchanges uses a market maker, but this is becoming less common over time.
It is perhaps best to explain the mechanics of limit order books by means of an example.
We see from the example that a sufficiently large market order will exhaust the supply
of limit orders at that particular price, causing the price to move, an example of a price
impact. As is apparent from Figure 4.3, the price impact for an order of a given volume
Price
depth of
best asks
$4.07
$4.05
bid–ask spread
$4.04
$4.02 depth of
best bids
$4.00
Figure 4.3 Market depth in a limit-order book. The figure depicts the depth of the top
of the book for shares of Citigroup on the BATS Exchange, 08:10 EDT, 21 July 2010
68
4.2 What is liquidity?
is lower in markets with higher volumes of limit orders outstanding, and with larger vol-
umes at and near the current best bids and asks – that is, price impact is smaller in
deeper markets.
■ Tightness is the cost of turning around a trading position in a short period of time.
Tighter markets mean lower trading costs.
■ Depth refers to the size and continuity of the market, in terms of participants and vol-
ume of trading. Large orders can be absorbed by deep markets without affecting the
price much.
■ Resiliency refers to the speed with which the market price recovers after being driven
away from its intrinsic value by uninformative shocks.
■ Immediacy refers to the time it takes to find a counterparty, initiate, clear and settle a
trade.
69
Chapter 4 Liquidity
Taken together, these notions provide the formal way to understand the various fac-
ets of market liquidity in financial markets. For example, if applied to the quant crisis of
2007, both depth and tightness sharply fell, because of the large amount of orders on the
same side of the market, usually sell, which were unusually large compared to the depth.
Similarly, the investor strike that commenced in the fall of 2007 signified the near disap-
pearance of depth in asset backed securities (ABS) markets.
70
4.3 Liquidity models
In other words, the exogenous shock triggers a margin call – a funding liquidity prob-
lem. In order to meet the margin call the traders have to sell the stock into a falling
market – a market liquidity problem. This in turn leads to more margin calls, triggering
more selling, etc. A vicious feedback loop is formed between deleveraging and funding
problems. These feedback loops are further amplified by client redemptions, as investors
have a tendency to redeem from poorly performing funds. Such loops explain much of
the quant event of 2007. Figure 4.4 illustrates these mechanisms.
A fundamental result, shown mathematically by Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2009), is
that the cumulative effect of a margin spiral coupled with a loss spiral is greater than the
sum of their separate effects. This can be seen mathematically by using simple convexity
arguments, and intuitively from the flow diagram in Figure 4.4.
Initial losses
Reduced positions
Higher margins
Client
Losses on redemptions
existing positions
71
Chapter 4 Liquidity
Allen and Gale refer to the relationship between liquidity and asset prices as cash-in-
the-market pricing, whereby the price of a risky asset in equilibrium is equal to the lesser
of the present discounted value of future dividends and the amount of cash available
from buyers divided by the number of shares sold – the cash-in-the-market price. The lat-
ter case arises when there is a shortage of liquidity, resulting in assets being underpriced
and returns therefore excessive.
If funding liquidity is scarce, the price of cash gets bid up and the price of the risky
asset bid down. This could happen, for example, if banks hoard cash because of some
precautionary principle. It may even happen with longer-dated government bonds of an
AAA-rated government. We have seen this phenomenon in crises past, and it played a key
role in the events in the fall of 2008, and with some banks in the European sovereign debt
crisis.
One could say that the opportunity cost of holding cash goes down during such crisis
episodes. Not only are there fewer investment opportunities, but financial institutions are
under risk constraints and thus prevented from increasing their holdings of risky assets,
or even longer maturities of safe assets. This creates an endogenous risk feedback loop
between falling prices for illiquid assets, preference for cash and difficulties in holding
illiquid assets, demonstrated in Figure 4.5.
Taken to the extreme, if everybody wants liquidity (cash), the price of risky assets falls
to zero, which in turn creates incentives for some agents to buy those assets, which then
puts upward pressures on prices. If the prices increase too much, everybody prefers the
risky asset, but then no liquidity is provided, so its price gets bid up. Of course, rational
economic agents realise this and, as a consequence, there must be an equilibrium price
where the profit in the states of the world with high liquidity demand is sufficient to com-
pensate for all the other states where no profits are made, so that the agents simply bear
the opportunity cost of holding liquidity.
Initial
Prices falling away
shock
from fundamentals
Risky
assets
become
illiquid
Preference for cash
Risky assets sold
Difficulties in holding
illiquid risky assets
72
4.4 Policy implications
In other words, asset prices are low in states where banks need more liquidity. But this
is exactly the wrong time from an efficiency point of view for there to be a transfer from
the banks needing liquidity to the providers of liquidity.
Liquidity premium
This suggests that assets should bear a liquidity premium, where liquidity, or the lack
thereof, is priced in by the markets. Investors require compensation for taking on liquidity
risk when they purchase securities that may later be difficult or expensive to sell. Thus,
illiquid securities must offer higher returns than liquid assets.
Several empirical studies have shown that liquidity effects are indeed priced. For exam-
ple, Acharya and Pedersen (2005) tested their liquidity adjusted CAPM model on portfo-
lios of stocks varying by firm size and found that illiquid stocks – defined as stocks with
high average transactions costs – are shown to have high liquidity risk. These results help
to explain the higher than expected returns on small-cap stocks and other illiquid invest-
ments such as private equity.
73
Chapter 4 Liquidity
Regulations
In the ongoing reform of financial regulations, especially Basel III, liquidity is for the first
time an integral part of international regulation, in the form of the net stable funding ratio
(NSFR) and the liquidity coverage ratio (LCR). These aim at bringing the funding needs of
banks more in line with their outflows, both with maturity matching liabilities and assets
and ensuring that banks have sufficient liquidity to withstand a short-term liquidity dry-up.
Macro-prudential policies
Liquidity is at the heart of what makes systemic crises different from more routine market
turmoil. This arises when all financial market participants – not only the banks – with-
draw all possible liquidity from the market. In today’s highly integrated economy, that is
extremely grave.
The challenges in mapping out the financial network mean that even though it is
clearly necessary to consider network effects when formulating macro-prudential policy,
it is less clear how the immense complexity of the interconnections can be handled in
practice. The challenge for the supervisor is that in order to adequately address concerns
about liquidity, not only do they have to collect more and better information about the
amount of risk taken by financial institutions individually, but more importantly they
need to consider the impact of aggregate positions across the financial system. They fur-
ther have to take into account factors that may lead to heavy selling as a response to a
small exogenous shock.
74
4.5 Summary
Many initiatives have been launched for the purpose of mapping out the network infra-
structure of the financial system, with all major supervisory agencies, various partnerships
between public and private entities, private institutions and academic researchers all work-
ing on this problem. This is not an easy task. Interbank exposures, followed by lender/bor-
rower relationships, are probably clearest and easiest to map out, though true exposures
are obscured by collateral and contingent liabilities. Supervisors are able to get access to
every financial transaction made, including quantity and prices and names of counterpar-
ties, and some preliminary steps have been made in making use of this information in
network analysis. It is, however, not sufficient to look at direct exposures, because market
participants have to make decisions about the creditworthiness of other financial institu-
tions, even those to which they have no direct link. These decisions may influence how
reputation is perceived by third parties. This is the problem that was analysed in Figure 1.8.
4.5 Summary
Liquidity is essential for the functioning of financial markets. Because the financial system
works best when liquidity is ample, it is easy to take it for granted, only to miss it during
crises. One reason is that liquidity is a complicated and multifaceted concept, with no
single understanding of what it is.
The most common high-level notions of liquidity were provided by the BCBS, identi-
fying two interrelated facets: funding liquidity and market liquidity. The former relates
to the availability of cash to the markets and the second to the ability to trade. These
are highly interrelated and their disappearance during crisis is often caused by feedback
effects from one to the other. That gives rise to policy actions cutting the feedback loops.
Liquidity directly affects the pricing of financial assets, which can be demonstrated by
cash-in-the-market impacts.
Liquidity has a direct impact on government policy, for example, LOLR provision by
central banks, but carries with it problems of moral hazard. Liquidity has become a prior-
ity since 2007, and many initiatives have been launched trying to understand it and incor-
porate it into macro-prudential policies.
3 Compare and contrast the two notions of liquidity proposed by the Basel committee.
4 What is a limit order book, and how can we think about liquidity from the point of view
of limit order books?
5 Describe a mechanism whereby margins and fire selling viciously interact with each
other, creating a crisis.
6 How can the supply and demand for an asset move its price away from the fundamental
price?
75
Chapter 4 Liquidity
References
Acharya, V. and Pedersen, L. H. (2005). Asset pricing with liquidity risk. J. Finan. Econ., 77:
375–410.
Allen, F. and Gale, D. (1994). Limited market participation and volatility of asset prices. Amer.
Econ. Rev., 84: 933–55.
Allen, F. and Gale, D. (2005). From cash-in-the-market pricing to financial fragility. J. Eur. Econ.
Assoc., 3: 535–46.
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2006). The management of liquidity risk in financial
groups. Technical report, pp. 1–25.
Black, F. (1971). Toward a fully automated exchange, part I. Financial Analysts J., 27: 28–35.
Brunnermeier, M. and Pedersen, L. H. (2009). Market liquidity and funding liquidity. Rev. Finan.
Stud., 22(6): 2201–38.
Danielsson, J., Shin, H. and Zigrand, J.-P. (2012b). Endogenous extreme events and the dual
role of prices. Ann. Rev. Econ., 4(1): 111–29; download from www.riskresearch.org.
Davis, E. P. (1999). A reappraisal of market liquidity risk in the light of the Russian/LTCM global
securities markets crisis. Bank of England.
International Monetary Fund (1998). World economic outlook and international capital mar-
kets: interim assessment. Financial turbulence and the world economy. Technical report.
www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/weo1298/index.htm.
Kyle, A. (1985). Continuous auctions and insider trading. Econometrica, 53(6): 1315–36.
76
5 The central bank
The most important single institution in the financial system is the central bank, also
known as a reserve bank. Central banks have a monopoly on the creation of money
and hence play a key role in ensuring price stability, as well as ensuring stable mac-
roeconomic conditions and the soundness of the financial system. Even though these
objectives are often in conflict with each other, they also lead to the same ultimate
objective, succinctly expressed by William McChesney Martin Jr, former head of the
United States (US) Federal Reserve System (Fed) who said that the Fed’s most impor-
tant job is ‘to take away the punch bowl just as the party gets going’.
Central banks were initially created with a narrow purpose in mind, to help com-
merce or, as in the case of the United Kingdom (UK), to provide stable war funding.
Over time, the roles of the central banks have expanded significantly, they acquired
a monopoly on the printing of banknotes, and they have significant autonomy in the
setting of interest rates. Most central banks started out as private institutions, but all
are now directly controlled by the central government, and most are owned by it.
With the expansion of objectives and power of the central banks, they often find
it difficult to reconcile the various tools and objectives. For example, the exercise of
financial stability may require significant injections of liquidity into the economy,
undermining price stability. Over time, as the nature of the challenges facing the
economy has changed, their priorities have shifted. From the second part of the nine-
teenth century, until 1914, financial stability was the main objective of most central
banks as monetary stability was taken care of by the gold standard. During the Bretton
Woods era, and until the 1980s, these roles switched and inflation became the main
Chapter 5 The central bank
problem facing central banks, with financial stability less important because heavy
regulations limited the scope for financial crises.
Eventually, this led to the neglect of financial stability, contributing to the build-up
of systemic risk, and the crisis starting in 2007. This, in turn, has made financial stabil-
ity the main objective of central banks. However, massive injections of liquidity into
the financial system in recent years are likely to make monetary policy yet again the
main objective of central banks.
Key concepts
■ Quantitative easing
■ Open market operations
■ Central bank interest rate
■ Objectives of central banks
■ Independence of central banks
78
5.1 The origins of central banks
79
Chapter 5 The central bank
80
5.2 Banking supervision
As universal banking becomes more common, the same bank may be engaged in very
different activities and, therefore, fall under the supervision of several different regulatory
agencies. Having a multiplicity of separate supervisors, all crawling over parts of the self
same institution, is neither efficient nor cost effective.
In 1998, the incoming government in the UK transferred responsibility for the prudential
supervision of commercial banks from the BoE to the newly created Financial Services
Authority (FSA). This meant that the UK had a ‘tripartite’ regulatory system, which included
the BoE, the FSA and the Treasury. However, when the crises started in 2007, the tripartite
arrangement was found lacking. It failed to identify the build-up of problems in the finan-
cial system prior to the crisis and did not deal adequately with the early stages of the crisis.
A major reason for these failures was that the tripartite arrangement lacked a leader-
ship structure. It gave the Treasury responsibility for maintaining the overall legal and
institutional framework, with the Bank responsible for financial stability but without the
tools and information needed to carry this out adequately; the tools lay instead with the
FSA, which did not bear the responsibility. This meant that nobody was really in charge.
The government partially rectified this in 2009, giving the Bank the statutory objective of
contributing to the maintenance of financial stability. The Bank took over the FSA’s macro-
prudential role in early 2013.
The situation is more muddled in the euro zone where the European Central Bank
(ECB) has responsibility for monetary policy but supervision is primarily under national
control. Even though it is generally considered desirable for a central authority to be
responsible for supervision within the European Union (EU), or at least the Euro zone,
this is difficult given the current political structure of the Union.
The reason is that when a supervisory authority takes action, it often has substantial
national implications, potentially reducing revenues (and tax income) or committing
large amounts of taxpayers’ money. The government agency in charge of the taxpayers’
funds is the treasury or the ministry of finance. Under the current EU structure, each
country is directly responsible for its own finances, and therefore supervision has to be
the purview of the nation state.
This means that the ECB is in the rather curious situation of being in charge of mon-
etary policy, as well as financial stability, but without any supervisory powers. The EU has
attempted to partially solve this problem by hosting the new European Systemic Risk Board
(ESRB) within the ECB, in principle, providing the necessary information for the ECB to
efficiently exercise its financial stability function. However, with supervision in the hands of
the nation states, its powers are necessarily more limited than those of other central banks.
The EU is currently aiming to set up a common supervisor in Europe, and eventually
a banking union, starting with the single supervisory (SSM).
81
Chapter 5 The central bank
Taylor rule
Having a monetary policy objective, perhaps a formal inflation target, does leave open
the question of how the central bank should meet the objective. One approach is the
Taylor rule, proposed by Taylor (1993), whereby the central bank sets the nominal
interest rates based on changes in inflation, output and possibly other economic vari-
ables. Under the rule, the central bank should increase nominal interest rates by more
than 1% in response to a 1% increase in inflation. By having a formal rule, a central
82
5.3 Monetary policy
where it is the target short-term nominal interest rate, pt is the inflation rate (the GDP
deflator), p*t is the desired rate of inflation, rt* is the equilibrium real interest rate, yt is
an estimate of the logarithm of real GDP, and yt is the logarithm of potential output,
obtained by a linear trend. yt - yt is the output gap. The parameters are restricted to be
positive, ap, ay 7 0, and Taylor (1993) proposed setting them at 0.5.
In general terms, the Taylor rule seeks to apply negative feedback to the economy,
increasing rates when either capacity is stretched or inflation is above target and reducing
them when the opposite applies. This clearly matches central banks’ objectives in qualita-
tive terms, but an important practical problem is the dependence of the rule on quanti-
ties that can only be approximated. In particular, GDP is only known with a considerable
lag, and is subject to frequent revisions. Even in the long run, GDP is only an approximate
measure of the economy.
Many central banks, explicitly or otherwise, use a form of the Taylor rule to set inter-
est rates. It is, however, most suited for very large currency areas, such as the US, because
it disregards the impact of interest rates on exchange rates. For much smaller countries,
higher interest rates may lead to inflows of hot money and carry trading.
83
Chapter 5 The central bank
20%
15%
10%
5%
0%
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011
John Maynard Keynes (1936) identified the pathological case of liquidity traps, illus-
trated in Figure 5.2. The supply of money intersects the demand for money (D) on the
perfectly elastic part of the demand curve (the flat part to the right), and an increase
in money supply from S1 to S2 does not therefore change the interest rate. That means
a conventional monetary policy is unable to stimulate an economy.
84
5.3 Monetary policy
Interest rate
S1 S2
D
Money balances
In order to prevent the economy from sliding into deflation and to provide an economic
stimulus, some central banks have resorted to a more direct control of the quantity of
money, called quantitative easing (QE), to be used when other measures are not successful.
Conceptually, open-market operations and QE may seem to be the same, because in both
cases the central bank is purchasing assets from banks using money (M0 or M1) it has cre-
ated ex nihilo (out of nothing). In practice, the difference between these two operations is
significant, in scale, frequency, asset composition, maturities and motivation. We might say
that while open-market operations are a scalpel, QE is more like a sledgehammer.
In QE, the central bank may buy exactly the same assets as in open-market opera-
tions, typically short-dated government bonds, but under QE a much broader range of
assets may be purchased, including longer-dated securities and even non-government
assets, such as corporate bonds. Open-market operations tend to be more frequent and
to involve much smaller amounts and shorter maturity assets than QE.
The motivation is also different for open-market operations and for QE. In the former,
the explicit objective is to fine-tune the quantity of money, while QE is also presented as
a way to stimulate the economy and a means for the central bank to directly support the
government financially. The stimulus happens for several reasons, for example, because
the increased money supply encourages demand whilst putting downward pressure on
exchange rates, helping exporters and the trade balance. The direct support of govern-
ments happens because the central banks have become significant purchasers of govern-
ment bonds in some countries, helping to keep yields and government debt down. Even
though central bank holdings of government debt count as much as any other holding of
government debt, because the central bank is owned by the government, on a net basis
government debt falls when the central bank buys it.
‘Let us suppose now that one day a helicopter flies over this community and drops
an additional $1000 in bills from the sky, . . . Let us suppose further that everyone is
convinced that this is a unique event which will never be repeated . . .’
Milton Friedman (1969)
The BoE’s QE operations amount to £325 billion at the time of writing, or £5,242 for
each of the 62 million people that live in the UK. Instead of buying government bonds,
the Bank’s QE operations would probably have been much more effective if it had sim-
ply sent an envelope with £5,242 in notes to each person in the UK.
86
5.5 Bailing out Governments
Act keeping the commercial banking separate from investment banking, and rules aiming
at minimising liquidity risk in mortgages.
Active prevention relates to policies designed to smooth outcomes in financial mar-
kets in real time, making sure that regular activity does not get out of hand. Active preven-
tion is intended to be reactive to the situation at hand rather than being an essentially
static framework like passive prevention. Examples include rules specifying minimum
bank capital and reserves, amount of liquidity or maximum leverage. These are generally
based on a dynamic assessment of bank activities, and nowadays may involve sophisti-
cated financial models.
Finally, resolution refers to dealing with a crisis already underway – ex post. Such poli-
cies were first formalised after the O&G failure in 1866 which led to the establishment of
LOLR, aiming to provide liquidity to solvent but illiquid banks. Resolution also relates to
having a special resolution regime for failed banks, such as prompt corrective action in the
US. Policies like living wills and bail-ins also fall under this category.
Resolution and passive prevention share in the advantage that the key decisions are
made during previous crises, with policies less exposed to shifting priorities than in active
prevention.
The introduction of new financial stability tools often follows when the authorities do
a postmortem analysis on a crisis. Besides the examples mentioned above, a prominent
case is establishment of the Bretton Woods system, especially the World Bank and the
International Monetary Fund (IMF).
87
Chapter 5 The central bank
16% UK
12% USA
8%
4%
0%
2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011
Figure 5.3 Central bank holdings of government bonds relative to GDP, end of year
Data source: Federal Reserve Board, UK Debt Management Office and the World Bank
88
5.5 Bailing out Governments
That means the ECB has limited legitimacy in its efforts to to fulfil one of the funda-
mental objectives of a central bank – bailing out its government in times of crisis. This is
the reason why the ECB’s purchases of European government bonds have been so limited
compared to the purchases of the BoE and Fed. Instead, the ECB tries to do its job indi-
rectly, by supplying liquidity to financial institutions, in the hope that it will relieve the
pressure on the sovereign. This is not as efficient as using the central bank to bail out the
sovereign directly. The ECB signalled change in policy in September 2012, announcing its
intention to buy the bonds of distressed European sovereigns. This has run into significant
opposition, not least from Germany, and at the time of writing it is unclear what the out-
come will be.
89
Chapter 5 The central bank
90
5.6 Challenges for central banking
One of the clearest manifestations of how the emphasis is shifted from monetary
policy to financial stability and macroeconomic objectives is UK inflation, which has
frequently exceeded its annual target rate since the crises from 2007. The risk is the crea-
tion of inflationary expectations, which would be costly to eventually fight. It is far from
obvious that interest rates could currently be raised without a recurrence of the crisis.
With this key lever unavailable it is not clear that a contractionary monetary policy could
be effective.
91
Chapter 5 The central bank
the short run, printing money has been a success and has prevented the financial system
from collapsing, the economy from sliding into a full-blown depression, and governments
from defaulting.
In the longer term, there is a price to pay. Until the crises from 2007, such policies
were generate generally dismissed out of hand, because of their inevitable inflationary
effects and the cost imposed on the economy because of increased uncertainty. The only
legitimate use of monetary policy was to maintain low and stable inflation, a point made
explicit in many central bank charters.
Many of the governments now enthusiastically embracing money creation have in the
past condemned others for responding to domestic crises in exactly the same way. For the
next decade or two this will make it very hard for them to credibly forswear the further
use of monetary policy for such purposes: financial entities will simply assume that if the
need is sufficient, governments will do what it takes.
This has serious implications. At present, contractionary influences remain strong and
there is little evidence that inflationary expectations are building up, but the threat and
the associated costs are clear. It took many years to defeat the 1970s inflation, with cen-
tral bank independence and credibility playing a vital role in that fight. These have now
been impaired, suggesting that the coming battle against inflation will be similarly long
and painful.
Hyperinflation
Governments sometimes completely lose control of money. The reason might be that
as inflation increases, government revenue decreases, so the government needs to
print money to finance itself. That, however, leads to more inflation, and a vicious
cycle is formed. This process was modelled by Cagan (1956) who showed that it is
necessary to increase the money supply at a double exponential rate for the govern-
ment’s revenue to keep up. The empirical evidence is consistent with his model, as
seen in Figure 5.4 which shows the growth of money supply during the hyperinflation
in Germany and Zimbabwe.
Even though the y-axis in the figure is on a logarithmic scale, the growth is exponential,
so inflation is growing at a double exponential rate. Besides Zimbabwe and Germany,
many countries have experienced hyperinflation, as seen in Table 5.1.
Germany
106 104
101
102
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007
92
5.7 Summary
Notes. The Reserve Bank of Zimbabwe reported inflation rates for March 2007–July 2008. The authors (Hanke and Kwok, 2009, Table 2)
calculated rates for August 2008–14 November 2008
Source: On the measurement of Zimbabwe’s hyperinflation, Cato Journal, Vol. 29, No. 2, 356 (Hanke, S. H. and Kwok, A. K. F. Spring/
Summer 2009). Copyright © Cato Institute. All rights reserved.
The general reason why a country ends up with hyperinflation is that the government
surrenders control of money creation because it is under some imperative to raise revenue at
all costs. In the end, hyperinflation is extremely costly. As Vladimir Lenin said: ‘The best way
to destroy the capitalist system is to debauch the currency’, as quoted by Keynes (1920).
5.7 Summary
The central bank is the most important institution in the financial system because
it has a monopoly on creating money. It generally has five objectives: price stability,
macroeconomic performance, financial stability, banking supervision and bailing out
its government. There are differences between countries. The first two objectives are
likely to be legal objectives, but financial stability has risen in prominence during the
ongoing crisis. The supervisory function remains controversial with good arguments
for and against the central bank taking on the responsibility. The bailout function is
more like a dirty secret, not something the central banks or governments want anyone
to notice.
Central banks control the supply of money either directly or indirectly to achieve price
stability. Central banks have resorted to unconventional methods, such as QE, since
2007 to stimulate the economy and finance the government. Their long-term impacts are
unclear but include some risk of inflation.
The priorities of the central bank objectives have changed over time, from financial
stability to price stability and back to financial stability. These objectives are quite
different and often in conflict with each other. For example, financial stability may
require money creation, undermining price stability, whilst prudential banking super-
vision could lead to the creation of hidden risks. Another contentious issue is central
bank independence, considered desirable for monetary policy but not entirely com-
patible with financial stability. In a worst case scenario, the central banks may lose
control of money, resulting in hyperinflation.
93
Chapter 5 The central bank
94
References
borrow overnight from their national central banks after providing acceptable collateral.
This rate provides a ceiling for the overnight market interest rate, and is similar in nature
to the discount rate used by the Fed. There is also a deposit facility where banks can make
overnight deposits with their national central banks. The interest rate on this facility simi-
larly provides a floor for the overnight market interest rate.
The benchmark interest rate for the BoE is known as the BoE base rate, which is the
rate that the BoE charges banks for secured overnight borrowing. It is usually transacted
as an overnight repo against high-quality collateral. This is more comparable to the Fed’s
discount rate rather than to the federal funds rate.
2 What is more important as a central bank function: financial stability or monetary policy?
3 How have the common views of the relative importance of financial stability versus
monetary policy changed over time?
4 What is the danger of deflation, and what policy remedies for it do you recommend?
6 What is quantitative easing, and how does it compare to more conventional monetary
policy operations?
7 Why is quantitative easing discussed more widely today than in the past?
11 How can a central bank bail out its government? Why is it harder for the ECB to fulfil
this function than central banks in other countries?
References
Cagan, P. (1956). The monetary dynamics of hyperinflation. In Friedman, M., editor, Studies in
the Quantity Theory of Money. University of Chicago Press.
Friedman, M. (1969). The optimum quantity of money. In Friedman, M., editor, The Optimum
Quantity of Money and Other Essays, chapter 1, pp. 1–50. Adline Publishing Company,
Chicago.
Goodhart, C. (2002). The organizational structure of banking supervision. Economic Notes,
31(1): 1–32.
Goodhart, C. and Schoenmaker, D. (1995). Should the functions of monetary policy and bank-
ing supervision be separated? Oxford Economic Papers, 47: 539–60.
95
Chapter 5 The central bank
96
6 The Asian crisis of 1997
and the IMF
In 1997, several countries in East Asia experienced one of the most severe currency
and financial crises since the Great Depression. Exchange rates, asset prices and eco-
nomic activity collapsed with financial and corporate insolvency widespread.
The crisis caught everybody by surprise. The East Asian countries seemed to have
done everything right, avoiding mistakes causing crises elsewhere, for example, in
Latin America and Europe. The macroeconomics appeared sound, and the countries
had balanced budgets and tight monetary policy.
Instead, the underlying weaknesses were in the private sector, with excessive for-
eign currency borrowing that led to bad investment decisions. This was fuelled by the
apparent belief that the governments would ensure stable exchange rates, and even
bail out borrowers. The macroeconomic fundamentals were sound, the financial fun-
damentals not.
There is not complete unanimity on which countries were affected. Four are always
included: Indonesia, South Korea, Malaysia and Thailand, as all experienced spec-
tacular growth in the 1990s, followed by the 1997 crash and respectable recovery.
All but Malaysia were forced to call in the International Monetary Fund (IMF), so
we mostly omit Malaysia from the analysis. Other Asian countries affected include
Hong Kong, Singapore and Taiwan, but these avoided the worst, so we also exclude
them here.
Detailed analysis of the Asian crisis, with the benefit of hindsight, indicates that
foreign currency speculation and a sudden stop in foreign lending were a significant
immediate cause of the crisis, fuelled by weak fundamentals. Given the weaknesses in
Chapter 6 The Asian crisis of 1997 and the IMF
the financial fundamentals, a crisis in all of the countries was probably inevitable; if it
had not happened in 1997, it would have occurred within a few years.
The main policy conclusion drawn by the crisis countries themselves was that they
could only rely on themselves for liquidity support and, in response, have built up
vast currency reserves.
These reserves did not protect them from significant exchange rate fluctuations
once the global crisis was underway in 2007, and South Korea had to enter into cur-
rency swap contracts with the Federal Reserve System (Fed), helping to stabilise its
exchange rate. This clearly demonstrates the limited protection afforded by vast
reserves, and it is quite possible that the reserves only serve to prevent small crises,
making the eventual one large. In particular, large reserves do not imply that a coun-
try should avoid addressing underlying structural weaknesses.
The IMF, or the Fund as it is sometimes referred to, played an important and con-
troversial role in the crisis. It is a part of the United Nations and was originally set up
as a part of the Bretton Woods system, to manage the fixed exchange rate regime at
the time. Over time, the role of the Fund has shifted; for the past few decades it has
been the main international mechanism for responding to financial and economic
crises, as well as the enforcer of foreign claims on governments. It can provide sig-
nificant amounts of money as emergency assistance – a package – but does in return
demand what is known in the Fund’s jargon as structural adjustments. This includes
macroeconomic policies like fiscal and monetary tightening and improving the capi-
tal accounts, but also some microeconomic adjustments, for example, labour market
reform, cuts in subsidies and more recently anti-corruption measures. These policies
are a part of the Washington consensus.
At its core, the Asian crisis was not very different from many other crises throughout
history, a clear example of the observation that all crises are fundamentally the same,
only the details differ. It has clear parallels with the ongoing global crisis; many of the
underlying fundamental weaknesses are the same, and some policymakers involved
in the European sovereign debt crisis have drawn direct lessons from the Asian crisis.
Perhaps the most interesting parallel between the Asian crisis and the crisis from 2007
is how different policies are when they have to be implemented domestically or abroad.
Key concepts
■ East Asia crisis of 1997
■ IMF
■ Maturity and currency mismatches
■ Challenges in fighting crises
■ Washington consensus
■ Structural adjustment
98
6.1 Building up to a crisis
99
Chapter 6 The Asian crisis of 1997 and the IMF
The East Asian countries opened up their capital accounts and liberalised the financial
sector, all while maintaining sound macroeconomics. Sovereign debt was low and falling:
see Figure 6.1. GDP growth was quite spectacular, ranging from 7.9% to 9.5% across the
region, as can be seen in Table 6.1. Other standard indicators, like inflation and unem-
ployment, all pointed to macroeconomic stability.
80%
1990
60% 1996
40%
20%
0%
Indonesia South Korea Malaysia Thailand
Annual
average Indonesia South Korea Malaysia Thailand
30%
20%
10%
0%
Indonesia South Korea Malaysia Thailand
100
6.1 Building up to a crisis
If investment is based on domestic savings, and especially if loans are maturity matched
to the ultimate investments, high investment rates are not a big concern for financial sta-
bility, even if one might question whether the funds can be sensibly invested. If, however,
the origin of the funds is short-term foreign currency borrowing from international capital
markets, the picture is different.
Initially, this was not the case for the East Asian countries; financing from international
markets was less than 1% of GDP in 1990. International borrowing was growing rapidly,
however, reaching 4% to 6% in 1996, as seen in Figure 6.3. Because these funds were
predominantly short-term, this rapidly growing exposure to international capital markets
signalled the building up of vulnerabilities to liquidity crises.
The high economic growth was partially reflected in the stock market (Figure 6.4). The
best year was 1993, caused by foreign inflows, both from direct purchases of equities
by foreigners and also from the indirect effect of domestic companies borrowing from
abroad. From 1994, the stock markets were doing poorly.
Perhaps the stock market anticipated the pending crisis better than foreign creditors, the
government or the IMF. After all, many investors in the stock market are well-connected
and well-informed local investors who would know of the build-up of vulnerabilities bet-
ter than most. Alternatively, those relatively poor returns may represent divestment by
foreigners, belatedly realising that with poor minority protection they had very limited
real ownership. The lenders felt themselves safe from the corporate governance prob-
lems, protected by convertibility, short duration, government guarantees and good mac-
roeconomic policies, and so continued to lend.
6%
1990 1996
4%
2%
0%
Indonesia South Korea Malaysia Thailand
Figure 6.3 Financing via international capital markets (gross inflows, % of GDP)
Data source: World Bank and IMF
101
Chapter 6 The Asian crisis of 1997 and the IMF
−20%
−40%
−60%
Figure 6.5 Drop in stock markets (local currency) and exchange rates in the second part
of 1997
Data source: Global Financial Data
6.2.1 Thailand
The first country to be hit by the crisis was Thailand. It had experienced spectacular
growth in the 1990s, fuelled by rapidly growing exports, and had maintained a relatively
fixed exchange rate of roughly 25 baht per USD since 1984.
A particular feature of the economy of Thailand was the prominence of special finance
companies, which were similar to banks and provided about 20% of all the credit in the
economy, on easy terms. The finance companies mainly financed themselves by short-
term dollar denominated loans from foreign investors.
The Thai economy started to run into difficulties towards the end of 1996, when inter-
est rates rose, and the economy slowed down due to sagging exports. One reason was
that the dollar appreciated in 1995, strengthening the baht, reducing the attractiveness of
exports and worsening the current account position.
As domestic companies ran into problems, Thai banks and finance companies reported
large increases in their non-performing loans. To keep the financial system stable, the
Central Bank of Thailand secretly lent about $20 billion to finance companies and weaker
banks at below market interest rates. These loans do not seem to have been a part of a
102
6.2 The crisis in individual countries
lending of last resort (LOLR) operation, but direct bailouts. Ultimately, this meant that the
Central Bank had lower reserves than expected, reducing confidence when that became
known.
The currency came under pressure towards the end of 1996, with the Central Bank
intervening in the currency market, building up increasingly large forward positions, fur-
ther reducing the effective amounts of reserves. Finally, a massive speculative attack took
place on 14 and 15 May 1997. Figure 6.6 shows the evolution of the currency. The Central
Bank of Thailand lost $10 billion defending the baht without success. On 15 May, the
Central Bank ordered all local and foreign banks to stop lending baht to anyone outside
the country, which eased the selling pressure for about a month.
Fresh concerns about the Thai economy surfaced on 19 June, prompting Thai
banks and corporations to sell baht in large numbers. The foreign creditors, which
used to roll over short-term debts, were suddenly demanding immediate repayment
as their loans matured. Few Thai borrowers had hedged against the possibility of a
collapse of the baht, and it would have been silly to do so, since the borrowing costs
when the frictional costs are included are higher than just borrowing in baht. On 2
July, the authorities concluded that the fixed rate system could not survive and let
the baht float.
This turned out to be the trigger for a fully fledged crisis in East Asia. The baht devalued
swiftly and lost more than half of its value, reaching its lowest point of 56 bahts to the
USD in January 1998. The Thai stock market dropped by 75% in baht terms and Finance
One, the largest Thai finance company at that time, collapsed.
Thailand got an IMF programme on 20 August 1997, with a package of $17.2 billion. The
markets were not impressed by the size of the package, nor the disclosure of $23.4 billion
in forward commitments by the Central Bank of Thailand, especially considering that
short-term private sector debts exceeded $30 billion. The baht continued falling.
The IMF recommended the closure of weaker financial institutions, but problems in
distinguishing between liquidity problems and solvency problems frustrated this process,
partly because financial institutions would rationally pay almost limitless bribes to be
placed on the list of liquid institutions. The Fund attached further conditions to its aid,
requiring fiscal and monetary tightening, the raising of taxes and reduction in expendi-
tures. This is a recipe it continued to follow in the other crisis countries.
40
IMF
worries
Baht/USD
attack
initial
35
float
30
25
103
Chapter 6 The Asian crisis of 1997 and the IMF
6.2.2 Indonesia
Indonesia under President Suharto embarked on an economic reform agenda in the early
1980s, restraining government spending, opening the economy to foreign investments
and easing regulations. The economy grew rapidly, whilst enjoying a current account sur-
plus, with foreign exchange reserves substantially increasing.
Similar to Thailand, Indonesian corporations were increasingly using short-term dollar
denominated debt to finance themselves. This worked well when the currency appreci-
ated during the 1980s and early 1990s, setting up a virtuous feedback loop between cur-
rency inflows, reduced cost of debt service and currency appreciation.
Behind it all was a strong culture of what was called ‘KKN’: corruption, collusion and
nepotism. Any foreign firm investing in an Indonesian company had to hand over partner-
ship rights to a presidential relative to ensure smooth approval. Individuals with personal
relationships to the Suharto regime made some of the largest fortunes in Indonesia.
Throughout the 1990s, difficulties were building up in the banking system whilst the
number of banks grew rapidly. The government heavily influenced lending decisions so it
could channel funds to favoured businesses, with banks made to lend to borrowers who
already had stopped servicing old loans – that is, in default. By the mid-1990s, non-per-
forming loans exceeded 25% of total loans made. The Indonesian currency came under
increasing pressure after the baht floated in July 1997, adversely affecting corporations
with unhedged dollar liabilities.
Indonesia asked for IMF assistance in October. The IMF General Manager, Michel
Camdessus, responded by saying that ‘The IMF strongly supports the approach that has been
followed by Indonesia, which sees this as an occasion to strengthen its economic policies even
if fundamentals are basically sound’ (IMF, 1997). This statement sounds naive: a country with
‘basically sound’ fundamentals should not suffer a crisis. In its analysis, the Fund seems to
have focused on macroeconomic fundamentals and neglected the financial fundamentals.
The IMF provided a package of $40 billion, attaching conditions to its programme,
most controversially that 16 banks be closed immediately, with limited protection to
depositors. The particular 16 banks seemed to have been chosen quite arbitrarily, and it
was unclear whether other banks would also be closed. Not surprisingly, the end result
was a run on the banking system and the country. While closing the 16 banks might
have been designed to demonstrate strength, within a few weeks a son of the president
reopened his bank under a different name, demonstrating a lack of commitment by the
Indonesian government, thus undermining the programme.
Similar to Thailand, the Fund required monetary and fiscal tightening, which the
Indonesian government found difficult to implement. For example, riots ensued when
subsidies were reduced. Eventually, the policies were adjusted and the Indonesian gov-
ernment agreed on another letter of intent with the Fund in January 1998.
104
6.2 The crisis in individual countries
105
Chapter 6 The Asian crisis of 1997 and the IMF
106
6.3 Reasons for the crisis
maturity and currency mismatches. Much funding was short-term foreign currency while
lending or investments were long-term in domestic currency. This creates a classical mis-
match problem for borrowers. What was special, but not unique, in the Asian crisis was
how prevalent such mismatches were.
The capital markets in East Asia were relatively underdeveloped, so that most financial
intermediation occurred through the banking system. If a country does not have sufficient
reserves to cover a sudden stop in the rollover of loans, it is vulnerable to a liquidity crisis.
Ito (2007) reports that the ratio of short-term bank borrowing to foreign reserves at the
end of June 1997 was 2.1 for South Korea, 1.6 for Indonesia and 1.4 for Thailand, signal-
ling significant fragility. In later analysis, the so-called Guidotti–Greenspan rule argues that
the ratio should not exceed 1.
A major ingredient was overconfidence. A history of currency stability encouraged for-
eign banks to lend, for the simple reason that their whole experience had always been
profitable. Central banks tolerated this for the same reason. Faith in convertibility and
the IMF made lenders comfortable, which is a necessary condition for future crises to
develop.
6%
Indonesia
0%
South Korea
−6% Malaysia
−12% Thailand
107
Chapter 6 The Asian crisis of 1997 and the IMF
Figure 6.8 Average and minimum (in crisis) exchange rates. USD/local currency,
1990 = 100
Data source: Global Financial Data
Instead, a V-shaped crisis is more indicative of a liquidity crisis, where a sudden stop
causes significant temporary difficulties. This causes the currency to collapse, making local
corporations more competitive than before, often with much lower debt, creating condi-
tions for rapid export-led growth. This is exactly what happened in the East Asian crisis.
These effects were most pronounced in South Korea, which has performed best since
the crisis. Table 6.2 shows the relative per capita GDP ranking of the four countries at key
points, expressed in percentiles. Notably, Indonesia was essentially in the same place in
1990 and 2007, consistent with other empirical results presented. Malaysia has shown a
small improvement, but Thailand has made the largest move in the ranking, but is still
below its 1996 place.
108
6.4 Policy options for the crisis countries
$12 billion in 1997. The observation that the crisis was broadly V-shaped does support
the view that it was more the sudden stop, rather than structural weaknesses, that caused
the crisis.
Of the four countries, South Korea exhibited the strongest signs of a pure liquid-
ity crisis. Events in the autumn of 1997 indicate that the possibility of the Central
Bank running out of reserves scared off investors and encouraged holders of the South
Korean currency to exchange it for dollars. This in turn become a self-fulfilling chain
of events, only ending after domestic assets became very cheap for holders of foreign
currency, and the IMF helped to provide liquidity. The fact that South Korea has the
smallest difference between pre- and post-crisis GDP further supports this observa-
tion. For the other three countries, the picture is more muddled. There was a clear
liquidity crisis but the relatively large shortfall in growth indicates that the very high
pre-crisis growth was caused as much by inflows of money as by the build-up of eco-
nomic strength.
Why did the sudden stop happen? If there had been no worries about the soundness
of the economies, there would have been no reasons for creditors to deny credit all of a
sudden. Furthermore, the fact that the economies performed well after the crisis does not
by itself justify the conclusion that everything was fine: after all, the affected economies
underwent significant structural changes as a consequence of the crisis. This means that
a sudden stop or liquidity explanations for the crisis are inadequate and only a manifesta-
tion of more fundamental problems.
109
Chapter 6 The Asian crisis of 1997 and the IMF
110
6.4 Policy options for the crisis countries
263
1990
225
2007
150
102 87
75 57
5 9 7 9
0
Indonesia South Korea Malaysia Thailand
(a) Foreign reserves in 1990 and 2007, in billions of 2007 USD
with rapid growth provides much better investment opportunities than a wealthy devel-
oped country. It would seem more natural for a wealthy country to export its capital to
a developing country rather than the other way around. Indeed, that had been the norm
until recently; during the first globalism, between 1873 and 1914, the United Kingdom
(UK) was the greatest exporter of capital, and since then the United States (US), until
recently. The lesson drawn by the Asian Tigers, however, is that while the benefits are
shared, the risks of this arrangement fall almost entirely on the borrower.
By accumulating foreign currency reserves, the crisis countries, in effect, are subsidising
the wealthiest countries, in particular, the US as the owner of the world’s reserve currency.
This keeps interest rates in the US low and its currency relatively strong. This adversely
affects the exports of the high-reserve countries.
The policy adopted after the crisis was the sacrificing of wealth for greater financial
security and policy independence. It is an open question whether that is an advisable
policy. While this does subsidise US consumers, it also encourages them to buy the very
products exported by these countries, helping domestic industry.
There are also very conflicting opinions on the sensibility of maintaining substantial
holdings of US government bonds. Some might say that by becoming a large creditor, it
gives these countries power. Others highlight the potential for the US to effectively ‘tax’
the capital exporting countries simply by debasing its currency, perhaps by quantitative
easing (QE).
Some other developing countries have emulated the foreign exchange (FX) and reserve
policy of the East Asian countries. While that does not indicate the policies are sensible, it
does signal they have widespread support.
111
Chapter 6 The Asian crisis of 1997 and the IMF
112
6.5 Role of the IMF
The fiscal and monetary tightening was questionable. None of the countries had dem-
onstrated a lack of discipline on that front prior to the crisis, and a sensible crisis response
was loosening, not tightening. The policies demanded by the Fund also were out of touch
with the underlying realities; for example, it set an inflation target for South Korea of 5.2%
for 1998, an impossible task given the sharp currency depreciation.
To achieve this, interest rates in South Korea were pushed above 20%, hitting the
industrial base, already reeling from the crisis, and further deepening the recession.
The demand for high interest rates disregarded the accumulated experience of fighting
crises over the preceding century or more, and is contrary to the policies used subse-
quently, for example in the ongoing crisis. The Fund has demanded very high inter-
est rates in some countries to which it has provided assistance in the ongoing crisis,
suggesting a deep-seated attachment to what most analysts consider an inappropriate
policy response.
Other reforms, such as cuts to subsidies and labour market reforms, might have been
laudable long-term goals but are hard to implement in the middle of a crisis. In Indonesia,
the resulting cuts in food and energy subsidies led to riots, and the end result in South
Korea was mass layoffs, leading to strikes and riots.
The problem is that the IMF can only exert influence when a country wants a
cheque. While riots are not palatable, avoiding them does not guarantee good policy.
The IMF’s policy was unpopular and disruptive, but one could argue that its structural
adjustment programmes laid the groundwork for the strong sustainable post-crisis
growth.
Heavy-handedness
The IMF was seen as acting heavy-handedly by the crisis countries, with the signature
manifestation of this being the signing ceremony of the agreement with Indonesia in
2008. In order to demonstrate commitment, both President Suharto and Managing
Director Michel Camdessus attended the ceremony. The photo taken at the occasion –
see Figure 6.10 – became the visible face of the IMF’s power. Of course, the photo says
nothing about the actual relationship between the IMF and Indonesia, but it did resonate
with popular perceptions of events.
Strong resentment against the Fund lingered, and the countries did their best to repay
their loans ahead of schedule: South Korea in 2001, Thailand in 2003 and Indonesia in
October 2006. The resentment was fuelled by politicians deflecting blame from them-
selves, by the real economic disruption in the crisis and by the dislike anybody feels when
beholden. Of course, the ability to repay early can also be seen as a testament to the easy
terms of the loans and the effectiveness of the Fund’s policy demands.
113
Chapter 6 The Asian crisis of 1997 and the IMF
Figure 6.10 IMF Managing Director, Michel Camdessus and President Suharto, in 1998
Source: Agus Lolong/Getty Images
needs to be able to act decisively, providing funds in a very short amount of time. That
is exactly the advantage the central banks have in the provision of liquidity during crises.
As an international lender of last resort (ILOLR), the IMF does not have the ability to
print money on demand, and needs a significant amount of time to get support for lend-
ing operations. Therefore, the Fund is not in a position to be a LOLR, except perhaps in
special cases. It is consequently unable to deal directly with an international liquidity
crisis. If it is not the IMF in such circumstances, it is nobody.
Furthermore, the loans from the IMF are in dollars. If the dollars are spent defend-
ing the local currency, which then devalues, the government’s local currency liability is
increased and this will worsen whatever the market is worried about — unsustainability
of finances, excess foreign borrowings, etc. Hence, the dollar loans would do little to
change market perception. To be effective, the loans would have to be fully in local
currency and the IMF would need to put its money where its mouth is, as one expects
of a LOLR.
This means that comparing the scale of the IMF loans to the scale of changes in reserves is
not correct. IMF loans enable countries to take bigger bets, but the loans do not remove the
risk, and the country is presumably under attack because the risks were already perceived as
excessive.
That said, the IMF does represent member governments and hence has consider-
able powers of persuasion beyond simply providing funds. In January 1998, it helped by
114
6.6 Wider lessons
jawboning, backed up by realistic carrots and sticks. Still, the IMF packages were in hind-
sight clearly insufficient, even though that was not clear at the time.
115
Chapter 6 The Asian crisis of 1997 and the IMF
We should continue to question the extent to which the lessons that have been learned
from the last crisis will be relevant to the next. In the Asian crisis, as is so often the case, the
most damaging decisions were not those made before the crisis, but those during the crisis.
A longer-term view, focusing beyond the immediate newspaper headlines, might have dem-
onstrated that the crisis was as much about liquidity as structural deficiencies. Provision of
liquidity, backed up by a credible reform programme, would have prevented the worst.
Thinking back, it now seems that the countries’ governments have not sufficiently
taken on board the necessary lessons, perhaps with the exception of South Korea. The
objective of the structural adjustment programmes was to help the affected countries,
and their failure to grow sufficiently, demonstrated by their failure to improve their global
ranking post-crisis, suggests that the programmes did not take hold.
This is partly because the issues were misdiagnosed at the time, but also because
many of the regimes reverted to type as soon as the pressure came off. A thorough imple-
mentation of many of the Fund’s programmes would probably have helped the countries
perform better. For example, corruption remains a serious problem in all of the coun-
tries, except perhaps South Korea, and the IMF’s anti-corruption stance is laudable.
The crisis marks the beginning of a reduction in GDP per capita growth, but correlation
does not imply causation. The very high pre-crisis growth was in part based on unsustain-
able policies, such as the dependence on short-term foreign capital. Therefore, it is just as
likely that the post-crisis slower growth is more sustainable and less prone to crises, and
therefore to be preferred.
Ultimately, this means that Asian crisis countries remain vulnerable. Their large cur-
rency reserves might provide protection, but in the absence of sensible reforms, helping
to move them up the relative wealth ladder, a future crisis remains a likely eventuality.
116
6.7 Summary
Before the European crisis countries get assistance, they have to implement extreme
austerity programmes and structural reforms, just like the East Asian countries had to do
in 1997. Also, while some liquidity assistance is provided, it is far from enough to assure
the markets. Meanwhile, no end to the European sovereign debt crisis is in sight.
6.7 Summary
Some countries in East Asia suffered a severe financial and economic crisis in 2007, in
particular South Korea, Malaysia, Indonesia and Thailand. Of these, all but Malaysia
requested assistance from the IMF.
Prior to the crisis, the fundamentals appeared sound, and the crisis came as a surprise,
but underneath were significant private sector problems, in particular, extensive short-
term foreign currency borrowing.
Initial explanations for the crisis focused on weak fundamentals and moral hazard,
with subsequent analysis highlighting the importance of liquidity.
The IMF came under strong criticism for its performance in the crisis, but it was ham-
pered by institutional difficulties beyond its control. Many of the mistakes made by the
Fund are visible only with the benefit of hindsight.
Some of the lessons from the Asian crisis have been taken on board in the current crisis, espe-
cially the early stages. Unfortunately, similar mistakes now appear to be repeated in Europe.
2 What does it mean when we say that the economic fundamentals were sound but not
the financial fundamentals?
3 Compare and contrast the causes of the crisis, the resolution of the crisis and the post-
crisis reactions across the three countries.
4 Some commentators have argued that panic and contagion played an important role in
the crisis. What is your view on this analysis?
5 Initial explanations for the crisis focused on moral hazard and related issues. These
were eventually dismissed as a main cause. Why?
6 Later analysis, especially in the countries affected, focuses on liquidity. Explain the basis
of the argument; discuss why it might be correct and what might be missing.
7 What was the role of the IMF? Did it give necessary help and support to the countries
concerned or did it make matters worse?
9 Are there parallels between the Asian crisis and the crisis dating from 2007?
117
Chapter 6 The Asian crisis of 1997 and the IMF
References
Alba, P., Bhattacharya, A., Claessens, S., Ghosh, S. and Hernandez, L. (1998). Volatility and con-
tagion in a financially integrated world: lessons from East Asia’s recent experience. Paper pre-
sented at the PAFTAD 24 Conference, ‘Asia Pacific Financial Liberalization and Reform’, 1998.
Goldstein, M. (1998). The Asian Financial Crisis: Causes, Cures, and Systemic Implications.
Institute for International Economics, Washington DC.
International Monetary Fund (1997). Camdessus announces IMF support for Indonesia’s eco-
nomic program. News brief no. 97/19, 8, October 1997, www.imf.org/external/np/sec/
nb/1997/nb9719.htm.
Ito, T. (2007). Asian currency crisis and the International Monetary Fund, 10 years later:
Overview. Asian Econ. Policy Rev., 2: 16–49.
Radelet, S. and Sachs, J. (2000). The onset of the East Asian financial crisis. In Krugman, P., edi-
tor, Currency Crises. University of Chicago Press. www.nber–org/chapters/c8691.
Weisbrot, M. (2007). Ten years after: the lasting impact of the Asian financial crisis. Technical
report. www.cepr.net/documents/publications/asia_crisis_2007_08.pdf.
118
7 Banking crises
Policymakers formulating banking policy and fighting banking crises need to consider
several conflicting objectives. We want banks to actively finance economic activity and
hence take on risk, but at the same time we want to curtail excessive risk-taking. Once a
crisis is under way, we need to balance moral hazard considerations against the benefit of
robust recapitalisations of banks, all whilst trying to minimise the costs to the taxpayers.
Banking crises cannot easily be avoided, as they are an inevitable consequence of
having a vibrant banking system and economy. The only way to completely prevent
banking crises is to restrict the banking system so severely that banks are unable to
fulfil their socially useful role of financing risky activities, seriously holding back eco-
nomic growth. What we can do is to reduce the incidence of banking crises and to
minimise the costs of fighting them once they are underway.
Banking crises tend to have the same underlying causes. When times are good, banks
enjoy access to significant amounts of credit. The banks, flush with money, look for bor-
rowers, but traditional companies can only absorb so much money, not enough for all the
liquid funds available. Therefore, as the banks search for borrowers, those they find are
increasingly of low quality, often involved in real-estate speculation. Initially, the result-
ing weaknesses in the banks’ loan books are not very visible since the price of real estate
and equities increases sharply, creating a virtuous cycle between bank lending and prices.
High prices create the illusion of a good collateral which further stimulates lending.
Eventually, valuations of assets are increasingly out of tune with the underlying eco-
nomic fundamentals, and as in the tale by Hans Christian Andersen, it is as if some-
body cries out ‘the Emperor has no clothes’ and everything reverses at warp speed,
prices collapse and credit is withdrawn. This is typical of endogenous risk.
Chapter 7 Banking crises
The reason why such booms and busts in asset prices cause banking crises is the
inherent fragility of banks that comes from fractional reserve banking. Under this
arrangement, when depositors put their money into a bank, the bank then turns
around and lends most of it out, keeping a small fraction as reserves. The fragility
arises because deposits generally are of short maturity, and some can be withdrawn
whenever the depositor wants – demand deposits – whilst the loans tend to be of
longer maturity. If a sufficiently large number of depositors want their money, the
bank will run out of cash, because it cannot similarly call on its own borrowers to
repay their loans. We call such an event a bank run. Bank runs are contagious, and can
spread quickly throughout the financial system. The reason is that the banking system
is built on trust, so if depositors lose confidence in banks they flee to cash.
Bank failures matter because they create negative externalities, adversely impacting
on the economy. Banks provide essential services, and without banks companies can-
not do business, nor can individuals go about their lives in their usual way. The failure
of an individual bank might not be that costly because the authorities have in place
robust mechanisms for preventing collateral damage from bank failures, but if we expe-
rience a wave of bank failures – a banking crisis – the impact on society will be serious.
The incidence and seriousness of banking crises in the developed world has fallen
significantly since the Great Depression because the authorities in most countries
have in place effective regulations preventing bank failures and robust mechanisms
for coping with the failure of individual banks, preventing failures from spreading to
the entire banking system.
Historically, this was not the case, and bank crises have caused significant economic
damage. For example, Kupiec and Ramirez (2009) studied the United States (US) from
1900 until 1930 and found that bank failures significantly reduced economic growth.
A one-standard-deviation shock to the share of liabilities in failed banks was found to
cause a 17% decline in industrial production and a 4% decline in GDP.
Key concepts
■ Banking crises
■ Moral hazard
■ Good bank – bad bank
■ Causes of banking crises
■ Why it is so hard to prevent banking crises
120
7.1 Money and early banking
a good account of early banking history and further discussions on fractional reserve
banking, de Soto (2009) is an excellent book. Ferguson (2008) documents the his-
tory of money and Graeber (2011) provides a comprehensive survey of the history of
money and credit.
Early banking
It is unclear who was first engaged in fractional reserve banking. Initially, such banking
was illegal, not least because of the Catholic Church’s ban on the charging of interest –
usury. Fractional reserve banking began to gain legal recognition as governments realised
they could also benefit by borrowing large sums of money from banks, often to finance
wars. Inevitably, banks often failed because of sovereign defaults.
Below we discuss two examples of early banks, the famous Medici bank of Florence,
which functioned as a fractional reserve bank, and the Amsterdamsche Wisselbank in the
Netherlands, which operated as a full reserve bank for most of its existence. We will see
how they innovated and made their money, what risks they faced and how they eventu-
ally failed.
121
Chapter 7 Banking crises
15 florins
Medici
Merchant
Florence
Bill of exchange agreed at
3 florins per pound
(a) Initial deal
Bill of exchange
Medici
Merchant
London
5 pounds
Gains if florin Gains if florin
depreciates appreciates
(b) Three months later
122
7.2 Moral hazard
a civil war. Failure of the Bruges branch followed, due to poor management, fraud and,
again, excessive lending.
Definition 7.1 Moral hazard Moral hazard is what happens when those taking risk
do not have to face the full consequences of failure but get to enjoy all the benefits of success.
The consequence of moral hazard is that those fortunate enough to be in that situation are
encouraged to take on more risk than they otherwise would do.
123
Chapter 7 Banking crises
Moral hazard is pervasive throughout the economy, such as in standard insurance con-
tracts. Moral hazard is not something that should be eliminated, since that would sharply
curtail socially optimal risk taking. For example, an important development in modern
economies was the creation of limited liability corporations, firms where the owners do
not face the full consequences of failure but get all the benefits. Even though limited
liability corporations create moral hazard, few would argue they should be banned or
that the underlying moral hazard should be substantially reduced, since the benefits out-
weigh the costs.
Moral hazard is usually not much of a problem when those subject to moral hazard get
compensated for doing so. That compensation is why insurance companies are content to
write insurance contracts in the full knowledge that such contracts induce the insured to
take more risk. To contain such risk taking, insurance companies write into the contracts
clauses designed to prevent excessively risky behaviour, and try to price risk properly.
Unfortunately, this is often not the case in the financial system. Banks receive explicit
or implicit guarantees from the government but such insurance is almost never priced.
Governments can try to prevent excessive risk taking, but this is also frequently ineffective.
Addressing this problem is a main motivation for financial regulations. The problem arises
because the externalities from the failure of an important financial institution can out-
weigh any possible moral hazard considerations. This leaves the authorities with a typical
risk–return trade-off between the benefits of preventing panic now against the costs of
inducing riskier activity later.
Financial institutions, of course, know this and are incentivised to take on too much risk
when things are good in the full expectation of a bailout when things are bad. The bigger,
the more dangerous, the worse-run and more interconnected a financial institution is, the
more likely it is to be bailed out.
Taken together, the moral hazard problem in the financial industry is particularly hard,
with no obvious solution. In order to contain the problem, governments regulate the finan-
cial industry, but it can be difficult to the point of impossible to effectively contain excessive
risk taking. The powerful tools at the government’s disposal tend to be very blunt and could
easily curtail risk taking excessively, whilst the more surgical tools may not be effective.
1
www.imf.org/external/pubs/cat/longres.aspx?sk=26015.0.
124
7.3 Costs of banking crises
12
0
1978 1981 1984 1987 1990 1993 1996 2000 2003
banking crises. The relative calm before the 2007 crisis led to the misleading conclusion
that the world was becoming safer; instead, this period was more like the calm before
the storm.
It is remarkably hard to make sustained changes in levels of risk, because improvements
addressing existing fears have the side-effect of improving confidence, leading to greater
risk taking.
Costs
Banking crises impose costs on the economy in two main ways. The first is from the direct
fiscal costs of resolving a crisis, like the provision of deposit insurance, liquidity support,
recapitalisation and the like. This cost can be more or less accurately measured.
The second cost is the indirect effect on the economy, for example, the impact on
asset markets, reduced consumption and investment, the impaired channelling of funds
from savers to ultimate users, the contraction of government revenues, sharply expanding
fiscal expenditures and the shortfall in economic growth. This is much harder to meas-
ure, and the available studies inevitably have to rely on fairly crude methods to do this.
Consequently, we do need to take such measurements with reservation. Laeven and
Valencia (2008) estimate output losses by extrapolating from the trend of real GDP prior
to a crisis, and calculating the aggregate difference between the trend prediction and
actual outcomes during and after a crisis. There are many other ways of doing this analysis.
This calculation will often overstate the output losses. For example, suppose a country
is on an unsustainable growth path fuelled by inflows of foreign money. In this case, the
GDP growth in the years before the crisis will be artificially high, and the output loss,
therefore, will be overstated. Since most of the necessary macroeconomic data are in
publicly available databases, it would be straightforward to use alternative methodolo-
gies to calculate the costs of crises, and many authors have done so.
A small sample of the results is shown in Table 7.1. We see that Argentina in its 1980
crisis used more than half of its GDP to resolve the crisis, but the impact on GDP was rela-
tively small at 11%. This calculation is of course complicated by the fact that Argentina
experienced hyperinflation at the time.
The Scandinavian crisis of the early 1990s imposed significant direct fiscal costs on
Finland, but less so on Sweden. However, the output shortfall is significant. Note that it is
likely to be overstated because the GDP was artificially high at the top of the boom, and
125
Chapter 7 Banking crises
Table 7.1 Country systemic banking crises. Fiscal cost and output loss
are represented as percentages of GDP
Source: Systemic Banking Crises: a New Database, IMF Working Paper, pp. 34–51 (Laeven, L. and
Valencia, F. 2008), International Monetary Fund
these numbers do not quite correspond with those in Section 7.5.3 below, produced by
one of the central banks involved.
The size of the country matters: while the cost of the S&L crisis in 1988 in the US was
quite significant in monetary terms, relative to GDP the cost was not very high, in part
because only a small part of the financial sector was directly affected.
Costs of resolution
The IMF database was originally developed by the World Bank and some of the devel-
opers of the database published an interesting paper (Honohan and Klingebiel, 2003)
focusing on the fiscal costs of banking crises and how the various government responses
contribute to this cost. They found that if countries do not extend some policies of unlim-
ited deposit guarantees, open-ended liquidity support, repeated recapitalisations, debtor
bailouts and regulatory forbearance, the fiscal costs of resolution will be around 1% of
GDP on average, one-tenth of the actual costs. If, however, governments employ all of the
approaches above, the fiscal costs will be six times larger than in actuality.
It is important to note, however, that quantifying the costs of crisis and government
action, or inaction, is quite challenging. There are strong causal effects, where a bad crisis
might lead to bad outcomes, so that some of the policy measures taken might be associ-
ated with the severity of the outcomes.
It is also hard to estimate the cost of inaction. For example, the decision to allow
Lehman to fail was followed by a reversal of policy and effectively unlimited support to
many other institutions. Many commentators argue that the cost of continued inaction
would have been much higher than the cost of this support, but this remains controversial.
126
7.4 Causes of banking crises
coupled with inflows of hot money from abroad, and/or an accommodating fiscal and
monetary policy.
However, such booms are artificially created by money, not fundamentals, and even-
tually prices become so misaligned with the underlying economy that a small shock can
trigger a rapid reversal. This means that banking crises are often directly linked with mac-
roeconomic crises.
There are often country-specific differences. A report from the Basel Committee for
Banking Supervision (BCBS) in 2004 discusses the origins of banking crises in G10 coun-
tries and identifies several common factors – the regional economy, asset prices, financial
liberalisation and poor regulation in addition to bank specifics. We report a subset of
these results in Table 7.2. What is interesting is that bank-specific factors are least com-
mon and financial liberalisation is always present.
Financial liberalisation
Many governments faced with a heavily regulated financial sector and anaemic growth
opt for financial liberalisation in the belief that it may promote growth. If a government
opts for this policy, the execution does have to be right. A common mistake is to reduce
oversight and activity restrictions but maintain implicit or explicit government guaran-
tees such as deposit insurance. This creates a nasty moral hazard problem because it can
enable financial institutions to borrow cheaply and use the money for high-risk activities.
Deregulation has been at the core of many banking crises, such as the S&L crisis in the
US in the 1980s and the Scandinavian crisis in the late 1980s and early 1990s.
Corruption
A frequent cause of individual bank failures is corruption and mismanagement. We dis-
cuss one example in detail below, that of BCCI. Caprio and Honohan (2009) describe two
examples of what they call bad banking and bad policies in Latin American countries,
in Venezuela in 1994 and the Dominican Republic in 2003. In both cases, it involved
banks that were so large as to be systematically important. The banks did not seem to
Macroeconomic Banking
factors system
Switzerland (1991–1996) ✓ ✓ ✓ : :
Spain (1978–1983) ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ :
UK (1991) ✓ : ✓ : ✓
Norway (1988–1993) ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ :
Sweden (1991–1994) ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ :
Japan (1994–2002) ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ :
US (1982–1995) ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓
Source: Table 6 in BCBS Bank Failures in Mature Economies, Basel Committee, Working Paper 13, p. 67
(Ms Natalja v. Westernhagen et al. 2004), Bank for International Settlements
127
Chapter 7 Banking crises
record deposits as liabilities, enabling their insiders to loot the banks’ assets from inside,
that is, steal the banks’ assets. Because of the banks’ systematic importance, the central
bank of each country felt it necessary to make depositors whole, destabilising the macro-
economy. Furthermore, the rogue bank in Venezuela paid high deposit rates, forcing other
competing banks to do the same.
Zombie banks
If financial institutions, in effect, are insolvent but able to continue operating because
of government support, they are often referred to as zombie banks. The term was first
used by Kane (1989) when referring to the S&L crisis, but it became especially com-
mon when referring to the Japanese banking sector following that country’s crisis in
the early 1990s. See BCBS (2004) for more details on the Japanese crisis. In the 1980s,
Japanese banks made large loans that eventually turned out to be bad, with many
involving real estate. Instead of resolving the bank failures, closing down the failed
banks or recapitalising them, the government opted to keep them on life support,
often using a process called evergreening, whereby a bank is allowed to keep a non-
performing loan on its books as if it were performing. That often involved lending
money to failed borrowers, just so that they could repay old loans, steadily increasing
loan losses to the bank.
Eventually, this meant that a large proportion of the Japanese banking system con-
sisted of zombie banks, significantly associated with the Japanese financial and economic
malaise. While the zombies were not the cause of the crisis, their presence adversely
affected recovery.
The Japanese lesson is that policymakers should prevent the emergence of zombie
banks at all costs, and hence aim to resolve, restructure or shut down failed banks as
quickly as possible. That was the approach taken by the Scandinavian governments in
resolving their banking crisis in the early 1990s. In the ongoing crisis, the governments of
the US, Switzerland and the UK have actively tried to prevent the emergence of zombie
banks. However, this has not been the case in many of the European countries affected
by the European sovereign debt crisis, and there are significant fears that zombie banks
may be emerging in Europe. The fact that the European Central Bank (ECB) has become
the sole provider of liquidity for certain banks, and even entire national banking systems,
whilst losses have not been properly recognised, supports the view that some European
governments prefer to let their banks turn into zombies to make the necessary effort to
resolve their banking crises.
128
7.5 Bank and banking system failures
Herstatt
Herstatt was a large German bank that was forced into liquidation by the German author-
ities on 26 June 1974. On that day a number of banks had released payments of German
marks to Herstatt in Frankfurt in exchange for USD that were to be delivered in New York.
Because of time-zone differences, Herstatt ceased operations between the times of the
respective payments. Herstatt had taken receipt of payment from European banks (in
marks) but not yet made the corresponding dollar payments. Consequently, mostly US
creditors were left holding unsecured claims. This is an example of settlement risk. The
failure of Bank Herstatt was one factor that led to the creation of the continuous linked set-
tlement platform, which was launched almost 30 years later in 2002. For more details on
the Herstatt case, see BCBS (2004).
Banco Ambrosiano
Banco Ambrosiano was an Italian bank which collapsed in 1982 with important conse-
quences for future regulations. See, for example, Stoler and Kalb (1982) for a description
of events, and Herring and Litan (1995) for the regulatory implications. It was the largest
private banking group in Italy in its time, with operations in 15 countries. At the centre
of the bank’s failure was its chairman, Roberto Calvi, called by the Italian press ‘God’s
Banker’ due to his close association with the Holy See.
Calvi was determined to transform his bank into a major international financial insti-
tution from a relatively small regional bank with strong religious overtones. One of his
initial steps was to form a Luxembourg holding company not subject to Italy’s banking
regulations.
Calvi’s problems began in 1978, when the Bank of Italy conducted an extensive audit
of his financial empire, noting unorthodox operations involving $1.2 billion in unsecured
USD borrowings. Calvi was buying up Ambrosiano stock, using money borrowed on inter-
national financial markets. The bank collapsed because the Italian lira fell relative to the
dollar.
Calvi was sentenced to four years in jail, but released pending appeal. He fled Italy but
was found hanged under Blackfriars Bridge in London in 1982. The failure of Ambrosiano
left more than 200 international financial institutions with large losses, threatening the
stability of the entire international banking system. Ultimately, this brought changes in the
way the world’s major banks do business. The BCBS responded to the Banco Ambrosiano
collapse in 1983 with the first major revision of the Concordat.
BCCI
BCCI was a bank registered in Luxembourg with head offices in Karachi and London.
In July 1991, BCCI, one of the 300 or so branches and subsidiaries of foreign banks
operating in London, failed because of widespread fraud. BCCI’s complex structure
consisted of a holding company, incorporated in Luxembourg, and two main sub-
sidiaries incorporated in the Cayman Islands and Luxembourg. See Truell and Gurwin
(1992) for more information. BCCI had branches in over 70 countries with the UK
offices being branches of the Luxembourg subsidiary. Its principal shareholders were
in Abu Dhabi.
129
Chapter 7 Banking crises
It is now believed that BCCI’s financial statements had been falsified from its establish-
ment in 1972. A scheme of deception was developed to support BCCI’s rapid growth and
to conceal lending losses. To achieve this, BCCI failed to record deposit liabilities and cre-
ated fictitious loans that generated substantial profits. Fraud also took place within BCCI’s
treasury operations. BCCI used depositors’ money to fund their own proprietary trading
activities, and covered up the resulting losses with more fictitious loans.
Prior to these problems surfacing in 1990, supervisors and commercial bankers were
wary of BCCI because of its rapid growth and opaque corporate structure. However, while
BCCI was sometimes mentioned in the press ‘chiefly for the mystery that surrounded
it’, financial market participants generally saw BCCI as a bank that made losses through
incompetence rather than fraud.
From the spring of 1990, concerns about the evidence of fraud within BCCI led to
ongoing discussions between BCCI’s auditors (Price Waterhouse), banking supervisors
and BCCI’s shareholders. In 1991, Price Waterhouse became increasingly convinced that
the fraud within BCCI was endemic, with published financial statements grossly inaccu-
rate, and informed the Bank of England (BoE) of its findings.
The liquidators, Deloitte & Touche, filed a lawsuit against the bank’s auditors, Price
Waterhouse and Ernst & Young. This was settled for $175 million in 1998. BCCI creditors
also attempted to sue the BoE as BCCI’s regulators. This case demonstrated the reputa-
tional risk for central banks that also oversaw banking supervision, and was one motiva-
tion for the separation of banking supervision from the BoE in 1997.
130
7.5 Bank and banking system failures
■ First and foremost the need for strong and effective supervision of insured depository
institutions, particularly if they are given new or expanded powers or are experiencing
rapid growth.
■ Second, this can be accomplished only if the industry does not have too much influ-
ence over its regulators and if the regulators have the ability to hire, train and retain
qualified staff. In this regard, the bank regulatory agencies need to remain politically
independent. The S&L supervisor was too close to the industry it regulated during the
early years of the crisis, and its policies significantly contributed to the problem.
■ Third, the supervisors need adequate financial resources. The S&L supervisor was given
insufficient resources for the supervision of the newly deregulated industry, with many
new activities.
■ Fourth, the S&L crisis highlights the importance of promptly closing insolvent, insured
financial institutions in order to minimise potential losses to the deposit insurance fund
and to ensure a more efficient financial marketplace. The failure to promptly close fail-
ing institutions creates uncertainty, adversely affecting both the financial system and
the economy at large.
■ Finally, resolution of failing financial institutions requires that the deposit insurance
fund be strongly capitalised with real reserves, not just government guarantees. The
reason is that a deposit insurance fund is allocated to its intended purpose, ensuring
efficiency and rapid disbursement. It takes much longer to raise funds from the govern-
ment, because a political decision is needed.
The S&L crisis, and other bank failures in the US at the same time, had a significant
impact on how the US authorities have approached financial regulation. In response, they
have significantly improved the quality of supervision, absorbing the lessons of the S&L
crisis, for example, by developing one of the best resolution regimes in the world, prompt
corrective action.
131
Chapter 7 Banking crises
time when risk-taking was on the increase by inexperienced banks, government oversight
was decreasing. This is typical of the problems of deregulation as discussed above.
This led to a rapid increase in the balance sheets of the banks, as well as asset prices
generally, with increased leverage the main cause. For example, nominal non-financial
private sector debt increased by 52% in Norway and by 87% in Sweden, causing asset
price bubbles. Housing prices in the five years before the peak increased in real terms by
80% in Finland, 44% in Sweden and 38% in Norway. Similarly, equity prices tripled in
nominal terms in Sweden and Finland and doubled in Norway.
Moe et al. (2004) argue that the fiscal cost of the banking recapitalisation was 8.9% of
GDP in Finland, 3.9% in Sweden, and 2% in Norway. Table 7.2 gives 12.8% for Finland,
highlighting the challenge of estimating the cost of banking crises.
132
7.5 Bank and banking system failures
300 Iceland UK
Ireland US
200 Spain
100
0
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008
A distinguishing feature of the Icelandic crisis was that the real-estate bubble was
smaller than in other bubble economies, with the bubble manifesting itself more clearly
in the stock market, as seen in Figure 7.3. While there are several reasons for this, the most
important is that the stock market was more easily manipulated and more useful in pro-
viding collateral in the alleged fraud committed.
Although the banks were highly risky, this was not evident from publicly available num-
bers, as they were amongst the most highly capitalised banks in Europe according to the
Basel capital regulations – see Figure 16.4. One reason is that the bank capital numbers
were illusory, since the banks funded purchases of their own equity issues. After that was
prevented by the supervisor, banks simply funded equity issues in other Icelandic banks,
hedging the exposure by using a contract for difference. This served the dual purpose of
increasing tier 1 capital, without the dilution causing prices to fall. All of this helped to
create the appearance of high demand for the stocks, fuelling stock-price increases early
in the bubble, and preventing prices from falling late in the bubble, after the professional
investors caught on to what was happening and started to sell the stocks.
Another way to inflate bank stock prices was by goodwill which was continually increas-
ing, sanctioned by the banks’ accountants, the main international accounting firms, with-
out much apparent concern as to value. This contributed to the accounts overstating the
value of assets.
Taken together, the causes of the banking crisis were over-ambitious goals without the
competence to pull it through, supported by aggressive accounting treatment and per-
mitted by poor regulatory oversight. As the banks expanded, this developed into corrup-
tion, incompetence and looting the banks from inside. The privatisation of the banking
system delivered the banks in the hands of politically connected groups, who continued
enjoying strong connections to the political classes. When the banks started to expand,
the government did not correspondingly expand the supervisory structure, so over time
the supervisors became less and less effective. The supervisor took an excessively legal-
istic approach, making it easy for the banks to find loopholes in the regulations. In other
words, the enforcement of the regulations targeted the letter of the law, not the spirit of
the law, and lost touch with the objectives for which the rules were created.
The banks enjoyed seemingly unlimited access to funds until late in the bubble, and
used some of those funds to manipulate their own capital and share prices, all in a posi-
tive feedback loop. Analysis by financial professionals did not seem to provide much
133
Chapter 7 Banking crises
B3 2000
Rating 1000
CDS spread
Ba3
CDS spread 500
Rating
Baa3
200
A3
100
Aa3 50
Aaa
2006 2007 2008 2009
Figure 7.4 Moody’s credit ratings for Kaupthing and CDS spreads
Data source: Moody’s, Markit and Bloomberg
discipline. We can see this from Figure 7.4, showing the credit ratings and credit default
swap (CDS) spreads for the largest bank, Kaupthing. The ratings, in particular, were sur-
prisingly good right up until the collapse, whilst the CDS spreads were steadily increasing
from the middle of 2007 when the global crisis started.
Lessons
Countries with large financial systems have spent many decades or centuries develop-
ing banking structures and the related supervisory structures. Creating such a setup from
scratch in the span of a few years is quite challenging and needs significant political com-
mitment. This demonstrates the importance of institutions in ensuring that markets func-
tion efficiently.
This relates to peculiarities caused by operating within Europe.2 Because of the com-
mon European market, European banks were able to operate across the EU, with minimal
scrutiny from the host country, since supervision was mostly in the hands of the home
supervisor. The absence of pan-European supervision was exploited by the Icelandic
banks, enabling their rapid expansion.
7.6 Summary
Banking crises are an unfortunate consequence of modern economies, and while we can sig-
nificantly mitigate their incidence and consequences, they cannot be prevented altogether
in a cost-effective way. The main culprit is the inherent vulnerabilities in banking, such as the
fractional reserve system. Another factor is the importance of trust and interdependence in
banking, and the overconfidence and tendency to conceal weakness that result.
Banking crises, while well understood, are still quite frequent, because it can be dif-
ficult to identify the underlying problems until it is too late, and banks have incentives to
ignore and hide the problems.
The authorities are in a difficult position when it comes to resolving banking crises, hav-
ing to balance a robust response against moral hazard considerations.
2
Iceland is not a member of the European Union (EU) but is a member of the European Economic Area
(EEA), giving it full access to European markets.
134
References
Several bank crises have had a profound impact on financial regulations, such as those
of Herstatt, Ambrosiano and BCCI. Doubtless the current crisis will also be influential.
We discussed three banking crises in some detail: the S&L in the US in the 1980s, the
Scandinavian crisis of the early 1990s and the recent Icelandic crisis.
2 Banking crisis are frequent and well understood. We know why they happen, the best
way to deal with them and we have a good understanding of how to prevent them.
Why then are they so frequent?
4 What are the ingredients that enable some countries to remain financial centres for
centuries, while other countries do not seem to manage it?
5 What are the main lessons from the the savings and loan crisis?
6 The Swedish resolution of its banking crisis in the early 1990s is usually considered the
‘gold standard’ in crisis resolution. Why might that be the case?
References
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2004). Bank failures in mature economies. Working
paper no. 13, Bank of International Settlements.
Benediktsdottir, S., Danielsson, J. and Zoega, G. (2011). Lessons from a collapse of a financial
system. Economic Policy, 26: 183–231.
Caprio, G. and Honohan, P. (2009). Banking crises. In Berger, A., Molyneux, P. and Wilson, J.,
editors, The Oxford Handbook of Banking. Oxford University Press.
de Soto, J. H. (2009). Money, Bank Credit, and Economic Cycles. Ludwig von Mises Institute,
Auburn, AL.
Ferguson, N. (2008). The Ascent of Money. The Penguin Group.
Graeber, D. (2011). Debt: The First 5,000 Years. Melville House Publishing, New York.
Herring, R. J. and Litan, R. E. (1995). Financial Regulation in the Global Economy. The Brookings
Institution, Washington DC.
Honohan, P. and Klingebiel, D. (2003). The fiscal cost implications of an accommodating
approach to banking crises. J. Banking Finance, 27(8): 1539–60.
Kaminsky, G. L. and Reinhart, C. M. (1999). The twin crises: the causes of banking and balance-
of-payments problems. Amer. Econ. Rev., 89: 473–500.
Kane, E. J. (1989). The S&L insurance mess: how did it happen? Technical report, Urban
Institute Press.
Kupiec, P. H. and Ramirez, C. D. (2009). Bank failures and the cost of systemic risk: evidence
from 1900–1930. Technical report, FDIC.
135
Chapter 7 Banking crises
Laeven, L. and Valencia, F. (2008). Systemic banking crises: a new database. Technical report,
IMF. IMF Working Paper.
Moe, T. G., Solheim, J. A. and Vale, B. (2004). The Norwegian banking crisis. Technical report,
Norges Bank. Occasional Paper no. 33.
Moysich, A. (2000). The savings and loan crisis and its relationship to banking. In Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation, History of the 80s — Lessons for the Future. Volume I: an Examination of
the Banking Crises of the 1980s and Early 1990s, Chapter 4. FDIC, Washington DC.
Reinhart, C. M. and Rogoff, K. (2009). This Time Is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly.
Princeton University Press.
Selgin, G. (2003). Adaptive learning and the transition to fiat money. Econ. J., 113(484): 147–65.
Stoler, P. and Kalb, J. B. (1982). The great Vatican bank mystery. http://time.com/time/
magazine/article/0,9171,951806,00.html.
Truell, P. and Gurwin, L. (1992). False Profits: the Inside Story of BCCI, the World’s Most Corrupt
Financial Empire. Houghton Mifflin, Boston, MA.
136
8 Bank runs and deposit insurance
During the Great Depression of 1929 to 1933, the United States (US) lost over one-
third of its banks to bankruptcies and people preferred to store their money under
their mattresses to keeping it in banks. At the same time, a loss of confidence in Austria
led to a run on its banks and government, spilling over to Hungary and Germany.
These bank failures were a major contributor to the Depression.
While the Great Depression is the worst example of contagious bank runs in his-
tory, waves of bank runs were quite common in the nineteenth and early twentieth
centuries. Since then, they have been much less common, especially in developed
economies, not least because policymakers have much clearer understanding of the
damage caused by bank runs and have developed much better tools for prevent-
ing them. The run on Northern Rock in 2007 is unique. This does not mean we have
become successful in preventing bank runs, rather they have changed form and are
more likely to happen in the wholesale markets.
Bank runs happen because of a fundamental weakness in fractional reserve bank-
ing systems. A basic model of a bank is an institution that collects demand deposits
and makes long-term loans. If a sufficient number of depositors want to get their
money back, the bank fails because most of its assets are tied up in long-term
loans. For this reason, if depositors are worried that a bank’s loans are of a low
quality they will demand their deposits back, and cause a bank run. A bank run
can happen even if there is nothing wrong with the bank; all we need is for deposi-
tors to get worried, and then a bank run becomes a self-fulfilling prophecy. A bank
run can lead to cascading failures within the banking system because depositors
Chapter 8 Bank runs and deposit insurance
Key concepts
■ Bank runs
■ Deposit insurance
■ Retail and wholesale funding
■ Moral hazard
■ Diamond and Dybvig model
138
8.1 Bank runs and crises
20%
10%
0%
1920 1923 1926 1929 1932 1935 1938
Figure 8.1 Bank failure rate 1920–1939 in the US. Main years of Great Depression
highlighted
139
Chapter 8 Bank runs and deposit insurance
The government reaction to the bank failures was inadequate. A potentially useful
move was made in December 1931, when the Reconstruction Finance Corporation (RFC)
was founded to provide finance for banks and firms in need of liquidity. However, then
the Speaker of the House insisted that RFC loans to banks be publicised and once this
requirement was enacted, in January 1933, banks in trouble stopped seeking RFC aid
because to be seen receiving RFC loans simply triggered runs.
The Federal Reserve System (Fed) was not prepared to sign off on a federal guarantee
for bank deposits in March 1933, nor did it feel there were any additional measures it
should recommend. Finally on 4 March, President Roosevelt closed all the banks in the
country for more than a week – bank holiday – and under the federal government’s super-
vision, weaker banks were merged into stronger banks. Depositors received compensation
for roughly 85% of their former deposits.
In response to this crisis, the Glass–Steagall Deposit Insurance Act was passed in
June 1933 establishing deposit insurance coverage in the amount of $2,500, and the
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) as the authority to regulate and super-
vise state non-member banks. We can see from Figure 8.1 that these measures were
successful in stopping the cascading failures, since the US experienced virtually no
bank failures for the remainder of the decade, even if the Great Depression had a
double dip in 1936.
140
8.1 Bank runs and crises
of the FSA, said, the UK could have avoided the run on deposits at Northern Rock had
there been a depositor protection scheme such as exists in the US.
Summary
Until its failure, the funding model of Northern Rock was considered sound by the bank
itself, its supervisors and the capital markets. With the benefit of hindsight, we recognise
that all of these parties were misguided. Northern Rock remained solvent only so long as
liquidity was in effect infinite. Because liquidity was thought infinite, Northern Rock and
most other banks in the world behaved in a way that ensured liquidity would dry up.
Therefore, the failure of Northern Rock was almost certain, given time.
If the deposit insurance scheme of the UK had been effective, the actual run on Northern
Rock probably would have been prevented, sparing the authorities the embarrassment of
141
Chapter 8 Bank runs and deposit insurance
seeing it play out on the TV screens. Deposit insurance would not have prevented the fail-
ure of the bank, considering that only 23% of its funding came from deposits.
As a response to the Northern Rock failure, the authorities were forced to announce
unlimited deposit insurance in order to reassure bank clients and prevent contagious runs
across the UK banking sector. This demonstrates the problem created when the authori-
ties have inadequate policies in place and then are confronted by a crisis. The authorities
are forced to overreact in order to prevent more damage. In other words, the UK went
from having a deposit insurance scheme that was too weak to one that was too strong.
Background
In the simple version of the Diamond–Dybvig model presented here, the banking system
is illiquid, meaning that not all banking system obligations can be met if all holders of
those obligations simultaneously claim what they have been promised.
There are two main ingredients in the model:
1 Depositors are initially individually uncertain about their profile of consumption, that
is whether they prefer to consume early or late.
2 The banking system deals with depositors on a first-come, first-served basis.
Setup
The economy has three periods, t = 0, 1 and 2, the economy starts at date 0 and all
agents have an endowment of $1. There is an intertemporal technology (reflecting the
illiquidity of assets) which can be represented by the following:
t = 0 t = 1 t = 2
-1 1 R
142
8.2 Modelling deposit insurance
Autarky
Autarky is the condition of economic self-sufficiency, without trade. Under autarky, there
are no means to shift consumption and agents solve the optimisation problem individu-
ally. Ex-ante 1t = 02, all agents are identical. The expected utility for each agent is given by
Assuming the utility function is increasing and concave – standard form with non-satiation
and risk aversion – the late agent will have higher eventual utility than the early agent.
c2 c2
2R
autarky
autarky
R R
op
tim
al
c1 c1
0 1 0 1 2
(a) Autarky (b) Optimal social insurance
143
Chapter 8 Bank runs and deposit insurance
∼ 2 + U1c
max E1U2 = U1c ∼2
1 2
∼
c1
∼ 2 + U1R12 - ∼
= U1c c 122
1
Optimisation, differentiating with respect to ∼c 1, and setting the result to zero, gives the
standard result (assuming an interior solution) that the marginal rate of substitution equals
the marginal rate of transformation:
∼2
U′1c 1
∼2 = R (8.1)
U′1c 2
The optimal consumption allocation satisfies the first-order condition and the budget
constraint. At the optimum, we do not want to give consumption to those who do not
value it, therefore, early agents’ date – 2 consumption is equal to late agents’ date – 1
consumption, which is zero.
144
8.2 Modelling deposit insurance
This good equilibrium achieves optimal risk sharing and demonstrates the role of finan-
cial intermediation in increasing welfare. A crucial question regarding this fractional reserve
system is whether the bank will be able to fulfil its contractual obligations. This depends
on investors’ anticipation about the safety of the bank.
Consider first the case that a late investor anticipates that the bank will be able to fulfil
its obligations. If late investors trust their bank, they will prefer to withdraw at t = 2, thus
the proportion of time t = 1 withdrawals will be l. So in order to avoid premature liqui-
dation, the bank should have a liquid reserve of at least lc*1.
Multiple equilibria
There is a potential for multiple equilibria in this model: a good equilibrium of no run
described above and a bad equilibrium where a bank run takes place. The good equilib-
rium is better than the bad in the sense of Pareto efficiency. In the bank run equilibrium,
everyone prefers to receive a risky return with a mean of 1 even if holding the endowment
until t = 2 provides a return exceeding 1 if there is no run.
Bank runs are a type of self-fulfilling prophecy, caused by a shift in expectations. This
shift could happen for almost any reason. Each depositor’s incentive to withdraw her
funds depends on what she expects other depositors to do. If enough depositors antici-
pate that other depositors will withdraw their funds, they all have an incentive to rush to
be the first in line to withdraw their funds, since the face value of deposits is larger than
the liquidation value of the bank’s assets.
Bank runs
To illustrate a bank run, suppose there are N depositors, each endowed with $1, so the
amount the bank has on hand at t = 1 is $N. Given the optimal contract, the total value
of deposits is $N11 + p2, hence, the bank does not have enough cash to pay off all
depositors at t = 1.
The first person to demand her money at t = 1 will get the full amount 1 + p and this
applies to all the agents in the queue up to the fraction 1>11 + p2 when the bank runs
out of assets. The bank’s payoff to any agent depends only on the agent’s place in line
and not on future information about agents behind her in the queue. Therefore, the last
N11 - 1>11 + p22 get nothing, and all agents will want to be the first in the queue.
Note that for runs to be an equilibrium, demand deposits must yield more than 1 if
withdrawn at t = 1. If deposits yield 1 when withdrawn at t = 1, the outcome is not an
improvement on the autarkic outcome, with the bank simply mimicking each agent hold-
ing their endowment, but then this shows that a demand deposit which is not subject to
runs provides no liquidity services. It is precisely the transformation of illiquid assets into
liquid assets that is responsible both for the liquidity service provided by banks and for
their susceptibility to runs.
145
Chapter 8 Bank runs and deposit insurance
probability is small enough, as the good equilibrium dominates autarky. Since in a run, the
fraction 1>11 + p2 get ∼c 1 at t = 1, while the rest get nothing, the expected utility is
∼2
U1c 1
E1U2 =
1 + p
∼2
U1c
Run E1U2 =
1 ∼ 2 + 11 - l2U1c
6 lU1c ∼2
1 2
1 + p
Analysis
The instability of fractional reserve banking systems comes mainly from the coordination
failure among investors. Once they have made their deposits, anything that causes them
to anticipate a run will lead to a run. In this framework, banks with pure demand deposits
will be very concerned about maintaining confidence because they realise that the good
equilibrium is very fragile.
Analysis
Within the stylistic framework of the model, a government deposit insurance scheme has
a natural advantage over a privately funded scheme. The reason is that the government
has the power to tax depositors to finance insurance, therefore effectively preventing a
146
8.3 Pros and cons of deposit insurance
run. A private scheme cannot rely on such powers, and instead would need to have suffi-
cient reserves to make the insurance credible. Since holding such reserves would be costly,
a government provision of deposit insurance is more efficient than private provision.
In the real world, this is not as clear-cut. For example, it would be politically very dif-
ficult to actually tax those withdrawing early, and as a consequence the government
might have to maintain a funded deposit insurance fund, or provide guarantees. This
might remove the efficiency advantages of the government.
One example of difficulties in taxing agents withdrawing early can be seen from the
process of resolving the failure of Bernie Madoff. The authorities are trying to claw back
funds from those who successfully took the money out of the fund, but this has turned
out to be a very long and very expensive process, with uncertain outcomes.
‘The deposit insurance system is indeed a monster and it is a monster that threatens
to devour the very system it is intended to protect.’
Deposit insurance is often criticised for creating moral hazard and incentives for
excessive risk-taking by banks. By guaranteeing deposits, market incentives to monitor
banks and to demand an interest payment commensurate with the risk of the bank are
diminished.
Moral hazard
Moreover, it can be difficult for insurance premiums to properly internalise the cost of
risk, because of problems of asymmetric information. The bank knows more about its
operations than outsiders, which therefore gives the bank incentives to take more hidden
risk – moral hazard. Furthermore, risk-sensitive deposit insurance gives rise to problems
of pro-cyclicality.
The depositors themselves also contribute to moral hazard. If they know they are
protected regardless of what the bank does, their incentive is to put their money into
the bank with the highest interest rates. This is very similar to the problem analysed in
the Krugman model of governments guaranteeing borrowers, and the problem in the
S&L crisis. In addition, it creates competitive problems for banks that are prudently run,
because they cannot attract deposits. This was the case in the Venezuelan banking crisis.
147
Chapter 8 Bank runs and deposit insurance
retail depositors. Provided the institutional investors run the bank, deposit insurance is
not sufficient to prevent the retail depositors from running the bank. This was the case
with Northern Rock.
This picture is somewhat muddled by the fact that post-Lehman, it is often assumed
that governments insure all providers of liquidity to the banks, both institutional and
retail. This is supported by the fact that in the crisis from 2007, credit losses have been
very small. For example, by the middle of 2012 only two European countries had imposed
losses on bank creditors, the UK and Denmark, a minuscule amount in the former case
and small in the latter. In spite of the massive amounts of public money provided to the
banks, the authorities have not wanted to hit private creditors.
More generally, changes in the structure and functioning of financial markets have
been reducing the significance of deposit insurance schemes as devices to deal with sys-
temic risks of runs. This reflects the greater importance of wholesale financial markets
and funding in the system, as well as the increasing systemic relevance of institutions that
either do not have deposit insurance protection, such as money market mutual funds and
hedge funds, or are perceived as too big to fail (TBTF).
148
8.4 Summary
The financial crisis happened at a time of maximum political pressure, in the months
before elections. This forced the government to reinstitute deposit insurance for its banks,
even if the government and the central bank president had said strongly and often that
they would never do so. Even though the authorities at the time held the view that deposit
insurance creates moral hazard and free-rider problems, and therefore should be limited,
this view proved unsustainable.
This experience suggests that deposit insurance is a practical necessity for any indus-
trialised nation, and that governments cannot credibly commit to not providing deposit
insurance, because the political and economic pressures to do so in times of crisis become
overwhelming. Consequently, governments are better off recognising the eventuality and
maintaining a deposit insurance scheme.
8.4 Summary
The fractional reserve banking system is inherently fragile and subject to bank runs. The
experience from the Great Depression demonstrated how devastating contagious bank
runs can be, and how effective deposit insurance is in preventing bank runs. This is not as
clear-cut with modern banks depending significantly on wholesale funding.
The fragility of banks and the importance of deposit insurance are succinctly modelled
by Diamond and Dybvig who clearly demonstrate the positive contribution of financial
intermediation and simultaneously how it can increase the fragility of the financial sys-
tem. This fragility can be addressed by the government by providing deposit insurance,
perhaps by taxing those who aim to run banks and by compensating those who are at the
end of the queue and otherwise would not get their funds back. Within the simple con-
fines of the model, this is sufficient to ensure bank runs will not happen.
At the same time, full deposit insurance does lead to moral hazard. If depositors do not
care what a bank does with its money, a badly run or even fraudulent bank will simply
offer more interest than its competitors, expand rapidly, and make dodgy loans.
The alternative of having no deposit insurance scheme is not politically credible, as
the example of Argentina demonstrated. In case of a bank run, depositors will exert enor-
mous political pressure to fix the problem and make them whole. A bank run is a highly
visible event, demonstrating that the authorities have failed to adequately supervise the
financial system. This is highly embarrassing, as we saw in the case of Northern Rock. The
authorities are left to scramble to implement deposit insurance, and since the worst time
to make policy decisions is usually during a crisis, it is much better to be prepared and
have a well thought-out deposit insurance scheme in place.
149
Chapter 8 Bank runs and deposit insurance
(a) What were the underlying risk factors that ultimately caused the the failure of
Northern Rock?
(b) How did the reaction of the British authorities to the crisis at Northern Rock
directly contribute to the bank run?
(c) Compare and contrast bank runs in wholesale markets and retail markets from
the point of view of Northern Rock.
An agent does not know if she is early or late at t = 0, but learns it at t = 1. Fraction l
are early, and 1 - l late.
(a) Suppose the utility function takes the form
U1c2 = 1 - 1>C
Derive the utility levels of both early and late agents under autarchy.
(b) Design an optimal insurance contract for the two agents.
3 Before the crisis from 2007, the general trend was for deposit insurance being reduced
or even abolished. Very quickly, this sentiment changed, for example, in the case of
Northern Rock. Why was that, and do you think extensive deposit insurance is here to
stay?
References
Borio, C. (2009). Ten propositions about liquidity crisis. Working paper no. 293, Bank of
International Settlements.
Dewatripont, M. and Tirole, J. (1994). The Prudential Regulation of Banks. MIT Press.
Diamond, D. and Dybvig, P. (1983). Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity. J. Polit. Econ.,
91: 401–19.
Kovacevich, R. M. (1996). Deposit insurance: It’s time to cage the monster. www.minneapolisfed.
org/publications_papers/pub_display.cfm? id=2682.
Miller, G. P. (1996). Is deposit insurance inevitable? Lessons from Argentina. Int. Rev. Law Econ.,
16: 211–232.
Santos, J. A. C. (2000). Bank capital regulation in contemporary banking theory: a review of
the literature. Technical Report 90, Bank for International Settlements. www.bis.org/publ/
work90.pdf?noframes–1.
Shin, H. S. (2008). Reflections on modern bank runs: a case study of Northern Rock. Mimeo,
Princeton University.
150
9 Trading and speculation
Trading is an essential part of economic life, facilitating the needs of economic agents
to acquire or dispose of tradable assets. For example, the main transaction for most
people involves real estate, and that is trading. Intimately connected to trading is
speculation. Few economic terms evoke such strong and different reactions as spec-
ulation. For some, speculation is the root of instability, undermining sensible gov-
ernment policy, while for others it brings rationality to a world where governments
constantly manipulate the economy for political reasons.
The term speculation has multiple meanings in common parlance. In a classic text,
Security Analysis, by Graham and Dodd (1934), speculation is the opposite of invest-
ment, borrowing money to buy assets without proper fundamental research. A more
common usage suggests that speculation is the making of risky investments for the
purpose of short-term profit. Most people tend to distinguish between speculation
and investing based on the amount of risk. A trader in a bank using 1 million to buy
an asset with a 50% chance of delivering nothing and a 50% probability of doubling
the money might be said to be speculating, whilst allocating the funds to a long-term
position in an AA corporate bond is investment.
There is a fine line between what might be considered legitimate and illegitimate
speculative activity. Speculators play a useful role in society, providing useful risk-
sharing and hedge facilitation, since for anybody wishing to hedge away risk, some-
one needs to be willing to take on that risk – to be the counterparty to the trade. That
counterparty is often a speculator.
For example, farmers need to make decisions about their crops early in the year,
but can sell them only much later, when they harvest. If crop prices collapse on the
market, the farmer may be wiped out. It is not surprising that the first hedging markets
Chapter 9 Trading and speculation
in the world developed in agriculture. Aristotle describes the use of a futures contract
for olive oil, but the first documented futures exchange is the Dōjima rice exchange in
Japan in the 1730s, set up to help the Samurai, who were paid in rice, needing to get
stable conversion to coin. The first exchange-traded commodities futures contracts
were listed on the Chicago Board of Trade in 1864, a model soon replicated around
the world, for example in India in 1875, covering cotton futures.
Other speculative activity is less salubrious and it might be tempting to impose
rules to prevent such behaviour. Large financial institutions are able to make such
large speculative bets that they not only risk bankruptcy but also threaten financial
stability, causing systemic risk. One of the most infamous examples is the failure of
LTCM in 1998. Unfortunately, it is not easy to effectively regulate speculation, because
it can be quite difficult to distinguish between illegitimate and legitimate speculative
activities, and if one is concerned about speculation, it may be better to target the
tools employed by speculators, rather than the motives of those trading.
Key concepts
■ Speculation
■ Moral hazard
■ Proprietary trading
■ Financial transaction tax
■ Trading strategies
152
9.1 Trading scandals and abuse
arose from the activities of Bruno Iksil, a well-known player in the credit default swap
(CDS) market, who accumulated such large positions that he got nicknamed the
‘London whale’, supposedly moving prices with his trading.
It seems that the bank had little understanding of what he was up to, finding his
strategy ‘flawed, complex, poorly reviewed, poorly executed, and poorly monitored.
The portfolio has proven to be riskier, more volatile and less effective as a hedge than
we thought’, according to senior bank management. The trading scandal will not
much affect the financial fortunes of JP Morgan Chase; its first-quarter profits in 2012
dropped to $4.9 billion, from $5.6 billion a year earlier. The scandal may, however,
have a significant indirect impact on the bank because of how it affects the debate
on the regulation of financial institutions and whether banks should be allowed to
engage in proprietary trading under the Volcker rule.
While the ‘London whale’ reflected the activities of few individuals over a relatively short
period of time, a much larger scandal involving LIBOR price-fixing was first reported by the
Wall Street Journal in 2008, with Barclays Bank fined for its participation in the scandal in 2012.
The LIBOR price-fixing scandal is quite serious, as it undermines the integrity of a key
interest rate and the banking system as a whole. The scandal will embolden efforts to
strictly regulate the financial system.
Ponzi schemes
A classical, and common, fraudulent investment operation is a Ponzi scheme. A fund pays
investors profit from their own money, or money paid in by new investors, rather than
153
Chapter 9 Trading and speculation
Rogue traders
Employees of banks are not always willing to accept the restrictions imposed by risk poli-
cies, giving rise to the phenomenon of rogue trader. A recent example is Jérôme Kerviel’s
liberal interpretation of ‘low-risk arbitrage’ causing a €4.91 billion loss to his employer,
Société Générale, possibly costing him three years in prison. This may be the largest loss
attributed to a rogue trader.
154
9.2 Trading and risk
actively involved in the market for most other financial assets. Banks are engaged in trad-
ing on behalf of their clients, but also often trade on their own account, termed propri-
etary trading, or prop trading in short. This is done with the explicit purpose of making
profit by taking on risk – that is, speculating.
While some market participants are engaged in proprietary trading, most act instead on
behalf of investors like pension funds, insurance companies, mutual funds and sovereign
wealth funds. Investors often choose to subcontract investment decisions to those market
participants, not exerting direct control over investment decisions but usually monitoring
investment performance by various means, such as comparison with a benchmark, which
might be a stock market index. This is often referred to as the ‘institutionalisation’ of the
market. A large number of different investment schemes are on offer, and relatively unso-
phisticated investors can find it rather hard to evaluate the different options. This means
there is an obvious risk of fraud or misrepresentation, or even Ponzi schemes. As a result,
mutual funds are highly regulated in most jurisdictions.
Hedge funds
An important category of financial institution is hedge funds which exist in some markets
influenced by a relatively liberal US approach to financial services. Hedge funds are less
regulated than other financial institutions, provided they sell their services only to rela-
tively sophisticated and wealthy investors, often called accredited investors.
It is sometimes said that hedge funds are unregulated, but that is not strictly true. They
are subject to securities law, their manager is typically regulated, and all their counter-
parties such as brokers and lenders will also be regulated, so they are at least indirectly
subject to regulation.
Beyond their regulatory status and types of clients, it is very difficult to classify hedge
funds. They are extremely diverse, engaging in a large number of different trading activities,
often using very complicated trading strategies. Because of the lack of regulation, hedge funds
are able to take on risk and investment strategies not open to other market participants, per-
haps their defining characteristic. Hedge funds are designed to provide good performance to
investors, where performance fees supposedly improve the alignment of interests between
clients and manager, though how much of this gain is captured by clients is less clear.
Before 2007, most commentators on financial stability thought the next crisis would
originate in the hedge fund sector, due to the impact of the failure of LTCM in 1998.
However, the crises from 2007 instead took place in the most regulated part of the finan-
cial system, and as a consequence, concerns about hedge funds do not attract a high
priority from policymakers, except in Europe where there has recently been a wave of
regulatory initiatives aimed at the sector.
155
Chapter 9 Trading and speculation
materialised. However, as it turned out, many of the new financial instruments proved to be
quite damaging, enabling financial institutions to amass significant amounts of hidden risk.
As a consequence, some commentators have argued that financial innovation provides
no value to society whilst destabilising the financial system. Perhaps most succinctly, this
is stated as: ‘the most important financial innovation that I have seen in the past 20 years
is the automatic teller machine’ (Paul Volcker in the Wall Street Journal, 2009b). Volcker
further notes that financial innovation ‘moves around the rents in the financial system’,
benefiting the inventor, not the clients.
Value investing
A classical approach to investing is value investing, a strategy proposed by Graham and
Dodd (1934). This involves finding companies that are trading below their inherent worth,
by finding stocks with strong fundamentals, like earnings, dividends, book value and cash
flow. The most successful investor of all times, Warren Buffett, follows value investing.
Value is an example of a mean reversion trade, where assets are bought when prices have
fallen and sold when prices have risen. As such, under normal conditions, when prices move
within their typical ranges, value investing has a stabilising effect on prices, increasing demand
when they are low and reducing it when high. In extreme conditions, however, this may not
be the case, because value investors are likely to take severe losses and may be forced to liqui-
date portfolios, in a firesale. Value investors stabilise prices only when they are making money.
156
9.3 Trading activities
that is subject to the least amount of scrutiny. We will see many examples later in the
book of how this might done in practice and the consequences it has had.
145
135
125
115
Feb Mar Apr May Jun Jul Aug Sep Oct
Feedback effects
When carry traders are borrowing the low interest rate currency and buying the high inter-
est rate currency, it is likely to lead to the appreciation of the latter. Initially the effects
may not be particularly apparent, as positions are likely to increase gradually, but the
price impact becomes stronger with time.
157
Chapter 9 Trading and speculation
However, it is quite likely at some point that traders will realise the currency has appreci-
ated too much, causing them to rapidly unwind their positions. The rapidity is self-generating
because unwinding increases losses, leading to a currency crash. This results in a weakening
of the high-interest currency, which in itself is an incentive for other traders to unwind their
positions. If everyone tries to unwind at the same time, the high-interest currency is sold into
a falling market, creating an adverse endogenous risk feedback loop, shown in Figure 9.2. It
is sometimes said that the prices go up by the escalator and down by the elevator (lift).
These effects were formally modelled by Morris and Shin (1998, 1999) in their global
games model, showing that speculators have incentives to wait until the last minute to
exit the trade, but no longer. If a trader exits too early, she will lose money, and also if she
exits too late. This leads to herd behaviour among speculators, caused by strategic com-
plementarities. We present their model in detail in Chapter 12, Section 12.5.
Dollar
weakens
Unwind
carry trade
Contagion
Hungary New Zealand
Ma
ZD
rg
ll N
in
c
Se
all
Crisis
Hedge fund
158
9.3 Trading activities
This has happened several times, for example, in February 2006 when a mini-crisis in
Iceland adversely affected the exchange rates of several countries such as Hungary, New
Zealand and South Africa.
159
Chapter 9 Trading and speculation
anybody else. As legend has it, he was able to profit from the defeat of Napoleon at Waterloo
in 1815 because his pigeons brought the first news of the defeat to the City. Other technolo-
gies, such as post riders, semaphore and the telegraph, have served the same purpose.
Since the 1970s, high-speed computers, data networks and algorithmic trading have
become the main tools for gaining trading advantages. Today, computer algorithms
directly interface with trading platforms and place orders without immediate human
intervention, and are now the biggest generator of trading volume. As a consequence,
policymakers have become quite worried about the potential for systemic risk arising from
computer-based trading (CBT), especially after the Flash Crash of 2010.
‘These trades occurred as a result of so-called stub quotes, which are quotes gen-
erated by market makers . . . at levels far away from the current market in order
to fulfil continuous two-sided quoting obligations even when a market maker has
withdrawn from active trading.’
(Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) and
Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC) report)
The causes of the flash crash remain controversial. A joint report by the SEC and
the CFTC in September 2010 blames a fragmented and fragile market, where a sin-
gle institution selling a large number of so-called E-Mini S&Ps, that is a stock market
index futures contract on the S&P-500 index, exhausted available buyers.
The crisis quickly spilled over from the futures markets into equities markets. As
trading systems detected the large volumes and price drops, many HFTs then exited
160
9.3 Trading activities
10800
10600
10400
10200
10000
40 105
30 104
20
103
10
102
0
14:45 14:50 14:55 15:00 14:45 14:50 14:55 15:00
(a) Accenture transaction prices (b) Sotheby’s transaction prices
1400
1200
1000
800
600
400
200
0
10:00 11:00 12:00 13:00 14:00 15:00 16:00
(c) Accenture number of trades
1000
800
600
400
200
0
10:00 11:00 12:00 13:00 14:00 15:00 16:00
(d) Sotheby’s number of trades
from the market. The official report finds that the crash eventually stopped when the
Chicago Mercantile Exchange implemented automatic stabilisers, pausing trading.
That enabled market participants to react, verify prices and the system, leading the
market to recover quickly. This chain of events is typical of endogenous risk.
The official conclusion remains controversial, and many commentators have disa-
greed with both the assumptions and the conclusions.
161
Chapter 9 Trading and speculation
Analysis
The speed of trading may make it easier for anomalous outcomes and asynchronicities
between different markets to self-correct, compared to human-only trading. Therefore,
events like the 1987 crash might have been less severe if trading had been faster. The
fact that the Flash Crash played out within a single day, and high-frequency extreme
outcomes do not generally result in extreme daily outcomes, indicates that problems in
high-frequency trading (HFT) self-heal. In other words, HFT might reduce the incidence
of market crashes. However, this issue has not been well studied, and it is not obvious
whether the effects will always be benign.
The critical difference between human and automated trading systems is common
sense. Faced with a new and unexpected situation we know that traders make some deci-
sions that look strange with hindsight, but their decisions will be expressed in shades of
grey and have some guiding principles behind them. By contrast, fully automatic systems
may fail catastrophically, and because of this will often shut down entirely when market
parameters exceed those of normal conditions. The price for liquidity always increases
under extreme circumstances, but where systems are highly automated and much of the
liquidity depends on them, this tendency becomes much stronger and the price may
approach infinity for short periods, as illustrated by Figure 9.4.
In the event, the Flash Crash did not cause much damage, because the markets recov-
ered quite quickly and the crash happened early in the trading session. If, however, the
Flash Crash had happened at the end of the trading day, and the markets closed around
the lowest point, the damage could have been substantial. It would have affected any-
body using daily marking, and many traders would have been hit by margin calls. It is
possible that an endogenous risk vicious feedback loop could have set in, causing prices
to continue spiralling downwards.
sale from an asset. Both cause prices to fall. There is no reason to assign a pernicious
motive for short selling, any more than it is malicious to profit from prices increasing.
The financial crises starting in 2007 demonstrated the complacency of such attitudes.
Certain trading activities directly contributed to the crises, and policymakers ever since have
sought to develop rules that would regulate trading in a way that increases financial stability.
Bank B Bank C
Bank A Bank D
(a) Bilateral
Bank B Bank C
CCP
Bank A Bank D
(b) CCP
164
9.4 Policy issues
would be reduced. This is exactly what a central counterparty (CCP) does, because it acts
as a counterparty to each and every trade, and therefore knows all the exposures and
can net them out, as seen in Figure 9.6(b). This also solves the problem of counterparty
credit risk, provided there are no worries about the solvency of the CCP. As a side benefit,
it reduces complexity in the financial system because the CCP will prefer only a relatively
small number of standardised instruments.
Contrast the situation in which most contracts are bilateral. In this case the contracts
are likely to be customised, making it difficult to calculate aggregate positions for the
banks involved. For a third party such as a regulator it would be impossible.
Safety of CCPs
CCPs eliminate most, but not all, counterparty credit risk, because market participants
are still exposed to the credit risk of the CCP itself. The failure of a CCP would significantly
contribute to systemic risk, since a substantial part of the financial system will be directly
exposed to it. For these reasons, the CCPs need to be safest of institutions, and they usu-
ally do enjoy explicit or implicit government guarantees. CCPs have been bailed out in the
past, for example, in Hong Kong in 1987. This, however, means that the CCP is an institu-
tion that is too big to fail (TBTF), with its own attendant problems.
The need for CCP safety creates another problem, as noted by Zigrand (2010).
During a crisis, the CCP might feel compelled to sharply increase margins, in order to
protect itself, thereby transmitting problems to members. Of course, the same might
happen regardless because any counterparty in bilateral transactions might behave in
the same way. Counting the arrows in Figure 9.6, it is clear that a CCP market with N
participants has 2N margined relationships, while without a CCP there are N(N – 1)
relationships. Assuming perfect netting between partners, exactly half of these will
require margin.
In the special case where position sizes are the same in each market, and if we make the
assumption that the CCP would respond to the crisis by increasing margins by an amount
165
Chapter 9 Trading and speculation
similar to that of any other participant, the total increase in required margins will be
roughly 2/N of the size. Even if there are multiple CCPs, the pro-cyclical effect of margin
increases could be reduced by the presence of CCPs. In practice, gains will be more mod-
est, because in the CCP market the individual positions will typically be larger, and the
institution might have offsetting positions, recognised in the bilateral market but not the
CCP market, but the benefits of netting can still be significant.
Conclusion
The move towards CCPs is broadly positive, and to the extent that the various political dif-
ficulties can be overcome, would lead to a more stable financial system. However, CCPs
contribute to the commoditisation of the finance industry and will reduce profits; conse-
quently, industry opposition will be entrenched. Within the US most trading will move to
CCPs because of the Dodd–Frank Act.
Clearing houses follow recommendations made by the Bank for International
Settlements (BIS) in 2004, and the ongoing crisis has triggered a review of those stand-
ards. It is likely that CCPs will be required to further boost their financial safeguards, espe-
cially given their renewed importance.
9.4.2 Bonuses
A particular issue that has become quite controversial recently is bank bonuses. Bank
employees are amongst the most highly compensated individuals in the world, enjoy-
ing bonuses that in theory are connected to their individual profitability, their division
or bank.
In most cases, those engaged in trading for somebody else are incentivised by perfor-
mance bonuses, so that when they achieve high returns they share in the profits, but if
profits are low, or losses incurred, the trader receives only regular income. While this does
incentivise good performance and risk-taking, it does create certain problems, related
to the issue of incentives of guaranteed intermediaries discussed later in Section 14.7, as
both payoff structures have a similar option-like structure.
Perhaps the main problem is that the trader shares in the profits but not the losses. In
other words, the risk-return profile is asymmetric. This means that an individual trader
might be quite content taking significant amounts of risk; if the bet turns out well, she
will get large bonuses, but otherwise her employer fails. While that might not be the
type of risk profile her superiors, shareholders, supervisors and other stakeholders desire,
she is the one making the trading decisions. See Macrae and Watkins (1998) for more on
these issues.
Various stakeholders might want to prevent such excessive risk-taking, employing many
layers of controls intended to restrain risk. Management typically restricts traders in the
types of securities they may trade, the level of risk anticipated, and the amount of capital
employed. Senior management will impose similar restrictions on divisions, and regula-
tors on banks. Despite all these many-layered restrictions, in practice, it can be difficult
to contain risk-taking. Trading strategies are often very complicated and it may be impos-
sible for any outsider to make sense of what is happening. In addition, the trader has an
166
9.4 Policy issues
167
Chapter 9 Trading and speculation
bonuses are to be limited by law. A new rule, from the European Parliament, applies
to senior employees of EU-based banks anywhere in the world as well as to EU-based
staff of non-European banks. This covers all forms of bonuses, where the ratio of bonuses
to salary will be limited to 1:1. This would have several different implications: we
could expect base salaries to increase, non-European banks to move trading activities
away from the Union, and traders to resign from European banks and move out of the
Union.
If we could assume that funding for their activities (and hence the risk) would actually
move with them, it could then make banking safer within the EU, provided that all core
banking activities actually remained onshore and European governments did not sim-
ply find themselves obliged to bail out foreign banks. The extensive support provided by
the Federal Reserve System (Fed) to foreign banks, like Royal Bank of Scotland (RBS) and
HSBC, discussed later in Section 14.5.1 is an interesting precedent.
Such initiatives also raise employees’ incentives to gain and retain a bank job, while
reducing the optionality that incentivises risk-taking. However, other distortions are
introduced. For example, there are indications that basic salaries in banking are sharply
increasing from their already high levels. This improves the industry’s position in the com-
petition for new graduates, to the detriment of other employers like regulators and the
non-financial industry.
Initiatives
It is therefore not surprising that several initiatives aiming at preventing excessive risk-
taking in banks have been launched by various policymakers. For example, the US, as a
part of the Dodd–Frank Act, has proposed the so-called Volcker Rule, named after a former
governor of the Fed, Paul Volcker, aimed at restricting commercial banks from engaging in
proprietary trading.
168
9.4 Policy issues
Tobin tax
A specific example of an anti-speculative FTT is the Tobin tax, as proposed by the econo-
mist James Tobin in 1972, which is a uniform worldwide tax on spot currency transactions.
He argued that, designed correctly, the tax would cushion exchange rate fluctuations
by penalising short-term financial capital flows and ‘throw some sand in the wheels of
super-efficient financial markets and create room for differences in domestic interest
rates, thus enabling national monetary policy to respond to domestic macroeconomic
needs’ (Tobin, 1996). He further claimed that such a tax could strengthen the weight of
fundamentals on exchange rates, diminish excess volatility and expand the autonomy of
national monetary policies.
1
bankingcommission.independent.gov.uk.
169
Chapter 9 Trading and speculation
Given the large trading volumes in foreign exchange markets, estimated by the BIS to
be $4 trillion per day in April 2010, even a very small tax rate might be expected to bring
in significant revenue. That is not true, however, because trading volumes would probably
collapse as a consequence of the tax.
The main argument against the Tobin tax is that for it to be effective, it needs to be
introduced in every financial centre, otherwise foreign exchange trading would move to
the areas where the tax has not been implemented. It is hard to know how serious this
problem would be, because there are significant costs in relocating and such offshore
activities would still need to interact with the taxed onshore sector.
It might be harder to prevent the migration of trading to derivative contracts, beyond
the control of the authorities. For example, if a bank sells beef for pounds and buys a
matching quantity of beef for dollars, it has entered into two livestock contracts, not for-
eign exchange (FX) contracts, yet has still contrived to exchange dollars for pounds. There
are myriad similar ways to mask the true nature of financial transactions.
FTT in Europe
As a part of its post-crisis regulatory reform agenda, the EU proposed a FTT in 2011 to
take effect in 2014. This would affect financial transactions between financial institu-
tions, taxed at 0.1% for shares and bonds and 0.01% for derivative contracts. The FTT
has met significant opposition, especially by the UK, the Netherlands and Sweden, and
there have been proposals to apply it only to the euro zone. At the time of writing, it is
unclear what the final outcome will be. Some states, including Germany and especially
France, are implementing a unilateral FTT regime, which will provide interesting experi-
mental data.
170
Appendix: Basic terminology of trading
9.5 Summary
Speculation and trading is an essential part of the financial system. They provide key ser-
vices to economic agents, but also have the potential for destabilising financial markets
and even causing crises.
Trading scandals of various types are common, such as the case of JP Morgan Chase
and the London whale, the LIBOR price-fixing scandal, Ponzi schemes like the Madoff
scandal, and rogue traders.
There are many categories of market participants, for example proprietary traders who
aim to generate trading profits for their employer. Most market participants act on behalf
of investors, a part of the institutionalisation of dishonesty markets. Perhaps the most
controversial market participants are hedge funds.
Financial institutions have been very active in financial innovation, the creation
of various types of new financial instruments, but this remains quite contentious,
and some respected commentators claim that financial innovation benefits only the
inventors.
Trading involves various types of activities like value investing, technical trading
and momentum trading, but also carry trading which has frequently been blamed for
undermining government policy. Perhaps the most controversial trading strategy is
short selling.
Following the crisis from 2007, there have been various initiatives aiming at curbing
perceived abuses in the financial system. These include protecting us from casino bank-
ing, limiting bonuses and taxing trading.
2 This is followed by a process called clearing that involves the exchange of information,
regulatory reporting and various other activities that must take place before a transaction
can be completed.
3 The last stage, the actual exchange of money, securities or goods, is called settlement.
While some trading takes place in a formal venue called an exchange, most trad-
ing bypasses exchanges, and takes place over-the-counter in a bilateral deal between
counterparties.
171
Chapter 9 Trading and speculation
For example, on organised exchanges, market makers are often permitted to acquire
stock for the purpose of later selling it to meet anticipated customer demand.
Clearing and settlement involve procedures meant to reduce the risk to each party that
the other party will fail to complete the transaction as agreed, that is counterparty risk.
These activities are often concentrated in an institution called a clearing house.
Definition 9.4 Clearing house A clearing house is a firm that sits in between buyers
and sellers, acting as a counterparty for each, and also clearing trades, that is taking care
of the movements of assets and money. They net trades among their members, manage
collateral before facilitating payment and delivery at the settlement date, and take care of
the various accounting details. See Figure 9.7 for the various steps.
Definition 9.5 Netting Netting means that we consider the net amounts owed by
two counterparties, not the gross amounts. For example, if party A owes B $10 million, and
B owes A $11 million, the gross amount is $21 and the net amount $1 million.
A clearing house may act as a CCP in a particular market. In order to be included in a CCP,
it is necessary for a security to be standardised.
Assets Assets
Clearing
Seller Buyer
house
Money Money
Collateral
management, move
money and assets,
accounting,
regulations, netting,
reporting
172
References
4 Carry trades
(a) What are carry trades?
(b) Are speculative activities such as carry trades beneficial or not to the economy?
(c) How can carry trades be vehicles for contagion?
6 What are the main arguments in favour and against curbing high-frequency trading?
7 What is the main contribution of CCPs, and how could they increase financial instability?
References
BBC (2012b). Barclays’ widening Libor-fixing scandal. www.bbc.co.uk/news/business-18671255.
Danielsson, J. and Keating, C. (2009). Bonus incensed. Vox EU, 25 May. http://voxeu.org/index.
php?q=node/3602.
Duffie, D. and Zhu, H. (2011). Does a central clearing counterparty reduce counterparty risk?
Stanford University Working Paper.
Financial Services Authority (2009a). Reforming remuneration practices in financial services.
Technical report.
Financial Services Authority (2012). Final notice. Technical report www.fsa.gov.uk/static/pubs/
final/barclays-jun12.pdf.
Financial Times (2010b). HSBC in clearest warning over relocation. Financial Times, 3 September.
www.ft.com/cms/s/0/5e0ba186-b6bd-11df-b3dd-00144feabdc0.html#axzz1zsbIzMf.
Financial Times (2012a). DoJ probes $2bn JPMorgan trading loss. Financial Times, 15 May. www.
ft.com/cms/s/0/39133792-9e9f-11e1-9cc8-00144feabdc0.html#axzz1x8DGs4zP.
Financial Times (2012b). JPMorgan whale harpooned. Financial Times, 11 May. ftalphaville.
ft.com/blog/2012/ 05/10/995211/jpmorgan-whale-harpooned/.
Graham, B. and Dodd, D. (1934). Security Analysis. Whittlesey House (McGraw-Hill).
Hull, J. C. (2011). Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 8th edition. Prentice Hall.
Kohn, M. (2003). Financial Institutions and Markets, 2nd edition. Oxford University Press.
Leeson, N. (1999). Rogue Trader. Sphere, London.
Liikanen, E. (2012). High-level expert group on reforming the structure of the EU banking sec-
tor. Technical report, European Union.
173
Chapter 9 Trading and speculation
174
10 Credit markets
The most important financial products are fixed income assets, composed of various
credit instruments, like bonds, structured credit products and credit derivatives. The
reason is that credit is an absolute necessity for the modern economy, allowing peo-
ple to save for retirement and get mortgages, governments to finance their operations
and stimulate the economy in recessions, and private companies to finance opera-
tions and expansions.
Of the fixed income assets, the most important are bonds. Financial institutions,
corporations and governments depend on bonds for financing, and any problems in
accessing the bond markets can quickly cause significant difficulties. That means the
bond markets exert significant power over borrowers. Perhaps the best expression of
their power was by a Bill Clinton strategist, James Carville, who said that he wanted
to be reborn as the bond market because it is the most powerful force in the universe.
Currently, some European governments are facing the wrath of the bond markets.
Investors in fixed income markets are often faced with borrowers of an unknown
quality and need some mechanisms to ascertain the credit quality, and monitor bor-
rower performance. The most common way to achieve this is by using credit ratings
issued by credit rating agencies (CRAs). These are private companies whose business it
is to report on credit quality.
Trying to forecast credit risk is difficult in the best of times and the CRAs have been
under almost constant criticism for the quality of ratings and the impact downgrades
have on borrowers. As a result, there are frequent calls for reforms of the credit rating
business, but it is not obvious how that could be accomplished.
Chapter 10 Credit markets
We can also use various types of mathematical credit models to forecast credit risk.
Of these credit models, the so-called reduced form models are particularly useful
when it comes to mapping between the probability of default and credit spreads.
Key concepts
■ Fixed income
■ Margins and haircuts
■ Credit rating
■ Reduced form credit models
■ Spreads
■ Securitisation
1
See www.imf.org/external/data.htm, www.bis.org/statistics/secstats.htm, www.sifma.org/research/statistics
.aspx and www.world-exchanges.org/statistics.
176
10.1 Market for credit
40
Government
30 Financial institutions
Corporate issuers
20
10
0
1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010
(a) Domestic
20
Government
15 Financial institutions
10 Corporate issuers
5
0
1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011
(b) International
177
Chapter 10 Credit markets
Domestic International
P = a
T ct
t=1
11 + rt2t
178
10.2 Credit rating agencies
happen because of a downgrade causing bond prices to fall in price, the failure of a bor-
rower to make payments, changes in the probability that payments will not be made or will
be delayed, changes in interest rates, or the amount of money recovered in case of default.
The two key terms to note are opinion and creditworthiness. CRAs do not provide advice,
only opinion. There is an important legal difference between those terms, because advice
implies an obligation to be right, while opinion does not. It is therefore easier to challenge
advice in a court of law than it is to challenge opinion.
The CRAs are generally considered to have considerable expertise in credit risk and are
regarded by many as unbiased evaluators of such risk. As a consequence, their ratings are
widely accepted by both market participants and government agencies, and many inves-
tors are restricted to hold only rated instruments.
Ratings
Ratings take the form of a letter grade, as shown in Table 10.2 where we show ratings from
both S&P and Moody’s. For S&P the highest rating is AAA, followed by AAA-, AA+ all the
way down to default. Moody’s has a similar arrangement, but note that ratings from two
different agencies are not directly comparable, even if we broadly expect them to provide
similar information.
179
Chapter 10 Credit markets
Spreads
The yield curve is a curve showing several yields or interest rates across different maturi-
ties, that is, the time at which the payment is due. Each debt issue has its own yield curve,
determined by its credit rating. The difference in the yields for different ratings is called a
spread. The lower the credit rating, the higher the yield. We show in Figure 10.2 a typical
term structure for bonds of different rating categories.
180
10.2 Credit rating agencies
5.3%
5.2%
Yield
5.1% C AA
5.0% B Risk free
5 10 15 20
Time to maturity in years
Conflict of interest
Ratings are generally solicited and paid for by the issuer of debt and not the investor.
Good ratings enhance the marketability of debt issues, enabling issuers to place debt
more easily at lower interest rates. The prospect of bad ratings may cause an issuer not to
go ahead, thus depriving CRAs of substantial fees. This leads to the perception that the
181
Chapter 10 Credit markets
CRAs are too willing to provide good ratings in order to generate fee income. The agencies
strongly reject the possibility of any conflict of interest.
However, in a world where issuers can go ratings shopping, that is, talk to several CRAs
before picking one to rate an issue, worries about conflict of interest are unlikely to disap-
pear. These problems have become especially pertinent following the crises from 2007
because of how banks were able to use the ratings models to structure credit products.
We discuss that topic in detail later in the book.
182
10.3 Credit models
More recently, the US and European authorities have been encouraging the creation of
new CRAs, and we can expect new CRAs in the future, including some that charge buyers,
not issuers.
Legal protection
Given the importance of CRAs, it is no surprise that they are frequently sued by aggra-
vated investors. However, in the US, they have consistently maintained that they are no
different from financial journalists offering opinions, thus getting protection from the First
Amendment to the US constitution – free speech. This would make them different from
consultants and auditors who have a contractual obligation to provide a correct opinion,
given the facts available to them at the time.
The CRAs have until now prevailed in US courts, but changes in law may alter that.
Furthermore, no such protection of free speech exists in Europe so they need different
legal protection there.
This leaves the question of whether the CRAs should be held legally accountable for
inaccurate ratings. While it might seem just that investors be able to sue them for dam-
ages, the end result would only be that the expected cost of damages be built into their
fee structure. Since any damages would probably be substantial, the cost of ratings would
increase significantly. It is not clear if that would be of benefit to investors.
Furthermore, in a world where two agencies have 80% of the market it would be dif-
ficult to punish either severely, because that might force it to leave the business, leaving
only one major CRA. The case where the accounting firm Arthur Andersen had to close
down following its mistakes with Enron serves as a cautionary tale.
Solution
While it is not feasible to do away with the ratings agencies altogether, nor would it be
sensible to substantially restructure the existing ones, there are several steps that could
be taken to minimise the problems created by ratings agencies. It would be of significant
benefit to encourage competition in the ratings business, to try to move away from a
model whereby the issuer pays for the ratings, and finally to reduce the impact of CRAs in
financial regulations. Some steps have been taken in these directions, but it remains to be
seen how effective they will be.
183
Chapter 10 Credit markets
contingent claims against the firm’s assets, where a default occurs whenever the firm’s
asset value falls below the debt value. A key advantage of this approach is that the prob-
ability of default and recovery rates is directly related to firm-specific characteristics.
However, a disadvantage is that asset values are not directly observable and may be dif-
ficult to estimate.
We therefore get:
Note here that the pd is the cumulative risk-neutral probability of default: if T = 2, then
pd gives the probability of default in two years, not the conditional probability of default,
which is the probability of default occurring in year 2 given no default in year 1. Since the
credit spread is defined as s = r - rf , we can substitute to get:
1 - pd + pdz = e - sT
Therefore
1 - e - sT
pd =
1 - z
184
10.4 Margins, haircuts and mark-to-market
Haircuts
Haircuts are intimately related to initial margins. When securities are pledged as collateral
for a transaction, only a portion of the current market value counts as a pledge, with the
rest termed a haircut. Used this way, the haircut serves the same function as initial margins.
185
Chapter 10 Credit markets
The term haircut has other related meanings, such as indicating losses to bondhold-
ers in credit restructuring. For example, when discussing the losses facing the owners of
Greek sovereign debt, the term used is a haircut.
Leverage
Haircuts and margins are directly related to leverage. In particular, the inverse of the haircut
or initial margin shows implied leverage. Suppose a trader enters into a financial transac-
tion, buying a security for $100 million, posting a 25% initial margin and borrowing the rest
from her broker. Therefore, the trader uses $25 million of her own money and $75 million
borrowed from her broker. The trader has therefore leveraged her $25 million three times.
Data source: Financial Stress and Deleveraging Macrofinancial Implications and Policy, Global Financial Stability
Report, p. 42 (Citigroup and IMF staff estimates 2008), International Monetary Fund
186
10.4 Margins, haircuts and mark-to-market
Mark-to-model or magic
A requirement for marking-to-market can cause particular problems when assets are illiq-
uid because in that case there may not be a proper market price or, even if a market price
were available, it would change if the firm bought the asset. In these conditions, firms
may have to resort to marking-to-model, by using an internal pricing model to get valua-
tions. This became common practice in the crises from 2007 for many structured credit
products. The obvious problem is that no model is correct, and some are particularly bad.
As a result, it is sometimes said that marking-to-market really means marking-to-magic
because the dependence on untestable assumptions is so strong.
187
Chapter 10 Credit markets
10.5 Securitisation
New fixed income assets are often created out of other fixed income assets in a financial
practice called securitisation. Securitisation has long been a common practice in financial
markets, often resulting in useful products, and is not itself problematic. Such views have
changed following the crisis of 2007 because of the role played by securitisation in the
shadow banking system, which undermined financial regulations prior to the crisis.
Some of the clearest examples of this are the failure of Northern Rock in the UK in 2007
and the subprime mortgage crisis in the US.
Securitisation is where various types of credit assets are pooled together and sold in
various forms to creditors. Common examples of credit assets include credit card debt,
car loans and mortgages. Securitisation is often related to what is known as the originate
and distribute model of banking, whereby a bank specialises in lending and then sells off
a portfolio of loans on the secondary market.
Securitisation has long been a feature of financial markets and throughout his-
tory various forms of securitisation have been used. For example, a particular securiti-
sation instrument called a covered bond, or Pfandbriefe in German, was first created in
nineteenth-century Germany and has been in use ever since. A more recent example is
the US government creating a government-sponsored entity called Fannie Mae whose
purpose is to create a liquid secondary market for mortgages.
Mechanics of securitisation
While there are many different ways to design structured products, a common way is to
pool assets that pay cash regularly in a reasonably predictable manner, put them into a
special purpose vehicle (SPV) and sell rights to the cash flow.
Definition 10.1 Special purpose vehicle A special purpose vehicle (SPV), also
known as a special purpose entity, is a legal entity, usually a limited company or limited
partnership, set up for specific, narrow and often temporary purposes. They might, for
example, be used to isolate a firm from risk or to hide ownership. SPVs can be very useful, but
can also be used for more nefarious reasons, such as Enron’s use of them to commit fraud.
Definition 10.2 Sponsor The financial institution that sets up the SPV is known as a
sponsor. It chooses the assets and engages a manager, and may provides guarantees to it. It
is the owner of the SPV and often retains an equity position.
188
10.5 Securitisation
Fees
Rating
agencies
Interest &
Borrow Sell to Sells to principal
Insurance
companies
Premiums
In securitisation, the sponsor sets up an SPV which often buys assets already held
by the sponsor, perhaps financing the purchase by issuing bonds to outside investors.
Typically, the value of the bonds is lower than the value of the assets, with the difference
being equity contributed by the sponsor. The bonds are known as asset backed securities
(ABSs) since the bonds are backed by the underlying assets. Additional protection may be
provided by equity and junior tranches.
Figure 10.3 shows a typical securitisation process, the players involved and the flow of
funds. The process starts by a homeowner borrowing from a mortgage originator. After the
mortgage originator has accumulated enough mortgages, it sells them to an investment
bank that intends to package them into a structured credit product.
The investment bank creates an SPV out of the mortgages it bought, and sells the rights
to the payment flow to investors. The bank then pays fees to CRAs to obtain ratings to
reassure the investors, and may pay premiums to insurance companies to protect some
parts of the SPV.
189
Chapter 10 Credit markets
issued by the SPV. Furthermore, by creating a separate SPV, the firm isolates the cash flow
generating assets and collateral so that securities issued by the SPV are not a general claim
against the company, just against those assets.
The obvious reason to securitise assets is to transfer risk. In the originate and distribute
model of banking, securitisation frees up capital and funding, allowing the firm to lend
again. Securitisation allows banks to provide more and cheaper credit than they other-
wise could, lowering the total cost of financing loans.
Investors also benefit in that securitisation allows them to invest in otherwise inac-
cessible assets, which is desirable for diversification purposes. For example, if you want
to have some exposure to Japanese retail credit risk, without securitisation you would
need a presence in Japan, advertising, regulatory approvals and so on. But if a Japanese
bank securitises its credit card portfolio, then a Western investor can get access to this
class of investment without the costs associated with opening a credit company in
Japan.
Securitisation also allows for increasing specialisation in the financial system. One can
separate what used to be one process in traditional banking into multiple different steps.
For example, the origination of loans might be done by those specialising in local markets
but not rich in capital. Borrowers get better terms and access to lending than they would
get otherwise.
These loans are then sold on to investment banks with specialised skills in packaging
loans and the necessary capital to buy them off the originators. Finally, the packaged
loans can be split up into different risk categories, so that the risk can be precisely tar-
geted at those who most desire it and will pay the most to get it.
Drawbacks
While the seller of portfolios of mortgages or credit card receivables might benefit
from getting rid of the risk, the buyers of the loans face a ‘lemons’ problem2 because
the originators are likely to be better informed about the loans than the sellers and,
therefore, may be tempted to securitise the lowest-quality loans and hold on to the
better loans.
This directly relates to moral hazard because if a seller is not intending to hold the loan
for more than a few months, it may care less about credit quality than if it held the loan
until maturity. This was exactly the key problem in the market for subprime mortgages
prior to the crises from 2007: the lenders did not care much about mortgage quality, as
noted for example by Bitner (2008).
Securitisation also carries with it risk for the sellers. In the case of Northern Rock, the
bank was dependent on securitisation, and when it encountered difficulties in placing its
mortgage portfolios on the secondary markets, it collapsed.
2
The term lemon problem relates to a famous paper by Akerlof (1970) on asymmetric information. In Ameri-
can English a lemon is a dodgy used car.
190
References
10.6 Summary
The credit markets are fundamental to the functioning of modern economies, channel-
ling savings to productive investments. In order to lend money, investors like to know the
credit risk of their counterparties. The most common way to do that is by using ratings
from CRAs. These are controversial, with many critics claiming that ratings quality is low.
An alternative way to access credit quality is by using mathematical models, such as
structural models and reduced form models. The latter are especially useful in allowing
for a conversion from spreads to probabilities of default.
Fixed income assets are often used as inputs into new assets, generally called struc-
tured credit. This is a long-established practice in financial markets, providing useful ben-
efits to market participants, but can also be abused. Such products were at the heart of
the crisis from 2007.
Margins and haircuts provide useful information to investors, but can increase financial
instability when used in a mechanistic fashion.
Securitisation, whereby different fixed income instruments are packaged together and
sold as one, is an old financial technique, dating back to the nineteenth century. When
used properly, it can increase the efficiency of financial markets, but when misused may
cause moral hazard and even crises.
References
Akerlof, G. (1970). The market for ‘lemons’: quality uncertainty and the market mechanism.
Quart. J. Econ., 84(3): 488–500.
Bitner, R. (2008). Confessions of a Subprime Lender: An Insider’s Tale of Greed, Fraud, and
Ignorance. John Wiley & Sons.
191
Chapter 10 Credit markets
Black, F. and Scholes, M. (1973a). The pricing of options and corporate liabilities. J. Polit. Econ.,
81(3): 637–54.
Fabozzi, F. J. (2009). Bond Markets, Analysis, and Strategies, 7th edition. Pearson.
Hull, J. C. (2011). Options, Futures, and other Derivatives, 8th edition. Prentice Hall.
Hull, J. C. (2012). Risk Management and Financial Institutions, 3rd edition. Prentice Hall.
International Monetary Fund (2008). Global financial stability report: containing systemic risks
and restoring financial soundness. April 2008, pp. 1–211.
Merton, R. C. (1974). On the pricing of corporate debt: the risk structure of interest rates.
J. Finance, 29: 449–70.
Murphy, D. (2009). Unravelling the Credit Crunch. CRC Press.
Washington Post (2004). Credit raters’ power leads to abuses, some borrowers say. Washington
Post, 24 November. www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/articles/A8032-2004Nov23.html.
192
11 Currency markets
No financial market sees more government intervention than the foreign exchange (FX)
market. After all, every economy is sensitive to the exchange rate and policymakers
often want exchange rates to reflect the underlying economic fundamentals, because
misalignments and excessive exchange rate volatilities imply significant economic costs.
Every government needs to decide on what type of exchange rate regime it wants,
ranging from letting its currency float freely, to various ways it can tie the currency to
that of another country, all the way to joining a currency union. However, determin-
ing an exchange rate regime is not a trivial proposition. Leave it to the market, and the
result may be FX volatility. Leave it to the government, and the outcome may be mis-
alignment and currency crisis. Choosing a sensible exchange rate regime is hard, and
governments are sometimes guided by wishful thinking and blind pursuit of outdated
goals, perhaps only wanting to replace the existing arrangement.
A key reason why governments find it so hard to manage their exchange rates is
because of the size of the FX market, as it has more trading volume than any other
financial market – see Figure 11.1.
Volume in the FX market has increased rapidly, from $1.5 trillion per day in 1998
to $4 trillion in 2010, or around one quadrillion dollars per year. The most actively
traded currency is USD, involved in 42% of all trades. This is not surprising given the
reserve currency status of the dollar. Because the dollar is so liquid, most currency
pairs do not trade bilaterally; for example, going from the Malaysian ringgit to the
Hungarian forint would probably involve a detour to the dollar. The dollar is followed
by the euro, the yen and sterling. Surprisingly, even though China is the second larg-
est economic area in the world, its currency constitutes only 0.15% of trading. This is
Chapter 11 Currency markets
4
2007
3
2010
2
1
0
Total Spot Forwards Swaps Options ETD
(a) Daily volume by instrument, USD trillions. ETD = exchange-traded derivatives
HKD
CAD
SRF
AUS
GBP
Yen
Euro
USD
40% 1998
30% 2010
20%
10%
0%
UK US Japan Singapore Switz. Hong Kong
(c) Relative volume of trade by country where trade takes place
Figure 11.1 Bank for International Settlements (BIS) survey of the FX market
Data source: BIS triannual survey of the FX market: www.bis.org/publ/rpfx10.htm
because the Chinese government actively discourages currency trading and employs
capital controls.
At least 92% of FX trading involves the currencies of large developed economies,1 with
the rest mostly smaller developed economies or larger stable developing economies.
The FX market has no single physical location, and instead takes place on computer sys-
tems. However, the individual traders and banks do have a physical location and the main
geographic centre of FX trading is London, making up 37% of the global total trading vol-
ume, a number that has been steadily increasing; in 1995 it was 29%. This is not that sur-
prising, since trading is concentrated in the largest financial centres and large volumes in
one geographical area attract traders, further increasing volume. There are many reasons
for this, for example, the supply of specialised human resources and technical support.
1
In the order of volume: USD, euro, Japanese yen, pound sterling, Australian dollar, Swiss franc, Canadian
dollar, Hong Kong dollar, Swedish krona, New Zealand dollar, Norwegian krone and Danish krone.
194
11.1 Fixed or floating
The daily FX turnover dwarfs the underlying economic activities. The International
Monetary Fund (IMF) found the world’s GDP in 2010 to be $63 trillion and the World
Trade Organization (WTO) global trade to be $18.5 trillion. In other words, the global
trade in goods and services is only around 1.85% of the global trade in FX. It follows
that the bulk of the activity in FX markets is due to speculation, the buying or selling
of currencies solely to profit from anticipated changes in exchange rates, by means
of high frequency trading (HFT), exploiting arbitrage between currencies (triangular
arbitrage) and prices on different trading platforms.
Key concepts
■ Currency regimes
■ Capital controls
■ Bretton Woods
■ Gold standard
■ Reserve currency
■ Sterilisation
195
Chapter 11 Currency markets
196
11.2 Foreign exchange interventions
Furthermore, floating exchange rates might not be any more unstable than fixed
exchange rates; one is more likely to see more gradual adjustment in floating rate regimes
rather than the sudden and sharp jumps resulting from devaluations in fixed regimes.
Floating regimes might have higher volatility but fixed regimes bigger jumps.
Perhaps the main argument in favour of a flexible exchange rate is that it allows for an
independent monetary policy, enabling the government to respond to economic con-
cerns more easily. As a consequence, floating rate regimes might be less crisis prone than
fixed rate regimes. Furthermore, since differences in national inflation rates and price lev-
els are more likely to be directly reflected in the exchange rate, floating rate countries are
less likely to have an under- or overvalued currency for longer periods.
Conclusion
Both sets of arguments have compelling elements. Over time, countries have alternated
from one arrangement to another, usually not satisfied with their choice. The ultimate
conclusion seems to be that no exchange rate regime is perfect; governments are quite
willing to experiment with a new arrangement, as the large number of regimes discussed
in the appendix bear witness to.
Most, if not all, governments, however, take the view that at least some interventions
in the FX market are necessary. Whilst academic economists are often vocal in their oppo-
sition to FX interventions, those actually in charge disagree.
Mechanics of interventions
Denote the exchange rate by e, which is the amount of domestic currency per unit of
foreign currency, and the interest rate by i. Denote foreign variables by *. It is common to
assume the foreign country is the United States, since it has the reserve currency. Suppose
a central bank decides to fix its exchange rate (peg) at level e. The FX market is in equi-
librium when the uncovered interest rate parity (UIP) condition holds, meaning that the
domestic interest rate equals the foreign interest rate plus the expected movement in the
exchange rate:
it = it* + Et - 1 ∆et
Et - 1 ∆et = 0
Given that investors are not expecting any changes in the exchange rate because of
the peg, they are only willing to hold the foreign and domestic currency if they offer the
197
Chapter 11 Currency markets
same interest rate. To ensure equilibrium in the FX market, the central bank must set
it = it*.
That imposes a particular restriction on the central bank. When it intervenes by print-
ing money, it would normally affect interest rates, but they must not change. Hence, the
bank needs to adjust the money supply in order to keep the interest rates constant. In
other words, it sterilises the intervention. This eliminates any independence or discretion
that the central bank has over the money supply and therefore over monetary policy,
leading to the ‘impossible trinity’ discussed in Section 11.4.3.
11.2.1 Sterilisation
When a central bank intervenes in the currency markets to prevent an appreciation of
the currency, the money supply usually increases; after all, the central bank is buying
foreign currency with freshly printed domestic money. This is, of course, inflationary, and
since the central bank may prefer to prevent the inflation, it often couples interventions
with sterilisation. Sterilisation means that the domestic money supply is held fixed, while
an unsterilised intervention is where the central bank intervenes without offsetting the
domestic money supply.
Mechanics of sterilisation
Consider the balance sheet of the central bank in Table 11.1, where it purchases $10 billion.
Step 1. The central bank purchases USD 10 billion and invests that amount in US Treas-
uries, so B* = $10 billion.
Step 2. Its liabilities (monetary base) increase by the same amount: M c by e * $10
billion.
Step 3. The central bank now sells domestic bonds by the same amount and, there-
fore, takes money out of circulation: M Te * $10 billion and B c e * $10 billion.
Step 4. After the intervention the net assets of the bank have not changed, but:
The changes in the holdings of foreign assets are offset one-for-one by the changes in
domestic asset holdings, and the purchase of foreign assets has no effect on the domestic
money supply. However, the exchange rate would probably fall because of the purchase
of foreign currency.
198
11.2 Foreign exchange interventions
Uses of sterilisation
The use of intervention to keep exchange rates low has become increasingly common in
recent years. Lavigne (2008) estimates that from the $1.3 trillion in accumulated reserves
between 2000 and 2006 in emerging markets in Asia, 75% have been sterilised. He further
finds that China has been the biggest user of sterilisation, sterilising 80% of its interven-
tion. This is in addition to using extensive capital controls, administrative controls and
regulations, and state ownership of large parts of the banking system as means to manage
the exchange rate.
Limitations
In principle, a government can intervene indefinitely to prevent appreciations; however,
its ability to sterilise the interventions depends on the central bank’s holdings of govern-
ment bonds. This is not a major problem because the government, as the owner of the
central bank, of course, can just issue new debt. This does not mean that sterilisation is
always a recommended policy when intervening.
Sterilisation is costly because the central bank acquires foreign bonds and sells domes-
tic bonds. Since the yield on foreign bonds is likely to be much lower than the yield on
domestic bonds, the difference is a cost to the central bank.
Sterilisation involves encouraging banks to accumulate government bonds and so
might be considered as a tax on banks. The banks are holding government bonds instead
of lending to private investors, potentially holding back economic growth. Finally, as the
central bank continues to intervene and sterilise, sovereign debt keeps on accumulating,
affecting the solvency of the state.
199
Chapter 11 Currency markets
Note. Belgium, Canada, Luxembourg, the Netherlands and New Zealand did not have capital controls
in the OECD’s time
Source: OECD (2002), Forty Years’ Experience with the OECD Code of Liberalisation of Capital Movements, OECD
Publishing. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264176188-en
200
11.3 Capital controls
proponent of free capital flows, with most major economies, such as that of the US, opposed.
Abdelal (2007) argues that Germany was in favour of free capital flows not least because
they saw it as a fundamental component in the establishment of a common European cur-
rency. When the French governments of the 1980s came to the German view, support for
free capital flows globally was pushed to the forefront of the Washington consensus agenda.
While many developing countries have permanent capital controls in place, the best
known and most controversial use of capital controls is in China.
This was a U-turn in Fund policy, because up until that point the IMF had been
opposed to capital controls, at least from the 1970s. This is also the first case of a
country subject to European Union (EU) rules resorting to capital controls. While
Iceland is not an EU member, it is in the European Economic Area (EEA). In order to
comply with both EEA and IMF requirements, Iceland had to impose traditional strict
capital controls, requiring Central Bank authorisation for all purchases of foreign cur-
rency, and in practice preventing foreign direct investment.
Since the crisis starting in 2007, several countries have employed various forms of 2.0
capital controls. For example, Brazil introduced a tax on financial transactions in October
2010. It is a tax of 6% on non-resident equity and debt inflows and also requires a 6%
margin payment to trade derivatives. Thailand also imposed controls in October 2010,
in the form of a withholding tax on non-resident interest income and capital gains from
state bonds. South Korea has restricted the size of the FX derivative books of its banks as a
202
11.4 Exchange rate regimes
macro-prudential measure, and imposed a 14% withholding tax and a 20% capital gains
tax on foreign purchases of government bonds.
203
Chapter 11 Currency markets
a currency union. In between those choices are the various alternatives discussed in the
appendix at the end of this chapter.
M * V = P * Q
where M is the total amount of money in circulation, V the velocity of money, P the price
level and Q an index of the real value of expenditures. Whenever goods are exported,
payment is received in gold, which can be converted into domestic currency. To pay for
imports, the importer exchanges domestic currency for gold. If a country has a trade defi-
cit, it is losing gold and, hence, prices must fall, assuming V and Q are constant. This
encourages exports and discourages imports, helping to eliminate the trade deficit. The
system self-corrects and speculation is stabilising. See Figure 11.2 for how this works.
Problem of deflation
The main downside of the gold standard is deflation. The world money supply of gold is tied
to the production of gold, and when gold discoveries are rare, the normal situation, the world
supply of gold will not increase as fast as global production and real world income, especially
204
11.4 Exchange rate regimes
Trade deficit
Pimports Pdomestic
imports exports
Trade imbalance
eliminated
in times of a booming world economy, having a strong deflationary effect. Accordingly, British
price levels fell by 18% between 1873 and 1879 and by a further 19% by 1896.
Deflation is more costly than inflation for several reasons, the most important of which
is that since interest rates cannot fall below zero, those owning money benefit from delay-
ing purchases because they know their money will be more valuable in the future.
Deflation affects agricultural producers badly. For example, a farmer with a fixed mort-
gage receives less and less money for his products and has to pay more interest in real
terms. The main agricultural exporters, like the US, Australia, Canada and Argentina, all
suffered from deflation, and were quite crisis prone as a consequence. By contrast, capital
exporters like the UK did well out of the deflation and the stability of the gold standard.
The benefits for the capital exporters were not uniformly distributed. The landed
classes who supplied the capital profited, but those working, and especially the working
class, lost out. Voting rights were restricted to property owners, so governments remained
firmly in favour of the gold standard.
Several factors contributed to the increasing instability of this system and led to its
breakdown after its reintroduction following the first World War (WWI). The introduction
of universal suffrage and the emergence of political parties representing the working class
made domestic considerations more important than maintaining convertibility.
205
Chapter 11 Currency markets
Member countries were to adopt an adjustable peg system, with capital controls,
fixing their currencies to the dollar. The dollar, in turn, was pegged to gold at a value of
$35 per ounce. Par values could be changed to correct a ‘fundamental equilibrium’, which
was to be decided by the newly created International Monetary Fund (IMF), which was
also responsible for monitoring national economic policies and could extend balance of
payment financing to countries facing problems.
The capital controls were somewhat effective, especially early on, but required extensive
regulation. When current account convertibility was reintroduced in 1959 it became easy to
avoid the capital controls.2 The adjustable peg meant, in theory, that trade deficits could be
eliminated without experiencing painful deflations. In reality, parity changes were rare as they
eroded the credibility of a central bank, and were often accompanied by a political crisis.
1 Domestic priorities had become increasingly important and led to policies that were
inconsistent with the exchange rate system.
2 The main mechanisms were not really working. Capital controls were envisaged to
allow governments to follow their own monetary policies but were difficult to enforce
since it was easy to over-invoice and under-invoice trade.
3 The final problem area was the so-called Triffin dilemma, named after the economist
Robert Triffin, who observed that the tendency for the Bretton Woods system to meet
excess demand for reserves through the growth of foreign dollar balances made it
dynamically unstable. Accumulating dollars as reserves was attractive only as long as
there was no question about their convertibility into gold. As foreign dollar balances
grew relatively large compared to the gold reserves of the US, doubts started to grow
about its commitment to convertibility. If all countries sought to convert their reserves
into gold, the US would be forced to abandon the dollar peg to gold.
This happened in the end, with a run on the dollar, because of inadequate mone-
tary and fiscal discipline in the US. Faced with high expenditure for the war in Vietnam
and an expansion of welfare programmes, the US increased spending, disregarding
the consequences on the Bretton Woods system. In the spring of 1971, flows from the
dollar to the German mark surged and Germany finally allowed the mark to float
upwards. Other countries followed. As the flight from the dollar grew stronger, the
Nixon administration finally suspended convertibility, bringing about the end of the
Bretton Woods system.
2
Current and capital account convertibility refers to the freedom to convert the local assets into foreign
assets and vice versa at an exchange rate determined by the market.
206
11.4 Exchange rate regimes
are all destabilising, and direct government intervention is needed to bring the system
under control.
Such views often seem to be based on a reinterpretation of what Bretton Woods was
rather than a call for the adoption of the particular arrangement. The Bretton Woods
system failed for particular reasons. It is not possible to maintain a fixed exchange rate
regime in a world where countries have widely differing prospects and economic policies.
Even in the relatively small world of Europe, it is proving to be quite challenging. It would
be necessary to reimpose strict capital controls, and even in that case, countries would be
subject to damaging periodic realignments.
Consequently, returning to a Bretton Woods-type arrangement for the world’s financial
system would not be a sensible response to the ongoing crisis.
At best, a country can achieve two out of the three. Suppose we start with a country in
equilibrium and with fixed exchange rates. If the country then embarks on an expansion-
ary monetary policy, or simply loses control of inflation, the money supply is increasing.
In this case, speculators can borrow the country’s currency and exchange it for foreign
money. Such a trade is likely to attract a large number of market participants. In order for
the government to maintain the exchange rate, it can either continue selling its foreign
currency reserves until they run out, at which time the exchange rate peg will collapse, or
impose capital controls.
We have seen many combinations of these policies over time as shown in Table 11.3.
During the time of the gold standard, member countries gave up independent mon-
etary policy in order to get fixed exchange rates and free capital mobility. This was the
single longest period of a stable international currency regime ever recorded. The Bretton
Woods system opted for capital controls, as did China.
Gold standard ✓ ✓ ✕
Bretton Woods ✓ ✕ ✓
China today ✓ ✕ ✓
EU/US today ✕ ✓ ✓
207
Chapter 11 Currency markets
25
20
15
10
5
0
1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005
208
11.6 Undervaluation and ‘currency wars’
The interesting part is that these losses tend to materialise mainly before the currency
collapses. The authors conclude that the economic costs of a currency collapse do not
appear to arise from the collapse of the currency itself but reflect other factors.
They find that the collapse seems to actually have positive effects on output. Output growth
tends to slow down prior to a currency crisis, with positive growth rates the norm post-crisis.
209
Chapter 11 Currency markets
Historically, one currency, or asset, tends to assume the role of a reserve currency. In the
nineteenth century it was gold and the pound sterling, but over time, the US dollar has
taken over that function.
There are significant advantages in owning a reserve currency, most importantly that
foreign countries hold it as reserves. That means foreigners have exchanged real goods for
paper, a deal which is quite good for the country with the reserve currency.
It is often argued that the fact that major products are priced in a reserve currency con-
veys some benefits to the owner of the reserve currency, perhaps because it eliminates
210
11.7 Reserve currency
currency risk. That is not true. Prices are set in a competitive international market, and if the
reserve currency weakens, the price of commodities will increase by an offsetting amount,
other things being equal. The risk does not go away; it just moves from FX to prices.
Reserve currencies tend to make other countries unhappy. When reserves are building
up there is a transfer of real goods in return for a nominal asset. Furthermore, if that coun-
try decides to misbehave, creating inflation or doing quantitative easing (QE), it is taxing
reserves held by other countries.
Having a reserve currency can create particular problems when a country is declining
in power and wealth. Even though the USD had long overtaken sterling as a reserve cur-
rency, some countries with particularly close relationships to the UK, like Canada, Hong
Kong and Kuwait, continued keeping reserves in sterling until the early 1970s. This meant
that when the UK was forced to devalue the pound, it adversely affected their closest
allies. To keep these allies happy, the UK was forced to make side payments to them, fur-
ther increasing the British difficulties.
6% $10
Debt
4%
$5
2%
0% $0
2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011
Figure 11.4 Fraction of US government debt held by major creditor countries, and total
debt, USD trillions
Data source: US Treasury
211
Chapter 11 Currency markets
By December 2011, US government debt was $15 trillion, having tripled since 2000. The
largest owner of US debt is the Social Security Trust Fund with 19%, followed by the Fed at
11.3%, leaving China in third place at 8%. Overall, 33% of the debt is held by foreign enti-
ties, not necessarily governments. Traditionally, Japan has been the largest holder but it is
now in second place, followed by Brazil, Taiwan and Russia. The US itself does not feel the
need to hold large foreign reserves, which by the end of 2011 amounted to $147 billion.
11.8 Summary
The largest financial market by volume is the market for foreign exchange. Since the level
of exchange rates is vitally important for most countries, it is not surprising that few, if any,
markets see more government intervention than the FX market. Every government needs
212
Appendix: Exchange rate regimes
to have a currency regime in place, ranging from being fully tied to other currencies to
freely floating.
Governments have various mechanisms for intervening in the FX market. If the exchange
rate is overvalued, it can only continue intervening until it runs out of foreign reserves, but
it can intervene indefinitely to maintain an undervalued currency. Governments often
couple such interventions with sterilisation, a simultaneous reduction in the money
supply.
Because of the ‘impossible trinity’, governments do not have full choice in the policy
measures they can implement, and often resort to capital controls. While the traditional
sort of capital controls was aimed at tightly controlling the flow of foreign currency in and
out, ‘capital controls 2.0’ target hot money.
If a country undervalues its currency, this often leads to significant friction with its trad-
ing partners, sometimes called ‘currency wars’.
One country in the world has the reserve currency. Historically, that was sterling, but
over the past century or so the US dollar has been the reserve currency. Its status is under
threat, and other currencies such as the renminbi or the euro may take over.
Currency board
A country pegs its exchange rate to a foreign currency, setting the exchange rate regime
and the actual exchange rate into law. A key example is Argentina up until late 2001,
which had the peso linked to the dollar.
213
Chapter 11 Currency markets
Adjustable peg
The adjustable peg is similar to a single currency peg but with less commitment and more
open and frequent adjustments. In practice, it is rather difficult because adjustments put
a strain on central bank credibility. The Bretton Woods system was based on an adjust-
able peg setup.
Basket peg
The currency is not pegged to a specific currency but is fixed to a weighted basket of two or
more currencies. This is a useful approach for countries with geographically diversified trade
patterns. The basket can be designed according to country-specific criteria or to a compos-
ite currency (SDR, for example). Theoretically a basket peg can be as rigid as a single cur-
rency peg. In practice, however, countries that use a basket peg frequently keep the weights
secret and can thus adjust the weights or the exchange rate level at their own discretion.
Crawling peg
The exchange rate is set in a rule-based manner and can be regularly reset in a series of
mini-devaluations, which can occur as often as weekly, usually based on a predetermined
rate or a function of inflation-rate differentials. High-inflation countries frequently opt for
a crawling peg, since the exchange rate can be readjusted to allow for inflation differen-
tials without giving up the benefits of a deterministic exchange rate.
Free float
The exchange rate is determined by demand and supply in the FX market without any or
with just minor official intervention. This option requires little or no official reserves but
also mostly prevents the accumulation of reserves. There are no truly freely floating cur-
rencies today.
214
References
central bank of the country is the central bank of the main country, like the Fed or the
ECB, which makes the arrangement firm and provides for lending at last resort. Unilateral
dollarisation is more unstable, since the country needs to have enough foreign currency
reserves to meet all possible demands for foreign currency, extending to all types of
money including M0, M1, M2 and M3, otherwise the setup is subject to runs.
5 What is a speculative attack? Do they force the government to abandon a sensible pol-
icy, or make the government see reality?
7 What was the Bretton Woods system, and would you want to see it adopted now?
13 Is it likely that the euro will become the next reserve currency?
References
Abdelal, R. (2007). Capital Rules: the Construction of Global Finance. Harvard University Press.
Ahamed, L. (2009). Lords of Finance, the Bankers Who Broke the World. The Penguin Group.
Arnason, R. and Danielsson, J. (2011). Capital controls are exactly wrong for Iceland. Vox
EU, 14 November. www.voxeu.org/article/iceland-and-imf-why-capital-controls-are-entirely-
wrong.
Bussiere, M., Saxena, S. C. and Tovar, C. E. (2010). Chronicle of currency collapses re-examining
the effects on output. Technical report, ECB. Working paper series no. 1226, July.
Eichengreen, B. (1996). Golden Fetters: the Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919–1939.
Oxford University Press.
Ferguson, N. (2008). The Ascent of Money. The Penguin Group.
Frankel, J. A. (1999). No single currency regime is right for all countries at all times. Working
paper 7338, National Bureau of Economic Research.
215
Chapter 11 Currency markets
Gosh, A. R., Gulde, A.-M. and Wolf, H. C. (2002). Exchange Rate Regime: Choices and
Consequences. MIT Press.
Hume, D. (1752). On the balance of trade. In Essays, Moral, Political and Literary. Edinburgh
and London.
Krugman, P. R. and Obstfeld, M. (2006). International Economics: Theory and Policy, 7th edition.
Pearson.
Laeven, L. and Valencia, F. (2008). Systemic banking crises: a new database. Technical report,
IMF. IMF Working Paper.
Lavigne, R. (2008). Sterilized intervention in emerging-market economies: trends, costs and
risks. Discussion paper 2008-4, Bank of Canada.
Marsh, D. (2010). The Euro: the Politics of the New Global Currency. Yale University Press.
McCallum, B. T. (1996). International Monetary Economics. Oxford University Press.
OECD (2002). Forty years’ experience with the OECD code of liberalisation of capital move-
ments. Technical report.
Reinhart, C. M. and Rogoff, K. (2009). This Time Is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly.
Princeton University Press.
Sarno, L. and Taylor, M. P. (2003). The Economics of Exchange Rates. Cambridge University Press.
Sicsic, P. (1992). Was the Franc Poincaré deliberately undervalued? Explorations in Economic
History, 29: 69–92.
216
12 Currency crisis models
Countries that peg their exchange rates are susceptible to currency crises if the
exchange rate is out of alignment with the underlying economic fundamentals, espe-
cially if the exchange rate is overvalued, the case considered in this chapter. This often
leads to speculative attacks, where speculators aim to force a devaluation by a massive
sale of the currency on the open market. If speculators believe that the exchange rate
is sustainable, and the government is determined to keep the peg, they will act in a
way that supports the currency regime. If, however, they lose that belief, the specula-
tors may force a realignment.
Mechanically, a speculative attack can be implemented by borrowing large
amounts of domestic currency and immediately selling it for a foreign currency, or
alternatively by entering into forward foreign exchange contracts. Once the peg is
abandoned, the speculator can realise her profits by converting foreign currency to
domestic currency at the more advantageous rate and repay the loan, or buy the for-
eign currency at the now cheap rate.
A key factor in whether an exchange rate regime is sustainable is the strength of the
underlying economic fundamentals, referring to variables like inflation, the balance of
payments, unemployment, economic growth and the budget deficit. A country with
strong fundamentals is better able to maintain its exchange rate policies and repel
speculative attacks, which in turn makes it less likely that an attack will be launched
in the first place.
Chapter 12 Currency crisis models
Key concepts
■ Speculative attacks
■ First-generation currency crisis models
■ Second-generation currency crisis moments
■ Global games models
■ Argentina
■ ERM crisis
c Cost to speculators
d Log of domestic credit
e Spot exchange rate (domestic/foreign)
e Fixed exchange rate
ẽ Shadow exchange rate
en Desired exchange rate
i, i* Domestic and foreign interest
k Threshold level of reserves
/ Proportion of speculators who attack
L Loss function of the government
m Log of domestic nominal money supply
p Log of price level in the domestic country
Q Cost of abandoning the peg
r Log of government foreign exchange reserves
T Timing of attack
v Payoff from attacking
x Noisy signal of fundamentals
Cost(Δe) Indicator function of cost of abandoning the peg
a Elasticity of agents’ demand for money
u Fundamentals
m Growth rate in domestic credit
c, h Parameters
218
12.1 First-generation models
Setup
The assets available to domestic residents are domestic money, domestic bonds, foreign
money and foreign bonds. The domestic government uses the stock of foreign currency it
holds to fix the exchange rate. The model is built around five equations:
The money supply, m, and prices, p, are in logs, as well as the growth in domestic money,
m. i is the interest rate and e is the nominal exchange rate, neither in logs. Equation (12.1)
describes the equilibrium condition in the money market. The elasticity a is positive, so the
real demand for money is a decreasing function of the domestic interest rate. Equation (12.2)
shows that the nominal money supply equals the sum of domestic credit and the foreign
exchange reserves. Equation (12.3) is the first derivative of domestic credit in relation to time
and shows that domestic credit is increasing at the positive, constant, rate of m.
The government runs persistent deficits that are financed by money creation at rate m.
Equations (12.4) and (12.5) respectively indicate that the price level follows the PPP rule
and the interest rate obeys the UIP condition.
The model
Under an assumption of perfect foresight, and assuming the exchange rate is fixed and
equal to log e, it follows that:
Et - 1 Δet = 0
it = it*
219
Chapter 12 Currency crisis models
Substituting (12.2) for the nominal money supply in m in (12.1), (12.4) for the domestic
price level pt in (12.1), and (12.5) for the domestic interest rate it in (12.1) leads to:
By assumption, the foreign price level p*t and the foreign interest rate i* are constant, as
is e. According to (12.6), the depletion rate of foreign exchange reserves is -m, so it fol-
lows that:
kt = k0 - mt (12.7)
Equivalently:
dt = d0 + mt(12.8)
k0 and d0 are the initial levels of reserves and credit, respectively, at time t = 0.
Equation (12.7) shows that the foreign exchange reserves decrease proportionally to
the growth in domestic credit in order to keep the nominal money supply and thus the
exchange rate fixed.
Unsustainability
To keep the foreign exchange rate fixed, the central bank uses its foreign currency reserves
to absorb any currency the public does not want to hold at the fixed rate e. Therefore the
foreign reserves decrease at the same speed as the increase in the central bank holdings of
domestic government debt.
This is obviously not sustainable as the central bank will eventually run out of foreign
exchange reserves, supposing it has no means to increase them. At that time, the fixed
exchange rate regime will have to be abandoned. We assume that the government will
support the fixed rate as long as its net reserves remain positive. After the fixed rate regime
collapses, the exchange rate floats freely for ever.
Et - 1 Δet = log m
220
12.1 First-generation models
Employing the shadow exchange rate, the money market equilibrium in (12.6) becomes:
log ẽ t = am + dt
Time of attack, T
First, suppose the attack happens late when log ẽ 7 log e, after which the peg is aban-
doned. In that case we would see a perfectly anticipated discrete rise in the exchange rate
equal to log ẽ - log e and the speculators would reap an instantaneously infinite rate of
profit. This represents an arbitrage opportunity giving speculators the incentive to attack
earlier and pre-empt their competitors, which will lead to an attack happening before
log ẽ 7 log e.
If, on the other hand, speculators attacked early, when log ẽ 6 log e, they would suffer
a loss since the currency would actually appreciate following the attack. Therefore, there
is no incentive to attack and the fixed exchange rate regime will survive.
Therefore, the attack must happen when log ẽ = log e, that is when the shadow
exchange rate equals the fixed exchange rate. Let T denote the time of attack. Substitute
(12.8) for dt and knowing that at T the shadow exchange rate is equal to the peg, we get:
log e = am + d0 + mT
Solving for T:
log e - d0 - am
T =
m
Prior to the crisis, the quantity of money remains constant but its composition var-
ies: domestic credit grows at rate m while reserves decrease at the same rate. After the
crisis, the government has lost all its foreign reserves and the money stock equals domes-
tic credit and thus grows at the same rate m. The solution can be seen graphically in
Figures 12.1 and 12.2.
log e
te
g e ra
Actual exc han
T Time
221
Chapter 12 Currency crisis models
k
kt if
no
kT at
ta
c
k
T Time
Analysis
The 1G model suggests that currency crises originate from an expansionary monetary pol-
icy incompatible with a fixed exchange rate regime. Speculators rationally anticipate that
the fixed exchange rate regime cannot be indefinitely maintained and launch an attack
before the foreign exchange reserves are exhausted. The model relies on strong assump-
tions such as perfect foresight, UIP and PPP.
In this model, all agents are completely rational except the government itself, since its
policy of ongoing monetary expansion eventually destroys the fixed exchange rate regime.
The underlying message of the model, however, is not that speculative attacks can be fore-
seen perfectly, but rather that it illustrates how private agents respond to inconsistent eco-
nomic policies. The 1G model shows that a large asset market event, for instance an attack,
does not necessarily need to be associated with a large shock but can build up gradually.
222
12.2 The Argentinian crisis
75%
50%
25%
0%
1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001
10000
1000
100
10
1
1990 1995 2000 2005
and making Argentina dependent on IMF financing. The beginning of the end was when
the IMF, dissatisfied with the Argentinian government for not complying with fiscal tar-
gets, held back on more loans.
Argentina partially defaulted on its international obligations in December 2001 and
abandoned the currency board a few weeks later. As a consequence, Argentina went into
a deep crisis, experiencing a GDP decline of 15% in 2002, with unemployment rising to
over 20%. Since then, Argentina has been mostly shunned by the capital markets, and is
still in negotiations with creditors over the sovereign default of 2002.
While Argentina has reached settlement with many of its creditors, it is being pursued
by so-called ‘vulture funds’ who buy distressed sovereign obligations and pursue the debt-
ors in international courts. One example of this was the seizure of an Argentine naval ship
in Ghana in October 2012, at the request of a subsidiary of the American hedge fund Elliot
Capital Management: see BBC (2012a). This is the same fund as in Section 19.3, where we
discuss the enforcement of sovereign debt claims.
Analysis
At the heart of the problem was a fiscal policy inconsistent with the currency board. The
dollar peg eliminated monetary policy as a policy tool and put strong restrictions on fiscal
policy to keep debt sufficiently low to avoid an overvaluation of the peso. Fiscal prudence
was also needed to maintain the credibility of the guarantee to convert pesos to dollars
at parity, which was needed to attract capital inflows, and to support the ability of the
government to act as a lender of last resort (LOLR).
223
Chapter 12 Currency crisis models
This issue was especially delicate in Argentina with its history of irresponsible fiscal
olicy. The fiscal policy was the result of institutional weaknesses, which persistently
p
pushed the government to commit more fiscal resources than it was capable of mobilis-
ing. A key reason was fiscal federalism, whereby regional governments could raise debt
with limited central government oversight. The IMF was an enthusiastic supporter of the
currency board, but after the crisis the chief economist of the IMF, Michael Mussa (2002),
recognised the mistakes:
‘In these kinds of conditions, the choice of the currency board, though effective in
the short-term as a tool to stabilize the economy and the price level, was risky over
the medium- to long-term. The currency board eliminated an expansionary mon-
etary policy and money creation as a mean to raise revenues, while it required long-
term fiscal discipline at the same time. If fiscal discipline was not adhered to, the
medium-term dangers were strongly increased. Adding to these dangers was the fact
that in Argentina only a limited market for long-term debt issued in pesos existed,
forcing the government to finance its deficit by external borrowing in dollars, raising
the costs of a devaluation even further.’
The Argentinian crisis is consistent with the 1G model. The government ran an unsustain-
able monetary and fiscal policy, exhausting all foreign currency resources before aban-
doning the currency board. Towards the end, it was subject to a speculative attack.
While it employed extensive capital controls, they were always quite leaky, for exam-
ple, one could buy stocks in Argentinian companies, exchange them for American deposi-
tary receipts (ADRs) in New York, sell them there and receive dollars. Interestingly, the
ADRs traded at a 40% discount, which was the amount of the eventual depreciation.
1 First, it would like to run the economy with a higher level of aggregate demand, requir-
ing a currency devaluation. We can summarise these wishes into a variable denoted en ,
which we call the desired exchange rate, that is, the exchange rate the government
would choose if it had not made a commitment to the fixed rate.
2 Second, there is a cost if the fixed rate peg is to be abandoned. This could be inter-
preted as political pain or loss of credibility of the monetary institutions. We
224
12.3 Second-generation models
summarise this by the cost of exchange rate change, Cost(Δe). For simplicity we
assume that the function Cost (Δe) can take only two possible values:
0 for Δe = 0
Cost(Δe) = e
Q for Δe 7 0
3 Finally, the peg will be more costly to defend when a devaluation is expected than
when it is not. By the UIP condition, an expected devaluation means that the domes-
tic interest rate will have to rise to defend the peg and this is likely to hurt the
economy.
Decisions
We capture these three concerns in the following loss function that the government
faces:
The term hE(Δe) reflects the expected economic pain associated with defending the peg
with increasing interest rates. h is a parameter that shows the strength of this loss.
We assume that the desired exchange rate of the government, en , is always higher
(weaker) than the fixed exchange rate, e, which means that the government is bothered
only by an overvaluation of the currency but not by an undervaluation. The term (en - e)
is then the extent to which the currency is overvalued relative to the level which the
government would like. c is a parameter of the magnitude of the loss associated with the
overvaluation.
We assume that if the government chooses to devalue, it will have no further reason to
change the exchange rate further, so from then on, the expected depreciation would be
zero. Hence, the cost of devaluation is simply Q. Figure 12.5 is a graphical description of
this situation, highlighting the multiple equilibria. Two cases can be distinguished, each
with two subcases.
2 1
Q
Defend Abandon
ê
ē A B
225
Chapter 12 Currency crisis models
Case 1: Market participants expect the government to resist the pressure to devalue,
therefore, E(Δe) = 0.
The government now has two options. It can either stick to the peg or it can devalue. If it
decides to keep the peg, the cost of abandoning the peg is equal to zero, Cost(Δe) = 0,
and the government faces the following loss function:
L1 = 5c(en - e)62
If, however, the government decides to devalue, it bears the costs of the abandonment
and its total loss becomes:
L = Cost(Δe) = Q
Facing these options, the government will defend if the loss associated with keeping
the peg is lower than the abandonment cost:
L1 6 Q
This condition is satisfied for all values of en between e and B in Figure 12.5. If en sur-
passes point B, the loss function passes the abandonment cost of Q and it becomes
more costly to defend the peg than to devalue.
Case 2: Market participants expect the government to surrender to market pressure and
allow the currency to depreciate, which means that E(Δe) 7 0. The government again
has two options. Either it can decide to defend the peg, leading to the following loss
function:
Alternatively, it can decide to give up the peg, suffering the loss of the abandonment
cost function:
Cost(Δe) = Q
L2 6 Q
The government will now defend its exchange rate for all en between e and A in Figure 12.5.
Analysis
Figure 12.5 shows that for levels of en just slightly higher than e, it is optimal for the govern-
ment to defend the peg, no matter what market participants expect. For very high values
of en the exact opposite is true and it is always optimal for the government to devalue. This
causes trigger effects, whereby a very small change in fundamentals can cause a large
change in exchange rates.
The interesting case occurs when the government finds itself in a situation between
points A and B in Figure 12.5. Here the following condition holds:
L1 6 Q 6 L2
226
12.3 Second-generation models
In this intermediate situation, the government will find it optimal to validate the
arket’s expectations. If the market expects the government to defend, the government
m
faces L1 and will find it optimal not to devalue. If market participants expect the govern-
ment to abandon the peg, the government is confronted with L2 and will find it optimal
to abandon. In this region there are multiple equilibria and the government will follow
market participants’ expectations, which are, therefore, self-fulfilling. A speculative attack
would then succeed simply because it was expected to succeed.
A country whose desired exchange rate, en , falls between A and B could find it easy or
completely impossible to defend a fixed exchange rate regime, depending on whether the
market expects it to devalue or not.
Role of fundamentals
The state of the fundamentals is reflected in the difference between the desired exchange
rate, en , and the current peg, e. If fundamentals are strong, there is no need to stimulate the
economy by devaluing. On the other hand, a country with weak fundamentals may wish to
depreciate so it can improve its economic situation. Figure 12.5 shows that the smaller the
gap between the desired exchange rate and the fixed parity, the easier it will be to defend.
The state of fundamentals is also expressed through the slope of the loss functions
of the government, which are determined by the level of en . The higher the value of Q
(a country with a sizable political investment in the peg), the easier the government will
find it to defend, ceteris paribus.
The main points of the 2G model are the following:
Stable peg
Depreciation
227
Chapter 12 Currency crisis models
1
This was only a unit of account, not a medium of exchange. It was constructed as a fixed basket of
European currencies. Member countries were Belgium, Denmark, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy,
Luxembourg, The Netherlands, Portugal, Spain and the United Kingdom.
228
12.4 The European crisis, 1992–1993
If, for example, Italy decided to use its own discretion over monetary policy and
expand its money supply, this would result in higher inflation in Italy, weakening the lira.
This gave Italy two choices: either the Italian Central Bank intervened to buy lire on the
open market or it devalued the lira, choosing a new central parity for the lira to fluctu-
ate around. Neither choice was attractive, intervening was costly and may not have been
effective, and devaluing was also costly, causing the Central Bank to lose credibility, set-
ting in inflation and making speculative attacks more likely. Therefore, the best choice for
Italy was to adopt the German monetary policy to ensure the strength of the lira.
The country with the strongest currency did not face these problems, especially if it
chose to contract its money supply. Therefore, the country with the strongest currency
has freedom of action, and the others have to follow.
Other countries
The German decision to raise interest rates strengthened the mark, putting pressure on
other members of the ERM who felt they had no choice but to also raise their interest
rates, in effect importing the German monetary policy. However, the German decision
was based on the special considerations of the reunification, and other members of the
ERM were in a different situation, with many in a recession. This meant that the optimal
monetary policy for them was an interest rate reduction, not an increase, and the need to
follow Germany meant their economic situations further deteriorated.
The situation could have been alleviated if Germany had lowered its interest rates, but
it refused to do so, recommending realignment instead. Other member countries of the
ERM rejected realignment, increasingly advocating abandoning the ERM altogether.
229
Chapter 12 Currency crisis models
floor, prompting the Bank to announce a ‘temporary’ withdrawal from the ERM, made
permanent on 19 September. The cost of defending the pound was estimated by the UK
Treasury to be £3.3 billion, around £800 million being due to direct trading losses, with
the rest lost profit from foreign reserves, sold before the pound depreciated.
Italy followed the UK out of the ERM, while Spain, although staying in the ERM, deval-
ued the peseta by 5%. The attacks continued well into 1993, with the franc, peseta,
krone and escudo under pressure. On 30 July 1993, all the ERM currencies except the
Dutch guilder and Irish punt were quoted at the bottom of their bands against the mark.
A thorough revamping of the ERM was announced on 1 August, with the size of the
bands widened from ;2.25% around par to ;15%, which finally managed to ease specu-
lative pressures.
1G analysis
The ERM crisis is not easily explained by the 1G model. The member countries devalu-
ated long before they ran out of reserves, but perhaps most importantly, the curren-
cies of many of the countries recovered over the next 18 months, suggesting that the
initial weakness of the exchange rates was not due to long-run increases in the money
supply and high inflation. Instead, the countries might just have had an overvalued
exchange rate, with a small devaluation necessary for them to become competitive
again. In other words, the devaluation was useful for the affected countries. While
this is contrary to the workings of the 1G model, it does point to the positive benefits
that speculation can bring about in forcing governments to abandon inappropriate
economic policies.
2G analysis
The 2G models were directly motivated by the ERM crisis and consequently describe the
crisis much better than the 1G models. The link between fundamentals and the attack
was weak in the crisis, with the timing random. At this time, the fundamentals were in
an indeterminate state in the language of the 2G models. The only thing that determines
whether an attack takes place is the speculators’ self-fulfilling expectations, and a small
change in expectations can then trigger a crisis.
Choices
Member countries were left with a difficult choice. They could match the German inter-
est rates, but that might not even be sufficient, because if the speculators perceived the
government as being unable to withstand the pressure, the interest rate increase had to
be very high. However, since that would have adversely affected the real economy, the
governments were unwilling to maintain very high interest rates, except perhaps in the
very short run. The speculators realised this, making the attack inevitable. The only way to
prevent the attack was either to maintain a credible monetary policy, matching Germany,
or to have sufficient reserves to repel any attack. With the benefit of hindsight, an attack
on the ERM was inevitable.
The level of fundamentals played an important but indirect role. Countries with weak
fundamentals, like high unemployment, low growth, weak banking systems or high
short-term debt, were the first to be attacked. In the context of the Copeland model in
230
12.5 Global games currency crisis model
Figure 12.5, this means that those countries had a higher slope of the loss functions and,
hence, a smaller defend area e - A and also a smaller indeterminate area A – B.
Setup
The government maintains a peg and gets net benefits from holding the peg:
+ -
f 1u , / 2 = u - /
where u, uniformly distributed, is the underlying strength of the economy – the funda-
mentals. There is a continuum of speculators, where only some number may choose to
attack the currency. Denote / ∈ [0, 1] as the proportion of speculators who attack.
The peg fails regardless of what the speculators do when u … 0, and always survives
when u Ú 1. When 0 6 u 6 1, the peg is ‘ripe for attack’, and is abandoned if and only if
u 6 /, that is, if and only if a sufficiently large speculative attack is launched.
In the context of the Copeland model in Figure 12.5, u 6 1 corresponds to the area
e - A, u 6 0 to the area beyond B to the right, and the intermediate 0 6 u 6 1 cor-
responds to A – B. Unlike the Copeland model, the decision to attack in the immediate
area is explicitly linked to how many speculators attack, which is what provides a unique
equilibrium solution.
231
Chapter 12 Currency crisis models
1 - c if / 7 u
v (u, /) = e
-c if / … u
The speculators face a coordination problem when u ∈ (0,1). If one speculator attacks
and nobody else does, the attack fails and she loses money. If, however, everybody
attacks except the one speculator, she also loses money. The speculators, therefore, want
to attack only when everybody else attacks.
The speculators have imperfect information and receive a noisy signal about the
fundamentals:
xi = u + s i
where si is uniformly distributed over [-e, e]. The distribution over u conditional on xi is
uniform over
[xi - e, xi + e]
The speculator makes a decision based on what she thinks everybody else will do. This
means there is a unique equilibrium in switching strategies, that is switching from refrain-
ing to attacking. Denote the switching point as x*.
Solution
The level of fundamentals where the peg will fail, u*, depends on the switching point x*,
which in turn depends on the failure point u*, solving u = /.
If all follow x* - switching, / is the proportion whose signal is below x* when the true
state is u*:
x* - 1u* - e2
/ =
2e
x* - 1u* - e2
u* =
2e
At the switching point x*, the speculator is indifferent between attacking and refraining:
232
12.5 Global games currency crisis model
Pr1u 6 u* | x*2 = c
u* - (x* - e)
= c
2e
u* = 1 - c
x* = 1 - c - e(2c - 1)(12.9)
As e S 0, x* S u*.
Verification of solution
We can verify that when xi 6 x*, the speculator wants to attack, and when xi 7 x*, she
wants to refrain. Suppose xi 6 x*:
u* - (xi - e)
Pr(peg fails ∙ xi) =
2e
u* - (x* - e)
7
2e
= Pr(peg fails ∙ x*)
and conversely for when xi 7 x*. Switching strategy around x* is equilibrium. In fact, it is
the unique equilibrium.
x* - (u - e)
= /
2e
or
un = x* + e - 2e/
233
Chapter 12 Currency crisis models
Second, the answer is given by the probability that the true state is higher than un , condi-
tional on signal x*. This is
(x* + e) - un
2e
(x* + e) - (x* + e - 2e/)
=
2e
= /
Call the proportion of speculators who attack the incidence of attack. The cumulative dis-
tribution function over the incidence of attack is the identity function. Therefore, the den-
sity function over the incidence of attack is uniform over [0, 1].
How is this answer affected by the size of the noise e? Not at all! As e S 0, the uncer-
tainty concerning u dissipates, but the strategic uncertainty is as severe as ever.
Analysis
A key difference between the global games model and the 2G model is that in the former there
is only one equilibrium. Speculators have imperfect information about the state of the funda-
mentals, leading them to guess what other speculators would do, and launching a speculative
attack if and only if they think other speculators will join them – strategic complementarity.
This means that the markets react suddenly, one moment supporting the peg, with an
attack the next moment, causing the peg to fail. This means that a very small change in
the speculators’ beliefs can lead to a very large outcome.
At the same time, the likelihood of an attack is directly correlated with the state of the
fundamentals. This leads to interesting results on the impact of transparency and disclosure.
When fundamentals are weak, greater public disclosure of the state of the fundamen-
tals increases the probability of attack, since the strategic uncertainty dissipates, making
coordinated attack easier. Fundamental uncertainty also dissipates, increasing the incen-
tive for attack. This provides support for a policy of constructive ambiguity.
When fundamentals are strong, greater public disclosure of fundamentals decreases
the probability of attack. Strategic uncertainty dissipates, causing a coordinated pull back
from attack. Fundamental uncertainty also dissipates, further increasing incentives to
refrain from attack.
There is an important difference between ex ante decisions on disclosures and oppor-
tunistic disclosures. In the former case, the authorities are providing regular updates on
the economy outside a crisis state, while in the latter they are disclosing information
opportunistically, with the explicit purpose of affecting the behaviour of speculators.
This, of course, is noted and can backfire on the authorities.
12.6 Summary
The focus in this chapter has been on formal models of currency crises. We started out
with the earliest crisis model, the 1G model, where the authorities run an unsustainable
monetary policy, using reserves to intervene to maintain a peg. Speculators know this, and
234
12.6 Summary
launch an attack on the currency before the authorities run out of reserves. This model is
quite simplistic and is not directly consistent with most crises, except that of Argentina.
In response, the 2G models were developed, where a key ingredient is the expectation
of speculators of the intentions of the authorities. A main result is that we can get self-
fulfilling crises. If speculators believe the authorities will maintain the peg they will not
attack, but if they believe the authorities will not, an attack is forthcoming. Therefore, the
speculators will be seen as correct, regardless of what they do.
These models can be used to analyse the ERM crisis of the early 1990s, where specula-
tors attacked the British pound when they realised that the UK would not stay within the
ERM target zone.
An important problem with the 2G is the presence of multiple equilibria. This is solved
by the global games models, where speculators have imperfect information about the
fundamentals and need to coordinate to launch an attack. Here, the markets can very sud-
denly transit from stability to crisis as a tiny bit of extra information affects expectations.
4 Recall the 2G model by Copeland. At the centre of the model is the loss function of the
government
where C(Δe) is an indicator function that can take only one of two values:
0 for Δe = 0
C(Δe) = e
Q for Δe 7 0
For simplicity assume throughout this question that the fixed exchange rate is set
at e = 0, and that if the government devalues, it will directly move to the desired
exchange rate, so that E(Δe) = (en - e).
235
Chapter 12 Currency crisis models
(a) Assuming that the government has a reputation of defending the exchange rate, and
speculators expect that it will stick to that policy in the future, what level of the de-
sired exchange rate, en, would induce the government to give up the peg and devalue?
Derive your results analytically and mathematically and show them in a graph.
(b) Now the government appoints a new president of the central bank who has a
reputation of being ‘soft’ on the exchange rate commitment. Now speculators
expect that a devaluation is probable. What level of the desired exchange rate, en ,
would induce the government now to give up the peg? Again, derive your results
analytically and mathematically and plot them.
(c) Assuming now that speculators have not finally decided whether the appointment
of the new central bank president weakens the exchange rate commitment,
(i) For what levels of en does the government definitely devalue?
(ii) For what levels of en does the government definitely defend?
(iii) What happens in between?
(iv) What role do fundamentals play?
(d) You can now assume that c = 2, h = 3 and Q = 64
(i) For what levels of en does the government definitely devalue?
(ii) For what levels of en does the government definitely defend?
(iii) Show how good fundamentals give the government more leverage in defend-
ing the exchange rate.
5 Was the speculative attack on some European currencies in the early 1990s positive or
negative for the economies of the affected countries?
6 Why does the global games model only have one equilibrium while the 2G model has two?
7 Explain the role of strategic complementarities in how speculators all agree on whether
to attack or refrain.
References
BBC (2012a). Argentina ship in Ghana seized over loans default. www.bbc.co.uk/news/
world-africa-19827562.
Copeland, L. (2000). Exchange Rates and International Finance. Prentice Hall.
Flood, R. P. and Garber, P. M. (1984). Collapsing exchange rate regimes: some linear examples.
J. Int. Econ., 17: 223–34.
Krugman, P. (1979). A model of balance-of-payments crises. J. Money Credit Banking, 11(3): 311–25.
Morris, S. and Shin, H. S. (1998). Unique equilibrium in a model of self-fulfilling currency
attacks. Amer. Econ. Rev., 88: 587–97.
Morris, S. and Shin, H. S. (1999). Risk management with interdependent choice. Oxford Review
of Economic Policy, 15: 52–62, reprinted in Bank of England Financial Stability Review, 7, 141–50.
www.bankofengland.co.uk/fsr/fsr07art5.pdf.
Mussa, M. (2002). Argentina and the Fund: from Triumph to Tragedy. Institute for International
Economics, Washington DC.
Obstfeld, M. (1996). Models of currency crises with self-fulfilling features. Eur. Econ. Rev., 40(3–5):
1037–1047.
Obstfeld, M. and Rogoff, K. (1996). Foundations of International Macroeconomics. MIT Press.
236
13 Financial regulations
to be able to take risk in order to fund the SMEs. This causes a conflict for supervisors
because they cannot simultaneously curtail risky banking activities and want banks to
participate in economic recovery.
Financial regulations may also have other less visible costs. They may just encourage
financial institutions to continue the same risky activities out of sight – perhaps creat-
ing a shadow banking system – making it even harder for the authorities to understand
and regulate banking activities. Regulations may also encourage financial institutions
to move activities to other jurisdictions, depriving the domestic economy from some
of the benefits banks bring.
Designing and implementing financial regulations is difficult. They are essential
for the protection of society, but all too frequently fail, not providing protection, and
even perversely increasing systemic risk.
Key concepts
■ Motivation for financial regulations
■ Macro-prudential and micro-prudential policies
■ Bank capital and capital ratios
■ Unintended consequences of regulations
■ Basel Committee for Banking Supervision (BCBS)
■ Basel I and Basel II
238
13.1 Banking regulations
239
Chapter 13 Financial regulations
Because of the complexity of bank products, and the high costs of monitoring bank
performance, it is beyond anybody, except experts, to understand the underlying risks.
Certainly, for retail clients this is quite infeasible. It is more efficient for a dedicated gov-
ernment agency to monitor financial institutions on the behalf of bank clients.
Laissez-faire
A frequently expressed view on banking regulation is laissez-faire. A bank should be left
alone to prosper and fail like any other private enterprise; the government should exercise
minimum regulations and certainly not protect banks in times of failure.
This has been the prevailing official policy at many times in history, for example, in the
nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. Some forms of this view also affected banking
policy prior to the crisis starting in 2007. However, such a laissez-faire approach to banking
is not credible.
The reason is the externalities arising from bank failures. When the authorities are faced
with large losses being imposed on society as a result of a banking crisis, they have no
choice but to act because the political pressure on the government becomes unbearable.
If it refuses to act, the government faces punishment by the voters. Just three examples
discussed elsewhere in this book are the crises of 1866 in the UK, of 1907 in the US, and of
Argentina in the early 1990s. Deciding not to regulate the financial sector is not a credible
option for the authorities. Being forced to intervene in times of crisis without adequate
preparation is a worst-case outcome. It is better for the authorities to regulate the finan-
cial sector and be prepared for the eventual crisis.
240
13.1 Banking regulations
Endogenous risk
Some prudential regulations, especially those addressing risk-taking, can directly increase
endogenous risk. This happens exactly because the regulations aim at preventing excessive
risk-taking by banks, thereby preventing large losses or even bankruptcies. This is some-
times referred to as smoothing the road. Reducing excessive risk is a laudable goal but can
be difficult to implement in practice, and regulations aiming at containing risk taking may
have the perverse consequence of actually increasing risk. There are several reasons why
this may happen.
Risk is very hard to measure. From a statistical point of view, it involves volatility clus-
ters, fat tails and non-linear dependence, which means that the basic statistical problem
of risk forecasting is quite hard. Often, these risk forecasts are then input into complicated
models, where, because of non-linearities, risk can be amplified in a way that is hard to
detect. In addition, banks have an incentive to under-report risk, and even worse, some
employees of banks – the traders – have even stronger incentives to under-report risk.
241
Chapter 13 Financial regulations
If the road is smooth, and risk is perceived as low, it creates incentives to take more risk.
Because after all, if everything is safe, what is wrong with a little bit more risk? The prob-
lem is that such risk-taking is not immediately visible but is seen only much later. For
example, it was decisions taken in the supposedly low-risk environment between 2003
and 2007 that created the conditions for the subsequent crisis. From a statistical point of
view, it is impossible to detect such hidden build-up of risk.
Smoothing the road is pro-cyclical, encouraging banks to take too much risk when
things are good and too little risk when things are bad.
Incentives of supervisors
A particular problem arises because of the incentives of banking supervisors. When the
banking system is functioning well without headline failures, the supervisors are unlikely
to get much credit whilst bankers and even politicians complain about excessive regula-
tory burdens on this profitable economic activity. If then a big failure occurs, the head of
the supervisory agency may face acrimonious hearings in the country’s parliament and be
pilloried in the press. After all, the supervisor had all the information about the bank but
did not act on it to prevent failure.
There is a danger that the incentives of supervisors are to prevent failure at all costs
and, hence, for the supervisor to become too risk-averse. This means that the incentive
problem of the supervisor is inverse to that of the banker.
It is therefore necessary to have some mechanisms in place to prevent excessive super-
visory risk aversion. One way to do so is by performing cost–benefit analysis on regula-
tions. Unfortunately, that is quite difficult to do in practice.
This problem leads to a particular form of pro-cyclicality. During upswings, regulations
become increasingly lax, amplifying the boom, and after a crisis they become excessively
strict, magnifying the downturn. There are clear signs of this in the current cycle.
242
13.1 Banking regulations
243
Chapter 13 Financial regulations
Avoidance incentive
Financial innovation
New regulation
Regulation Q was a US regulation limiting the interest rates that banks could pay on
deposits. This created incentives to create a parallel banking system, money market
mutual accounts, where market interest rates could be paid.
The Eurodollar market first came into being in the 1950s when the Soviet Union’s oil
revenue – all in US dollars – was being deposited outside the US in fear of being fro-
zen by US regulators. This resulted in a vast offshore pool of dollars outside the con-
trol of US authorities, primarily held in Europe, hence, the term Eurodollar. This was a
major contribution to London becoming a world-leading financial centre.
Regulatory capture
In an ideal world, the supervisors are concerned only with the safety and soundness of
the banking system. In practice, there are often many other reasons why the government
chooses to regulate the banking system. It may have altruistic ulterior motives, such as requir-
ing banks to provide unprofitable banking services to disadvantaged sectors of society, or the
government may want to have national champions. Bank lobbying is also quite strong and
aims at creating banking regulations that favour the incumbents, discouraging entry into the
banking system and providing protection for banks’ profits and even the odd bailout.
In this case, banking supervisors may end up being captured by banks. This means that
the supervisory agency no longer works for society; instead, in effect, it works in the inter-
est of the banks. Such regulatory capture can happen for many reasons, for example,
when banks recruit staff out of supervisory agencies at vastly higher salaries, which might
give the staff an incentive to behave in a way that encourages private-sector recruitment.
In other cases, the banks may bypass the supervisor by going directly to the politicians,
who after all are in charge of the supervisor. Supervisory agencies are often accused of
regulatory capture, but this can be hard to verify. For example, it is often claimed the SEC
has been captured, but that case demonstrates the difficulty in distinguishing between
deliberate laxness in enforcement, incompetence or regulatory capture. A better example
was the supervisor for the S&Ls, as we discussed in Section 7.5.2.
244
13.2 Bank capital
Resource problems
Supervisory agencies have a serious resource problem compared to the banks they are
supervising. The government is likely to pay much less than the banks and have fewer staff
members, meaning the authorities can be seriously outgunned when dealing with the
banks. Any well-performing supervisor is subject to poaching from the private sector, and
the authorities often have real difficulty holding onto staff.
Summary
The challenges in banking supervision are indicative of how hard the problem is. It is not,
and will not be, possible to create anything resembling a perfect regulatory structure;
instead, we have to do our best and have multiple safeguards in place so we can simulta-
neously protect society and avoid excessive risk aversion.
Because each bit of regulation changes behaviour, we may need further regulation
to address the newly created problem, and so forth. While such cycles are inevitable,
they are also a sign of poor regulatory design. Regulations often have unforeseen conse-
quences, and we should consider the regulation of the financial system holistically, tak-
ing into account the entire body of regulations and the financial system and not looking
at individual components in isolation. That is not easy. Regulators are under constant
demand from lobbyists, assorted pundits and politicians, generally demanding action on
the specific point, disregarding the need for an integrated approach to regulations.
Equity
Consider a simplified balance sheet of a bank.
Assets Liabilities
The bank has assets (loans), as well as liabilities (deposits). The difference between
these two is net worth or equity:
245
Chapter 13 Financial regulations
Equity is the amount of money the owners have invested in the bank, and has no direct
connection with the market value of a bank.
We illustrate the calculation of bank equity by Example 13.3.
A bank started five years ago. Assuming the original stock price was 1000, and there
are no dividends or taxes, profits in years 1, 2, 3 and 5 were 100 in each year, while
the loss in year 4 was 250. In this case the shareholders’ equity is
There are several different types of equity, for example tangible equity which is cash
raised from shareholders or retained through earnings. Those different types of equity are
a function of the underlying accounting rules, local traditions and national law.
Capital
The concept of capital is broader than that of equity and includes a range of instruments,
so that some of a bank’s liabilities may be a part of its capital:
It is useful to start with a simple balance sheet of a bank. Suppose we have two cat-
egories of assets, a riskless asset, perhaps a government bond, denoted by A1 and risky
corporate loans denoted by A2. Then the total assets of the bank are A = A1 + A2. Capital
is denoted by C.
The ratio of capital to assets is called the capital adequacy ratio (CAR).
Assets Liabilities
C
CAR = Ú a
A
In many cases, the capital ratio is risk-sensitive, so that low-risk assets contribute less to
the denominator than high-risk assets. In this case, the CAR might become
C
CAR = Ú a, w1 6 w2 (13.2)
w1A1 + w2A2
246
13.2 Bank capital
Capital instruments
The most basic form of capital is (common) equity, but certain liabilities, known as capital
instruments, can also be a part of capital. These include preference shares, subordinated debt,
long-term bonds and hybrid instruments which are bonds that can be converted into equity.
13.2.1 Pro-cyclicality
An important problem with banking and capital is pro-cyclicality.
Definition 13.3 Pro-cyclicality A term that refers to how some economic quan
tity relates positively to economic fluctuations. It is the opposite of countercyclicality. See
Figure 13.2 below for an example.
When the economy is doing well, banks have ample funds which they seek to lend out,
but often find that high-quality borrowers have all the credit they need. Banks therefore
start lending to increasingly low-quality borrowers, often in the real-estate sector, creating
a real-estate bubble. When eventually the bubble bursts and the economy takes a turn
for the worse, banks find themselves faced with large amounts of defaults and sharply
curtail lending, often referred to as a credit crunch. This makes asset prices drop even fur-
ther. This means that bank lending amplifies the business cycle and is hence pro-cyclical.
Start with the definition of equity from Equation (13.1) and assume equity = $12
and assets = $100. Suppose the authorities impose a minimum CAR of a = 8%. The
CAR is then
$12
= 12% 7 a (13.3)
$100
➨
247
Chapter 13 Financial regulations
In this case, the bank is comfortably exceeding the regulatory CAR and employing
leverage of
$100
= 8.3
$12
If the economy takes a turn for the worse and the bank suffers losses of 3% of its
assets, that is $3, the CAR becomes
$12 - $3
= 9.3% 7 a (13.4)
$100 - $3
and the bank is closer to violating its regulatory constraint. Now the leverage has
increased to 10.7.
Since the bank prefers to maintain a buffer above the minimum 8%, it will do what it
can to increase its CAR, and the most obvious way to do so is to reduce leverage and sell
off some of its more risky assets.
This means that capital constraints increase the pro-cyclicality of bank capital and
bank leverage. For example, before 2007 banks were excessively free with their lending,
but after the crises started, they sharply curtailed lending, especially to the politically
sensitive SME sector.
Risk sensitivity
The problem of pro-cyclicality is made worse if the capital ratio is risk sensitive because
the same asset would have lower weights at the top of the cycle than at the bottom of the
cycle, amplifying the amplitude. This can be seen in Figure 13.2.
This can be seen clearly from the CAR in (13.2) and Example 13.4. Suppose A2
represents high-risk real-estate lending. At the top of the cycle most signs point to the risk
in real estate being low, and hence w2 will be low, keeping the CAR high. If the bubble
then bursts, real estate becomes more risky and w2 increases sharply, causing the CAR to
fall. The impact can be seen Example 13.5.
4
3
2 No risk sensitivity
Risk sensitive capital
1
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Year
248
13.2 Bank capital
Suppose before the shock the risk weight is 1, so w = 1. (13.3) therefore becomes
$12 $12
= = 12% 7 a
w * $100 $100
Because of the shock, the risk weight increases to w = 1.5, and (13.4) becomes
$12 - $3 $12 - $3
= = 6.1% 6 a
w($100 - $3) 1.5($100 - $3)
Because of the risk sensitivity, the CAR fell further, and the bank is no longer meet-
ing its regulatory constraint, causing it either to be shut down by the authorities or to
receive a bailout.
Cliff effects
The presence of a rigid capital ratio may have unexpected adverse consequences. If a bank’s
capital ratio falls below the minimum specified by banking regulators, currently 8%, the
bank most likely would be shut down, and as it gets closer to the 8% it draws increasing
unwanted scrutiny from the authorities. For this reason banks prefer to keep a significant
buffer above the minimum, generally around 12–13% before the crises from 2007.
Suppose a bank finds its capital ratio falling, needing to improve its CAR. The bank can
increase capital by selling equity or other capital instruments on the financial markets.
Because the bank is likely to be in this situation only in times of difficulty, this option is
likely to be quite costly, and if it coincides with a financial crisis, it may be impossible.
20% UK
US
10%
0%
1880 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000
249
Chapter 13 Financial regulations
The bank can also reduce the amount of assets held or the riskiness of its portfolio by
selling risky assets and refusing to provide new loans. This process is termed deleveraging.
If only one bank is in difficulty, with the financial system generally in good shape, such
deleveraging is not all that problematic. However, if it happens during crises the situation
is rather different.
In this case, a general sell-off of risky assets throughout the financial system is likely to
be taking place. This means that the price of risky assets is likely to fall precipitously, sig-
nificantly below their fundamental values, and the bank may get only firesale prices. The
bank may also refuse to provide new loans and to roll over existing loans, perhaps leading
to a credit crunch. Those borrowers most likely to be affected are SMEs. This will lead to
further economic slowdown.
Both actions exacerbate the crisis, and cause an endogenous risk of vicious feedback
between worsening economic conditions and bank difficulties. This shows how fixed capi-
tal ratios can by themselves increase systemic risk.
250
13.3 International financial regulations: Basel
failures in particular, those of Bankhaus Herstatt in 1974 and Banco Ambrosiano in 1982,
served as a wake-up call to the authorities, making it clear that if we want to have regula-
tions in the first place, they need to be international. This means that the home regulator,
where the bank has its headquarters, needs to have oversight of its banks’ activities every-
where in the world, and the host regulators, countries where the bank operates, need to
cooperate actively with the home regulator and other host regulators.
Supervise everywhere
There are two main reasons why regulation needs to be international. First, there have
been well-documented cases where a financial institution was regulated in one country
but misbehaved in another. This happened because the home supervisor was responsible
only for activities at home, while the host supervisors assumed the home supervisor was
in charge, and at the same time the different national supervisors did not communicate.
This suggests that it is necessary to have international regulations to ensure banks are
regulated wherever they operate, with supervisors cooperating on enforcement.
Regulatory arbitrage
The second problem arises if financial regulations and supervision are not harmonised
across jurisdictions, and financial institutions can shop for the jurisdictions with the most
lax regulations or supervision, a process called regulatory arbitrage. In the best case, this
leads to the most lax environment to be used, but in a worst case, countries may compete
by relaxing financial regulations in order to attract multinational banks.
1
Belgium, Canada, France, Italy, Japan, Germany, Sweden, the Netherlands, the UK and the US, as well
as Luxembourg. Spain later became a member.
2
To include Argentina, Australia, Brazil, China, Hong Kong SAR, India, Indonesia, South Korea, Mexico,
Russia, Saudi Arabia, Singapore, South Africa, Sweden, Switzerland and Turkey.
251
Chapter 13 Financial regulations
At times, the Committee uses this common understanding to develop guidelines and
supervisory standards in areas where they are considered desirable. In this regard, the
Committee is best known for the Concordat and the Basel Accords.
One important objective of the Committee’s work has been to close gaps in interna-
tional supervisory coverage in pursuit of two basic principles: that no foreign banking
establishment should escape supervision; and that supervision should be adequate. The
Concordat, originally published in 1975 (in response to the Bankhaus Herstatt crisis), set
down the principles for sharing supervisory responsibility for banks’ foreign branches,
subsidiaries and joint ventures between host and home supervisory authorities. A major
review was made in 1983 following the failure of Banco Ambrosiano.
The most important part of the Committee’s work is the Basel capital accords, a set of
internationally harmonised rules for determining the adequacy of the capital of interna-
tionally active banks. The first Basel Accords, now referred to as Basel I, were proposed in
1988 and implemented in 1992, while their successor, Basel II, was proposed in the late
1990s and at least partially implemented from 2008. The Committee has already pro-
posed the next iteration, Basel III.
13.3.2 Basel I
A key motivation for Basel I was events in the early 1980s when banks competed vigor-
ously in making corporate loans. At the time, bank capital ratios of major banks in Europe
and the US were perhaps 8–10%, while Japanese banks operated with lower bank capital
and saw major gains in market share. This led to competitive pressures to lower bank
capital in Europe and the US. Regulators became alarmed and proposed Basel I with the
primary aim of specifying minimum capital for banks operating in the world’s major finan-
cial centres.
Basel I was broadly successful in achieving its designated purposes, raising capital levels
at a time when they were low and trending down.
252
13.3 International financial regulations: Basel
in financial regulation that can often lead to surprising outcomes. In this case, 364-day
loans have become quite popular, replacing much longer-maturity loans, often with the
tacit understanding that they will be rolled over after 364 days. They do create, however,
unnecessary liquidity risk and therefore make the financial system more fragile and even
increase systemic risk.
13.3.3 Basel II
The BCBS embarked on a revision of Basel I in the mid-1990s, which came to be called
Basel II and was introduced to the world around the turn of the century. Since then,
extensive lobbying has taken place, delaying its implementation to 2008 in most relevant
jurisdictions. This means that Basel II reflects concerns and regulatory thinking from the
mid-1990s, so it was already out of date by the time of its implementation.
Basel II improves on the capital regulations in several ways. It substantially improves
the risk sensitivity of the minimum capital requirements. While market risk regulations
remain unchanged, an internal rating based (IRB) approach is introduced for the calcula-
tion of credit risk. Basel II also introduces operation risk.
In the IRB approaches, banks’ internal assessments of key risk drivers serve as primary
inputs to the capital calculation. Because the approach is based on banks’ internal assess-
ments, the potential for more risk-sensitive capital requirements is substantial.
Menu of approaches
While Basel I took a one-size-fits-all approach to capital calculations, Basel II more
explicitly recognises that banks are different. One reason is that Basel I applied mostly to
large international active banks, while the EU intended Basel II to apply to essentially all
banks in its member states, requiring a more nuanced approach for calculating capital,
taking into account that some banks are sophisticated and run their own models whilst
others engage in very basic activities, outsourcing the few needed calculations. Banks
can choose between three different approaches for calculating capital, ranging from
simple ratios to sophisticated internal modelling. The menu of approaches is demon-
strated in Figure 13.4.
253
Chapter 13 Financial regulations
Increased sophistication
ratings based measurement
approach Internal models approach
Foundation
Standardised
internal ratings
approach
based approach
Revised Standardised
approach Basic indicator
standardised
approach
approach
While the main focus of Basel II is still on refining the minimum capital requirements,
the attention has gradually shifted towards the pillars II and III as the current crisis calls for
a more stabilising regulatory regime.
Pillar II forms an integral part of the proposal. It obliges regulators to assess the qual-
ity of the risk models of individual banks, allowing the models to be more flexible with
respect to banks’ particular circumstances whilst encouraging closer cooperation between
the supervisor and the bank.
However, allowing regulators such flexibility raises the need for a mechanism ensur-
ing that pillar II is implemented uniformly across countries and that quality assessments
undertaken under its auspices are consistent across regulators.
Pillar III reflects the conventional wisdom that sufficient transparency in the market is
helpful in increasing stability. This, however, has been somewhat disappointing and has
not proven effective.
254
13.3 International financial regulations: Basel
There are two main factors at work. First, the counterparties who are supposed to do
the monitoring share in the same hubris as the banks that are being monitored. We see
clear examples in a later chapter when we discuss the problem of toxic capital and assets.
Second, it is very hard to make sense of the information being put out. Aggregate sum-
mary numbers can hide a myriad of problems, especially in complex asset classes, while
the understanding of fine-grained disclosures depends on intimate knowledge of a bank’s
operations.
‘The proposed regulations fail to consider the fact that risk is endogenous. V
alue-at-Risk
can destabilise and induce crashes when they would not otherwise occur.
Heavy reliance on credit rating agencies for the standard approach to credit risk
is misguided as they have been shown to provide conflicting and inconsistent fore-
casts of individual clients’ creditworthiness. They are unregulated and the quality of
their risk estimates is largely unobservable.
Financial regulation is inherent procyclical. Our view is that this set of propos-
als will, overall, exacerbate this tendency significantly. In so far as the purpose of
financial regulation is to reduce the likelihood of systemic crisis, these proposals will
actually tend to negate, not promote this useful purpose.’
Sovereign debt
It is quite common for countries to consider their own domestic currency sovereign debt
as riskless, often writing it into law. Even though very few countries are considered risk-
free, traditionally this may not have been that big a problem because governments in
difficulty with domestic debt payments simply resorted to inflating the debt away rather
than directly defaulting.
The Basel I accord follows in this tradition, considering the debt of OECD member
countries to be riskless, for the purpose of capital calculations. This means that any bank
holding OECD government debt did not have to hold capital against it. This was, of
course, a subsidy to the government, paid for by a tax on regular borrowers.
This practice is not that problematic so long as countries issue debt in their own cur-
rency, but with the establishment of the euro a new problem has emerged. Member
countries of the euro zone issue debt in euros. This means that they cannot resort to
inflating away their debt as they used to before the euro, a common practice in many
countries such as Greece and Italy. While Basel II does not necessarily consider sov-
ereign debt risk-free, the EU does in the case of ‘exposures to Member States central
government . . . denominated and funded in the domestic currency of that central
255
Chapter 13 Financial regulations
government’.3 This means all member governments of the euro zone issue risk-free
debt, at least for the purpose of bank capital calculations. Note that this does not mean
the governments can borrow at risk-free rates, but rather that loans to governments do
not attract a capital charge.
This has caused particular problems in the euro zone since it sent the signal that gov-
ernment debt was risk-free and in turn meant that banks did not consider the acquisition
of sovereign debt as speculative investments, but rather the byproduct of prudent treas-
ury operations.
Tier 1 capital
The most important part of tier 1 capital is common equity. Depending on the jurisdiction,
there are two other types of tier 1 capital, disclosed reserves and preferred stock. These
instruments differ depending on each national regulator, but are always close in nature to
common equity, usually referred to as upper tier 1 capital. In the US, regulators prefer tangi-
ble equity, as it provides the most protection. This is disliked by European banks.
Tier 2 capital
Tier 2 capital contains a much broader range of instruments, and is the lesser of the two
ratios. Note that just like in tier 1, there may be important differences between jurisdic-
tions as to what is allowed as a part of tier 2.
A relatively unimportant part of tier 2 capital is undisclosed reserves, revaluation
reserves and general provisions. The key instruments are subordinated debt and hybrid
instruments. The former has a flaw in that it provides protection only in case of default
and not prior to bankruptcy, when it is most needed. The second instrument had an
important deficiency that manifested itself during the crises from 2007, where the protec-
tion thought to be afforded by the hybrid capital instruments turned out to be illusionary.
C = T1 + T2
a i = 1w i Ai
CAR = N
Ú 8%
where T1 and T2 denote tier 1 and tier 2 capital, respectively, w1 = 0 is the risk weight on the
safe asset A1 and wi, i 7 1 are the risk weights on the risky assets. N is the number of assets.
3
Article 89(1)(d) of the EU capital requirements directives (CRDs) (amended by Directive 2009/111/EC
or ‘CRD II’), and Annex VI Part 1 paragraph 4.
256
13.4 Summary
For larger banks, the risk weights are calculated by using internal models, whereby
the bank uses historical data and statistical models to forecast the risk of its assets. These
models need to be approved by the supervisor.
Capital calculations
Recall the discussion from Section 13.2 above. We replicate it here in the table below,
having added in tier 1 and tier 2.
Assets Liabilities
Suppose a bank holds $1 billion in sovereign debt and $2 billion in corporate loans,
whilst it has tier 1 capital of $50 million and tier 2 capital of $200 million. Its capital
ratio is then:
50 + 200
= 12%
0 * 1000 + 1 * 2000
13.4 Summary
The focus of this chapter has been on banking regulations. Banking has always been one
of the most regulated parts of the economy because of the externalities induced by bank-
ing, whereby the downside from failure can seriously affect society while the bankers
enjoy the upside.
However, financial regulations carry with them serious side-effects. They can result in
the hiding of risk-taking, prevent socially desirable activities or spur undesirable financial
innovation.
One of the most common ways to regulate banks is by capital requirements, and under
current regulations banks are required to have capital to risk-weighted assets of at least 8%.
Traditionally, financial regulations were the purview of the nation state, but following
the post-Bretton Woods deregulation of the global economy, banking is increasingly global,
and banking regulations have followed with first the Basel I and then the Basel II accords.
Appendix: Value-at-risk
The Basel committee introduced an amendment to Basel I in 1996, stipulating that a
new category of capital requirements was to be created, those arising from market risk.
Fundamental to the amendment is the concept of VaR defined as a loss threshold: for a
given probability, p,
Pr [- losses Ú VaR] = -p
257
Chapter 13 Financial regulations
For more details see, for example, Danielsson (2011). The probability specified by the
Committee is 99% and the holding period is 10 days. Capital arising from trading activi-
ties is defined as
Capital = 3 VaR99%
10-day + constant
Because it is hard to obtain a proper 10-day VaR, the Committee allows banks to use the
square-root-of-time rule and do the calculation as
99%
Capital = 3210 VaRdaily + constant
This means that the bank capital for trading activities is based on a multiple of the risk of
an event that happens 2.5 times a year on average, the VaR99% daily.
6 What is pro-cyclicality, and to what extent are regular banking activities pro-cyclical?
7 Outline the specific mechanism by which bank capital and capital regulations are pro-cyclical
8 Can bank capital that cannot be drawn down in times of need still fulfil a useful function?
9 What are the main objectives and achievements of the Basel Committee?
11 What you think about the assumption in Basel that sovereigns are risk free?
12 Consider a bank that has $100 in cash, no other assets, and no liabilities. The bank
operates in a country with a 8% minimum CAR requirement
(a) Suppose the bank raises $900 in deposits and invests all of its cash on hand in risk
free government bonds. What will its CAR be?
(b) Suppose instead the bank invests $800 in a AA rated bond that attracts a risk weight
of 1, with the rest in the government bond. Is the bank meeting its CAR requirement?
(c) If the bank instead allocates $500 to a BB rated bond with a risk weight of 2, $300
to the AA bond, with rest to the government bond. Is the bank meeting its CAR
requirement?
(d) The bank invests $800 in a AA rated bond that attracts a risk weight of 1, with the
rest in the government bond. Suppose the markets fear inflation and interest rise
by 4% and as a consequence the market value of all bonds drops by 4%. Is the
bank meeting its CAR requirement?
(e) Comment on the last answer from the point of view of the impact of leverage on
the bank’s capital structure.
258
References
References
Alessandri, P. and Haldane, A. G. (2009). Banking on the state. Mimeo, Bank of England.
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (1996). Amendment to the Capital Accord to Incorporate
Market Risks. www.bis.org/publ/bcbs24.pdf.
Bruner, R. F. and Carr, S. D. (2007). The Panic of 1907: Lessons Learned from the Market’s Perfect
Storm. John Wiley & Sons.
Crockett, A. (2000). Marrying the micro- and macro-prudential dimensions of financial stabil-
ity. The General Manager of the Bank for International Settlements, www.bis.org/review/
rr000921b.pdf.
Danielsson, J. (2011). Financial Risk Forecasting. John Wiley & Sons.
Danielsson, J., Embrechts, P., Goodhart, C., Keating, C., Muennich, F., Renault, O. and Shin,
H. S. (2001). An academic response to Basel II. www.bis.org/bcbs/ca/fmg.pdf.
Dewatripont, M. and Tirole, J. (1994). The Prudential Regulation of Banks. MIT Press.
Goodhart, C. (2009). The Regulatory Response to the Financial Crisis. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK.
Goodhart, C. (2011). The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision: a History of the Early Years
1974–1997. Cambridge University Press.
Kohn, M. (1999). Early deposit banking. Mimeo, Dartmouth College, Hanover, NH.
Schumpeter, J. (1942). Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. Harper, New York.
259
14 Bailouts
We could define a financial crisis as an event where the public is called on to bail out
privately owned financial institutions. The bankers may tell the government that if a
bailout is not forthcoming immediately, the country’s financial system will collapse.
This leaves the political leaders in a difficult situation. Should they take the gamble
that the bankers are exaggerating? Should they believe the bankers and bail them out?
Bailouts create moral hazard, as defined in Section 7.2. This arises when the gov-
ernment is unable to properly price the bailout, something it usually cannot do. If
policymakers appear to be willing to bail out the banks, the banks are encouraged to
take on more risk in the future. If creditors believe that a financial institution will be
bailed out, they will factor that in when pricing credit extended to the institution. In
other words, if a bank can be expected to be bailed out, it can borrow more cheaply
than if bailing out is unlikely. This also reduces the incentives of creditors to monitor
and discipline the bank. This means that bailouts provide perverse incentives and
increase financial fragility.
However, if the authorities do not bail out the banks, the country risks a systemic
crisis. The total breakdown of payments systems and the inability of individuals and
firms to receive funds and make purchases is not pleasant to contemplate. During the
Great Depression, the last time we faced a global financial crisis, it may have been
possible for the economy to function without a banking system. People had access
to basic necessities such as food without banks. In the modern, highly linked world,
financial services are much more interwoven into the economy, and very few peo-
ple or companies could survive long without banking services. This means that the
Chapter 14 Bailouts
authorities have no choice but to do whatever they can to prevent a widespread bank-
ing collapse.
Although it is hard to justify using taxpayers’ funds to support some of the wealthi-
est segments of society, bailouts have been the usual response in crises past, and are
increasingly likely in the future. Of course, policymakers do not like being put in this
position. They may proclaim before a crisis happens that they will never do bailouts,
which if credible would constrain risk-taking. However, this threat is not particularly
credible. Therefore, it is better for the authorities to be prepared for crises, recognise
their likelihood, and have the necessary financial and legal structures in place. If well
prepared, they could aim to impose stringent conditions on the banks, protecting
taxpayers and minimising moral hazard.
Much of the damage caused by the crisis starting in 2007, and many a previous cri-
sis, is due to the authorities being woefully unprepared, because of the complacency
created by years of apparently benign economic conditions.
This suggests that when it comes to regulating the financial industry and provid-
ing bailouts, the interests of the taxpayers are at a serious disadvantage. Not only can
the banks exert targeted lobbying at the government to water down any regulations,
but the technical ability of the government to respond effectively is limited. Senior
government ministers and their advisers are unlikely to understand the underlying
problem in detail. How is the government to know whether a banker is bluffing when
saying ‘if you do not bail me out this afternoon the financial system will collapse’?
Key concepts
■ Bailouts
■ Liquidity support
■ Lending of last resort
■ Moral hazard
■ Guarantees and bubbles
■ Bailouts in the crisis from 2007
■ The ECB and European banking problems
262
14.1 Successful and unsuccessful bailouts
Sweden, 1992
Perhaps the most highly regarded example of a government bailout of the financial indus-
try is from Sweden in 1992. Sweden employed the approach of good bank – bad bank,
with the government taking over dodgy bank assets in return for significant shareholdings.
Since the government held on to the bad assets, some of which turned out to be more
valuable than envisioned, the eventual cost to the Swedish government was found by
Moe et al. (2004) to be 3.9% of GDP, significantly below the initial cost of the bailout.
Government debt increased sharply following the crisis, as seen in Figure 14.1, reaching
73%, but falling steadily to 38% in 2011.
100%
80%
60%
40% Sweden
20% Ireland
0%
1990 1995 2000 2005 2010
(a) Total (domestic plus external) gross general government debt/GDP
1000% Sweden
800% Ireland
600%
400%
200%
0%
1990 1995 2000 2005 2010
(b) Total (public plus private) gross external debt/GDP
263
Chapter 14 Bailouts
Two things from this episode stand out. First, the bailout never threatened the solvency
of the Swedish state; Standard & Poor’s rating on foreign debt dropped from AAA to AA + ,
recovering quickly back to AAA. Second, shareholders lost out since there was no bailout
of bank owners.
Ireland, 2008
The global crisis that started in 2007 was especially damaging to those countries that had
rapidly growing banking systems, like Ireland, paid for by foreign borrowing. The amounts
involved were significant, and growing rapidly as seen in Figure 14.1, where total (public plus
private) gross external debt/GDP has grown by over 12% a year over the past two decades to
over 10 times GDP. This is how Ireland got the funds to grow its banking system to become the
third largest in the European Union (EU) relative to GDP by 2007, as indicated by Figure 1.2.
During the bubble years, this created a virtuous cycle between borrowing abroad, lend-
ing the money out domestically and increasing valuations of domestic assets. Because the
valuations were based on demand fuelled by foreign money, once the money stopped
flowing, prices collapsed, causing a banking and economic crisis.
By 2008, the Irish banks were facing significant difficulties, and unable to roll over
loans. After Lehman collapsed, all funding dried up. The government at the time faced
two choices: it could let the banks default, seriously disrupting the domestic economy but
letting the bulk of the losses fall on foreign creditors; or it could provide guarantees for
bank obligations in the hope that this would reassure foreign creditors so that they would
continue providing funding, thus preventing a banking collapse. The government was pres-
sured to adopt the second option by major creditor countries, such as France, Germany
and the United Kingdom (UK), that wanted to shield their banks from the Irish problems.
The correct decision depended on the nature of the problem. If the problem was a
short-term liquidity crisis, with the Irish economy basically sound and asset valuations real-
istic, the right choice was clearly a bailout, and the government proceeded on this basis,
providing a state guarantee for all bank obligations, initially without taking over sharehold-
ers’ equity. This transferred the private bank debt to the sovereign. The government may
have analysed it in a way similar to the Copeland second generation (2G) currency crisis
model discussed in Section 12.3, considering itself to be in the multiple equilibria region of
the model, and hence being able to determine the outcome by a firm commitment.
Because of the very large scale of banking activities in Ireland, and the inability of the
Irish government to print euros to finance a bailout, substantial losses on the guaranteed
loans called into question government finances. This made the situation much more com-
plex. The debt assumed by the government has proved to be so large that it dominated
all other sources of government debt, creating serious concerns over the government’s
ability to pay. As a result, the guarantees did not restore confidence in the Irish financial
system, because concerns over bank security were replaced by concerns over the state’s
ability to meet its obligations, making it endogenous to the problem. Figure 14.1 shows
that government debt/GDP sharply increased from 25% in 2007 to 109% in 2011, beyond
its debt tolerance, so that Ireland had to be bailed out by the EU. The Irish taxpayers will
have to pay for the bank bailout for a long time to come, suffering a serious contraction in
economic performance and austerity as a consequence.
264
14.2 The historical origins of Lending of last resort (LOLR)
With the benefit of hindsight, the decision to bail out the banks in the way it was done
appears to have been a mistake. If the government was under so much pressure from the
EU that it had no choice but to do the bailout, presumably it could have demanded conces-
sions from the EU, sharing the burden. Although such a confrontational approach would
have been unpopular with other European countries, it appears that the government’s
negotiating position was quite strong. If the government had refused to bail out the banks,
they would have defaulted, but most of the losses would have fallen on foreign creditor
banks. The government could then have implemented a much cheaper bad bank – good
bank model, focusing on continuing to provide uninterrupted banking services but not
providing a blanket guarantee. It may well be that the Irish bailout will be considered as a
textbook illustration of a cardinal rule: do not attempt bailouts you cannot afford.
265
Chapter 14 Bailouts
but O&G did not recognise the losses on its books, instead carrying on as if it had no hidden
losses. When its situation became serious, it sold shares to the general public proclaiming
that the bank was safe and had no bad assets. At the time, this was legal and there was no
obligation for any firm to publish accounts or reveal its true financial situation.
In 1866, O&G collapsed in spectacular fashion. Walter Bagehot, then editor of The
Economist, wrote that the partners of the firm ran their business ‘in a manner so reck-
less and foolish that one would think a child who had lent money in the City of London
would have lent it better’.
In this case, the partners of O&G believed there would be a bailout by the BoE. A del-
egation of three bankers walked from the Bank to O&G, where a brief look at the ledgers
told them all they needed to know. O&G was broke. The Bank faced a delicate decision.
If O&G failed, there would be panic. If it was saved, the many other firms in the ‘finance’
game would also expect to be rescued. The Bank chose the former.
Because the Bank did not bail out O&G, nor provide liquidity support to other banks,
even refusing to grant loans against government securities, panic spread through the
banking system, and liquidity vanished. The market for otherwise safe assets like UK treas-
uries dried up as well.
It is not clear why the Bank took that view. Moral hazard was clearly a significant concern,
but other factors weighed on it. The BoE was a private institution competing with the likes of
O&G, and its future profits were likely to be enhanced by seeing important competitors fail.
The O&G partners were supposed to lose all of the assets in a bankruptcy. However,
this was not the case. One of the senior partners, and a member of the family, was a
Barclay who a few years later started a bank with the eponymous name. The last Overend
became the largest shareholder in that bank.
The partners of O&G eventually faced private prosecution because the government did
not feel they had done anything wrong; financial regulations and rules of conduct were
unknown at the time. The only crime they could be charged with was theft, which was
a narrowly defined concept. In the prosecution the O&G partners hired the UK govern-
ment’s senior lawyer to defend them, so that the same lawyer was representing both the
accused and the government who would judge them. They were acquitted.
266
14.3 What are bailouts?
Under the gold standard, the monetary arrangement in 1866, liquidity was gold bars.
A country had a limited supply of gold bars, so if a central bank provided liquidity to one
bank, it might not be able to provide it to another. Thus the central bank had to find a
way to ensure that only the banks that really needed liquidity got it. The penalty rate was
just a price to ration scarce liquidity so that it flowed towards the highest-value demand-
ers. The Bank Charter Act of 1844, also known as Peel’s Act, restricted the amount of
paper money that could be created (paper backed by gold), but it could be suspended in
an emergency, which happened in 1847 and 1857.
The BoE successfully dealt with the banking panics of 1878 and 1890 by following
Bagehot’s rules, while the panics of 1847, 1857 and 1866 led to acute financial crises
because the BoE hesitated to engage in LOLR. Bagehot’s analysis of the 1866 crisis, and
his recommendations for how the government should resolve crises and provide LOLR,
was the first modern analysis of financial stability and policy remedies. It has been hugely
influential and has shaped policy throughout the world ever since.
It established the doctrine of LOLR, enabling the UK to successfully deal with the crises
that came after O&G’s. The inability to provide the necessary liquidity support in the 1907
crisis in the United States led that country to finally establish a central bank explicitly to pro-
vide LOLR. The failure to follow Bagehot’s rules was a significant contributor to the Great
Depression.
Equity injections
The most obvious way to provide the bailout is by a capital injection by the government,
whereby the bank issues new shares that are bought by the government. This is the best
outcome for taxpayers because it is the only one that allows them to participate in the
upside if the bank performs well after the bailout.
267
Chapter 14 Bailouts
Ways to do bailouts
Who
Treasury Central bank Central bank
does it
Problem
Solvency Liquidity Liquidity
addressed
Equity injection
Preference shares Let all borrow
Soft loans Lower interest Only lend to
Options
Debt guarantees rates those needing
Buying problem QE funds
bank assets
The main worry about equity injections is that they represent the partial nationalisation
of the bank, with the government having the same rights as other shareholders. The gov-
ernment might be tempted to use its rights for political purposes, thus distracting the
bank from its normal mission.
Preference shares
An alternative to a direct capital injection is preference shares. These are special types of
shares that do not come with voting rights, but provide a special type of fixed dividends
with priority over regular dividends. They do not have a maturity date, and the company
can skip a payment without being declared bankrupt. We can think of preference shares
as a hybrid between debt and equity. In a bankruptcy, preference shares are prioritised
above common shares.
Loans
The third alternative is for the government to lend funds to the bank directly, replacing
funds not provided by the market. This is related to preference shares, except that the
loan will have a fixed term and will place the government higher in the repayment queue
if the institution fails.
268
14.3 What are bailouts?
Loan guarantees
The government can also guarantee that banks’ creditors get repaid, so that if the bank
fails, the government picks up the tab. If the government has a sufficiently high credit rat-
ing, it lowers the cost of funding of the bank, making it equal to that of the government.
The advantage to the government over directly lending to the bank is that the govern-
ment does not have to come up with funds immediately.
Preferences
Of these options, the bank prefers them in reverse order, with the guarantee and buying
problem assets the most desirable and the equity positions the most unpalatable. The
reason is that when the government provides equity the owner’s share is diluted. The tax-
payers have the opposite ordering of preferences. They get most for their money by direct
equity stake and least with the guarantee.
269
Chapter 14 Bailouts
system when faced with shocks by providing large amounts of liquidity. This could be
seen as a put option, insuring against bad outcomes.
The provision of liquidity is a standard central bank tool, to be used either as a part of
regular monetary policy operations or to increase liquidity in times of stress. It does, how-
ever, have two side effects.
Terms of lending
This leaves open the question of the terms on which the central bank should lend. On the
one hand, it is preventing the failure of a financial institution and not only should it be
rewarded for doing so, but the financial institution in question should be reprimanded.
This calls for high interest rates.
However, high interest rates can have adverse consequences in that they can induce
financial institutions to take on more risk than they otherwise would do. In addition, the
institution is by definition vulnerable and higher interest rates may increase that fragility,
both by increasing its cost and also because of signalling.
270
14.3 What are bailouts?
Asset choice
Another question facing the central bank is what assets to accept as collateral for the
loans it is making to the bank. Ideally, it provides loans only against very high-quality
assets such as government bonds. However, in a crisis the market is unwilling to accept
assets that normally would be easy to pledge in the markets. This means that if a central
bank insists on accepting only high-quality assets, it would be prevented from performing
its LOLR role, because the banks in need of lending are in this position precisely because
they have insufficient high-quality assets. Indeed, a common pattern in a crisis is that the
central bank starts with stringent requirements on asset quality and then slowly relaxes
them over time, perhaps accepting junk in the end.
An early example is from the 1825 crisis. This is a quote from a former director of the
BoE, Jeremiah Harman, from 1825, commenting on that year’s crisis, from Bagehot (1873):
‘We lent by every possible means and in modes we have never adopted before;
we took in stock on security, we purchased Exchequer bills, we made advances
on Exchequer bills, we not only discounted outright, but we made advances on
the deposit of bills of exchange to an immense amount, in short, by every possible
means consistent with the safety of the Bank. Seeing the dreadful state in which
the public were, we rendered every assistance in our power.’
Jeremiah Harman, 1825
The ECB
The European Central Bank (ECB) has made significant longer-term assistance to banks, as
seen later in Figure 14.7. The scope, and especially the long duration, of this programme
start to blur the distinction between a direct bailout and LOLR. A bank that needs support
for many years is no longer facing liquidity problems, rather it is more likely to be insol-
vent. This signals that the European authorities are unable to recognise the difficulties
271
Chapter 14 Bailouts
in their banking system and instead of properly resolving the crisis are using the ECB to
create ‘zombie banks’. If the authorities want to help the banks, it would be better to
recognise the problems and use taxpayers’ money directly to recapitalise them. Using the
ECB in this manner is not appropriate.
14.4.1 Bail-ins
Bail-ins were proposed by Calello and Ervin (2010) at Credit Suisse who argue that the
best way to handle a crisis at a large, systemically important bank is to force creditors,
rather than taxpayers, to assume losses if the bank gets into difficulty. This would happen
at a time when the bank is still operating as a going concern, thus preventing its failure.
The bail-ins are overseen by the regulators rather than bankruptcy courts.
There are no automatic triggers for the bail-in; instead, regulators decide when to
implement them, presumably right before collapse – one minute to midnight. That pre-
vents banks from gaming the triggers, and investors from speculating on their activation.
The idea of bail-ins is controversial, particularly with banks, which naturally expect the
possibility of their adoption to push up their funding costs.
Bail-ins do have several benefits. They prevent bankruptcies and thus circumvent
both the bankruptcy courts and more importantly cross-border issues in resolution.
Furthermore, they shield taxpayers from having to bail out banks.
Bail-ins are designed for the failure of a single bank, where the creditors are sufficiently
robust to take the hit. In a more systemic event, it is unlikely that the creditors would
effectively be able to do so, and if forced, might simply spread the systemic event to other
creditor banks and the wider economy via non-bank creditors. This means that a bail-in is
not a general substitute for a bailout, but can lower the costs associated with bank failures.
14.4.2 Forbearance
A different way to provide assistance to banks is to use forbearance and allow evergreening,
also known as ‘extend and pretend’ or ‘delay and pray’. Generally, this refers to the prac-
tice of not recognising losses on a loan and instead rolling it over when payments come
272
14.5 Bailouts in the crisis starting in 2007
due. The idea is that a bank can run down bad loans slowly and earn its way out of dif-
ficulty. While this can stave off the closure of the bank, it does not come without cost.
Evergreening makes banks’ balance sheets look arbitrarily healthy, thereby deceiving
shareholders and counterparties. Since the bank is using its limited funds to refinance bad
loans instead of using those funds to make good new ones, it reduces the overall credit in
the economy, holding back economic growth.
Evergreening is of course not a bailout, but contravenes accounting rules and prevailing
laws, and normally would be discouraged by banking supervisors. If the authorities instead
actively encourage evergreening, they are imposing a cost on the rest of the economy to
support the banks. Furthermore, evergreening can easily lead to zombie banking, as in
Japan from 1990. Of course, with near-zero interest rates the practice becomes much easier.
273
Chapter 14 Bailouts
Citigroup
JP Morgan
Wells Fargo
GMAC
0 10 20 30 40
USD billions
Figure 14.3 Largest TARP bailout recipients in the private financial sector, USD billions
Data source: propublica.org, as of 19 March 2012
700
600
Maximum
Bear Stearns
500
merger
USD billions
$687
400
300
200
Lehman
failure
100
0
2008 2009 2010
no doubt considering RFC. However, the Fed was forced to do so under the Freedom of
Information Act, after a lawsuit brought by Bloomberg.
This programme, in its various forms, was much more comprehensive than TARP.1
Below, we present information from three of the largest facilities,2 with Figure 14.4 show-
ing the aggregated amounts.
The programme started at the end of 2007, and peaked at the end of 2008, the worst
time of the global crisis. At that time, the Fed had around $700 billion outstanding, but
starting from early 2009 the numbers tapered off, and by the second quarter of 2010 all
loans had been paid off.
The largest amounts outstanding were on 4 December 2008. Figure 14.5 shows the
largest borrowers at that time. Citigroup was not surprisingly the largest, with $61 billion,
1
See www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/reform_transaction.htm for more information.
2
Term Auction Facility, Primary Dealer Credit Facility, and Term Securities Lending Facility.
274
14.5 Bailouts in the crisis starting in 2007
Citigroup
RBS
Bank of America
Wachovia
Wells Fargo
Merrill Lynch
Credit Suisse
Barclays
Goldman Sachs
Deutsche Bank
0 10 20 30 40 50 60
USD billions
Figure 14.5 Largest borrowers from Fed emergency lending, outstanding loans on
4 December 2008, USD billions
Data source: The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
Citigroup
Bank of America
RBS
Wells Fargo
Barclays
JP Morgan
Dexia
HBOS
Figure 14.6 Profit of largest recipients from Fed emergency lending, USD billions
Data source: Bloomberg (2011)
but more surprisingly was followed by a foreign bank, the Royal Bank of Scotland (RBS).
Below that, well-known American and European institutions were significant borrowers,
for example Goldman Sachs at $28 billion and Deutsche Bank at $24 billion.
The interest rate on the loans was generally below market rates, in some cases only
0.01%, so the banks were able to make significant profits. Bloomberg (2011) has calcu-
lated those profits, and we report their numbers in Figure 14.6. Citigroup comes in largest
at $1.8 billion, but many others made large profits. This constituted a direct subsidy of
financial institutions at the expense of taxpayers.
275
Chapter 14 Bailouts
failure of Lehman Brothers in September 2008 that the British banks faced their largest
difficulties. The government took stakes in RBS, Lloyds TSB and HBOS in October 2008,
injecting £37 billion of capital into the three banks, leaving it with more than a 50% stake
in RBS and 43% of the combined HBOS and Lloyds TSB, after facilitating their merger.
The government subsequently allocated an additional £19 billion of capital into RBS,
increasing its stake to 84%. In addition, the BoE provided covert liquidity to some banks:
£36.6 billion for RBS and £25.4 billion for HBOS.3
1200 3000
1000 2500
Total assets
800 2000
Lending
600 1500
400 1000
200 Lending 500
Total assets
0 0
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Figure 14.7 ECB lending to banks and total assets, billion euros
Data source: ECB
3
www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm200910/cmhansrd/cm091125/debtext/91125-0004.
htm#09112522000002.
276
14.5 Bailouts in the crisis starting in 2007
14.5.4 Analysis
When the crisis started in 2007, the major central banks and financial institutions were
not prepared for a liquidity crisis. After all, such a global event had not happened in
developed economies for almost a century. The financial markets reacted in a way typical
of crises past, and liquidity disappeared. The central banks eventually reacted by provid-
ing liquidity, at first quite reluctantly but eventually supplying seemingly infinite amounts
of funds to financial institutions.
The defining event was the bailout of AIG and the failure of Lehman Brothers in
September 2008. The latter was transformational and signalled the start of the most
severe phase of the crisis, when central bank lending increased sharply. At the height of
the crisis, bank lending by both the Fed and the ECB exceeded 5% of GDP, and direct
bailouts in various forms were quite substantial.
Downsides
The authorities sent inconsistent signals, first bailing out Bear Stearns, creating the impres-
sion that any similar bank failure would be treated in the same way. When AIG failed,
they had no choice but to bail it out, but the failure of Lehman demonstrates the main
problem. While the question of whether Lehman should have been bailed out is debat-
able, and something we discuss later, it did establish the principle that the failure of a
sufficiently large bank, one that is too big to fail (TBTF), will result in a bailout.
The fact that the liquidity support was highly profitable to the receiving banks is quite
worrying, because it amplifies the moral hazard problems created by the bailout.
The efforts to draw a line under support and curtail moral hazard were unsuccessful,
instead underlining the fact that the authorities could not in practice deny support. This
weakened their bargaining position, and the generous terms of post-Lehman bailouts are
a direct result of this miscalculation.
277
Chapter 14 Bailouts
rates. While the US problem was more liquidity based, the amount of support in Europe
implies that the problem is deep-seated solvency difficulties amongst euro zone banks.
However, the European authorities are still addressing the problem as if it were a liquid-
ity crisis and seem very reluctant to face up to the real difficulties. The historical experi-
ence of banking crises suggests that decisive action is necessary to minimise the costs, and
by using the ECB to delay the inevitable, Europe is sharply increasing the eventual costs
of this banking crisis. Apparently, large parts of the European banking system would not
survive without ECB funding, meaning that these banks are, in effect, zombie banks.
There are several reasons why this might be the case. A single nation state, with its own
central bank, can act much more decisively and quickly than a group of countries with
divergent interests. This is why the US, the UK and Switzerland have addressed the prob-
lems of their banking systems much more robustly than the EU. While the EU squabbles
over which measures to take, the banking crisis continually deepens, creating a solvency
crisis out of a liquidity crisis.
If this crisis becomes another Great Depression, the inability of the EU to address its
banking and sovereign debt problems will be the main reason. The EU has the resources
to solve the problem, but what is lacking is the political will to implement the necessary
programmes.
between 2005 and 2010, while the salary of the average worker has increased by only
15%. Average bank pay was the same in 2010 as it was before the crisis in 2007.
While it might be surprising that the bankers earn the same before and after the crisis,
it is not that unexpected when one considers how aggressive they can be in getting paid.
For example, after AIG failed, the very employees in the credit default swap (CDS) divi-
sion that brought down AIG and almost the world’s financial system demanded, and got,
bonuses in the millions of dollars if they were to continue solving the mess they created.
Some got the retention bonuses and promptly left. The division’s chief executive told the
Wall Street Journal (2009a) that the ensuing public outcry ‘stunned people [working for
him] such that our wind-down has slowed down’.
Similarly, at the height of the European sovereign debt crisis, the BBC4 interviewed a
trader who said that:
‘he had been looking forward to a recession in order to profit from it. “I dream
of another moment like this”, adding: “Anybody can actually make money. It’s an
opportunity.” ’
Politicians, therefore, need to consider the moral dimension in providing bailouts in addi-
tion to what they consider rational economic arguments.
14.6.2 Challenges
The government’s problem in understanding the complexity of the financial system is
made worse by the fact that its task is more difficult than that of the banks. A bank has
only to worry about its own risk, while the government has to worry about the risk of each
and every bank, individually and in aggregate. The reason is that the endogenous risk cre-
ated by the banking system can be identified only if the financial system in its entirety is
studied. The only body with the power to do that is the supervisor.
The government’s task of effectively providing bailouts is complicated by the close con-
nections between government and industry. The financial system in many countries is
in effect an oligopoly of very large, powerful and well-connected financial institutions.
Indeed, one could say the more banks a country has, the less political power they have.
The opposite is now happening: the number of banks is falling while their size is increas-
ing, making this problem worse. The revolving door between the industry and govern-
ment in some countries can exacerbate this problem. Eventually, these problems may
lead to regulatory capture.
4
www.bbc.co.uk/news/magazine-15095191.
279
Chapter 14 Bailouts
Model
Suppose banks are perceived to operate under an implicit government guarantee but are
otherwise unregulated entities and therefore subject to severe moral hazard.
The government guarantees lead to excessive lending, creating an asset price bubble,
in a self-reinforcing process of more lending and further-rising asset prices. This will make
the financial conditions of the banks seem sounder than they actually are. At some point
the bubble bursts and asset prices plunge, making the problems facing the banks visible
and forcing them to stop operating, causing a further fall in asset prices.
Model setup
The production function – a function that provides the output of a firm, an industry, or an
entire economy for inputs under consideration – has the following quadratic form:
where P is a random variable and a and b are parameters. The economy is able to borrow
at a fixed world interest rate, which we can, without loss of generality, set to 0. Capital
will earn its marginal product, so the first derivative of (14.1) with respect to capital, the
rental per unit of capital, will be
df1K2
= a + P - 2bK
dK
We assume investors are risk neutral. In the absence of any distortions, capital will be
invested up to the point where the expected return, r, equals the cost of funds, the world
interest rate we set to 0. Therefore:
1a + E3P42 - 2bK = r = 0
Solving for K:
1a + E3P42
K =
2b
Moral hazard
At this point a large number of guaranteed financial intermediaries enter the picture.
Their liabilities are guaranteed by the government and their owners do not need to put up
any capital of their own and can simply walk away if their institutions fail.
The earnings of the financial intermediaries depend on e, with a profit for any realisa-
tion of P leading to r 7 0. The intermediaries need not consider any negative outcome
because the guarantee ensures their returns cannot be negative. Since any economic profit
will necessarily be competed away among the intermediaries, two conclusions follow:
1 All available capital K will be purchased by guaranteed intermediaries in the end and
all other agents will be driven out. This captures the extreme level of leverage of the
guaranteed intermediaries.
280
14.7 Model of asset bubbles
2 Investment is pushed up to the point where r = 0 for the highest possible value of P.
This captures the over-optimistic investment behaviour of the intermediaries.
Moral hazard decisively influences the behaviour of financial intermediaries in such a set-
ting. In normal economic conditions, investors are responding to the expected value of a cer-
tain investment. Guaranteed intermediaries, however, will focus not on the expected value of
an investment but on what Krugman terms the Pangloss value – referring to a character from
Voltaire’s Candide – which is the return that would be achieved in the most favourable case.
Suppose that a = 1, b = 0.25 and P is either 0 or 1 with both values occurring with
equal probability so that the expected value of P is E3P4 = 0.5. The undistorted
level of investment is
1 + 0.5
K = = 3
210.252
But guaranteed intermediaries will base their investment decision not on the expected
value of P = 0.5 but on the Pangloss value and therefore assume that P = 1. The
level of investment will be pushed up to
1 + 1
K = = 4
2(0.25)
The result is over-investment which lowers expected welfare because the increased loss
in the bad state will not be offset by increased gain in the good state.
t = 1 t = 2
p Outcome p Outcome
281
Chapter 14 Bailouts
In an undistorted economy we can solve backwards for the price that risk-neutral inves-
tors are willing to pay. The expected return in the last period is 50, which is consequently
the price of land purchased at the end of t = 1. At t = 0, therefore, the expected return
on land purchased is the expected return at t = 1 of 50 plus the expected selling price
at the end of t = 1, which is also 50, for an expected value at t = 0 of 100, the total
expected return over the periods.
Guaranteed intermediaries will base their investment decision not on the expected value
but on the Pangloss value – the best-outcome value independent of probabilities. Again,
working backwards, at the end of t = 1, the intermediaries are willing to pay the Pangloss
value of the third period return, which is 100. At t = 0 they will therefore be willing to
pay the most they could hope to realise in both subsequent periods, which is the Pangloss
return at t = 1 plus the Pangloss resale value at the end of t = 1, which is 100. Guaranteed
intermediaries will therefore pay 200 for one unit of land, so that in the end they will have
driven out all other investors and raised the price to double what it would have been in an
undistorted economy. Figure 14.8 shows the Pangloss values for the three periods.
Analysis
The central message of this simple model is the adverse impact caused by government
guarantees of banks. Because creditors assume they will be bailed out, they are willing
200
Expected value
150
Pangloss value
100
50
0
Period 0 Period 1 Period 2
282
14.8 Summary
to lend to banks at low interest rates even though they think the banks’ investments
are bad.
In addition, these guarantees give banks an incentive to price risky investments with
over-optimistic assumptions. Any kind of activity involving uncertain but diminishing
returns to capital – almost all activities – will as a consequence see higher levels of invest-
ment than would be made by equity investors focusing on expected returns. Nor do the
banks’ creditors have any incentive to withdraw funding.
This has two adverse impacts for society. First, it encourages excessive risk-taking at the
expense of the taxpayer, a classic form of moral hazard. Second, it leads to asset price
bubbles that are destined to burst, destabilising financial markets on the way up and
causing a crisis on the way down.
14.8 Summary
Governments often find it necessary to bail out private financial institutions in order to
prevent an individual failure becoming a full-blown financial crisis. There is a right way
and a wrong way to implement bailouts, with the Swedish government’s actions in 1992 a
model of a successful bailout, and the Irish bailout of 2008 less successful.
The main issue in bailouts is moral hazard where the expectation of government sup-
port induces financial institutions to take more risk.
The first formal government bailout policy was LOLR, formulated after the 1866 crisis.
Bailouts have been used frequently, both before and after that date, for example, during
the crisis from 2007 where central banks in effect replaced the interbank markets and
large financial institutions received bailouts, most significantly AIG.
Bailouts can take many forms, in particular direct bailouts, LOLR and liquidity pro-
vision. The damage from bank failures can be mitigated by bail-ins and banks can be
helped by regulatory forbearance. In implementing bailouts, it is important to distinguish
between illiquidity and insolvency, even though conceptually their boundary is a broad
grey area and identifiable only in extreme cases.
We demonstrated a simple model of how government guarantees can lead to asset
price bubbles, which contributed to the 2007 crisis and is of continuing concern given the
apparent determination of governments to prevent private sector bank losses.
283
Chapter 14 Bailouts
6 Should the central bank charge a penalty rate when doing LOLR?
7 Does the existence of LOLR encourage excessive risk taking?
8 How could the problem of moral hazard associated with bailouts be reduced?
9 Should the bailout be based on banks’ size or interconnectedness? Offer one example
for each form of bailout.
10 How can we justify using taxpayers’ money to bail out those who own and run banks,
especially when the bank owners and managers represent one of the richest segments
of the population, who then receive a transfer from their poorer countrymen?
11 What are the main arguments for keeping bailouts secret and the main arguments for
making them public?
12 If a central bank provides liquidity assistance to banks, what should the time span for
the assistance be?
13 What is your view on the ECB liquidity programmes?
14 What is a Pangloss value?
15 How can the concept of Pangloss value be used to explain the behaviour of investors?
Is it rational?
(a) Consider a two-period model with an initial investment at t = 0 and returns in
p
eriods t = 1 and t = 2. With probability p the returns will be y, otherwise the
returns will be x. The following holds: x 7 y and 0.5 7 p 7 1. What is the value
of the return that investors can expect? What is the Pangloss value?
(b) The government explicitly guarantees all investments, so that investors at t = 0
bid up the price to the Pangloss value. Now the government announces that it will
bail out investors only once and will then withdraw all guarantees. Show that this
leads to a situation of multiple equilibria.
(c) Prove that the government guarantee at t = 0 makes losses worse if things turn out to
be bad in t = 1 than they would have been without any explicit or implicit guarantees.
References
Bagehot, W. (1873). Lombard Street: a Description of the Money Market. H.S. King, London.
Bloomberg (2011). Secret Fed loans undisclosed to Congress gave banks $13 billion in income.
www.bloomberg.com/news/2011-11-28/secret-fed-loans-undisclosed-to-congress-gave-
banks-13-billion-in-income.html.
Calello, P. and Ervin, W. (2010). From bail-out to bail-in. The Economist, 28 January.
Capie, F. and Wood, G. E. (2006). The Lender of Last Resort. Routledge.
Elliot, G. (2006). Overend & Gurney, a Financial Scandal in Victorian London. Methuen.
Goodhart, C. (1999). Myths about the lender of last resort. Technical report FMG SP 120,
London School of Economics. http://fmg.lse.ac.uk/pdfs/sp120.pdf.
Krugman, P. (1998). What happened to Asia? Mimeo, MIT.
Moe, T. G., Solheim, J. A. and Vale, B. (2004). The Norwegian banking crisis. Technical report,
Norges Bank. Occasional Paper no. 33.
Stiglitz, J. (2009). Obama’s ersatz capitalism. www.nytimes.com/2009/04/01/opinion/01stiglitz.
html?_r=1&scp=2&sq=stiglitz&st=cse.
Wall Street Journal (2009a). Action on AIG unit may cost taxpayers. Wall Street Journal, 13 April.
online.wsj.com/article/ SB123957925343711995.html.
284
15 Dangerous financial instruments
Financial institutions are continually creating ever more complex financial instru-
ments, motivated by potential profits from new types of trading strategies, the ability
to market new instruments to their clients, to move risk off their balance sheets, or
to hide the risk-taking activity from other parts of the institution, supervisors and cli-
ents. While the new instruments may be highly profitable during boom times, they
also act as enablers for excessive risk-taking and as accelerators for small events to
spill out of control. They can contribute directly to financial crises, just one exam-
ple being their role in the crisis from 2007 which included new instruments like
CDOs, CDSs, SIVs and conduits. This is why we might term them dangerous financial
instruments.
These dangerous instruments undermined the extensive monitoring process we
had implemented to prevent the excessive build-up of systemic risk-taking. They did
that by enabling banks to spin off a part of their balance sheet, helping banks to
do more business and take on more risk with the same amount of capital, and even
replacing bank supervisors with more emollient rating agencies.
The main problem arises because of the complexity of the financial instruments.
Not only is it hard for non-experts to understand the inherent riskiness, but the finan-
cial instruments often depend on a number of assumptions about the stochastic
behaviour of market variables and the estimation of complicated statistical models.
In this process there are many things that can go wrong. The designer of the product
may not understand all the issues, the underlying assumptions are likely to be inad-
equate, and the statistical models will be estimated with significant degrees of uncer-
tainty. In short, these instruments are priced and their risk is assessed with complex
Chapter 15 Dangerous financial instruments
statistical models, and since every statistical model is wrong by definition, prices and
risk will similarly be incorrectly imputed.
The underlying modelling weaknesses are masked by high profits during boom
times. A large adverse shock may be required to lay bare the mistaken model assump-
tions. The main problem is that this is most likely to happen when the financial sys-
tem is already heading into a crisis, so that a reassessment of the riskiness of these
instruments becomes part of a vicious endogenous risk feedback loop between reas-
sessment, institutional difficulty and prices.
Fundamentally, the main problem of the dangerous financial instruments is that
they ignore the likelihood of systemic losses.
Key concepts
■ Complexity
■ Derivatives
■ Credit default swaps
■ Collateralised debt obligations
■ Special investment vehicles
■ Conduits
■ Rating agencies
g
R Default correlation
Covariance matrix
𝚽1 # 2 Standard normal distribution
f1 # 2 Standard normal density
A 1R
286
15.1 Complexity kills
287
Chapter 15 Dangerous financial instruments
15.2 Derivatives
‘Derivatives are financial weapons of mass destruction, carrying dangers that, while
now latent, are potentially lethal.’
Warren Buffett (2003)
Derivatives are securities that derive their value from something else, called the underlying
asset. The underlying asset is commonly another security, perhaps shares in IBM, a physical
asset like bushels of wheat or a non-traded financial asset such as a bundle of mortgage loans.
The underlying asset can also be something abstract, like the occurrence of an event or the
prevalence of a special state of the world. For example, there are weather derivatives whose
value depends on the temperature or rainfall in some place over a particular period, and credit
derivatives whose value hinges on whether a firm files for bankruptcy in a set timeframe. Fixed-
income instruments are one type of derivatives, their underlying asset being the interest rate.
Different sorts of derivatives are designed for different purposes. Many derivatives con-
tracts were originally designed to bring together parties exposed to offsetting risks so that
they could net them out, a practice called hedging. Others provide optionality, build in
leverage, or create exposures to risks otherwise not tradable in financial markets.
Derivatives carry with them significant hidden dangers. Not only do they allow highly
leveraged bets on financial markets, but also the risk is often deeply hidden.
Volume
The volume of trading in derivatives markets has grown significantly over the past few
years. The Bank for International Settlements (BIS) collects data on the volume of deriva-
tives trading, shown in Figure 15.1. Figure 15.1(a) shows the total notional amounts, or
the face amounts, used to calculate payments. This amount does not change hands.
60
400 FX
FX, CDS
Interest
Interest
300 40
CDS
200
20
100
15 Interest
Interest
3
10 CDS
2
5 1
288
15.3 Credit default swaps
By contrast, Figure 15.1(b) shows the gross amount, which is the sum of the value of contracts
owned by a financial institution, without taking netting into account. Therefore, it shows the
worst-case situation of what happens when counterparties default and loss is 100%.
The amounts are shown in trillions of dollars, and we see that the notional amounts
significantly exceed the global GDP of about $60 trillion. The more important gross
amounts are slightly less than half the global GDP. The rapid growth over just a few years
is a significant concern, and the lack of concern by the world’s policymakers prior to the
crisis starting in 2007 is itself a cause for concern.
‘catastrophic enabler of the dark forces that have swept through financial markets’.
‘They are, says a former securities regulator, a “Ponzi Scheme” that no self-respecting
firm should touch. [. . .] Alan Greenspan, who used to be a cheerleader, has dis-
owned them in “shocked disbelief”. They have even been ridiculed on “Saturday
Night Live”, an American TV show.’
Much of the criticism relates to the fact that the CDS market had blossomed without
much oversight, allowing the sellers of CDSs to amass excessive amounts of risk. At the
same time, the fact that CDSs are OTC instruments implies that the market for them is
fairly non-transparent, so it is difficult to identify net exposure.
What is a CDS?
A CDS is an instrument providing insurance that protects the buyer of the CDS against the
default of some third party called the reference entity. Suppose a bank owns a high-risk
bond and wishes to hedge that risk. The bank, known as the protection buyer, would enter
into a contract with another institution, the protection seller. The protection buyer pays a
regular fee to the protection seller until the CDS expires, unless a credit event happens,
which could be a default but might also include other occurrences. In this case, the protec-
tion seller would buy the risky bond at par value from the protection seller and no more
payments take place. This is described in Figure 15.2. For detailed information on how
CDSs are created, see Appendix A. In some cases, when the reference entity is high risk, all
the fees may be up front. This, for example, has been the case for some Greek CDSs.
289
Chapter 15 Dangerous financial instruments
Annual
payments
Protection Protection
buyer seller
(a) No default
Par value
of bond
Protection Protection
buyer seller
(b) Default
Benefits of CDSs
In principle, CDSs are quite useful instruments, allowing users to trade and manage credit
risk separately from other risks and cash flows. They provide an efficient way to hedge
credit risk, spreading risk to those best able to assume that risk, and allowing users to effi-
ciently diversify and tailor risk-taking. CDSs also enable speculation, in principle, increas-
ing the efficiency of financial markets.
290
15.3 Credit default swaps
Creditor Bank A
Creditor Bank B
Creditor Bank B
Bank C
Information
asymmetry
Bank B
Step 4 To hedge its exposure, bank B buys a CDS from bank C. Now A, B and C are all
exposed to each other. This is shown in Figure 15.4.
Throughout this process, the gross amount increases with each step, but the net
amount remains the original exposure to the creditor, who after all has paid back the loan
so the net exposure in the system is zero. This problem is shown in Figure 15.4, showing
the gross exposures and the zero net. This creates a chain of vulnerabilities, contributing
to the problem of interconnectedness in the financial system, creating systemic risk.
Consequently, the failure of a major dealer would have major repercussions for the rest
of the market participants, exactly the problem created by AIG and Lehman. Furthermore,
because CDS contracts are not cleared on a clearinghouse, they are not government regu-
lated, nor standardised, making it very difficult to calculate net obligations. There are no
public records showing whether sellers have the assets to pay out if a bond defaults.
291
Chapter 15 Dangerous financial instruments
It is difficult to develop a clear picture of which institutions are the ultimate holders of
some of the credit risk transferred. It can even be difficult to quantify the amount of risk
that has been transferred. This is the main systemic risk posed by CDSs.
Related to this is the problem that the protection seller might need to come up with
significant funds during a crisis episode, when it and the financial system are under stress.
Perverse incentives
A CDS affects normal incentives in financial markets. It can create moral hazard since
the initial lender has less incentive to ensure the quality of the underlying loans and
monitor the borrower if the risk is sold off to a third party, who probably has less infor-
mation about the borrower than the initial lender. This can lead to a lower quality of
loans.
CDSs also provide perverse incentives for creditors. Pragmatic lenders who hedge their
economic exposure through CDSs can often make higher returns from CDS payouts than
from out-of-court restructuring plans. Bankruptcy codes assume that creditors always
attempt to keep solvent firms out of bankruptcy; however, if a creditor holds a CDS it may
be more profitable to trigger a bankruptcy even if that significantly reduces the amount of
money received by bondholders.
This may have been behind the bankruptcy of Six Flags, a failed American theme-park
operator, as noted by The Economist (2009) where the Fidelity mutual fund turned down
an offer that would have granted unsecured creditors an 85% equity stake, and as a con-
sequence uninsured bondholders will receive less than 10% of the equity now that Six
Flags has filed for protection.
‘I think that derivative products [such as] the CDS on sovereign debt have to be at
least very, very regulated, rigorously regulated, limited or banned [. . .]’
Christine Lagarde, former French minister and now managing
director of the International Monetary Fund (IMF),
quoted in the Financial Times (2010a)
The EU has decided to impose a permanent ban on naked CDSs, strongly supported by
Germany and opposed by the UK.
292
15.4 Collateralised debt obligations
‘These balanced measures will ensure that sovereign CDS are used for the purpose
for which they were designed, hedging against the risk of sovereign default, without
putting at risk the proper functioning of sovereign debt markets [. . .] Short selling
did not cause the crisis, but can aggravate price declines in distressed markets.’
Michel Barnier (2011), commissioner for the single market
Naked CDSs, however, are not the evil instrument the politicians sometimes make
them out to be. A European Commission report concluded that CDSs had no adverse
impact on bond markets, where the prices of CDSs and sovereign debt largely moved in
tandem. These issues are discussed by Duffie (2010).
Banning naked CDSs could also deepen a crisis. Market participants might have an
indirect exposure to a counterparty. Furthermore, by banning naked CDSs, market par-
ticipants might attempt to reconstruct the hedge by other means, perhaps by shortening
government bonds or bank equities or otherwise reducing their exposure. Because such
activities would be less visible, it would be typical of regulations driving risk-taking under-
ground, reducing transparency and financial stability.
Definition 15.1 Tranche A tranche, French for slice, is a particular slice of the risk,
and hence payments flow from a CDO. Tranches often get the same credit rating as regular
bonds. The main tranches are:
■ Super senior (AAA)
■ Senior notes (AA)
■ Mezzanine (A to BB)
■ Equity (unrated), a.k.a. toxic waste.
Higher-rated (senior) tranches get paid before lower-ranked mezzanine tranches, with any
residual cash flow paid to an equity tranche.
Tranches are usually sold separately. The CDO structure allows the senior tranches to
obtain credit ratings in excess of the average rating on the collateral pool as a whole,
because of an assumption of diversification within the pool of assets.
Maximising the size of desirable tranches is a key objective of the designers of CDOs.
Often, the mezzanine tranches are the easiest to sell, with the sponsoring bank left hold-
ing the super senior and equity tranches. This depends on buyer preference, however,
293
Chapter 15 Dangerous financial instruments
and in many cases the AAA and AA tranches are easiest to place because buyers simply
count the As (see safety) while mezzanine investors do more modelling. By retaining AAA
tranches, the sponsoring bank might obscure its profits on the structure, by selling it later
and booking it as separate profit.
Assets Tranches
Special
$100 million
purpose Mezzanine
of subprime
vehicle BBB $1.6 million
mortgages
(SPV)
Equity
(toxic waste)
$8.6 million
294
15.4 Collateralised debt obligations
concentrating the probability of default in the equity tranche, composed of $50 mil-
lion. Provided the underlying mathematical assumptions are correct, in particular the
probability of default is actually 25% and the bonds are uncorrelated, the tranching is
correct.
8
6
4
2
0
0% 1% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 80%
Probability of default
295
Chapter 15 Dangerous financial instruments
Probability
rho = 0.2 rho = 0.6 rho = 1
40%
20%
0%
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Defaults
(a) All outcomes
4%
Probability
2%
0%
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Defaults
(b) Focus on bottom 5%
r Probability of defaults
8 - 10 6 -7
0% 0.04% 1.93%
20% 1.46% 6.84%
40% 4.77% 8.83%
60% 9.15% 8.59%
80% 14.47% 6.70%
100% 25.00% 0.00%
Table 15.2 presents the same information in a different way, focusing on what happens
to the sizes for the AAA and mezzanine tranches when the correlations increase, com-
pared to the benchmark case where the correlations equal 0.
296
15.4 Collateralised debt obligations
which keeps track of US recessions. The biggest boom years in the subprime market were
entirely recession-free. Since mortgage defaults are highly dependent on the state of the
economy, the estimation of default correlations would have been skewed towards zero.
Even if the sample contained a downturn, it would be difficult to estimate the correla-
tions because, as noted by Duffie (2007), there is a serious shortage of good models for
estimating default correlations.
The problem of correlated defaults is worse than this, because even if accurate correl-
ation estimates had been available, so long as the industry used Gaussian copula meth-
ods the dependence in mortgage defaults would still have been underestimated. The
reason is that the Gaussian copula assumes constant correlations regardless of the state of
the economy, while in actuality the correlations are much higher in downturns. The tech-
nical name for this is non-linear dependence (discussed in Section 3.3.1) and an asym-
metric copula, properly taking this into account, is much more accurate. Unfortunately,
it is very challenging to use such asymmetric copulae, not least because it is difficult to
identify the best copula to use unless very large amounts of data are used, much more
than are available.
Optimisation
Certain tranches of CDOs are more valuable than others. This means that banks might
want to maximise the size of these tranches at the expense of the rest. This is known as
optimising the CDO structure. In order to facilitate this process, the rating agencies supplied
297
Chapter 15 Dangerous financial instruments
the banks with computer software enabling them to optimise the CDOs in-house before
they were submitted to the rating agency.
This undermines the integrity of the whole process. The assignment of probabilities to
the various tranches using the mathematical approach discussed above is correct condi-
tional on the assets put into it. If the assets are preselected to maximise certain tranches,
the probability assignments are biased. This is a variant of data mining as studied in
econometrics.
A related and perhaps even more important problem is that the optimisation of the
structure also minimises the quality of the asset pool. In other words, if the sponsor wants
to optimise ratings, the cheapest way is to use assets with high loss given default and
assets that have higher default correlations than are assumed in the modelling. This in
turn affects the true value of all the tranches.
The end result is that before 2007, sponsors demanded assets that were high risk, with
low expected recovery rates and high default correlations and probability of default, in
other words, garbage assets. If one of the criteria for high profits is maximising the use of
garbage assets, it should not come as a surprise that this all ends in tears.
A CDO has many parallels with fractional reserve banking, and one could easily view
a CDO as a type of bank. For example, both are subject to the same fundamental fra-
gility in an economic downturn. A bank is vulnerable to a run and a CDO is sensitive
to downgrades on the ratings of the tranches and funding problems as the probability
of default or the correlations increase. This applies especially to conduits and SIVs
(see below).
Both fractional reserve banks and CDOs substitute idiosyncratic risk with systemic
risk. The reason is that both are vulnerable to idiosyncratic risk factors, perhaps
298
15.4 Collateralised debt obligations
problems facing an individual bank or bad CDO modelling. This may enable a rela-
tively small idiosyncratic problem to undermine confidence in the banking system,
spreading and amplifying idiosyncratic risk to systemic proportions.
Rating agencies
The rating agencies are private firms whose job it is to provide investors with information
about the credit quality of financial instruments being offered.
For corporate bonds, especially in the US, investors can rely on over 80 years of rat-
ings history to assess the quality of ratings, and thereafter make an independent deter-
mination of ratings quality. For bonds in other countries, both corporate and sovereign,
the ratings history is much shorter, usually much less than two decades, making it much
harder to ascertain ratings quality.
It is, however, with the various credit instruments where the ratings have been most
severely criticised. The ratings on the many CDO-type instruments were significantly
lacking in quality, ignoring the impact of correlations and how such instruments con-
centrate catastrophe risk. The market for dangerous credit instruments was fuelled by
over-optimistic ratings, and the ratings agencies failed in their mission of providing inde-
pendent quality advice to investors.
There is evidence that rating agencies made significant mistakes. For example, in May
2008, Moody’s acknowledged that it had given AAA ratings to billions of dollars of struc-
tured finance products due to a bug in one of its rating models. In March 2007, First Pacific
Advisors discovered that Fitch used a model assuming home prices could only increase.
Conduits
A conduit is a simple structure involving a bank that sells some assets to a SPV, for example
credit card receivables, loans or mortgages, in other words, various asset backed securi-
ties (ABSs). The conduit issues an asset-backed commercial paper (ABCP) to fund perhaps
90% or more of the purchases, the rest coming from its equity. The payments from the
assets first go to pay interest on the ABCP; any excess belongs to the equity holder. The
ABCP pays interest based on short-term rates, whereas the return from the assets is based
on longer-term rates. The conduit’s net interest income is comprised of a term structure
component (long rates – short rates) and a credit spread component. The ABCP is usually
AAA-rated due to over-collateralisation, so the cost of funding is low.
The sponsor guarantees funding for the SPV, so if it is unable to borrow sufficient
amounts of money at reasonable terms, the sponsor steps in and funds the SPV. These
liquidity guarantees provide a steady profit to the sponsor when times are good, but sub-
ject it to significant liquidity risk, realised at the worst time when the markets are already
in turmoil.
299
Chapter 15 Dangerous financial instruments
We can compare traditional banking with conduit banking, by considering the main
balance sheet items:
The conduit bank has direct parallels with a traditional bank, and is subject to
the same main risk factors: default risk, bank runs (liquidity risk) and maturity mis-
matches. The problem is that the vulnerabilities of the conduit bank are less visible
and understood than the vulnerabilities of the traditional bank, and the regulatory
ways to address them less developed.
In good times, structures like conduits allow banks to enhance their earnings by ben-
efiting from the return of the conduit’s assets without having to hold the asset themselves.
This means that banks can avoid regulatory capital requirements on those assets.
If the bank retains the equity portion, it retains most of the risk, both from losses on the
assets and also from the liquidity guarantees. However, the exposure to the conduit was
not covered by bank regulations before 2007, Basel I. This enabled the bank to take more
leverage and more risk than regulations would otherwise allow.
SIVs
A structured investment vehicle (SIV) is similar to a conduit, but rather than just having
equity and ABCP in its capital structure, it also has a mezzanine level, so that senior debt
can be highly rated despite there being only a small amount of equity. This allows greater
leverage. The mezzanine notes are typically of longer duration. They provide higher-
yieldingand longer-term instruments for investors seeking something riskier than ABCP.
Liquidity risks
Perhaps the main danger in these structures from a financial stability point of view is the hid-
den liquidity risk. The sponsoring banks generally provide backup liquidity lines, guaranteeing
funds to the structure if it is unable to raise money elsewhere at reasonable rates. This has two
purposes: first, it increases the security and attractiveness of the structure, and secondly it
provides fees to the sponsor for providing the backup line. Even though the backup lines were
quite risky to provide, they did not attract regulatory capital. This meant that these structures
had a direct advantage over other forms of risk-taking, which generally require capital.
SIVs and conduits face serious funding liquidity risks. Their funding is short term, being
rolled over frequently, often every three months. They are also highly sensitive to lenders’
confidence in their structure, as the ability to borrow depends on the credit quality, since
ABCP investors want to be convinced that the vehicle’s assets are worth significantly more
than the ABCP. If asset values dip even a little, it may suddenly be impossible to roll funding
300
Appendix A: Mechanics of CDSs
over. An ABCP buyer’s strike is therefore the equivalent of a bank run. In this case, the vehicles
may be forced to draw upon the backup liquidity line provided by the sponsoring bank.
In the end, it was the need to fund the structures at a time when the crisis had already
started and funding was scarce, that caused significant problems in 2007, for example
triggering the failure of IKB.
While the crisis started in the US, it quickly crossed the Atlantic, and seemed to affect
medium-sized European banks especially badly. IKB, a small, partly state-owned
German bank, was the first European victim of the subprime crisis. It had created a
conduit some years earlier, and at the start of the crisis the assets held by the conduit
suffered losses. Consequently, the conduit was unable to roll over its loans and had
to draw on its credit line from IKB. The amount of money required was beyond the
ability of IKB to provide, and it eventually received a bailout from private entities and
the government amounting to €5 billion.
15.5 Summary
Complexity in financial instruments can be quite profitable when things are good, but
make financial institutions much more vulnerable both to an individual shock and espe-
cially to a systemwide shock.
The growth in volume of the various complex instruments has been exponential in
recent years, especially that of CDSs. This is an instrument that significantly contributed
to the crisis beginning in 2007, not least because of its OTC nature and general lack of
transparency.
Another complex instrument that has proven to be quite dangerous is the CDO. The rea-
son is that CDOs often contained a significant number of subprime mortgages, and mistakes
in modelling created the illusion that high-risk assets could be repackaged into safe assets.
Two financial instruments caused significant problems in the early days of the crisis,
SIVs and conduits, not least because of the embedded but hidden liquidity guarantees.
The rating agencies rated the tranches of the structured credit products with the same
rating categories as corporate bonds, but it turned out that the risk characteristics of these
two asset types were fundamentally different.
301
Chapter 15 Dangerous financial instruments
Typically, the reference instrument will be a debt security or a loan, where the allowed
credit events include default, so the protection seller will compensate the protection
buyer if the reference entity defaults. After a credit event, the holder of the reference
instrument will get the recovery value, so the protection seller will suffer a loss of par
minus recovery. Unlike a typical option, the premium on a CDS is usually paid periodi-
cally and this payment terminates in the event of a default.
The range of credit events on a CDS is usually chosen from bankruptcy, obligation
default, violation of covenant, repudiation/moratorium, restructuring, reduction in inter-
est or principal, or the lowering of seniority.
Terminology
‘Buy’ means buying protection:
■ Pay premium
■ Receive default payment if credit event occurs
■ Sells/hedges credit risk
■ Equivalent to selling a bond.
■ Receive premium
■ Pay default payment if credit event occurs
■ Buys/takes on credit risk
■ Equivalent to buying a bond.
An example
Suppose that two parties enter into a five-year credit default swap on 1 September 2012.
Assume that the notional principal is $100 million and the buyer agrees to pay 90 basis
points 190100 of 1%2 annually for protection against default by the reference entity. The
CDS is shown in Figure 15.8.
302
Appendix B: CDO calculations
Payment if default by
reference entity
If there is no credit event, the buyer receives zero payoff and pays $900,000
1$100,000,000 * 0.0092 on 1 September in each of the years 2013, 2014, 2015, 2016 and
2017. If there is a credit event, a substantial payoff is likely. Suppose the buyer notifies the
seller of a credit event on 1 April 2014. If the contract specifies physical settlement, and
the reference entity is a bond, the buyer has the right to sell bonds to the writer issued by
the reference entity at the full face value of $100 million.
If the contract specifies cash settlement, an independent calculation agent will poll
dealers to determine the mid-market value of the cheapest deliverable bond a predesig-
nated number of days after the credit event. Suppose this bond is worth $35 per $100 of
face value, then the cash payoff would be $65 million 1$100 million - $35 million2. The
total amount paid per year, as a percentage of the notional principal, to buy protection is
known as the CDS spread. We can calculate the implied probability of default from the
CDS spreads.
n
a b =
n! , a3b = 3
k k!1n - k2! 2
where n is the total number of elements and k the desired number of elements we want
in a combination, K is the random variable, and k the outcome.
But how to get the probabilities? The outcomes are binomially distributed. The prob-
ability of exactly k outcomes in a sample of size n with independent probabilities pd is
n
g1k n, pd2 = Pr1K = k2 = a b pdk 11 - pd2n - k (15.1)
k
303
Chapter 15 Dangerous financial instruments
0 0.729 0.729
1 0.243 0.972
2 0.027 0.999
3 0.001 1.000
where g() denotes the binomial density. This gives 2.7% in our example. In our case, we
are more interested in at least k defaults in a sample of n, that is, the binomial distribu-
tion, G(), with the outcomes shown in Table 15.3:
For simplicity, assume that if the benchmark corporate bond defaults, there is no recov-
ery, so for a $1 million AAA bond:
304
Appendix B: CDO calculations
The SPV has a net inflow of $12 million 110 * $10 million * 0.122 if all goes well, but
there is considerable risk that some of the loans will default so that it is very unlikely that
all the money will come in.
From Table 15.4, the probability of all 10 bonds defaulting is 9.54 * 10-7. The prob-
ability of 9 or 10 bonds defaulting is 9.54 * 10-7 + 2.86 * 10-5. This number is recorded
in the last column of Table 15.4. Going up the table, the probability of 8 to 10 bonds
defaulting is 4.158 * 10-4 6 0.003, while the probability of 7 to 10 bonds defaulting is
0.00351 7 0.003. To summarise:
This means that the probability of getting $3.6 million 13 * $10 million * 0.122
in interest payments from the SPV, 99.958%, is higher than the probability of get-
ting paid from the AAA bond, 99.3%, while the probability of getting $4.8 million
14 * $10 million * 0.122 in interest payments from the SPV, 99.65%, is lower than the
AAA default probability. We conclude that the payment flow from the first three bonds
gets an AAA rating. Similarly for the BBB:
Of the flow from the first five bonds that is less risky than the corresponding BBB, three
are AAA, so the flow from the next two bonds gets BBB.
Tranching
We can tranche the payments in the following way. The SPV has a net inflow of $12 mil-
lion from interest payments 110 * $10 million * 0.122, plus principal, if all goes well.
Flow from the first three bonds, $3.6 million 13 * $10 million * 0.122 + principal, is
safer than AAA, so that it gets AAA rating. An investor will get the AAA interest rate, or 6%
plus the principal back ($30 million).
Flow from the next two bonds, $2.4 million 12 * $10 million * 0.122 + principal,
gets a BBB rating. An investor will get the BBB interest rate, or 8% plus the principal back
($20 million).
The rest of the flow, $12 - $1.8 - $1.6 = $8.6 million + principal, goes to the equity
investor. As she has rights to the last $50 million, her interest rate is 17.2%.
X ∼ n10, 12
Suppose the probability of default is pd. We can then say that default happens if the out-
come of the random variable is below the inverse normal distribution at the probability pd;
if X … Φ-1(pd2 default
if X 7 Φ-11pd2 no default
305
Chapter 15 Dangerous financial instruments
where Φ is the normal distribution (CDF). Therefore, we have a simple way to deal with
the probability of defaults mathematically, most importantly since this framework ena-
bles us to incorporate correlated defaults, via the Gaussian copula, quite easily. In this
case, we need to make the random variable X correlated across multiple assets. This
means that if we observe a low value of X for one asset, and hence observe a default, we
are more likely to see the same for different assets (if the correlations are positive).
Generally speaking, suppose we have N assets, then we would say that the random
variable X is an N * 1 vector, with each element corresponding to an asset. Therefore, X
X ∼ n10, g2
has the distribution
where g is the covariance matrix. However, we want to consider a simpler case, where the
correlations are all constant, denoted by r. We then have in the three-asset case:
g = c rs2s1
s21 rs1s2 rs1s3
s22 rs2s3 s
rs3s1 rs3s2 s23
This means it is relatively straightforward to set up the problem using common factors,
where the outcome for each asset has two components: the first is the common factor
and the second is idiosyncratic. In our setup, we have constant correlations, so we get:
a = 1r
xi = af + 21 - a2Pi outcome for bond
(15.2)
F ∼ n10, 12 common factor
Zi ∼ n10, 12 idiosyncratic shock
where the factor is F, with common outcome f, whilst the idiosyncratic shock is ei. We
then have that the probability of default conditional on the factor f is
Pr1xi 6 Φ-11pd2 f2
From (15.2) we have that the probability of default, conditional on the factor f, is
Φ-11pd2 - af
Pr1xi 6 Φ-11pd2 f2 = Φ a b
21 - a2
= pd f
We are still left with the factor. Conditional on f we can get the expected cashflow from
the portfolio (and indeed the entire distribution, perhaps for risk analysis). Suppose we
want the probability of k defaults. From (15.1) we get:
n
g1k n, pd, f2 = a b 1pd f2k11 - pd f2n - k
k
306
Appendix B: CDO calculations
L-∞
g1k n, pd, f2f1f 2df
2 Is the rapid growth of derivatives over the past few decades a cause for concern?
3 There are some proposals for using structured credit products to solve the EU sovereign
debt problem. What sort of product could they be, why are they proposed, and would
they work?
5 The EU has effectively prohibited CDSs on European sovereign debt. It argues that the
CDS market contributes to the crisis. Do you agree?
7 How can we use CDOs to turn high-risk assets into safe assets?
9 Some commentators have said that CDOs, especially those containing subprime assets,
are the equivalent of catastrophe insurance, in particular, the highest rated tranches.
Identify the arguments in favour of the statement.
12 When the crisis started in 2007 it was often blamed on US structured credit products
that crossed the Atlantic and adversely affected some European banks. What were
those products, and why were some banks so badly affected?
13 We have three subprime mortgage backed securities, S1, S2, S3, each with a par value
of 1 million dollars. Each of these securities has a 20% default probability, where the
defaults are independent across securities.
Suppose an AAA bond has a 1% probability of default, an A bond 5% and a BB bond 8%.
(a) Calculate the probability and cumulative probability of 0, 1, 2 and 3 defaults.
(b) Suppose you package the securities into a collateralised debt obligation (CDO).
How big would you make the AAA tranche?
307
Chapter 15 Dangerous financial instruments
References
Barnier, M. (2011) quoted in Barker, A., EU ban on ‘naked’ CDS to become permanent. Financial
Times, 19 October, www.ft.com/cms/s/0/cc9c5050-f96f-lle0-bf8f-00144feab49a.html.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (2009). Revenge of the steamroller: ABCP as
a window on risk choices. Unpublished paper, Division of International Finance.
Buffett, W. (2003). Avoiding a mega-catastrophe. Fortune, 24 March.
Coval, J., Jurek, J. and Stafford, E. (2008a). The economics of structured finance. Harvard
Business School Working Paper 09-060.
Coval, J. D., Jurek, J. W. and Stafford, E. (2008b). Economic catastrophe bonds. Mimeo, Harvard
University.
Crouhy, M., Galai, D. and Mark, R. (2000). Risk Management. McGraw-Hill.
Duffie, D. (2007). Innovations in credit risk transfer: implications for financial stability. Mimeo,
Stanford University.
Duffie, D. (2010). Is there a case for banning short speculation in sovereign bond markets?
Financial Stability Review, 14, Banque de France.
Duffie, D. and Singleton, K. (2003). Credit Risk. Princeton University Press.
Financial Times (2010a). The benefits of naked CDS. Financial Times, 2 March.
Hull, J. C. (2011). Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 8th edition. Prentice Hall.
Hull, J. C. (2012). Risk Management and Financial Institutions, 3rd edition. Prentice Hall.
Li, D. X. (2000). On default correlation: a copula function approach. J. Fixed Income, 9: 43–54.
Murphy, D. (2009). Unravelling the Credit Crunch. CRC Press.
The Economist (2009). No empty threat. Credit-default swaps are pitting firms against their own
creditors. The Economist (US), 18 June.
308
16 Failures in risk management and
regulations before the crisis
The most damaging global financial crisis since the Great Depression started in 2007.
While the underlying causes are varied, failures in financial regulations and financial
risk management played a key role.
By 2007, the prevailing view by market participants and banking supervisors was
that the problem of financial risk had been reduced to an engineering-type exercise.
So long as risk was measured correctly and the appropriate correction mechanisms
were employed, either imposed by banking supervisors or built into internal risk man-
agement, the financial system would remain in an almost permanent state of safety.
This was incorrect. The nature of financial risk was misunderstood because the risk
controls not only failed to protect but also created conditions for excessive risk-taking,
because economic agents have strong incentives to find areas of weakness and exploit
those to make profit.
This happens clandestinely, outside the scrutiny of banking supervisors or even sen-
ior bank management and internal risk control. We learn about excessive risk-taking
only when it is too late and things blow up. To the outside world, the system looks
stable and the general perception of stability creates incentives to take on more risk,
because, after all, ‘what could possibly go wrong?’ In the words of Hyman Minsky,
stability breeds instability.
It also draws heavily on previous chapters in this book, such as Chapter 1 (sys-
temic risk), Chapter 3 (endogenous risk), Chapter 13 (financial regulations) and
Chapter 15 (dangerous financial instruments). It also connects to Chapter 18 (ongo-
ing developments in financial regulation).
Key concepts
■ Why the safeguards failed
■ Complexity and financial engineering
■ Prudential versus system regulations
■ Toxic assets and capital fragility
A Assets
C Capital
T1, T2 Tier 1 and Tier 2
w Risk weight
310
16.1 Regulatory failures
311
Chapter 16 Failures in risk management and regulations before the crisis
This can be seen in the calculation of market risk, specified in the 1996 amendment to
Basel I as a multiple of value-at-risk (VaR). Bank capital for trading activities is based on
a multiple of the risk of an event that happens 2.5 times a year on average, VaR99% daily. Such
events do not seem very systemic or a threat to financial stability.
Definition 16.1 Tail risk or extreme risk We refer to the risk of very large and
very frequent adverse outcomes in financial markets as extreme risk. Another name for it is
‘tail risk’ because extreme outcomes happen in the far left tail of return distributions. While
there is no consensus as to what constitutes extreme risk, a useful definition is an event that
happens no more than once every five years on average. We might observe two five-year
events close to each other and none for 10 years. There is no specific time period over which
the adverse event happens. It could play out in 10 minutes as in a flash crash type of event,
in one day as in the 1987 crash, or even over several months as in 2008.
This regulatory and internal risk management focus on particular aspects of risk explains
why the financial industry was able to take on excessive levels of risk undetected. Financial
risk models have become quite successful at forecasting day-to-day risk and banks in turn
have become very good at managing such risk. This success was noted by the supervisors.
Unfortunately, it is much harder to model and understand extreme risk.
This focus on day-to-day risk levels impacted on the distribution of financial returns in
a particular way. Borrowing language from the statistical literature on risk modelling, we
can say that active risk management may cause the volatility to decrease and the tails to
thicken. We see a depiction of this in Figure 16.1 (repeated from Figure 3.9). The blue line
shows what the distribution of market outcomes could be if financial institutions were not
actively trying to manage day-to-day risk, whilst the red line shows what happens when
they do. The impact of active risk management is to reduce the probability of uncommon
0.5
Risk of very large
risk management
0.4
Distribution of risk
outcomes
by active
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
−3 −2 −1 0 1 2
Market outcomes
312
16.1 Regulatory failures
events, shown by the red line being below the blue line in the sides of the distribution,
but at the expense of the red line being higher in the tails, signalling a high probability of
extreme outcomes.
This approach to risk management led to an attitude well described by an old joke. A
policeman sees a drunk man crawling on the ground at night and asks him what he is up
to. The drunk responds that he is looking for his keys. The policeman says why are you
looking there? The drunk says that is where the light is. The lesson from this story is that
financial institutions and banking supervisors became blinded by their success in finding
risk where it is visible and neglected to search for risk elsewhere.
Unfortunately, those who really want to maximise risk, like bank traders, were actively
searching for the dark areas, so almost by definition, if the supervisors or the bank risk
managers were looking in one area, excessive risk-taking took place elsewhere.
This meant that prior to 2007, the financial system had all the outward signs of low
risk, and the era became known as ‘the great moderation’. Alas, that very perception cre-
ated conditions for excessive risk-taking and the subsequent crisis.
Fat tails
Since many methods in portfolio theory and derivative pricing assume that returns are nor-
mally distributed, they break down in the presence of fat tails. It is, however, in the field of
financial regulations and risk management where the lack of normality is crucially impor-
tant. An inappropriate assumption of normality leads to the gross underestimation of risk:
‘[. . .] as you well know, the biggest problems we now have with the whole evolu-
tion of risk is the fat-tail problem, which is really creating very large conceptual dif-
ficulties. Because as we all know, the assumption of normality enables us to drop
off the huge amount of complexity in our equations [. . .] Because once you start
putting in non-normality assumptions, which is unfortunately what characterizes
the real world, then these issues become extremely difficult.’
Alan Greenspan (1997)
313
Chapter 16 Failures in risk management and regulations before the crisis
money on quantitative trading. The markets began to move in a way that was inconsist-
ent with the computer models used by banks. This triggered selling, resulting in price
drops, further creating difficulties typical of the feedback loops associated with problems
of endogenous risk. Goldman Sachs’s flagship Global Alpha fund, which used quantita-
tive strategies across a range of asset classes, had lost 27%:
‘“We were seeing things that were 25-standard deviation moves, several days in a
row”, said David Viniar, Goldman’s chief financial officer. “There have been issues
in some of the other quantitative spaces. But nothing like what we saw last week.”’
Financial Times (2007)
‘“Wednesday is the type of day people will remember in quant-land for a very long
time”, said Mr Rothman, a University of Chicago Ph. D. who ran a quantitative fund
before joining Lehman Brothers. “Events that models only predicted would happen
once in 10,000 years happened every day for three days.”’
Wall Street Journal (2007)
Value-at-risk
Perhaps the most common measure of financial risk is VaR. While it has been widely criti-
cised, most of the commentators do not seem to properly understand the nature of the
measure, in particular those claiming it is dependent on normality. That is not true, even
if actual implementations frequently do so. The fault there lies with the modellers, not
the concept.
VaR does, however, have several flaws, making it inappropriate in most cases for appli-
cations in financial stability.
■ First, it is not sub-additive, meaning it is not relevant for assets that most of the time
deliver steady returns but very rarely suffer large losses. An example of such assets is
high-risk bonds. A misuse of VaR in this context has been at the heart of many losses,
for instance, those suffered by UBS in 2007, as noted by UBS (2008).
314
16.1 Regulatory failures
■ Second, VaR typically applies only to a single-day loss, independent of other days. This
means that a series of small losses individually might not seem too worrying if judged
by VaR, even if the accumulated losses might be so large as to cause a bank to fail.
■ Third, VaR is only as good as the underlying statistical model, most of which are rather
poor. In particular, attempting to model extreme outcomes or multi-day losses with
VaR is generally impossible if an accurate risk assessment is desired.
■ Finally, VaR can capture only perceived risk, not actual risk, because it depends on using
historical data for the risk forecast.
We saw one example of this in the discussion of the JP Morgan Chase ‘whale’ in
Example 9.1. The risk does not seem to have been picked up by the bank’s internal models:
the average VaR for the first three months of 2012 for chief investment office (CIO) activi-
ties was $129 million, compared to $60 million the year before. In other words, the per-
ceived risk was only a small fraction of the actual risk, a clear example of how risk builds
up out of sight. This also demonstrates the problems of relying on risk measures like VaR,
because it is conceivable that JP Morgan Chase had many days with large losses but never
violating its VaR limit on a single day.
315
Chapter 16 Failures in risk management and regulations before the crisis
External
shock
Financial difficulties
Forced
sales
and banking supervisors. The banks wanted to focus on their own activities, and for the
supervisors it was hard enough to ensure that each institution was prudently run without
having to consider the more complicated issues of interconnectedness and its contribu-
tion to systemic risk.
316
16.2 Capital and the crisis
317
Chapter 16 Failures in risk management and regulations before the crisis
C = T 1 + T2
CAR = Ú 8% (16.1)
w1 * A 1 + w2 * A 2
It is in the interest of any bank to make the CAR look as large as possible, for a given set
of assets and liabilities. To this end, a bank might employ capital structure optimisation to
maximise the numerator of (16.1) whilst minimising the denominator.
318
16.2 Capital and the crisis
In principle, hybrid instruments sound like a good idea. They provide stable long-term
funding to a bank, whilst providing protection when things get rough. They are, of course,
inferior to equity. Not only is equity the banks’ own money while hybrids are just bor-
rowed money; equity also is money owned by the banks’ owners, which presumably
incentivises them to behave prudently.
The main problem with hybrids is how they were set up; in particular, it was generally
at the discretion of the bank when a payment could be deferred or the bond converted.
In other words, there was no explicit trigger for conversion, and the experience during the
crisis showed that banks were quite reluctant to trigger conversion.
An important reason seems to have been that banks sold these instruments to pre-
ferred clients with the promise of a high return, and were reluctant to see them suffer
losses. In other words, reputation risk held them back. The banks converted only when
forced to do so by the supervisors during the crisis.
Another key reason was that a conversion into equity is dilutive and thus runs against
shareholder and perhaps management interests.
Finally, doing a conversion signals that the financial institution is in difficulty and, there-
fore, creates the potential for a run, not only on the bank converting but also on other banks.
This meant that the protection afforded by the hybrid capital instruments turned out
to be illusory for the most part; the markets recognised this and ignored hybrids when
calculating bank capital and evaluating the strength of financial institutions.
319
Chapter 16 Failures in risk management and regulations before the crisis
■ Tier 1/RWA This is the more strict Basel ratio, tier 1 capital divided by risk-weighted
assets (RWA).
■ Core tier 1/RWA This focuses only on the equity part of tier 1, since core tier 1 is com-
posed of shareholders’ equity and retained earnings.
■ Tier 1/TA This replaces RWA with total assets (TA).
■ Tangible equity/TA This replaces tier 1 with tangible common equity, the subset of
shareholders’ equity that is not preferred equity and not intangible assets.
Aggregate results
Figure 16.3 shows the four ratios. Of those, tier 1/RWA is trending upwards, therefore, the
Basel capital ratio was sending the signal that the banks were becoming more capitalised
and, hence, safer over time. However, we see that from 2002 equity has been reduced and
other forms of tier 1 have become an increasing part of tier 1 capital.
8.5%
8.0%
7.5%
Tier 1/RWA
7.0%
Core tier 1/RWA
6.5%
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007
(a) Risk-weighted assets (RWA)
3.6%
3.4%
3.2%
3.0% Tier 1/TA
2.8% Tangible equity/TA
3.4% 2000
2002 2003
Tier 1/RWA
3.2% 2001
3.0% 2004
2007 2006
2.8%
2005
320
16.2 Capital and the crisis
This is in line with Figure 16.3(b); tier 1/TA first increases sharply but then starts drop-
ping from 2004, whilst the most conservative capital measure, tangible equity over TA, is
steadily dropping throughout the sample period. These results support the analysis of the
impact of financial engineering on the capital structure; the visible reported component
is increasing, but a look at the components that are harder to manipulate shows that the
banks’ capitalisation was getting worse over time.
Finally, Figure 16.3(c) shows a cross-plot of tangible equity/TA to tier 1/RWA, along
with a regression line. We see here the relationship is trending downwards, albeit with a
high degree of uncertainty. This demonstrates how Basel capital and conservatively calcu-
lated capital were evolving at a different rate.
Individual results
A similar picture emerges by looking at individual European institutions in Table 16.1 dur-
ing the first quarter of 2008, when the crisis was becoming serious and considerable focus
was on bank capital. What is interesting is the change in rankings of different institutions
when we switch from using the Basel ratio all the way to tangible equity/TA. Figure 16.4
shows the ranking of capital, identifying four categories of banks.
CS went from being the best capitalised bank to below average, whilst UBS went from
being the tenth lowest capitalised bank in the sample to the lowest. Both of these banks,
especially the latter, experienced significant difficulties in the crisis. DB, similarly, went
from 35 to 2. Banks like HSBC maintained a fairly consistent ranking across all the measures.
The sample contains some institutions that ran into difficulties. Interestingly, AIB,
which was now in serious trouble with the sovereign debt crisis in Ireland, was looking
relatively healthy, whilst RBS was showing clear signs of financial engineering.
Figure 16.4 shows this same information in a different way, as a cross-correlation
between tier1/RWA and tangible equity/TA, where we identify banks that have received
some government assistance. There seems to be little or no connection between needing
help and having a weak capital base; if anything, the most highly capitalised banks with
the best capital were more likely to get into trouble.
321
Chapter 16 Failures in risk management and regulations before the crisis
40
BPM
AIB
MPS
Kaupthing
Santander
Landsbanki
High conservative
Sabadell
DnBN NOR
Stan Char
capital
Glitnir
30 HSBC
Rank by tangible equity/TA
Banesto
Anglo Irish
BPI
BBVA Popolare
Nordea
ISP CS
Low capital
20
High capital
Erste Bank structure optimisation
BCP
SEB
HBOS
Lloyds
BNPP
A&L
BankInter
Commerz
10
Low conservative
DB SocGen
Dexia
capital
RBS B&B
Barclays
CASA
DB
UBS
0
0 10 20 30 40
Rank by tier 1/RWA
Figure 16.4 Capital rankings of European banks in Q1 2008. Those that failed or got
significant government help between 2007 and July 2012 in red
Data source: Lehman Brothers (2008). Note: 1 worst capitalised, 42 best capitalised
Analysis
These results do not provide much indication that bank capital is doing what is expected
of it; at least, it is hard to reconcile the fact that many of the most highly capitalised insti-
tutions failed, while many of the low capitalised banks survived the crisis, and amongst
those that seemed most active in capital structure optimisation, most survived.
However, using TA, as in the leverage ratio is also problematic. After all, if two banks
have the same amount of capital and one buys government bonds and the other junk
bonds, both would have the same leverage ratio, but the second bank is a lot more risky.
For this reason, it is better to have banks meet multiple capital ratios at the same time,
which is indeed what Basel III aims to do.
These results are consistent with those of Blundell-Wignall and Atkinson (2010) who con-
tend that banks’ ability to arbitrage the capital weights to reduce capital and expand leverage
is very extensive. They give a simple example showing that the Basel risk-weighting approach
has allowed banks to expand their leverage almost without limit for all practical purposes.
322
References
Ultimately, this provides a good argument for transparency. Instead of trusting the
bank to put assets into the right risk bucket and apply the correct formula for diversifica-
tion and unlikely events, the market could make that judgement independently. What the
crisis demonstrated is that if the market is not given information, it is likely to make crude
worst-case assumptions, which does not benefit anybody.
16.3 Summary
While there are many reasons for the crisis that started in 2007, failures in financial regula-
tions and risk management were a direct contributor.
If regulations and risk management function as intended, risk-taking by banks is con-
tained and bank failures, and certainly near-systemic crises, are highly unlikely. A key rea-
son why the crisis happened in 2007 is that financial regulations and risk management
at the time focused on frequent non-extreme events, neglecting tail risk, whilst ignoring
endogenous risk and the systemic aspect of bank activities.
Perhaps the single most identifiable failure of regulations was in the Basel Accords and
especially bank capital regulations. Prior to the crisis, banks appeared to be highly capi-
talised, but this was mostly illusory, because banks used capital structure optimisation to
manipulate their CAR.
2 It is sometimes said that the outcome of active risk management is to lower volatility and
fatten the tails. What does this mean, and do you agree?
6 Did the hybrid capital instruments work effectively in the early stages of the crisis from
2007?
7 What you think about the assumption in the Basel accords and EU laws that sovereigns
are risk free?
References
Blundell-Wignall, A. and Atkinson, P. (2010). Thinking beyond Basel III: necessary solutions for
capital and liquidity. OECD Journal: Financial Market Trends, Volume 2010, Issue 1.
Danielsson, J. (2011). Financial Risk Forecasting. John Wiley & Sons.
Financial Services Authority (2009b). The Turner review: a regulatory response to the global
banking crisis. Technical report, European Central Bank. www.fsa.gov.uk/pubs/other/turner_
review.pdf.
323
Chapter 16 Failures in risk management and regulations before the crisis
Financial Times (2007). Goldman pays the price of being big. Financial Times, 13 August.
Goodhart, C. (2009). The Regulatory Response to the Financial Crisis. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK.
Greenspan, A. (1997). Discussion at symposium: Maintaining Financial Stability in a Global
Economy, p. 54. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City.
Larosiere, J. (2009). The high-level group report on financial supervision in the EU. Technical report.
http://ec.europa.eu/commission_barroso/president/pdf/statement_20090225_en.pdf.
Lehman Brothers (2008). Capital advisory group: current topics. Technical report, Lehman
Brothers.
UBS (2008). Shareholder report on UBS’s write-downs. Technical report.
Wall Street Journal (2007). One ‘quant’ sees shakeout for the ages – ‘10,000 years’. Wall Street
Journal, 11 August.
324
17 The ongoing crisis:
2007–2009 phase
The worst global financial crisis since the Great Depression started in August 2007,
reached a peak in the second part of 2008 and seemed to be over by 2009. However,
that turned out to be wrong — a second phase started in 2010 and, at the time of
writing, it is getting worse by the day. In this chapter the focus is on the first phase,
whilst Chapter 19 addresses the European sovereign debt crisis.
The underlying causes of the crisis are familiar. Banks took on too much debt whilst
not recognising the increasing underlying risks, in the short run making everybody
feel better off. The complexity and the hidden risk and the shadow banking system
enabled those desiring to ignore problems to continue investing.
It all ended in tears. Crises require people to sell assets below the price at which
they bought them. Market participants came to realise that their assumptions were
wrong, that valuations had been too high, so out of sync with reality that a correction
became inevitable. This happened in 2007.
This chain of events is well known to policymakers who had set in place safeguards
both to prevent such excesses building up and to protect us from the eventual failure.
The safeguards failed. Developments in the financial system had outpaced the regula-
tory and supervisory structure. Financial institutions were increasingly taking advantage
of globalised markets, the structure of banks was changing and they were increasingly
dependent on models and complexity for profits whilst relying more and more on short-
term wholesale funding. All of this meant that financial institutions were becoming more
interconnected and dangerous. Regulations did not keep up; the Basel II Accord, imple-
mented in 2007, represents state-of-the-art regulatory thinking from the late 1990s.
As financial institutions became ever more international, the potential for cross-
border banking failures was mostly ignored, with no effective internationally
Chapter 17 The ongoing crisis: 2007–2009 phase
coordinated supervision or resolution regimes. Even in Europe, with its common mar-
ket in financial services, supervision was a strictly national affair, and the supervisors
in different countries did not speak much with each other. The regulatory and super-
visory structure in place in 2007 was inadequate for the banking system at the time.
Key concepts
■ First and second globalisms
■ Hidden risk
■ How banking has changed
■ Investors’ strike
■ Liquidity and bailouts
■ Bear Stearns, AIG and Lehman
■ The fall of 2008
■ Subprime
■ Response to the crises
17.1.1 Globalism
The crisis was a product of the relatively liberalised economic environment that fol-
lowed the collapse of the Bretton Woods system in the early 1970s. The global economy
has been gradually opening, with increasingly free trade and capital flows, along with
326
17.1 Build-up to a crisis
deregulation and privatisation. If there is one defining term for the general economic envi-
ronment, it is globalism. This is not, however, the first but the second time globalism has
been the prevailing philosophy.
Throughout this period of ever increasing globalism, we did not suffer a global finan-
cial crisis, and when this crisis happened, everybody was ill-prepared.
327
Chapter 17 The ongoing crisis: 2007–2009 phase
328
17.1 Build-up to a crisis
markets when a shock hit, providing a put option. The impact was to increase moral
hazard and stimulate asset bubbles, both in equities but perhaps more importantly in
American real estate.
329
Chapter 17 The ongoing crisis: 2007–2009 phase
A narrow notion of the EMH captures the inability to systematically make money
by forecasting. This is not problematic and is supported by empirical evidence. After
all, if markets were not efficient in that sense, one could easily make almost infinite
profits. This is the view that is most prevalent in academic studies referring to efficient
markets.
There is, however, another interpretation of the EMH which is the view that a belief
in efficient markets makes people blind to the faults of the market. For example, former
Fed chairman, Paul Volcker, said in 2011 that it was ‘clear that among the causes of the
recent financial crisis was an unjustified faith in rational expectations [and] market effi-
ciencies’. This view is more common amongst non-economists, who often attribute the
wider meaning to those using it formally in the narrow sense.
‘The received wisdom is that risk increases in recessions and falls in booms. In con-
trast, it may be more helpful to think of risk as increasing during upswings, as finan-
cial imbalances build up, and materialising in recessions.’
These words were very prescient, written seven years before the crisis erupted. But
what are the mechanisms that allow risk to build up whilst hidden away?
330
17.3 The changing nature of banking
between credit expansion, speculative investments and rising prices. Eventually, the bub-
ble bursts.
The complexity of finance and the use of models add to the pro-cyclicality. The com-
plexity enables financial institutions to create ever more categories of instruments, sup-
posedly increasing efficiency, but often this complexity just serves to hide risk-taking. A
clear example of this is shown by the postmortem analysis done by UBS into its losses at
the beginning of the crisis (UBS, 2008). Amongst the many findings is inappropriate use of
value-at-risk (VaR) models for credit exposures.
Financial models contribute to pro-cyclicality. They are generally based on short price
histories, and so long as prices are going up and risk is perceived as low, the models give
a signal to buy, creating a bubble. Risk estimates are always influenced by recent experi-
ence, which can be especially dangerous when the pace of innovation is high. At that
time, new products are introduced that did not exist in more stable times; innovation is
aimed at avoiding perceived risks and gives a pretext for the idea that this time is different
and risks are really lower.
Funding
The most expensive way for a bank to fund itself is via capital, followed by long-term bor-
rowing. The shorter the maturity of funds, the cheaper they are. For that reason, prior to
the crisis, financial institutions, driven by competitive pressures, were increasingly resort-
ing to the shortest possible funding – overnight (Brunnermeier, 2008, reports up to 40%
for large American banks). Of course, any bank’s assets have much longer maturities, so
331
Chapter 17 The ongoing crisis: 2007–2009 phase
that such a funding strategy gives rise to a significant maturity mismatch. We see the fund-
ing options in the following table:
While overnight funding is the cheapest for banks in normal times, it maximises liquidity risk.
One of the first things to happen when the crisis started in 2007 was a drying up of the inter-
bank market, causing banks relying on overnight funding to face a significant liquidity squeeze.
In principle, borrowing overnight from the interbank market is not much different from
depending on retail deposits, which are payable on demand. In practice, the differences
are significant: overnight repos are much more dangerous.
While both sorts of funding are subject to bank runs, sophisticated investors in the
interbank market are much more likely to do a run than retail depositors. The reason is
that they monitor their counterparties very carefully, and spot problems quickly. By con-
trast, retail depositors tend only to react after the problems hit the news. A good example
of this was the failure of Northern Rock, where the institutional run took place over a
month before the retail run.
Shadow banking
A traditional, even caricature, view of a bank has it collecting demand deposits and
making long-term loans. While such a picture has always been over-simplistic, in recent
years it is increasingly outdated, not least as banks have embraced what is called shadow
banking. This enables banks to move risk into entities directly under their control but
not a part of the balance sheet. This can help in tax and risk management, and aid in
capital structure optimisation. One example of this is conduits as banks as discussed in
Example 15.2.
Shadow banking is not a term with a single precise meaning, but generally refers to
institutions and banking practices that exist outside the traditional regulated banking
sector.
Shadow banking enabled regulated financial institutions to conduct business outside
the glaring eye of bank supervisors, shareholders, accountants and other stakeholders, in
a way that was legal and compliant with extant regulations.
The move towards shadow banking is a clear example of Goodhart’s Law. By putting
heavy regulations on bank capital and assets, regulators created the incentives that made
bank capital and assets poor measures of financial solidity. Shadow banks were one of the
mechanisms used.
It is worth noting that many structures such as SIVs and conduits that were off-balance
sheet and, hence, a part of the shadow banking system, under regulations prior to 2007,
no longer enjoy that status under the Basel II Accord, which took effect in 2007 in many
countries.
332
17.4 Crisis, 2007–2008
Given the long time it took to move Basel II from proposal to implementation – seven
years – if that process had been faster, some of the problems causing the crisis might have
been prevented, since banks would not have been able to take on so much risk without
it being noticed.
40
30
20
10
0
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007
333
Chapter 17 The ongoing crisis: 2007–2009 phase
Bear Stearns
The weakest of the American investment banks, Bear Stearns, started facing serious dif-
ficulties in early 2008. As losses mounted, in March 2008 the New York Federal Reserve
Bank (NYFed) gave a $29 billion loan to JP Morgan to facilitate its takeover of Bear Stearns,
buying it at $10 a share. Bear traded at $172 in January 2007, and at $93 in February 2008.
The Chairman of the Fed, Ben Bernanke, defended the bailout in the Senate Banking
Committee, saying ‘Given the exceptional pressures on the global economy and finan-
cial system, the damage caused by a default by Bear Stearns could have been severe and
extremely difficult to contain.’
Temporary calm
While the bailout temporarily prevented widespread disruption in financial markets, it
was highly controversial and created the expectation that the authorities should similarly
bail out other banks that were considered too big to fail (TBTF). This temporarily calmed
the markets, but by September 2008 two important financial institutions were facing dif-
ficulties, Lehman Brothers and AIG.
DILEMMA 17.1 The controversial decision not to bail out Lehman Brothers
Those arguing that this was the right decision maintain that if Lehman had been bailed
out, it would have cemented expectations by the markets that any bank would be
bailed out, encouraging risk-taking and simply creating ingredients for a larger failure
down the road – a pure example of moral hazard. Lehman’s failure crystallised a prob-
lem already present, making both market participants and the authorities realise the
gravity of the situation and creating the conditions for the eventual crisis response.
Those arguing in favour of a bailout say that because of the failure, global liquid-
ity almost completely dried up, with interbank lending, trade financing and the like
falling to zero, setting the world economy on the road to collapse. The failure created
334
17.4 Crisis, 2007–2008
unnecessary uncertainty, not only causing the severe crisis of the last part of 2008, but
also leading to the European sovereign debt crisis. By bailing out Lehman, the authori-
ties would have been given more time to implement measured, negotiated and less
damaging crisis-fighting methods.
17.4.2 AIG
The day after Lehman Brothers failed, one of the world’s largest insurance companies,
AIG, received a bailout from the NYFed. It was considered more systematically important
than Lehman Brothers because it was the largest writer of CDSs in the world, and it was
feared that its default would trigger a systemic crisis, especially coming right after the
failure of Lehman. For an overview of how AIG got into such problems with CDSs, see, for
example, Lewis (2009).
‘It is hard for us, without being flippant, to even see a scenario within any kind of
realm of reason that would see us losing one dollar in any of those transactions.’
Joseph J. Cassano, the AIG executive in charge of the
credit default swap (CDS) unit, August 2007
AIG was one of the world’s largest insurance companies with a trillion-dollar balance
sheet, 116,000 employees and operations in 130 countries. It set up a London-based bank
that quickly became the world’s largest seller of CDSs. The reason why AIG was able to
become such a large writer of CDSs was that it had an AAA rating, making it the safest pos-
sible counterparty, requiring the smallest haircuts. It wrote about $450 billion worth of
corporate CDSs, which suffered small losses, and about $75 billion of subprime-mortgage
CDSs which suffered more losses after the crisis started. This eventually caused AIG to be
downgraded, increasing its funding costs and haircuts, in a typical vicious feedback loop.
Given the danger posed by the failure of AIG, the authorities felt they had no choice
but to provide a bailout, eventually amounting to $130 billion. Note, however, that the
losses to taxpayers will be much smaller, even though the final amount will not be known
for some time. The US taxpayer also gave tens of billions of dollars to financial institutions
that were counterparties to AIG, most to Goldman Sachs and Deutsche Bank.
While the collapse of AIG could be handled more surgically by avoiding bailing out
its counterparties, the existing resolution regime did not allow for that option. Given the
alternatives, the bailout was the lesser of two evils, as the failure of AIG might have trig-
gered a systemic crisis.
335
Chapter 17 The ongoing crisis: 2007–2009 phase
credit crunch. The extreme risk levels are clearly visible in the VIX, seen in Figure 17.2,
which shot up in September.
The crisis threatened to cause a repeat of the Great Depression, however, as we dis-
cussed in Section 2.4, the authorities took on board the lessons from the Depression and
did the necessary to stop the liquidity crisis in its tracks.
A clear manifestation of the determination of the authorities was the scale of the vari-
ous bailouts provided to the financial sector, as discussed in Section 14.5. In the absence
of these bailouts, it seems likely that large parts of the European and American banking
systems would have failed, with catastrophic consequences for the real economy.
Figure 2.6 showed the collapse in world trade during the Great Depression. We add to
that figure current trade data in Figure 17.3, and show both time periods scaled to begin
at 100. World trade fell significantly in the second half of 2008, but quickly recovered.
80
60
40
20
0
2007 2008 2009
140
120
100
80
60 Great Depression
40 Current crisis
336
17.5 Was it a subprime crisis?
100
90
80
70
SP 500
60 FT 100
50 DAX
337
Chapter 17 The ongoing crisis: 2007–2009 phase
One example is from Alistair Darling (2011), the then UK Chancellor (minister of
finance) who described the governor of the BoE, Mervyn King, as ‘impish’ and ‘incred-
ibly stubborn’ and excessively focused on moral hazard, maintaining that ‘a penalty
interest rate must apply to any help given by the Bank’, reflecting Bagehot’s rules.
Darling further quotes King as saying ‘He regretted not having confronted these issues
before’, referring to the need for liquidity in the second part of 2007.
338
References
17.7 Summary
The focus in this chapter has been on the first part of the ongoing global crisis, 2007
to 2009. The background to the crisis is the era of the second globalism following the
collapse of the Bretton Woods system, with ever increasing international capital flows,
especially to the US, helping to maintain very low interest rates. This was not a cause for
concern because large countries exported deflation, keeping inflation low.
The central theme is that it was a classical financial crisis, but with many unique ingredients
such as inadequacies in financial regulations and excessive amounts of financial engineering.
The visible crisis was the manifestation of inappropriate investment decisions, poor
risk estimates and mistaken assumptions on liquidity, all made over the preceding years.
Subprime was the trigger, but its role was only ancillary.
Fortunately, the authorities had studied the policy mistakes during the Great
Depression, and been determined not to repeat them.
2 Describe a typical crisis/bubble and analyse the 2007–2009 crisis in the context of that.
4 What was the role of complex assets and marking to market/model/magic in the crisis?
5 How has banking changed over the past decades and how did that make banks more
vulnerable?
6 What were the initial signs of the crisis in the summer of 2007?
7 What were the main symptoms of the crisis when it reached its peak?
9 Many commentators maintain the failure to bail Lehman out was the main factor in the
crisis becoming so severe. Today, European authorities use the example of Lehman as a
justification for supporting European banks. Do you agree?
References
Bernanke, B. S. (2005). The global saving glut and the US current account deficit. Speech deliv-
ered at the Sandridge Lecture, Virginia Association of Economists, Richmond, VA.
Bitner, R. (2008). Confessions of a Subprime Lender: an Insider’s Tale of Greed, Fraud, and
Ignorance. John Wiley & Sons.
Borio, C. and Disyatat, P. (2011). Global imbalances and the financial crisis: link or no link?
Technical report, BIS. Working Paper 346.
Brunnermeier, M. (2008). Deciphering the 2007–08 liquidity and credit crunch. J. Econ.
Perspect., 23(1): 77–100.
339
Chapter 17 The ongoing crisis: 2007–2009 phase
Crockett, A. (2000). Marrying the micro- and macro-prudential dimensions of financial stabil-
ity. The General Manager of the Bank for International Settlements, www.bis.org/review/
rr000921b.pdf.
Darling, A. (2011). Back from the Brink: 1,000 Days at Number 11. Atlantic Books, London.
Huertas, T. F. (2010). Crisis: Cause, Containment and Cure. Palgrave Macmillan.
Lewis, M. (2009). The man who crashed the world. Vanity Fair, August.
Lewis, M. (2011). The Big Short: Inside the Doomsday Machine. Penguin.
Murphy, D. (2009). Unravelling the Credit Crunch. CRC Press.
Reinhart, C. M. and Rogoff, K. (2009). This Time Is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly.
Princeton University Press.
UBS (2008). Shareholder report on UBS’s write-downs. Technical report.
Volcker, P. (2011). Financial reform: Unfinished business. www.nybooks.com/articles/archives/
2011/nov/24/financial-reform-unfinished-business.
340
18 Ongoing developments in
financial regulation
Reforms of financial regulations tend to come after crises. Then, after some decades
have passed and those who stood watch during the crises have retired, standards
relax, until it all starts over again.
We have already seen some examples of this in this book. The Overend and Gurney
(O&G) crisis of 1866 led to lending of last resort (LOLR) policies, and the Great
Depression motivated a number of new regulations like deposit insurance and the
Glass–Steagall Act, while regulatory failures in the United States in the early 1980s led
that country to develop prompt corrective action. Such crisis response is not always
positive, as there is great political pressure on policymakers to ‘do something now’
and quick policymaking is often bad policymaking.
One of the main causes of the crisis from 2007 was the failure of financial regu-
lations. In response, G20 member countries, represented by the Financial Stability
Forum (FSF), issued an influential report in 2008, identifying five priority areas of
what it saw as the post-crisis regulatory reform process: ‘Strengthened prudential
oversight of capital, liquidity and risk management. Enhancing transparency and val-
uation. Changes in the role and uses of credit ratings. Strengthening the authorities’
responsiveness to risks. Robust arrangements for dealing with stress in the financial
system.’
Not surprisingly, a large number of initiatives have been launched since 2007
by various nation states, government organisations, financial institutions, lobbying
groups, academics and other assorted pundits. The mother of all reform battles has
been launched, and we are seeing the most substantial restructuring of financial regu-
lations since at least the 1930s.
Chapter 18 Ongoing developments in financial regulation
342
Chapter 18 Ongoing developments in financial regulation
Regulatory reform is technical, and the language often impenetrable. Add to that
the multiple agendas being pursued, the many special interests being protected,
and the fact that the discussion tends to take place in closed meetings, and it is
clear that the debate is complex and difficult to follow.
However, at the time of writing, half a decade has passed since the 2007 crisis
started and a picture is starting to emerge on the post-crisis regulatory landscape. For
a roadmap, see Baudino (2011).
New government agencies have been tasked with the study of systemic risk, even-
tually to develop regulations and strategies for addressing systemic risk. This falls
under the general heading of macro-prudential regulations. The Basel Accord has been
identified as needing significant reform, and it will see changes in the calculation of
capital and the introduction of liquidity constraints. Enhanced monitoring and crisis
response is a central plank of the new regime. Individual countries have also launched
important initiatives, and we have seen a reshuffle of supervisory agencies.
Unfortunately, it appears that some areas identified as key contributors to the crisis
from 2007 are unlikely to be effectively addressed. The most important of these is
the too big to fail (TBTF) problem. TBTF institutions played a central role in attenu-
ating market discipline and breeding excess confidence before the crisis. A signifi-
cant effort is going into this area by the various authorities, but the core problem is
likely to remain. In fact, it has been made worse, by encouraging mergers and further
entrenching the assumption that national champions will receive national support.
Less clarity exists on risk-taking. We hear politicians complain in one sentence
about excessive risk-taking and the need to do something about risk, and in the next
sentence demanding more lending to the politically sensitive SME sector. The view
of the policymakers, reasonably enough, is that the financial system should be taking
risk primarily in areas that benefit the economy rather than just speculating. In prac-
tice, no such clear delineation exists.
At the moment, chastened by recent and painful experience, financial institutions
are content to run with modest amounts of risk. However, past experience indicates
that this reticence is unlikely to survive competitive pressures for long, nor that regu-
lators will be very effective in enforcing it against the will of market participants.
Different regulatory initiatives may sometimes be in conflict with each other. Since
insurance companies need to invest large amounts of reserves, they are a large tra-
ditional buyer of bank bonds. One issue has arisen with Solvency II, the European
insurance regulations to be implemented in 2014. It will induce insurance companies
to hold shorter-dated instruments, while banks will need to issue longer instruments.
This interferes with the insurers’ ability to fulfil their social role, and raises questions
where bank funding is going to come from. However, this remains controversial and
several studies, such as that by Gorter and Bijlsma (2012), maintain that the impact
will be relatively small.
Such conflicting views highlight the difficulty in quantifying the impact of new reg-
ulatory initiatives, as debate participants often have compelling arguments, backed
up by detailed studies, but with widely different conclusions and even methodologi-
cal approaches.
343
Chapter 18 Ongoing developments in financial regulation
Key concepts
■ Post-crisis regulatory reform
■ New institutions and the changing role of old institutions
■ Basel III
■ Flexible capital buffers
■ SIFIs, G-SIBs and too big to fail
344
18.1 New and changed institutions
The crisis demonstrated that the central banks have to play a key role in financial sta-
bility because they have a monopoly on printing money, one of the vital instruments in
support and resolution operations. However, they can play this role effectively only if they
also have appropriate supervisory information and powers, and the willingness to use
them. The result is that the central banks have been gaining new responsibilities.
This is the case in the United Kingdom, where many of the functions of the Financial
Services Authority (FSA) are to be merged with the BoE, leaving only micro-prudential regu-
lations. Similarly, in the US, the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) used to supervise
investment banks, but the remaining investment banks have become bank holding compa-
nies and, hence, are subject to prudential regulation by the Federal Reserve System (Fed).
The SEC remains a significant regulator in issues relating to securities markets and trading.
However, the central banks have also lost some power to the treasury/ministries of
finance, as any bailouts need government approval, and the new systemic risk institutions
enshrine the role of the treasury, especially in the US.
The treasury
The crisis demonstrated the key role played by the treasury because it manages the public
purse. Vast amounts of public money were allocated to fighting the crisis and, since the
treasury is ultimately responsible for public money, it necessarily took a pivotal role. This
does not mean the treasury is better equipped to do this than the central banks or the
supervisors; far from it, the technical expertise lies with the latter. One could say that the
treasury has regained some of its historical role lost the when the central banks became
independent.
While it is inevitable that the treasuries are intimately involved in the regulatory reform
process, and need to take the lead in any bailout operation, this does not come without
cost. The role of the treasury has led to an unfortunate politicisation of financial regula-
tion. The reason is that government agencies like the supervisor or central bank are one
step removed from the political process. The treasury is directly under political control.
This inevitably means that the treasury is more populist, more susceptible to lobbying.
The political leanings of the minister, and the political advisers he or she makes use of,
can directly affect the regulatory reform agenda. Not only can this lead to sharp differ-
ences between various countries, it may also contribute to regulation risk since we may
expect rapid policy shifts when governments change.
345
Chapter 18 Ongoing developments in financial regulation
other relevant bodies like the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and make recommenda-
tions to member states.
IMF
One international organisation has taken on a new life with the crisis, the IMF. By early
2007, the Fund was in serious financial difficulties, laying off staff, and there was specula-
tion it might be shut down altogether. Its reputation had been damaged by the previous
crises it engaged with, in Asia in 1997, and in Turkey and Argentina in the early 2000s.
No large economy had requested Fund assistance after Argentina, and because interest
on loans to countries in crisis is the major source of revenue for the IMF, it was suffering
financially from the lack of crises. By 2006, it had found itself without a mission or money.
All of this changed in 2007. As individual countries got into serious difficulties, it was felt
that the only body with sufficient expertise, authority and funds to help those countries was
the IMF. It has taken a pivotal role in the European crisis, being involved with Cyprus, Iceland,
Hungary, Greece and other countries, and has become one of the main players in formulating
the crisis response. It has a very limited role, however, in formulating regulatory policy.
EU
The crisis exposed significant weaknesses in the approach of the European Union (EU)
to financial regulation and supervision. Financial regulations are to a significant extent
designed and implemented on a Union level, but implemented only on a state level.
Before the crisis, different national supervisors had limited interaction with each other
and often applied widely differing standards to regulations. The European Central Bank
(ECB) was focused only on monetary stability, and there was almost no macro-prudential
policymaking within the EU. The EU has been addressing this problem since 2007, and
has taken major steps towards more centralised European supervision via new institutions
like the European Systemic Risk Board (ESRB), the European Banking Authority (EBA) and
the European Securities and Markets Authority (ESMA). The EU is currently planning the
Single Supervisory Mechanism (SSM) as an embyonic pan-EU supervisor.
346
18.1 New and changed institutions
This does leave a vacuum, and at the time of writing it is unclear how it will be filled.
The EU would like to fill it with a new powerful institution tasked with Union-wide super-
vision and macro-prudential regulations, but this has run into significant opposition from
various member states. If the EU is unsuccessful, the power vacuum will probably be filled
by the ECB at Union level and various state bodies like the FPC.
347
Chapter 18 Ongoing developments in financial regulation
supervision was essentially a national affair. Supervisors in different countries had a lim-
ited overview of the overseas activities of financial institutions operating in their juris-
diction. This even extended to the EU, where it became especially problematic because
banks were able to operate throughout the Union because of the common market, but
without any centralised overview of their activities.
In response to this, various initiatives are underway to coordinate the activities of super-
visors. An important example of this is the activities of the Senior Supervisors Group, rep-
resenting 10 major banking nations. Within this work, colleges of supervisors have regained
a renewed importance, referring to multilateral working groups of relevant supervisors
working together to ensure consolidated supervision of internationally active banking
groups. Colleges of supervisors have become one of the key components in the ongoing
reform of financial regulation. However, enforcement is the last frontier of coordination
and cooperation, and there is some way to go.
While cooperation among supervisors has improved considerably since the crisis, there
have been some hiccups, most famously in the case of UK bank Standard Chartered,
accused by the New York Department of Financial Services of money laundering. It
informed the FSA only 90 minutes before announcing the allegations, and appears not
to have cooperated much with other US supervisory agencies, even though some of them
had supervisory powers over the bank.
‘The objective of the [regulatory] reforms is to improve the banking sector’s ability
to absorb shocks arising from financial and economic stress, whatever the source,
thus reducing the risk of spillover from the financial sector to the real economy.’
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2011b)
These priorities are consistent with the definitions of systemic risk in Section 12.1.
The main impetus of the reforms is on capital, prioritising equity and introducing sev-
eral categories of capital buffers. In addition, the proposals include liquidity regulations
and the management of counterparty risk. At the time of writing, the latest version of the
Basel III was published by the BCBS in June 2011, and we follow that here.
18.2.1 Capital
The Basel III proposals make several important changes to how capital is calculated.
Under Basel II, the main parts of capital are tier 1 and tier 2, and since most of the direct
problems caused by capital relate to tier 2, it is not surprising that it is to be significantly
reduced in importance and most emphasis put on tier 1, especially equity.
348
18.2 Basel III
Types of capital
Regular bank capital will continue to be split into tier 1 and tier 2, and the minimum capital
adequacy ratio (CAR) will remain at 8%. However, the relative amount of tier 1 will increase,
with especially more emphasis put on equity, that is the common equity tier 1 (CET1). For
technical details on the terminology of the capital regulations, see BCBS (2011c).
Several new categories of equity are to be introduced. A capital conservation buffer can
be used to absorb losses during stress, while a countercyclical buffer fluctuates with the
general state of the economy, and global systemically important banks (G-SIBs) are to get
a separate capital charge. Therefore:
By 2019, if all goes according to schedule, the capital ratios will be as indicated in
Table 18.1, with the transition in steps over the coming years as seen in Table 18.2.
Data source: Basel III: a global regulatory framework for more resilient banks and banking
systems, Technical Report, 2011b, Annex 4 (Basel Committee on Banking Supervision 2011),
Bank for International Settlements
349
Chapter 18 Ongoing developments in financial regulation
Conservation buffer
The idea behind the conservation buffer is to solve one of the worst problems with capital
buffers. They do not provide any protection if they cannot be used in times of crisis. It
therefore makes sense for financial institutions to be able to reduce their capital levels in
times of difficulty, and that is the purpose of the conservation buffer, allowing for up to a
2.5% reduction in capital when needed.
Drawing down the buffers is not without consequences. Banks are restricted in pro-
viding distributions to shareholders, other capital providers and employees, because
these stakeholders are supposed to bear the risk that recovery will not be forthcoming.
Furthermore, the banks are likely to be given a deadline for rebuilding their buffers.
350
18.2 Basel III
The reason why AIG was bailed out, and why the failure of Lehman was so damaging, is
exactly because they were systemically important.
Not surprisingly, G-SIBs are singled out in the Basel process:
G-SIBs are to have an extra buffer of 1–3.5% of CET1, though the last 1% of that is cur-
rently an empty bucket designed to be a disincentive for banks to get bigger.
The G-SIB surcharge is intended, at least in part, to reflect the extra risk created by
G-SIBs and to neutralise the advantage the TBTFs are felt to enjoy. This is part of several
policy initiatives aimed at this category of banks, discussed in Section 18.6 below.
Table 18.3 shows the latest list of institutions deemed to be G-SIBs, along with their
capital charges.
CoCos
The problems associated with hybrid bank capital, as discussed in the last chapter, have
led to the introduction of capital instruments with a more explicit trigger called contin-
gent convertibles (CoCos). While there are several different versions of CoCos, one of the
most common is bonds that turn into equity if a bank’s capital ratio becomes too low,
while another type involves write-downs. A key distinction between CoCos and other
capital instruments is that the former focuses on explicit early triggers and hence early
interventions, while the latter is more related to resolution and disincentives.
Several banks have already issued CoCos, but the only nation requiring their use is Swit-
zerland, where UBS has issued write-down CoCos and Credit Suisse (CS) convertible CoCos.
While CoCos are not a direct part of the Basel III proposals, there are some indications
that they may become included in some form, as hinted by the statement that ‘all classes
of capital instruments fully absorb losses at the point of non-viability before taxpayers are
exposed to loss’ (Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, 2011a).
If CoCos are to become a key part of bank capital, the interesting question is who
holds them. If it is only other financial institutions, systemic risk is not reduced, and may
5 3.5% (Empty)
4 2.5% Citigroup, Deutsche Bank, HSBC, JP Morgan Chase
3 2.0% Barclays, BNP Paribas
2 1.5% Bank of America, Bank of New York Mellon, Credit Suisse, Goldman Sachs,
Mitsubishi UFJ FG, Morgan Stanley, Royal Bank of Scotland, UBS
1 1.0% Bank of China, BBVA, Groupe BPCE, Group Crédit Agricole, ING Bank,
Mizuho FG, Nordea, Santander, Société Générale, Standard Chartered,
State Street, Sumitomo Mitsui FG, Unicredit Group, Wells Fargo
Data source: Update of group of global systemically important banks (G-SIBs) Annex 1 (Financial Stability Board 2012),
Bank for International Settlements
351
Chapter 18 Ongoing developments in financial regulation
18.3 Liquidity
Some national jurisdictions, like the UK, have long required banks to hold liquidity buff-
ers, but such requirements have not extended to international regulations. In particular,
Basel II is essentially silent on the question of liquidity.
Events from 2007 have demonstrated the fallacy of such complacency, because the
sudden disappearance of liquidity was at the heart of the crisis, and remains a major
problem in the ongoing sovereign debt crisis.
352
18.3 Liquidity
First, it was assumed that banks could always obtain funding liquidity, which meant
that they naturally migrated to the cheapest forms of liquidity, overnight repos. When the
interbank market dried up in 2007, banks that relied heavily on short-term funding found
themselves in significant difficulty. Because funding problems happen very quickly –
literally overnight – the banks, the authorities and everybody else were caught unpre-
pared, and governments had to rapidly provide bailouts. Longer and more stable funding
would have made it easier to deal with these problems.
Second, it was assumed that some types of funding were more stable than they turned
out to be. For example, bank deposits coupled with deposit insurance have historically
represented funding that was considered unlikely to evaporate quickly. Deposit insurance
schemes were thought to provide sufficient assurance to depositors, and hence prevent
bank runs. However, the limitations of deposit insurance schemes have made depositors
more skittish, especially those holding high-interest Internet savings accounts. Events in
the crisis demonstrated that depositors were sensible enough to withdraw large amounts
of money at the slightest whiff of trouble.
For these reasons, liquidity regulations have became a priority in the Basel III proposals,
and the Committee has proposed two liquidity ratios, the 30-day LCR and the one-year
net stable funding ratio (NSFR).
Numerator
The assets need to be unencumbered, meaning that they have not been pledged or allo-
cated to other purposes, and hence are ready to be monetised.
A key challenge lies in the definition of high quality liquid assets. Two categories of
assets are defined, level 1 and level 2. Level 1 assets are traditionally highly safe and liquid
assets, such as cash, demand deposits with central banks and marketable government
and international agency securities that meet certain conditions. Level 2 assets contain
marketable government and international agency securities that are more risky than their
level 1 counterparts as well as low-risk liquid corporate bonds.
The included assets should be monetisable, at a low cost, providing a relatively certain
amount to a bank facing funding problems.
Denominator
It is harder to define what to include in the denominator. The basic idea is that banks
have certain amounts of outflows and expect to receive some amounts of money. The
difference between the two, the net cash outflow, needs to be sufficiently low. There are
several challenges in the determination of net flows. A bank may have a reasonably clear
353
Chapter 18 Ongoing developments in financial regulation
idea of outflows, but less of potential inflows, especially in times of stress. For example,
while it may have positions that are fully netted out, actually receiving funds depends on
the solvency of the counterparty.
Other problems include how to account for net flows from derivative positions and
other complex assets, where valuations may be model driven and assets only traded over-
the-counter (OTC).
At the time of writing, it is unclear how these issues will be resolved.
National discretion
National supervisors have significant discretion in how they implement the ratio, giving
rise to fears of inconsistent implementation, regulatory arbitrage and a race to the bottom.
Costs
Maintaining a large buffer of liquid assets is costly for the banks. These assets cannot be
used for other, more lucrative, purposes and the LCR, therefore, will directly affect the
banks’ profitability. They maintain that this will reduce their lending capacity, especially
in the context of the LR, with the sectors most affected presumably the SMEs.
This leads to one of the typical dilemmas in the regulatory reform process. More liquid
assets make the banks more resilient, but at the expense of less lending.
Dilemma
The dilemma for the policymakers is that true stability is strongly associated with high
costs. When banks are the most overconfident – right before a crisis happens – they are
least willing to pay the premium associated with stable sources of funding, and prefer to
take more risk by funding short term. Whatever definition of ‘stable funding’ is adopted,
in the next crisis banks will be meeting this requirement from the cheapest available
sources. This funding will be cheapest because it is the least stable.
While seeking stable sources of funding is a sensible idea, like liquidity it seems almost
certain to disappoint when tested in the next crisis, because banks’ incentive to reduce
their funding cost is too strong.
Gaming
Perhaps the main concern about the LCR is the same as worries about the integrity of
bank capital. Banks were able to use capital structure optimisation to significantly game
their capital levels. There is no reason to believe that there is any less scope for gaming
when it comes to liquidity. If anything, the problem might be worse because with capi-
tal we have three decades of observations on how it can be gamed and, hence, have an
354
18.3 Liquidity
understanding of how to minimise the problem. The worry is that the banks would be
more inventive and more nimble in the gaming process than the supervisors.
There are many ways to undermine the LCR. A bank might enter into contracts that
effectively encumber a large part of its liquid resources, but not in a way considered
encumbering by the supervisors.
Another way might be contracts that give rise to large cash requirements when a
bank comes under stress. So long as these do not give rise to any net cash flows (how-
ever defined) under normal circumstances, these might leave the LCR intact, but also
mean that at the onset of a crisis liquid resources would collapse much faster than
anticipated.
While these loopholes are obvious, there are many ways to achieve the same purpose
in a less visible way.
Stable funding is defined as the fraction of equity and liability financing expected to
be reliable sources of funds over a one-year horizon, during extended stress. At the time
of writing, the definition is still quite vague, but more details are expected when the final
version of Basel III is published.
Issues
The NSFR demonstrates the common dilemma between safety and credit creation. One
of the main functions of banks is maturity transformations, simultaneously providing sav-
ers with demand deposit accounts and making long-term loans. Therefore, maturity mis-
matches are inherent in any bank, and not something that should be eliminated, or even
significantly reduced.
Therefore, a strict interpretation of the NSFR might seriously undermine the maturity
transformation function of banks, to the detriment of society.
Another concern relates to cliff effects. One result from the Basel capital ratios was the
creation of 364-day loans, one day short of one year, triggering capital requirements. A
one-year NSFR might do the same, with banks preferring 364-day loans.
This has two important disadvantages. First, it increases liquidity risk because borrow-
ers will have to worry about rolling over loans every 364 days. This is the type of risk that
is most likely to manifest itself during turmoil, at exactly the worst time. The second prob-
lem is that it disrupts business planning, because companies cannot count on long-term
funding for long-term projects. It might lead to funding migrating away from banks onto
the capital markets, where larger companies can issue longer-term bonds. This in turn
disadvantages the SMEs, because their access to the capital markets is more limited than
that of their larger competitors.
355
Chapter 18 Ongoing developments in financial regulation
18.3.3 Danger
Perhaps the main worry about the liquidity ratios is that they may create an impression of
protection that is not veridical. This would endogenously encourage more risk-taking and
therefore undermine financial stability. It would be disastrous if the authorities assumed
the liquidity ratios were successful, and hence that liquidity crises could not happen.
In the next crisis the authorities should be prepared for reported liquidity to prove just as
illusory as reported capital. The ratios came under heavy criticism from the industry and
in response an amended, less strict, version was announced at the start of 2013.
Dilemma
There are two main problems for the authorities. First, there is the classical one whereby
a safe and resilient financial system may be over-conservative when it comes to lending.
Second, for a country with weak banks to make the rules stricter may perversely cause
banks to collapse, whilst maintaining weak regulations and low capital levels may give
the banks sufficient breathing room to improve their financial positions over time. The
various national positions on capital levels can be understood in the context of those two
concerns.
National positions
Perhaps surprisingly, the countries that most advocate more restrictive Basel III rules,
including more capital, are the US, the UK and Switzerland. The last two are countries
with particularly large financial sectors and all three share in a relatively laissez-faire tradi-
tion on financial regulation. They are joined by Sweden, Denmark and the Netherlands
within the EU, and by Canada and Australia among other BCBS members.
Even more surprisingly, the countries that most strongly advocate weak regulations
and low capital are Germany and France, especially the latter. If we consider the public
statements of the leaders of those countries, one would get the impression that they are
against risk-taking and speculation, advocating strict regulations, but in the committees in
which the rules are being drafted, those countries advocate the opposite.
The difference in national attitudes can partly be explained by the fact that countries
with relatively stronger banks, and countries whose banks have been more forthcoming
in recognising problem assets and recapitalising, find it easier to require more capital. If
banks are weak and have been allowed to hide losses, they will find it more difficult to
increase capital. The attitude of the Germans and the French depends in large part on the
role of banks in their economies, and for the French the amount of dirigiste influence the
state has over banks’ lending and general economic activity.
356
18.4 How much capital?
The Basel III proposals are the outcome of an agreement amongst all member countries
of the BCBS, and in the end, the capital levels were much lower than desired by certain
members. For some countries, this is not necessarily that problematic, because they can
simply unilaterally insist on more capital, a position taken by several countries, including
the US and Canada. The situation is different in Europe, because of the maximum harmo-
nisation principle, and as usual is more complex.
Single rulebook
This principle is well stated by Andrea Enria (2011), head of the EBA, who highlights the
great importance, when implementing European regulations, of consistent implementa-
tion and of the single rulebook. This obviously makes sense because inconsistent rules and
implementation can be a cloak for protectionism, encourage regulatory arbitrage and
increase frictional costs.
This has implications for the enthusiasm for more capital, because the single rulebook
implies that all member states need to have ‘exactly the same rules on the definition of
capital and maintain them up to date in a coordinated fashion in light of financial innova-
tion’. This means that member countries should not be allowed to require more capital
for their banks than agreed to by the EU, and cannot seek to establish an independent
brand based on higher regulatory standards.
Main dilemma
Maximum harmonisation is quite important for the EU, not least because of the impor-
tance of the common rulebook. It is also a defence against further tiering of the market,
which happens when the stronger countries rush ahead, undermining the market image
of the weaker ones.
The eventual outcome is problematic, however, especially if the eventual capital
requirements in Europe will be lower than outside the Union. This will send a sig-
nal that North American and Asian BCBS member countries will have more resilient
banking systems. It is possible that this will cause higher-quality clients to migrate to
these banks, leaving poorer-quality clients and riskier activities to the EU. Lower capital
requirements will at least suggest that Europe has a more fragile banking system than
the rest of the world.
357
Chapter 18 Ongoing developments in financial regulation
Perhaps the real problem is that it signals both a deep current malaise and an unwill-
ingness to tackle it, guaranteeing the crisis will fester.
Eventually, enough wiggle room was found to allow member countries to adopt any
minimum capital ratios they desire.
Studies
Admati et al. (2010) argue that increased bank equity brings with it significant economic
benefits, whilst lowering leverage and the risk of bank failures. Other studies find that
Basel III will be costly, for example studies by the New York Federal Reserve Bank (NYFed)
(Angelini et al., 2011) and the BIS (2010). The latter finds that a 1% increase in equity will
lead to a 0.19% reduction in GDP over four years. An FSA study (de Ramon et al., 2012)
finds that quantifying the pros and cons is difficult. The Institute of International Finance
(2010) finds a much stronger impact, where a 2% increase in capital, along with other
elements of Basel III, will cost 3.1% of GDP over five years.
GDP impact
It is very hard to identify the costs and benefits of Basel III. By a first approximation,
increased capital increases the cost of doing business, reducing lending and increasing
the cost of lending. However, if the banking systems become more resilient, requiring
fewer and smaller bailouts and, hence, are less prone to boom and bust cycles, these
costs are partially, and even fully, offset.
In addition, standard Modigliani–Miller analysis would predict that reduced funding
costs because of higher capital would provide greater security for well-capitalised banks.
This implies that the GDP impact of higher capital would be very small. After all, every
time a bank issues new capital, the economic impact is non-detectable.
It is hard to see how a relatively modest increase in bank capital, tiny compared to
GDP, could have anything but a very moderate economic impact. This suggests that the
studies with the low impact numbers are more credible.
358
18.5 Recovery and resolution
would do almost anything to prevent them. More capital would be a cheap way to pre-
vent systemic crises, so long as it was effective.
And herein lies the relevant question. What is the best way to prevent systemic risk,
taking into account the effectiveness and cost? If the answer is capital, it is obvious that
capital requirements should be increased. If the answer is not necessarily capital, then the
capital increases are harder to justify.
To this day, this question has not been answered in a satisfactory way.
When financial institutions become large, the problems of resolution become much
harder, and even more so when they involve multiple jurisdictions.
Before the crisis, the problem of cross-border resolution had been to a large extent
ignored because of the many inherent complexities. It is hard to see how an international
agreement could effectively override markedly different national regimes. The failure
of Lehman Brothers demonstrated the complacency inherent in the extant resolution
regimes.
359
Chapter 18 Ongoing developments in financial regulation
When Lehman brothers failed, there was a scramble to file for bankruptcy. The bank-
ruptcy filing in New York occurred just after midnight on Monday 15 September,
beating the London filing by a few minutes. Even if London had been first, it would
not have made much difference, because liquidity in Lehman Brothers was han-
dled centrally in New York. It swept to New York each night, only to be released
to the regional operations the next day. The Friday sweep took $8 billion out of
London.
At the point of failure, a single integrated operation with a common treasury func-
tion, the situation on Friday, was replaced by around 100 discrete entities, all insol-
vent and with their bankruptcies being handled by their respective national regimes.
Each administrator has a duty to maximise recovery for the creditors to its entity,
which places them in a competitive situation, and four years after the bankruptcy
there are still fresh, multi-billion-dollar claims being made by one administrator
against another. As most of these will need to be addressed in court, it is clear that for
most creditors substantial repayment remains a distant prospect, and also that the
frictional costs of the bankruptcy will be very high.
While the scramble for filing was not all that important, the bigger problem was
that proceedings in the US, UK and other jurisdictions all went on independently,
without adequate legal grounds to establish one, consolidated proceeding.
Source: based on information from Financial Times (2008) and Sorkin (2010)
Lehman Brothers was international in life but national in death, as noted by Thomas
Huertas.
The administrators of a single bankrupt entity are not allowed to place cooperation
with other administrators above the interests of the creditors whose money they are
spending, so it is sometimes difficult for them to justify cooperative information shar-
ing unless it is clear that their creditors will benefit. An external entity could assist in
promoting efficient information sharing and cooperation and reduce duplicated effort.
In 2009, the FSB announced principles for cross-border and crisis management. Based
on the Lehman experience, this should be of some help. Building on supervisory colleges,
a new entity called a crisis management group (CMG) should be in place, ready to handle
crisis management. The CMGs are meant to improve information sharing, build-up of
trust and cooperation between various authorities.
However, beyond that it is not clear how much a CMG can achieve, in practice, as
the fundamental problem is one of conflicting fiduciary duty. By law, administrators are
not allowed to give preference to the interests of other group companies over those of
their creditors, so while better information sharing would perhaps save time it would not
prevent the attempts by administrators to maximise their outgoing claims against other
group companies, and to minimise the incoming claims they accept. Intragroup arrange-
ments will be complex, so this will remain a recipe for lengthy wrangling even if a CMG
can provide improved access to company data.
360
18.6 What about too big to fail?
Bank incentives
Banks have direct incentives to become TBTF. Any bank that is perceived as TBTF is
more likely to be bailed out than smaller banks. Creditors notice this, and provide
funds to the TBTFs at lower costs than to their smaller competitors, because those
loans are implicitly underwritten by the government. This funding cost advantage gives
the TBTFs a competitive advantage over their competitors. After all, if your failure trig-
gers a systemic crisis, you will be bailed out. Your funding costs will reflect that bailout
and so your competitive situation is improved. Finally, in order to become TBTF, it
helps to be seen as big, interconnected and dangerous. If a bank is badly run, it is more
361
Chapter 18 Ongoing developments in financial regulation
dangerous and more likely to become seen as TBTF. This creates perverse incentives for
bank management.
Supervisors
In the past, banking supervisors have not been very concerned about the TBTF institu-
tions. They were not subject to more stringent prudential requirements, nor was their
range of activities restricted. On the contrary, if anything, the tendency of policymakers
was to treat TBTF banks more lightly than other banks, reflecting the perceived benefits of
diversification and management sophistication. In other words, because of their size, they
were considered safer than smaller institutions.
Government
Politicians are also to blame for the TBTF problem. Countries often like to have national
champions, big and powerful banks, visible on the global stage, demonstrating the prow-
ess of the country. Therefore, governments actively encourage banks to become large, to
become TBTF.
A view frequently expressed by governments before 2007, and even to this day, is that
what is good for the national banking champion is good for finance and hence the country.
National champions are, almost by definition, TBTF, and frequently identified as a major
contributory factor to the crisis from 2007. They are one of the main reasons why we have
so far been unable to resolve the banking crisis in Europe.
An interesting observation from Table 18.3 is how many European countries are repre-
sented. The US has its fair share of G-SIBs, eight, but it is within the means of such a large
economy to bail out one or even more of its G-SIBs. Banking assets in the US are much
smaller than in the EU. Furthermore, of the top banks in Table 18.3, JP Morgan’s assets
equal 15% of GDP and Citigroup’s 13%. Overall, the assets of US banks aggregate to less
than the country’s GDP.
The same cannot be said for the European countries; for example, the UK and France
each have four G-SIBs. Two European countries facing a sovereign debt crisis have some
banks in the G-SIB group, Spain with two and Italy with one. The European banks are
also much larger relative to their national GDP than in the US: Deutsche Bank has 84%
of Germany’s GDP, Santander 92% of Spain’s GDP, and RBS, Barclays and HSBC together
have 337% of the British GDP.
Summary
The crisis demonstrated the problem of TBTF institutions by identifying the importance
of systemic risk compared to idiosyncratic risk. In principle, a large, globally diversified
firm may be less likely to fail than smaller and more concentrated firms. Problems in one
362
18.6 What about too big to fail?
business line are offset by profits elsewhere, and diversification may in principle protect
a large financial institution against idiosyncratic risk, so long as its idiosyncratic risk was
different from that of other financial institutions.
Instead, the crisis showed that financial institutions were exposed to the same
risk to a much greater extent than envisioned and, therefore, exposed to similar self-
reinforcing collapses in confidence as their counterparts. If the markets have doubts
about the institution’s solvency, diversification will not protect it. Lehman was but one
example.
New initiatives
The authorities have recognised that crisis mergers were unfortunate, and have proposed
a range of new measures intended to avoid them in the future.
A number of initiatives are aimed at the TBTF problem, most within the FSB. This
includes special resolution regimes, additional regulations and increased intensity of
supervision, and the G-SIB capital surcharges.
363
Chapter 18 Ongoing developments in financial regulation
Finally, we can expect competition for G-SIB status to be intense because of the lower
funding costs it will bring. The G-SIB designation officially identifies the banks as such.
It sends a signal that the banks are under a special watch, and most likely would not be
allowed to fail. In turn, it makes them a preferred counterparty, lowering their cost of
funding and giving them a competitive advantage. In other words, the G-SIB surcharge
institutionalises the category of institutions that were perhaps the main contributor to the
crisis, and are most likely to be bailed out in the future.
18.7 Summary
Following the crisis that started in 2007, a significant revamp of financial regulations has
been underway. One large set of changes relates to the Basel process and the work of the
FSB. The next iteration of the capital accords, Basel III, is expected to be implemented
from 2013, tightening the calculation of bank capital, introducing drawdown buffers,
countercyclical buffers and special charges for G-SIBs. The accord also specifies new regu-
lations on liquidity.
Several government regulatory institutions have been created as a consequence of the
crisis; some have acquired more responsibility and others less. The relationship between
the central banks, the supervisors and the treasuries has been altered, with the central
banks taking on more responsibility but also losing some of their independence to the
treasury.
Many other ideas have been discussed but have not made it into the reform process.
Some problems, most importantly what to do about TBTFs, are not being dealt with in a
satisfactory manner.
Chapter 9 discussed several regulatory initiatives, CCPs, FTT, restrictions on bonuses
and narrow banking, and we have not repeated that discussion here.
Until a new crisis emerges, the initiatives discussed here, and in Chapter 9, are likely
to be the final word on the financial regulatory process, as there seems to be insufficient
political will to tackle more fundamental issues.
4 Compare contrast the systematic risk institutions in the US, UK and EU.
5 What is the problem the European banking union is meant to solve and what is the
main reason why it may not happen?
7 Which do you prefer, the risk-weighted Basel CAR or the leverage ratio?
364
References
9 Does the NSFR positively or negatively affect the problem of maturity mismatches?
10 What is the maximisation harmonisation principle, and do you think it should be used
to set European capital levels?
12 Do you think that the problem of too big to fail is being adequately addressed?
References
Admati, A. R., DeMarzo, P. M., Hellwig, M. F. and Pfleiderer, P. (2010). Fallacies, irrelevant facts,
and myths in the discussion of capital regulation: why bank equity is not expensive. Working
Paper, Graduate School of Business, Stanford University.
Angelini, P. L., Clerc, L., Curdia, V., Gambacorta, L., Gerali, A., Locarno, A., Motto, R., Roeger, W.,
den Heuvel, S. V. and Vlcek, J. (2011). Basel III: long-term impact on economic performance
and fluctuations. Technical report, Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2011a). Basel Committee issues final elements of the
reforms to raise the quality of regulatory capital. www.bis.org/press/p110113.pdf.
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2011b). Basel III: a global regulatory framework for
more resilient banks and banking systems. Technical report.
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2011c). Global systemically important banks:
assessment methodology and the additional loss absorbency requirement. www.bis.org/
publ/bcbs207.pdf.
Bassani, G. and Trapanese, M. (2011). Crisis management and resolution. In Quagliariello, M.
and Cannata, F., editors, Basel III and Beyond. Riskbooks, London.
Baudino, P. (2011). The policy response: from the G20 requests to the FSB roadmap; working
towards the proposals of the Basel Committee. In Quagliariello, M. and Cannata, F., editors,
Basel III and Beyond. Riskbooks, London.
BIS (2010). Assessing the macroeconomic impact of the transition to stronger capital and
liquidity requirements. www.bis.org/publ/othp10.pdf.
Borio, C., Drehmann, M., Gambacorta, L., Jimenez, G. and Trucharte, C. (2010). Countercyclical
capital buffers: exploring options. Technical report, BIS. Working Paper 317.
de Ramon, S., Iscenko, Z., Osborne, M., Straughan, M. and Andrews, P. (2012). Measuring
the impact of prudential policy on the macroeconomy. A practical application to Basel III
and other responses to the financial crisis. Technical report, FSA. Occasional Paper
Series 42.
Enria, A. (2011). The future of EU regulation. www.eba.europa.eu/cebs/media/aboutus/
Speeches/The-Future-of-EU-Regulation–British-Bankers-Association–29-June-2011.pdf.
Financial Stability Forum (2008). Report of the financial stability forum on enhancing market
and institutional resilience. Technical report.
Financial Times (2008). Winding up Lehman Brothers. Financial Times, 7 November.
Gorter, J. and Bijlsma, M. (2012). Strategic moves. www.risk.net/life-and-pension-risk.
365
Chapter 18 Ongoing developments in financial regulation
Institute of International Finance (2010). Interim report on the cumulative impact of proposed
changes in the banking regulatory framework. Technical report.
Institute of International Finance (2012). Making resolution robust. Technical report.
Quagliariello, M. and Cannata, F. (2011). Basel III and Beyond. Riskbooks, London.
Repullo, R. and Saurina, J. (2011). The countercyclical capital buffer of Basel III: a critical assess-
ment. CEMFI Working Paper 1102, June 2011.
Sorkin, A. R. (2010). Too Big to Fail: Inside the Battle to Save Wall Street. Penguin.
366
19 Sovereign debt crises
Sovereign debt crises happen when a national government – the sovereign – is unable
to service its debt. This form of crisis was common in the developed world until the
second World War (WWII), but after that has mostly been consigned to emerging
markets countries.
The reason is that developed countries are able to borrow in their own currency,
and so can usually find ways to avoid defaulting, perhaps by inflating the debt away.
Recently, however, sovereign debt has become a serious policy issue for some mem-
bers of the euro zone.
This chapter focuses on giving a general background to sovereign debt crises in gen-
eral, as well as the causes of the European sovereign debt crisis. The crisis in Europe is
still ongoing, and because of the rapid developments, we maintain a separate chapter
on that crisis online at www.GlobalFinancialSystems.org.
Key concepts
■ Newfoundland
■ External and domestic debt
■ Sovereign defaults and corporate defaults
■ Enforcement of sovereign debt
■ Currency unions and sovereign debt crises
■ European sovereign debt crisis
Chapter 19 Sovereign debt crises
19.1 Newfoundland
In the long history of sovereign debt crises, creditors have resorted to a variety of extreme
means to enforce their claims. However, they have never used liquidation, in the same
way as a corporation is liquidated, except in the case of Newfoundland. We follow this
story as told by Hale (2003).
Newfoundland is the extreme easternmost part of Canada. The British established a
settlement there in 1497 and the economy was primarily based on fishing. It became the
first self-governing part of the British Empire in 1855 and by the end of the nineteenth
century it enjoyed most of the trappings of sovereignty.
The Newfoundland government borrowed heavily to finance its military expenditures
in the first World War (WWI), and continued increasing its debt throughout the 1920s.
By 1933, its public debt was about three times GDP. By that time the economy had col-
lapsed, not least because the Catholic countries of Latin America stopped buying fish
because of the Great Depression.
The government of Newfoundland asked the British government for help, which
obliged by sending a Royal Commission to investigate the situation. While Newfoundland
preferred to default, this was not considered palatable to the Commission, which
declared: ‘No part of the British Empire has ever yet defaulted on its loan obligations [. . .]
bankruptcy is at best an ugly word and carries a stigma which a nation even more than an
individual would do well to avoid.’
The Deputy Leader of the (opposition) Labour Party, Clement Attlee, suggested that default
was preferable to giving up democracy. Referring to Britain’s own default on its wartime loans
from the United States (US), he said: ‘All the best countries default nowadays’ (Hansard
1933). But in the early 1930s it was impossible to imagine a British dominion defaulting.
The Commission’s proposal was that Newfoundland temporarily give up its independ-
ence to a UK-appointed administration – a dictatorship in all but name – and this was
agreed to by Newfoundland’s population in 1933.
Following WWII, the UK government felt compelled to resolve the issue. The alterna-
tives were for Newfoundland to become a part of the UK, to become a part of the United
States (US), to become independent or to merge with Canada. The first choice was unpal-
atable to the UK, and the second disliked by Canada, so only the last two were considered.
The UK-run administration held a referendum, and a slim majority rejected confedera-
tion with Canada. The administration repeated the referendum several weeks later, this
time getting a majority vote for confederation. The British North America Act required
that the local parliament solicit the federation with Canada, but as Newfoundland had
368
19.2 Sovereign debt
1
See www.measuringworth.com.
369
Chapter 19 Sovereign debt crises
External defaults get much more attention than domestic defaults. One reason is that
they are more common, but it is also because external defaults are highly visible in inter-
national capital markets and, hence, the international press; whereas domestic defaults
are less visible, and often more indirect.
External debt
Most countries prefer to issue domestic currency debt, but this is often not a viable option,
perhaps because the domestic debt market is underdeveloped and not very deep. In this
case, a country might resort to issuing foreign currency debt to overseas investors. We
refer to this as external debt. Of course, anything will sell if priced appropriately, so the
implication is that the yield at which domestic debt can be sold appears unattractively
high compared to that of foreign debt.
Countries default regularly on external debt, often because of adverse external factors,
such as falling commodity prices, increases in interest rates or the sudden stop or reversal
of capital flows. External borrowing, not surprisingly, is strongly pro-cyclical. High com-
modity prices are often correlated with increased borrowing, setting the stage for a debt
crisis when commodity prices eventually drop.
Many emerging markets countries prefer short-term borrowing because it is cheaper
than longer maturities. Investors also prefer shorter maturities, both because that mini-
mises their risk and also because it gives them more ability to discipline borrowers.
However, short-term borrowing introduces roll-over risk and makes a country more vul-
nerable to a liquidity crisis, as we have seen in the East Asian case.
Domestic debt
Domestic currency debt, mostly held by local citizens, has traditionally been the major
part of the overall stock of public debt, perhaps averaging at around two-thirds of total
debt. This proportion is much higher for developed economies. Unlike external debt, out-
right defaults of domestic debt are much less common than defaults on external debt.
Governments, however, have numerous indirect options for reducing the domestic debt
burden, for example inflation, the forced conversion of debt to lower coupon rates, and
a unilateral reduction in principal. Both the UK and the US have resorted to such meas-
ures. Another possibility is financial repression in the form of an interest rate ceiling with
a simultaneous rise in inflation. India, for example, introduced interest rate ceilings in the
wake of its external debt restructuring in 1972–1976.
The many alternatives for reducing the debt burden mean that it is often difficult to deter-
mine exactly what constitutes a default and what is just an event that happens to reduce the
debt burden. The extensive ‘wiggle-room’ this provides borrowers is one reason why foreign
lenders tend to prefer foreign-currency debt, issued in developed countries’ jurisdictions.
370
19.2 Sovereign debt
denomination. For example, between 1542 and 1547 the pound lost 83% of its silver con-
tent. The tools of inflating away debt have changed over the years and the introduction of
fiat money made it much easier for governments to create inflation.
High inflation by itself does not have to imply default, so long as interest rates com-
pensate or the debt is inflation indexed, but a rapid increase in inflation when debt is not
indexed strongly signifies that a government is deliberately deflating debt away. Some
commentators have claimed that the inflation in the US in 1947–1948 was deliberately
created to reduce WWII debt, and once that debt had reached manageable levels, the
government slowed down the inflation. One could argue that the various quantitative
easings (QEs) are a form of inflating debt away.
371
Chapter 19 Sovereign debt crises
Reputation risk
A country that defaults suffers a loss to its reputation, which may hamper its access to
international capital markets or increase future costs of borrowing. Since the ability to tap
the international capital markets at a low cost is quite valuable, it provides direct incen-
tives not to default.
One example of this was provided by South Africa repaying apartheid-era debt. The
Economist (1999) had strong opinions about the consequences: ‘[South Africa’s] credit
rating would be wrecked as it came to be lumped in with other deadbeats. Foreign inves-
tors would be deterred and South Africa would have to pay more for future borrowing.’
Contagion
In Europe, banks are exposed to high-risk European sovereigns, and this may trigger their
default and transmit a sovereign debt crisis to their home country. This works as a channel
for contagion.
372
19.2 Sovereign debt
However, the more exposed a country is to the global economy, the better its previous
reputation, and the less its citizens are prepared for the event, the bigger the impact of a
sovereign default. This is why it is so difficult for European countries to contemplate a default.
The costs can be expected to be much larger than, say, for Argentina which defaulted in 2002.
Some countries manage easily with very high debt levels, perhaps exceeding 240% of
GDP as in Japan, whilst others default with debt levels of 40%. The inability to maintain
high debt levels was called debt intolerance by Reinhart et al. (2003). This happens when a
weak institutional structure, and a problematic political system, make external borrowing
a tempting way to avoid tough decisions regarding fiscal spending and taxing.
What matters is the point at which lenders cease to lend, which depends on their
belief on whether the loan will be repaid. This will be influenced mainly by how much
damage they perceive the borrower is exposed to if they default. If this is high for what-
ever reason, for example because the lender has a big army, the borrower does a lot of
international trade, or the borrower has a big reputation to protect for some other reason,
then the debt/GDP ratio can get high.
Debt intolerance manifests itself in the extreme duress many emerging markets experi-
ence at external debt levels that would seem quite manageable by the standards of more
developed countries. Default can occur in emerging markets at levels of debt well below
the 60% ratio of debt to GDP that is enshrined in the Maastricht Treaty, though the com-
parison is not entirely fair. Maastricht applies to highly developed countries and some
less developed countries that receive credit enhancement via the euro and associated
political machinery; as a result its signatories can be expected to be highly debt tolerant.
Mexico defaulted in 1982 with a ratio of debt to GNP of 47% and Argentina in 2001
at around 50%. Reinhart and Rogoff (2009) find that external debt exceeded 100% of
GNP in only 16% of defaults of emerging markets during 1970–2008. More than half the
defaults occurred at levels below 60%, and 20% occurred below 40%. The threshold level
is determined by the history of the country. A serial defaulter with persistent inflation and
weak institutions and in which citizens are inured to crises will have a lower threshold
than a country that appears to have lower credit risk.
The country that successfully manages the world’s highest debt level is Japan, where
the government debt reached 230% in 2011. The reason such a high debt level is sus-
tainable is that all of the debt is in domestic currency, interest rates are almost zero and
➨
373
Chapter 19 Sovereign debt crises
most of the debt is held by domestic agents. This high debt is not without problems.
The Japanese economy has been stagnating for two decades, often suffering from bor-
derline deflation. If the government attempts to stimulate the economy, it may cause
interest rates to increase, sharply increasing the debt burden. Any attempt to inflate
the debt away would be opposed by the electorate, an unusually high proportion of
whom are beyond retirement age and consequently living primarily on savings.
Vulnerabilities
As a country’s debt gets closer to the intolerance level, it becomes increasingly vulner-
able to shocks. It may not have the funds for a fiscal stimulus, and any negative shock will
reduce tax revenues and, hence, increase the relative debt burden. Even though policy-
makers may find that their debt levels appear manageable under the current – favourable –
economic situation, high debt may mean the country is unable to respond to a crisis. We
see some of this in the European sovereign debt crisis.
This means that it can take very little to trigger a sovereign debt crisis, and it can hap-
pen without any significant changes in wealth or income. All that is needed is a change in
confidence. This means that many of the same forces are at work in a sovereign debt crisis
as in a currency crisis, and we can easily analyse them with one of the second-generation
(2G) currency crisis models discussed earlier.
If the market begins to suspect that a government may not be able to pay back its debt,
it will demand a higher compensation for taking on the higher risk of default. A spike in
bond yields, driven by fear that a government will fail to honour its debt, makes debt refi-
nancing for a country difficult to impossible. This is a sovereign debt crisis. We illustrate
the mechanisms in Figure 19.1.
Funding ample
Sudden stop
374
19.3 Enforcement
19.3 Enforcement
Even though it is just not possible to legally enforce sovereign debt as efficiently as corpo-
rate debt, creditors have a wide variety of means at their disposal to compel governments
to repay.
Institutions
There are several supranational mechanisms for addressing sovereign debt. Perhaps the
most prominent of those is the Paris Club, which is a group of finance officials from 19 of
the world’s largest economies, meeting in the French Ministry of Economy, Finance and
Industry. They provide specialised financial services such as war funding, debt restructur-
ing, debt relief and debt cancellation. Resorting to the Paris Club is often the last course
of action for highly indebted poor countries. Recent examples include the cancelling of
some of the debt of Nigeria, Liberia and the Democratic Republic of Congo.
The International Monetary Fund (IMF) (see Krueger, 2002) proposed a formal legal
mechanism for dealing with sovereign debt restructuring. This would have established
similar legal structures for sovereign debt as exist for corporate debt. However, this initia-
tive was rejected by almost everybody.
Military enforcement
In centuries past, some states resorted to rather extreme measures to guarantee their
claims. Egypt reneged on its obligations to France and Britain in 1882 and as a response
both countries invaded Egypt, making it a British ‘protectorate’. Just a few years before,
the British invaded Istanbul in 1876 in the wake of one of Turkey’s defaults.
Similarly, the US interventions in Venezuela in the 1890s and the Dominican Republic
in 1916 and the occupation of Haiti in 1915 were at least partly motivated by debt repay-
ment concerns. Haiti was effectively run as a military dictatorship by the US Marines, who
used their control of the country’s institutions, such as the customs house, to enforce US
interests.
The French and Belgian occupation of the Ruhr region in Germany between 1923 and
1925 was motivated by German difficulties in making war reparations. The formal pretext
was that Germany was 10 days late in delivering 100,000 telegraph poles!
375
Chapter 19 Sovereign debt crises
for $400m for a debt bought at $10m.’ Peru was forced to pay because it sent funds to
Euroclear to pay bond holders participating in its restructuring, and the Court of Appeals
in Brussels enjoined Euroclear from making the payments because they violated pari passu
clauses. A similar case was reported by the BBC (2012a) in which Ghana impounded
an Argentinian naval vessel at the request of Elliot Capital Management, to enforce the
fund’s claim against Argentina arising from that country’s sovereign default in 2002.
■ Carrots. The creditor can offer to stretch out maturities or raise interest rates to coun-
teract the costs of a haircut. The sovereign can also offer credit enhancements, such as
collateral securities or guarantees. This is quite costly for the sovereign, perhaps even
removing the advantages of defaulting in the first place. Also these sweeteners may run
foul of existing covenants and may violate pari passu clauses.
■ Sticks. If the sovereign is unable or unwilling to fund a restructuring plan, it can
employ a variety of encouragements to get maturity extensions, interest rate reductions
or haircuts. The sovereign can either threaten default or actually default. In every sov-
ereign restructuring over the past 30 years until the Greek restructuring, the sovereign
either suspended payments or threatened default on debt that was not a part of the
restructuring.
376
19.4 Background to the European sovereign debt crisis
Second, don’t delay recognising that debt levels are unsustainable. The longer govern-
ments try to prevent an inevitable restructuring, the higher the costs. Mexico in 1982 and
Argentina in 2001 are good examples of such mistakes. Of course, with governments usu-
ally out of power following restructuring, it can be tempting for them to hold on as long
as possible.
Third, keep track of government obligations. In most cases, the government has a rela-
tively clear idea of its own direct liabilities, but the problem is caused by unmonitored bor-
rowing by other government entities, like local governments or state-owned enterprises,
enjoying a sovereign guarantee. Such borrowing can often explode under the radar. This
was a major problem for Argentina, and is now emerging as a problem for Spain and China.
Fourth, ask for enough relief. If a country comes out of a restructuring process with debt
levels that are too high, the problem remains, and the country may have to go through
many rounds of debt restructuring. A cautionary tale is the repeated debt restructuring of
Latin American countries in the 1980s, and the ongoing problems with Greece.
Fifth, be ruthlessly efficient. Sovereign debt crises don’t come alone, but are usually
the final part of significant underlying problems and are often accompanied by other
crises. It is in everybody’s interests to resolve the crisis as quickly as possible. This is likely
to require dealing with some uncomfortable underlying causes (such as reduced competi-
tiveness or unsustainable expenditure) as well as the crises that result from them.
Finally, be even-handed and treat all creditors the same way. Creditors will always jockey
for advantage. Commercial banks may say they have always provided funds and govern-
ment creditors may use geopolitics. Debtors should not discriminate amongst its creditors,
unless absolutely necessary. One exception might be trade and supplier debt. However,
for every creditor accorded preferential treatment, the remainder must be treated more
harshly, and overall resentment will be increased by any perceived lack of fairness.
377
Chapter 19 Sovereign debt crises
Debt/GDP
100 100%
80%
90
60%
80 40%
The Faroe Islands are a Danish possession situated between Iceland and Scotland. Even
though they are part of Denmark, and use the Danish currency, they are not a member
of the EU. The economy of the Faroes is primarily based on fishing. As the neighbour-
ing countries expanded their economic zones to 200 miles, the Faroese fishing fleet lost
access to its traditional fishing grounds, and profits plummeted. In response, the govern-
ment of the Faroes resorted to subsidising its only export sector – fishing – to the tune of
34% of total exports throughout the 1980s.
Prior to the crisis in 1990, government net debt never exceeded 50% of GDP. Private
debt, however, had been increasing rapidly, reaching 125% of GDP in 1990. The private
borrowing was facilitated by government guarantees, capital subsidies and production
guarantees. Some of the loan guarantees were deliberately kept secret from the Faroese
parliament, the Danish government and the general public, while bad book-keeping
shielded other support from scrutiny.
The guarantees meant the foreign creditors only worried about the ability of the Faroese
government to repay the loans. Creditors implicitly assumed the Faroese sovereign debt
was underwritten by the Danish government, with its AAA rating, even though no explicit
guarantees were issued. The Danish government did not seem all that concerned and did
nothing to disabuse the creditors.
The money was not put to good use, export subsidies directly added to the debt bur-
den and many, if not most, investments turned out to be sour. In addition to financial
intermediation, the local banks actively engaged in interest rate and tax arbitrage between
the Faroe Islands and Denmark, reaping significant profits.
Eventually, it all got too much, and as the economy was hit by exogenous shocks due to a
slowdown in the global economy and reduced fishing catch, a sovereign debt crisis ensued.
The first affected were the banks, and the Danish financial supervisor became concerned
and demanded that the banks shut down their arbitrage schemes and sharply increase
loan provisions. This was the final straw for the banks. They defaulted and the Danish
government forced the Faroese government to take the banks over at its own expense. This
caused debt to reach 140% of GDP, mostly borrowed from the Danish government.
To the chagrin of the Faroese, the Danish deposit insurance fund and foreign banks,
like Danske Bank, got off relatively scot-free. As the domestic banks defaulted, the GDP
378
19.4 Background to the European sovereign debt crisis
contracted by 40%, and 15% of the population emigrated. The crisis soured relations
between the Faroese and their colonial masters. The Faroese maintained that Denmark
had acted with malice in forcing them to assume too much debt in the crisis and imposing
too much austerity, a view vindicated by the Danish state commission report on the crisis
in January 1998 and a Danish parliamentary decision to ask the government to renegoti-
ate the settlement terms in favour of the Faroese. The Danes worried about moral hazard
and claimed the Faroese had been irresponsible and should not have an open-ended
claim on the Danish treasury.
The conflict simmered until March 1998, when the Social Democrats won a majority in
the Danish parliament, provided that the Faroese Social Democratic MP supported them,
which he did, securing a settlement of the dispute worth DKK 1.5 billion to the Faorese
authorities, or 20% of the islands’ GDP.
After the crisis, the Faroese economy recovered swiftly, with an annual growth of 4%
between 1995 and 2010. The Faroese ran a capital account surplus amounting to 13%
of GDP per year for a decade, eliminating the sovereign debt. This was helped by the
re-exports of the excess investment goods acquired prior to the crisis, and a sharp fall in
imports, not least because of widespread emigration.
There are many parallels between the Faroese crisis and the ongoing European sover-
eign debt crisis, especially for Greece. Both countries got into difficulty because of excess
borrowing, facilitated by belonging to a currency union with an AAA-rated partner. The
creditors implicitly assumed that the debt was somehow underwritten, and that fiscal
misconduct was prevented by the rules of the greater community. In neither case did the
senior partner seem all that concerned, even as the sovereign debt spiralled upwards.
In the Faroese case, the crisis in state relations was eventually resolved when political
necessities outweighed the cost of the bailout. It did help to have representation in the
parliament of the main protagonist.
379
Chapter 19 Sovereign debt crises
The German monetary union in 1857 was a success. It replaced the currencies of the
many German states with a dual system that lasted until the German unification of 1870,
with the two currencies themselves replaced by the mark in 1875.
The other main success was the Belgium–Luxembourg monetary union of 1922. This
came under stress on occasion, especially in the 1980s when Belgium unilaterally deval-
ued the franc, infuriating the Luxembourgers. In response, Luxembourg set up a standby
central bank, ready to switch over to Luxembourg francs within 24 hours if Belgium mis-
behaved again.
Intergovernmental transfers are very common, as, for example, in development aid. Most
of these do not imply that the countries involved are members of a transfer union. For
example, development aid fails both of the tests in the definition above.
Is the EU a transfer union or not? If we look at the EU budget for 2010 (European Union,
2011, Annex 2c, p. 75), we see that the net amount received by member countries is
around 0.3% of the GDP of the Union, even though for some member countries it might
be as high as 4%. It is harder to identify net transfers within individual countries, but one
report attempts to do that for Spain for 2005 (Spanish government, 2008, table 1, p. 13),
finding that intra-region transfers amount to 2.2% of the GDP of Spain, in some regions
amounting to 16% of that region’s GDP.
This suggests that a transfer union is defined by the magnitude of the transfers.
Individual nation states transfer an order of magnitude more funds between regions than
the EU. Consequently, individual nation states are generally transfer unions, but the EU
is not.
380
19.4 Background to the European sovereign debt crisis
monetary policy. Also, over time, it is likely that some countries prosper and others are
left behind. If so, they will come to require different monetary policies. This suggests
that unless a transfer union is in place, currency unions among near equal parties are
unstable.
Definition 19.2 Maastricht debt criteria The deficit must not exceed 3% annually,
with the possibility of temporary suspension in exceptional cases. Government debt must
not exceed 60% of GDP, and if it is higher, must approach the 60% at a satisfactory pace.
Table 19.1 shows the debt and deficits of member countries in the year they joined.
More than half violated Maastricht criteria that year, and of those that qualified, two are
now in a state of crisis.
2
Austria, Belgium, Cyprus, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg,
Malta, the Netherlands, Portugal, Slovakia, Slovenia and Spain.
3
Montenegro, Andorra, Monaco, San Marino, Vatican City and Kosovo.
381
Chapter 19 Sovereign debt crises
Table 19.1 Euro zone deficit and debt in first year of euro membership and Maastricht compliance
382
19.4 Background to the European sovereign debt crisis
Table 19.2 Euro zone debt to GDP, Maastricht compliance, and ratings in August 2012
2011 Rating,
primary August Compliance with
Country 1995 debt 2007 debt 2011 debt 2011 deficit balance 2012 Maastricht
Belgium
Netherlands
Finland
Estonia
Italy
Austria
Spain
Luxembourg
Cyprus
Slovakia
Germany
Ireland
Slovenia
France
Malta
Portugal
Greece
383
Chapter 19 Sovereign debt crises
B− B−
B+ Greece Ireland Italy B+
BB+ Portugal Spain Cyprus BB+
BBB BBB
A− A−
A+ A+
AA AA
AAA AAA
1995 2000 2005 2010
(a) 1995 to July 2012
Greece Spain
B− B−
Portugal Italy
B+ Ireland Cyprus B+
BB+ BB+
BBB BBB
A− A−
A+ A+
AA AA
AAA AAA
2010 2011 2012
(b) August 2009 to July 2012
Austria Italy
Belgium Netherlands
1000% France Portugal 1000%
500% Germany Spain 500%
Ireland
100% 100%
50% 50%
10% 10%
1980 1990 2000 2010
10 times the GDP, and Italy the smallest at 1.2. In round terms, external debt has increased
10 times since the collapse of Bretton Woods.
384
19.4 Background to the European sovereign debt crisis
Estonia
Slovakia
Slovenia
Ireland
Luxembourg
Greece
Finland
Cyprus
Spain
Austria
Netherlands
Belgium
Germany
France
Portugal 1999−2007
Italy 2008−2011
−2% 0% 2% 4% 6%
Estonia
Slovakia
Slovenia
Greece
Finland
Ireland
Austria
Cyprus
Netherlands
Luxembourg
Portugal
France
Belgium
Italy 1999−2007
Spain 2008−2011
−1% 0% 1% 2% 3% 4% 5% 6%
in a precarious position. We can see economic and productivity growth in Figures 19.6
and 19.7, respectively.
It is important to note that the benefits of the euro zone do not all flow in one direc-
tion. The presence of uncompetitive countries in the euro zone has over many years weak-
ened the euro and so improved external (to EU) terms of trade for the most competitive;
385
Chapter 19 Sovereign debt crises
these have also benefited from growth at the expense of their less competitive neighbours.
Germany’s full employment and relatively healthy domestic finances are due in part to
the currency union. Below we present background analysis on main crisis countries. More
information is in the online chapter at www.GlobalFinancialSystems.org.
Greece
The crisis had its origins in Greece, which was one of the fastest growing economies in the
euro zone in the 1990s and early 2000s, averaging an annual growth rate of close to 4%.
This was fuelled by a rapid increase in debt, 68% between 1995 and 2011, the highest in
the euro zone. At the time it joined the euro, it already violated the Maastricht criteria, but
unlike the other two high-debt countries, Italy and Belgium, its primary balance was low.
Furthermore, the debt numbers were manipulated downwards, and are reported as provi-
sional. To comply with the monetary requirements for joining the euro, the Greek govern-
ment consistently and deliberately misreported the country’s official economic statistics.
For example, Greece paid several investment banks to execute deals that moved a high level
of debt off-balance sheet in order to conceal the actual level of debt. Greece never enjoyed
a high credit rating; still, until 2009 its rating was A, and as recently as 2004 it was A +.
While there are many reasons for the crisis in Greece, prior to joining the euro its ability
to borrow too much was limited by its high inflation and perceived structural weaknesses.
The governments would use devaluations to stimulate the economy when needed. After
it joined, it was able to borrow at almost the same interest rate as Germany, as investors
assumed in the early years of the currency union that bonds of various euro zone coun-
tries carried equal risks.
After a general election in 2009 swept a new government into office, the incoming
prime minister, George Papandreou, revised the actual deficit figures of the country from
an originally estimated 6% to 12.7%, later increased to 13.6%. Accumulated sovereign
debt reached 165% of GDP in 2011.
As the true situation of Greece’s public finances became apparent, Greek public debt
was downgraded several times, leading to rapid increases in bond yields as a default
started to appear like a real possibility. The new government embarked on a course of
harsh austerity measures but did not manage to convince the markets.
Ireland
The second country to run into difficulties was Ireland. We have already discussed its prob-
lems in Section 14.1. The difficulties in Ireland were quite different in nature from those in
Greece. The government seemed quite prudent in its public financing; the problems were
in the banking sector, mostly financed with borrowing from abroad. After the government
failed in its attempt to use sovereign liquidity guarantees to the banks as means to restore
confidence, the Irish debt levels increased from 25% in 2007 to 108% in 2011, and are still
rising. The Irish government obtained an €85 billion bailout from the EU in 2010.
Portugal
Soon after Greece got into difficulty, Portugal followed, for many of the same reasons but
not on as extreme a scale as Greece. Eventually, it got a €78 billion bailout from the EU and
the IMF in 2011. In return, it has to implement austerity measures, such as privatisation,
386
19.4 Background to the European sovereign debt crisis
increasing sales taxes, freezing or cutting benefits, cutting school spending, freezing pen-
sions and reducing the number of civil servants. Unemployment reached 14.8% in the
beginning of 2012. To date, Portugal has been able to comply with the requirements, and
the current consensus suggests that its problems are less profound than those of Greece.
Cyprus
Cyprus is the latest country to get into difficulty, caused primarily by the exposure of its banks
to Greece. It requested a bailout from the EU in the summer of 2012, but delays in coming to
an agreement led to a banking crisis in March 2013, which ended with a bailout agreement
with the EU and the IMF, with large haircuts imposed on bank creditors and depositors.
Spain
The situation in Spain is in many ways similar to that of Ireland. In both cases the govern-
ment had low debt, and the problems were created in the banking sector. In both coun-
tries, real-estate speculation played an important part, especially in Spain.
The Spanish government was slow to wake up to its problems; as problems in the
banking sector mounted, and as unemployment sharply increased, it was perceived as sit-
ting on its hands. This undermined investor confidence in the government, in spite of its
low debt levels at the time, and the cost of borrowing increased sharply, along with debt
downgrades. In 2012, finally recognising the problems in the banking sector, the govern-
ment got a banking bailout from the EU. In exchange, Spain gave up some supervisory
control over its banking sector, the first step towards a banking union. After all, ‘he who
pays the piper calls the tune’!
Italy
If we had been studying the statistics presented here in 2007, none of the crisis countries
would have shown particular weaknesses compared to other member states. The only
exception is Italy. It was not compliant with the Maastricht criteria when it joined, with
debt of 113%, and its debt levels are essentially the same now as they were in 1995. It had
the lowest economic growth in the euro zone in the first eight years of the euro, the sec-
ond lowest productivity growth after Spain (almost zero) and is ageing rapidly. The main
positive factor is that Italian debt is mostly held domestically.
Italy so far has avoided a sovereign debt crisis, but there are considerable fears that it
might get to that state if it is not able to effectively address its structural problems.
387
Chapter 19 Sovereign debt crises
at the same time their borrowing rates are likely to improve. Initially, such countries find
it easier to borrow, while at the same time they have less ability for dealing with a crisis. It
seems optimistic of the designers of the euro in the 1990s to discount such an eventuality.
The problem has become so extreme because no member country (supposedly) can
leave the euro zone, so that the fate of the weakest member automatically becomes a
direct concern of the strongest number. Lenders’ belief in this proposition was the reason
for the sharp reduction in interest rates enjoyed by the weaker countries, contributing
greatly to the economic booms preceding the crisis.
388
19.5 Summary
enabling factor is the euro, the cross-border economic activity it (by design) increased,
and the result that a major crisis in any member country can cause a crisis of confidence
elsewhere.
This is why the crisis response of the European authorities is so important. To date, the
response has not been sufficient to stop the crisis, and the situation is at best stable but
in a very unsatisfactory state. More probably it will continue to deteriorate, as the funda-
mental problems remain unaddressed. It seems likely that some trigger may be required
to bring about fundamental change.
19.5 Summary
We started by discussing one of the extreme cases of dealing with the sovereign debt cri-
sis, when the country of Newfoundland was liquidated.
The topic of this chapter is sovereign debt crises, perhaps the most common form of
crisis throughout history. We discussed the nature of sovereign debt crises, what makes
sovereign debt special and different from corporate debt, how the interests of creditors can
be protected, and how a country should respond when faced with a sovereign debt crisis.
Even though there is no international court that enforces sovereign debt, creditors have
a variety of means at their disposal, historically military intervention and more recently a
range of sanctions.
We followed this by a discussion of the European sovereign debt crisis, starting with the
first sovereign debt crisis in the EU, and analysis of monetary unions, why they succeed and
why they fail. This is key to understanding the European sovereign debt crisis, and we ana-
lysed to what extent the necessary conditions for a successful monetary union have been
present in the euro zone. Finally, we discussed some of the European countries that are expe-
riencing economic difficulty, why it is so difficult to solve the crisis, and the global impact.
We leave a detailed analysis of current events to a chapter that is published online at
www.GlobalFinancialSystems.org.
2 How can a government default on its debt without actually declaring default?
3 Yields on government bonds of the US are currently trading at record lows. How can
this be reconciled with the fact that the US is approaching its greatest level of debt to
GDP in its history, apart from in wartime?
4 Do you think a return to gunboat diplomacy would be useful in dealing with sovereign
debt crises?
5 The role of entities buying sovereign bonds on the secondary market at a big discount is
controversial, especially the so-called ‘vulture funds’. Do you agree with their methods
and, more generally, what is your view on the enforcement mechanisms that should
exist for sovereign debt?
389
Chapter 19 Sovereign debt crises
6 What is the main reason why the euro zone was established?
7 What are main conditions for a successful monetary union, and did the euro zone fulfil
those criteria?
11 Does a country suffer more when it experiences a currency crisis or when it experiences
a banking crisis or a sovereign debt crisis?
12 Many commentators talk of contagion when it comes to sovereign debt crises. Identify
how this could happen.
References
BBC (2012a). Argentina ship in Ghana seized over loans default. www.bbc.co.uk/news/
world-africa-19827562.
Borensztein, E. and Panizza, U. (2008). The costs of sovereign default. Technical Report
WP/08/238, IMF.
Buchheit, L. C. (2011). Sovereign debt restructuring – the legal context. Cleary Gottlieb Steen &
Hamilton LLP, New York.
Daníelsson, J. and Oskarsson, H. (2012). The first sovereign debt crisis in the EU. Vox EU, 11
September. www.voxeu.org/article/europe-s-pre-eurozone-debt-crisis-faroe-islands-1990s.
European Union (2011). EU budget 2010 financial report. Technical report.
Gulati, M. and Triantis, G. (2007). Contracts without law: sovereign versus corporate debt.
University of Cincinnati Law Review, 75: 977–1004.
Hale, D. (2003). The Newfoundland lesson. The International Economy, 17(3): 52–61.
Hansard (1993) http://hansard.millbanksystems.com/commons/1933/dec/12/newfoundland-
bill#S5CV0284PO_19331212_HOC_267.
Homer, S. and Sylla, R. (1996). A History of Interest Rates. Rutgers University Press.
Kaseki, J.-R. (2007). Preying on the poor. The Guardian, 27 September.
Krueger, A. O. (2002). A new approach to sovereign debt restructuring. Technical report, IMF.
Marsh, D. (2010). The Euro: the Politics of the New Global Currency. Yale University Press.
Mundell, R. A. (1961). A theory of optimum currency areas. Amer. Econ. Rev., 51: 657–65.
Reinhart, C. M. and Rogoff, K. (2009). This Time Is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly.
Princeton University Press.
Reinhart, C. M., Rogoff, K. and Savastano, M. A. (2003). Debt intolerance. Technical report,
NBER.
Spanish government (2008). Las balanzas fiscales de las CC.AA. españolas con las aa. Públicas
Centrales 2005. Technical report, Ministerio de Economía y Hacienda.
Sturzenegger, F. and Zettelmeyer, J. (2007). Debt Defaults and Lessons from a Decade of Crises.
MIT Press.
The Economist (1999). South Africa’s debt: unforgivable. The Economist (US), 24 April.
390
Glossary
Basel III the next version of the international capital DJIA the Dow Jones industrial average index is a popu-
accords, intended to be implemented from 2013 but lar United States stock market index.
being delayed. EBA European Banking Authority.
BCBS Basel Committee for Banking Supervision is a ECB European Central Bank.
group of senior officials that design international finan- ECU European Currency Unit.
cial regulations, best known for the Basel Accords.
EEA European Economic Area.
BCCI Bank of Credit and Commerce International, a
EMH the efficient market hypothesis maintains that
Luxembourg-registered bank, with head offices in
one cannot systematically earn excessive profits from
Karachi and London. It was established in 1972 and
exploiting public information.
collapsed in 1991 after massive fraud.
BIS Bank for International Settlements. EMS European Monetary System.
CAC collective action clauses permit the majority or ESMA European Securities and Markets Authority.
supermajority of creditors to modify key features of ESRB European Systemic Risk Board.
the terms of bonds, including principal and interest EU European Union.
payments.
EURIBOR Euro Interbank Offered Rate, a reference
CAPM capital asset pricing model. rate calculated from the averaged interest rates at
CAR capital adequacy ratio. which euro zone banks offer to lend unsecured funds
CBT computer based trading. to other banks.
CCP central counterparty. FDIC Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation.
CDO collateralised debt obligation. Fed the Federal Reserve System is the central bank of
CDS credit default swap. the United States.
391
Glossary
FPC Financial Policy Committee. NYFed the New York Federal Reserve bank is the most
FSA Financial Services Authority. important branch of the Fed. It is the Fed’s main
interface with financial markets.
FSB Financial Stability Board.
O&G Overend and Gurney.
FSF Financial Stability Forum, a group of financial autho
rities of the G7 countries. It is superseded by the FSB. OECD Organisation for Economic Cooperation and
Development, a Paris-based international organisation.
FSOC Financial Stability Oversight Council.
OTC over-the-counter.
FT100 the main British stock market index.
PPP purchasing power parity.
FTT financial transaction tax.
QE quantitative easing.
FX foreign exchange.
RBS Royal Bank of Scotland is a large British bank
GATT General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade.
that got bailed out by the government in the crisis
G-SIB global systemically important banks that have
from 2007.
been identified by the FSB as being especially large
RFC Reconstruction Finance Corporation.
and whose failure poses a special danger to the
world economy. RWA risk-weighted assets of a bank, used in capital
calculations.
G20 a group of large countries that include Argentina,
Australia, Brazil, Canada, China, France, Germany, India, S&L savings and loans, a part of the United States
Indonesia, Italy, Japan, Mexico, Russia, Saudi Arabia, financial system that was in a crisis in the 1980s.
South Africa, South Korea, Turkey, the United Kingdom, S&P Standard & Poor.
the United States and collectively the European Union. S&P-500 the Standard & Poor’s 500 index is the most
GDP gross domestic product. representative United States stock market index.
GNP gross national product. SDR special drawing rights, a virtual currency created
HBOS a large British bank that failed in the crisis from by the IMF.
2007. SEC Securities and Exchange Commission.
HFT high-frequency trading. SIC Special Investigation Commission.
HSBC a large British bank. SIFI systemically important financial institution.
IIF the Institute of International Finance is the main advo- SIV structured investment vehicle.
cacy group (lobbyists) of internationally active banks. SME small and medium-sized enterprise.
IKB a German bank that was the first financial institu- SNB Swiss National Bank.
tion to fail in the crisis in 2007.
SPV special purpose vehicle.
ILOLR international lender of last resort.
SSM Single Supervisory Mechanism, the embryonic
IMF International Monetary Fund. pan-EU supervisor.
IOSCO International Organization of Securities TA total assets of a bank, used in capital calculations.
Commissions is an association of organisations that
TARP Troubled Asset Relief Program.
regulate the world’s securities and futures markets.
TBTF too big to fail.
IRB internal rating based refers to banks developing
UBS a large Swiss bank.
their own methodologies for assessing risk.
UIP uncovered interest rate parity.
LCR liquidity coverage ratio.
UK United Kingdom.
LIBOR London Interbank Offered Rate, average inter-
est rate from banks calculated by the British Bankers’ US United States.
Association. USD US dollar.
LOLR lending of last resort. VaR Value-at-Risk is a common statistical technique
LR leverage ratio. for forecasting market risk.
LTCM Long Term Capital Management, a celebrated VIX implied volatility of the S&P-500 index.
hedge fund that failed in 1998, triggering a global crisis. WTO World Trade Organization.
MPT modern portfolio theory. WWI First World War.
NSFR net stable funding ratio. WWII Second World War.
392
Bibliography
Abdelal, R. (2007). Capital Rules: The Construction of Barnier, M. (2011) quoted in Barker, A., EU ban on ‘na-
Global Finance. Harvard University Press. ked’ CDS to become permanent. Financial Times,
Acharya, V. and Pedersen, L. H. (2005). Asset pricing 19 October, www.ft.com/cms/s/0/cc9c5050-f96f-
with liquidity risk. J. Finan. Econ., 77: 375–410. 11e0-bf8f-00144feab49a.html.
Admati, A. R., DeMarzo, P. M., Hellwig, M. F., and Pflei- Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (1996).
derer, P. (2010). Fallacies, irrelevant facts, and myths Amendment to the Capital Accord to Incorporate
in the discussion of capital regulation: why bank Market Risks. www.bis.org/publ/bcbs24.pdf.
equity is not expensive. Working Paper, Graduate Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2004). Bank
School of Business, Stanford University. failures in mature economies. Working paper no. 13,
Adrian, T. and Shin, H. S. (2010). Liquidity and leverage. Bank of International Settlements.
J. Finan. Intermed., 19: 418–37. Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2006). The
Ahamed, L. (2009). Lords of Finance, The Bankers Who management of liquidity risk in financial groups.
Broke the World. The Penguin Group. Technical report, pp. 1–25.
Akerlof, G. (1970). The market for ‘lemons’: quality un- Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2011a). Ba-
certainty and the market mechanism. Quart. J. Econ., sel Committee issues final elements of the reforms to
84(3): 488–500. raise the quality of regulatory capital. www.bis.org/
Alba, P., Bhattacharya, A., Claessens, S., Ghosh, S. and press/p110113.pdf.
Hernandez, L. (1998). Volatility and contagion in a Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2011b). Ba-
financially-integrated world: lessons from East Asia’s sel III: a global regulatory framework for more resil-
recent experience. Paper presented at the PAFTAD 24 ient banks and banking systems. Technical report.
Conference, ‘Asia Pacific Financial Liberalization and Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2011c).
Reform’, 1998. Global systemically important banks: assessment
Alessandri, P. and Haldane, A. G. (2009). Banking on methodology and the additional loss absorbency re-
the state. Mimeo, Bank of England. quirement. www.bis.org/publ/bcbs207.pdf.
Allen, F. and Gale, D. (1994). Limited market participa- Bassani, G. and Trapanese, M. (2011). Crisis manage-
tion and volatility of asset prices. Amer. Econ. Rev., 84: ment and resolution. In Quagliariello, M. and Canna-
933–55. ta, F., editors, Basel III and Beyond. Riskbooks, London.
Allen, F. and Gale, D. (2005). From cash-in-the-market Baudino, P. (2011). The policy response: from the G20
pricing to financial fragility. J. Eur. Econ. Assoc., 3: requests to the FSB roadmap; working towards the
535–46. proposals of the Basel Committee. In Quagliariello,
Anderson, G. M., Shughart, W. F., II and Tollison, R. D. M. and Cannata, F., editors, Basel III and Beyond. Risk-
(1988). A public choice theory of the great contrac- books, London.
tion. Public Choice, 59: 3–23. BBC (2012a). Argentina ship in Ghana seized over loans
Angelini, P. L., Clerc, L., Curdia, V., Gambacorta, L., Gerali, default. www.bbc.co.uk/news/world-africa-19827562.
A., Locarno, A., Motto, R., Roeger, W., den Heuvel, S. V. BBC (2012b). Barclays’ widening Libor-fixing scandal.
and Vlcek, J. (2011). Basel III: long-term impact on eco- www.bbc.co.uk/news/ business-18671255.
nomic performance and fluctuations. Technical report, Benediktsdottir, S., Danielsson, J. and Zoega, G. (2011).
Federal Reserve Bank of New York. Lessons from a collapse of a financial system. Eco-
Arnason, R. and Danielsson, J. (2011). Capital controls nomic Policy, 26: 183–231.
are exactly wrong for Iceland. Vox EU, 14 November. Bernanke, B. (1995). The macroeconomics of the Great
www.voxeu.org/article/iceland-and-imf-why-capital Depression: a comparative approach. J. Money Credit
controls-are-entirely-wrong. and Banking, 27(1): 1–28.
Bagehot, W. (1873). Lombard Street: a Description of the Bernanke, B. S. (2005). The global saving glut and the
Money Market. H.S. King, London. US current account deficit. Speech delivered at the
Bandt, D. and Hartmann, P. (2000). Systemic risk: a sur- Sandridge Lecture, Virginia Association of Econo-
vey. Working paper no. 35, European Central Bank. mists, Richmond, VA.
393
Bibliography
BIS (2010). Assessing the macroeconomic impact of the Brunnermeier, M. and Pedersen, L. H. (2009). Market li-
transition to stronger capital and liquidity require- quidity and funding liquidity. Rev. Finan. Stud., 22(6):
ments. www.bis.org/publ/othp10.pdf. 2201–38.
Bitner, R. (2008). Confessions of a Subprime Lender: an Buchheit, L. C. (2011). Sovereign debt restructuring –
Insider’s Tale of Greed, Fraud, and Ignorance. John the legal context. Cleary Gottlieb Steen & Hamilton
Wiley & Sons. LLP, New York.
Black, F. (1971). Toward a fully automated exchange, Buffett, W. (2003). Avoiding a mega-catastrophe. Fortune,
part I. Financial Analysts J., 27: 28–35. 24 March.
Black, F. (1995). Hedging, speculation, and systemic Buffett, W. (2012). Why stocks beat gold and bonds.
risk. J. Derivatives, 2: 6–8. Fortune, 27 February.
Black, F. and Scholes, M. (1973a). The pricing of op- Bussiere, M., Saxena, S. C. and Tovar, C. E. (2010).
tions and corporate liabilities. J. Polit. Econ., 81(3): Chronicle of currency collapses re-examining the ef-
637–54. fects on output. Technical report, ECB. Working pa-
Black, F. and Scholes, M. (1973b). The valuation of per series no. 1226, July.
option contracts and a test of market efficiency. J. Fi- Cagan, P. (1956). The monetary dynamics of hyperinfla-
nance, 27: 399–418. tion. In Friedman, M., editor, Studies in the Quantity
Bloomberg (2011). Secret Fed loans undisclosed to Theory of Money. University of Chicago Press.
Congress gave banks $13 billion in income. www. Calello, P. and Ervin, W. (2010). From bail-out to bail-
bloomberg.com/news/2011-11-28/secret-fed-loan- in. The Economist, 28 January.
sundisclosed-to-congress-gave-banks-13-billion-in- Capie, F. and Wood, G. E. (2006). The Lender of Last Re-
income.html. sort. Routledge.
Blundell-Wignall, A. and Atkinson, P. (2010). Thinking Caprio, G. and Honohan, P. (2009). Banking crises. In
beyond Basel III: necessary solutions for capital and Berger, A., Molyneux, P., and Wilson, J., editors, The
liquidity. OECD Journal: Financial Market Trends, Vol- Oxford Handbook of Banking. Oxford University Press.
ume 2010, Issue 1. Committee on the Global Financial System (1999). A
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System review of financial market events in autumn 1998.
(2009). Revenge of the steamroller: ABCP as a win- Technical report, Bank for International Settlements.
dow on risk choices. Unpublished paper, Division of Copeland, L. (2000). Exchange Rates and International
International Finance. Finance. Prentice Hall.
Borensztein, E. and Panizza, U. (2008). The costs of sov- Coval, J., Jurek, J. and Stafford, E. (2008a). The econom-
ereign default. Technical Report WP/08/238, IMF. ics of structured finance. Harvard Business School
Borio, C. (2009). Ten propositions about liquidity cri- Working Paper 09-060.
sis. Working paper no. 293, Bank of International Coval, J. D., Jurek, J. W. and Stafford, E. (2008b). Eco-
Settlements. nomic catastrophe bonds. Mimeo, Harvard University.
Borio, C. and Disyatat, P. (2011). Global imbalances Crockett, A. (2000). Marrying the micro- and macro-
and the financial crisis: link or no link? Technical re- prudential dimensions of financial stability. The
port, BIS. Working Paper 346. General Manager of the Bank for International Settle-
Borio, C., Drehmann, M., Gambacorta, L., Jimenez, G. ments, www.bis.org/review/rr000921b.pdf.
and Trucharte, C. (2010). Countercyclical capital Crouhy, M., Galai, D. and Mark, R. (2000). Risk Manage-
buffers: exploring options. Technical report, BIS. ment. McGraw-Hill.
Working Paper 317. Danielsson, J. (2011). Financial Risk Forecasting. John
Brady Commission (1988). Report of the presidential Wiley & Sons.
task force on market mechanisms. Technical report, Danielsson, J. and Keating, C. (2009). Bonus incensed.
Government Printing Office, Washington, DC. Vox EU, 25 May. http://voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/
Brown, W. A. (1940). The international gold standard 3602.
reinterpreted, 1914–1934. Technical report, National Danielsson, J. and Oskarsson, H. (2012). The first sov-
Bureau of Economic Research. ereign debt crisis in the EU. Vox EU, 11 September.
Bruner, R. F. and Carr, S. D. (2007). The Panic of 1907: www.voxeu.org/article/europe-s-pre-eurozone-debt-
Lessons Learned from the Market’s Perfect Storm. John crisis-faroe-islands-1990s.
Wiley & Sons. Danielsson, J. and Shin, H. S. (2003). Endogenous risk.
Brunnermeier, M. (2008). Deciphering the 2007–08 liquid- In Modern Risk Management – a History. Risk Books,
ity and credit crunch. J. Econ. Perspect., 23(1): 77–100. London. www.riskresearch.org.
394
Bibliography
Danielsson, J., Embrechts, P., Goodhart, C., Keating, C., Enria, A. (2011). The future of EU regulation. www.
Muennich, F., Renault, O. and Shin, H. S. (2001). An eba.europa.eu/cebs/media/aboutus/Speeches/The-
academic response to Basel II. www.bis.org/bcbs/ca/ Future-of-EURegulation–British-Bankers-Association–
fmg.pdf. 29-June-2011.pdf.
Danielsson, J., Shin, H. and Zigrand, J.-P. (2012a). En- Epstein, G. and Ferguson, T. (1984). Monetary policy,
dogenous and systemic risk. In Haubrich, J. G. and Lo, loan liquidation, and industrial conflict: the Federal
A. W., editors, Quantifying Systemic Risk. University of Reserve and open market operations of 1932. J. Econ.
Chicago Press for NBER; Download from www.risk His., 44: 957–83.
research.org. European Union (2011). EU budget 2010 financial re-
Danielsson, J., Shin, H. and Zigrand, J.-P. (2012b). En- port. Technical report.
dogenous extreme events and the dual role of prices. Fabozzi, F. J. (2009). Bond Markets, Analysis, and Strate-
Ann. Rev. Econ., 4(1): 111–129; download from www. gies, 7th edition. Pearson.
riskresearch.org. Ferguson, N. (2008). The Ascent of Money. The Penguin
Danielsson, J., Shin, H. and Zigrand, J.-P. (2012c). Pro- Group.
cyclical leverage and endogenous risk. Mimeo, LSE, Financial Services Authority (2009a). Reforming re
www.riskresearch.org. muneration practices in financial services. Technical
Darling, A. (2011). Back from the Brink: 1,000 Days at report.
Number 11. Atlantic Books, London. Financial Services Authority (2009b). The Turner re-
Davis, E. P. (1999). A reappraisal of market liquidity view: a regulatory response to the global banking cri-
risk in the light of the Russian/LTCM global securities sis. Technical report, European Central Bank. www.
markets crisis. Bank of England. fsa.gov.uk/pubs/other/turner review.pdf.
de Ramon, S., Iscenko, Z., Osborne, M., Straughan, M. Financial Services Authority (2012). Final notice. Techni-
and Andrews, P. (2012). Measuring the impact of cal report. www.fsa.gov.uk/static/pubs/final/barclays-
prudential policy on the macroeconomy. A practical jun12.pdf.
application to Basel III and other responses to the fi- Financial Stability Board (2012) Update of global
nancial crisis. Technical report, FSA. Occasional Paper systemically important banks (G-SIBS) Annex 1, Bank
Series 42. for International Settlements.
de Soto, J. H. (2009). Money, Bank Credit, and Economic Financial Stability Forum (2008). Report of the financial
Cycles. Ludwig von Mises Institute, Auburn, AL. stability forum on enhancing market and institution-
Dewatripont, M. and Tirole, J. (1994). The Prudential al resilience. Technical report.
Regulation of Banks. MIT Press. Financial Times (2007). Goldman pays the price of be-
Diamond, D. and Dybvig, P. (1983). Bank runs, deposit ing big. Financial Times, 13 August.
insurance, and liquidity. J. Polit. Econ., 91: 401–19. Financial Times (2008). Winding up Lehman Brothers.
Duffie, D. (2007). Innovations in credit risk transfer: Financial Times, 7 November.
implications for financial stability. Mimeo, Stanford Financial Times (2010a). The benefits of naked CDS. Fi-
University. nancial Times, 2 March.
Duffie, D. (2010). Is there a case for banning short spec- Financial Times (2010b). HSBC in clearest warning over
ulation in sovereign bond markets? Financial Stability relocation. Financial Times, 3 September.
Review, 14, Banque de France. Financial Times (2012a). DoJ probes $2bn JPMorgan
Duffie, D. and Singleton, K. (2003). Credit Risk. Prince- trading loss. Financial Times, 15 May.
ton University Press. Financial Times (2012b). JPMorgan whale harpooned.
Duffie, D. and Zhu, H. (2011). Does a central clearing Financial Times, 11 May.
counterparty reduce counterparty risk? Stanford Uni- Flood, R. P. and Garber, P. M. (1984). Collapsing ex-
versity Working Paper. change rate regimes: some linear examples. J. Int.
Eichengreen, B. (1996). Golden Fetters: the Gold Stand- Econ., 17: 223–34.
ard and the Great Depression, 1919–1939. Oxford Uni- Frankel, J. A. (1999). No single currency regime is right
versity Press. for all countries at all times. Working paper 7338, Na-
Eichengreen, B. and Irwin, D. (2009). The slide to pro- tional Bureau of Economic Research.
tectionism in the Great Depression: who succumbed Friedman, M. (1969). The optimum quantity of money.
and why? NBER Working Paper 15142. In Friedman, M., editor, The Optimum Quantity of
Elliot, G. (2006). Overend & Gurney, a Financial Scandal Money and Other Essays, chapter 1, pp. 1–50. Adline
in Victorian London. Methuen. Publishing Company, Chicago.
395
Bibliography
Friedman, M. and Schwartz, A. (1963). A Monetary His- Hull, J. C. (2011). Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives,
tory of the United States: 1867–1960. Princeton Univer- 8th edition. Prentice Hall.
sity Press. Hull, J. C. (2012). Risk Management and Financial Insti-
Goldstein, M. (1998). The Asian Financial Crisis: Causes, tutions, 3rd edition. Prentice Hall.
Cures, and Systemic Implications. Institute for Interna- Hume, D. (1752). On the balance of trade. In Essays,
tional Economics, Washington, DC. Moral, Political and Literary. Edinburgh and London.
Goodhart, C. (1999). Myths about the lender of last re- Institute of International Finance (2010). Interim report
sort. Technical report FMG SP 120, London School of on the cumulative impact of proposed changes in the
Economics. http://fmg.lse.ac.uk/pdfs/sp120.pdf. banking regulatory framework. Technical report.
Goodhart, C. (2002). The organizational structure of Institute of International Finance (2012). Making reso-
banking supervision. Economic Notes, 31(1): 1–32. lution robust. Technical report.
Goodhart, C. (2009). The Regulatory Response to the Fi- International Monetary Fund (1997). Camdessus an-
nancial Crisis. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK. nounces IMF support for Indonesia’s economic pro-
Goodhart, C. (2011). The Basel Committee on Banking gram. News brief no. 97/19, 8 October 1997, www.
Supervision: a History of the Early Years 1974–1997. imf.org/external/np/sec/nb/1997/nb9719.htm.
Cambridge University Press. International Monetary Fund (1998). World economic
Goodhart, C. and Schoenmaker, D. (1995). Should the outlook and international capital markets: interim as-
functions of monetary policy and banking supervi- sessment. Financial turbulence and the world econo-
sion be separated? Oxford Economic Papers, 47(4): my. Technical report. www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/
539–60. weo/weo1298/index.htm.
Gorter, J. and Bijlsma, M. (2012). Strategic moves. International Monetary Fund (2008). Global financial
www.risk.net/life-and-pension- risk. stability report: containing systemic risks and restor-
Gosh, A. R., Gulde, A.-M. and Wolf, H. C. (2002). Exchange ing financial soundness. April 2008, pp. 1–211.
Rate Regime: Choices and Consequences. MIT Press. International Monetary Fund, Bank for International Set-
Graeber, D. (2011). Debt: The First 5,000 Years. Melville tlements, Financial Stability Board (2009). Report to
House Publishing, New York. G20 finance ministers and governors. Guidance to as-
Graham, B. and Dodd, D. (1934). Security Analysis. sess the systemic importance of financial institutions,
Whittlesey House (McGraw-Hill). markets and instruments: Initial considerations. Tech-
Greenspan, A. (1997). Discussion at symposium: Main- nical report.
taining Financial Stability in a Global Economy, p. 54. Ito, T. (2007). Asian currency crisis and the Internation-
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City. al Monetary Fund, 10 years later: Overview. Asian
Gulati, M. and Triantis, G. (2007). Contracts without Econ. Policy Rev., 2: 16–49.
law: Sovereign versus corporate debt. University of Kaminsky, G. L. and Reinhart, C. M. (1999). The twin
Cincinnati Law Review, 75: 977–1004. crises: the causes of banking and balance-of-payments
Hale, D. (2003). The Newfoundland lesson. The Interna- problems. Amer. Econ. Rev., 89: 473–500.
tional Economy, 17(3): 52–61. Kane, E. J. (1989). The S&L insurance mess: how did it
Hanke, S. H. and Kwok, A. K. F. (2009). On the meas- happen? Technical report, Urban Institute Press.
urement of Zimbabwe’s hyperinflation. Cato J., 29(2): Kaseki, J.-R. (2007). Preying on the poor. The Guardian,
353–64. 27 September.
Hansard (1933). http://hansard.millbanksystems.com/ Kashyap, A. K., Rajan, R. G. and Stein, J. C. (2008). Re-
commons/1933/dec/12/newfoundland-bill#S5CV thinking capital regulation. http://online.wsj.com/
0284PO_19331212_HOC_267. public/resources/documents/Fed-JacksonHole.pdf.
Herring, R. J. and Litan, R. E. (1995). Financial Regula- Kaufman, G. G. (1996). Bank failures, systemic risk, and
tion in the Global Economy. The Brookings Institution, bank regulation. Cato J., 16(1): 17–46.
Washington, DC. Keynes, J. M. (1920). The Economic Consequences of the
Homer, S. and Sylla, R. (1996). A History of Interest Rates. Peace. Harcourt Brace, New York.
Rutgers University Press. Keynes, J. M. (1924). A Tract on Monetary Reform.
Honohan, P. and Klingebiel, D. (2003). The fiscal cost Macmillan.
implications of an accommodating approach to Keynes, J. M. (1936). The General Theory of Interest,
banking crises. J. Banking Finance, 27(8): 1539–60. Employment and Money. Macmillan.
Huertas, T. F. (2010). Crisis: Cause, Containment and Kindleberger, C. (1986). The World in Depression, 1929–
Cure. Palgrave Macmillan. 1939, 2nd edition. University of California Press.
396
Bibliography
Kindleberger, C. P. (1996). Manias, Panics, and Crashes: Macrae, R. and Watkins, C. (1998). A disaster waiting to
a History of Financial Crises, 3rd edition. John Wiley & happen. Mimeo, www.cs.rhul.ac.uk/home/chrisw/
Sons. Disaster.pdf.
Kohn, M. (1999). Early deposit banking. Mimeo, Dart- Madura, J. (2010). Financial Institutions and Markets,
mouth College, Hanover, NH. 9th edition. South Western College, Cincinnati, OH.
Kohn, M. (2003). Financial Institutions and Markets, 2nd Marsh, D. (2010). The Euro: the Politics of the New Global
edition. Oxford University Press. Currency. Yale University Press.
Kovacevich, R. M. (1996). Deposit insurance: It’s time McCallum, B. T. (1996). International Monetary Eco-
to cage the monster. www.minneapolisfed.org/ nomics. Oxford University Press.
publications papers/pub display.cfm?id=2682. Merton, R. (1995). A functional perspective of financial
Krueger, A. O. (2002). A new approach to sovereign intermediation. Financial Management, 24: 23–41.
debt restructuring. Technical report, IMF. Merton, R. C. (1974). On the pricing of corporate
Krugman, P. (1979). A model of balance-of-payments debt: the risk structure of interest rates. J. Finance, 29:
crises. J. Money Credit Banking, 11(3): 311–25. 449–70.
Krugman, P. (1998). What happened to Asia? Mimeo, Miller, G. P. (1996). Is deposit insurance inevitable? Les-
MIT. sons from Argentina. Int. Rev. Law Econ., 16: 211–32.
Krugman, P. R. and Obstfeld, M. (2006). International Minsky, H. (1992). The financial instability hypothesis.
Economics: Theory and Policy, 7th edition. Pearson. Working paper, Mimeo, Yale University.
Kupiec, P. H. and Ramirez, C. D. (2009). Bank failures Mishkin, F. S. and Eakins, S. (2011). Financial Markets
and the cost of systemic risk: Evidence from 1900– and Institutions, 6th edition. Pearson.
1930. Technical report, FDIC. Moe, T. G., Solheim, J. A., and Vale, B. (2004). The Nor-
Kyle, A. (1985). Continuous auctions and insider trad- wegian banking crisis. Technical report, Norges Bank.
ing. Econometrica, 53(6): 1315–36. Occasional Paper no. 33.
Laeven, L. and Valencia, F. (2008). Systemic banking Morris, S. and Shin, H. S. (1998). Unique equilibrium in
crises: a new database. Technical report, IMF. IMF a model of self-fulfilling currency attacks. Amer. Econ.
Working Paper. Rev., 88: 587–97.
Larosiere, J. (2009). The high-level group report on Morris, S. and Shin, H. S. (1999). Risk management with
financial supervision in the EU. Technical report. interdependent choice. Oxford Review of Economic
http://ec.europa.eu/commission barroso/president/ Policy, 15: 52–62, reprinted in Bank of England Finan-
pdf/statement 20090225 en.pdf. cial Stability Review, 7, 141–150. www.bankofengland.
Lavigne, R. (2008). Sterilized intervention in emerging- co.uk/fsr/fsr07art5.pdf.
market economies: trends, costs and risks. Discussion Moysich, A. (2000). The savings and loan crisis and its
paper 2008-4, Bank of Canada. relationship to banking. In Federal Deposit Insurance
Leeson, N. (1999). Rogue Trader. Sphere, London. Corporation, History of the 80s – Lessons for the Future.
Lehman Brothers (2008). Capital advisory group: cur- Volume I: an Examination of the Banking Crises of the 1980s
rent topics. Technical report, Lehman Brothers. and Early 1990s, Chapter 4. FDIC, Washington, DC.
Lewis, M. (2009). The man who crashed the world. Mundell, R. A. (1961). A theory of optimum currency
Vanity Fair, August. areas. Amer. Econ. Rev., 51: 657–65.
Lewis, M. (2011). The Big Short: Inside the Doomsday Murphy, D. (2009). Unravelling the Credit Crunch. CRC
Machine. Penguin. Press.
Lewis, M. K. and Mizen, P. D. (2000). Monetary Econom- Mussa, M. (2002). Argentina and the Fund: From Tri-
ics. Oxford University Press. umph to Tragedy. Institute for International Econom-
Li, D. X. (2000). On default correlation: a copula func- ics, Washington, DC.
tion approach. J. Fixed Income, 9: 43–54. Obstfeld, M. (1996). Models of currency crises with self-
Liikanen, E. (2012). High-level expert group on reform- fulfilling features. Eur. Econ. Rev., 40(3–5): 1037–47.
ing the structure of the EU banking sector. Technical Obstfeld, M. and Rogoff, K. (1996). Foundations of In-
report, European Union. ternational Macroeconomics. MIT Press.
Lowenstein, R. (2000). When Genius Failed – the Rise OECD (2002). Forty years’ experience with the OECD
and Fall of Long-Term Capital Management. Random code of liberalisation of capital movements. Techni-
House, New York. cal report.
397
Bibliography
Quagliariello, M. and Cannata, F. (2011). Basel III and Sullivan, R., Timmermann, A. and White, H. (1999).
Beyond. Riskbooks, London. Dangers of data mining: the case of calendar effects
Radelet, S. and Sachs, J. (2000). The onset of the East in stock returns. J. Econometrics, 105(1): 249–86.
Asian financial crisis. In Krugman, P., editor, Currency Taylor, J. B. (1993). Discretion versus policy rules in
Crises. University of Chicago Press. www.nber.org/ practice. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Pub-
chapters/c8691. lic Policy, 39: 195–214.
Reinhart, C. M. and Rogoff, K. (2009). This Time Is Dif- The Economist (1999). South Africa’s debt: unforgivable.
ferent: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly. Princeton Uni- The Economist (US), 24 April.
versity Press. The Economist (2009). No empty threat. Credit-default
Reinhart, C. M., Rogoff, K. and Savastano, M. A. (2003). swaps are pitting firms against their own creditors.
Debt intolerance. Technical report, NBER. The Economist (US), 18 June.
Repullo, R. and Saurina, J. (2011). The countercyclical Tobin, J. (1996). A currency transactions tax, why and
capital buffer of Basel III: a critical assessment. CEMFI how? Open Economies Review, 7: 493–9.
Working Paper 1102, June. Truell, P. and Gurwin, L. (1992). False Profits: the Inside
Santos, J. A. C. (2000). Bank capital regulation in con- Story of BCCI, the World’s Most Corrupt Financial Em-
temporary banking theory: A review of the literature. pire. Houghton Mifflin, Boston, MA.
Technical Report 90, Bank for International Settle- UBS (2008). Shareholder report on UBS’s write-downs.
ments. www.bis.org/publ/work90.pdf?noframes¯1. Technical report.
Sarno, L. and Taylor, M. P. (2003). The Economics of Ex- Volcker, P. (2011). Financial reform: Unfinished busi-
change Rates. Cambridge University Press. ness. www.nybooks.com/articles/archives/2011/nov/
Schumpeter, J. (1942). Capitalism, Socialism and Democ- 24/financial-reformunfinished-business.
racy. Harper, New York. Wall Street Journal (2007). One ‘quant’ sees shakeout for
SEC and CFTC (2010). Findings regarding the market the ages – ‘10,000 years’. Wall Street Journal, 11 August.
events of May 6, 2010. Technical report. Wall Street Journal (2009a). Action on AIG unit may cost
Selgin, G. (2003). Adaptive learning and the transition taxpayers. Wall Street Journal, 13 April. online.wsj.
to fiat money. Econ. J., 113(484): 147–65. com/article/SB123957925343711995.html.
Shin, H. S. (2008). Reflections on modern bank runs: A case Wall Street Journal (2009b). Paul Volcker: think more
study of Northern Rock. Mimeo, Princeton University. boldly. Wall Street Journal, 14 December. online.wsj.
Shin, H. S. (2010). Risk and Liquidity. Clarendon Lectures com/ article/SB100014240527487048255045745863
in Finance. Oxford University Press. 30960597134.html.
Sicsic, P. (1992). Was the Franc Poincaré deliberately un- Washington Post (2004). Credit raters’ power leads to
dervalued? Explorations in Economic History, 29: 69–92. abuses, some borrowers say. Washington Post, 24
Sorkin, A. R. (2010). Too Big to Fail: Inside the Battle to November. www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/arti-
Save Wall Street. Penguin. cles/A8032-2004Nov23.html.
Spanish government (2008). Las balanzas fiscales de Weisbrot, M. (2007). Ten years after: the lasting impact
las CC.AA. españolas con las AA. Públicas Centrales of the Asian financial crisis. Technical report. http://
2005. Technical report, Ministerio de Economía y www.cepr.net/documents/publications/asia_crisis_
Hacienda. 2007_08.pdf.
Stiglitz, J. (2009). Obama’s ersatz capitalism. www. Zigrand, J.-P. (2010). What do network theory and en-
nytimes.com/2009/04/01/opinion/01stiglitz.html? dogenous risk theory have to say about the effects of
r=1&scp=2&sq=stiglitz&st=cse. CCPs on systemic stability? Financial Stability Review,
Stoler, P. and Kalb, J. B. (1982). The great Vatican 14, Banque de France.
bank mystery. http://time.com/time/magazine/arti-
cle/0,9171,951806,00.html.
Sturzenegger, F. and Zettelmeyer, J. (2007). Debt
Defaults and Lessons from a Decade of Crises. MIT
Press.
398
Index
399
INDEX
400
INDEX
401
INDEX
402
INDEX
403
INDEX
404
INDEX
405
INDEX
406
INDEX
407
INDEX
408
INDEX
409
INDEX
410
INDEX
fractional reserve banking 67, 78, 120, 121 G-SIB (global systemically important banks) 349,
bank runs 137, 139 350–1, 362, 364
collateralised debt obligations and 298–7 G10 economies
deposit insurance modelling 144–6 banking crises in 127
systemic risk and 11–13 G20 341, 342, 345–6
fragilities gains from trade, deposit insurance model 144
bank capital 317, 318–19 Gale, D. 71–2
banking systems 12 gaming 354–5
banks 120 garbage assets 287, 298
France Garber, P.M. 219
bank capital 356 GATT (General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade) 35
euro zone and 382–5 Gaussian copula 295, 297
sovereign debt defaults 369 GDP see gross domestic product
United Kingdom and, currency wars 209–10 General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) 35
Frankel, J.A. 213 Germany
Franz Ferdinand, Archduke 3 bank capital 356
fraud bank runs 137
BCCI 129–30 euro zone and 382–5, 386
Iceland banking system crisis 133 European Exchange Rate Mechanism 228–9
free floats 214 Great Depression 27
free riding 35 hyperinflation 92–3
free trade 35 interest rates 229
Friedman, Milton 32, 85–6 mark as reserve currency 228
Friedman’s helicopter 85–6 monetary policies 228–9
FSA see Financial Services Authority reunification 229
FSB (Financial Stability Board) 345–6, 359, 360 sovereign bonds 184–5
FSF (Financial Stability Forum) 341, 345 sovereign debt enforcement 375
FSOC (Financial Stability Oversight Council), USA 346 Giffen goods 43
FT100 index 154 Glass–Steagall Act, USA 29, 168, 241
FTT (financial transactions tax) 169–70 Glass–Steagall Deposit Insurance Act 140
full reserve banking 123 global games currency crisis model 231–4
the Fund see International Monetary Fund global imbalances 21, 329
fundamental equilibrium 206 global impact of European sovereign debt crisis 388–9
fundamental uncertainties 233–4 global savings gluts 329
fundamentals 217 global systemically important banks (G-SIB) 349,
2G currency crisis models 227 350–1, 362, 364
financial, Indonesia 104 globalism 326–7
macroeconomic, Indonesia 104 first 1, 99, 327
underlying, prices reflecting 43 history forgotten 327
weak, Asian crisis 1997: 106, 107 second 327
funding banks 331–2 systemic risk 327
funding liquidity 353 Washington consensus and anti-globalism 328
Asian crisis 1999: 108 GMAC 274
crises and 67 gold 47, 121
market liquidity and, interdependencies between gold standard 22, 27, 121
70–1 adjustment mechanism 205
meaning 65–7 deflation and 204–5
risk 65, 300 exchange rate regime 204–5
scarceness 72 Great Depression and 27–8, 33, 37
futures 152 impossible trinity 207
FX see foreign exchange lending of last resort 267
411
INDEX
412
INDEX
413
INDEX
414
INDEX
415
INDEX
416
INDEX
funding liquidity and, interdependencies between minimum capital adequacy ratios, Basel III 349
70–1 minimum capital requirements (Pillar I), Basel II 254
increasing importance 67 Minsky, Hyman 9, 40, 330
meaning 65–6 modern portfolio theory (MPT) 47
price impacts 68 Modigliani–Miller analysis 358
risk 65 Moe, T.G. 132, 263
terminology 69–70 momentum strategies 53
market makers 68, 172 momentum trading 159
market orders 68 monetary aggregates 11
market oriented structural reforms, Argentina 222 monetary base see M0
market participants, trading risk 154–5 monetary institutions, credibility 224
market risk monetary policies
Basel II 254 Argentina 223–4
regulation 74 build up to crisis 328–9
markets central banks see central banks
derivatives 67 conflicts between financial stability and 90–1
discount 3 contractionary 82
efficient 329–30 European Central Bank 81
limit order 68 European Union see European Union
markets’ fear gauge see VIX expansionary 82
marking-to-magic 187 Germany 228–9
marking-to-market 10, 187, 287 Great Depression 30–4
marking-to-model 187 impossible trinity 207
Marsh, D. 381 neutral 82
Marton, William McChesney Jr 77 primacy 328
maturities UK, Great Depression 22
credit ratings and 180–1 United States 22–3
loans 12 monetary stability, central banks 79, 80
mismatches 99, 107, 110, 332 monetary unions 213, 381
maximum harmonisation principle, EU 357–8 money
maximum leverage, banks 87 Asian crisis 1997: 100–1
McCarthy, Sir Callum 140–1 debasement 121
mean reversion 57 definition 121
mean reverting assets 59 fiat 121
mean–variance diagrams 47 high-powered see M0
Medici bank 121–3 hot, capital controls and 202, 203
Mellon, Andrew 26 legal tender 121
merger arbitrage 57 losing control, central banking challenges 91–3
mergers, banks 363 multiplier 12
Merrill Lynch 275 narrow see M1
Merton, R. 10, 56, 183 parallels between Great Depression and 2007–2009
Mexico crises 36
banking crises 126 printing 4, 87–8
sovereign debt 373, 377 price to pay 92
mezzanine notes, structured investment vehicles 300 as tax on assets 88
mezzanine tranches, CDOs 293–4 quantity theory of 204
microeconomic theory 43 supply
micro-prudential regulations 240–1, 345 contraction 30–2
military sovereign debt enforcement 375 multiplier 67
Millennium Bridge 41–3 reductions 67
Miller, G.P. 148 types 11–12
417
INDEX
money market mutual funds 148 New York Federal Reserve Bank (NYFed) 22, 58, 63,
Moody’s 179–81, 299 79, 333, 358
moral hazard 10 Newfoundland 368–9
Asian crisis 1997: 106, 112 Nigeria
asset bubbles, government guarantees causing sovereign debt enforcement 375
279–83 non-linear dependence 48, 287, 297, 313–15, 331, 333
bailouts see bailouts normal distribution 313, 314
banking crises 119, 123–4 normality 313–15
credit default swaps 292 Northern Rock 28, 137, 140–2, 188, 190, 275, 332
definition 123 Norway
deposit insurance 147 banking crisis 127, 131–2
government guarantees causing asset bubbles notional principals, CDSs 302
279–83 NSFR (net stable funding ratio) 74, 355
insurance and 124 NYFed see New York Federal Reserve Bank
liquidity injections increasing 329
liquidity policy implications 74 Obama, Barack 269
risk taking and 124 Obstfeld, M. 219
securitisation 190 off-balance sheet risk 332
Morgan, John Pierpont 250 offers 68
Morgan Stanley 274 oligopolies, credit rating agencies 182–3
Morris, S. 158, 231 on the margin 19
mortgage originators 189 ‘one minute to midnight’ 272
mortgage-related products 55 ongoing crisis, 2007-2009 phase 325–6
motivation, lending of last resort 270 build-up to crisis 326–30
Moysich, A. 131 changing nature of banking 331–3
MPT (modern portfolio theory) 47 crisis, 2007-2008: 333–7
multiple equilibria 225–8 hidden and ignored risk 330–1
deposit insurance model 145 policy response 338
Mundell, R.A. 380 subprime mortgage role 337–8
Mussa, Michael 224 ongoing developments in financial regulation 341–65
open market operations 32
naked credit default swaps 292–3 central banks’ monetary policy 82, 83, 85
naked short selling 163 liquidity provision in bailouts 269
narrow banking 168–9 operational risk, Basel II 254
narrow money see M1 opportunity costs 72
national banking champions 362 optimal risk sharing, deposit insurance model 145
national discretion, liquidity coverage ratio 354 optimal social insurance, deposit insurance model
national institutions, regulatory reform 344–5 143–4
national interests, focus on, Great Depression 34–5 optimisation
national positions, capital 356–7 bank capital structure 317–18, 319
negative externalities 120 collateralised debt obligations 297–8
negative feedback 83 deposit insurance model 144
net stable funding ratio (NSFR) 74, 355 option pricing theory 183
Netherlands optionality 288
bank capital 356 options 67
euro zone and 382–5 put 49–52
netting 172, 289 short 57
netting out 291 orders 171
network effects 3 originate and distribute model of banking 188
network vulnerabilities, credit default swaps 290–2 Oskarsson, H. 377
neutral monetary policy 82 OTC see over-the-counter
418
INDEX
419
INDEX
420
INDEX
421
INDEX
422
INDEX
423
INDEX
424
INDEX
425
INDEX
426