06.beifuss Final Edit Formatted
06.beifuss Final Edit Formatted
06.beifuss Final Edit Formatted
Francis Beifuss*
INTRODUCTION
* Francis Beifuss, 2024 J.D. Candidate at University of Louisville Brandeis School of Law. I thank Professor
Tim Hall for pointing me toward this issue, Professor Kathryn Moore for invaluable feedback, and special thanks
to Professor C.J. Ryan whose guidance and mentoring profoundly impacted my academic writing. Thank you to
Katy Harvy for the feedback and encouragement during the submission processes. Thank you to the FYM of vol.
62 who worked on this project. Special thanks to Kenneth Schwalbert, Alexandra Just, and Rachel Gumbel for
their exceptional editing, I owe you all. Thanks to my Uncle Lou Sanner for listening to me rant about this topic at
length, many nights. Finally, a very special thanks to my loving wife Kathlene for your continual support and
encouragement.
1
Mike Bryant, The Real Story of Healthcare Denial, ST. CLOUD INJURY LAW NEWS, LEGAL EXAMINER (Oct.
11, 2009), https://stcloud.legalexaminer.com/health/medical-malpractice/real-story-of-health-care-denial/
[https://perma.cc/MYQ5-6AUT]; see also Sam Stein, Dawn Smith, Brain Tumor Victim: How Her Story Became
Rallying Cry For Health Care Reform Supporters, HUFFPOST (May 25, 2011),
https://www.huffpost.com/entry/dawn-smith-brain-tumor-vi_n_309797 [https://perma.cc/JM27-3DTA].
2
Mike Bryant, supra note 1.
3
Id.
4
Id.
5
Id.
6
Id.
7
Id.
8
Peter K. Stris, ERISA Remedies, Welfare Benefits, And Bad Faith: Losing Sight of The Cathedral, 26 HOFSTRA
LAB. & EMP. L.J. 387, 396–98 (2009).
761
762 UNIVERSITY OF LOUISVILLE LAW REVIEW [Vol. 62:3
are few repercussions her insurer would face.9 If Dawn sought a remedy for
her wrongful denials, she would have to go through the insurer’s internal
appeal process, like she did, before she could bring a claim against her them.10
Then she would have to go through an external review process.11 Since that
did not work, if she took Cigna to court, assuming she received her Cigna
care through her or a family member’s employer, she would be able to
recover, with near certainty, zero dollars outside the cost of the originally
denied care.12
The confounding lack of remedy is due to a three-part wall.13 Each
layer interlocks, reinforcing the others:14 (1) damages immunities—insurers
of employer-sponsored plans are generally only subject to equitable remedies
and are not exposed to consequential or punitive damages;15 (2) consulting
physician malpractice immunity—the doctors that insurers hire to determine
if a claim is medically necessary are treated solely as fiduciaries to the plan,
avoiding a meaningful duty of care as a medical doctor to the patient-
claimant;16 (3) and, finally, a complex system of express, reverse, and implied
preemption, where states are charged with creating insurance regulations and
monitoring mechanisms but have no enforcement powers—resulting in a
bizarre, rigid regulatory terrain.17
Dawn’s story begs the questions: How often are claims denied? What
happens when they are? How have things changed since her case? Lastly,
what can be done to keep her story from repeating today?
Over 178,000,000 Americans received healthcare plans through
employers in 2021.18 This means over one-half of Americans receive
9
See id.; see Aetna Health Inc. v. Davila, 542 U.S. 200, 209 (2004).
10
See Bilyeu v. Morgan Stanley Long Term Disability Plan, 683 F.3d 1083, 1088 (9th Cir. 2012) (“As
a general rule, an ERISA claimant must exhaust available administrative remedies before bringing a claim
in federal court.”)(citation omitted); 29 U.S.C. § 1133 (2022); see also 1 WILLIAM T. BARKER & RONALD
D. KENT, NEW APPLEMAN INSURANCE BAD FAITH LITIGATION § 8.04(e)(i) (Matthew Bender, ed., 2d ed.
2022).
11
See Bilyeu, 683 F.3d at 1088; see BARKER & KENT, supra note 10.
12
See Peter K. Stris, supra note 8, at 396–98.
13
See Aetna Health Inc., 542 U.S. at 208–09; see Skelcy v. United Health Grp., Inc., 620 F. App'x 136, 143–44
(3d Cir. 2015); see CIGNA Corp. v. Amara, 563 U.S. 421 (2011).
14
See Aetna Health Inc. 542 U.S.; see Skelcy v. United Health Grp., Inc., 620 F. App'x 136 (3d Cir. 2015); see
CIGNA Corp. v. Amara, 563 U.S. 421 (2011).
15
See Pilot Life Ins. Co. v. Dedeaux, 481 U.S. 41, 53–54 (1987)
16
See Pegram v. Herdrich, 530 U.S. 211, 222–25 (2000); Skelcy, 620 F. App’x at 140, 143–44.
17
See Peter K. Stris, supra note 8; see generally Terry L. Corbett, Operationalizing the Healthcare Benefit
Corporation, 24 J. HEALTHCARE L. & POL’Y 267 (2021) (describing the issues treating doctors as fiduciaries raises
regarding insureds’ access to care).
18
See KATHERINE KEISLER-STARKEY & LISA N. BUNCH, U.S. CENSUS BUREAU, HEALTH INS. COVERAGE IN
THE UNITED STATES: 2021 3–4 (2022). The term employer does not include all governmental employers, but
excludes TRICARE recipients and generally other government employees who receive their health insurance from
a direct government fund. Id. Additionally, the term may still cover government contractors who are subcontracted
or where a government entity outsources their funding for care to an insurance company. Id.
2024] Illusory Remedies 763
19
Id. (2021 Census Bureau report on health insurance coverage, estimating 54.3% of the country receives health
insurance from an employer).
20
See Sharon J. Arkin, Tort Actions Against Health Maintenance Organizations and Their Doctors, 23
WHITTIER L. REV. 609, 609–12 (2002); Matthew G. Vansuch, Not Just Old Wine in New Bottles: Kentucky Ass'n
of Health Plans, Inc. v. Miller Bottles a New Test for State Regulation of Insurance, 38 AKRON L. REV. 253, 267–
68 (2005).
21
Sharon J. Arkin, supra note 20; Matthew G. Vansuch, supra note 20.
22
Lee Black, ERISA: A Close Look at Misguided Legislation, 10 J. OF ETHICS AMA 307, 307 (2008); see
Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) of 1974, 29 U.S.C. § 1001 (1974).
23
See Peter K. Stris, supra note 8, at 387.
24
See Sharon J. Arkin, supra note 20 (the primary statutory complaints raised by this article pertaining to
accessible tort actions remain essentially untouched); see also 29 U.S.C. §§ 1001–1461 (1974); see Gobeille v.
Liberty Mut. Ins. Co., 577 U.S. 312 (2016) (one of the most recent landmark ERISA cases pertaining to health
insurance reporting and describing the judicial lack of interest or ability to change ERISA policy).
25
See infra discussion section (II)(A).
26
See Aetna Health Inc. v. Davila, 542 U.S. 200, 208–09 (2004); see Skelcy v. United Health Grp., Inc., 620 F.
App'x 136, 143–44 (3d Cir. 2015); see CIGNA Corp. v. Amara, 563 U.S. 421, 439–40 (2011).
27
See generally EMP. BENEFITS SEC. ADMIN.(EBSA), REPORTING AND DISCLOSURE GUIDE FOR EMPLOYEE
BENEFIT PLANS (2017), https://www.dol.gov/sites/dolgov/files/ebsa/about-ebsa/our-activities/resource-
center/publications/reporting-and-disclosure-guide-for-employee-benefit-plans.pdf [https://perma.cc/DRT2-
U35Z] [hereinafter EBSA REPORTING GUIDE]; see infra discussion section (II)(C).
28
EBSA REPORTING GUIDE supra note 27; see U.S. GOV’T ACCOUNTABILITY OFF., GAO-11-268, PRIVATE
HEALTH INSURANCE DATA ON APPLICATION AND COVERAGE DENIALS 10 (2011) (“In overseeing insurer activity,
states vary in the data they require insurers to submit on denials and internal appeals of denials.”).
764 UNIVERSITY OF LOUISVILLE LAW REVIEW [Vol. 62:3
29
See generally VICTOR E. SCHWARTZ ET AL., POSER, WADE, AND SCHWARTZ’S TORTS (14th ed. 2020); See
U.S. GOV’T ACCOUNTABILITY OFF., supra note 28.
30
VICTOR E. SCHWARTZ ET AL, supra note 29.
31
See U.S. GOV’T ACCOUNTABILITY OFF., supra note 28.
32
EBSA REPORTING GUIDE, supra note 27; see Lee Black, supra note 22.
33
Lee Black, supra note 22; Sharon J. Arkin supra note 20; see Employee Retirement Income Security
Act (ERISA) of 1974, 29 U.S.C. §§ 1131-1136 (1974) (detailing civil and criminal penalties available,
who can enforce them, and when they can be enforced).
34
See KATHERINE KEISLER-STARKEY & LISA N. BUNCH, supra note 18; Peter K. Stris, supra note 8.
35
See generally 29 U.S.C. §§ 1001–1461 (2022). See also Health Insurance Portability and Accountability Act
of 1996, Pub. L. No. 104–191, § 1, 110 Stat. 1936 (codified at 42 U.S.C. § 210 (2003)); see also The Patient
Protection and Affordable Care Act, Pub. L. No. 111-148, § 2718 (2010).
36
See Aetna Health Inc. v. Davila, 542 U.S. 200, 208–09 (2004); see Skelcy v. United Health Grp., Inc., 620 F.
App'x 136, 143–44 (3d Cir. 2015); see CIGNA Corp. v. Amara, 563 U.S. 421, 439–40 (2011).
37
Contra Gobeille v. Liberty Mut. Ins. Co., 577 U.S. 312, 323 (2016) (“These various requirements are not
mere formalities.”).
38
Peter K. Stris, supra note 8, at 396–98.
2024] Illusory Remedies 765
their plans describe and engaging in shareholder primacy.39 When fines are
significantly less costly than the bad behavior is profitable, which obligation
controls behavior?
After decades of litigation and legislation, the insurers’ position has
mostly improved, while patients find dwindling avenues for meaningful
redress.40 The United States Supreme Court has heard cases challenging
every one of ERISA’s prongs described here, and without fail, have upheld
the insurers’ interests typically in near unanimous decisions.41 Individual
states have little they can affect. The only avenue for long-term, system-wide
correction for this issue, is through federal legislation. That legislation must
remove immunity from penalties and get doctors back into the business of
considering patients first.
In addition to legislation, a more readily achieved resolution, would
require no additional legislation. ERISA gives the federal government the
ability to request information from insurers.42 The Department of Labor—the
federal agency delegated with enforcing employee benefits—could enact a
claim denial reporting system, as is done for Medicare,43 for ERISA plans
immediately.44 That information would make obfuscating insurance
malpractice much more difficult and would illuminate the severity of the
issue. Currently, without meaningful remedies, ERISA’s hulking patchwork
of regulation will remain mere suggestions, and insureds will continue to rely
on a massive illusion.45
This Note will argue that, outside of sweeping reform or an exodus
from ERISA markets, the best solutions to these issues would be through
modifications to the Department of Labor’s denial reporting requirements, as
well as surgical repeals and modifications to existing sections of the Act,
removing the cancerous lines that have metastasized throughout the
American healthcare system.46
Part I of this Note will describe the history and rationale behind
ERISA health insurance and where it is today in a post-Affordable Care Act
39
Id.
40
See Id. at 396–98; see BARKER & KENT, supra note 10, § 8.04(b)(ii).
41
See Pegram, 530 U.S. 211 (2000); Gobeille, 577 U.S. at 312; Aetna Health Inc., 542 U.S. at 200;
CIGNA Corp., 563 U.S. at 421; Humana Inc., 525 U.S. at 299; PacifiCare Health Sys., 538 U.S. at 401;
Metro. Life Ins. Co., 554 U.S. at 105.
42
See Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) of 1974, 29 U.S.C. § 1027 (2024).
43
Karen Pollitz et al., Claims Denials and Appeals in ACA Marketplace Plans in 2020, KAISER. FAM. FOUND.
(Jul. 5, 2022), https://www.kff.org/private-insurance/issue-brief/claims-denials-and-appeals-in-aca-marketplace-
plans [https://perma.cc/7JJC-89DE].
44
Id.
45
U.S. DEP’T OF LAB. & U.S. DEP’T OF HEALTH AND HUM. SERV., REPORT TO CONGRESS ON A STUDY OF
THE LARGE GROUP MARKET 5 (2011).
46
Id.
766 UNIVERSITY OF LOUISVILLE LAW REVIEW [Vol. 62:3
I. BACKGROUND
A. Overview of ERISA
ERISA is highly technical and vast.48 It covers all forms of employee
benefits and has been added to for decades.49 Major bills like the Affordable
Care Act (ACA), and the Health Insurance Portability and Accountability Act
of 1996 (HIPAA) extensively modified and added to ERISA.50 The issues
raised in this Note mostly live in the high limbs of ERISA’s giant tree of
legislation. To understand the relevant issues, therefore, a cursory
understanding of the roots and trunk of ERISA—in other words, its
conceptual foundation—is necessary.
Congress established ERISA in 1974 to cure legal constraints arising
from the growing number of companies that had offices and employees
spanning numerous states. 51 Thanks to advances in communications and
travel, like the interstate highway system, rail, and telecommunications, the
world had become much smaller.52 However, expanding businesses also
increased employers’ legal landscape creating difficulties; each state had its
own standards for many forms of employee benefit plans—including pension
funds, stock options, termination benefits, health insurance, disability, and
47
See generally Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) of 1974, 29 U.S.C. § 1001; see generally
Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act, Pub. L. No. 111-148, 124 Stat. 119 (2010).
48
See Lee Black, supra note 22 (“ERISA is a complex law that uses somewhat ambiguous language to set up
what is, essentially, a skeletal regulatory system for employer-sponsored health plans.”).
49
See History of EBSA and ERISA, EMP. BENEFITS SEC. ADMIN., https://www.dol.gov/agencies/ebsa/about-
ebsa/about-us/history-of-ebsa-and-erisa [https://perma.cc/DG4G-LHHJ] (last visited Feb. 8, 2024).
50
See also Health Insurance Portability and Accountability Act of 1996, Pub. L. No. 104–191, § 1, 110 Stat.
1936 (codified at 42 U.S.C. § 210 (2003)); see The Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act, Pub. L. No. 111-
148, § 2718 (2010).
51
29 U.S.C. § 1001(a) (1974). (“The Congress finds that the growth in size, scope, and numbers of employee
benefit plans in recent years has been rapid and substantial; that the operational scope and economic impact of
such plans is increasingly interstate . . . .”)
52
Id. at § 1001; See M. Ayhan Kose & Ezgi O. Ozturk, A World of Change, 51 INT’L MONETARY FUND FIN.
& DEV. 6, 7 (2014).
2024] Illusory Remedies 767
53
See Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) of 1974, 29 U.S.C. § 1001(a); see Lee Black, supra
note 22.
54
29 U.S.C. § 1001(a).
55
Matthew G. Vansuch, supra note 20.
56
See Regina T. Jefferson, Rethinking the Risk of Defined Contribution Plans, 4 FLA. TAX REV. 607, 612 (2000)
(“When ERISA was enacted, defined benefit [one type of pension plan] was the predominant [retirement] plan
type.”).
57
Id.
58
Eric Whiteside, How Do Pension Funds Work?, INVESTOPEDIA (Apr. 29, 2022)
https://www.investopedia.com/articles/investing-strategy/090916/how-do-pension-funds-work.asp
[https://perma.cc/D62M-F6BG].
59
Id.
60
29 U.S.C. § 1001 (b); KATHRYN MOORE, UNDERSTANDING EMPLOYEE BENEFITS 6 (2nd ed., 2020); see Peter
K. Stris, supra note 8.
61
29 U.S.C. § 1001 (1974); see MOORE, supra note 60; see Peter K. Stris, supra note 8.
62
See Eric Whiteside, supra note 58.
63
Id.
768 UNIVERSITY OF LOUISVILLE LAW REVIEW [Vol. 62:3
exposed to fines.64
Health insurance, on the other hand, is anything but simple. For a
claim to be covered, the insurer must determine if the procedure or medical
device is medically necessary, which requires the opinion of medical
professionals;65 when they disagree, who determines which opinion controls
what an insurance company must pay for? Additionally, ERISA welfare
benefits fines are restricted to much smaller sums than those available for
other benefit plans.66 Typically, fines are no more than $100 a day for failing
to furnish plan information for more than thirty days after a proper request.67
The fairly insignificant amount of these fines for not sending plan
information also raises the fair question: so what? In essence, the civil
enforcement structure through fines does little more than push insurers to
give someone the contractual language letting them know if they are being
wrongfully denied but does little once they are equipped with that
knowledge.68
Speaking on ERISA fines, in Gobeille v. Liberty Mut. Ins. Co.,
Justice Kennedy, writing for the majority, noted the mandates are serious and
implied there was a steep price for noncompliance: “These various
requirements are not mere formalities. Violation of any one of them may
result in both civil and criminal liability.”69 What he failed to mention,
however, is that the standard for criminal action requires a willful state of
mind, the most difficult mens rea to prove, and that civil risks were few, as
this Note will demonstrate.70
B. Plan Types
Health insurance plans in the U.S. break down into three main
categories: public, private individual, and group.71
Public plans are sponsored by either the local or the federal
government.72 They can be further broken down into entitlements like
Medicaid and government-as-employer programs like TRICARE.73
Although TRICARE, personal private, ACA market plans, religious
64
See Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) of 1974, 29 U.S.C. §§ 1131-1136 (detailing civil
and criminal penalties available and their enforcement mechanisms).
65
See 29 C.F.R. §§ 2590.715-2719 (2022); see also Karen Pollitz et al., supra note 43.
66
29 U.S.C. §§ 1131-1136.
67
Id.
68
See EBSA REPORTING GUIDE, supra note 27.
69
Gobeille v. Liberty Mut. Ins. Co., 577 U.S. 312, 323 (2016).
70
See id.; see Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) of 1974, 29 U.S.C. §§ 1131–1136.
71
See KEISLER-STARKEY & LISA N. BUNCH, supra note 18.
72
Id. at 3.
73
Id.
2024] Illusory Remedies 769
74
See Alan M. Levine, ERISA Title I Fundamentals, LEXISNEXIS,
https://www.morrisoncohen.com/siteFiles/files/ERISA%20Title%20I%20Fundamentals.pdf
[https://perma.cc/773Q-REU8] (last visited Apr. 10, 2024).
75
BARKER & KENT, supra note 10, § 8.04(b)(ii).
76
Id. It must be determined if the instrumentality of employment pulls more into the private or public sector,
through a six factor test: (1) whether the instrument is for a government purpose; (2) whether performance is on
behalf of multiple political subdivision; (3) whether private, state, or political subdivisions have ownership interests
or powers; (4) whether control and supervision is under a public authority; (5) whether express or implied statutory
authority is necessary for creation and use; and (6) the degree of financial autonomy and source of operating
expenses. Id.
77
See Id.
78
See Corbett, supra note 17. Unions are a special case because unions do not employ all their members. Id.
But unlike a normal association, they are considered an employer, larger unions may self-insure or seek a fully-
funded plan option for their members. Id. The union intersection with ERISA provides a considerable wrinkle, in
the ERISA landscape. Id. What is important to understand for this Note, is how it impacts ERISA prevalence. Id.
Unions hold a major share of the U.S. labor market and the related health insurance market share. Id; see Luke
Petach & David K. Wyant, The Union Advantage: Union Membership, Access to Care, and the Affordable Care
Act, 23 INT’L J. HEALTH ECON. & MGMT. 1, 2 (2023).
79
Corbett, supra note 17.
80
See GARY CLAXTON ET AL., EMPLOYER HEALTH BENEFITS: 2022 ANNUAL SURVEY KEISER FAM. FOUND,
30 (2022).
81
KEISLER-STARKEY & LISA N. BUNCH, supra note 18, at 3, 4; see Employee Retirement Income Security Act
(ERISA) of 1974, 29 U.S.C. §§ 1181–1191(d). 26 I.R.C. § 5000 (2022)
82
CLAXTON ET AL., supra note 80, at 163. For the purposes of this Note, fully-funded plans are also known as
insured or fully-insured plans. To reduce confusion between insured, and insureds or the state of being insured this
paper uses the fully-funded terminology.
83
KEISLER-STARKEY & LISA N. BUNCH, supra note 18, at 3–4
84
CLAXTON ET AL., supra note 80, at 9.
770 UNIVERSITY OF LOUISVILLE LAW REVIEW [Vol. 62:3
advantages the insurer receives from having a captive client base, that is at
least healthy enough to work, and from having certain administrative
functions performed by the employer’s internal human resource departments,
are traded back in part to the employer and the employees through reduced
rates.85
Self-funded or self-insured plans are those where the employer will
foot the bill for any covered medical expenses, but employers typically use a
health insurance company to perform the administrative duties required to
manage an ERISA plan.86 Self-funded companies present many of their own
problems for employees, because they are not subject to nearly any state law
governing insurance.87 Rather, they are completely covered by ERISA,
giving them an extreme amount of leeway in determining acceptable
coverage.88 Self-funded plans have few bounds other than those written into
the terms of their plans,89 whereas when an insurance company is the actual
insurer, a fully-insured plan, they are bound by some state laws that may
mandate certain minimum standards.90
This Note will predominantly address issues arising from fully-
funded plans. While all the issues discussed apply to self-funded plans, it is
important to distinguish between the incentive structures for self-funded
firms, and insurance companies.91 In a self-funded plan, the claim
administrators, which are typically actual insurance companies, are
compensated through a fee system instead of a premium structure.92 It is not
clear if this actually has a large impact on claims outcomes.93 To draw a
connection between claim denials and the compensation structure for claim
administrators requires consideration of many more market incentive, which
is a task beyond the scope of this Note.94 Accordingly, this Note narrows its
focus on fully-funded plans, where the incentives are much more bare.95
Essential to this Note are the basic concepts of claims for coverage
and their subsequent denials. Unlike most other forms of insurance,
85
KENNETH S. ABRAHAM & DANIEL SCHWARCZ, INSURANCE LAW AND REGULATION: CASES AND
MATERIALS 383–84 (7th ed. 2020).
86
Id.; see Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) of 1974, 29 U.S.C. §§ 1181–1191(d).
87
ABRAHAM & SCHWARCZ, supra note 85; see 29 U.S.C. §§ 1181-1191(d).
88
ABRAHAM & SCHWARCZ, supra note 85, at 400.
89
Id.
90
Id.
91
Id.
92
Id.
93
Metro. Life Ins. Co. v. Glenn, 554 U.S. 105, 114 (2008).
94
ABRAHAM & SCHWARCZ, supra note 85, at 400.
95
Id.
2024] Illusory Remedies 771
96
Id. at 383.
97
Id.
98
Id.
99
Id.
100
See Preauthorization, HEALTHCARE.GOV, https://www.healthcare.gov/glossary/preauthorization/
[https://perma.cc/3N4S-RJCD] (last visited Apr. 10, 2024).
101
See Haley Sweetland Edwards, How You Could Get Hit With a Surprise Medical Bill, N.Y. TIMES (Mar. 7,
2016, 2:38 PM EST) https://time.com/4246845/health-care-insurance-suprise-medical-bill/
[https://perma.cc/QV9Y-TSLC].
102
Id.
103
See EBSA REPORTING GUIDE, supra note 27.
104
See HEALTHCARE.GOV, supra note 100.
105
See Karen Pollitz et al., supra note 43 (analyzing CMS data on Healthcare.gov market plans’ claim denial
data and finding less than one percent of claims were appealed).
106
See Mark Henricks & Kim Porter, Medical Bankruptcies: Can You File for Bankruptcy Over Medical Bills?
FORBES (Aug. 11, 2022, 4:00 PM), https://www.forbes.com/advisor/debt-relief/medical-bankruptcies/
[https://perma.cc/R4Y4-X79S].
107
See Infra discussion section (II)(C).
772 UNIVERSITY OF LOUISVILLE LAW REVIEW [Vol. 62:3
By far the most common reason for denials was “all other reasons.”118 These
denial reason categories are applicable to group plan denials, and the
companies that administer Medicare and Medicaid plans are companies that
108
See EBSA REPORTING GUIDE, supra note 27; see also infra discussion section (II)(C).
109
KATHERINE GRACE CARMAN ET AL., THE HISTORY, PROMISE AND CHALLENGES OF STATE ALL PAYER
CLAIMS DATABASES: BACKGROUND MEMO FOR THE STATE ALL PAYER CLAIMS DATABASE ADVISORY
COMMITTEE TO THE DEPARTMENT OF LABOR 1 (Jun. 2, 2021), https://home.treasury.gov/policy-issues/financial-
markets-financial-institutions-and-fiscal-service/federal-insurance-office/about-fio [https://perma.cc/9NKS-
U82U].
110
See Gobeille v. Liberty Mut. Ins. Co., 577 U.S. 312, 323 (2016).
111
U.S. GOV’T ACCOUNTABILITY OFF., supra note 28.
112
Id.
113
Id.
114
Karen Pollitz et al., supra note 43.
115
Id.
116
See id.
117
Id.
118
Id.
2024] Illusory Remedies 773
also manage large group plans, like Blue Cross Blue Shield and Cigna. The
necessary elements for a denial tracking system to function are already in
place, showing that denial tracking could be readily incorporated for ERISA
plans. 119
Following the CMS data, seventy percent of internal claim appeals
were completely successful, but less than one percent of denials were
appealed.120 It is possible that the reason for appeal success prevalence is that
unreasonable denials are so rare that the small percentage of wrongful denials
are easy to catch; however, more likely, the rarity of appeals themselves
points to issues of inertia and completely asymmetrical competition between
insurers and insureds.121
Basic economic doctrine has held for centuries that firms and
individuals act in their interest.122 While the more recent field of behavioral
economics has cast some doubt on the uniformity of firms’ and individuals’
ability to act rationally, the basic concept still holds.123 Firms and individuals
take actions because they feel that the value or utility of the outcome will
outweigh the cost or opportunity cost expenditure of the act.124 In other
words, people do not cheat on their taxes or steal because the penalties and
social costs, multiplied by a probability of being caught, outweigh the
perceived benefits—at least for some. And people do things like purchase
cars because the utility they bring outweighs the cost.125
The larger a group is, the more interests that become relevant.126 This
is especially true in policymaking.127 The increasingly peripheral interests are
referred to as externalities.128 Classic examples of weighing externalities are
119
Id.
120
Id.
121
Margaret G. Farrell, ERISA Preemption and Regulation of Managed Healthcare: The Case for Managed
Federalism, 23 AM. J. L. AND MED. 251, 265-266 (1997); See generally Katherine T. Vukadin, Unfinished
Business: The Affordable Care Act and The Problem of Delayed And Denied Erisa Healthcare Claims, 47 J.
MARSHALL L. REV. 1 (2014); See Ivan Major, Two-Sided Information Asymmetry in the Healthcare Industry, 25
INT’L ADVANCES IN ECON. RSCH., 177 (2019).
122
See generally RICHARD H. THALER, MISBEHAVING: THE MAKING OF BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS (Jun. 14,
2016).
123
Id.
124
JACK P. FRIEDMAN ET AL., BARRON’S DICTIONARY OF BUSINESS AND ECONOMICS TERMS (5th ed. 2012). In
economics, utility is catchall term to describe the more subjective forms from which entities derive value and is the
quantifying of qualitative values like taste, smell, or status; and non-monetary quantitative values like calories or
dosage. See id.
125
Id. See generally RICHARD H. THALER, supra note 122.
126
JACK P. FRIEDMAN ET AL., supra note 124.
127
See RICHARD H. THALER supra note 122.
128
Id.
774 UNIVERSITY OF LOUISVILLE LAW REVIEW [Vol. 62:3
seen in health and welfare.129 For example, economists weigh the loss in tax
income from burdening a power plant with expensive air filtration machinery
against the cost of having a population riddled with lung diseases from
pollution.130 The diseases are negative externalities of the pollution, and
avoiding lost work and medical expenses are positive externalities of the
regulatory requirements.131 When given a large-scale problem, like pollution
control or health insurance policy, the sum of all externalities, original costs,
and benefits equal what is termed as the “social cost” or “social benefit,”
depending on whether the externality is a net loss or gain.132 In sum, so long
as the social benefit of an action continues to outweigh the social cost of that
action, a course of action is likely advisable.
1. Perverse Incentives.
When narrow interests create a social cost, this is often the result or
cause of a perverse incentive.133 The cobra effect describes this concept’s
origin in economics.134 The British Empire, concerned about cobras in Deli,
put a bounty on their heads; but this led to the breeding of cobras, and
increased their overall population.135
A perverse incentive scenario more like the one at play in ERISA
healthcare markets.136 In this context, there is a student who parks in an area
near enough to the Brandeis School of Law, that is functionally equidistant
to the paid-for parking lots. Unfortunately, it is metered. But, after deducing
they would only receive–on average–one fifteen-dollar ticket a semester, they
weighed the cost of being a scofflaw against the utility of essentially free
parking. It would cost them at least $300-$330 to pay for parking for the
school year; they could also park for free around a twenty-minute walk from
129
See generally Bruce C. Greenwald & Joseph E. Stiglitz, Externalities in Economies with Imperfect
Information and Incomplete Markets, 101 Q. J. OF ECON. 229 (1986).
130
See id. at 230.
131
Çağatay Koç, The Productivity of Healthcare and Health Production Functions, 13 HEALTH ECON. 739,
741–43 (2004).
132
JACK P. FRIEDMAN ET AL., supra note 124.
133
Perverse Incentives, FORBES (Feb. 20, 2009), https://www.forbes.com/2009/02/19/incentives-
compensation-bonuses-leadership_perverted_incentives.html?sh=6c7515745b3b [https://perma.cc/79L2-6P3E];
Patrick Warczak Jr., The Cobra Effect: Kisor Roberts, and the Law of Unintended Consequences, 54 AKRON L.
REV. 111, 112 (2020).
134
Patrick Warczak Jr., supra note 133.
135
Id.
136
See David McAdams & Michael Schwarz, Perverse Incentives
in the Medicare Prescription Drug Benefit: 44 INQUIRY: J. HEALTH CARE ORG., PROVISION, & FIN.157,
158 (2007) (“Since insurers prefer to attract less costly patients, each insurer has an incentive to offer less
generous coverage than its competitors (at a lower price). In some situations, this can create a ‘race to the
bottom’ in which a competitive insurance market fails to offer any insurance product providing
meaningful coverage.”).
2024] Illusory Remedies 775
the school every day. The solution is obvious, roll the dice on the metered
area.137 A student dodging parking tickets because the incentives line up is
hardly a major issue, maybe even whimsical. But, when gatekeepers of access
apply that logic healthcare, the social cost is catastrophic. 138 Consider the
analog of theft. Imagine the only punishments for theft were having to return
what was stolen and paying legal defense fees. There would be an incentive
to steal anything more valuable than cost of associated legal fees.139 The cost
incurred socially would include massively increased retail security;
depressed sales and income tax revenue; and the cascading effects of the
ensuing vigilantism, as the legitimacy of the justice system waned.140 In the
healthcare context, when firms find the rate of denying claims is more
profitable than approving them, including factors like marketability, they
reach market equilibrium.141 As in the theft analogy, if the regulatory solution
is ineffective, and other market factors do not reign in a market with perverse
incentives the social cost will spiral.142
2. Inelastic Demand.
Inelastic demand and market choice are two more central factors in
market equilibrium deranging outcomes in ERISA healthcare.143 Demand is
a primary market mover; it is how much something is wanted or needed.144
Elasticity is how much the price can fluctuate without effecting demand.145
The more necessary something is for survival or the more coerced into its
use, the more inelastic its demand becomes.146 Insulin has an inelastic
demand curve for diabetics, EpiPens for people with severe allergies, oil for
shippers, and so on.147
137
JACK P. FRIEDMAN ET AL., supra note 124. over the course of two years of this parking experiment the
students has paid $45 in tickets, or only 14% of the price to pay for parking).
138
See Lee Black, supra note 22.
139
See Patrick Warczak Jr., supra note 133.
140
See Lee Black, supra note 22; see also Bruce C. Greenwald & Joseph E. Stiglitz, supra note 129.
141
JACK P. FRIEDMAN ET AL. supra note 124. Market equilibrium is where the price for something meets the
demand for it. Id. Markets will fluctuate, events like Market equilibrium occurs when the price and quantity of an
item are aligned with an equal market demand and market supply. Id. Markets will fluctuate; for instance, events
like supply shortages may drive the cost of something up beyond demand, and there may be a mismatch where
firms work to adjust their model to return their supply and demand to equal at a desired profit margin. Id. There
are an almost incalculable number of factors affecting price for any good or service, which is why price stability is
often treated as dispositive as to whether a market is stable instead rather than other concepts like supply, demand
elasticity, and speculated security. See id.
142
See Patrick Warczak Jr., supra note 133.
143
Çağatay Koç, supra note 131, at 741.
144
JACK P. FRIEDMAN ET AL., supra note 124.
145
Çağatay Koç, supra note 131, at 741.
146
Id.
147
Id.
776 UNIVERSITY OF LOUISVILLE LAW REVIEW [Vol. 62:3
148
Coercion, FREE LEGAL DICTIONARY, https://legal-dictionary.thefreedictionary.com/coercion
[https://perma.cc/2MC6-W63B] (last visited Nov. 7, 2022).
149
See generally Ekow N. Yankah, The Force of Law: The Role of Coercion in Legal Norms, 42 U. RICH. L.
REV. 1195 (May, 2008).
150
Id,; see also ABRAHAM & SCHWARCZ, supra note 85, at 383–84.
151
ABRAHAM & SCHWARCZ, supra note 85, at 383–84; Yankah, supra note 149.
152
ABRAHAM & SCHWARCZ, supra note 85, at 383-84; Yankah, supra note 149.
153
Çağatay Koç, supra note 131, at 741 (describing how demand can be artificially created in large work forces,
given appropriate incentive structures).
154
ABRAHAM & SCHWARCZ, supra note 85, at 383–84; see G. EDWARD MILLER ET AL., AGENCY FOR
HEALTHCARE RSCH. & QUALITY, MEPS INSURANCE COMPONENT CHARTBOOK 2022 114–15 (2022); and see
AGENCY FOR HEALTHCARE RSCH. & QUALITY, Medical Expenditure Panel Survey (MEPS) Insurance
Component (IC) https://datatools.ahrq.gov/meps-ic [https://perma.cc/E5BW-SQM2] (last visited Feb. 28, 2023).
155
See generally David Horton, Infinite Arbitration Clauses, 168 U. PA. L. REV. 633 (2020).
156
See Sam Hughes et al., Federal Solutions to Address Rising Costs of Employer-Sponsored Insurance, CNTR.
FOR AM. PROGRESS (Feb. 2024), https://www.americanprogress.org/article/federal-solutions-to-address-rising-
costs-of-employer-sponsored-insurance/ [https://perma.cc/U9KV-LBF9]; see also Employee Retirement Income
Security Act (ERISA) of 1974, 29 U.S.C. §§ 1181–1191(d).
157
See Yankah, supra note 149; see also Çağatay Koç, supra note 131.
158
Health Insurance Portability and Accountability (HIPAA) Act of 1996, Pub. L. No. 104-191, 100
2024] Illusory Remedies 777
Stat. 2548; Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act (ACA), Pub. L. No. 111-148, 124 Stat. 119 (2010);
Mental Health Parity and Addiction Equity Act of 2008 (MHPAEA), Pub. L. No. 110-343, 122 Stat. 3881
(2018).
159
See Jason Grant, UnitedHealth to Pay $14.3M in 'Landmark' Settlement Over Mental Health Parity Law,
ALM BENEFITS PRO, (Aug. 19, 2021), https://www.benefitspro.com/2021/08/19/in-first-joint-state-fed-
enforcement-of-mental-health-insurance-coverage-parity-laws-ag-james-announces-14-3m-settlement-412-
120152/?slreturn=20221007193928 [https://perma.cc/3LM7-HMNB].
160
See Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) of 1974, 29 U.S.C. §§ 1885–1885(n); see 26 I.R.C.
§ 9816 (2022).
161
29 U.S.C. §§ 1885-1885(n); 26 I.R.C. § 9816.
162
29 U.S.C. §§ 1885-1885(n); 26 I.R.C. § 9816.
163
Pre-Existing Conditions, U.S. DEP’T OF HEALTH AND HUMAN SERV. https://www.hhs.gov/healthcare/about-
the-aca/pre-existing-conditions/index.html [https://perma.cc/8FFZ-3FCY] (last visited Feb. 17, 2024). See also
Vukadin, supra note 121.
164
See Vukadin, supra note 121.
165
Tracking Public Opinion on National Health Plan: Interactive, KAISER FAM. FOUND. (Oct. 16, 2020),
https://www.kff.org/interactive/tracking-public-opinion-on-national-health-plan-interactive/
[https://perma.cc/5GSZ-S4RM]; Public Opinion on Single-Payer, National Health Plans, and Expanding Access
to Medicare Coverage, KAISER FAM. FOUND. (Oct. 16, 2020), https://www.kff.org/slideshow/public-opinion-on-
single-payer-national-health-plans-and-expanding-access-to-medicare-coverage/ [https://perma.cc/R63C-
DXCV]. Though these studies are a couple years old, they show a contentious field where there is intense dissent
over whether there should be a universal healthcare plan or not. There is growing popular support for a Medicare-
for-all solution, but it is not great enough to reasonably overcome legislative opposition. However, there is much
greater popular support for making healthcare availability fairer, and some level of governmental increase to
availability. See id.
166
Id.
778 UNIVERSITY OF LOUISVILLE LAW REVIEW [Vol. 62:3
healthcare markets?167 Such bills will likely not impact ERISA healthcare
markets as much as reformers hope.168 Recall the parking scenario, like
paying for infrequent inexpensive tickets being cheaper than paying for
parking, if the cost of penalties for wrongfully denying claims is cheaper than
paying for them, then the math becomes simple, and the incentives
perverse.169
167
See 29 U.S.C. §§ 1885–1885(n); see also 26 I.R.C. § 9816.
168
Lee Black, supra note 22.
169
See Yankah, supra note 149; see infra pp. 18-19; see also Çağatay Koç,, supra note 131, at 741.
170
See David McAdams & Michael Schwarz, supra note 136; see Lee Black, supra note 22.
171
See 29 U.S.C. § 1132.
172
Id. (“A civil action may be brought— . . . by a participant, beneficiary, or fiduciary (A) to enjoin any act or
practice which violates any provision of this subchapter or the terms of the plan, or (B) to obtain other appropriate
equitable relief (i) to redress such violations or (ii) to enforce any provisions of this subchapter or the terms of the
plan.”)
173
Id. (Injunctive relief can be in the form of an order for an insurer to approve coverage for something they
refuse to cover; this would address a situation where a healthcare provider will not perform a treatment without
prior authorization—so no money has been spent, and an exact cost may be unknown. Equitable relief is more
ambiguous, but it generally refers to costs incurred in reliance or by dues owed by performance. If an insured has
incurred costs from treatments that should have been covered but were denied, the insurer may have to pay those
costs. This is similar to expectancy damages, but it is limited to actual costs or dues.).
2024] Illusory Remedies 779
174
BARKER & KENT, supra note 10, § 8.04(c)(iii).
175
29 U.S.C. § 1131.
176
Id.
177
See Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) of 1974, 29 U.S.C. § 1132; see Employee
Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) of 1974, 29 U.S.C. § 1028; see also United States v. Phillips, 19 F.3d
1565, 1584 (11th Cir. 1994) (“The only logical interpretation of Part 1 of ERISA is that the term ‘willfully’
in section 1131 requires a finding of only general intent and that section 1028 provides additional statutory
defenses not otherwise present for general intent crimes. Under this interpretation, sections 1131 and 1028 serve
distinct purposes; the term ‘willfully’ as used in section 1131 ensures that the act was done voluntarily and not by
accident or mistake; and section 1028 provides the proper scope of defenses in accordance with the codified
‘prudent man’ standard as determined by Congress.).
178
Phillips, 19 F.3d at 1565; United States v. Gray-Burriss, 920 F.3d 61 (D.C. Cir. 2019); Sealed Order, United
States v. Lontine, No. 3:02-cr-00365 (D. Or. Jul. 15, 2004); Sealed Order, United States v. Mayhew, No. 3:02-cr-
00364 (D. Or. Jul. 15, 2004); Plea Agreement, United States v. Higgs et al, No. 4:05-cr-00239 (W.D. Mo. Feb. 8,
2006) (please entered for two defendants). Author performed exhaustive searches using Lexis+, Westlaw,
Bloomberg Law, with no jurisdictional limitations. Author also searched through Federal Department of Justice
databases. Author holds that it is likely his search has not found cases which were brought. But, the scarcity of
caselaw, dockets, and legal news, indicate a clear lack of either prosecutorial interest, or efficacy of the statute.
Compare this statute, to similarly situated white collar criminal statutes like those which apply to securities, and
the void of indictments is unsettling.
179
See generally Lee Black, supra note 22.
180
Id.; see also 29 U.S.C. §§ 1131–1136.
181
See Peter K. Stris, supra note 8.
780 UNIVERSITY OF LOUISVILLE LAW REVIEW [Vol. 62:3
182
See EBSA REPORTING GUIDE, supra note 27.
183
29 U.S.C. §§ 1131–1136(2024); see also Peter K. Stris, supra note 8.
184
See Bryant, supra note 1; see also Arkin, supra note 20, at 667–69.
185
Arkin, supra note 20, at 667–69.
186
See 29 U.S.C. § 1133; see also 29 C.F.R. § 2590.715-2719 (2022).
187
BARKER & KENT, supra note 10, § 8.04(c)(iii); 29 U.S.C. § 1133; 29 C.F.R. §§ 2590.715-2719
(2022). There are exceptions for going through the internal processes: if it can be shown that the insurer
is not responsive, or their internal review processes does not comply with statute. Id.
188
29 C.F.R. § 2560.503-1 (2023) (explaining claims procedures for health insurance in general, including
appeals for group plans under ERISA).
189
Id.
190
U.S.C. § 1132(c)(1). Plan language, also referred to as detailed plan language, is essentially the contract the
insurer must honor; ERISA cases often turn on whether there is a reasonable interpretation of the language within
the plan which the insurer is contradicting. Id.
191
See generally HEALTH INFO. CTR. ERISA CLAIMS AND APPEALS PROCEDURES, PACER CTR. (2016),
https://www.pacer.org/health/pdfs/HIAC-h15.pdf [https://perma.cc/D58A-5F5E].
192
See PacifiCare Health Sys. v. Book, 538 U.S. 401, 406–07 (2003); see also Horton, supra note 155.
193
MARY FRANCES DERFNER & ARTHUR D. WOLF, COURT AWARDED ATTORNEY FEES ¶ 16.63 (2022)
(“Dague was decided under a pair of ‘prevailing party’ fee-shifting statutes requiring use of the lodestar
2024] Illusory Remedies 781
methodology. Because the statutes providing for fees in favor of a ‘prevailing party’ are given a uniform
interpretation, the courts of appeals have applied the reasoning of Dague to preclude contingency enhancements
under a variety of other federal fee-shifting statutes that employ the ‘prevailing party’ language. A non-exhaustive
list of “prevailing party” statutes under which contingency enhancements are prohibited include: . . . ERISA.”).
194
See Lina Velikova, The Truths & Myths Behind Medical Bankruptcies, MEDALERTHELP (Jan. 14, 2022).
https://medalerthelp.org/blog/medical-bankruptcies/ [https://perma.cc/5GJ8-W8TE].
195
Id.; see also DERFNER & WOLF, supra note 193.
196
See DERFNER & WOLF, supra note 193.
197
Id.; see Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) of 1974, 29 U.S.C. § 1132; see also BARKER
& KENT, supra note 10, § at 8.04(c)(i); and see PacifiCare Health Sys., 538 U.S. at 406–07 (2003).
198
Complaint at 1, Popovchak et al. v. UnitedHealth Grp. Inc. et al., (S.D.N.Y. Dec 21, 2022) (No. 1:22-cv-
10756). This case is a mass tort, being spearheaded by a healthcare provider. It exemplifies the scenario where an
interest is large enough for equitable remedies to justify litigation intervention. This case also pulls in several other
federal statutory violations, and it may show a viable legal strategy to for Plaintiffs’ attorneys to follow in the future
because the additional causes of action may allow them to bypass the strict preclusion of punitive and consequential
damages.
199
DERFNER & WOLF, supra note 193.
200
See U.S. GOV’T ACCOUNTABILITY OFF., supra note 28, at 25. While the data from this report is more than
twelve years old, it does state that diagnostic treatment appeals are more likely to result in a reversal—which
suggests there is a higher prevalence of frivolous denial of diagnostic care, although it is inconclusive as to the
degree. Id.
782 UNIVERSITY OF LOUISVILLE LAW REVIEW [Vol. 62:3
testing, but also by the extreme cost of chronic illness.201 Pain management
is far cheaper.202 From the perspective of an insurer, it is also far cheaper to
have a chronically ill person move to public care through Medicaid or
Medicare.203
With a young cancer patient like Dawn Smith, when comparing the
costs of receiving treatments resulting in remission—or—being slowed from
receiving diagnostic care, until her tumor is inoperable the second option is
a fraction of the cost.204 The American Cancer Society published a study in
2017, providing three case studies that were descriptive of a typical cancer
patient’s cost profile, which ranged from over $123,000 to $201,000 in
treatment costs over a single year.205 Especially considering the high rate of
cancer patients who suffer return bouts after remission,206 there is a clear
perverse incentive to move chronically or severely ill patients as quickly and
quietly toward long term government care as possible.207
B. Doctors as Fiduciaries
1. Basic Concept and Functionality
201
See AM. CANCER SOC’Y, THE COST OF CANCER 9–12 (2017),
https://www.fightcancer.org/sites/default/files/Costs%20of%20Cancer%20-%20Final%20Web.pdf
[https://perma.cc/X9XX-D7BZ].
202
See generally McAdams & Schwarz, supra note 136.
203
See AM. CANCER SOC’Y, supra note 201 (If someone paid $1,000 a month for their health insurance
premiums, it would take 124 months to pay in the cost of a twelve-month period of cancer treatment for the least
expensive case study. That calculation excludes the cost of plan administration and the value of interest from
investing premiums over time, so the total calculation is, of course, more involved. Regardless of how the other
factors impact overall cost, shifting these kind of losses to a public system as fast as possible is clearly preferred
because the chance that the account of a chronically ill person proving a net positive is very low.).
204
Id.
205
Id.
206
Andrea S. Blevins Primeau, Cancer Recurrence Statistics, CANCER THERAPY ADVISOR (Nov. 30, 2018),
https://www.cancertherapyadvisor.com/home/tools/fact-sheets/cancer-recurrence-statistics/
[https://perma.cc/A8MY-VNRG].
207
Id.; see also AM. CANCER SOC’Y, supra note 201.
208
Everything You Need to Get Started In Medical Billing & Coding: 3.04: More About Insurance & the
Insurance Claims Process, MED. BILLING & CODING CERTIFICATION,
https://www.medicalbillingandcoding.org/insurance-claims-process/ [https://perma.cc/P5C4-HEM8] (last
checked, Jan. 22, 2023).
209
See 29 C.F.R. §§ 2590.715-2719 (2022); see also Karen Pollitz et al., supra note 43.
2024] Illusory Remedies 783
210
AM. MED. ASS’N, 2021 PRIOR AUTHORIZATION STATE LAW CHART (2021), https://www.ama-
assn.org/sites/ama-assn.org/files/corp/media-browser/public/arc-public/pa-state-chart.pdf [https://perma.cc/J7R9-
B2KJ] (explaining how the state where the plan is issued controls what the specific review standards are, and how
the state of issuance is typically the determined by the employer and not the beneficiary).
211
See generally Skelcy v. United Health Grp., Inc., 620 F. App’x 136 (3d Cir. 2015); and see Corbett, supra
note 17, at 296–98.
212
See Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) of 1974, 29 U.S.C. § 1109(a); see Aetna Health
Inc. v. Davila, 542 U.S. 200, 220 (2004); see also Pegram v. Herdrich, 530 U.S. 211, 220–22 (2000) (The Health
Maintenance Organization (HMO) in Pegram was a hybrid system where patients were treated by the same
organization that acted as the insurer in a pre-paid arrangement. The doctors who saw patients were directly
incentivized not to treat patients through an associated bonus structure. Id.); and see Corbett, supra note 17, at 296–
98.
213
29 U.S.C. § 1002(21)(A).
214
See Pegram, 530 U.S. at 227–28.
215
Id. at 229; see also Wit v. United Behav. Health, 79 F.4th 1068, 1082–83 (9th Cir. 2023).
216
Pegram, 530 U.S. at 229.
784 UNIVERSITY OF LOUISVILLE LAW REVIEW [Vol. 62:3
217
Id.; see also Corbett, supra note 17, at 296–98.
218
Pegram, 530 U.S. at 211.
219
See id.; Corbett, supra note 17, at 296–98.
220
See Pegram, 530 U.S. at 229.
221
See id.; and see Sam Stein, supra note 1.
222
See Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) of 1974, 29 U.S.C. § 1109.
223
29 U.S.C. § 1109.
224
Kathy Katella, Can a Second Opinion Make a Difference?, YALE MED. (Jan. 15, 2020)
https://www.yalemedicine.org/news/second-opinions [https://perma.cc/AKA2-YX3Z].
225
See generally Major, supra note 121.
226
Id.
227
See Lauren Rousseau and I. Eric Nordan, Tug v. Mingo: Let the Plaintiffs Sue – Opioid Addiction, The
Wrongful Conduct Rule, and the Culpability Exception, 34 W. Mich. U.T.M. Cooley L. Rev. 33, 73 (2017).
228
Corbett, supra note 17, at 298–99.
2024] Illusory Remedies 785
229
See Pegram v. Herdrich, 530 U.S. 211, 229 (2000).
230
See Aetna Health Inc. v. Davila, 542 U.S. 200, 220 (2004) (“This strongly suggests that the ultimate
decisionmaker in a plan regarding an award of benefits must be a fiduciary and must be acting as a fiduciary when
determining a participant’s or beneficiary’s claim.”).
231
See generally HEALTH INFO. CTR., supra note 191.
232
Id.
233
See Bryant, supra note 1; see also infra discussion in Introduction.
234
Bryant, supra note 1. see Am. Med. Ass’n, supra note 210.
235
Id.; see, e.g., Skelcy v. United Health Grp., Inc., 620 F. App’x 136, 143–44 (3d Cir. 2015).
236
RESTATEMENT (THIRD) OF TORTS: CONCLUDING PROVISIONS, Duties to Patients & Others § 3I (Am. L. Inst.
2022).
237
See Metro. Life Ins. Co. v. Glenn, 554 U.S. 105, 127–28 (2008) (Scalia, J. dissenting) (“A third-party
insurance company that administers an ERISA-governed disability plan and that pays for benefits out of its own
coffers profits with each benefits claim it rejects. I see no reason why the Court must volunteer, however, that an
employer who administers its own ERISA-governed plan ‘clear[ly]’ has a conflict of interest.”).
238
Id.
239
Id.
786 UNIVERSITY OF LOUISVILLE LAW REVIEW [Vol. 62:3
As stated, the only reliable data on claim denial comes from CMS.249
But that data only tracks the CMS plans of Medicare and Medicaid.250 A
Kaiser Family Foundation report on recent CMS data found less than one
percent of claim denials were appealed by insureds, and of the appeals, over
seventy percent were reversed.251 From this CMS data, it may be extrapolated
that probable only a tiny percentage of denials are appealed.252 It can also be
240
See Skelcy v. United Health Grp., Inc., 620 F. ’pp'x 136, 143–44 (3d Cir. 2015).
241
JOSEPH D. ZAMORE ET AL., BUSINESS TORTS § 5.03 (2022).
242
See id. § 22.02.
243
Id. § 5.03.
244
See LOUIS R. FRUMER & MELVIN I. FRIEDMAN, PERSONAL INJURY: ACTIONS, DEFENSES, DAMAGES § 77.03
(2023).
245
Id.
246
See AMA Principles of Medical Ethics, AM. MED. ASS’N, https://code-medical-ethics.ama-
assn.org/principles [https://perma.cc/8J22-ATDA] (last visited Feb. 13, 2023).
247
Id.
248
Id.
249
See infra discussion section I.
250
Karen Pollitz et al., supra note 43.
251
Id.
252
Id.
2024] Illusory Remedies 787
extrapolated from the data that a denied claim’s merit and appellate status are
not correlated in a way that predicts merit of non-appealed claims because
there is no control group studied here.253 To determine how many valid
claims are being denied, a random sampling or complete review would need
to be taken.254 The void of information begs the question: Who should be
collecting and aggregating claim denial data for ERISA plans?
253
Id.
254
See Abolfazl Asudeh et al., On Detecting Cherry-picked Trendlines, 13 VLDB ENDOWMENT 939–41
(2020).
255
See, e.g., Gobeille v. Liberty Mut. Ins. Co., 577 U.S. 312 (2016); see also U.S. GOV’T ACCOUNTABILITY
OFF., supra note 28.
256
What We Do, EMP. BENEFITS SEC. ADMIN., https://www.dol.gov/agencies/ebsa/about-ebsa/about-us/what-
we-do [https://perma.cc/L44E-893L] (last visited Jan. 22, 2023); Industry Directory, INS. INFO. INST.,
https://www.iii.org/services/directory/company-categories/state-insurance-departments [https://perma.cc/7JY2-
U6TQ] (last visited Feb. 17, 2024); CARMAN ET AL., supra note 109; About FIO, U.S. DEP’T OF THE TREASURY,
https://home.treasury.gov/policy-issues/financial-markets-financial-institutions-and-fiscal-service/federal-
insurance-office/about-fio [https://perma.cc/7VZR-3APN] (last visited Jan. 22, 2023).
257
See infra discussion sections (II)(C)(1)-(9).
258
Telephone Interview with anonymous representatives, Emp. Benefits Sec. Admin. (Dec. 16, 2022, Sept. 28
2022, Sept. 02, 2022, Aug. 30, 2022); E-mail from Francis Beifuss to NAIC representative (Nov. 1, 2022, Nov. 2,
2022); Telephone Interview with anonymous representative, U.S. Department of the Treasury (Nov. 1, 2022).
259
See EBSA REPORTING GUIDE, supra note 27, at 2.
788 UNIVERSITY OF LOUISVILLE LAW REVIEW [Vol. 62:3
Liberty Mut. Ins. determined that state reporting systems usually conducted
through All-Payer Claims Databases (APCD) cannot enforce penalties.260
Vermont had a system where it enacted fines for non-compliance.261 Insurers
were supposed to report data about their insured, specifically cost and
demographic data.262 Liberty Mutual brought suit against the imposition, and
in an eight to one split, the Supreme Court upheld that the fines were
preempted by ERISA, thus rendering the state’s enforcement mechanism
useless.263
260
See generally Gobeille v. Liberty Mut. Ins. Co., 577 U.S. 312 (2016).
261
Id. at 315.
262
Id. at 315–16.
263
Id. at 326–27.
264
EMP. BENEFITS SEC. ADMIN, What We Do, supra note 256.
265
Id.; see also EMP. BENEFITS SEC. ADMIN., History supra note 49.
266
EMP. BENEFITS SEC. ADMIN., History, supra note 256; and see EMP. BENEFITS SEC. ADMIN, What We Do,
supra note 49.
267
EMP. BENEFITS SEC. ADMIN., History, supra note 256; and see EMP. BENEFITS SEC. ADMIN, What We Do,
supra note 49; see also JANET L. YELLEN ET AL., REALIZING PARITY, REDUCING STIGMA, AND RAISING
AWARENESS: INCREASING ACCESS TO MENTAL HEALTH AND SUBSTANCE USE DISORDER COVERAGE, U.S.
DEP’T OF LAB. 3 (2022); and see Telephone Interview with anonymous representatives, Emp. Benefits Sec.
Admin., supra note 258 (An EBSA representative clarified that plans and issuers, referenced in the above report,
as meaning the sponsoring employer and the plan they procure. Claim administrators are not considered the issuer.).
268
See U.S. GOV’T ACCOUNTABILITY OFF., supra note 28, at 5.
269
Id.
270
Id.
2024] Illusory Remedies 789
staff and other support staff to ensure compliance; and the EBSA countering
the incentives they have for negligence is rational.271 Moreover, the
employers have plenty of time to correct the behavior of the claim
administrators before any actual penalties are levied; and their account size
and the nature of the relationship between a claim administrator as opposed
to an insurer, gives self-funded firms significant leverage to control or fire
claim administrators.272
Conversely, in the case of fully-funded plans, EBSA leveraging fines
against the employer directly and immediately makes little to no sense.273 The
rationale is that the employer, once it notices wrongful healthcare claim
denials, should fight for their employees and should sue their insurers if they
are non-compliant.274 However, employers with fully-funded plans are often
smaller with fewer resources, and they do not have the option to leave a plan
the way an administrator can be fired.275 The plan, therefore, ultimately takes
the risk away from the perpetrator and places it on an employer, in hopes that
market solutions will prevail in curbing bad insurer behavior.276
The problem with that assertion is health insurance in the U.S. does
not operate like a normal market.277 Instead, the health insurance market is
insulated from normal remedies and avoids many anti-trust laws through the
McCarren Ferguson Act—discussed in more depth in section (II)(D)—
allowing the industry to set somewhat uniform standards, even if those
standards are sub-optimal.278 Even if the health insurance market did respond
to normal market pressures, the current system would unnecessarily still pit
employees against employers. 279
As an example, imagine an employee in a firm with thirty full-time
271
AL STEWART, U.S. DEP’T OF LAB., ANNUAL REPORT ON SELF-INSURED GROUP HEALTH PLANS MARCH
2021 4 (2021), https://www.dol.gov/sites/dolgov/files/EBSA/researchers/statistics/retirement-bulletins/annual-
report-on-self-insured-group-health-plans-2021.pdf.
272
See BARKER & KENT, supra note 10; see also Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) of 1974,
29 U.S.C. § 1133.
273
See BARKER & KENT, supra note 10.
274
YELLEN ET AL., supra note 267, at 39–41.
275
See STEWART supra note 271.
276
See Major, supra note 121.
277
See McCarran-Ferguson Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 1011–1015; see also United States v. Robertson, 158 F.3d 1370,
71–72 (9th Cir. 1998) (clarifying that “. . . Congress enacted the McCarran-Ferguson Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 1011–
1015, . . . [to] allow[ ] the states to continue regulating the insurance industry despite its interstate effects.”); contra
Humana Inc. v. Forsyth, 525 U.S. 299, 314 (1999) (“Because RICO [federal law] advances the State's interest in
combating insurance fraud, and does not frustrate any articulated Nevada policy, we hold that the McCarran-
Ferguson Act does not block the respondent policy beneficiaries' recourse to RICO in this case.”); see discussion
infra Section I.(D).
(insurance in general was insulated from federal anti-trust laws because information is necessary for firms to
function, and they provide a backstop or safety net. So they are allowed to share information insureds, which
normally could amount to price fixing).
278
United States v. Robertson, 158 F.3d at 1370.
279
See Major, supra note 121, at 178–79. United States v. Robertson, 158 F.3d 1370.
790 UNIVERSITY OF LOUISVILLE LAW REVIEW [Vol. 62:3
employees. The employee is denied an MRI, and it is clear from their plan
language and personal context that the MRI should be covered. Their
employer is a small firm, so they, like most others, outsource health insurance
to a fully-funded plan like one through United Health Systems.280 United
denies the claim, while breaking a series of ERISA plan requirements and
resulting in confusion, and gives bad advice for how their denial should be
resolved, which in turn creates further delays.281 If requested by the
employee, the EBSA will contact the employer and let them know they are
violating the terms of their care plan. Because it is the employer’s duty to
police the insurer,282 this puts whomever at the small firm is wearing the
human resources hat that day against an insurer.283 They can only really leave
once a year.284 It also likely has an obvious chilling effect—employees
accusing their employers and source of healthcare of potentially criminal
wrongdoing certainly presents a difficult proposition to the wronged.285 This
is especially so when the wrongdoing is clearly not the fault of the employer,
who likely has no idea there is even an issue, because of the reporting
requirements set by the EBSA.286
In its current Reporting and Disclosure Guide for Employee Benefits,
the EBSA does not require insurers to notice anyone other than beneficiaries
or participants of a denial of a claim for care.287 In fact, they may be violating
privacy act regulations for disclosing the entirety of a claim denial to the
employer who is supposedly policing them.288
The EBSA provides a necessary function of helping curb issues of
lacking accountability; however, their methods are monolithically aimed
toward self-funded plans.289 There is also a major issue creating a conflict
between maintaining barriers of privacy between employers and employees
when it comes to their healthcare outcomes.290 There needs to be a
280
See STEWART supra note 271, at 4–5.
281
HEALTH INFO. CTR., supra note 191.
282
See STEWART supra note 271.
283
Id.
284
See EBSA REPORTING GUIDE, supra note 27, at 5–8.42 U.S.C. §§ 300gg-1(a)-(c) (restrictions on denying
insurance coverage for preexisting conditions, can be avoided outside of special enrolment periods, this and
contractual obligations makes leaving a plan partway through difficult and risky).
285
See Vukadin, supra note 121.
286
See EBSA REPORTING GUIDE, supra note 27, at 5–8.
287
Id. at 2–5.
288
Id. at 2 (The row entitled “Notification of Benefits Determination” states that “[a]dverse benefit
determinations must include required disclosures (e.g., the specific reason(s) for the denial of a claim . . .” must be
disclosed only to “[c]laimants (participants and beneficiaries or authorized claims representatives).”).
289
See U.S. GOV’T ACCOUNTABILITY OFF., supra note 28, at 5.
290
See EBSA REPORTING GUIDE, supra note 27, at 2.(consider the implication of having to explain to an
employer that insurance is not covering a necessary form of care, while an above-board human resources
department should handle that, without asking what the coverage is for, it creates issues in advocacy and many
small firms do not have actual human resources departments).
2024] Illusory Remedies 791
The U.S. Department of the Treasury stores Form 5500’s, which are
forms that organizations with 100 employees or more must use to report their
ERISA and ACA compliance information.295 The Form 5500’s are fairly
scant,296 but they provide some raw data for medium-to-large firms on ERISA
participation.297 This reporting determines the number of U.S. residents on
ERISA plans.298 However, the scope of Form 5500 is quite limited: It does
not capture those who have employer-sponsored health insurance from firms
with under 150 employees. Considering that employers with 100 or more
employees must provide insurance plans to their employees and that smaller
firms have incentives through tax and labor market realities, the number of
people receiving insurance from employers who are not required to send in
Form 5500’s are immense.299 Additionally, the Department of the Treasury
established the Federal Insurance Office (FOI) in 2010, which collects
market data and proposes executive and legislative action.300 It has stated
291
See STEWART supra note 271.
292
See AM. CANCER SOC’Y, supra note 201.
293
Id.
294
UnitedHealth Group, Annual Report (Form 10-K) 66 (Dec. 31, 2021) (UnitedHealth Group reported
$212,206,000,000 in total consolidated assets in 2021).
295
See Dodd-Frank Act, 12 U.S.C. § 5383(a)(1)(C) (2022); see U.S. DEP’T OF THE TREASURY, supra note 256;
see U.S. DEP’T OF LAB., EMP. BENEFITS SEC. ADMIN., USER GUIDE 2019 FORM 5500 GROUP HEALTH PLANS
RESEARCH FILE 2 (2021) [hereinafter USER GUIDE 2019 FORM 5500].
296
See Form 5500, U.S. DEP’T OF LAB. (2022), https://www.dol.gov/sites/dolgov/files/EBSA/employers-and-
advisers/plan-administration-and-compliance/reporting-and-filing/form-5500/2022-form-5500.pdf
[https://perma.cc/F4L2-YL48].
297
USER GUIDE 2019 FORM 5500, supra note 296.
298
Id. Additionally, the Department of the Treasury established the Federal Insurance Office (FIO) in 2010,
which collects market data and proposes executive and legislative action. See U.S. DEP’T OF THE TREASURY, supra
note 256. It has stated however, health insurance outside of Medicare and Medicaid is generally outside the scope
of FIO. Id.
299
Id.
300
U.S. DEP’T OF THE TREASURY, supra note 256.
792 UNIVERSITY OF LOUISVILLE LAW REVIEW [Vol. 62:3
301
Id.
302
See CARMAN ET AL., supra note 109, at 1–2.
303
INS. INFO. INST., supra note 256.
304
See Gobeille v. Liberty Mut. Ins. Co., 577 U.S. 312, 323 (2016); and see BARKER & KENT, supra
note 10, § 8.04(d).
305
CARMAN ET AL., supra note 109, at 5.
306
Id.
307
Id. at 1.
308
Id. at 7.
309
Id.
310
See id. See generally Gobeille v. Liberty Mut. Ins. Co., 577 U.S. 312 (2016).
311
See Gobeille, 577 U.S. at 323.
312
See id.; see CARMAN ET AL., supra note 109, at 2 (“This [Gobeille] has created a significant limitation:
ACPDs can no longer mandate submission of data on a large proportion of the population covered by employer-
sponsored insurance.”).
2024] Illusory Remedies 793
system and should not be tampered with. But if the second only includes
cherry-picked data and, in reality, it is providing cover for an extremely
unhealthy system, then the issue with skewed data becomes clearer. When
insurance companies get to pick and choose what data is sent to the APCDs,
they can quickly turn into government-legitimized marketing tools.313
313
See infra discussion section (II)(D).
314
ABRAHAM & SCHWARCZ, supra note 85, at 112.
315
Id.
316
See McCarran-Ferguson Act, INS. INFO. INST. https://www.iii.org/publications/insurance-
handbook/regulatory-and-financial-environment/mccarran-ferguson-act [https://perma.cc/JG6H-B34V] (last
visited Feb. 19, 2024); and see McCarran-Ferguson Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 1011-1015.
317
See ABRAHAM & SCHWARCZ, supra note 85, at 112; see also U.S. GOV’T ACCOUNTABILITY OFF., supra
note 28.
318
See ABRAHAM & SCHWARCZ, supra note 85, at 112–15.
319
Id. at 118–19.
320
Id.; JACK P. FRIEDMAN ET AL., supra note 124 (defining a cartel as a group of independent market participants
who collude to improve profits and dominate the market). Cartels typically operate in related markets or the same
market. Id. They are anti-competitive and are generally outlawed through anti-trust laws. Id. Cartels price fix, rig
bidding, and set output. Id.
321
ABRAHAM & SCHWARCZ, supra note 85, at 112; JACK P. FRIEDMAN ET AL., supra note 124.
322
ABRAHAM & SCHWARCZ, supra note 85.
794 UNIVERSITY OF LOUISVILLE LAW REVIEW [Vol. 62:3
323
Id.
324
29 C.F.R. §§ 2590.715-2719 (2022); See infra discussion section (II)(D)(1).
325
See Vukadin, supra note 121.
326
See U.S. GOV’T ACCOUNTABILITY OFF., supra note 28.
327
Contacts and Score Card, NAT’L ASS’N INS. COMM’R,
https://view.officeapps.live.com/op/view.aspx?src=https%3A%2F%2Fcontent.naic.org%2Fsites%2Fdefault%2F
files%2Finline-files%2Findustry_mcas_2021_scorecard_ltc%2520_all.xlsx&wdOrigin=BROWSELINK (last
visited Feb. 19, 2024).
328
See Gobeille v. Liberty Mut. Ins. Co., 577 U.S. 312, 323 (2016); and see U.S. GOV’T ACCOUNTABILITY
OFF., supra note 28.
329
U.S. GOV’T ACCOUNTABILITY OFF., supra note 28.
330
Regulator, NAT’L ASS’N INS. COMM’R, https://content.naic.org/regulator [https://perma.cc/T9A5-4NJH]
(last visited Jan. 22, 2023).
331
E-mail from Jacob Kline, NAIC Representative, to Francis Beifuss, author (Nov. 2, 2022, 12:06 EST) (on
file with author) (stating, “Thank you for reaching back out. To gain access to MCAS, a CoCode [an insurer
identifier] would be necessary to proceed with account creation. Any questions, please let us know. Thanks, Jacob
Kline, NAIC Service Desk, National Association of Insurance Commissioners Customer Service and
Support/Help Desk, 1100 Walnut St., Ste 1500, Kansas City, MO 64106-2197 P:
[816.783.8500|tel:8167838500].”).
332
See Freedom of Information Act, 5 U.S.C. § 552(b)(4).
333
Asudeh et al., supra note 254 (detailing how data can be manipulated through cherry-picking to show
seemingly accurate information that is highly misleading).
334
NAT’L ASS’N INS. COMM’R, supra note 327.
2024] Illusory Remedies 795
Figure (II)(1)335
Yes, that is it.336 What little information the NAIC’s report contained is scant
and, based on the information contained within, it is unclear what the actual
requirements, if any, exist for insurers reporting to the NAIC.337 The NAIC
has no governmental authority to demand data from insurers.338 The
organization states “Our goal is to bring state regulators together to serve the
public interest. We provide tools and resources to help regulators set
standards and best practices, provide regulatory support functions, and
educate consumers and stakeholders on U.S. state-based insurance
regulation.”339 However, the NAIC will not give the detailed report to a non-
335
Id.
336
Id.
337
See Gobeille v. Liberty Mut. Ins. Co., 577 U.S. 312, 323 (2016); U.S. GOV’T ACCOUNTABILITY OFF., supra
note 28.
338
U.S. GOV’T ACCOUNTABILITY OFF., supra note 28.
339
Regulator, NAT’L ASS’N INS. COMM’R, https://content.naic.org/regulator [https://perma.cc/T9A5-4NJH]
796 UNIVERSITY OF LOUISVILLE LAW REVIEW [Vol. 62:3
insurer.340 Because they are a private organization, this data is likely not
discoverable under a Freedom of Information Act request either.341
Considering these factors, it is impracticable to assess the credibility of their
claims and subsequently the usefulness of the data.342
7. Private Organizations
350
See infra discussion section (II)(C)(1)-(8).
351
Id.
352
Id.; see JANET L. YELLEN ET AL., supra note 267.
353
EBSA REPORTING GUIDE, supra note 27, at 5-8.
354
Karen Pollitz et al., supra note 43.
355
Id.
356
Metro. Life Ins. Co. v. Glenn, 554 U.S. 105, 128 (2008); Çagatay Koç, The Productivity of Healthcare and
Health Production Functions, 13 HEALTH ECON. 739, 741-743 (2004); see infra discussion section (III)(C)(1)-(8);
David McAdams & Michael Schwarz, Perverse Incentives in the Medicare Prescription Drug Benefit: 44 no.
2 INQUIRY: THE J. OF HEALTHCARE ORG. PROVISION & FIN.157 (2007).
357
Karen Pollitz et al., supra note 43.
358
See id.
359
See generally Andres Almazan et al., Firms’ Stakeholders and the Costs of Transparency (Nat’l Bureau of
Econ. Rsch., Working Paper No. 13647, 2007).
360
Id.
361
Michael T. Graham et al., 8 Best Practices for Handling ERISA Benefit Claims, LEXISNEXIS LAW 360 (Sept.
27, 2019), https://www.law360.com/articles/1203105/8-best-practices-for-handling-erisa-benefit-claims
[https://perma.cc/6MLG-6587].
362
KEISLER-STARKEY & BUNCH, supra note 18, at 4–5; Mark P. Cussen, Top 5 Reasons Why People Go
Bankrupt, INVESTOPEDIA (Mar. 4, 2021), https://www.investopedia.com/financial-edge/0310/top-5-reasons-
people-go-bankrupt.aspx [https://perma.cc/3U5L-G6VS].
363
See generally Almazan et al., supra note 359.
798 UNIVERSITY OF LOUISVILLE LAW REVIEW [Vol. 62:3
D. Preemption
364
Preemption, CORNELL L. SCH. LEGAL INFO. INST. (last visited Jan. 30, 2024),
https://www.law.cornell.edu/wex/preemption [https://perma.cc/LXQ2-TM23].
365
Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) of 1974, 29 U.S.C. § 1144(a).
366
Margaret G. Farrell, supra note 121, at 254–56.
367
See Humana Inc. v. Forsyth, 525 U.S. 299, 311–12 (1999) (discussing the place of the McCarran-Ferguson
Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 1011–1015, in ERISA and when state reverse preemption may apply); and see N.Y. State
Conference of Blue Cross & Blue Shield Plans v. Travelers Ins. Co., 514 U.S. 645 (1995) (holding that certain
state surcharge requirements avoiding preemption because they are insurance industry-wide).
368
Margaret G. Farrell, supra note 121, at 254–56; see also BARKER & KENT, supra note 10, at § 8.04(d)(i)-
(iii) (2nd 2022).
369
Gobeille v. Liberty Mut. Ins. Co., 577 U.S. 312 (2016); Farrell, supra note 121, at 254-256.
370
Contra Gobeille, 577 U.S. at 323 (“These various requirements are not mere formalities. Violation of any
one of them may result in both civil and criminal liability.”); see Peter K. Stris, supra note 8, at 396–98; and see
Sharon J. Arkin, supra note 20.
371
See Gobeille, 577 U.S. at 323; see also discussion infra Sections II.A––C.
2024] Illusory Remedies 799
372
See Gobeille, 577 U.S. at 323; and see Forsyth, 525 U.S. at 311–12.
373
See Bryant, supra note 1; see U.S. DEP’T OF LAB. & U.S. DEP’T OF HEALTH AND HUM. SERV., supra note
45; see also discussion infra Section II.(C).
374
See EBSA REPORTING GUIDE, supra note 27, at 5–8; see also infra discussion section (II)(C).
375
KEISLER-STARKEY & BUNCH, supra note 18, at 4–5; Lina Velikova, supra note 194.
376
See ABRAHAM & SCHWARCZ, supra note 85, at 112–17.
377
Id.
378
Id.
379
Id.
380
Id.
381
Id.
382
See ABRAHAM & SCHWARCZ, supra note 85, at 112–17.
383
Id.; see also McCarran-Ferguson Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 1011–1015.
384
BARKER & KENT, supra note 10, at § 8.04(d).
385
See generally Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) of 1974, 29 U.S.C. §§ 1001–1461; and
see BARKER & KENT, supra note 10, at § 8.04(d).
800 UNIVERSITY OF LOUISVILLE LAW REVIEW [Vol. 62:3
386
See BARKER & KENT, supra note 10, at § 8.04(d); see also McCarran-Ferguson Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 1011–
1015.
387
Rebecca Wilson, Self Funded vs Fully Insured vs Level Funded Plans, BLUE RIDGE RISK PARTNERS (Aug.
10, 2021), https://www.blueridgeriskpartners.com/blog/eb-types-of-health-plans [https://perma.cc/G9S8-2Z3S].
388
The Basics of an ERISA Life, Health, and Disability Insurance Claim—Part Three: Plan and Claims
Administrators, MCKENNON L. GRP. PC, https://mslawllp.com/the-basics-of-an-erisa-life-health-and-disability-
insurance-claim-part-three-plan-and-claims-
administrators/#:~:text=In%20contrast%20to%20the%20Plan,and%20dismemberment%20insurance%20benefit
s%2C%20etc. [https://perma.cc/H5N9-RPGA] (last visited Feb. 20, 2024).
389
Id.
390
Id.
391
See id.
392
Id.
393
Wilson, supra note 387; see Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) of 1974, 29 U.S.C. §
1002(16); see also U.S. DEP’T OF LAB. & U.S. DEP’T OF HEALTH AND HUM. SERV., supra note 45, at 2.
394
ABRAHAM & SCHWARCZ, supra note 85, at 112.
395
Id.; see Wilson supra note 387.
396
See id.
2024] Illusory Remedies 801
397
See generally Metro. Life Ins. Co. v. Glenn, 554 U.S. 105 (2008); and see generally Gobeille v. Liberty Mut.
Ins. Co., 577 U.S. 312 (2016); see Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) of 1974, 29 U.S.C. §
1144(a); see also BARKER & KENT, supra note 10, at § 8.04(d).
398
29 U.S.C. §§ 1144(b)(2)(A)–(B); see also Edward Alburo Morrissey, Deem and Deemer: ERISA Preemption
Under the Deemer Clause as Applied to Employer Health Care Plans with Stop-Loss Insurance; Legislative
Reform., 23 J. of Legis., no. 2, 307, 308–309 (1997).
399
29 U.S.C. §§ 1144(b)(2)(A)–(B).
400
29 U.S.C. §§ 1191(a).
401
Id.
402
Id.; see Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) of 1974, 29 U.S.C. § 1144(b)(2)(A)-(B);
Morrissey, supra note 398; and see Metro Life Ins. Co., 554 U.S. 105.
403
See generally Aetna Health Inc. v. Davila, 542 U.S. 200 (2004).
404
Id. at 212–14.
405
BARKER & KENT, supra note 10, at § 8.04(d)(ii).
406
Id.
802 UNIVERSITY OF LOUISVILLE LAW REVIEW [Vol. 62:3
407
See generally Gobeille v. Liberty Mut. Ins. Co., 577 U.S. 312 (2016).
408
AGENCY FOR HEALTHCARE RSCH. & QUALITY, supra note 154.
409
See G. EDWARD MILLER ET AL., supra note 154; Id. at 26.
410
See generally BARKER & KENT, supra note 10, at § 8.04.
411
See, e.g., Gobeille v. Liberty Mut. Ins. Co., 577 U.S. 312 (2016); Metro. Life Ins. Co. v. Glenn, 554 U.S.
105 (2008); Aetna Health Inc. v. Davila, 542 U.S. 200 (2004).
412
See Gobeille, 577 U.S. at 312; Glenn, 554 U.S. at 105; Aetna Health Inc., 542 U.S. at 200.
413
See Gobeille, 577 U.S. at 312; Glenn, 554 U.S. at 105; Aetna Health Inc., 542 U.S. at 200.
414
See, e.g., Glenn, 554 U.S. at 123–24 (Roberts, C.J., concurring).
415
See AM. CANCER SOC’Y, supra note 201; see infra discussion section (II)(B).
416
See infra discussion section (I)(D).
417
See Steve Aldana, 18 Wellness Program Incentive Ideas from the Best Corporate Wellness Programs In
2023, WELLSTEPS (Feb. 7, 2023) https://www.wellsteps.com/blog/2020/01/02/wellness-program-incentive-ideas/
2024] Illusory Remedies 803
[https://perma.cc/Z7NV-XU8B].
418
Id.
419
Id.
420
Id.
421
See discussion infra Sections I.D.–II.A-B.
422
See AM. CANCER SOC’Y, supra note 201; 29 C.F.R. §§ 2590.715-2719; 29 U.S.C. §§ 1181-1191(d).
423
SARA ROSENBAUM ET AL., U.S. DEP’T OF HEALTH AND HUMAN SERV., MEDICAL NECESSITY IN PRIVATE
HEALTH PLANS: IMPLICATIONS FOR BEHAVIORAL HEALTH CARE 30 (“Similarly, when the denial is based on
medical necessity, the rule requires the plan either to explain the scientific or clinical judgment used in applying
the plan’s terms or to include a statement that such an explanation will be provided free of charge if requested.”).29
C.F.R. §§ 2590.715-2719; 29 U.S.C. §§ 1181-1191(d).
424
29 U.S.C. § 1144(b)(2)(A); Metro. Life Ins. Co. v. Glenn, 554 U.S. 105 (2008).
425
See AM. CANCER SOC’Y, supra note 201.
426
See Nick Versaw, How Much Does an MRI Cost? COMPARE.COM (Feb. 1, 2022),
https://www.compare.com/health/healthcare-resources/how-much-does-an-mri-cost [https://perma.cc/M9E8-
LBHL].
427
See AM. CANCER SOC’Y, supra note 201; LUPUS FOUND. OF AM., Lupus Facts and Statistics
https://www.lupus.org/resources/lupus-facts-and-statistics [https://perma.cc/4MWW-HJM7] (last visited Jan. 22,
2022).
428
See AM. CANCER SOC’Y, supra note 201.
429
Rebecca Wilson, supra note 387.
430
See AM. CANCER SOC’Y, supra note 201.
431
Id.
804 UNIVERSITY OF LOUISVILLE LAW REVIEW [Vol. 62:3
no longer the problem of large insurers. 432 So, if insurers can keep insureds
from being diagnosed with a serious illness until their illness is so out of hand
that disability, hospice, or death are the outcome, insurers can save
tremendous amounts of money.433 In these cases, insurers may have to cover
some costs they previously denied, and pay their attorneys’ billable hours.434
But even the high cost of defense is much cheaper than the cost of taking an
insured through a multi-decade fight with recuring cancer, especially if the
ratio of denials to legal action are as low as they appear.435 Without serious
penalty exposures from injured parties, the parties with a motivation for
seeking correction—the people affected by insurers’ casual indifference—
will continue to be treated like infrequent, inexpensive parking tickets in a
very, very, expensive parking lot.436
IV. SOLUTIONS
A. Transparency and Data
432
Id. at 14.
433
See infra discussion Sections (II)(A),(B).
434
Id.
435
Id.; AM. AM. CANCER SOC’Y, supra note. 201; Karen Pollitz et al, supra note 43.
436
See infra discussion section (I)(D).
437
See Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) of 1974, 29 U.S.C. § 1143; Karen Pollitz et al.,
supra note 43.
438
Id.
439
Id.
440
29 U.S.C. § 1143.
441
AGENCY FOR HEALTHCARE RSCH. & QUALITY, supra note 154.
2024] Illusory Remedies 805
This solution would be an ideal landing page for the data collected by the
EBSA.442 Making data about claim denial rates public would help provide a
market solution.443 With trustworthy data, it would be easier for employers
to make informed decision on which insurers provide quality service.444
B. Removal of Immunities
1. Civil Penalties
442
See id.
443
See generally Asudeh et al., supra note 254; see also discussion infra Sections I.(D), II.(C). Publicizing
accurate denial rate data could diffuse some insurer benefits for operating as a cartel. Insurers would be subject to
informed consumer market inputs and would have to carefully balance anti-competitive behavior against drawing
regulator attention. In other words, they could uniformly have high denial rates, which would be more likely to
draw the attention of regulators, or they could compete with each other.
444
Asudeh et al., supra note 254;
445
See 29 U.S.C. § 1132; and see Mass. Mut. Life Ins. Co. v. Russell, 473 U.S. 134, 148 (1985) (“Thus, the
relevant text of ERISA, the structure of the entire statute, and its legislative history all support the conclusion that
in § 409(a) Congress did not provide, and did not intend the judiciary to imply, a cause of action for extracontractual
damages caused by improper or untimely processing of benefit claims.”).
446
See infra discussion I.(D), II.(A).
447
Id.; DERFNER & WOLF, supra note 193.
448
DERFNER & WOLF, supra note 193.
449
See AM. CANCER SOC’Y, supra note 201, at 22–23.
450
See What is the ‘Loss of Chance’ Doctrine in Medical Malpractice Cases?, POWERS & SANTOLA, LLP,
https://www.powers-santola.com/blog/loss-of-
chance/#:~:text=Under%20the%20loss%20of%20chance,is%20harmed%20by%20the%20disease.
[https://perma.cc/X9KP-FTAE] (last visited Feb. 21, 2024).
451
See 29 C.F.R. §§ 2590.715-2719 (2022); see also ROSENBAUM ET AL., supra note 423.
452
ROSENBAUM ET AL., supra note 423.
806 UNIVERSITY OF LOUISVILLE LAW REVIEW [Vol. 62:3
453
ROSENBAUM ET AL., supra note 423.
454
See RESTATEMENT (THIRD) OF TORTS § 3(e) (AM. L. INST. 1997).
455
Id.
456
See infra discussion sections (I)(D), (II)(B).
457
But see 29 C.F.R. §§ 2590.715-2719 (2022); but see 29 U.S.C. § 1132 (2022).
458
See infra discussion section (II)(B).
459
Id.; Vukadin, supra note 121, at 12–13.
460
See Aldana, supra note 417. See generally Anna Chorniy et al., Regulatory Review Time and Pharmaceutical
Research and Development, 30 HEALTH ECON. no. 1, 113 (Jan. 2021).
461
See Chorniy et al., supra note 460 (detailing contemporary financial issues in pharmaceutical research and
development, which lead to high prescription drug costs). One of the primary effects of high research and
development costs is that it makes pharmaceutical companies capital intensive. For pharmaceutical companies with
the traditional incentive to find treatments, there is an incentive to develop innovative treatments only if there is a
subsequent profit sufficient to justify not investing that capital in other market sectors. This makes the barrier
finding treatments for rare disease or creative solutions less desirable, or possibly untenable, from the perspective
of a traditional pharmaceutical company. However, for an insurance company, the incentives are reversed: its
incentive is to have people have as little and as inexpensive care as possible by denying claims and refusing to pay.
2024] Illusory Remedies 807
2. Criminal penalties
3. Enforcement
462
29 U.S.C. 1131 (2022).
463
Id.; 29 U.S.C. 1132 (2022).
464
4 ARKIN, BUSINESS CRIME: CRIMINAL LIABILITY OF THE BUSINESS COMMUNITY ¶16.01 (Matthew Bender
ed., 2022).
465
Id.
466
See infra discussion section (II)(C).
467
Id.
468
See generally YELLEN ET AL., supra note 267.
469
See What We Do, SEC. EXCH. COMM’N, https://www.sec.gov/about/what-we-do [https://perma.cc/C2YC-
EE94] (last visited Mar. 1, 2023).
470
See generally YELLEN ET AL. supra note 267; see infra discussion section (II)(C).
471
See DERFNER & WOLF, supra note 193 (discussing the ban of awarding attorneys’ fees under ERISA as an
obstacle to recovery).
808 UNIVERSITY OF LOUISVILLE LAW REVIEW [Vol. 62:3
472
See Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) of 1974, 29 U.S.C. § 1144.
473
29 U.S.C. § 1144(b)(2)(B); 29 U.S.C. § 1144(b)(2)(A).
474
29 U.S.C. § 1144 (b)(2)(B); Morrissey, supra note 398.
475
29 U.S.C. § 1001.
476
See Aetna Health Inc. v. Davila, 542 U.S. 200, 201 (2004).
477
See Gobeille v. Liberty Mut. Ins. Co., 577 U.S. 312, 323 (2016); and see CARMAN ET AL., supra note 109.
478
William W. Buzbee, Asymmetrical Regulation: Risk, Preemption, and The Floor/Ceiling Distinction, 82
N.Y.UNIV. L. REV. 1547, 1558 (Dec. 2007).
479
See BARKER & KENT, supra note 10, at § 8.04(d).
480
See generally McCarran-Ferguson Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 1011–1015; see Humana Inc. v. Forsyth, 525 U.S. 299,
308 (1999) (noting that, because the McCarran-Ferguson Act gives the sates powers in a reverse preemption
scheme, modern implicit preemption would not apply to this Act under the field preemption doctrine but may still
apply under conflict preemption if there is a direct conflict between the Act and state statutes where meeting both
standards is impossible).
481
Id.
2024] Illusory Remedies 809
D. Market Stabilization
482
See discussion infra Sections II.D, III.A-B, & IV.B-C. If insurance firms are no longer able to elude
accountability, they will likely become less profitable, and these costs would be passed on to consumers.
483
ABRAHAM & SCHWARCZ, supra note 85, at 383-384.
484
See infra discussion section (IV).
485
See generally BARKER & KENT, supra note 10, at § 8.04; see discussion infra Section IV.
486
BARKER & KENT, supra note 10, at § 8.04.
487
See infra discussion sections (I)(E), (II).
488
See Steve Cicala et al., Regulating Markups in US Health Insurance, 11 AM. ECON. J. OF APPLIED ECON.,
71, 71–72 (2019).
489
Id.
490
Id.
491
Id.
810 UNIVERSITY OF LOUISVILLE LAW REVIEW [Vol. 62:3
492
See Matthew Fiedler, Designing A Public Option That Would Reduce Health Care Provider Prices, UCS
LEONARD D. SHAEFFER CTR. FOR HEALTH POL’Y & ECON. & BROOKINGS (2021),
https://www.brookings.edu/essay/designing-a-public-option-that-would-reduce-health-care-provider-prices/
[https://perma.cc/77WQ-QR8B].
493
Id.; see also Cicala et al., supra note 488.
494
See Cicala et al., supra note 488.
495
See generally STEPHEN DUCKETT, THE AUSTRALIAN HEALTH CARE SYSTEM (6th ed. 2022).
496
Id.
497
Id.
498
Id.
499
See Cynthia Cox et al., Nine Changes to Watch in ACA Open Enrollment 2023, KAISER FAM. FOUND. (Oct.
27, 2022) https://www.kff.org/policy-watch/nine-changes-to-watch-in-open-enrollment-2023/
[https://perma.cc/ZU88-4YUR].
500
Id.; see infra discussion (I)(B).
501
Cox et al., supra note 499.
502
Id.; see Cicala et al., supra note 488.
503
Cox et al., supra note 499; ABRAHAM & SCHWARCZ, supra note 85, at 667.
2024] Illusory Remedies 811
CONCLUSION
ERISA has created an untenable healthcare landscape by allowing
insurers to profiteer off a completely asymmetrical legal and procedural
scheme. Mechanisms of accountability have been hollowed out, leaving only
an illusory bulwark for consumers and a very real wall guarding insurers’
profits.504 As a result, insurers have a license to steal from over half the
country that seems to be completely un-tracked.505
Currently, insurers are immune from claims of bad faith.506 If caught,
they only pay for what they promised in the first place.507 It is unknown how
many claims are actually denied annually, but, if the CMS system where
claim administrators are not nearly as conflicted as they are in fully-funded
insurance plans deny around 18% of claims annually, it belies rationality to
think a less monitored and more conflicted claim administrator would deny
fewer than 18% of claims.508 Consider the volume of 20% of claims
generated by 178,000,000 people.509 If the CMS data holds for ERISA plan
appeals, then less than 1% of that massive number is appealed.510 Even a
generous margin of error is given, say between 0.5% and 5% of claims are
appealed, or otherwise circumvented, that still leaves 95% or more denied
claims left alone.511 How many of those are for diagnostic treatments?512
In addition to lacking accountability through lacking data on claims
denials, insurers are faced with perverse incentives: when held liable for the
tiny fraction of claims they face, they are only subjected to paying some
defense attorney’s fees, which pales in comparison to the cost of a thirty-
year-old, like Dawn Smith, who would have otherwise beat her first cancer
504
See Cicala et al., supra note 488; see infra discussion section II.
505
See infra discussion section II.(C).
506
See Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) of 1974, 29 U.S.C. § 1132; and see Mass. Mut.
Life Ins. Co. v. Russell, 473 U.S. 134, 148 (1985).
507
Karen Pollitz et al, supra note 43; see infra discussion section II.(A).
508
Karen Pollitz et al, supra note 43; see infra discussion section II.(C).
509
Karen Pollitz et al, supra note 43; see infra discussion section II.(C).
510
Karen Pollitz et al, supra note 43.
511
Id.
512
U.S. DEP’T. OF LAB. & U.S. DEP’T. OF HEALTH AND HUM. SERV., supra note 45 (finding claim denials to
diagnostic testing where more commonly frivolous than others).
812 UNIVERSITY OF LOUISVILLE LAW REVIEW [Vol. 62:3
diagnosis.513 Even by delaying the process of care, insurers can cut a lot of
working years off of a claimant’s life. Once someone is too sick to work, the
common trend is to leave the ERISA market and to enter into either Medicare
or Medicaid.514 Even if insureds stay on their ERISA plan for one reason or
another, one round of hospice is a lot cheaper than a lifetime of chronic illness
or multiple rounds of catastrophic care.515 Belief in a comforting illusion, that
other predatory markets only normalized because industry leaders had
sudden changes of heart, will not fix our deranged healthcare market.516
Fixing our national issues regarding access to healthcare will take
deliberate, forceful, and thoughtful interventions.517 We can start by
immediately instituting a comprehensive tracking system for denials of care
and, ideally, by eventually removing civil damages immunities, selectively
repealing express preemption under ERISA, and controlling for the increase
in price that will cause for care. If we can do that, the illusion of the redress
for wronged beneficiaries might be dispelled, stirring the sedated legislators,
so they can get to the business of stripping immunities and holding insurers
to do no harm. So, hopefully, people like Dawn can focus more on acquiring
essential treatment and diagnoses, rather than on being consumed with
wrongful claim denials from their insurers, in order to receive the care that
they so clearly deserve.518
513
See AM. CANCER SOC’Y, supra note 201; see Bryant, supra note 1.
514
See AM. CANCER SOC’Y, supra note 201, at 8.
515
Id. at 23.
516
See Tim Devaney, Dem Bill Cracks Down on Payday Lenders, THE HILL (Apr. 7, 2016, 1:52 PM EST),
https://thehill.com/regulation/legislation/275499-dem-bill-cracks-down-on-payday-lenders/
[https://perma.cc/DW66-RMKN].
517
See, e.g., Fiedler, supra note 492; see, e.g., Cicala et al., supra note 488.
518
See Bryant, supra note 1.