85 Miss LJ697
85 Miss LJ697
85 Miss LJ697
Citations:
Please note: citations are provided as a general guideline. Users should consult their preferred
citation format's style manual for proper citation formatting.
Provided by:
University of Glasgow Library
-- Your use of this HeinOnline PDF indicates your acceptance of HeinOnline's Terms and
Conditions of the license agreement available at
https://heinonline.org/HOL/License
-- The search text of this PDF is generated from uncorrected OCR text.
-- To obtain permission to use this article beyond the scope of your license, please use:
Copyright Information
2014 NATIONAL LAWYERS CONVENTION
Moderator:
697
698 MISSISSIPPI LAW JOURNAL [VOL. 85:3
examples, it's used to argue for tightening certain rules, for low-
threshold, ten percent poison pills, for maintaining staggered
boards, which institutional investors have long been resisting, and
to advocate for changes that would limit the rights of short-term
shareholders. And, in particular, activist engagements disclaim
it's used as the basis for an approach that is advocated for boards
to follow. What is suggested is that, by and large, boards should
"circle the wagons" and view activists as an adversary that the
best outcome would be if it could be defeated.
Now, this is a claim that, in our view, requires testing. If you
take the view that market prices are efficient, which John Macey
here subscribes to, then you can rule out this view on the basis of
your assumptions about market efficiency because, if the stock
prices in the short term fully reflect long-term values, then this
problem goes away. But what we are doing in our work is we are
willing to accept that markets sometimes might be inefficient, but
even if they are inefficient, as I show in a paper published last
year in the Columbia Law Review, it doesn't follow that this
problem exists. It could exist, but it wouldn't necessarily exist
because there are effects going in both directions, and, therefore,
the short-termism claim, the myopic activism claim is really a
testable, empirical position, and even though this claim has been
around and has been put forward forcefully for about three
decades, the people supporting it have not provided empirical
support.
Last year, Marty Lipton and I had a debate at The
Conference Board in New York, and following this debate,
Wachtell Lipton issued a memo authored by Marty in which he
challenged me, kind of accepting the need for empirical testing,
that the important question for resolving the different views
between him and me with respect to hedge fund activists. The
important question, Marty said, was to study for companies that
are the subject of hedge fund activism and remain independent.
What is the impact on the operational performance and stock price
performance relative to the benchmark after a 24-month period?
So he was urging that empirical work be done that doesn't look
just at short-term consequences but looks at stock price and
operating performance after a 24-month period. And Mike
Weisbach and I, we took up this challenge, and we undertook a
2016]1 THE SHORT- TERMISM DEBATE 703
[Applause.]
problem with money managers who are agents for other people's
money as well.
What I'd like to do, though, rather than trying to assess or
critique Lucian's methodology, is to say let's assume that Lucian is
right, that this study and all of his observations are completely
accurate and that, on average, the five-year performance of about
2,000 companies that experienced activist activity from 1994 to
2007, that those companies outperformed the market over a three-
year and five-year period thereafter. Assuming all that is true, I'm
not really sure what it proves. Lucian talked about causality, and
the paper actually concedes that causality is a harder thing to
prove. But let's take one hypothesis as to what might explain that,
assuming that Lucian's numbers are true, and it's a hypothesis
that, I think, has some basis in what I've seen in terms of the way
companies are run.
Let's assume that companies tend to underperform when
they're spending a lot of money on investments for the future.
They ramp up their CAPEX spending, they ramp up their
investment in long-term R&D, and that hurts earnings in the near
term. So for some period of time those companies are
underperforming. Let's assume that those companies are more
likely to be targeted by activists, and I think that's one of the
points that Lucian's paper does make, which he didn't cover in his
presentation, but that underperforming companies tend to be
disproportionately targeted by activists. And let's assume that the
companies respond to the activist activity by reversing course,
cutting back on investment, cutting back on CAPEX. They will
experience, for some period of time, an increase in earnings and
an increase in performance, and perhaps a corresponding increase
in stock price, and you can sustain that for some period. It's not
black and white. You don't suddenly flip a switch from one to the
other, but you can sustain that performance after you've been
investing for some period of time and underperforming. You can
sustain outperformance for some period of time, even a three-year
or five-year time period. Lucian views three to five years as long-
term. I don't view that as long-term. I think long-term is much
longer than three to five years.
So if the scenario I just hypothesized is what's happening,
then even if Lucian's numbers are correct, it doesn't mean that the
2016] THE SHORT- TERMISM DEBATE 709
activity is healthy in the long run, and that's just one example. I
could probably come up with other examples of what might
explain the numbers, if they're true, that don't result in the policy
conclusions that Lucian reaches from his numbers.
I think equally importantly, from my perspective in advising
companies and boards for quite a long time, the problem of short-
termism goes way beyond activism and activist interventions.
Really, every publicly traded company is subject to what I think of
as the tyranny of quarterly earnings. If you miss your quarterly
earnings, you get punished, and that's just a fact of life for every
public company, and that's been true before activists. I think
activists may exacerbate the issue but it's an issue that overlays
every board and every management of a public company, and they
respond to it. If you talk to managers, if you talk to boards, they
do want to invest for the long term and they do want to do what's
right for the company, but they also feel constrained and feel the
need to manage within the constraints of meeting their quarterly
earnings, and that drives a lot of activity that I think is not
healthy for companies in the long term.
Take one example. Last year Michael Dell took Dell, Inc.,
private, and in the interest of full disclosure we represented
Michael in that transaction. And the motivating factor in his
decision to take the company private was that he felt he could not
take, as a public company, the steps that he needed to take to
transform the company for the future. He basically said, "What I
need to do here will hurt short-term earnings, it'll punish the
stock price, and we won't be allowed to get to the long-term
because somebody will come in and intervene before we can get
there." So he spent the entire year waging a battle to take the
company private and endured a lot of criticism. People said he was
doing it for the money. I mean, he's worth enough that he's not
doing it for the money. He was doing it for the future of the
company, and there are other examples of people taking
companies private for exactly that reason.
A few minutes ago I said I didn't feel qualified to critique the
methodology of Lucian's study but there is one observation I do
feel qualified to make, because it's essentially definitionally true,
which is that you can't measure the world that might have been,
By that I mean you can't measure the world in which companies
710 MISSISSIPPI LAW JOURNAL [VOL. 85:3
[Laughter.]
rather have more time for reflection and repose." The controversy
goes deeper than that though. It's also a question about how much
power should management and the board of directors have over
the corporations that they're entrusted to run on behalf of the
shareholders. I don't think that shareholders have a lot of power
right now. I'm not saying it's a bad thing. I'm just saying it's a
descriptive matter. It is the law in every state, most notably, and
importantly, Delaware, that the business and affairs of a
corporation are run by or under the direction of the corporation's
board of directors. And so all that this debate really is about is
around the edges, should management really be able to deprive
shareholders of a potential to have an activist investor come in
and agitate for change in ways that management finds
uncomfortable or maybe a little embarrassing or things like that?
So, really, what this debate is about is accountability.
Now, I want to talk a little bit about the counter-factual, and
make three very quick points. One is, the study that Lucian and
his co-author did, and that Steve is criticizing basically says, look,
an activist investor comes in, and when the activist investor comes
in there's an immediate and very significant, in the twenty
percent range, increase in the stock of the company that is the
subject of the activist investor's investment. And then, at the
behest of Marty Lipton, who now says he doesn't like data, Lucian
went out and collected all this data, and says, "Well, the share
price stays up for three or five years." Now we're told, "Well, these
aren't good measures. They're the only measures available, and
three to five years is not a particularly good amount of time. Let's
look at a longer period of time."
There are two issues I have with that. Number one is, this is
not true, but let's assume that after a three-year period of big-time
share increase after an activist investor comes in, let's say the
share price of the target company plummets to twenty percent
below the activist investor price. I think that would be a bad thing
but it would in no way cause me to think that, gee, we should
somehow exalt incumbent management over activist investors?
Why? Well, the reason is very simple. If I'm a shareholder in a
target company and somebody comes in and purchases shares and
causes the value of my equity to go up in a very short period of
time by twenty percent, and even if I think the share price may
2016] THE SHORT- TERMISM DEBATE 713
[Applause.]
Columbia Law Review article from last year), and it may be that
these people are not all concerned about quite the same problem.
In most cases, they're motivated by what they think of as clear
examples of activist shareholders, along with the market more
generally, pushing boards of directors to engage in short-term
rather than long-term projects, and they see this as being bad.
And they certainly start off with nothing like Professor Bebchuk's
evidence, but sort of an intuition or an impression that something
is wrong here.
From that, it's not immediately clear exactly what the
problem is. In a very interesting section of Professor Bebchuk's
paper-the section I think is actually the more important and
revealing-he has to take about three or four pages to nail down
precisely what the supposed problem is before he can go out and
do an empirical study on the issue as he finally defines it. So he
has to do a bit of interpretation on what the problem is in order to
formulate a proposition that is sufficiently specific to be proved or
disproved by statistical, empirical evidence. And what I'm going to
suggest is that the interpretation that Professor Bebchuk uses,
which is undoubtedly one that many people actually have in mind,
is nevertheless not the only interpretation of the alleged problem
with short-termism. In fact, there is another interpretation of
what the problem is, and this interpretation is not touched one
way or the other by Professor Bebchuk's statistical analysis.
Moreover, I think that this interpretation probably better captures
what the best informed people who worry about short-termism are
actually concerned about.
As you'll recall, Professor Bebchuk's interpretation includes
the idea that activist shareholders, along with the market
generally, force boards of directors to undertake actions that cause
share prices to go up in the short term (however you define that)
but down in the long term (however you define that), and he very
rightly points out that this is only possible if markets are
informationally inefficient in some pretty important ways. For, if
markets are informationally efficient and if this problem really
exists, it's impossible to see why, if we all know the price is going
to go down in the long term, the price doesn't also go down in the
short term as well. If we all know the price is going down
tomorrow, that means the price is going to go down today, so the
716 MISSISSIPPI LAW JOURNAL [VOL. 85:3
problem can't exist. In Professor Bebchuk's formulation-and as I
say, this is the formulation that a lot of people do have in mind-
there is an assumption that the market is, in this very important
and systematic way, inefficient.
The interpretation I'm about to give you is one that's
consistent with the market being efficient in all relevant ways. So
what is this other possible interpretation? I ask you to take a step
back and imagine that there is a given investment and two
investors each considering whether or not to make the investment.
What should they do? Well, the first thing they have to do is they
have to determine what they think the future cash flows of this
investment will be. Let's assume they agree completely on what
those cash flows are likely to be.
The next thing they have to do is discount those cash flows
back to present value to figure out how much they should pay for
them today. So, what rate should they use? Well, that depends on
the riskiness of the cash flows. Let's say they agree on that (you
can imagine them agreeing on the variance or standard deviation
of the expected cash flows, for example). Do the two investors then
necessarily agree on the discount rate? Answer-no, because they
might have different risk tolerances. Let's assume they have the
same risk tolerance as well. At this point, will they agree on the
discount rate? The answer is again no. And one of the reasons that
this will be, the primary one, I think, is that different people have
different values for the pure time value of money. Some people
want their money faster than others.
Everyone prefers money faster rather than slower, but for
some people the preference is stronger and for other people the
preference is weaker. Because of this, the people who want their
money back faster will tend to use high discount rates. The people
who are willing to get their money back later will use lower
discount rates. So even when people agree completely on the
objective characteristics (expected values, standard deviations) of
the future cash flows related to the investment, they might value
it differently if they have different discount rates, because of when
they want their money back and what their preferences are, how
much they're willing to sacrifice today in order to get a dollar
tomorrow.
2016] THE SHORT- TERMISM DEBATE 717
[Laughter.]
time. You did two to five. Why don't you look five to eight?
Probably if we didn't find anything there you would say, look from
ten to twenty.
So the reasons are the following. One is CEOs right now have
an average tenure which is not higher than five years. If you take
just an inside, on average, given those numbers, they probably
have, from this point on, a horizon that isn't longer than three
years. So the idea that if we insulated the CEO, and the CEO has
a horizon of four years, you would get someone that focuses ten
years from now. It's probably not there. More importantly, I think
we have every reason to believe that this effect doesn't show up
after five years. It can be done, but if you really believed that you
have this effect, then, Steve, you could become even wealthier
than as a partner at Wachtell Lipton. You can just have an index
fund that takes the shorts companies five years after activism,
and if you are right that there is a decline, that ETF would be
better for us to invest for retirement than an ETF that holds
companies five years.
Now, nobody in the market is trying to do this, which
suggests to me that there isn't really any significant belief in this
world that five years out there is a reversal. But if you want we
can go and do this. The only thing that I would like you to do say
to this wonderful audience is if we do-because Martin says the
important question is to look after two years. So my sense was if
the numbers come out differently, that might lead him to refine
his views somewhat. Now, when I listen to you it seems that you
remain kind of completely with the same view, even though the
numbers came differently. If you tell me, if you look at the
numbers from five years to ten years, and if you don't see a
reversal, that would affect my view, we'll be happy to do the study
for you.
STEVEN A. ROSENBLUM: I don't know what the study
would show if you did it because every study you've done supports
your world view and your ideology, so that's why I'm a skeptic
about statistics. I concede that I don't have the economics
background to attack the methodology. I think I was trying to
make a different point, which is that even if the studies are right,
there's just no doubt in my mind-and you can say it's anecdotal
and I've only seen a small subset, and you can do a study of a
722 MISSISSIPPI LAW JOURNAL [VOL. 85:3
[Laughter.]
724 MISSISSIPPI LAW JOURNAL [VOL. 85:3
[Laughter.]
that's the sole basis for setting policy and I think your
unwillingness to go out into the real world and understand how
businesses are run and what people are thinking is equally subject
to criticism as your criticism of us for not accepting your studies at
face value.
PROFESSOR LUCIAN A. BEBCHUK: There is a
marketplace of ideas in financial economics, so when I write a
paper, there are a lot of financial economists who are interested in
publishing papers, and if you see there are many issues Corporate
Finance where people are coming up with mixed evidence and
evidence on both sides, and people are working on those issues. I
understand that you don't find my study, but doesn't it bother you
that there isn't a study which is the opposite conclusion, and does
it bother you, or wouldn't you want to try to facilitate people who
would study this? Because Martin, in his memo, said the
important question was not what business leaders think but the
important question is what is the effect on stock returns and
operating performance. Those are hard numbers.
JUDGE E. NORMAN VEASEY: Before you answer that,
Jon wants to say something.
PROFESSOR JONATHAN R. MACEY: I'm learning a lot
and enjoying myself tremendously. I would like to focus on this
comment about should we get rid of quarterly reports and move to
some other timing sequence for reporting such that we don't focus
people very much on the short term, and the first thing I thought
to myself is, this would be a great study because we could take a
bunch of companies that did only annual financial reportings and
some that did quarterly, but we're never going to be able to do
that because the companies that only did this annually would be
in violation of the federal securities laws. But we do have a set,
which are companies that are closely held-limited liability
companies, companies that aren't subject to the securities laws'
reporting requirements; they're only subject to state law, and
state law only requires annual reporting, but we observe that
these companies, nevertheless, provide their investors with
quarterly reports. That is, people aren't willing to invest in
companies and wait a year prior to looking at financial results.
That, to me, is some evidence that the quarterly reporting system
is superior.
726 MISSISSIPPI LAW JOURNAL [VOL. 85:3
anyone who thinks that, really, strategy is the key piece here that
nobody has really been talking about?
JUDGE E. NORMAN VEASEY: Well, let's start with
Professor Macey is answering that.
PROFESSOR JONATHAN R. MACEY: Well, two things.
One, with respect to your chess premise, the fact is that we
observe in chess, people resign before games are over, and it must
be the case, because they don't resign before the game starts, that
the new positions of the pieces on the board as the game
progresses is providing them with some information about the
quality of their strategy and the quality of their opponent's
strategy, or to put it differently, share prices reflect the market's
assessment, i.e., an unbiased assessment, of the qualities, of the
strategies that management is deploying as they go about running
the company. And the debate is about the market's efficacy and
accuracy with respect to a comparison between the market's
ability to evaluate long-term strategy versus short-term strategy.
Something that Robert just said, it was completely
devastating to the position he's taking, that somehow that
managers are focused maybe too much on the short term, is that
we have an acknowledgment that when we look at, when we value
companies, a very large portion of that value is valuations about
how much wealth a company is going to contribute in the long
term; that is, what are the values of the business five years out.
Those are assessments about strategy because no one is talking
about the breakup value of these companies. Nobody is talking
about taking the assets and just selling them. People are talking
about valuing them as an ongoing concern which means valuing
the strategy that's being used in the deployment of those assets,
and the question is are share prices a legitimate mechanism for
evaluating strategy, and people obviously disagree here. I kind of
think yes, and other people think maybe not so much.
JUDGE E. NORMAN VEASEY: Okay. We have fifteen
minutes to go. We have four more people, at least four more people
who want to ask questions. Please, sir, go ahead.
ATTENDEE: Thank you. I haven't heard anything in this
discussion so far about the impact of corporate taxation and
capital gains taxation, and I raise that because I think it's
generally accepted that not only corporations, but investors are
730 MISSISSIPPI LAW JOURNAL [VOL. 85:3
[Applause.]
736 MISSISSIPPI LAW JOURNAL [VOL. 85:3