Hu Yunxi 2017 Researchpaper
Hu Yunxi 2017 Researchpaper
Hu Yunxi 2017 Researchpaper
Yunxi Hu
8586728
Ottawa, Ontario
December 2017
ABSTRACT
The paper is an empirical study on the relationship between economic growth and
pollution, using the data from the province of Sichuan, China. Three pollutants –
industrial wastewater, industrial solid wastes, and industrial gas waste – are considered.
The results – obtained from the Johansen co-integration test and the Granger causality
test – indicate that both industrial wastewater and industrial solid waste have a negative
1
1. INTRODUCTION
In an economy, the production uses energy, labor, capital, and raw materials to produce
goods and services. The environment plays an important role in the economy. In the
production of goods and services, raw materials, such as metals, minerals, water, tree,
etc. are extracted from the environment. Energy resources – coal, oil, natural gas – are
also extracted from the environment required to transform raw materials into goods and
acts to provide many ecosystem services, such as filtering air pollution, sequestering
carbon, and protect against flood risk. It also provides us with recreational activities and
education, and life quality possible. It is also vital for the wellbeing of the economy and
its citizens in both developed and developing world. (Richard Price, 2010, p.12).
According to the first law of thermodynamics, matter can never be destroyed or created:
the materials and energy that do not go into the final product are returned to the
environment as wastes. The wastes can also come from consumption. When people
drive cars, the exhaust from the cars adds to the stock of greenhouse gases in the
waste products.
With the development of society and economic growth, the attendant environment
pollution has become a serious issue. There are those who argue that Industrialization
2
and urbanization eventually leads to environmental degradation (Peng, 2006), while
others contend that economic growth and environment quality interact with each other
and will be promoting each other mutually (Beckerman, 1992). No clear-cut conclusion
has emerged from the debate, and the issue still needs to be studied further.
There is no denying that economic growth brings many benefits. However, the ever-
growth without the degradation of the ecosystems and the depletion of the natural
resources. As a result of human activities, the level of carbon dioxide (𝐶𝑂2 ) in the
atmosphere has being rising dramatically, and the world is facing the great challenge of
keeping the rise in the global temperature below two degrees. Researchers have found
that 15 out of 24 ecosystems were used unsustainably, and the consumption of natural
resources such as metals and minerals was rising at an increasing rate (Millennium
Ecosystem Assessment, 2003). Some take the view that the cost of inaction would be
far greater than the cost of action now, and using environmental resources sustainably
is consistent with the economic growth. Others think that the stocks of natural resources
are finite, and this places a limit on the extent to which the economy could expand.
There is a large body of empirical studies on the relationship between income and some
studies typically link GDP per capita – the dependent variable – to three independent
variables – industrial waste water, industrial solid waste, and industrial gas waste –
3
which represent the environmental quality. The World Bank Development Report (1992)
relates the percentage of the population that has no access to safe water or urban
sanitation to the level of income by using internal World Bank data and carries out an
analysis on the relationship between income and municipal solid waste per capita, using
OECD and World Resources Institute estimates for 39 countries in 1985. Seldon (1992)
uses a similar method to investigate the relationship between the estimated rate of
emission of several air pollutants with the country’s national income. These studies tend
to find an inverted “U” relationship between environmental quality and level of income.
This paper is an empirical study on the relationship between pollution and economic
growth for Sichuan, a province of China. The main employs reliable data and a common
and environmental quality for a broad set of environmental indicators. We use the
available data from the “Statistical Yearbook of Sichuan Province”, 1 which tracks
these measures are far from comprehensive, they at least represent the largest part of
environmental pollution. The main results that come out of our analysis is that indicators
of environmental quality no longer exhibit an inverted “U” relationship with GDP per
capita: industrial water waste and industrial solid waste show an “N” relationship with
1
Source: http://www.sc.stats.gov.cn/tjcbw/tjnj/
4
GDP per capita, and industrial gas waste exhibits no linear or nonlinear relationship with
The paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, the most prominent hypothesis linking
(EKC) – is presented. Most empirical studies on the linkages between economic growth
and environment are dedicated to confirming or rejecting the EKC. Section 3 is a short
review of the empirical literature on the relationships between pollutants and economic
test as well as the Granger causality test are presented in Section 6. In this section, the
main results of the paper are discussed. Section 7 contains some concluding remarks.
The data and the results of some tests are relegated to several appendices.
In the 1950s, the American economist Kuznets (1955) examined the relationship
between the economic growth (level of income per capita) and income inequality, and
drew the conclusion that as the economy embarks on its development path, income
inequality would firstly widen, and then gradually narrows down after the economy
reaches a certain stage. That is, income inequality exhibits an inverted U shape, when
Forty years later, another American economist, Grossman and Krueger (1991)
suggested an inverted U-shape relationship between GDP per capita and many
5
pollutants by analyzing panel data from 42 countries in the world. The intuitive logic
behind the EKC can be explained as follows. At low levels of income, the limited
income is devoted to meeting the basic needs of the population. As income rises, and
basic needs have been fulfilled, the quality of the environment – a particular type of
good – might yield more utility than an additional unit of consumption, and resources will
ensuing consequence that environmental quality now rise with economic growth.
The environmental Kuznets curve (EKC) – named after Kuznets, but not developed by
development and environment quality. The hypothesis asserts that pollution rises in the
early stages of economic development, but the trend is reversed after GDP per capital
surpasses a certain level. Figure 1 depicts the EKC, when the level of environmental
6
Figure 1.-Environmental Kuznets Curve (inverted “U” shape)
3. LITERATURE REVIEW
Most empirical studies on the linkages between environment and economic growth
Shafik and Bandyopadhyay (1992) discovered that emissions of sulfur dioxide (𝑆𝑂2 )
originally increased and then reduced as income per capital rises, confirming the EKC
rising income, found an inverted U-shape relationship between the two variables.
Seldon and Song (1994) confirmed the existence of the EKC by analyzing the
relationship between 𝐶𝑂2, 𝑆𝑂2, 𝑁𝑂2 , 𝐶𝑂, and suspended particular matter. Guo and Li
7
(2010) in conducted an empirical study on the linkages between pollutants and
economic growth, using panel data on 29 provinces of China, and concluded that
industrial solid waste (ISW) and GDP per capita were in line with the EKC.
Not all the empirical studies on the linkages between economic growth and environment
support the EKC hypothesis. Zhou, Yuan, and Xue (2009) carried out a study on Shanxi
province, using the industrial wastewater and GDP per capita, and the results they
obtained showed that the two variables exhibit a stable long-run N-shape relationship.
The same results were found by Ding (2012), who used data in on Guangxi Province.
Wang (2013), in a study on a costal area economy and marine environmental pollution,
found an N-shaped curve. Figure 2 depicts the N-shaped relationship between per
8
Gene and Alan (1995) used environmental indicators, such as urban air pollution, the
oxygen regime state in river, fecal contamination of river, and contamination of river by
economic growth and the environment. They found that environmental quality does not
steadily deteriorate with economic growth. Furthermore, economic growth first brings
deterioration to most indicators, and then improvement after that. The turning points of
different indicators vary, but in general, they are around the GDP per capita of $8000;
Shaik Feroz (2014) formulated a VAR model and used the variance decomposition
indicators and GDP per capita in western China from 1992 to 2010. This researcher
concludes that economic growth is a major cause of environmental pollution and that
there is also a reverse effect. However, the reverse effect is not immediate, but has a
lag. In addition, the variance decomposition shows that economic growth has little
explanatory power for the different kinds of the environmental pollution indicators. The
paper shows that the original EKC hypothesis of EKC cannot be generalized to the
global level since the empirical evidence only shows the results for developed countries.
What is even more striking is that there is no correlation between higher levels of
income and lower gas emissions (including six atmospheric pollutants in Spain), except
for 𝑆𝑂2 . The author argues that the relationship between income level and types of
9
In a paper entitled “Economic Growth and Environmental Pollution in Myanmar: An
Analysis of Environmental Kuznets Curve,” Aung et. Al (2007) tested the validity of the
EKC, and investigated the short-run as well as the long-run relationships between
indicators are 𝐶𝑂2 , 𝐶𝐻4 , 𝑁2 𝑂, and the economic growth indicators are GDP. The authors
also considered other proxies, such as trade intensity and financial openness,
urbanization and structural breaks in the country. The authors used annual data in
Myanmar over the period 1970-2014, and carried out the analysis using an
autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL) model. The empirical results show an absence of
the EKC for 𝐶𝑂2 and GDP, while evidence of the EKC is found for 𝐶𝐻4 and 𝑁2 𝑂. The
authors finally concluded that financial openness and trade liberation will contribute to
According to this author, the developing countries are at an early stage on the EKC
because developing countries desire economic growth and tend to consume cheaper
sources of energy. Massive infrastructures, such as roads and rail tracks, are in heavy
development are substantially energy intensive. And the concluded that compelling
10
George E. Halkos (2003), in a paper entitled “Growth and Environmental Pollution:
Empirical Evidence from China,” investigated the relationship between 𝐶𝑂2 and GDP
per capita by using time series data from 1960 to 2006, with additional variables in trade
and agriculture, industry and services sectors. The results indicate an inverted “U”
shape relationship between 𝐶𝑂2 and GDP per capita and that trade is also a
determinant of pollution.
Luo et al. (2014), in a research paper entitled ”Relationship Between Air Pollutants and
Economic Development of the Provincial Capital Cities in China during the Past
Decade,” chose GRP per capita (Gross Regional Product per capita) as economic
indicators, and 𝑃𝑀10 , 𝑆𝑂2 , 𝑁𝑂2 and the air pollution index (API) as air pollutants
indicators to find out if there is an EKC between the economic indicator and the
pollutant indicators. The analysis was conducted by using the 31 provinces’ data over
the time period 2003-2012. The results of the analysis indicated that three main
industries have a quadratic relationship with 𝑁𝑂2 , but a negative relationship with 𝑃𝑀10
and 𝑆𝑂2 . The API showed an inverted U-shape curve with the GRP per capita which
Economic growth in China,” Zhang Jiansheng and Li Qing (2011) investigated the
relationship of environmental pollution and economic growth, using the data during the
time period 1980-2009 in China. The final results are: industrial wastewater (IWW) and
11
GDP per capita have an “N” shape relationship with GDP per capita, while industrial gas
waste (IGW) and industrial solid waste (ISW) display a “U” shape relationship with GDP
per capita. The authors argued that the economic development has been achieved at
the cost of environmental degradation since the time of China’s reform and opening-up
policy. The authors suggested that China’s government should take measures to deal
with the conflict between environment and economic growth to achieve sustainable
development.
It would be common in developed countries, which have already passed the turning
point, to support economic growth and avoid environmental regulations. However, early
likely to harm the economy. Here are several reasons whether EKC hypothesis is
effective in policy making. First, EKC analysis is typically based on limited set of
pollutants so the conclusions made by these analyses cannot be applied to all types of
the Ecological Footprint, which is a measure of the pressure that man places on the
environment, unless energy use is removed from the measure (Caviglia-Harris et al,
2009). Furthermore, EKC relationship is strong when impacts are local. When impacts
are global, when income rises, carbon and greenhouse gas emissions increase, even in
the developed countries. Second, the supporting evidence has been found less reliable
than previously thought (Stern, 2004): EKC’s predictions of the relationship between
income and pollution are heavily influenced by the mathematical model adopted
12
(Millimet et al, 2003). Third, the cost of improving environmental quality and repairing
damage after the turning point may possibly be higher than the cost of preventing the
damage or undertaking the mitigation earlier. For example, the cost of avoiding the
pollution of a waterway is much less than the cost of cleanup after the damage has
been done. Fourth, there is evidence showing that similar level of wealth may perform
An economy produces a consumption good from four inputs: capital (K), labor (L),
energy (E), and materials (M). Following Stokey (1998), we assume that the output of
the consumption good at any time t is given by the following Cobb-Douglas production
function:
where 𝑌(𝑡) is the output at time 𝑡; 𝐴 is the total factor productivity a; 𝐾(𝑡) is the capital
input at time 𝑡; 𝛼, 0 < 𝛼 < 1, is a parameter; 𝐿(𝑡) is the labor input at time 𝑡; and 𝑧(𝑡) is
The index of environmental degradation 𝑧(𝑡) is assumed to lie inside the unit interval
[0,1], with the interpretation that the higher the value of 𝑧(𝑡), the dirtier the production
technology and the higher the output of the consumption good. The production function,
as specified by (1), embodies the assumption that dirtier technology yields higher output.
When 𝑧(𝑡) = 1 , the production technology is the one with the maximum pollutant
emissions. When 𝑧(𝑡) falls below 1, the environment improves with the introduction of
13
cleaner and more advanced technologies, but the output decreases. When 𝑧(𝑡) = 0,
We are not interested in population growth, and thus, shall assume that the population
The production function (1) can be expressed under the per capita form as follows:
Although consumption also generates pollution, it will be ignored. The model only
𝐶(𝑡)1−𝜎 −1 𝐵
(4) 𝑢(𝑡) = − 𝛾 𝑋(𝑡)𝛾 ,
1−𝜎
where 𝑢(𝑡) denotes the utility of the representative agent; 𝐶(𝑡) is the consumption of the
relative risk aversion. Also, 𝑋(𝑡) is the stock of pollution stock in the economy at time 𝑡,
and 𝐵 > 0 and 𝛾 > 1 are two parameters, which characterize the disutility from the
pollution stock.
The motion of the stock of pollution is governed by the following differential equation:
𝑑𝑋
(5) = 𝑥(𝑡) − 𝜂𝑋(𝑡)
𝑑𝑡
14
where 𝜂 > 0 is a parameter that represents the degree of purification capacity of the
environment.
Under the above setup, a social planner solves the following maximization problem:
Choose a time path for the production technology 𝑡 → 𝑧(𝑡), 0 ≤ 𝑧(𝑡) ≤ 1, 𝑡 ≥ 0, and a
time path for the consumption of the representative agent 𝑡 → 𝐶(𝑡), 𝑡 ≥ 0, to maximize
∞ 𝐶(𝑡)1−𝜎 −1 𝐵
(7) ∫0 𝑒 −𝜌𝑡 ( 1−𝜎
− 𝛾 𝑋(𝑡)𝛾 ) 𝑑𝑡
subject to
𝑑𝐾
(6) = 𝐴𝐾(𝑡)𝛼 𝑧(𝑡) − 𝛿𝐾(𝑡) − 𝐶(𝑡),
𝑑𝑡
𝑑𝑋
(5) = 𝐴𝐾(𝑡)𝛼 𝑧(𝑡)𝛽 − 𝜂𝑋(𝑡),
𝑑𝑡
𝐶 1−𝜎 −1 𝐵
ℋ(𝐾, 𝑋, 𝑧, 𝐶, 𝜆, 𝜇, 𝑡) = 𝑒 𝜌𝑡 ( − 𝛾 𝑋 𝛾 ) + 𝜆(𝐴𝐾 𝛼 𝑧 − 𝛿𝐾 − 𝐶)
1−𝜎
+𝜇(𝐴𝐾 𝛼 𝑧 𝛽 − 𝜂𝑋).
Let 𝑧(𝑡) denote the optimal production technology at time t and 𝐶(𝑡) the optimal
consumption also at time t. The capital stock and the stock of pollution at time t under
the optimal control 𝑡 → (𝑧(𝑡), 𝐶(𝑡)), 𝑡 ≥ 0, are denoted, respectively, by 𝐾(𝑡) and 𝑋(𝑡).
15
Also, let 𝜆(𝑡) and 𝜇(𝑡) denote, respectively, the shadow price of capital and the shadow
𝜕ℋ(𝐾(𝑡),𝑋(𝑡),𝑧(𝑡),𝐶,𝜆(𝑡),𝜇(𝑡),𝑡)
(9) = 𝑒 −𝜌𝑡 𝐶 −𝜎 − 𝜆(𝑡) = 0,
𝜕𝐶
time t.
𝜕ℋ(𝐾(𝑡),𝑋(𝑡),𝑧(𝑡),𝐶(𝑡),𝜆(𝑡),𝜇(𝑡),𝑡)
(11) = 𝜆(𝑡)𝐴𝐾 𝛼 + 𝜇(𝑡)𝛽𝐴𝐾 𝛼 𝑧(𝑡)𝛽−1 ≤ 0,
𝜕𝑧
The motion of the shadow price of capital is governed by the following adjoint equation:
𝑑𝜆 𝜕ℋ(𝐾(𝑡),𝑋(𝑡),𝑧(𝑡),𝐶(𝑡),𝜆(𝑡),𝜇(𝑡),𝑡)
(14) =− = −𝜆(𝑡)(𝛼𝐴𝐾(𝑡)𝛼−1 𝑧(𝑡) − 𝛿)
𝑑𝑡 𝜕𝐾
−𝜇(𝑡)(𝐴𝛼𝐴𝐾(𝑡)𝛼−1 𝑧(𝑡)𝛽 ).
Letting 𝜆(𝑡) = 𝑒 𝜚𝑡 𝜆(𝑡) denote the current shadow price of capital at time t along the
1 𝑑𝜆 𝜇(𝑡)
(15) = 𝜚 − (𝛼𝐴𝐾(𝑡)𝛼−1 𝑧(𝑡) − 𝛿) − 𝜆(𝑡) (𝛼𝐴𝐾(𝑡)𝛼−1 𝑧(𝑡)𝛽 )
𝜆(𝑡) 𝑑𝑡
16
When 𝑧(𝑡) = 1, (15) is reduced to
1 𝑑𝜆 𝛼𝑌(𝑡) 𝜇(𝑡)
(16) =𝜚+𝛿− (1 + 𝜆(𝑡) ).
𝜆(𝑡) 𝑑𝑡 𝐾(𝑡)
1 𝑑𝜆 𝛼𝑌(𝑡) 1
(17) =𝜚+𝛿− (1 + 𝛽).
𝜆(𝑡) 𝑑𝑡 𝐾(𝑡)
The motion of the shadow price of pollution is governed by the following differential
equation:
𝑑𝜇 𝜕ℋ(𝐾(𝑡),𝑋(𝑡),𝑧(𝑡),𝐶(𝑡),𝜆(𝑡),𝜇(𝑡),𝑡)
(18) =− = 𝑒 −𝜚𝑡 𝐵𝑋(𝑡)𝛾−1 + 𝜇(𝑡)𝜂.
𝑑𝑡 𝜕𝑋
Letting 𝜇(𝑡) = 𝑒 𝜚𝑡 𝜇(𝑡) denote the current shadow price of pollution at time t along the
1 𝑑𝜇 𝐵𝑋(𝑡)𝛾−1
(19) =𝜌+𝜂+ .
𝜇(𝑡) 𝑑𝑡 𝜇(𝑡)
Suppose that the initial value of capital, 𝐾0 , is much smaller than its steady state value.
Then at time 𝑡 = 0 the shadow price of capital 𝜆(0) is sufficiently larger than the shadow
price 𝜇(0) of pollution, and 𝑧(0) = 1. If 𝑡 is small, 𝑧(𝑡) = 1, and 𝑌(𝑡), 𝐾(𝑡), 𝑥(𝑡) all rise as
𝑡 rises above 0. However, as capital accumulation progresses, 𝜆(𝑡) decreases and 𝜇(𝑡)
increases. Eventually, 𝜇(𝑡) exceeds 𝜆(𝑡) and then 𝑧(𝑡) < 1. After that, 𝑧(𝑡) decreases
over time, and the EKC shows a downward sloping curve. For a more detailed analysis,
technology will be introduced, and pollution emissions will decrease after economic
development has reached a certain level. Moreover, both the pollution flow and the
17
pollution stock decrease in the convergence to the steady state. Figure 3 depicts the
Figure 3.- The Environmental Kuznets curve according to the Stokey model
In most empirical studies, the concentration and emission of pollution are two basic
variables used in analysis. Because industrial wastes are the main sources of pollution,
we shall choose use industrial wastewater (unit: 109 t), industrial solid waste (unit:104 t),
and industrial waste gas (unit: 104 𝑚3 ) as pollution indicators. In our model, waste gas
includes sulfur dioxide and smoke and dust emissions. Also, we use GDP per capita
(unit: RMB) to reflect economic growth. The data, which span the years from 1995 to
log form of each variable. Furthermore, it is much likely that we get stationary series
2
Source: http://www.sc.stats.gov.cn/tjcbw/tjnj/
18
after transformation with the characteristics remain unchanged. We use LNIWW to
represent industrial gas waste, and LNGDP to represent GDP per capita, respectively.
where ISW represents industrial solid waste (unit:104 𝑡); IGW represents industrial gas
waste (unit: 104 𝑚3 ); and IWW represents industrial wastewater (unit: 109 t).
6. THE RESULTS
Prior to the co-integration test for a relationship between environmental pollution and
economic growth, we conduct the unit root test for the stability of the time series
Table 1
Results of unit roots test
19
At the plain level, we cannot reject the null hypothesis that the time series for the four
variables are stable, i.e., none of them are stable. As a result, we take the first order
difference, according to the Table 1, all of the variables reject the null hypothesis under
5% significant level, which means they are stable under 5% significant level. After taking
the first order difference and we can then carry out the do co-integration.
Table 2
Result of the co-integration test
From table 2, it is easy to find that there exists co-integration relationships between
LNIWW, LNISW, LNIGW and LNGDP, which means that the growth of GDP contributes
to the decline of industrial waste water, industrial solid waste and industrial gas waste.
This paper carries out a regression on the variables industrial waste water, industrial
gas waste, industrial solid waste, and GDP per capita. There are two basic models: one
is time series and the other is panel data. In this paper, we use the time series model,
20
which was proposed by Grossman and Krueger (1995). The equation to be estimated
𝑦𝑡 = 𝛽0 + 𝛽1 𝑥𝑡 + 𝛽2 𝑥𝑡2 + 𝛽3 𝑥𝑡3 + 𝜀𝑡 ,
where 𝑦𝑡 represents pollution emission indicators, and 𝑥𝑡 represents GDP per capita.
Depending on the signs of the coefficients on the RHS of the above equation, one of the
When 𝛽1 > 0, 𝛽2 > 0, 𝛽3 > 0, the equation exhibits an “N” shape curve, i.e.
When 𝛽1 < 0, 𝛽2 > 0, 𝛽3 < 0, the equation exhibits a inverted “N” shape curve, i.e.
environment firstly improves, and gradually deteriorates and then improves with
economic growth;
When 𝛽1 > 0, 𝛽2 < 0, 𝛽3 = 0, the equation exhibits a inverted “U” shape curve, i.e.
the typical EKC, environment deteriorates before improves with economic growth;
21
When 𝛽1 < 0, 𝛽2 < 0, 𝛽3 = 0 , the equation exhibits a “U” shape curve, i.e.
Table 3
Result of EKC model
Pollution 𝛽0 𝛽1 𝛽2 𝛽3
emission
index
LNIGW - 3.456722 - 2.001231
2.984536 (0.0112) 0.991267 (0.0612)
(0.1267) (0.4120)
LNISW - 6.823411 - 0.761133
3.564394 (0.0034) 1.762322 (0.0137)
(0.0348) (0.0003)
LNIWW - 2.110036 - 1.440015
4.795647 (0.0423) 1.336168 (0.0069)
(0.0955) (0.0046)
different from zero with 𝛽1 > 0, 𝛽2 < 0, 𝛽3 > 0 ; we know that LNGDP and LNIWW
from zero and 𝛽1 > 0, 𝛽2 < 0, 𝛽3 > 0; we know that LNGDP and LNISW exhibits an “N”
relationship.
22
Also, the p-value is greater than 0.1 for some of the coefficients, and we cannot
conclude that the coefficients are significantly different from zero: there is no linear or
To summarize the analysis, LN GDP and LNIWW exhibits an “N” relationship instead of
inverted “U” relationship, LNGDP and LNISW exhibits an “N” relationship instead of
LNIWW, LNISW, LNIGW and LNGDP, and this means the growth of GDP contributes to
the decline of industrial wastewater, industrial solid waste, and industrial gas waste.
However, we do not know whether income changes lead to pollution emissions changes
Granger causality test to solve this problem. The results of the Granger causality test
23
Table 4
Result of Granger test
As can be seen from Table 4, Granger causality only exists between LNGDP and
LNIWW, LNISW and LNGDP, but no Granger causality between LNIGW and LNGDP.
Economically speaking, GDP per capita makes a large contribution to the industrial
wastewater and industrial solid waste, but not to industrial gas waste. Furthermore,
7. CONCLUSION
The goal of this paper is to determine whether the industrial pollution – industrial gas
waste, industrial solid waste and industrial wastewater – will affect economic growth.
The results of the paper show that the increase in industrial solid waste and industrial
24
wastewater would have a negative impact on economic development. Gas waste, on
the other hand, has a positive impact on economic development. However, this last
result does not necessarily mean we should produce more gas waste thinking that this
would have a positive effect on economic growth. In reality, the air quality in Sichuan
province is becoming worse and worse, and this problem has attracted government’s
attention to release new policies in order to improve the environment condition. The first
action to undertake is to phase out and shut down the business activities that are
technology-backward and that are causing heavy pollution. In 2001 and 2004, the
government shut down 30 thousand factories and companies that heavily consume
resources and energy. Efforts have been made to deal with the heavily polluting
industries such as: steel, cement, electricity, aluminum, and iron. The government also
suspended some projects that were not in accordance with the related industry policies.
The second action is to encourage recycling. Factories should make the best use of the
resources and control the waste generated in the process of production. The
25
Appendix A
Data Sources
26
Appendix B
OLS test result
27
REFERENCES
Arrow K. Bolin B., Costanza R., Dasgupta P., Folke C., Holling C.S., Jansson B., Levin
S., Mäler K., Perrings C. and D. Pimentel,1996, “Economic growth, carrying capacity,
and the environment.” Environment and Development Economics, 1, 104-110.
Beckerman W., 1992, “Economic growth and the environment: whose growth? Whose
environment”, World Development, (20):481-496.
Berman E. and L. Bui, 1998, “Environmental Regulation and Labor Demand: Evidence
from the
South Coast Air Basin”, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No.
6776.
Bimonte S., 2009, “Growth and environmental quality: Testing the double convergence
hypothesis”, Ecological Economics, 68, 2406–241.
Blazejczak J., Braun F. and D. Edler, 2009, “Global Demand for Environmental Goods
and Services on the Rise: Good Growth Opportunities for German Suppliers”, German
Institute for Economic Research, 5, 20, 138-145.
Boulding K. E., 1966, “The Economics of the Coming Spaceship Earth”, Environmental
Quality in a Growing Economy, ed., H. Jarrett, Baltimore, MD: John Hopkins Press.
Carraro C., De Cian E. and M. Tavoni, 2009, “Human Capital Formation and Global
Warming
Mitigation: Evidence from an Integrated Assessment Model”, CESIFO WP 2874.
Caviglia-Harris J., Chambers L., Dustin K. and R. James, 2009, “Taking the “U” out of
Kuznets: A comprehensive analysis of the EKC and environmental degradation”,
Ecological Economics, Elsevier, 68(4), 1149-1159.
Choudhury K. and L. Jansen, 1997, Terminology for integrated resources planning and
management. Rome, FAO, Soils Resources Management and Conservation, 59.
Cole M. A., 2004, “The pollution haven hypothesis and the environmental Kuznets
Curve: Examining the linkages”, Ecological Economics, 48(3), 71-81.
Coondoo D. and Dinda S., 2002, “Causality between income and emissions: a country
group-specific econometric analysis”, Ecological Economics, 40(3), 351-367.
Davidson C., 2000, “Economic growth and the environment: alternatives to the limits
paradigm”, BioScience 50:433–440.
Davis G. A., 1995, “Learning to love the Dutch disease: Evidence from the mineral
28
economies”, World Development, 23(10), 1765–1779.
Day K. M. and Graften R. Q., 2003, “Growth and the environment in Canada: An
empirical analysis, Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics”, 51(3), 197-216.
Dietz S., 2000, “Does an environmental Kuznets curve exist for biodiversity?” Institut für
Wirtschaftsforschung, Eidgenössische Technische Hochschule Zürich.
Easterlin R. A., 1974, “Does economic growth improve the human lot?”, Nations and
Households in Economic Growth, Academic Press.
Ekins P., 2000, “Economic Growth and Environmental Sustainability: The Prospects for
Green Growth”, Routledge, London.
Frontier Economics, 2009, “Alternative policies for promoting low carbon innovation.”
Report for Department of Energy and Climate Change.
George E. Halkos, 2003, “Environmental Kuznets Curve for sulfur: evidence using GMM
estimation and random coefficient panel data models”, Environmental and development
economics 8 (4), 581-601.
Grossman G. and Krueger A., 1992, “Environmental impacts of a North American free
trade agreement”, Garber P., The Mexico-US Free Trade Agreement, Cambridge, MA:
M ⅡPress.
Grossman G. and Krueger A., 1995, “Economic Growth and the Environment”,
Quarterly Journal of Economic, 110(2), 353-372.
Innovas, 2009. “Low Carbon and Environmental Goods and Services: an industry
analysis.” Report for BERR.
Jaffe A. B., Newell R. G. and R. N. Stavins, 2000, “Technological Change and the
Environment”, WP7970, National Bureau of Economic Research.
29
Jaffe A. B. and K. Palmer, 1997, “Environmental Regulation And Innovation: A Panel
Data Study,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, MIT Press, 79(4), 610-619.
Jaffe A. B., Peterson S. R., Potney, P.R. and R. N. Stavins, 1995, “Environmental
Regulation and the competitiveness of US Manufacturing: What does the evidence tell
us?”, Journal of Economic Literature, 23, 132-163.
Kuznets S., 1934, "National Income, 1929-1932". 73rd US Congress, 2nd session,
Senate document no. 124, 7.
Kuznets S., 1955, “Economic growth and income inequality,” American Economic
Review, 49.l-28.
Lewis W. A., 1954, “Economic Development with Unlimited Supply of Labour”, The
Manchester School, 22, 2:139-91.
Liang J. and McKitrick R., 2002, “Income growth and air quality in Toronto: 1973-1997”,
Mimeo, University of Guelph, Economics Department.
Liu G., 2006, “A causality analysis on GDP and air emissions in Norway”, Discussion
Papers, Statistics Norway, No.447.
Liu L., 2005, “The Environmental Kuznets Curve of Guangdong Province”, Research of
Environmental Sciences, 18(6), 6-11.
Magnani E., 2000, “The Environmental Kuznets Curve, environmental protection policy
and income distribution”, Ecological Economics 32, 431–443.
Omisakin A. O., 2009, “Economic growth and environmental quality in Nigeria: Does
environmental Kuznets Curve hypothesis hold?”, Environmental Research Journal,
3(1),14-18.
Panayotou T., 2000, “Economic Growth and the Environment.” CID Working Papers 56,
30
Center for International Development at Harvard University.
Peng L., Tong X. and Shen Y., 2008, “Quantitative process of environment and
economic progress in Shanghai”, China Population Resources And Environment,
18(3),186-194.
Peng S. and Bao Q., 2006, “Economic growth and environmental pollution: an empirical
test for the environmental Kuznets Curve hypothesis in china”, Research On Financial
And Economic Issues, (8):3-17.
Porter M. E. and C. van der Linde, 1995, “Towards a New Conception of the
Environmental Competitiveness Relationship”, Journal of Economic Perspectives 9, 97-
118.
Ranjan R. and J. Shortle, 2007, “The environmental Kuznets curve when the
environment exhibits hysteresis.” Ecological Economics, Elsevier, 64(1), 204-215.
Shen M. and Xv Y., 2000, “A new type of Kuznets Curve: the relationship between
economic growth and environment change”, Zhejiang Social Sciences, (7),53-57.
Stern D. I., Michael S. C. and Edward B. B, 1996, “Economic growth and environmental
degradation: The environmental Kuznets Curve and sustainable development”, World
Development, 24(7):1151-1160.
Stokey, N.L, 1998, “Are there limits to growth?”, International Economic Review, 39, 1-
31.
Turner R. K., Morse-Jones S., and B. Fisher, 2007, “Perspectives on the ‘Environmental
Limits’ concept: A report to the Department for the Environment, Food and Rural Affairs”,
CSERGE, Norwich.
Tim Everett, Mallika Ishwaran, Gian Paolo Ansaloni and Alex Rubin, 2010, “Economic
Growth and the Environment”.
Wang Y., Cui X., and Chen W., 2006, “Empirical research on the relationship between
31
economic growth and environmental degradation in Nanjing city” [J]. Resources and
Environment in the Yangtze Basin, 15(2), 142-146.
Wang Z., Wen Z.,Yan F., et al., 2007, “Verifying the environmental Kuznets Curve
hypothesis and its conditions in Beijing”, China Population Resources And Environment,
17(2), 40-47.
World Bank, 1992, World Development Report 1992: “Development and the
Environment “, Washington, DC: The World Bank.
Zhang B., Bi J., Ge J., et al., 2008, “Empirical study of environmental Kuznets curve in
south Jiangsu, Economic Geography”, 28(3), 376-379, 424.
32