Chapter Six: Demand

Download as pptx, pdf, or txt
Download as pptx, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 120

Chapter Six

Demand
Properties of Demand Functions
Comparative statics analysis of
ordinary demand functions -- the
study of how ordinary demands
x
1
*(p
1
,p
2
,y) and x
2
*(p
1
,p
2
,y) change as
prices p
1
, p
2
and income y change.
Own-Price Changes
How does x
1
*(p
1
,p
2
,y) change as p
1

changes, holding p
2
and y constant?
Suppose only p
1
increases, from p
1

to p
1
and then to p
1
.

x
1
x
2
p
1
= p
1

Fixed p
2
and y.
p
1
x
1
+ p
2
x
2
= y
Own-Price Changes
Own-Price Changes
x
1
x
2
p
1
= p
1

p
1
= p
1

Fixed p
2
and y.
p
1
x
1
+ p
2
x
2
= y
Own-Price Changes
x
1
x
2
p
1
= p
1

p
1
=
p
1

Fixed p
2
and y.
p
1
= p
1

p
1
x
1
+ p
2
x
2
= y
x
2
x
1
p
1
= p
1

Own-Price Changes
Fixed p
2
and y.
x
2
x
1
x
1
*(p
1
)
Own-Price Changes
p
1
= p
1

Fixed p
2
and y.
x
2
x
1
x
1
*(p
1
)
p
1
x
1
*(p
1
)
p
1

x
1
*
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p
2
and y.
p
1
= p
1

x
2
x
1
x
1
*(p
1
)
p
1
x
1
*(p
1
)
p
1

p
1
= p
1

x
1
*
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p
2
and y.
x
2
x
1
x
1
*(p
1
)
x
1
*(p
1
)
p
1
x
1
*(p
1
)
p
1

p
1
= p
1

x
1
*
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p
2
and y.
x
2
x
1
x
1
*(p
1
)
x
1
*(p
1
)
p
1
x
1
*(p
1
)
x
1
*(p
1
)
p
1

p
1

x
1
*
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p
2
and y.
x
2
x
1
x
1
*(p
1
)
x
1
*(p
1
)
p
1
x
1
*(p
1
)
x
1
*(p
1
)
p
1

p
1

p
1
= p
1

x
1
*
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p
2
and y.
x
2
x
1
x
1
*(p
1
) x
1
*(p
1
)
x
1
*(p
1
)
p
1
x
1
*(p
1
)
x
1
*(p
1
)
p
1

p
1

p
1
= p
1

x
1
*
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p
2
and y.
x
2
x
1
x
1
*(p
1
) x
1
*(p
1
)
x
1
*(p
1
)
p
1
x
1
*(p
1
) x
1
*(p
1
)
x
1
*(p
1
)
p
1

p
1

p
1

x
1
*
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p
2
and y.
x
2
x
1
x
1
*(p
1
) x
1
*(p
1
)
x
1
*(p
1
)
p
1
x
1
*(p
1
) x
1
*(p
1
)
x
1
*(p
1
)
p
1

p
1

p
1

x
1
*
Own-Price Changes
Ordinary
demand curve
for commodity 1
Fixed p
2
and y.
x
2
x
1
x
1
*(p
1
) x
1
*(p
1
)
x
1
*(p
1
)
p
1
x
1
*(p
1
) x
1
*(p
1
)
x
1
*(p
1
)
p
1

p
1

p
1

x
1
*
Own-Price Changes
Ordinary
demand curve
for commodity 1
Fixed p
2
and y.
x
2
x
1
x
1
*(p
1
) x
1
*(p
1
)
x
1
*(p
1
)
p
1
x
1
*(p
1
) x
1
*(p
1
)
x
1
*(p
1
)
p
1

p
1

p
1

x
1
*
Own-Price Changes
Ordinary
demand curve
for commodity 1
p
1
price
offer
curve
Fixed p
2
and y.
Own-Price Changes
The curve containing all the utility-
maximizing bundles traced out as p
1

changes, with p
2
and y constant, is
the p
1
- price offer curve.
The plot of the x
1
-coordinate of the
p
1
- price offer curve against p
1
is the
ordinary demand curve for
commodity 1.
Own-Price Changes
What does a p
1
price-offer curve look
like for Cobb-Douglas preferences?
Own-Price Changes
What does a p
1
price-offer curve look
like for Cobb-Douglas preferences?
Take


Then the ordinary demand functions
for commodities 1 and 2 are
U x x x x
a b
( , ) .
1 2 1 2
=
Own-Price Changes
x p p y
a
a b
y
p
1 1 2
1
*
( , , ) =
+

x p p y
b
a b
y
p
2 1 2
2
*
( , , ) . =
+

and
Notice that x
2
* does not vary with p
1
so the
p
1
price offer curve is
Own-Price Changes
x p p y
a
a b
y
p
1 1 2
1
*
( , , ) =
+

x p p y
b
a b
y
p
2 1 2
2
*
( , , ) . =
+

and
Notice that x
2
* does not vary with p
1
so the
p
1
price offer curve is flat
Own-Price Changes
x p p y
a
a b
y
p
1 1 2
1
*
( , , ) =
+

x p p y
b
a b
y
p
2 1 2
2
*
( , , ) . =
+

and
Notice that x
2
* does not vary with p
1
so the
p
1
price offer curve is flat and the ordinary
demand curve for commodity 1 is a
Own-Price Changes
x p p y
a
a b
y
p
1 1 2
1
*
( , , ) =
+

x p p y
b
a b
y
p
2 1 2
2
*
( , , ) . =
+

and
Notice that x
2
* does not vary with p
1
so the
p
1
price offer curve is flat and the ordinary
demand curve for commodity 1 is a
rectangular hyperbola.
x
1
*(p
1
) x
1
*(p
1
)
x
1
*(p
1
)
x
2
x
1
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p
2
and y.
x
by
a b p
2
2
*
( )
=
+
x
ay
a b p
1
1
*
( )
=
+
x
1
*(p
1
) x
1
*(p
1
)
x
1
*(p
1
)
x
2
x
1
p
1
x
1
*
Own-Price Changes
Ordinary
demand curve
for commodity 1
is
Fixed p
2
and y.
x
by
a b p
2
2
*
( )
=
+
x
ay
a b p
1
1
*
( )
=
+
x
ay
a b p
1
1
*
( )
=
+
Own-Price Changes
What does a p
1
price-offer curve look
like for a perfect-complements utility
function?
Own-Price Changes
What does a p
1
price-offer curve look
like for a perfect-complements utility
function?
U x x x x ( , ) min , .
1 2 1 2
Then the ordinary demand functions
for commodities 1 and 2 are
Own-Price Changes
x p p y x p p y
y
p p
1 1 2 2 1 2
1 2
* *
( , , ) ( , , ) . = =
+
Own-Price Changes
x p p y x p p y
y
p p
1 1 2 2 1 2
1 2
* *
( , , ) ( , , ) . = =
+
With p
2
and y fixed, higher p
1
causes
smaller x
1
* and x
2
*.
Own-Price Changes
x p p y x p p y
y
p p
1 1 2 2 1 2
1 2
* *
( , , ) ( , , ) . = =
+
With p
2
and y fixed, higher p
1
causes
smaller x
1
* and x
2
*.
p x x
y
p
1 1 2
2
0 = , .
* *
As
Own-Price Changes
x p p y x p p y
y
p p
1 1 2 2 1 2
1 2
* *
( , , ) ( , , ) . = =
+
With p
2
and y fixed, higher p
1
causes
smaller x
1
* and x
2
*.
p x x
y
p
1 1 2
2
0 = , .
* *
As
p x x
1 1 2
0 = , .
* *
As
Fixed p
2
and y.
Own-Price Changes
x
1
x
2
p
1
x
1
*
Fixed p
2
and y.
x
y
p p
2
1 2
*
=
+
x
y
p p
1
1 2
*
=
+
Own-Price Changes
x
1
x
2
p
1

x
y
p p
1
1 2
*
=
+

p
1
= p
1



y/p
2
p
1
x
1
*
Fixed p
2
and y.
x
y
p p
2
1 2
*
=
+
x
y
p p
1
1 2
*
=
+
Own-Price Changes
x
1
x
2
p
1

p
1

p
1
= p
1


x
y
p p
1
1 2
*
=
+


y/p
2
p
1
x
1
*
Fixed p
2
and y.
x
y
p p
2
1 2
*
=
+
x
y
p p
1
1 2
*
=
+
Own-Price Changes
x
1
x
2
p
1

p
1

p
1

x
y
p p
1
1 2
*
=
+
p
1
= p
1




y/p
2
p
1
x
1
*
Ordinary
demand curve
for commodity 1
is
Fixed p
2
and y.
x
y
p p
2
1 2
*
=
+
x
y
p p
1
1 2
*
=
+
x
y
p p
1
1 2
*
. =
+
Own-Price Changes
x
1
x
2
p
1

p
1

p
1

y
p
2
y/p
2
Own-Price Changes
What does a p
1
price-offer curve look
like for a perfect-substitutes utility
function?
U x x x x ( , ) .
1 2 1 2
Then the ordinary demand functions
for commodities 1 and 2 are
Own-Price Changes
x p p y
if p p
y p if p p
1 1 2
1 2
1 1 2
0
*
( , , )
,
/ ,
=
>
<

x p p y
if p p
y p if p p
2 1 2
1 2
2 1 2
0
*
( , , )
,
/ , .
=
<
>

and
Fixed p
2
and y.
Own-Price Changes
x
2
x
1
Fixed p
2
and y.
x
2
0
*
=
x
y
p
1
1
*
=
p
1
= p
1
< p
2

Fixed p
2
and y.
Own-Price Changes
x
2
x
1
p
1
x
1
*
Fixed p
2
and y.
x
2
0
*
=
x
y
p
1
1
*
=
p
1

p
1
= p
1
< p
2

x
y
p
1
1
*
=

Fixed p
2
and y.
Own-Price Changes
x
2
x
1
p
1
x
1
*
Fixed p
2
and y.
p
1

p
1
= p
1
= p
2
Fixed p
2
and y.
Own-Price Changes
x
2
x
1
p
1
x
1
*
Fixed p
2
and y.
p
1

p
1
= p
1
= p
2
Fixed p
2
and y.
Own-Price Changes
x
2
x
1
p
1
x
1
*
Fixed p
2
and y.
x
2
0
*
=
x
y
p
1
1
*
=
p
1

p
1
= p
1
= p
2


x
1
0
*
=

x
y
p
2
2
*
=

Fixed p
2
and y.
Own-Price Changes
x
2
x
1
p
1
x
1
*
Fixed p
2
and y.
x
2
0
*
=
x
y
p
1
2
*
=
p
1

p
1
= p
1
= p
2

x
1
0
*
=

x
y
p
2
2
*
=

0
1
2
s s x
y
p
*

p
2
= p
1

Fixed p
2
and y.
Own-Price Changes
x
2
x
1
p
1
x
1
*
Fixed p
2
and y.
x
y
p
2
2
*
=
x
1
0
*
=
p
1

p
1

x
1
0
*
=
p
2
= p
1

Fixed p
2
and y.
Own-Price Changes
x
2
x
1
p
1
x
1
*
Fixed p
2
and y.
p
1

p
2
= p
1

p
1

x
y
p
1
1
*
=

0
1
2
s s x
y
p
*
y
p
2
p
1
price
offer
curve
Ordinary
demand curve
for commodity 1
Own-Price Changes
Usually we ask Given the price for
commodity 1 what is the quantity
demanded of commodity 1?
But we could also ask the inverse
question At what price for
commodity 1 would a given quantity
of commodity 1 be demanded?
Own-Price Changes
p
1
x
1
*
p
1

Given p
1
, what quantity is
demanded of commodity 1?
Own-Price Changes
p
1
x
1
*
p
1

Given p
1
, what quantity is
demanded of commodity 1?
Answer: x
1
units.
x
1

Own-Price Changes
p
1
x
1
*
x
1

Given p
1
, what quantity is
demanded of commodity 1?
Answer: x
1
units.
The inverse question is:
Given x
1
units are
demanded, what is the
price of
commodity 1?
Own-Price Changes
p
1
x
1
*
p
1

x
1

Given p
1
, what quantity is
demanded of commodity 1?
Answer: x
1
units.
The inverse question is:
Given x
1
units are
demanded, what is the
price of
commodity 1?
Answer: p
1

Own-Price Changes
Taking quantity demanded as given
and then asking what must be price
describes the inverse demand
function of a commodity.
Own-Price Changes
A Cobb-Douglas example:
x
ay
a b p
1
1
*
( )
=
+
is the ordinary demand function and
p
ay
a b x
1
1
=
+ ( )
*
is the inverse demand function.
Own-Price Changes
A perfect-complements example:
x
y
p p
1
1 2
*
=
+
is the ordinary demand function and
p
y
x
p
1
1
2
=
*
is the inverse demand function.
Income Changes
How does the value of x
1
*(p
1
,p
2
,y)
change as y changes, holding both
p
1
and p
2
constant?
x
2
x
1
Income Changes
Fixed p
1
and p
2
.
y < y < y
x
2
x
1
Income Changes
Fixed p
1
and p
2
.
y < y < y
x
2
x
1
Income Changes
Fixed p
1
and p
2
.
y < y < y
x
1

x
1

x
1

x
2

x
2

x
2

x
2
x
1
Income Changes
Fixed p
1
and p
2
.
y < y < y
x
1

x
1

x
1

x
2

x
2

x
2

Income
offer curve
Income Changes
A plot of quantity demanded against
income is called an Engel curve.
x
2
x
1
Income Changes
Fixed p
1
and p
2
.
y < y < y
x
1

x
1

x
1

x
2

x
2

x
2

Income
offer curve
x
2
x
1
Income Changes
Fixed p
1
and p
2
.
y < y < y
x
1

x
1

x
1

x
2

x
2

x
2

Income
offer curve
x
1
*
y
x
1

x
1

x
1

y
y
y
x
2
x
1
Income Changes
Fixed p
1
and p
2
.
y < y < y
x
1

x
1

x
1

x
2

x
2

x
2

Income
offer curve
x
1
*
y
x
1

x
1

x
1

y
y
y
Engel
curve;
good 1
x
2
x
1
Income Changes
Fixed p
1
and p
2
.
y < y < y
x
1

x
1

x
1

x
2

x
2

x
2

Income
offer curve
x
2
*
y
x
2

x
2

x
2

y
y
y
x
2
x
1
Income Changes
Fixed p
1
and p
2
.
y < y < y
x
1

x
1

x
1

x
2

x
2

x
2

Income
offer curve
x
2
*
y
x
2

x
2

x
2

y
y
y
Engel
curve;
good 2
x
2
x
1
Income Changes
Fixed p
1
and p
2
.
y < y < y
x
1

x
1

x
1

x
2

x
2

x
2

Income
offer curve
x
1
*
x
2
*
y
y
x
1

x
1

x
1

x
2

x
2

x
2

y
y
y
y
y
y
Engel
curve;
good 2
Engel
curve;
good 1
Income Changes and Cobb-
Douglas Preferences
An example of computing the
equations of Engel curves; the Cobb-
Douglas case.

The ordinary demand equations are
U x x x x
a b
( , ) .
1 2 1 2
=
x
ay
a b p
x
by
a b p
1
1
2
2
* *
( )
;
( )
. =
+
=
+
Income Changes and Cobb-
Douglas Preferences
x
ay
a b p
x
by
a b p
1
1
2
2
* *
( )
;
( )
. =
+
=
+
Rearranged to isolate y, these are:
y
a b p
a
x
y
a b p
b
x
=
+
=
+
( )
( )
*
*
1
1
2
2
Engel curve for good 1
Engel curve for good 2
Income Changes and Cobb-
Douglas Preferences
y
y
x
1
*
x
2
*
y
a b p
a
x =
+ ( )
*
1
1
Engel curve
for good 1
y
a b p
b
x =
+ ( )
*
2
2
Engel curve
for good 2
Income Changes and Perfectly-
Complementary Preferences
Another example of computing the
equations of Engel curves; the
perfectly-complementary case.

The ordinary demand equations are
x x
y
p p
1 2
1 2
* *
. = =
+
U x x x x ( , ) min , .
1 2 1 2
=
Income Changes and Perfectly-
Complementary Preferences
Rearranged to isolate y, these are:
y p p x
y p p x
= +
= +
( )
( )
*
*
1 2 1
1 2 2
Engel curve for good 1
x x
y
p p
1 2
1 2
* *
. = =
+
Engel curve for good 2
Fixed p
1
and p
2
.
Income Changes
x
1
x
2
Income Changes
x
1
x
2
y < y < y
Fixed p
1
and p
2
.
Income Changes
x
1
x
2
y < y < y
Fixed p
1
and p
2
.
Income Changes
x
1
x
2
y < y < y
x
1

x
1

x
2

x
2

x
2

x
1

Fixed p
1
and p
2
.
Income Changes
x
1
x
2
y < y < y
x
1

x
1

x
2

x
2

x
2

x
1

x
1
*
y
y
y
y
Engel
curve;
good 1
x
1

x
1

x
1

Fixed p
1
and p
2
.
Income Changes
x
1
x
2
y < y < y
x
1

x
1

x
2

x
2

x
2

x
1

x
2
*
y
x
2

x
2

x
2

y
y
y
Engel
curve;
good 2
Fixed p
1
and p
2
.
Income Changes
x
1
x
2
y < y < y
x
1

x
1

x
2

x
2

x
2

x
1

x
1
*
x
2
*
y
y
x
2

x
2

x
2

y
y
y
y
y
y
Engel
curve;
good 2
Engel
curve;
good 1
x
1

x
1

x
1

Fixed p
1
and p
2
.
Income Changes
x
1
*
x
2
*
y
y
x
2

x
2

x
2

y
y
y
y
y
y
x
1

x
1

x
1

y p p x = + ( )
*
1 2 2
y p p x = + ( )
*
1 2 1
Engel
curve;
good 2
Engel
curve;
good 1
Fixed p
1
and p
2
.
Income Changes and Perfectly-
Substitutable Preferences
Another example of computing the
equations of Engel curves; the
perfectly-substitution case.

The ordinary demand equations are
U x x x x ( , ) .
1 2 1 2
= +
Income Changes and Perfectly-
Substitutable Preferences
x p p y
if p p
y p if p p
1 1 2
1 2
1 1 2
0
*
( , , )
,
/ ,
=
>
<

x p p y
if p p
y p if p p
2 1 2
1 2
2 1 2
0
*
( , , )
,
/ , .
=
<
>

Income Changes and Perfectly-


Substitutable Preferences
x p p y
if p p
y p if p p
1 1 2
1 2
1 1 2
0
*
( , , )
,
/ ,
=
>
<

x p p y
if p p
y p if p p
2 1 2
1 2
2 1 2
0
*
( , , )
,
/ , .
=
<
>

Suppose p
1
< p
2
. Then
Income Changes and Perfectly-
Substitutable Preferences
x p p y
if p p
y p if p p
1 1 2
1 2
1 1 2
0
*
( , , )
,
/ ,
=
>
<

x p p y
if p p
y p if p p
2 1 2
1 2
2 1 2
0
*
( , , )
,
/ , .
=
<
>

Suppose p
1
< p
2
. Then x
y
p
1
1
*
=
x
2
0
*
=
and
Income Changes and Perfectly-
Substitutable Preferences
x p p y
if p p
y p if p p
1 1 2
1 2
1 1 2
0
*
( , , )
,
/ ,
=
>
<

x p p y
if p p
y p if p p
2 1 2
1 2
2 1 2
0
*
( , , )
,
/ , .
=
<
>

Suppose p
1
< p
2
. Then x
y
p
1
1
*
=
x
2
0
*
=
and
x
2
0
*
. = y p x =
1 1
*
and
Income Changes and Perfectly-
Substitutable Preferences
x
2
0
*
. =
y p x =
1 1
*
y y
x
1
* x
2
*
0
Engel curve
for good 1
Engel curve
for good 2
Income Changes
In every example so far the Engel
curves have all been straight lines?
Q: Is this true in general?
A: No. Engel curves are straight
lines if the consumers preferences
are homothetic.
Homotheticity
A consumers preferences are
homothetic if and only if


for every k > 0.
That is, the consumers MRS is the
same anywhere on a straight line
drawn from the origin.
(x
1
,x
2
) (y
1
,y
2
) (kx
1
,kx
2
) (ky
1
,ky
2
)

p p
Income Effects -- A
Nonhomothetic Example
Quasilinear preferences are not
homothetic.


For example,
U x x f x x ( , ) ( ) .
1 2 1 2
= +
U x x x x ( , ) .
1 2 1 2
= +
Quasi-linear Indifference Curves
x
2
x
1
Each curve is a vertically shifted
copy of the others.
Each curve intersects
both axes.
Income Changes; Quasilinear
Utility
x
2
x
1
x
1
~
Income Changes; Quasilinear
Utility
x
2
x
1
x
1
~
x
1
*
y
x
1
~
Engel
curve
for
good 1
Income Changes; Quasilinear
Utility
x
2
x
1
x
1
~
x
2
*
y
Engel
curve
for
good 2
Income Changes; Quasilinear
Utility
x
2
x
1
x
1
~
x
1
*
x
2
*
y
y
x
1
~
Engel
curve
for
good 2
Engel
curve
for
good 1
Income Effects
A good for which quantity demanded
rises with income is called normal.
Therefore a normal goods Engel
curve is positively sloped.
Income Effects
A good for which quantity demanded
falls as income increases is called
income inferior.
Therefore an income inferior goods
Engel curve is negatively sloped.
x
2
x
1
Income Changes; Goods
1 & 2 Normal
x
1

x
1

x
1

x
2

x
2

x
2

Income
offer curve
x
1
*
x
2
*
y
y
x
1

x
1

x
1

x
2

x
2

x
2

y
y
y
y
y
y
Engel
curve;
good 2
Engel
curve;
good 1
Income Changes; Good 2 Is Normal,
Good 1 Becomes Income Inferior
x
2
x
1
Income Changes; Good 2 Is Normal,
Good 1 Becomes Income Inferior
x
2
x
1
Income Changes; Good 2 Is Normal,
Good 1 Becomes Income Inferior
x
2
x
1
Income Changes; Good 2 Is Normal,
Good 1 Becomes Income Inferior
x
2
x
1
Income Changes; Good 2 Is Normal,
Good 1 Becomes Income Inferior
x
2
x
1
Income Changes; Good 2 Is Normal,
Good 1 Becomes Income Inferior
x
2
x
1
Income
offer curve
Income Changes; Good 2 Is Normal,
Good 1 Becomes Income Inferior
x
2
x
1
x
1
*
y
Engel curve
for good 1
Income Changes; Good 2 Is Normal,
Good 1 Becomes Income Inferior
x
2
x
1
x
1
*
x
2
*
y
y
Engel curve
for good 2
Engel curve
for good 1
Ordinary Goods
A good is called ordinary if the
quantity demanded of it always
increases as its own price decreases.
Ordinary Goods
Fixed p
2
and y.
x
1
x
2
Ordinary Goods
Fixed p
2
and y.
x
1
x
2
p
1
price
offer
curve
Ordinary Goods
Fixed p
2
and y.
x
1
x
2
p
1
price
offer
curve
x
1
*
Downward-sloping
demand curve
Good 1 is
ordinary


p
1
Giffen Goods
If, for some values of its own price,
the quantity demanded of a good
rises as its own-price increases then
the good is called Giffen.
Ordinary Goods
Fixed p
2
and y.
x
1
x
2
Ordinary Goods
Fixed p
2
and y.
x
1
x
2
p
1
price offer
curve
Ordinary Goods
Fixed p
2
and y.
x
1
x
2
p
1
price offer
curve
x
1
*
Demand curve has
a positively
sloped part
Good 1 is
Giffen


p
1
Cross-Price Effects
If an increase in p
2
increases demand for commodity 1
then commodity 1 is a gross
substitute for commodity 2.


reduces demand for commodity 1
then commodity 1 is a gross
complement for commodity 2.
Cross-Price Effects
A perfect-complements example:
x
y
p p
1
1 2
*
=
+
c
c
x
p
y
p p
1
2
1 2
2
0
*
. =
+
<
so
Therefore commodity 2 is a gross
complement for commodity 1.
Cross-Price Effects
p
1
x
1
*
p
1

p
1

p
1

y
p
2

Increase the price of
good 2 from p
2
to p
2

and
Cross-Price Effects
p
1
x
1
*
p
1

p
1

p
1

y
p
2

Increase the price of
good 2 from p
2
to p
2

and the demand curve
for good 1 shifts inwards
-- good 2 is a
complement for good 1.
Cross-Price Effects
A Cobb- Douglas example:
x
by
a b p
2
2
*
( )
=
+
so
Cross-Price Effects
A Cobb- Douglas example:
x
by
a b p
2
2
*
( )
=
+
c
c
x
p
2
1
0
*
. =
so
Therefore commodity 1 is neither a gross
complement nor a gross substitute for
commodity 2.

You might also like