Chapter 3
Chapter 3
Chapter 3
Chapter Objectives
At the end of this chapter, you will be able to:
explain consumer preferences and utility
differentiate between cardinal and ordinal utility approach
define indifference curve and discuss its properties
derive and explain the budget line
describe the equilibrium condition of a consumer
Consumer behaviour can be best understood in three steps.
First, by examining consumer‘s preference, we need a practical
way to describe how people prefer one good to another.
Second, we must take into account that consumers face budget
constraints – they have limited incomes.
Third, we will put consumer preference and budget constraint
together to determine consumer choice.
3.1 Consumer preferences
A consumer makes choices by comparing bundle of goods. Given
any two consumption bundles, the consumer either decides that
one of the consumption bundles is strictly better than the other, or
decides that she is indifferent between the two bundles.
If He/she always chooses X when Y is available, then it is natural to
say that this consumer prefers X to Y.
o We use the symbol ≻ to mean that one bundle is strictly preferred to
another, so that X ≻Y should be interpreted as saying that the
consumer strictly prefers X to Y, in the sense that she definitely wants
the X-bundle rather than the Y-bundle.
o If the consumer is indifferent between two bundles of goods, we use
the symbol ∼ and write X~Y. Indifference means that the consumer
would be just as satisfied, according to her own preferences,
consuming the bundle X as she would be consuming bundle Y.
o If the consumer prefers or is indifferent between the two bundles we
say that she weakly prefers X to Y and write X ⪰ Y.
The relations of strict preference, weak preference, and indifference
are not independent concepts; the relations are themselves related.
For example, if X ⪰ Y and Y ⪰ X, we can conclude that X ~Y.
That is, if the consumer thinks that X is at least as good as Y and
that Y is at least as good as X, then she must be indifferent
between the two bundles of goods.
Similarly, if X ⪰ Y but we know that it is not the case that X~ Y,
we can conclude that X≻Y.
This just says that if the consumer thinks that X is at least as good
as Y, and she is not indifferent between the two bundles, then she
thinks that X is strictly better than Y.
3.2 The concept of utility
Economists use the term utility to describe the satisfaction or
pleasure derived from the consumption of a good or service.
Utility is the power of the product to satisfy human wants.
Given any two consumption bundles X and Y, the consumer
definitely wants the X-bundle than the Y-bundle if and only if the
utility of X is better than the utility of Y.
Q. Do you think that utility and usefulness are synonymous? Do
two individuals always derive equal satisfaction from consuming
the same level of a product?
Answer: Utility’ and ‘Usefulness’ are not synonymous.
Usefulness is product centric whereas utility is consumer centric.
Utility is subjective.
The utility of a product will vary from person to person.
That means, the utility that two individuals derive from
consuming the same level of a product may not be the same.
For example, non-smokers do not derive any utility from cigarettes.
Utility can be different at different places and time.
For example, the utility that we get from drinking coffee early in
the morning may be different from the utility we get during lunch
time.
3.3 Approaches of measuring utility
Q. How do you measure or compare the level of satisfaction (utility)
that you obtain from goods and services?
There are two major approaches to measure or compare
consumer‘s utility: cardinal and ordinal approaches.
The cardinalist school postulated that utility can be measured
objectively.
According to the ordinalist school, utility is not measurable in
cardinal numbers rather the consumer can rank or order the utility
he derives from different goods and services.
3.3.1 The cardinal utility theory
According to the cardinal utility theory, utility is measurable by
arbitrary unit of measurement called utils in the form of 1, 2, 3
etc.
E.g, we may say that consumption of an orange gives Rahel 10
utils and a banana gives her 8 utils, and so on.
From this, we can assert that Rahel gets more satisfaction from
orange than from banana.
Assumptions of cardinal utility theory
1. Rationality of consumers. The main objective of the consumer is to
maximize his/her satisfaction given his/her limited budget or income.
2. Utility is cardinally measurable. Utility is measured in subjective
units called utils.
3. Constant marginal utility of money. A given unit of money
deserves the same value at any time or place it is to be spent.
4. Diminishing marginal utility (DMU). The utility derived from
each successive units of a commodity diminishes.
5. The total utility of a basket of goods depends on the quantities of
the individual commodities. If there are n commodities in the bundle
with quantities X1 , X2 ,...Xn , the total utility is given by TU = f ( X1
, X2,......X n ).
Total and marginal utility
Total Utility (TU) is the total satisfaction a consumer gets from
consuming some specific quantities of a commodity at a
particular time.
As the consumer consumes more of a good per time period,
his/her total utility increases.
Marginal Utility (MU) is the extra satisfaction a consumer
realizes from an additional unit of the product. In other words,
marginal utility is the change in total utility that results from the
consumption of one more unit of a product.
Graphically, it is the slope of total utility.
Mathematically, marginal utility is:
“THEORY OF
PRODUCTION AND COST”