Chapter Two Micro
Chapter Two Micro
Chapter Two Micro
Chapter objectives
After successful completion of this chapter, you will be able to:
Explain consumer preferences and utility
Differentiate between cardinal and ordinal utility approach
Define indifference curve and discuss its properties
Derive and explain the budget line
Describe the equilibrium condition of a consumer
2.1 Consumer preferences
• Weak preference
• Given any two consumption bundles(X1,X2) and (Y1,Y2),if the consumer is indifferent
between the two commodity bundles or if (X1,X2) or (Y1,Y2),the consumer would be
equally satisfied if he consumes (X1,X2) or (Y1,Y2)
• Completeness
• For any two commodity bundles X and Y,a consumer will prefer X to Y, Y to X or will be
indifferent between the two.
• Transitivity
• It means that if a consumer prefers basket A to basket B and to basket C, then the
consumer also prefers A to C.
• More is better than less
• Consumers always prefer more of any good to less and they are never satisfied or
satiated. However, bad goods are not desirable and consumers will always prefer less
of them.
2.2 The concept of utility
than the Y bundle if (X1, X2) > (Y1,Y2).This means, the consumer preferred
bundle (X1, X2) to bundle (Y1,Y2) if and only if the utility (X1, X2) is larger
Total Utility (TU) is the total satisfaction a consumer gets from consuming
some specific quantities of a commodity at a particular time.
if a consumer consumes 4 units of a commodity and derives U1, U2, U3
and U4 from the successive units consumed, then TU = U1+U2+U3+U4.
In case the number of commodities consumed is greater than one, then
TU= TUx TUy + TUz + ……… TUn
As the consumer consumes more of a good per time period, his/her total
utility increases.
2.3.1.2 Total and marginal utility….
Given his limited income and the price level of goods and services, what
combination of goods and services should he consume so as to get the
maximum total utility?
a) the case of one commodity
• Suppose the consumer’s utility function is given as
• U =f (X)
• his/her total income spent (expenditure) on commodity X
• Total Expenditure would be: TE = QxPx
• where Qx is amount of commodity x and Px is price of good X.
2.3.1.4 Equilibrium of a consumer
Suppose the consumer’s utility function is given as U =f (X)
his/her total income spent (expenditure) on commodity X –Total
Expenditure would be: TE = QxPx
• where Qx is amount of commodity x and
• Px is price of good X.
• The consumer would like to maximize the difference between
the utility (satisfaction) and expenditure (sacrifice).
• The problem is a simple maximization of the function.
2.3.1.4 Equilibrium of a consumer
• The equilibrium condition of a consumer that consumes a single good X
occurs when the marginal utility of X is equal to its market price.
Proof
Given the utility function U f (X)
• If the consumer buys commodity X, then his expenditure
• the consumer would like to maximizes the difference between his utility and
expenditure.
• Max U – TE or
• U – Px Qx
• The problem is a simple maximization of the function.
• Two conditions must be fulfilled
• Necessary Condition (F.O.C)
• Sufficient Condition (S.O.C)
• The necessary condition (First Order Condition) for maximum,
require that the derivative of the function with respect to
independent variable (Qx) must be equal to zero.
dU d (Q X PX )
0
dQ X dQ X
MUx - Px =0
MU X PX
MUx
1
Px 24
2.3.1.4 Equilibrium of a consumer
• At any point above point C (like point A) where MUX > PX, it pays the consumer
to consume more.
• When MUX < PX (like point B), the consumer should consume less of X.
26
Cardinal Utility (cont…)
• He continues to switch his expenditure from one commodity to the
other till he reaches a stage where MU of each commodity is equal
per unit of expenditure
• Therefore, the consumer optimum follows the law of equi-marginal
utility.
• We can use a single commodity case to determine the general case.
• For commodity X, equilibrium occurs when MUx = Px
• MUx = Px and this can be written as
• MUx / Px = 1
27
• if the consumer consumes a bundle of n commodities i.e X1, X2
X3…… Xn , he/she would be in equilibrium or utility is maximized if
and only if:
i. when the marginal utility per money spent is equal for each good purchased
MU X 1 MU X 2 MU X n
.........
PX 1 PX 2 PX n
ii. his money income available for the purchase of the goods is exhausted.
In genral
b) the case of two or more commodities
For the case of two or more goods, the consumer‘s equilibrium is achieved
when the marginal utility per money spent is equal for each good purchased
and his money income available for the purchase of the goods is exhausted.
Example: Suppose Saron has 7 Birr to be spent on two goods: banana and
bread. The unit price of banana is 1 Birr and the unit price of a loaf of bread is
4 Birr.
The total utility she obtains from consumption of each good is given below.
Cont………………………………
• Exercise: Consider a consumer having only birr 7 in his
pocket to buy bread and banana
If the Price of banana is birr 4/kg and price of bread is birr
one per unit determine.
i. His marginal utility schedule for the two commodities
ii. Determine his optimum consumption of these two goods
iii. The total utility at optimum consumption
Bread, Price=birr 1/unit Banana, Price=4birr/kg
Quantity TU MU MU/P Quantity TU MU MU/P
of
0 0 0 0
1 6 1 12
2 11 2 20
3 14 3 26
4 13 4 29
5 13 5 32
6 11 6 31
Solutions
Bread , Price=birr 1/unit Banana, Price=4birr/kg
Quantity TU M MU/P Quantity TU MU MU/P
0 0 - - 0 0 - -
1 6 6 6 1 12 12 3
2 11 5 5 2 20 8 2
3 14 3 3 3 26 6 1.5
4 13 1 1 4 29 3 0.75
5 13 0 0 5 32 2 .5
6 11 -2 -2 6 31 -1 -0.25
2.3.1.6. Deriving Cardinalist Demand
• The marginal utility is the slope of the total utility function.
• The derivation of demand curve is base don the concept of diminishing
marginal utility.
• If the marginal utility is measured using monetary units the demand curve for a
commodity is the same as the positive segment of the marginal a
utility curve.
P1
Price b
P
c
P2
MUX
O Quantity
PriceP1
P
Demand
P2 Curve
O Quantit
Q1 Q Q2 y
Quantity of Y Deriving Cardinalist Demand
E3 P3
E2
P2
E1 P1
X1
1 X2 MU X Quantity of X
Price
a
P3
P2 b
P1 c
Demand Curve
X1 X2 X3 Quantity of X
2.3.1.5. Cardinal Utility (cont…)
Limitation of the Cardinal approach
a) The assumption that utility is a cardinal concept (utility is
objectively measurable) is doubtful.
• Utility is a subjective concept, which cannot be measured objectively.
b) The assumption of constant marginal utility of money is also
unrealistic..
c) The psychological law of diminishing marginal utility has been
established from introspection
d) The cardinal utility approach is on the basis of Ceteris Paribus
assumption.
• As a result it ignores the substitution and income effect.
35
2.3.2 The ordinal utility theory
In the ordinal utility approach, it is not possible for consumers to express the
utility of various commodities they consume in absolute terms, like 1 util, 2
utils, or 3 utils but it is possible to express the utility in relative terms.
The consumers can rank commodities in the order of their preferences as 1st,
2nd, 3rd and so on.
Therefore, the consumer need not know in specific units the utility of various
commodities to make his choice.
3.3.2.1 Assumptions of ordinal utility theory
• The ordinal utility approach is explained with the help of indifference curves.
• Therefore, the ordinal utility theory is also known as the indifference curve
approach.
3.3.2.2 Indifference set, curve and map
Indifference set/ schedule is a combination of goods for which the consumer
is indifferent.
It shows the various combinations of goods from which the consumer derives
the same level of satisfaction.
Consider a consumer who consumes two goods X and Y (table 3.3).
3.3.2.2 Indifference set, curve and map
• Indifference curve: An indifference curve shows different combinations of
two goods which yield the same utility (level of satisfaction) to the consumer.
• A set of indifference curves is called indifference map.
3.3.2.3 Properties of indifference curves
Find MRSX,Y.
Exceptional Indifference Curves
• indifference curves are convex to the origin and downward sloping
• However, the shape of the indifference curve reflects the degree of
substitution between the two commodity
• The shape of an indifference curve might be different if the
relationship between two commodities is unique
• Perfect substitutes: perfect substitutes are goods which can be
replaced for one another at a constant rate.
48
Exceptional IC (Cont …)
• Perfect substitutes
Total
IC3
IC2
IC1
Mobile
49
Exceptional IC (Cont …)
• Perfect complements: perfect complements are goods which are
to be consumed jointly at a constant rate
• If two commodities are perfect complements the indifference
curve takes the shape of a right angle (L –shape)
• Graphically it is shown as follows.
50
Exceptional IC (Cont …)
• Perfect complements
IC3
IC2
IC1
Right shoe
Left shoe 51
Exceptional IC (Cont …)
• A useless good: This shows the relationship between useless
good and another normal good.
• A good example is outdated book and food.
• since the outdated books are totally useless, increasing their
purchases does not increase utility.
• The person enjoys a higher level of utility only by getting
additional food consumption
• The indifference curve in this case will have a vertical one
52
Exceptional IC (Cont …)
• Fig.
IC1 IC2 IC3
Out dated
books
Food 53
3.3.2.5 The budget line or the price line
In reality, the consumer is constrained by his/her income and prices of the two
commodities.
This constraint is often presented with the help of the budget line.
The budget line is a set of the commodity bundles that can be purchased if the
entire income is spent.
It is a graph which shows the various combinations of two goods that a
consumer can purchase given his/her limited income and the prices of the two
goods
In order to draw a budget line facing a consumer, we consider the following
assumptions.
There are only two goods bought in quantities, say, X and Y.
Each consumer is confronted with market determined prices, PX and PY.
The consumer has a known and fixed money income (M).
3.3.2.5 The budget line or the price line
• Assuming that the consumer spends all his/her income on the two goods (X
and Y), we can express the budget constraint as:
• M P X P Y
X Y By rearranging the above equation, we can derive the
following general equation of a budge t line.
• Graphically,
3.3.2.5 The budget line or the price line
• Note that:The slope of the budget line is given is by (the ratio of the prices
of the two goods).
Any combination of the two goods within the budget line (such as point A) or
along the budget line is attainable.
• Any combination of the two goods outside the budget line (such as point B)
is unattainable (unaffordable).
• Example: A consumer has $100 to spend on two goods X and Y with prices $3
and $5 respectively.
• Derive the equation of the budget line and sketch the graph.
3.3.2.5 The budget line or the price line
Solution: The equation of the budget line can be derived as follows.
When the consumer spends all of her income on good Y, we get the Y-
intercept (0,20).
Similarly, when the consumer spends all of her income on good X, we obtain
the X- intercept (33.3,0). Using these two points we can sketch the graph of
the budget line.
Change in Income
If the income of the consumer changes (keeping the prices of the commodities
unchanged), the b udget line also shifts (changes).
It is important to note that the slope of the budget line (the ratio of the two
prices) does not change when income rises or falls.
Change in Income
Figure 3.7: Effects of increase (right) and decrease (left) in income on the
budget line
Change in prices:
An equal increase in the prices of the two goods shifts the budget line inward.
Since the two goods become expensive, the consumer can purchase the lesser
amount of the two goods.
An equal decrease in the prices of the two goods, one the other hand, shifts the
budget line out ward.
Since the two goods become cheaper, the consumer can purchase the more
amounts of the two goods.
Change in prices:
Figure 3.8: Effect of proportionate increase (inward) and decrease (out ward)
in the prices of both goods
Change in prices:
Figure 3.9: Effect of decrease in the price of only good X on the budget line
3.3.2.6 Equilibrium of the consumer
The preferences of a consumer (what he/she wishes to purchase) are indicated by
the indifference curve.
The budget line specifies different combinations of two goods (say X and Y) the
consumer can purchase with the limited income.
This occurs at the point where the indifference curve is tangent to the budget line
so that the slope of the indifference curve (MRS XY ) is equal to the slope of the
3.3.2.6 Equilibrium of the consumer……
Figure 3.10: Consumer equilibrium under indifference curve approach
The budget line specifies different combinations of two goods (say X and Y) the
consumer can purchase with the limited income.
This occurs at the point where the indifference curve is tangent to the budget line
so that the slope of the indifference curve (MRS XY ) is equal to the slope of the
3.3.2.6 Equilibrium of the consumer
Example: A consumer consuming two commodities X and Y has the utility
function U(X,Y) =XY + 2X . The prices of the two commodities are 4 birr and 2
birr respectively. The consumer has a total income of 60 birr to be spent on the
two goods.
• Solution
• a) The budget constraint of the consumer
is given by:
• PX.X+ PY.Y = M
• 4X+2Y= 60 …………….…………. (i)
• Solution
• (At the equilibrium, MRS can also be calculated as the ratio of the prices of the two
goods)
End of the Chapter
•.
! ! !
n d fo r
e E u n
h
T k y o tio
a n e n
h
T rA tt
o u
y