FROM PATRONAGE TO PROGRAM:
THE EMERGENCE OF PARTY-ORIENTED LEGISLATORS IN BRAZIL
Frances Hagopian, Carlos Gervasoni, and Juan Andres Moraes
Working Paper #344 – December 2007
Frances Hagopian is Michael P. Grace II Associate Professor of Latin American Studies
in the Department of Political Science and a faculty fellow of the Kellogg Institute at the
University of Notre Dame. Her recent works include The Third Wave of Democratization
in Latin America (Cambridge University Press, 2005), (coedited with Scott Mainwaring)
and Religious Pluralism, Democracy, and the Catholic Church in Latin America (Notre
Dame University Press, forthcoming).
Carlos Gervasoni (MA Political Science, Latin American Studies, Stanford University)
is a PhD candidate in the Political Science Department at the University of Notre Dame
and a professor of political science (on leave) at the Pontificia Universidad Católica
Argentina and Universidad Torcuato Di Tella in Buenos Aires. He has published several
articles on the politics of economic reform in Latin America, Argentine politics, and
electoral behavior.
Juan Andres Moraes is a PhD candidate in the Political Science Department at the
University of Notre Dame. His dissertation focuses on constituency service in Latin
America, with emphasis on Uruguay and Costa Rica. He is coauthor (with Daniel Buquet
and Daniel Chasquetti) of Fragmentación Política y Gobierno en Uruguay: ¿Un enfermo
imaginario? [Political Fragmentation and Government in Uruguay: An Imaginary
Patient?] (Universidad de la República, 1998).
Acknowledgements
We thank Diego Miranda, Guilherme Canela, and students at the University of Brasília
for help with administering the surveys on which this article is based; Fabiano Santos and
Marcio Grijó Vilarouca for sharing data on legislative roll-call votes in the 51st legislature
from the NECON/IUPERJ databank; Jon Bischof for superb research assistance; and
David Nickerson for methodological advice. We also thank for comments on earlier
versions of this work participants in the 2005 Kellogg Institute Regional Workshops,
Michael Coppedge, Wendy Hunter, Scott Mainwaring, Carlos Pereira, and Ben
Schneider, and at the David Rockefeller Center for Latin American Studies at Harvard
University, John Carey, Scott Desposato, Jorge Domínguez, Gretchen Helmke, Mala
Htun, and Steven Levitsky.
2
3
ABSTRACT
This paper explains the unanticipated emergence of party-oriented legislators and rising
party discipline in Brazil since the early 1990s. We contend that deputies in Brazil have
become increasingly party-oriented because the utilities of party-programmatic and
patronage-based electoral strategies shifted with market reforms, which created a
programmatic cleavage in Brazilian politics and diminished the resource base for state
patronage. Based on an original survey of the Brazilian Congress, we introduce new
measures of partisan campaigns, party polarization, and the values legislators attach to
party program and voter loyalty. Regression analysis confirms that deputies who believe
voters value party program run partisan, programmatic campaigns, and those in polarized
parties and those who believe voters are loyal to the party are willing to delegate
authority to party leaders and do not switch parties. Party polarization and the proximity
of deputies’ policy preferences to their party’s mean explain discipline on 236 roll-call
votes in the 51st legislature (1999–2001).
RESUMEN
Este artículo explica el inesperado surgimiento de legisladores orientados hacia los
partidos y la creciente disciplina partidaria en Brasil desde principios de los 90s.
Sostenemos que los diputados en Brasil han devenido crecientemente orientados hacia los
partidos porque las utilidades de las estrategias electorales partido-programáticas y
basadas en el patronazgo cambiaron con las reformas de mercado, las que crearon un
clivaje programático en la política brasileña y redujeron la base de recursos para el
patronazgo estatal. Con base en una encuesta original del Congreso Brasileño,
presentamos nuevas mediciones acerca de las campañas partidarias, la polarización de
partidos y los valores que los legisladores asignan al programa partidario y a la lealtad de
los votantes. El análisis de regresión confirma que los diputados que creen que los
votantes valoran el programa del partido, desarrollan campañas partidarias y
programáticas y que aquellos que se encuentran en partidos polarizados y quienes creen
que los votantes son leales al partido, están dispuestos a delegar autoridad a los líderes de
los partidos y no cambian de partido. La polarización de los partidos y la proximidad de
las preferencias de política de los diputados respecto de la media de sus partidos explican
la disciplina en 236 votaciones nominales en la 51º legislatura (1999–2001).
4
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and
Moraes
1
Why, in emerging democracies, where stable bonds between parties and voters are often
elusive and candidates compete for office more on the basis of the particularistic benefits
they can deliver to constituents than on their party’s programs of government, do party
parliamentary delegations become more disciplined and parties and politicians transform
the basis of their linkages with voters from clientelism to program? The move to partyoriented representation is typically explained, if at all, in one of two ways: as a response
to voters demanding—and rewarding—disciplined, programmatic challengers at the
polls, usually because their political tastes change along with socioeconomic
development; or as the result of change imposed by leaders who enjoy centralized control
over their parties. There has been less theoretical and empirical attention paid to the
alternative—incumbent politicians voluntarily surrender the autonomy they enjoy under a
particularistic system to their party leaders and shift the basis on which they mobilize
voters. This article focuses on such a possibility in the case of Brazil.
Brazilian parties of the center and right, hobbled by shallow roots in the electorate
and high rates of electoral volatility, have long been reputed to be among the weakest in
Latin America. In a system marked by permissive party legislation, electoral rules that
disjoin legislators from party leaders, and a brand of decentralized federalism that makes
nonlegislative political careers attractive, the common wisdom is that opportunistic
politicians hoping to build post-legislative careers in state and municipal executive office
switch parties at will and defect from their parties in legislative committees and on the
floor of Congress because leaders lack ballot control and other means with which to
sanction them. Unreliable parliamentary majorities, in turn, supposedly make party
governance nearly impossible or at minimum very expensive, as deputies must be bought.
Even former President Fernando Henrique Cardoso (1996: 13) once lamented that
Brazil’s fragmented, “ideologically fuzzy” political parties and autonomous politicians
made the task of gathering a majority for a bill a “case-by-case exercise” requiring
arduous negotiations.
Of late, however, there are signs that Brazilian parties are growing stronger:
electoral volatility is down and party unity in congressional voting has risen. Arguably,
parties are being transformed from loose patronage machines to programmatically
coherent and distinctive groupings. Key to this transformation is the emergence of
2
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
legislators that forego parochial campaigns, express willingness to delegate more
authority to party leaders, and accept party discipline in floor votes. Such party-oriented
behavior was once believed to be unique to members of the Workers’ Party (PT)—the
2005 corruption scandal that exposed illegal campaign contributions and monthly sidepayments to members of Congress in exchange for votes notwithstanding—but there is
mounting evidence that legislators across the board have exhibited such support of
parties.
This article attempts to explain the emergence in the 1990s of party-oriented
politicians, which we take to be a prelude to stronger parties. We contend that legislators
invest in their parties when the value of their parties’ reputations rises relative to their
personal ones, and that they look to parties to organize their competition in a climate of
growing insecurity over their ability to compete independently. The reasons behind such
a shift in the value of party and personal reputations can vary; in Brazil in the 1990s, the
catalyst was sweeping state and market reform. Once party legislative delegations began
to cohere on a range of contentious economic and administrative reforms and diverge
from their opponents, a distinctive, programmatic cleavage emerged in legislative voting.
At the same time that parties were becoming homogenized and polarized, creating value
for the party brands, state reforms that shrank the scope and resource base for state
patronage diminished the efficiency of personal, patronage-based electoral strategies. A
favorable response by voters to the offer of cohesive and programmatic parties reinforced
the shift from patronage and the personal vote to party and program.
To support our claim that Brazilian politicians are in fact becoming more partyoriented in both the electoral and legislative arenas, we move beyond the familiar records
of floor voting and party switching to examine also the basis of deputies’ campaign
strategies—the first study that we know of to do so—as well as attitudes toward
delegating resources and authority to party leaders. We also introduce new measures of
individual and partisan policy preferences, progressive career ambition, contact with
public officials, and politicians’ beliefs about the reasons for their party’s electoral
success. These measures are built upon responses to a survey of the Brazilian Congress
conducted in 1999-2001. While elite surveys have potential pitfalls—most notably,
respondents may exaggerate the nobility of their work or conceal their true preferences
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
3
and behavior, especially if they engage in clientelism, patronage or corruption (Kitschelt,
2000: 869)—surveys allow us to observe directly individual attitudes, motivations, and
behaviors, enabling a more powerful individual-level analysis of the orientation of
politicians toward parties and constituents than would otherwise be possible. While our
ability to draw conclusions about the degree and source of change is limited by the fact
that our survey captures the attitudes and behavior of politicians from only one Congress,
comparable legislative surveys conducted in 1988 (Mainwaring, 1999) and 1990 (Power,
2000) provide a baseline to chart at least some attitudinal change over time.
The paper proceeds as follows. First, we situate the theoretical debates about the
partisan and parochial behavior of legislators in the context of Brazil, and propose an
alternative explanation that attributes the emergence of party-oriented legislators to the
development of a programmatic dimension of party competition and the increase in the
value of party labels commensurate with a decline in patronage. Electoral, legislative, and
survey data confirm the rise of aggregate levels of party cohesion, programmatic
competition, partisan campaigns, legislative discipline, and pro-party attitudes. Next, we
test our hypotheses and several competing ones at the individual level. We show that 1)
the more polarized their parties, the more legislators perceive voters are loyal to their
party brand and value its program, and 2) the more they cohere around their party’s
positions on key issues, the more loyal, disciplined, and party-oriented they are. The final
part concludes.
PARTY AND PATRONAGE IN BRAZIL
Why do politicians privilege their personal reputations over party loyalty? One view
holds that where voters come cheap—they are poor, relatively uneducated, live in rural
isolation, cast ballots that can be easily monitored, and heavily discount the future—
politicians will make personal and especially patronage-based appeals. Another maintains
that politicians respond to their institutional incentives; in systems with candidatecentered electoral rules, they will cultivate a personal vote. Especially important are rules
governing ballot control, vote pooling, vote types, and district magnitude (Carey and
Shugart, 1995), but in federal systems or those with proscriptions on immediate
4
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
reelection, politicians are also accountable to whoever holds the key to their future career
ambition.
For many years, these theories appeared to explain why Brazilian parties were
fragmented, had shallow roots in the electorate, and lacked legislative discipline.1 On the
one hand, Brazilian politicians competed for the votes of the poor and barely literate in an
underdeveloped society whose late industrialization had delayed the emergence of a
working-class constituency, and parties had been weakened by a strong state and a
neocorporatist, neopatrimonial order (Faoro, 1958; Campello de Souza, 1976: 31, 36;
Mainwaring, 1999: 225-32).2 On the other, elected under a system of open-list
proportional representation in large, statewide, multimember districts (ranging in
magnitude from 8 to 70 and averaging 19.3) in which voters cast a single ballot for the
candidate of their choice, legislators faced with internal party competition had cause to
stake out autonomy from party leaders who did not control ballot access and to develop
their personal reputations (Mainwaring, 1999: 243–62; Ames and Power, 2007). Also
detracting from national party unity were federalism and fiscal decentralization that by
making state- and even municipal-level careers attractive options to reelection shifted the
focus of politicians to state and local parties and diminished their incentive to respond to
national party leaders (Mainwaring, 1999: 264-66; Samuels, 2003). Enough (10 to 15
percent) consistently voted against the majority of their parties on key roll-call votes to
force presidents to assembly fiscally costly multiparty coalitions (Lamounier, 2003: 275).
Moreover, in response to the substantial distributive rewards for joining a governing
coalition or even forming a new party (all leaders would hold seats on legislative
governing and agenda-setting bodies) and in the absence of sanctions by parties or voters,
party switching was endemic. From 1991 to 1995, 32 percent of deputies in the Chamber
changed affiliation, many more than once and even to ideologically noncontiguous
parties (Melo, 2004: 65-66, 102).3
But beginning in the mid-1990s, parties began to sink roots into the electorate and
engender greater loyalty from politicians. Volatility rates in lower chamber elections fell
from 45 percent in 1990 to 21 percent in 1994, and again to 12.5 percent in 1998, a rate
comparable to those of the most institutionalized party systems in Latin America from
1980 to 1997—Argentina (13 percent), Chile (10 percent), and Mexico (15 percent)
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
5
(Roberts and Wibbels, 1999: 577). At the same time, the number of deputies that defected
from their parties fell modestly to 26 percent (with fewer jumping to noncontiguous
ideological camps) (Melo, 2004: 65, 102), and party discipline rose. The Rice Index score
for the Congress as a whole climbed from 68 to 80 from 1986–90 to 1995–99, and it did
so in the catchall parties with low barriers to entry: between the 48th Congress (1987–
1991) and the 51st (1999–2003) party unity rose in the Party of the Liberal Front (PFL)
from 80 to 90, the Party of Brazilian Social Democracy (PSDB) from 67 to 91, and the
Party of the Brazilian Democratic Movement (PMDB), from 62 to 72 (Roma, 2004: 77).
Even in the PFL, known for its autonomous politicians, only 3 percent of legislators
voted against the recommendations of party leaders (with 13 percent abstaining) in the
51st Congress (1998–2002) (Roma, 2004: 81).
Why parties with weak programmatic identities and parochial patterns of
representation would develop more disciplined legislative delegations is puzzling. Brazil
has developed, but not fast enough to account for such impressive party discipline across
delegations from undeveloped states, and institutional incentives did not markedly
change. It is also doubtful that party leaders were able to impose programmatic change
and party discipline, as their counterparts did in Eastern Europe and Argentina
(Grzymala-Busse, 2002; Levitsky, 2003). Some scholars contend that legislative rule
changes in the late 1980s endowed parliamentary party leaders with substantial agendasetting powers and the authority to represent their delegations in procedural questions,
compensating them for candidate-centered electoral rules (Figueiredo and Limongi, 1999:
20–29), as well as the prerogative to make legislative committee assignments and
recommend that individual budget amendments be funded. Other scholars (Amorim Neto
et al., 2003: 558; Samuels 2004) are skeptical, contending that the appeal of committee
appointments is a hollow one and that executives, not party leaders, hold the key to the
pork barrel. Indeed, the impact of party loyalty on gaining seats on key congressional
standing committees during this period was not significant (Santos, 2002). Moreover,
party discipline rates did not begin to rise when the new rules were introduced in 1988
but only after 1994, when Fernando Henrique Cardoso formed a “parliamentary agenda
cartel” (Amorim Neto et al., 2003).
6
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
The thesis attributing party transformation to the demand of voters for more
cohesive and disciplined parties and politicians—because they become wealthier or better
educated; they want sharper partisan differences (as in the second half of the twentieth
century in the United States) (Rohde, 1991; Jacobson, 2000); or they want to influence
national policy, as occurred in Britain in the nineteenth century, when institutional
change deprived backbenchers of access to pork, patronage, and policy initiative and
power shifted to the cabinet and by implication the party that controlled the executive
(Cox, 1987: 136)—does not fare much better. Brazilian voters may have somehow
overcome their own collective action problem to value collective over particularistic
goods (Lyne, 2004), but the evidence that voters in fact demanded more programmatic
parties and collective goods in advance of their offer is thin. Even given falling rates of
electoral volatility, an identical proportion of the Brazilian electorate—45.6 percent—
identified with parties in 1989–1994 and 1995–2002 (Carreirão and Kinzo, 2004: 141–
42). As late as 2002, the only party that was deemed to have true partisans was the PT
(Samuels, 2006). Based on in-depth interviews conducted during the 1994 campaign, one
researcher characterized the typical Brazilian voter as lacking in political information,
moving away from voting on the basis of clientelism but not yet voting on the basis of
program, ideology, or party loyalties, and guided by preferences that were “unstable,
autonomous, and unpredictable” (Silveira, 1998). Respondents to the 2002 Brazilian
National Election Study (ESEB 2002) cited as their most important considerations in
voting for federal deputy the candidate’s record (33 percent) and issue positions (32.5
percent), followed by personal qualities (17 percent); only 7 percent mentioned the
candidate’s party.
One possible solution to our puzzle is that, as the skeptics contend, politicians are
not becoming more party-oriented, but legislative delegations are maintaining discipline
for strategic reasons (Ames, 2002). According to the “two-arena” thesis, autonomous
members support party-backed presidential initiatives in exchange for side payments
from the pork barrel critical for their reelection, and thus parties that are apparently
disciplined in the legislature are in fact weak and fractious in the electoral arena (Pereira
and Mueller 2004). Alternatively, as other leading Brazilian scholars contend, legislators
may allow party leaders to coordinate their votes in order to strengthen their collective
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
7
bargaining position with, and credibly threaten the legislative agenda of, a powerful
executive that concentrates budget-making initiative (Figueiredo and Limongi, 2002:
333; Santos, 2002). Both arguments could explain disciplined floor voting, but neither
would anticipate a broader pattern of party-oriented behavior and a turn from patronagebased to programmatic linkages between politicians and voters. We propose that
politicians are motivated to become party-oriented—to observe party discipline, remain
in their parties, campaign on party program, and be willing to invest their leaders with
real authority—not merely to bargain with the executive but also to develop their party
brands and organize their electoral competition in a context of structural change.
FROM PATRONAGE TO PARTY: A THEORY OF SHIFTING UTILITIES
The scholarly consensus on the choices of linkage strategies made by parties and
politicians generally and in Brazil in particular rests on the assumptions that the resource
base for dispensing patronage to politicians and to voters is stable, and that given access
to state resources demanded by citizens of the districts that hold the greatest electoral
value for them, politicians will cultivate a personal reputation. Further, with most
legislators invested in a personal vote, heterogeneous, catchall parties will be a
semipermanent feature of the political landscape, unless economic development
depresses the demand for patronage and raises the cost of providing it (Kitschelt and
Wilkinson, 2007: 24–28). We begin from the premise that if economic reforms were to
limit levels and access to federal and state government discretionary and patronage
spending—the asset base upon which parties and deputies traditionally made patronage
appeals—politicians’ incentives to preserve their autonomy from party leaders and their
parties as heterogeneous might also change. When such reforms engender programmatic
competition and parties become more homogeneous and polarized—the condition of
“conditional party government” (Aldrich and Rohde, 1998: 5)—at the same time that
access to patronage became restricted, the utility of personal reputations will diminish
relative to the value of the party brand, making party-oriented, programmatic linkage
strategies more attractive than personal, patronage-based ones.
We can think about this shifting calculus theoretically on two levels—that of
individual politicians and parties. Despite the collective incentives to strengthen the party
8
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
brand, individual legislators may yet succumb to their collective action dilemma, buck
the party leadership (which lacks sanctioning power over them), and persist in cultivating
a personal vote even with a shrinking patronage war chest. In the end, politicians in
systems such as Brazil with open-list proportional representation and large district
magnitudes ultimately must compete against one another, and deputies who can bring
pork to their districts may be more likely to be reelected than those who cannot or do not
(Pereira and Renno, 2003). For some deputies, even outright vote buying might still be an
efficient electoral strategy in areas of high poverty or unemployment. But with pork in
short supply and access to it restricted, most will not be able to buy votes. Whether they
cultivate a personal vote on another basis, such as constituency service, personal
experience, or competence; move to valence issues; or stand with their parties in
supporting or opposing government policies on salient—and polarizing—issues of the
day to gain election, they will now need the party label more than before, at minimum in
addition to their own personal reputation (Cox and McCubbins, 1993; Rohde, 1991). The
incentives now exist to work to create value for the party label by observing floor
discipline, conducting programmatic campaigns, and surrendering autonomy to party
leaders to coordinate their competition. In time, a virtuous circle will form: as some
deputies invest in and become oriented toward their parties, more will follow suit. This
argument necessarily assumes voter demand for the party brand. Even if voters do not yet
seek programmatic cohesion specifically and are not the initiators of the move toward
programmatic parties, as we have argued was the case in Brazil, voters most certainly
would reinforce it by becoming more attuned to policy differences between government
and opposition, more appreciative of ideological consistency between national party
leaders and members of Congress, and more responsive to party-oriented appeals. An
offer of party-oriented representation would have to resonate with voters, or else it would
be meaningless.
Party strength, of course, can be based on different things, and the emergence of
party-oriented legislators provides no assurance that party competition and party-citizen
linkages will become more programmatic. To explain the growing value of the party
program, we must view the problem from the perspective of party leaders who seek to
maximize their party’s electoral fortunes. Let us assume they may choose between
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
9
developing a program and coordinating the distribution of patronage resources, as Liberal
Democratic Party leaders did in Japan before 1994 (McCubbins and Rosenbluth 1995).
Even if competition might intensify and the ability to deliver pork might become an even
more prized resource for incumbent parties and politicians when the overall pool of
resources shrinks (Chubb, 1982), liberalizing economic reforms will reduce the number
of candidates who can count on the effectiveness of such a strategy, making it inefficient
from the party’s standpoint. If party leaders cannot distribute enough patronage to win
elections, claiming credit for good public policy outputs or opposing unpopular ones
becomes an attractive alternative. Now not only should deputies adopt more discipline in
the legislature to preserve the party brand, but they should also become more attached to
the party program.
Once more disciplined parliamentary parties make partisan-based electoral
competition imaginable, they also make it viable. This argument inverts the logic of the
two-arena thesis: parties with program value—those that are polarized on policy—create
incentives for autonomous politicians to abandon patronage-based, personal, and
parochial campaign strategies in favor of flying the party banner. Theoretically, the
emergence of conditional party government creates feedback loops to preserve party
discipline in the legislature and partisan value in the electoral arena. We may visualize
this argument as follows:
Figure 1
THE CHANGING UTILITIES OF PROGRAM AND PATRONAGE
Legislative arena
Parties’ increasing
polarization &
homogenization
Increased
value of party
and program
Delegation to leaders
Permanence in party
Economic
Reform
Fewer resources
for patronage
Diminished
value of
patronage-based
campaigns
Legislators invest
more in parties
and less in their
personal reputations
Partisan campaigns
Voters demand
for programmatic
parties
Electoral arena
Legislative discipline
10
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
This theory has several implications. In the aggregate, programmatic competition and a
decline in patronage should create incentives for legislators to vote with party leaders and
campaign on party program. If feedback loops indeed exist, as voters become loyal to
programmatic parties we should expect to see a greater incidence of both. We would also
expect the reduction in patronage and the emergence of programmatically distinctive
parties to lead deputies to confer authority on leaders to apply the whip in floor voting
and guard party ballot access. The implications are not as straightforward for party
switching. Absent sanctions for party-switching, nonideological deputies who seek career
advancement should have an incentive to defect from a party with a weak brand to one
with a stronger one, or to a party that offers opportunity for individual career
advancement in elective or appointed office. And although party leaders should want to
stem the tide in order to provide a credible product to voters, they also have a clear
incentive to welcome heavy hitters, as long as the new entrants are willing to observe
discipline. At the aggregate level, then, we would not necessarily expect party switching
to decline sharply.
Our theory also makes several predictions about which parties and politicians
should exemplify that behavior in the legislative and electoral arenas.
1. At the party level, politicians in parties whose legislative delegations cohere around a
set of key issues on the programmatic divide of state-market reform, and whose mean
position on those issues is polarized, that is, farther from the mean of the entire
legislature, should exhibit more party-oriented behavior than their counterparts in
heterogeneous, centrist parties.4
2. At the individual level, the more deputies
a. believe that program (patronage) has electoral value, the more (less) partyoriented they will be in the electoral arena.
b. believe that the party label has value, the more willing they will be to delegate
authority to party leaders and remain in that party.
c. cohere around their party’s positions on key issues, the more disciplined they will
be.
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
11
SURVEYING PARTY CHANGE IN BRAZIL
Brazil provides an apt case to apply this theory. The signature reforms of the Cardoso
administration—fiscal discipline, privatization of state-owned enterprises, deregulation of
markets, and state administration reforms—removed state discretion over economic
activity, reduced and professionalized the ranks of federal and state-government
employees, and diminished the scope and resource base for patronage and pork (Gaetani
and Heredia, 2002). Legislators also imposed severe limits on the number of budget
amendments that individual members could sponsor in order to recover their credibility
with voters in the wake of the 1993 congressional budget scandal.5 Moreover, the Camata
Law of 1995 (strengthened in 1999), which limited all state government payrolls to 60
percent of state revenue, and the Fiscal Responsibility Law (FRL) of 2000, which set
strict spending limits for all levels of government and prohibited the central government
from refinancing subnational debt, restricted the ability of governors to dispense
patronage.6 At the same time that the utility of particularistic strategies of representation
was declining, economic reforms requiring legislative supermajorities to amend the
constitution to allow foreign investment into strategic sectors, privatize state monopolies,
and reform the state administration sparked vibrant congressional and public debates in
the 1990s and eventually a programmatic divide.
To ascertain whether Brazilian politicians are oriented toward their parties or their
constituents, and if and why they are abandoning patronage for program, we must move
beyond the voting records, constituency characteristics, and ideological self-placement
scores that have not resolved the debate on Brazilian parties. We draw upon our 1999–
2000 survey of the Brazilian Congress to ascertain whether or not partisan legislative
delegations have become more cohesive and distinctive and to develop new measures of
party-oriented behavior and attitudes. A sixteen-page questionnaire was mailed to every
member of the Brazilian Congress in June 1999. Initial responses were supplemented
with personal interviews to achieve a sample representative of the Congress by party,
region, gender, and level of legislative activity7 (the chi2 statistics testing the null
hypothesis that the observed and expected number of cases by party, region, gender, and
legislative activity are the same yield p-values of 0.52, 0.91, 0.95, and 0.47 respectively)
(See Appendix A).
12
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
To build a measure of party homogenization and cohesion, we use a simple
standard deviation score to measure the dispersion of policy preferences for politicians on
a cluster of twenty state and market reforms included in our survey that constitute a
single dimension of competition.8 Partisan cohesion rates ranged from a fairly cohesive
.40 for the PSDB and .51 for the PT to a moderate .68 for the rightist Brazilian
Progressive Party (PPB) (now the PP), and a higher score of .85 for the PMDB and .87
for the PFL (now the Democratas). If not all Brazilian parties are homogeneous, they are
comparatively quite programmatically polarized on policy. To gauge the spread of
partisan preferences, we measured the distance between mean scores on this cluster of
state and market reforms for the PSDB-PFL governing alliance on the one hand and its
principal opposition, the PT and other left parties on the other, by calculating the absolute
distance between party means, which range from -2 to 2, and dividing these by the
maximum spread (4)—an adaptation of the Sani and Sartori (1983) measure of
ideological polarization. This distance (.55) was wider than that between the Peronists
and the Radical-Frepaso opposition in Argentina in 1997 (.50), and substantially wider
than between the Concertación and its rightist opposition in Chile in 1998 (.31) and the
PAN and the PRI-PRD opposition in Mexico in 2001 (.31) on similar clusters of statemarket reforms.9 Without a reliable baseline it is hard to make temporal comparisons of
party cohesiveness and distinctiveness, but based on an analysis of the ideal points of
legislators drawn from policy preferences expressed in 1995 and their voting records
from 1986 through 2004, Roma (2004: 69) concluded that party polarization sharpened
during the Cardoso presidency (1995–2002), especially in 1996 and 1999.10
To determine whether or not homogeneous and polarized parties also generated
the conditions for the emergence of party-oriented legislators, we turn to other survey
evidence, which confirms that in the aggregate attitudes also changed over time.11 The
percentage of legislators who, when given a choice between favoring the interests of their
district (their state), their party, or both would choose their state fell from 56 percent in
Mainwaring’s 1988 survey to 40 percent in 1999–2000, and twice as many (22 percent)
said they would take the interests of both party and state more or less equally into account
in 1999–2000 than in 1988 (when 11 percent did) (Mainwaring, 1999: 160). Brazilian
legislators also evinced a greater willingness to surrender autonomy to party leaders.
13
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
Deputies were asked by Power in 1990 and again in our survey in 1999–2000 to offer
their views on whether party leaders should exercise the whip on votes and expel a
member who voted against the party line, whether Brazil should adopt a closed-list
proportional representation electoral system, and whether there should be sanctions for
party switching. While support for application of the party whip was stable and support
for expelling members who defied the party whip actually fell slightly, support for a
change from open- to closed-list proportional representation increased by a third (from 27
to 36 percent) and support for expelling from the legislature representatives who switched
out of the parties on whose ticket they had been elected rose by 15 percent (from 55 to 63
percent) (Mainwaring, 1999: 168).
The value of the party label for Brazilian politicians also rose. By 2000, 37
percent of Brazilian politicians believed both their party label and personal reputation
were important to their election, and 58 percent attributed their election “almost
exclusively” (23 percent) or “largely” (35 percent) to their personal effort, a significant
decline since 1990 when 82 percent did (Power, 2000: 126).12 The factors politicians
believed most contributed to their party’s electoral success at the state level were the
party’s image, the image of its state leaders, and the loyalty of its voters; among the
perceived least important factors were the resources the party delivered to the state in the
preceding electoral cycle and those anticipated by voters in the future.13
By 1998 deputies on the whole also campaigned to a greater extent on issues and
on themes overlapping with what they perceived to be key aspects of their party’s
platform than on the basis of patronage, parochial, and personal appeals. Only 9 deputies
(out of 119 who answered this question) in the survey identified as one of their three most
important campaign appeals in 1998 their promise to work for resources or projects for
the municipality or the region. Of 357 (=119*3) total possible campaign messages, only
69 (19 percent) courted a personal vote (34 made parochial appeals, 24 stressed such
personal qualities as honesty, integrity, experience, and dedication; and 11 promised
patronage). Most appealed to voters on the valence issues that mattered most to them—
health, education, corruption/ethics in government, and unemployment (35 percent), on
more sharply polarized issues (38 percent), or on party-oriented appeals (4 percent). The
remaining 4 percent corresponds to missing answers.
14
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
Accompanying this shift, voters also attached value to party brands and
ideological consistency. In addition to declining electoral volatility, which could be
explained by other factors, 14 Lyne (2004: 24–27) contends that “partisan tides” (which
measure the change in party fortunes across elections and are generally taken to indicate
that some component of voters’ choice is driven by partisan positions on national issues
[cf. Cox and McCubbins, 1993]) were in evidence for all major parties except the PDT in
the 1990s. She also finds evidence of a clear decline in the pattern of successful deputy
candidates gathering most of their vote in municipalities in which they dominate—the
archetypal pattern evident in clientelistic systems—in favor of more dispersed votes
across their states over the period (Lyne 2004: 31). Voters rewarded ideological
consistency in the 1998 legislative elections by punishing incumbents in the rightist
coalition that had not voted with the government and their counterparts in the leftist
opposition that had not voted against the government (Pereira and Renno, 2003: 442–43).
Vote buying campaigns may also be less attractive than they once were; the Catholic
Church has spearheaded grassroots campaigns exhorting citizens not to sell their votes
but to cast them for parties with proposals for dealing with poverty.
CHOOSING PARTY AND PROGRAM: VARIABLES AND MEASUREMENT
To learn if Brazilian politicians are investing in strengthening their party labels and
programs or voting in a disciplined fashion because they are being handsomely rewarded
for their votes requires individual-level analysis. We draw from our survey to develop
new measures of politicians’ campaign strategies, willingness to accept rules changes,
cohesion on party program, and beliefs about the value voters place on patronage,
program, and the party label. We also reproduce measures used by other scholars to test
competing hypotheses about the behavior of Brazilian legislators. (See Appendix B for
the definition, measurement, and summary statistics for all dependent and independent
variables, including the wording of survey questions that generated them).
Dependent Variables
Our four dependent variables measure politicians’ behavior and attitudes. The first
(PARTISAN CAMPAIGN) measures campaign strategies based on program, taking into
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
15
account both the content of a deputy’s campaign appeals and their overlap with her
party’s positions. (See Appendix C for coding rules). The second (DELEGATION)
represents an index of average agreement with four party-oriented rule changes: (1) the
party whip should be applied to floor votes; (2) deputies should be expelled from their
party for voting against the party whip; (3) closed-list proportional representation should
be adopted; and (4) legislators should forfeit their mandates for party switching. While
questions about floor voting are theoretically separable from those about ballot access
and expulsion for party switching, they are empirically linked and do capture a single
dimension of underlying orientation toward parties (factor analysis strongly confirmed
the unidimensionality of the four items; Cronbach’s alpha=0.81). Our third dependent
variable (NO SWITCH) is a measure of post-1998 party switching. Since we want to
measure party loyalty, not a deputy’s degree of fickleness, we built this as a dichotomous
measure in which deputies who switched parties at least once are coded as one. Our
fourth and final dependent variable is voting discipline (DISCIPLINE), which represents the
percentage of the total number of votes on which a deputy followed or defected from the
recommendation of her party leaders on a set of 236 roll-call votes held during the first
three years of the 51st legislature (1999–2001) in which 10 percent of the Chamber either
voted contrary to the majority or absented themselves from the floor vote, and on which
the leader of at least one party issued a recommendation contrary to her counterparts.15
Changing Utilities
To test the effect of programmatic cohesion and polarization on the orientation of
legislators toward parties, we create variables of cohesion (COHESION) and polarization
(PARTY POLARIZATION) for each party, which we assign to deputies in those parties.
Because these are highly correlated (r=0.71) and produce severe multicollinearity when
both are used in our regressions, we include only the latter (results are broadly similar
when the former is used). We expect this variable to be significant for each of our four
dependent variables. At the individual level, our predictions are more fine-tuned. We
expect the more politicians believe the party label has value, which we measure by
deputies’ perceptions of the importance of voter loyalty to their party’s state-level
performance in the last election (VOTER LOYALTY VALUE), the less likely to abandon the
16
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
party and more willing to delegate authority to party leaders they will be. But because
party loyalty can be generated for a number of reasons (program, competence,
patronage), we believe the impact of voter loyalty on the type of campaigns deputies run
should be neutral. Here, we expect the more deputies credit the party program for their
party’s electoral success (PROGRAM VALUE), the more they will campaign on a
programmatic basis, and the more they credit that success to patronage (PATRONAGE
VALUE),
the less they will do so. Finally, to determine the independent impact of a
deputy’s own policy preferences on legislative behavior, we calculate the distance
between the average mean score of each deputy on the cluster of twenty salient state and
market reforms and initiatives and the mean score of her party on those same policies
(POLICY DISTANCE). We expect the higher this score, and thus the more distant a
legislator’s views from her party’s position, the less likely she would be to delegate
authority to party leaders and to follow their instructions on floor votes
Rival Hypotheses and Control Variables
The first group of variables tests the competing “electoral connection hypothesis”: (a)
electoral security (ELECTORAL SECURITY), which we measure as the number of votes a
deputy received minus the number of votes of the first alternate, over number of votes of
first alternate (this number is easily interpretable as the factor by which a given deputy
cleared the minimum number of votes needed to be elected). To take into account the
electoral risk associated with a certain party or coalition not reaching the electoral
threshold, we performed a similar calculation for the deputy’s party or coalition. When
this number was smaller than 1 (i.e., the party or coalition obtained less than twice as
many votes as the threshold), we used it to adjust the security of the deputy downward
(by multiplying her individual electoral security score by the party/coalition score). The
resulting number was logged to reflect the diminishing value of each additional vote over
the minimum to be elected; (b) electoral dominance (DOMINANCE), first introduced by
Ames (1995a, 1995b), which is an average of the percentage of the total votes a deputy
receives in each municipality of the state, weighted by the contribution of that
municipality to her overall total in the state (the district); and (c) the logarithm of district
magnitude (DISTRICT MAGNITUDE) commonly used in studies of Brazilian legislative
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
17
politics. Deputies with higher vote totals relative to their copartisans and those who
dominate districts—those with electoral bailiwicks—should rely on patronage and
personal appeals rather than party reputation and program and be in a stronger position to
switch parties, defy party leaders in floor voting, and maintain rules that preserve their
autonomy. Moreover, if, as institutionalists contend, under open-list proportional
representation the larger the district magnitude, the higher the level of intraparty
competition and the greater the incentives of individual legislators to cultivate a personal
reputation, then deputies in states with large district magnitudes should display less
partisan loyalty in campaigning.
A second set of variables tests a second major competing hypothesis for the
orientation of individual legislators: their progressive career ambition. By drawing
responses from our survey about which post the deputy sought next (reelection; senator;
governor; mayor; federal administrative post; state administrative post; or a position
outside politics), we can improve on the standard measure of career ambition—the post a
deputy next contested and/or filled—which imputes a retrospective consciousness to the
decisions guiding earlier actions and eliminates all ambitions that did not materialize,
especially for administrative appointments. We create a dummy variable, STATE
AMBITION (those
with ambitions to be elected mayor or governor or to acquire an
administrative post at the state level), and expect legislators focused on local and state
political careers to exhibit a negative sign on all four party-oriented behaviors (most
legislators who do not report state ambition report federal ambition; the resulting high
collinearity does not allow us to include both variables in the same regression). We also
consider the resources of individual politicians and the strength of their networks by
tapping survey responses on the frequency of contact the deputy has with local politicians
to create a LOCAL CONTACT variable; and with the state governor, cabinet secretaries, and
directors and superintendents of state agencies to create a variable of STATE CONTACT (the
three items are clearly unidimensional; Cronbach’s alpha = .91). We interact the latter
with membership in the state governing coalitions (STATE COALITION), as the effect of
state contacts are expected to be different for politicians in the government or the
opposition. Finally, we control for levels of development—expected to depress voter
demand for patronage-based campaigns, party switching, and politicians’ autonomy and
18
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
indiscipline—using the log of per capita state income (GDP PER CAPITA).
To test whether rising rates of party unity on legislative votes are a product of a
successful bargaining process in which deputies are satisfied with their individual payoffs
(Ames, 2002: 193–194), or part of a broader phenomenon of growing party-oriented
behavior among politicians also requires a measure of strategic incentives. Following
other scholars (Ames, 2002; Pereira and Mueller, 2004), we identify the percentage of
individual budget amendments funded by the executive in the two-year period from 2000
to 2001 (for amendments passed in 1999 and 2000) (AMENDMENTS FUNDED [%]), but we
interact this variable with membership in the federal governing coalition (COALITION) to
allow for different expectations for members of the governing and opposition parties. We
also test whether these same incentives may have a bearing on party switching and proparty attitudes, but do not expect them to have retrospectively influenced the kinds of
campaigns politicians ran.
We test these hypotheses using OLS regression models for party campaigning,
voting discipline, and delegation, and a logistic regression model for party switching. For
each dependent variable we proceed in two steps: we begin with a baseline model that
tests our hypotheses as well as existing competing ones, then drop all variables that are
far from statistical significance (t-ratio<1) in order to obtain more precise estimates for
the more significant coefficients. Table 1 summarizes our predictions and our results.
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes 19
TABLE 1
EXPLAINING PARTY-ORIENTED BEHAVIOR
Theoretical Approach and
Partisan Campaigns
Delegation
Variables (predicted effects Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4
in parentheses)
Electoral Connection
(-) ELECTORAL SECURITY
.28
.25
.01
-(.20)
(.19)
(.16)
(-) DISTRICT MAGNITUDE
.17
---(LOG)
(.25)
(-) DOMINANCE
-.10
-.60
-(1.37)
(.95)
Progressive Career Ambition
(-) STATE AMBITION
.12
--.09
-(.25)
(.20)
Level of Development
(+) GDP PER CAPITA
.50*
.63***
.33*
.19
(LOG)
(.28)
(.20)
(.19)
(.15)
Networks
(-) LOCAL CONTACT
-22*
-.23*
.08
-(.13)
(.12)
(.11)
(-) STATE CONTACT
.04
--.04
-(.09)
(.12)
(*) STATE COALITION
---.34
-0.39**
(.22)
(.16)
(+) STATE CONTACT *
---.04
-STATE COALITION
(.16)
(*) COALITION
--.26
-(.35)
Material Payoffs
(-)
AMENDMENTS
--.004
-FUNDED (%)
(.010)
(+) COALITION*
---.006
-A MENDMENTS
(.011)
FUNDED (%)
Changing Utilities
(+) PARTY POLARIZATION
(+)
PROGRAM VALUE
(-)
PATRONAGE VALUE
(+)
VOTER LOYALTY
VALUE
POLICY DISTANCE
-.25
(.21)
.28**
(.11)
-.10
(.09)
--
-26
(.20)
.27***
(.10)
-.10
(.08)
--
.70***
(.19)
---
.66***
(.14)
---
No Party Switching
Model 5
Model 6
-.04
(.61)
--
--
.85
(2.66)
--
-.57
(.62)
-.46
(.56)
-8.94***
(3.05)
-7.12***
(2.61)
.77
(.57)
.83*
(.50)
3.59
(2.75)
2.59
(2.25)
--
-2.00
(1.72)
-.82
(1.74)
4.55
(3.44)
-.98
(2.50)
3.65
(5.07)
-1.66
(1.37)
--
.11
(.15)
-.14
(.17)
--
.22
(.35)
-1.10***
(.38)
.41
(.63)
1.38***
(.51)
.01
(1.01)
--
-1.11***
(.33)
.34
(.57)
1.41***
(.45)
--
-1.43
(2.56)
--
--
11.11
(14.42)
--
-.03
(.02)
.02
(.02)
--
.92*
(.52)
--
.98*
(.51)
--
9.21***
(2.77)
--
--
--
--
.29***
.29***
.50*
(.08)
(.07)
(.27)
(-)
--.38
.36*
-(.22)
(.19)
Intercept
-1.72
-2.30
-3.57**
-1.97
-6.78
(2.01)
(1.70)
(1.84)
(1.28)
(5.18)
N
107
110
102
113
110
R2 /PSEUDO R2
.20
.19
.36
.36
.26
2
ADJ R
.11
.14
.26
.33
-Prob > F/ Prob. > chi2
.015
.001
.000
.000
.002
Standard errors in parentheses. *p<.10; **p < .05; ***p < .01.
(*) No effect is predicted because this variable is part of an interaction effect
Voting Discipline
Model 7
Model 8
--
.67***
(.25)
--7.22*
(4.32)
120
.27
-.000
---6.14*
(3.42)
47.67*
(26.23)
106
.32
.23
.000
--
3.71
(2.47)
---
--
9.13***
(2.14)
-----5.34*
(2.98)
58.49***
(19.83)
116
.28
.24
.000
20
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
RESULTS AND DISCUSSION
The empirical findings of this analysis are as significant for what they tell us is not true
about Brazilian politics as for what is. First, contrary to expectations that under open-list
proportional representation deputies would campaign most heartily against one another in
larger districts, the impact of district magnitude on legislators’ campaigns was not
significant. Deputies enjoying clear dominance in select municipalities (rather than
drawing a scattered shot of votes from across the state) were no less likely to campaign
on a partisan and programmatic basis than a patronage, personal, or parochial one. In
fact, our measures of dominance and electoral security were not statistically significant in
any model. More powerful is the impact of development, and our findings suggest we
take seriously the thesis that voter taste changes along with socioeconomic development:
the logged value of per capita state GDP exercised significant and powerful effects on
promoting partisan campaigning. It had an effect on deterring party switching, as other
scholars have found (Desposato, 2006), and it was close to significant on delegation and
voting discipline.
It is also the case that we have overreached in the power we attribute to
progressive career ambition, at least in the case of Brazil. An ambition for a state level
career does exercise a significant and negative effect on floor voting, but not on party
switching, delegation, or the basis of campaign appeals. What this implies is that deputies
who wish to remain in the legislature or join the federal administration have an incentive
to follow parliamentary party leaders, either to preserve the value of the party brand or
for the endorsement or campaign finance assistance of party leaders, relative to those who
plan to shift their careers to local and state venues. At a minimum, these results suggest
that our expectations about the influence of electoral rules and progressive career
ambitions need finer theoretical specification. They are not equally weighty in every form
of behavior.
Most surprising was the apparently limited impact of material payoffs. Using an
interaction term, we find that the percentage of individual budget amendments funded
was not a significant incentive for members of the opposition to defect from their party
leaders or for members of the governing coalition to observe discipline. These findings
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
21
contradict the results obtained by Ames (2002) based on pooled votes in the 49th and 50th
congresses (1991–1998) and Pereira and Mueller (2004: 785) for the 50th, but are
consistent with our theory that the value of patronage as an electoral strategy declined
during the 1990s. By the 51st Congress, when deputies placed greater value on their party
labels and the pork barrel was running dry, their incentives to cooperate with party
leaders in Congress increased. If party switching is primarily driven by political
opportunism—we know that members switch in the months after the election to better
position themselves for party leadership and choice administrative positions—politicians
in the state opposition who are well connected to state officials were significantly more
disposed to switch out of their party, and their well-connected coalition counterparts to
stay loyal. Those who meet frequently with local politicians are less likely to run partisan
campaigns. This is intuitively obvious and should not be controversial. Connections to
local and state politics, however, do not appear to impact voting records. A startling
finding of our survey is that governors were cited as the twelfth and least important
influence on congressional votes.
Our models suggest that other long-standing stereotypes of Brazilian politics may
need to be modified. The presumption that PT membership has a powerful, positive
impact on party-oriented behavior relative to the catchall parties notwithstanding, the PT
in the electorate is not as distinctive from other parties as the PT in the Congress: in
unreported results, a PT dummy was not significant in any party campaign model, and
controlling for party polarization and the value of voter loyalty, PT membership
exercised no independent impact on delegation, party switching, or voting discipline. In
another unreported result, politicians from the Northeast are slightly more likely to
employ clientelist, localist, or personal vote campaigning strategies, but they are more,
not less, likely to observe party discipline. That the Northeast is changing should not be
surprising: a casual glance at the 2006 electoral map confirms that Lula has painted the
Northeast red.
By comparison, the theory of changing utilities finds some support. Membership
in polarized parties is a significant predictor of sticking with one’s party, delegating
authority to party leaders, and heeding the recommendations of party leaders on
controversial floor votes. Legislators who believe the party program holds value in
22
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
elections and that patronage does not are embracing party-oriented campaigning. The
perception that voter loyalty was critical to the party’s electoral success in their home
state significantly influenced deputies not to switch out of their parties, and also served as
a strong inducement to surrender autonomy to party leaders. Finally, deputies who share
their party’s views on the state-market divide are significantly more likely to vote with
their party leaders’ recommendations, though the sign on delegation was not in the
predicted direction. While one might reasonably question whether issue preferences are
endogenous to votes and hence not a good measure of party-enhancing discipline, in fact
the universe of votes was considerably broader than the state-market divide from which
we generated these scores.
CONCLUSIONS
Brazilian politicians, once believed to be among the least party-oriented in Latin
America, are today more faithful to their parties in the legislature and in their
constituencies than they have been at any time since Brazil returned to democratic rule in
1985. Falling rates of electoral volatility and rising legislative voting unity are part of a
broader trend: party delegations are also programmatically coherent and distinctive, and
Brazilian politicians who value their party’s reputation do not sell their votes to the
highest bidder but voluntarily close ranks behind party leaders. While we cannot really
know the extent of this transformation due to a blurry baseline, if we assume that
previous scholarship was not completely erroneous, and if we are correct that there are
party-oriented legislators in Brazil today in parties across the board where strategic
incentives do not exist for them to become so, then we must address the sources and
significance of that transformation.
A series of new measures enables us to provide a more nuanced interpretation of
the effects of the electoral connection, progressive career ambition, and the effects of
development and partisanship than many previous studies. We find that the ambition to
enter state and local politics does indeed exercise a negative effect on floor discipline,
and opposition deputies who have more contact with state government officials are more
likely to switch out of their parties. We also find that high levels of socioeconomic
development spur partisan campaigns and depress party switching. Most surprisingly, a
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
23
pattern of electoral domination of municipalities, highly secure seats, and strategic
payoffs does not predict politicians’ behavior in the electoral or legislative arenas during
the 51st legislature (1999–2002). In light of these results, we need to rethink the
determining influence of electoral institutions, and shift our focus away from using them
to justify an apparent weakness of Brazilian political parties to identifying the causes of
stronger, more disciplined, and more programmatically cohesive parties, absent those
incentives. In other words, we need to identify the countervailing incentives that motivate
legislators to strengthen parties.
In this work, we explored two directions of change—the declining utility of
constituent-based strategies that raised the value of the party label vis-à-vis personal
reputation and the growing homogenization of parties along programmatic lines—which,
we argue, increased the incentives for deputies to delegate authority to party leaders to
coordinate their parties’ strategies to meet electoral competition. Party-oriented
legislators may have emerged for the same reasons they did in nineteenth-century
England—the loss of backbench access to patronage and an empty pork barrel (Cox,
1987)—but in the past decade in Brazil, this drama apparently unfolded in the opposite
sequence. Following lively debates over the country’s economic course, parties first
became more homogenous and polarized; indeed, we should not be using the term
“catchall” any longer as synonymous with Brazilian parties of the center and right.
Moreover, the more a deputy believed in his party program and that voters were loyal to
his party, the more willing he was to defer to his party leaders; the more he believed that
program had electoral value, the more likely he was to campaign on it; and the more he
shared the policy views of his party, the more likely he was to observe voting discipline.
These findings have important implications for Brazilian politics. As these
programs create value for the party brand and voters respond favorably to programmatic
coherence as well as governing competence, the incentive for parties and politicians to
offer such distinctive choices is reinforced. Any future narrowing of party polarization
could, of course, reverse the incentives to compete on program in favor of valence issues
or competence. But while only time will tell, it is possible the trend toward legislators
that are oriented toward their parties will outlive the structural and strategic changes that
gave rise to it. This might occur because the logic of programmatic competition may
24
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
create the necessary incentives for politicians to strengthen their parties by penalizing
party switching with a loss of mandate and by adopting a closed-list proportional
representation electoral system. Indeed, rule changes have already begun. In 2002 the
candidato nato (birthright candidate), which had guaranteed ballot access to incumbents,
was eliminated and efforts to reduce party fragmentation via the “barrier clause,” which
would have restricted the access of small parties to legislative leadership bodies and the
media beginning with the 2006 election, have been stalled only by the courts. Even a
mixed-member system to solve the dilemma of intraparty competition is now foreseeable.
Along with rule changes has come the greater insulation of social services from
clientelism. The loosening of political control over the distribution of the most basic
social services to the neediest families implied by the conditional cash transfer program,
Bolsa Familia (family stipend), and its precursor, Bolsa Escola (school stipend), was
only possible in a context of a diminishing value of patronage. Not surprisingly, the two
most cohesive parties—the PSDB and the PT—also substantially polarized on policy,
were the ones to initiate such changes.
Scholars of Brazil have long decried that autonomous politicians and the weak
parties they insist on preserving erode party discipline, make Brazil ungovernable, and
undermine political responsiveness—and representation. Rising party discipline has
mitigated Brazil’s worst governability problems, breaking the “deadlock” of Brazilian
democracy (Ames, 2001), and even the end of the scourge of party switching that so
openly flouts the popular will is in sight. A measure making party switching more
difficult was approved in the Chamber of Deputies in 2007 (as of this writing it is still
awaiting Senate action), but in any case the Supreme Court also in 2007 upheld an
Electoral Court interpretation of the 1990 Party Law that legislative seats belong to
parties, not individuals. Taken together, the break in the patronage chain, rising
programmatic cohesion and party loyalty, and rules changes that have already made party
government possible may now or will soon allow constituents to hold Brazilian parties
accountable on program and policy as well as for goods and services delivered. In time,
these changes may shape a new, ultimately stronger, pattern of political representation in
Brazil.
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
25
APPENDIX A
Returned questionnaires, supplemented by interviews conducted by students from the
University of Brasília, yielded 151 total responses (25.4 percent of the Congress), but to
make our analysis comparable to that of other researchers we omitted senators from this
study, resulting in a sample of 127. The sample overrepresents first-term members
including alternates (which were half of our sample but only about 40 percent of the
entire Congress). Although some nontrivial level of sample bias is inevitable in any
random sample of human subjects in general and legislators in particular, the size of the
bias in our sample is not large and the sample does reproduce the population in terms of
four important variables—party, region, gender, and level of legislative activity, making
it well within accepted standards for this type of population
26
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
Table A
Representativeness of Survey: Sample and Population Compared
Party
PFL
PSDB
PMDB
PPB
PT
PTB
PDT
PSB
PL
PCdoB
PPS
Other*
Total
Number of seats
Population
Sample
105
22
99
27
83
27
60
10
59
19
31
4
25
4
18
4
12
4
7
2
3
0
11
4
513
127
Percentage of seats
Population
Sample
20.5%
17.3%
19.3%
21.3%
16.2%
21.3%
11.7%
7.9%
11.5%
15.0%
6.0%
3.1%
4.9%
3.1%
3.5%
3.1%
2.3%
3.1%
1.4%
1.6%
0.6%
0.0%
2.1%
3.1%
100.0%
100.0%
Chi-square
P-value
0.52
Region
Northeast
North
Southeast
Center-West
South
Total
Gender
Women
Men
Total
Population
149
65
179
41
77
511
Population
29
484
513
Sample
41
15
44
8
19
127
Sample
7
120
127
Population
29.2%
12.7%
35.0%
8.0%
15.1%
100.0%
Population
5.7%
94.3%
100.0%
Sample
32.3%
11.8%
34.6%
6.3%
15.0%
100.0%
Sample
5.5%
94.5%
100.0%
P-value
Level of
legislative
activity
Very active
Active
Average
Weak
Very weak
Population
155
112
99
58
14
Sample
42
27
22
10
1
Population
35.4%
25.6%
22.6%
13.2%
3.2%
Sample
41.2%
26.5%
21.6%
9.8%
1.0%
P-value
0.91
P-value
0.95
0.47
Total**
438
102
100.0%
100.0%
Note: Partisan delegations for the entire congress are based on their size resulting from the 1998
election.
* PMN, PRONA, PSD, PSL, and PST.
** Source: Folha de Sao Paulo (2002). Caderno Olho no Voto (September 27). Available at
http://www1.folha.uol.com.br/folha/brasil/ult96u38553.shtml. Only 438 (of 513) deputies were
scored, 102 of whom were included in the sample.
27
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
APPENDIX B. VARIABLE MEASUREMENT AND SUMMARY DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS
Variable Name
Dependent variables
PART CAMPAIGN
DELEGATION
NO SWITCH
DISCIPLINE
Measurement
Obs
Mean
St. Dev.
See Appendix C for coding rules and
scores
Index of pro-party attitudes on four
survey itemsa
Dummy variable denoting no switches
after 1998 from party on which elected
Percent of roll-call votes cast in
agreement with party leadership’s
recommendation, 1999-2001
117
2.71
1.15
0
5
119
0.22
1.02
-2
2
126
0.75
.44
0
1
127
81.5
17.5
98.3
Measure of deputy’s electoral security
adjusted by coalition security
Logged value of district magnitude
127
0.50
0.55
-0.55
3.25
127
3.27
0.75
2.08
4.25
Measure of pattern of deputy’s electoral
support; two Federal District cases,
where DM = 1, dropped
Next position sought is mayor,
governor, or a post in the state
administration
Logged value of per capita state gross
domestic productb
Frequency of meetings with local
politiciansc
Frequency of meetings with high-level
members of state administration c
Member of state governing coalition (1)
or opposition (all others) (0)
Member of federal governing coalition
(PSDB, PFL, PMDB, PPB) (1) or opposition
(all others) (0)
Percentage of individual budget
amendments funded by executive
during 2000 and 2001
Absolute distance of mean position of
party’s legislators on cluster of statemarket issue from all legislators in
sample
Degree of importance deputy attached
to party’s platform in party’s state
election resultd
Degree of importance deputy attached
to resources delivered for party’s state
election resultd
Degree of importance deputy attached
to loyalty of state voters to party for
party’s state election resultd
Absolute distance of mean position on
cluster of 20 state-market issue items
from party mean positione
125
0.09
0.11
.001
0.74
127
0.28
0.45
0
1
127
8.61
.55
7.48
9.65
123
1.63
.86
-2
2
124
-0.52
1.33
-2
2
127
.39
.49
0
1
127
0.65
.48
0
1
119
29.2
0
93.6
127
0.77
.60
119
-0.12
1.19
-2
2
121
-0.40
1.25
-2
2
122
0.16
1.17
-2
2
120
0.50
.42
0.005
2.11
14.8
Min
Max
Independent variables
ELECTORAL
SECURITY
DISTRICT
MAGNITUDE (LOG)
DOMINANCE
STATE AMBITION
GDP PER CAPITA
(LOG)
LOCAL CONTACT
STATE CONTACT
STATE COALITION
COALITION
AMENDMENTS
FUNDED (%)
PARTY
POLARIZATION
PROGRAM VALUE
PATRONAGE VALUE
VOTER LOYALTY
VALUE
POLICY DISTANCE
27.8
0.02
1.99
28
a
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
Average of the responses to the four following questions: What is your view of the following propositions
(very negative [-2], negative [-1], neutral [0], positive [1], very positive [2])? (1) The party closes the
question and applies the party whip; (2) The party determines the order of the candidates to the Chamber of
Deputies on the list (instead of the open system that exists now); (3) A legislator loses his mandate if he
switches party after the elections; and (4) The party expels a legislator who votes against the party whip.
b
Figures are from 2001, and are available at www.ibge.gov.br.
c
No contact (-2); every three months (-1); monthly (0); every two weeks (1); and every week (2).
d
Values generated from responses to questions, “How important would you say the following national
(state) factors (your party’s electoral platform (the loyalty of state voters to your party) (the resources the
federal government recently transferred to your state) to your party’s performance in your state in the 1998
election?” Very little (-2); little (1); average (0); a lot (1); enormous (2)
e
Twenty items drawn from three questions (A-C):
(A) “Independently of the position of your party, what was your personal opinion with respect to the
following federal government proposals (total opposition [scored as -2], partial opposition [-1], indifferent
[0], partial support [1], total support [2]): (1) Fund for Fiscal Stabilization; (2) Relaxation of monopolies
(petroleum, energy, telecommunications); (3) Change in the definition of a national capital enterprise; (4)
Privatization of the Rio Doce Valley Mining Company; (5) Tax on financial transactions (CPMF); (6) End
of job tenure for public servants; (7) Social security reform of 1998; (8) Temporary labor contract; (9)
Sanctions against states that violate the Camata Law.”
(B) “How would you classify the effect of the following federal government policies on the country? (10)
Trade liberalization; (11) Privatization of federal enterprises; (12) Flexibilization of labor law; (13) Social
security reform; (14) Public administration reform.” Very negative (-2); very positive (2)
(C) “How would you classify the effect of the following policies of the federal government on your state?
(15) Trade liberalization; (16) Privatization of federal enterprises; (17) Privatization of state government
enterprises; (18) Flexibilization of labor law; (19) Social security reform; (20) Public administration
reform.” Very negative (-2); very positive (2).
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
29
APPENDIX C. CODING INDIVIDUAL CAMPAIGN APPEALS
In separate open-ended questions, deputies were asked to name the three most important
items in their party’s platform, and their three most important campaign appeals. We
coded the latter as personal, programmatic, or partisan, and awarded a score of 1 for each
programmatic or party-oriented campaign appeal (minimum = 0, maximum = 3). For
each campaign message in which there was overlap between the message offered by the
candidate and one of the most important points of the party platform as identified by the
respondent, the candidate received a score of 1, regardless of whether they were valence
issues or programmatic ones. Thus the maximum value for a party-oriented campaign is
6. We scored partial responses only up to the number of answers provided and dropped
nine deputies who did not provide an answer to either question.
Criteria
Personal Vote
Patronage/Pork
Parochial
Personal Qualities
Program
Valence Issues – I
Valence Issues – II
Other Program – I
Other Program – II
Partisan
Pro-party appeal
Political appeal
Endorsement of partystrengthening changes
Explicitly mention “resources” or
“projects”
Appeals to regional interests, either
generally or by name
Personality attributes; record in
office; type of commitment
Issue items in authors’ survey
generating the least amount of
controversy (as measured by
standard deviation score)
Issues not asked, but not likely to
generate conflict
Issue items in authors’ survey
generating the greatest amount of
controversy; those on which all
interests not likely to align
Highly charged issues not asked in
survey; ideological visions
Showing commitment to party as
representatives
Political alliances
Identified as one of most important
points on party platform
Sample Responses
Defense of concrete interests (public works, resources);
more resources
Defense of my state; region needs representation;
recovery of state of Pernambuco; economic
development for the region; water resources, irrigation,
and dam construction”(including São Francisco River
region)
Honesty (but not honesty in politics); seriousness (but
not seriousness in politics); competence; experience;
hard work; work already accomplished as
representative of the region; loyalty to grassroots
groups
Unemployment; corruption/ethics; health; education
(but not lack of funds for education)
Tourism; violence; physical security (segurança) (but
not seguridade, which also implies personal economic
security)
Privatizations; pension reform; workers’ rights; tax
reform; monetary stability; role of state in the
economy; sovereignty (definition of national capital);
agrarian reform; agriculture
Review of external debt; socialism; political reforms
(parliamentarism, check on executive and judiciary);
women’s rights; social justice; distribution of income;
alleviation of regional disparities
Voting with party platform; voting with party;
strengthening parties
Loyalty to president; opposition to governor
Party fidelity (whip); internal party democracy; active
participation in party; party spirit
30
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
ENDNOTES
1
On Carey’s (2002) “unity index,” which differs from the familiar Rice Index of party cohesion
(the difference between the percentage of party members voting yes and no averaged over the
votes in a particular Congress) by weighting votes by attendance and the closeness of the vote to
capture the degree of controversy legislation generates, party unity in Brazil was .75 from 1989 to
1998, lower than in Chile (.81 from 1997 to 2000), and Argentina (.88 from 1989 to 1991).
2
Although voters in large cities exhibited fairly stable partisan identification from 1945 to 1964
(Lavareda, 1991; Soares, 1967), in the interior parties did not espouse coherent programs and
formed opportunistic alliances in local elections with ideologically noncontiguous parties.
3
These figures differ from Desposato’s (2006: 69) and Mainwaring’s (1999: 145–46) because the
base includes all deputies who have served in the life of a legislature, including alternates
(N=620).
4
Morgenstern (2004: 127) also found the more ideologically cohesive the party, the higher voting
unity scores were in Argentina, Brazil, Chile, and Mexico.
5
Such amendments, an important source of district pork, declined from 73,642 in 1992 to 13,915
in 1994 to only 8,334 in 2000 (Samuels, 2003: 138).
6
To enforce compliance, the FRL imposed heavy fines, loss of mandate, and even jail time for
public officials in noncompliant states (18 of 27 at the time) (Bressan, 2002: 384).
7
Legislators are classified according to their “level of legislative activity” (an ordinal scale
consisting of five categories ranging from “very active” to “very weak”) based on their
attendance, committee membership and leadership, bill sponsorship, voting record, and
participation in floor debates (Folha de São Paulo, 2002).
8
The standardized item alpha score was .97 (see Appendix B for question wording), and factor
analysis confirmed the internal consistency of these categories. That this divide constituted the
single issue dimension of party competition in Brazilian politics in the 1990s is supported by
Leoni’s (2002) calculation of W-Nominate scores on roll-call votes in the 49th and 50th Brazilian
congresses.
9
All coalition scores are weighted by the size of the party delegations in the sample. Data on
Argentina, Chile, and Mexico are drawn from responses to comparable issue clusters from the
authors’ surveys.
10
Contrary to our survey findings, Power’s 1990, 1993 and 1997 surveys suggest that ideological
distance narrowed during the 1990s. But Roma (2004: 119–20) found the correlation between the
self-positioning of Brazilian deputies on the ten-point left-right scale and their location on the
same scale based on revealed ideal point positions (derived from stated opinions in 1995 and their
W-nominate scores on roll-call voting across legislatures in the 1990s) was only .44 (with 0
representing perfect correspondence and 1 total dispersion between ideological self-placement
and revealed positions), or “moderate” at best, and concluded based on their stated preferences on
policy and their voting record that politicians on both the left and right understated their
extremism later in the decade.
11
Power’s 1990 sample is also representative by party and region (Power 2000: 246).
12
Cross-temporal comparisons are complicated because respondents to our survey were offered
the option of responding “equally because of party label and personal effort” (which Power’s
survey unfortunately did not) to: “Some parliamentarians are elected because of their party
label—that is, the power of the party’s organization or its profile in public opinion. Others are
elected due to their individual capacity for organization or personal behavior in politics. Would
you say you were elected …” (other options were “almost exclusively” [2] or “mostly” [1]
because of party label).
13
Mean values of responses were: quality of candidates (.64); image of state leaders (.36); image
of party (.33); voter loyalty (.16); image of governor (.15); economy in state (.15); resources
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
31
anticipated in the future (.06); role of party members in state governments (-.22); and resources
delivered (-.40).
14
Such as a 1994 electoral calendar reform producing concurrent elections for president,
Congress, and state assemblies and improving economic performance and greater price stability
(Mainwaring, 1999: 221–22; Panizza, 2000: 507, 509, 520; Amorim Neto et al., 2003: 576).
15
We scored a vote coinciding with a party leader’s recommendation as 1, and a contrary vote, an
unexcused absence (a convenient means of opposing party leaders without voting against the
party whip), or an abstention as 0. We also included in our sample votes on which a quorum was
lacking if the quorum failed for this reason. Since we were testing the rival thesis that strategic
payoffs drove discipline, we dropped twenty-four votes in 2002 to match the “percentage of
amendments funded” variable (for which data were available only through 2001) as closely as
possible.
32
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
REFERENCES
Aldrich, J. H. & D. W. Rohde (1998). Measuring Conditional Party Government, Paper
presented at the annual meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association,
Chicago.
Ames, Barry (1995a). “Electoral Rules, Constituency Pressures, and Pork Barrel: Bases
of Voting in the Brazilian Congress.” The Journal of Politics 57, 2 (May): 324–
43.
Ames, Barry (1995b). “Electoral Strategy under Open-List Proportional Representation.”
American Journal of Political Science 39, 2 (May): 406–33.
Ames, B. (2001). The Deadlock of Democracy in Brazil. Ann Arbor: University of
Michigan Press.
Ames, B. (2002). A Theory of Legislative Parties in Brazil. In S. Morgenstern & B. Nacif
(Eds.), Legislative Politics in Latin America (pp. 185–221). Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Ames, B. and T. Power (2007). Parties and Governability in Brazil. In P. Webb & S.
White (Eds.), Political Parties in Transitional Democracies (pp. 179–212). Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Amorim Neto, O., G. W. Cox, & M. D. McCubbins (2003). Agenda Power in Brazil’s
Câmara dos Deputados, 1989–98. World Politics 55, 4: 550–78.
Bressan, S. (2002). Reforma Administrativa [Administrative Reform]. In B. Lamounier
& R. Figueiredo (Eds.), A Era FHC: Um Balanço [The FHC Era: An Accounting]
(pp. 369–94). São Paulo: Cultura.
Campello de Souza, M. do C. (1976). Estado e Partidos Políticos no Brasil (1930 a
1964) [State and Political Parties in Brazil (1930 to 1964]. São Paulo: Alfa-Omega.
Cardoso, F. H. (1996). In Praise of the Art of Politics. Journal of Democracy 7, 3: 8–19.
Carey, J. (2002). Getting Their Way or Getting in the Way? Presidents and Party Unity in
Legislative Voting. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political
Science Association, Boston, MA.
Carey, J. & M. S. Shugart (1995). Incentives to Cultivate a Personal Vote: A Rank
Ordering of Electoral Formulas. Electoral Studies 14, 4: 417–39.
Carreirão, Y. de S. & M. D. A. G. Kinzo (2004). Partidos Políticos, Preferencia Partidária
e Decisão Eleitoral no Brasil (1989/2002) [Political Parties, Party Preference, and
Electoral Choice in Brazil (1989–2002)]. Dados 47, 1: 131–68.
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
33
Chubb, J. (1982). Patronage, Power, and Poverty in Southern Italy: A Tale of Two Cities.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Cox, G. W. (1987). The Efficient Secret: The Cabinet and the Development of Political
Parties in Victorian England. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Cox, G. W. & M. D. McCubbins (1993). Legislative Leviathan: Party Government in the
House. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Desposato, S. (2006). Parties for Rent? Ambition, Ideology, and Party Switching in
Brazil’s Chamber of Deputies. American Journal of Political Science 50, 1: 62–80.
Estudo Eleitoral Brasileiro (ESEB). (2002). CESOP-FGV/Brasil02.Dez-1838. In Banco
de Dados do Centro de Estudos de Opinião Pública – CESOP – UNICAMP.
Available at: http://www.cesop.unicamp.br/busca/CESOP/pesquisa_usuario.
Faoro, R. (1958). Os Donos do Poder: Formação do Patronato Político Brasileiro [The
Power Barons: The Formation of the Brazilian Patrimonial Order]. Porto Alegre:
Globo.
Figueiredo, A. C. & F. Limongi (1999). Executivo e Legislativo na nova ordem
constitucional [Executive and Legislature in the New Constitutional Order]. Rio de
Janeiro: FGV.
Figueiredo, A. C. & F. Limongi (2002). Incentivos Eleitorais, Partidos e Política
Orçamentária [Electoral Incentives, Parties, and Budgetary Politics]. Dados 45, 2:
303–44.
Folha de São Paulo (2002). Caderno Olho no Voto [Eye on the Vote]. (September 27).
Available at: http://www1.folha.uol.com.br/folha/brasil/ult96u38553.shtml.
Gaetani, F. & B. Heredia (2002). The Political Economy of Civil Service Reform in
Brazil: The Cardoso Years. Prepared for the Inter-American Development Bank.
Grzymala-Busse, A. M. (2002). Redeeming the Communist Past: The Regeneration of
Communist Parties in East Central Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
Jacobson, G. C. (2000). Party Polarization in National Politics. In J. R. Bond & R.
Fleischer (Eds.), Polarized Politics: Congress and the President in a Partisan Era
(pp. 9–30). Washington, DC: Congressional Quarterly Press.
Kitschelt, H. (2000). Linkages Between Citizens and Politicians in Democratic Polities.
Comparative Political Studies 33, 6–7: 845–79.
34
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
Kitschelt, H. & S. I. Wilkinson. (2007). Citizen-politician Linkages: An Introduction. In
H. Kitschelt & S. I. Wilkinson (Eds.), Patrons, Clients, and Policies: Patterns of
Democratic Accountability and Political Competition (pp. 1–49). Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Lamounier, B. (2003). Brazil: An Assessment of the Cardoso Administration. In J. I.
Domínguez & M. Shifter (Eds.), Constructing Democratic Governance in Latin
America (pp. 269–91). Second Edition. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University
Press.
Lavareda, A. (1991). A Democracia nas Urnas: O Processo Partidário-Eleitoral
Brasileiro [Democracy at the Polls: The Brazilian Partisan-Electoral Process]. Rio
de Janeiro: IUPERJ/Rio Fundo.
Leoni, E. (2002). Ideologia, Democracia e Comportamento Parlamentar: A Câmara dos
Deputados (1991–1998) [Ideology, Democracy, and Parliamentary Behavior: The
Chamber of Deputies (1991–1998)]. Dados 45, 3: 361–86.
Levitsky, S. (2003). Transforming Labor-based Parties in Latin America: Argentine
Peronism in Comparative Perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Lyne, M. M. (2004). “Endogenous Institutions: Electoral Law and Internal Party
Dynamics in Brazil.” Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American
Political Science Association, Chicago, IL.
McCubbins, M. D. & F. M. Rosenbluth (1995). Party Provision for Personal Politics:
Dividing the Vote in Japan. In P. F. Cowhey & M. D. McCubbins (Eds.),
Structure and Policy in Japan and the United States (pp. 35–55). Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Mainwaring, S. P. (1999). Rethinking Party Systems in the Third Wave of
Democratization: The Case of Brazil. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
Melo, C. R. (2004). Retirando as Cadeiras do Lugar: Migração Partidaria na Câmara
dos Deputados (1985–2002) [Pulling the Seats out of Place: Party Migration in the
Chamber of Deputies (1985–2002)]. Belo Horizonte: UFMG.
Morgenstern, S. (2004). Patterns of Legislative Politics: Roll-Call Voting in Latin
America and the United States. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Panizza, F. (2000). Is Brazil becoming a ‘boring’ country? Bulletin of Latin American
Research 19, 501–25.
Pereira, C. & L. Renno (2003). Successful re-election strategies in Brazil: The electoral
impact of distinct institutional incentives. Electoral Studies 22, 3: 425–48.
Hagopian, Gervasoni, and Moraes
35
Pereira, C. & B. Mueller (2004). The Cost of Governing: Strategic Behavior of the
President and Legislators in Brazil’s Budgetary Process. Comparative Political
Studies 37, 7: 781–815.
Power, T. (2000). The Political Right in Postauthoritarian Brazil: Elites, Institutions, and
Democratization. University Park, PA: Pennsylvania State University Press.
Roberts, K. M. & E. Wibbels (1999). Party Systems and Electoral Volatility in Latin
America: A Test of Economic, Institutional, and Structural Explanations. American
Political Science Review 93, 3: 575–90.
Rohde, D. (1991). Parties and Leaders in the Postreform House. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
Roma, C. R. (2004). Atores, Preferências e Instituição na Câmara dos Deputados [Actors,
Preferences, and Institutions in the Chamber of Deputies]. Unpublished PhD Diss.,
University of São Paulo.
Samuels, D. (2003). Ambition, Federalism, and Legislative Politics in Brazil. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Samuels, D. (2004). Political Ambition, Candidate Recruitment, and Legislative Politics
in Brazil. Paper prepared for the conference Pathways to Power: Political
Recruitment and Candidate Selection in Latin America. Wake Forest University,
Winston-Salem, NC, April 3–4.
Samuels, D. (2006). Sources of Mass Partisanship in Brazil, Latin American Politics and
Society, 48, 2: 1–27.
Sani, G. & G. Sartori. (1983). Polarization, Fragmentation and Competition in Western
Democracies. In H. Dalder & P. Mair (Eds.), Western European Party Systems (pp.
307–40). Beverly Hills: Sage.
Santos, F. (2002). Partidos e Comissões no Presidencialismo de Coalizão[Parties and
Committees in Coalition Presidentialism]. Dados 45, 2: 37–64.
Silveira, F. E. (1998). A Decisão do Voto no Brasil [Deciding to Vote in Brazil]. Porto
Alegre: EDIPUCRS.
Soares, G. A. D. (1967). The Politics of Uneven Development: The Case of Brazil. In S.
M. Lipset and S. Rokkan (Eds.), Party System and Voter Alignments: CrossNational Perspectives (pp. 467–96). New York: Free Press.