Price Competition between International Airline Alliances
Volodymyr Bilotkach1
February 9, 2004
Abstract
This paper develops a model of price competition between two
international airline alliances, with consumers’ preferences vertically
differentiated by the number of stops. Alliances benefit the interline
passengers. Alliances with antitrust immunity do not benefit interline
passengers more than those without antitrust immunity, in contrast to the
Cournot-type settings. While antitrust immunity leads to higher fares for
non-stop travel between hubs of alliance partners, granting it might be
necessary to induce consolidation between carriers. Formation of
alliances with antitrust immunity is consistent with the proposed model,
even though such is likely to decrease individual carriers’ profit.
Keywords: Airline Alliances, Antitrust Immunity, Vertical Differentiation, Price
Competition, Hub-and-Spoke Networks
JEL Codes: D43, D49, L13, L29, L40, L93
Acknowledgements: I thank Stan Reynolds, seminar participants at The University of
Arizona, and conference participants in Seattle and Madrid for helpful comments. I am
solely responsible for any remaining errors and omissions.
1
Department of Economics, The University of Arizona, McClelland Hall 401, P.O. Box 210108, Tucson,
AZ 85721; e-mail: bilotkac@u.arizona.edu
1
I.
Introduction
Consolidation or formation of international airline alliances is an important phenomenon
currently reshaping the international airline industry. Airline consolidation can and does
take various forms, from shared use of facilities at a single airport to agreements covering
(and in effect uniting) large portions of partner airlines’ networks.
Yet, the most
noticeable feature of consolidating efforts between airlines is uniting of the alliance
members’ networks, referred to as code-sharing. A code-sharing agreement between
airlines A and B involves inclusion of flights, serviced by, say, airline A, into the airline
B's schedule, and vise versa. This form of partnership allows airlines to jointly market
each other’s flights, expand their networks, and sell seats on partner airline’s flights.
While Doganis (2001) claims that code-sharing is little more than a kind of potentially
unstable marketing alliance, it is common for the media to start talking about serious
partnership between the carriers when they start (or even propose to start) uniting their
networks and selling seats on each other’s flights. Also, this is typically the point where
regulatory authorities step in to examine possible effects of a partnership between
airlines.
Formation of international airline alliances raises questions concerning effects of
such partnerships on competition and welfare on the market. Answers to these questions
are of great interest to both scholars and regulatory authorities. In general, the question
regulators ask is not whether airlines should be allowed to cooperate, but rather how they
should be allowed to do it. Possibly the most important issue is the granting of antitrust
immunity (explicit right to jointly set fares) to alliance partners.
For example, the
problems with the code-sharing agreement between American Airlines (AA) and British
Airways (BA), discussed below, were directly related to the regulators' concerns that the
alliance thus formed would obtain market power on the largest London - US markets,
which is an important factor, given that a significant share of transatlantic travel passes
through London.
The model developed in this paper proposes a different approach to examining
airline consolidation, by departing from Cournot-type models, used in previous research
2
to address the issue, to a differentiated product Bertrand setting. This departure results in
a model that allows a coherent formal comparison of price effects of airline alliances with
and without the antitrust immunity, an important issue Cournot-type models have been
able to address only indirectly.
To date, the issue of welfare and competition effects of airline alliances has
received some attention of scholars.
The theoretical models of international airline
consolidation include works by Park (1997), Brueckner (2001 a) and Brueckner and
Whalen (2000). The common feature of the three models is that they all assume Cournottype competition. Also, Park assumes that alliance members equally share revenue from
interline passengers. Brueckner and Brueckner and Whalen only model the cases of
alliances where partner carriers are allowed to jointly set fares for interline trips (i.e.,
alliances with antitrust immunity). Park looks at the two categories of code-sharing
agreements: complementary and parallel. The difference between the two is that, while
the former does not involve overlapping partner carriers’ networks, the latter one does.
The general findings of Park’s analysis is that while complementary alliance is likely to
be welfare-increasing (due to removal of double marginalization present otherwise), the
parallel alliance tends to be welfare-decreasing, as it reduces competition on routes,
where alliance partners’ networks overlap. Brueckner (2001 a) models welfare effects of
formation of a single alliance with antitrust immunity, where partner airlines operate
simple overlapping hub-and-spoke networks.
He finds that alliance with antitrust
immunity will benefit interline passengers, but fares for travel between partner airlines
hubs will increase. On the balance, Brueckner suggests such an alliance will be welfareincreasing. Brueckner and Whalen (2000) construct a model of competition between two
international alliances with some horizontal product differentiation (through brand
loyalty).
However, the setup of that model only allows determining the impact of
alliances on interline fares, since the network structure does not include hub-to-hub
routes. Also, the model assumes antitrust immunity.
None of the models discussed in the previous paragraph has allowed a coherent
theoretical comparison of effects of alliances with and without the antitrust immunity,
primarily because it is not very clear how to model the latter within the Cournot-type
setups. Instead, researchers simply suggest that, since no explicit fare coordination is
3
allowed without antitrust immunity, double marginalization should persist.
Thus,
Cournot-type models conclude that code-sharing with antitrust immunity will lead to
decrease in interline fares. Yet, no formal distinction between the cases of alliances
without immunity and no alliances has been made. While some general arguments have
been proposed to suggest the existence of forces2, which should make interline fares
under code-sharing without immunity lower than in the case of no alliances, no coherent
model giving such a result in Cournot-type setting has been offered.
Empirical analysis of effects of international airline alliances has been offered by
Park and Zhang (2000), Brueckner and Whalen (2000), and Brueckner (2003). All of
these papers confirm that airline alliances benefit interline passengers by offering lower
fares. Park and Zhang also find evidence for increasing market power of the alliance
members at their hubs, even though they suggest that this effect is offset by cost savings
that alliance brings about to result in lower fares for departures from those hubs. While
finding that alliances decrease interline fares, Brueckner and Whalen fail to observe
statistically significant increase in fares due to establishment of an alliance for non-stop
travel on routes where such appears to decrease the number of competitors. Brueckner’s
empirical research shows that antitrust immunity decreases fares for interline trips to the
greater extent, as compared to the case of code-sharing without such immunity.
Our model takes a different approach to analyzing international airline alliances in
several dimensions. First, we use a more realistic model of the airlines transportation
network, which mirrors that of the transatlantic market, around which major alliances are
formed and compete (yet, the analysis can be applied to any arbitrary network). The
demand for airline flights is cast as a vertical differentiation model, in which all
consumers are willing to pay a premium for flights with fewer stops, other things equal.
Competition between airlines offering flights with different number of connections is an
important feature of international air travel.
Another diversion from the previous
literature is stepping away from quantity competition to price competition.
2
The primary such force referred to in the literature is the unanimity rule, required previously for setting of
the IATA fares. However, Doganis (1991) states that unanimity has been largely abandoned in the 80s,
which makes this argument less convincing, especially given that the empirical research uses data from late
90s.
4
The approach taken here allows us to directly model competition between
alliances with and without antitrust immunity and compare the equilibria thus obtained to
the one without alliances. Results of the analysis show that, unlike in the Cournot-type
models, granting partner airlines antitrust immunity does not lead to additional gains to
interline passengers, as compared to alliances without immunity. Thus, the differentiated
Bertrand approach adopted in this paper yields different predictions concerning antitrust
immunity, while keeping previous results regarding gains to interline passengers due to
establishment of the alliance. It is also shown that an alliance with antitrust immunity
leads to higher fares for travel between hub airports of the alliance members, also
consistent with the previous results. In addition to that, we offer an argument for why
airlines are inclined to enter alliances even though such may decrease profits of
individual alliance member (thus, formation of two alliances is consistent with our
model).
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section II describes airlines’
consolidation efforts, with emphasis on the transatlantic market. Section III develops and
analyses the model of price competition between alliances; cases of alliances with
antitrust immunity, alliances without antitrust immunity, and no alliance case are
considered separately. Section IV provides discussion of the model’s results, featuring
arguments for why airlines form alliances even when this decreases profits of individual
alliance members, as well as considering implications of our analysis for future research
and competition policy.
Section V concludes.
Proofs of Propositions are in the
Appendix.
II.
Airline Consolidation on International Markets
The “fashion” for consolidation among airlines started in the second half of 1990s.
According to Doganis (2001), over 500 various partnerships between airlines have been
recorded in 1998. These alliances take various forms, and differ in terms of scope and
(perceived) stability. Describing all possible forms of cooperation on international airline
markets is not the purpose of this paper (especially after it was well done by Doganis).
We will only take a brief look at the four major alliances that currently exist. The
5
common feature of all these partnerships is that all of them started with cooperation
between a major US carrier and a European airline, each operating a hub-and-spoke
network. Also, establishments of these partnerships coincided with further opening of the
transatlantic market. In fact, signing of an “open-skies” agreement between the United
States and the respective European country was a pre-requisite for approval of the codesharing agreement between the carriers. The first of the currently existing alliances
started with a major code-sharing agreement between KLM Royal Dutch Airlines and the
Northwest Airlines in 1993 (see, for instance, Economist, 2001, Transportation Research
Board, 2000). This agreement covered most of the networks serviced by those two
airlines, allowing for coordination of schedules and fares (backed by the antitrust
immunity the alliance was able to obtain).
Presently, KLM and Northwest form the core of a growing alliance, including
such carriers as Continental Airlines (not including transatlantic flights of this carrier),
and Air China. The core of the second alliance is formed by Lufthansa and United
Airlines (the so-called Star Alliance). British Airways and American Airlines are at the
core of the Oneworld alliance (total of eight airlines from Europe, Asia, North and South
America, and Australia). However, American Airlines and British Airways were known
to have problems trying to establish a comprehensive code-sharing agreement and obtain
anti-trust immunity for their transatlantic routes3. The youngest of those alliances is the
Skyteam group, core of which is formed by Delta Airlines4 and Air France (currently five
airlines, with Aeroflot Russian International Airlines in the process of joining the team).
Note that while alliances can consist of as many airlines as the alliance
management deems appropriate, antitrust immunity is given (by the US Department of
Transportation, in case a US carrier is involved5) to pairs of carriers within the alliance.
On the transatlantic market, in addition to KLM – Northwest pair, antitrust immunity has
3
The problem the regulators saw was that proposed alliance between American Airlines and British
Airways could effectively lead to those airlines establishing market power on some of the busiest and the
most important transatlantic routes, like London to New York and London to Chicago. Eventually, a
limited code-sharing agreement between the carriers was approved, yet no antitrust immunity was granted.
4
During the 1990s, Delta Airlines entertained the idea of entering into alliances with various European
carriers, but these attempts were unsuccessful. Yet, the alliance with Air France appears to be (at least to
the external observer) a serious commitment on part of the carriers involved.
5
I am not aware of antitrust immunity being granted to alliance groupings outside of international markets
involving United States.
6
been granted to Lufthansa – United, United – SAS Scandinavian Airlines, American
Airlines – Finnair and Delta Air Lines – Air France pairs. This means that in all of the
major alliances there are pairs of carriers with ability to coordinate their fares.
Finally, it is not as yet clear where alliances currently observed will lead to. One
can say that to some extent airline industry currently offers a test to Porter's (1990) claim
that "Alliances are frequently transitional devices.
They proliferate in industries
undergoing change and escalating competition, where managers fear that they cannot
cope." Evidence to this effect has been mixed. On one hand, we have seen seemingly
serious partnerships break down in a matter of weeks; on the other hand, stability and
rapid development of the currently established world-wide alliances prompted some to
suggest that they will in the future turn into major "mega-airlines" (Economist, 2001). In
either case, understanding how consolidation between airlines works and influences
economic welfare will help us answer some of the current and future competition policy
questions in the airline industry.
III.
1
Model
Model Setup
The purpose of this section is to develop a model of price competition between two
alliances, as well as to analyze and compare properties of equilibria under three different
scenarios. This sub-section provides the setup of the model, including description of the
network, demand and airlines’ cost structure.
Sub-section 2 analyzes properties of
equilibrium in case of two competing alliances with antitrust immunity. Afterwards, a
discussion of the equilibrium without cooperation between airlines is offered, followed
by the analysis of price competition between two alliances without antitrust immunity.
Finally, results of analysis under these different scenarios are compared and suggestions
regarding the welfare impacts of alliances are made.
We begin with description of the network, which is presented in the Figure below.
7
S3
S1
H2
H1
H3
H4
S2
Alliance I: airline 1 has its hub at H1 and airline 2
with hub at H2
Alliance II: airline 3 with hub at H3 and airline 4
with hub at H4
S4
Figure 1. Network structure
This network is set up in such a way as to mirror the transatlantic market. If we suppose
that H1 airport is Detroit Wayne Country International, H3 corresponds to Chicago
O’Hare, and further assume that H2 corresponds to Amsterdam Schiphol and consider H4
to be Frankfurt airport, we will obtain a model of networks offered by Northwest – KLM
alliance and the Star Alliance (the reader can choose specific spoke airports S1 through
S4 from among the US and European destinations to complete the picture).
Thus, we obtain a network of four distinct airlines (two on each side of the
ocean). Each of the airlines operates a single-hub network. Airline 1’s routes are shown
as solid lines; airline 2’s routes are represented as dashed lines. Thick solid and thick
dashed lines denote routes, serviced by airlines 3 and 4, respectively. In the analysis that
follows, two alliances are formed (airlines 1 and 2 form alliance I, while airlines 3 and 4
enter into alliance II), linking the end points on both sides of the ocean through hub
airports of the carriers.
It should be noted that we will apply the Bertrand model as an approximation to
competition in the airline industry, even though Hendricks et al. (1999) find that hub-and-
8
spoke networks cannot be a long-run equilibrium in case of pure Bertrand type
competition. Close examination of the networks US carriers have established since
deregulation reveals that usually US carriers operate multi-hub networks6, which is not
ruled out in the above mentioned paper as a possible result of Bertrand competition.
Another issue not considered by Hendricks et al. is a possible premium associated with
size of the network, which can also play some role in establishing the hub-and-spoke
network consistent with price competition7. Thus, nothing seems to suggest that the
network structure we observe on the market is inconsistent with price competition. The
network structure that will be used in the model can be thought of as a general
representation of the naturally occurring structure, which bears all major features of the
latter and simplifies the analysis. Among other reasons for adopting price competition,
the following can be stated.
Some research has been done to determine whether
competition in the airline industry is closer to Bertrand or Cournot model. Brander and
Zhang (1990) conclude that there is Cournot type competition in the airline industry, but
their conclusion stems only from the analysis of the non-stop flights on select duopolistic
markets originating from the congested O'Hare airport. Neven, Roeller and Zhang (1998)
provide the industry-wide analysis of the European market and conclude that the pattern
is consistent with Bertrand competition. Some recent evidence suggests fierce price
competition is very characteristic of the deregulated airline markets. For example, Busse
(2002) provides an empirical analysis of price wars in the US airline industry, and
discovers that over the time period the paper considers (1985-1992) price cuts by one
airline were always matched by the competitors8. Besides, rather narrow observed profit
margins in the industry are not consistent with the Cournot-type competition, which
clearly predicts positive mark-ups.
Note also that our network structure is different from those used in the previous
research in the following important ways. First, unlike in Brueckner (2001 a), our
6
Actually, all major carriers on the US market operate networks with several hubs, and Southwest does not
have a clearly identified hub. Single hub networks are served by some low-cost carriers not playing any
role on the transatlantic market, such as Frontier Airlines, Sun Country Airlines and JetBlue.
7
The issue of whether or not these premiums can play a role will be discussed in the next section.
8
I realize that this evidence could be attributed to the “kinked demand curve” theory, but price wars in the
industry appear to be a too common phenomenon, which should weaken this suggestion, as the “kinked
demand curve” hypothesis suggest certain degree of price stability, enforced by the fear that competitors
will slash their prices in response to your price cut.
9
network allows for two alliances; thus, we can explore the issue of competition between
airline partnerships. Second, even though network structure in Brueckner and Whalen
(2000) does allow for two alliances, it does not include routes between hub airports (in
their model all airlines operate out of a single hub). In summary, unlike previously
analyzed networks, ours allows to look at impact of airline alliances on all possible kinds
of routes.
Demand is modeled as follows. Consider a representative consumer, choosing
among the available ways to fly between the two cities. Without loss of generality,
consider a case, where the only options available to the consumer involve travel using
one or the other of the two alliances. In this case, a consumer using alliance J on a
market between cities i and j (all this analysis is easily applicable to the case with no
alliances) obtains the (indirect) utility:
VijJ = θ ij − (αpijJ + βnijJ )
(1)
where pijJ is the fare charged by airline(s) in alliance J; nijJ is the number of segments9 to
be flown when traveling with alliance J on a city-pair market under consideration; θ ij is
consumer’s reservation utility, which is a random variable with cumulative distribution
function F (θ ij ) ; α and β are positive parameters (without loss of generality, α can be
normalized to one). Also assume that the (indirect) utility of an outside alternative (not
flying) is equal to zero. Note that implicit in the indirect utility function above is the
vertical differentiation of the product: other things equal, flights with fewer segments are
strictly preferred to flights with more segments.
Facing two competing alliances on a city-pair market, a consumer will prefer
services of alliance J over those of alliance K if VijJ ≥ 0 and VijJ > VijK (in case these
indirect utilities are equal, we will assume that a consumer will be equally likely to
choose service of either of the two alliances). It can be easily seen that VijJ > VijK implies:
9
A flight segment is defined as a take-off and landing.
10
pijJ < pijK +
β K
(
nij − nijJ )
α
(2)
Given that θ ij is a random variable with cumulative distribution function F (θ ij ) we
obtain the following expression for the probability of consumer receiving the nonnegative indirect utility given that flying with alliance J is preferred to flying with
alliance K.
(
)
(
P V ijJ ≥ 0 = 1 − F αp ijJ + βn ijJ
)
[ ]
(3)
in a specific case where θ ij is distributed uniformly over the support θ ,θ we can write
the above expression as:
(
)
P V ≥ 0 = 1−
J
ij
∫
αpijJ + βnijJ
θ
θ − αpijJ − βnijJ
dθ
=
θ −θ
θ −θ
(4)
Assuming two alliances competing for N potential consumers on the city-pair market ij,
the expected demand alliance J will face under the price competition with product
differentiation can be written as:
⎧
⎪0
⎪⎪
qijJ = ⎨ 12 N 1 − F αpijJ + βnijJ
⎪
⎪ N 1 − F αp J + βn J
ij
ij
⎪⎩
(
(
(
(
))
))
β K
(nij − nijJ )
α
β
if pijJ = pijK + (nijK − nijJ )
α
β
if pijJ < pijK + (nijK − nijJ )
α
if pijJ > pijK +
(5)
Note that in case nijK = nijJ the textbook Bertrand competition case obtains.
(
(
Now let q~ij = N 1 − F αpijJ + βnijJ
)) be the total expected demand on a city-pair market ij.
β
pijJ ( pijK ) denote the price at which pijJ = pijK + (nijK − nijJ ) . Using this new
Further, let ~
α
11
notation, we can now write the following expression for demand faced by alliance J on a
given city-pair market.
⎧0
⎪
qijJ = ⎨ 12 q~ij
⎪q~
⎩ ij
if pijJ > ~
pijJ ( pijK )
if p J = ~
pJ ( pK )
(6)
if p < ~
pijJ ( pijK )
ij
J
ij
ij
ij
One can easily verify that (6) will be true irrespective of whether alliance J offers travel
with more, fewer, or the same number of stops than does alliance K. As a final touch, let
π ( pijJ ) denote the difference between pijJ and ~pijJ ( pijK ) for the cases where nijJ < nijK .
This difference, which will always be positive, will be called the premium for travel with
less stops. This completes general description of the demand side of the market.
The main assumptions related to the cost structure over the network are constant
returns to scale and separability of costs across the segments of the network. Note that
Winston (1985) states that one of the general conclusions from research on cost structure
of airlines is that the industry is characterized by constant returns to scale. Further, for
the purposes of tractability of the analysis, some cost symmetry assumptions will be
introduced. First, costs of carrying a passenger between hubs across the ocean are
assumed the same for all carriers:
O
C H1 1H 2 = C H2 1H 2 = C H3 3 H 4 = C H4 3 H 4 = C HH
(7)
where the superscript O means ‘overseas route’. Similar symmetry will be assumed
about costs of flying between ‘domestic’ hubs10:
D
C H1 1H 3 = C H2 2 H 4 = C H3 1H 3 = C H4 2 H 4 = C HH
10
(8)
Note that ‘domestic’ refers more to the side of the ocean than to a country. That is, Amsterdam –
Frankfurt route will be considered ‘domestic’ for our purposes, even though the cities are actually in
different countries.
12
Finally, we will assume the same costs for non-stop flights between any of the hubs and
D
any of the spokes (we will denote this cost through C SH
). Note that it is sufficient for all
the analysis that follows to assume that cost of carrying a passenger on a non-stop flight
between a hub and a spoke on each side of the ocean (that is, it is sufficient to assume
that all such costs are the same across the European routes and across the US routes,
while European cost need not be equal to the US cost), but the simplified assumption
adopted here does not change the results in any fundamental way.
Adopting these assumptions, we can write the airline’s total cost function as:
(
D
D
C i = 2C SH
* QSH
) +C
i
D
HH
(
D
* QHH
) +C
i
O
HH
(
O
* QHH
)
i
(9)
It must be noted that quantities in (9) refer to the total traffic on the segments of the
network, and not to the number of passengers traveling between particular cities.
2
Alliance Competition Equilibrium with Antitrust Immunity
The first scenario to be considered is the one of competition between two alliances, with
both competitors enjoying antitrust immunity. This means that alliance members will
jointly set fares for the routes, on which their networks overlap (which includes all the
overseas trips). To make the problem more tractable for the reader we will assume that
alliance members will equally divide their traffic on the routes between hubs of the two
carriers forming an alliance. Also, revenue, obtained by alliance members on overseas
spoke-to-spoke routes and on routes from domestic spokes to overseas hub of the
competing alliance (the routes, travel on which actually requires change of carrier) will
be equally divided by the two carriers.
Another assumption in line with previous
literature is that the travel from domestic hubs to overseas spokes will not require change
of the carrier within an alliance. These assumptions provide a little simplification to the
cumbersome notation that follows.
For the current scenario, we can identify two parts of the airline’s revenue
function, depending on whether the prices are set independently by the carrier or jointly
with an alliance partner. Thus, for a carrier i within an alliance J the total revenue will be
given by:
13
TRi = R i + R J
(10)
where:
R J = p SJD SO 2q Si D SO + p SJ
+ p SJ
i
OHD
2q Si
i
OHD
J
DHO
2q Si
J
DHO
+ p SJ
K
DHO
q Si
K
D HO
+ p HJ J H J q Hi J H J + p HJ K H J q Hi K H J
R i = p Si D S D q Si D S D + p Si
D
i
DHD
O
2q Si
i
DHD
D
O
D
+ p Si
j
DHD
O
2q Si
D
j
DHD
(11)
O
+ p Hi J H K q Hi J H K
D
D
D
(12)
D
Obviously, the airline’s total profit will be given by the difference between (10) and (9),
and demands for individual routes will be determined according to (6). Subscripts and
superscripts in (11) and (12) have the following meaning. Subscript S stands for 'spoke',
subscript H for 'hub'. Subscripts D and O stand for 'domestic' and 'overseas', respectively.
Uppercase J denotes alliance to which airline belongs, while uppercase K - other alliance;
lowercase j denotes airline belonging to a different alliance, but operating a domestic
hub. Thus, for example, q Si
K
DHO
would be read: 'airline i's traffic from a domestic spoke to
an overseas hub operated by a member of the competing alliance'. The first term in (11)
includes two of the four overseas spoke-to-spoke routes, and the third term includes one
of the two respective routes, due to equal division of revenue on those routes between
alliance members.
First, let us see whether the problem can be simplified by deleting some routes,
where traffic will be zero in equilibrium. This can in fact be done, as suggested by the
following proposition.
Proposition 1: Under price competition with no capacity constraints, vertical product
differentiation and cost symmetry as defined above, if nijJ < nijK , then alliance K will have
zero traffic on the route. Further, in equilibrium for each alliance there will be positive
mark-ups for the routes between its hubs, as well as between any of its hubs and any of
the spokes.
14
The proof is in the Appendix. From Figure 1 it is evident that routes mentioned in
Proposition 1 are the ones where each alliance provides travel with fewer stops and will
therefore make positive profit.
For the routes, where both alliances offer flights with the same number of
connections, the classical Bertrand result will apply (owing to the cost symmetry), as
generalized in the following Proposition, which, together with Proposition 1, complete
description of price competition equilibrium between two alliances with antitrust
immunity.
Proposition 2: All spoke-to-spoke markets and all markets for travel between hubs of
different alliances will be equally divided among the alliances, provided the above cost
symmetry assumptions are satisfied.
Again, the proof is in the Appendix. Before we consider other scenarios, let us review a
simple case of totally symmetric cost and demand structure to see what the profit of a
single alliance member will be. Assume that average cost for each flight segment is c
across the network (that is, cost of a trip involving n segments is cn) and premiums for
travel with less stops are kπ , where k = nijK − nijJ , in case alliance J is offering travel
with fewer stops.
Proposition 2 implies that in equilibrium, if nijJ = nijK , then
pijJ = pijK = nc , so no positive profit will be made on those routes. Consider the cases
where
nijJ < nijK .
On
those
routes
the
price
will
be
set
at
the
level
pijJ = cnijK + kπ = c(nijJ + k ) + kπ = cnijJ + k (c + π ) . So, the profit airline j will get from
each passenger on such route will be equal to k (c + π ) . The specific routes where profit
will be positive are the following:
1) Domestic spoke - domestic hub. The total profit an airline j from an alliance J
will make on such routes will be 2(c + π )q SjD H D (where q SjD H D is the expected
demand, as defined by (6)). The coefficient 2 represents two such routes.
Note that here k is equal to one.
15
2) Domestic spoke - overseas hub. The profit here is again 2(c + π )q SjD H O (k is
equal to one, as before).
3) Domestic hub - overseas hub of the same alliance. The profit on this route
will be just (π + c)q HJ D H O . The constant here is equal to one because, while the
price charged will be pijJ = 3c + 2π (note that here k is equal to two), the
airline will only serve half of the total traffic on this route.
Domestic hub to overseas spoke routes are not considered here, since according to what
has been previously assumed those passengers will be carried by the other alliance
member. So the total profit of airline j from alliance J under these circumstances will be:
j
Π Alliance
= (π + c)[2q SjD H D + 2q SjD H O + q HJ D H O ]
(13)
Or, we can also write this in terms of the total demands:
j
Π Alliance
= (π + c)[2q~SD H D + 2q~S D H O + q~H D H O ]
3
(14)
Price Competition Equilibrium without Alliances
In order to assess effects of emergence of airline alliances on fares and traffic on the
market in question, we need to see what the situation will look like when alliances are
absent, and all four carriers compete with each other. Now the fares are determined not
within an alliance but separately by each carrier.
Analyzing the no-alliance equilibrium requires imposing certain assumptions on
fare setting on the routes, requiring change of carrier. Since there is no cooperation
between airlines, a customer on such routes will be required to purchase separate tickets
for travel within the network of each of the airlines, included into his itinerary11. The
11
For example, when traveling from spoke 1 to spoke 3 using airlines 1 and 2, the customer will have to
either purchase a ticket for travel from spoke 1 to hub 2 on airline 1, and then another ticket from hub 2 to
spoke 3 on airline 2; or, the customer can purchase the ticket for travel from spoke 1 to hub 1 on airline 1,
and continue on another ticket from hub 1 to spoke 3 on airline 2.
16
question is how airlines will treat passengers, for whom travel within the carrier’s
network is only part of the journey.
Doganis (1991) indicates there essentially are two ways for airlines to deal with
the interline passengers in case the actions are not coordinated. The airline providing a
portion of the interline traffic on the ticket sold by a different carrier can specify the
portion of total fare it wishes to receive to agree to carry such a passenger. This
arrangement is termed pro-rating. One can see that such an arrangement does implicitly
assume some degree of coordination between the carriers involved.
According to
Brueckner, and Bamberger et al., such arrangements are taking place in cases when codesharing partners do not have antitrust immunity, which would allow them to charge a
single fare for the interline trip. The second approach to setting interline fares is for the
airline to charge a corresponding full fare for its portion of the journey, that is acting as if
it were not able to distinguish interline passengers. Besides, airlines are often unable to
sell tickets for travel to the end points outside of their network (or, network of the
respective alliance). Thus, for travel between some end-points on some airlines one
might have to buy two separate tickets, whether from the airlines or through a travel
agent. The point is that in case there are no alliances and no coordination of interline
fares is taking place, we can work with the assumption that carriers will not distinguish
interline passengers from those traveling entirely within their networks.
In this case, an airline’s revenue function will be of the form:
TRi = pSi DSD qˆ Si DSD + pSi
+p
i
HDi HO
qˆ
i
HDi HO
i
D HD
+p
2qˆ Si
i
HDi HDj
i
D HD
qˆ
+ pSi
i
HDi HDj
j
D HD
+p
2qˆ Si
i
HDj HO
j
D HD
qˆ
+ pSi
i
HDj HO
D HO
2qˆ Si
D HO
(15)
Note several things in which this revenue function is different from the one for the
alliance case. First, the fares entering the function are now determined by the airline
itself, and not by the alliance. Second, q̂ is different from q in case of the alliance
equilibrium, since q̂ also includes passengers continuing their travel on other carriers
after using service of airline i (or, passengers, continuing travel on airline i after using
services of other carriers). Third, demand for interline trips will be determined as a
17
function of the total price (which is just the sum of prices of different carriers for separate
portions of the journey), and a consumer will have more than two options to choose from;
yet, this does not affect the final results in any fundamental way. The equilibrium for the
case of no alliances is summarized in the following Proposition.
Proposition 3: For the case of price competition without alliances, assuming the demand
and cost symmetries as above, the following will be true:
a) All non-stop hub-to-hub routes will be equally divided by airlines offering service
between the respective hubs, and carriers will earn normal profit;
b) Domestic spoke-to-spoke markets will be equally divided by servicing airlines and
carriers will earn normal profit on those markets;
c) All traffic on domestic spoke-to-hub markets will be performed by an airline
operating the hub, and this carrier will earn positive profit on the route;
d) All traffic on domestic spoke to overseas hub markets will be performed by an airline
operating the domestic hub and offering travel with less connections; the carrier will
earn economic profit on the route;
e) Overseas spoke-to-spoke markets will be equally divided between the airlines, but
fares on those market will be higher than under the alliance competition equilibrium
and all carriers will make positive profit;
f) The division of traffic on one-stop hub-to-hub markets is not determined
unambiguously, but carriers do not earn positive profit on those markets.
Proof is included into Appendix. Let us compare the case of no alliances to the alliance
competition with antitrust immunity. Results presented here suggest that creation of
alliances increases fares for travel between hubs of the alliance partners, decreases fares
for travel on the international spoke-to-spoke markets and leaves all other fares
unchanged. This basic conclusion is the same as reached by Brueckner (2001 a). It is
reasonable to suggest, in fact, that Cournot competition over our network would lead to
similar results, when it comes to comparing no alliance equilibrium to that of competition
between two alliances with antitrust immunity (even though the analysis itself would
likely be more complicated). In both cases, alliances lead to lower interline fares due to
removal of double marginalization, but the sources of the double marginalization in this
and Brueckner’s models are different. Also, approach employed here can be more easily
applied to networks of any configuration to make predictions on the movement of fares
and traffic volume as a result of proposed partnerships.
18
Let us now return to our hypothetical example developed in the previous subsection, to determine individual carrier’s profit in equilibrium without alliances, as well
as to compare it with that under the previously studied scenario. The routes on which an
airline j will be making positive profits are:
1) Domestic spoke - domestic hub. The total profit an airline j will make on such
routes will be 2(π + c)q~S D H D . The coefficient 2 represents two such routes.
2) Domestic spoke - overseas hub to which an airline offers service. The profit
here is again 2(π + c)q~S D H O
3) Domestic spoke - overseas spoke. The total profit on these routes will be
2(π + c)q~SD SO . The airline will charge the fare equal to 2c + π to those
passengers on this market using an airline for only one segment of their
journey, and 3c + π to passengers using airline's services for two segments of
their journey. In either case, the per passenger profit will be equal to π + c
and each of the airlines will be serving half of the total traffic on the domestic
spoke to overseas spoke market.
Then, the total profit on an airline in the no alliance equilibrium will be:
j
Π NoAlliance
= 2(π + c)[q~SD H D + q~SD H O + q~S D SO ]
(16)
and further:
j
j
Π Alliance
− Π NoAlliance
= (π + c)[q~H D HO − 2q~S D SO ]
(17)
or, in the more general case of N spokes on each side of the ocean:
j
j
Π Alliance
− Π NoAlliance
= (π + c)[q~H D H O − Nq~S D SO ]
19
(18)
Note that our model allows us to easily incorporate hub-and-spoke networks of any size
(not just consisting of two spokes on each side of the ocean) into our analysis.
4
Alliance Competition Equilibrium without Antitrust Immunity
The final scenario to be considered is the one of competition between two alliances
without antitrust immunity. We assume in this sub-section that two alliances are formed
(i.e., partner airlines’ networks are connected through code-sharing agreements), while
none of the alliances obtains antitrust immunity (i.e., alliance members are not allowed to
set fares jointly). This scenario will be modeled by relaxing the critical assumption of the
no alliance case that carriers are unable to distinguish between passengers traveling
within their network. That is, instead of charging on-line and interline passengers the
same fares for travel within their network, each carrier will now select separate fares for
passengers traveling within their network, and those continuing their trips using services
of the alliance partner. The key distinctions between this scenario and the one with the
antitrust immunity are the following. First, interline fares are not set by alliance members
cooperatively, but rather are composed as the sum of sub-fares, charged by individual
alliance members. And second, alliance members are not allowed to cooperate in setting
fares for trips between their hub airports.
To analyze properties of price competition equilibrium under this scenario,
previously obtained results can be employed.
First, since alliance partners are not
allowed to coordinate their actions on routes between their hubs, the result from part (a)
of Proposition 3 applies.
Also, results from parts (b) through (d) from the same
Proposition hold in this scenario, as does result from part (f). All this is true, since there
are no institutional differences between the scenario, analyzed in this sub-section, and the
case of price competition without alliances. These result suggest, at this point, only one
difference between alliance competition equilibria with and without antitrust immunity:
fares for non-stop travel between hubs of alliance members will be higher under the
scenario with antitrust immunity.
Thus, the only routes left are the overseas spoke-to-spoke routes, travel on which
will require change of carrier. It can in fact be shown that in this case the fares set for
interline trips will be the same as the ones observed under the alliance competition
20
framework with the antitrust immunity. In fact, even though no explicit coordination of
fares is allowed, all carriers will still have strong incentive to undercut their sub-fares for
the interline trips to the marginal (and average, in our case) cost level. Indeed, if we
consider a situation, where sub-fares are set at the level above average cost in such a way
that the total interline fare is the same for both alliances, any fare undercutting by any of
the airlines (provided the resulting fare is still at or above the airline’s average cost) will
channel the entire traffic on a given overseas spoke-to-spoke route through the network
of the alliance, of which the undercutting airline is a member. That is, the logic of fierce
price competition applies to this case. Naturally, since both alliances offer services with
the same number of connections and also have the same costs, this undercutting of subfares will lead to average (and marginal under the cost structure imposed here) cost
pricing and no economic profit for airlines. Thus, interline fares in case of alliance
competition equilibrium will be the same, regardless of whether carriers have the antitrust
immunity.
Finally, let us return to the hypothetical example we worked with previously to
analyze individual carrier’s profit under the scenario of alliance competition without
antitrust immunity. Note that under this scenario positive profits will be made only on
the following routes:
1) Domestic spoke - domestic hub. The total profit an airline j will make on such
routes will be 2(π + c)q~S D H D . The coefficient 2 represents two such routes.
2) Domestic spoke - overseas hub to which an airline offers service. The profit
here is again 2(π + c)q~S D H O
Which yields total profit under this scenario, equal to:
j
Π Noimmunity
= 2(π + c)[q~S D H D + q~S D H O ]
which clearly yields:
21
(19)
j
j
Π Alliance
− Π Noimmunity
= q~H D H O (π + c)
(20)
j
j
Π NoAlliance
− Π Noimmunity
= 2q~S D SO (π + c)
(21)
and:
That is, if we have two alliances with no antitrust immunity, price competition between
them will yield the lowest profit to an individual carrier, as compared to both other
scenarios, considered here.
5
Concluding Comments
Analysis of the three different scenarios can allow us to make the following conclusions
concerning the effect of establishment of alliances on fares charged on different routes.
First, establishment of alliances clearly benefits interline passengers, whether or not
carriers involved obtain antitrust immunity.
This conclusion mirrors results of the
previous theoretical and empirical research. Second, the extent of the benefits to interline
passengers does not appear to depend on whether or not alliance partners enjoy antitrust
immunity. This conclusion is different from results of Cournot-type competition models.
While both this model and the previously developed ones rely on removal of double
marginalization due to cooperation between carriers, Cournot type models suggest that
absence of antitrust immunity only results in partial removal of double marginalization.
Whereas under price competition formation of two competing alliances completely
removes rents, previously extracted from interline passengers, regardless of whether or
not allied carriers are allowed to coordinate setting of fares. Third, establishment of
alliances with antitrust immunity makes passengers on the routes between hubs of
alliance members worse off12, whereas this adverse effect is absent for alliances without
antitrust immunity.
12
In fact, establishment of Northwest – KLM alliance did not raise many such concerns, since this alliance
actually created non-stop flights between Amsterdam and Northwest’s hub airports (Detroit, Minneapolis
and Memphis), thus creating benefits for some passengers, who previously had to make connecting flights.
22
The table below describes main findings of the analysis, paying specific attention
to changes that occur as we move from the no alliance case to competition between
alliances with and without antitrust immunity.
Table 1. Main findings of the analysis.
Route
No Alliances (Baseline
Scenario)
Changes due to
Establishment of Alliances
without Antitrust Immunity
Changes due to
Establishment of
Alliances with Antitrust
Immunity
Domestic Spoke Domestic Hub
(e.g., Spoke 1 - Hub 1)
Monopolized by the airline
opera ting the hub
No change
No change
No change
No change
No change
No change
No change
No change
Traffic increases, fares
decrease; no positive
mark-ups
Traffic increases, fares
decrease; no positive
mark-ups
No change
Traffic decreases, fares
increase; allied carriers
earn positive mark-ups
No change
No change
Domestic Spoke Overseas Hub
(Spoke 1 – Hub 2)
Domestic Spoke Domestic Spoke (Spoke 1
– Spoke 2)
Domestic Hub Domestic Hub
(Hub 1 – Hub 3)
Domestic Spoke Overseas Spoke (Spoke 1
– Spoke 3)
Monopolized by the
domestic airline operating
the non-stop route from its
hub to the overseas hub
Divided by the two
domestic airlines. No
positive mark-ups
Divided by the two
domestic airlines. No
positive mark-ups
Equally divided by all
airlines. However, there
are positive mark-ups,
accruing to each of the
airlines providing portion
of service on this interline
trip
Equally divided by the
airlines providing such
non-stop service. No
positive mark-ups
Overseas hub-to-hub
routes, on which non-stop
service is possible (Hub 1
– Hub 2)
Overseas hub-to-hub
No positive mark-ups.
routes, on which no nonDivision of traffic between
stop service is possible
airlines not clear
(Hub 3 – Hub 2)
Note that establishment of alliances with antitrust immunity will decrease traffic on the
overseas hub-to-hub routes operated by the alliance partners. But it does not necessarily
imply that total traffic on that segment of the network will decrease. Total traffic can
change in either direction, depending on the magnitude of decrease in the number of
passengers traveling between hubs of the alliance members, relative to the increase in the
number of interline passengers, which will use this segment of the network as part of
their itinerary.
23
Regarding welfare impact of establishment of alliances, the following general
conclusions can be made. Since establishment of alliances without antitrust immunity
decreases fares on some routes, leaving all other fares unchanged, we can say that such
development will be welfare-increasing, even though airlines are not likely to be willing
to enter into such partnerships. Welfare impact of alliances with antitrust immunity (as
compared to the case without alliances) is ambiguous. However, we can suggest that
such alliances will be more likely to increase total welfare, the larger the overseas spoketo-spoke markets are relative to the market for travel between hubs of alliance partners.
If we consider actual cases from the transatlantic market, recall that proposed alliance
with antitrust immunity between American Airlines and British Airways was eventually
stopped by the regulators due to fears that the carriers would obtain dominant position on
London – New York and London – Chicago markets. That is, it was believed that
potential losses to consumers on markets between hubs of the proposed alliance partners
would not be offset by potential gains to interline customers. Further, on being denied
the antitrust immunity American Airlines and British Airways decided not to enter into a
code-sharing agreement at all, which appears to be a wise choice according to our model.
Second case concerns the Northwest – KLM alliance. This partnership did not meet
much resistance from regulators. Indeed, traffic on Amsterdam – Detroit and Amsterdam
– Minneapolis routes is rather small, so possible losses to passengers on these routes are
more likely to be offset by gains to interline passengers. Further, Northwest – KLM
partnership actually created non-stop services between KLM and Northwest hubs, so it
can even be claimed that passengers on these hub-to-hub routes lost very little if at all
from this development.
24
IV.
Discussion and Implications of the Model's Results
This section discusses implications of the model, developed in the previous section of the
paper. We begin by considering a seeming paradox that comes from (18). Entering the
international alliance can reduce carrier’s profit (provided two alliances are present). The
next subsection establishes that it is optimal for carriers to act so as to form two alliances
and for each alliance to seek antitrust immunity.
We also outline implications for
research and antitrust policy, consistent with the model developed in this paper.
1
Carriers’ Incentives to Form International Alliances
Result (18) above suggests that, when two alliances compete with each other, there is a
possibility that a carrier’s profit will be reduced as a result of entry to the alliance13.
Moreover, the possibility that the profit will decline is higher the larger the network the
carrier has to offer on its side of the ocean. And from Section II we will notice that at the
core of all of the airline alliances are the big network carriers. This fact obviously
demands explanation.
Several explanations to the above mentioned empirical fact can be offered. The
first explanation that comes to mind is related to the economies of traffic density. This
argument suggests that by increasing traffic on the transoceanic spoke-to-spoke routes an
airline will be able to utilize its capacity more fully and thus decrease average cost of
carrying passengers. This can be true, and it has been noted as a reason (and in some
cases – the reason) for entering an international alliance. However, we need to find a
justification, consistent with our model’s assumption.
Another possible explanation relates to other dimensions of the product
differentiation, not captured by the model.
There can be some other premiums,
associated with the alliance travel. For example, all alliances (in fact, all airlines) offer
frequent flier programs. Establishment of alliance expands the network, over which
frequent flier miles can be collected and redeemed, thus making allied frequent flier
program more attractive to customers. Our model might also have failed to consider the
13
Further, entering alliance without antitrust immunity definitely leaves the carrier worse off, when two
such alliances compete.
25
premium for seamless travel: when choosing between the two airlines offering the same
fare you will prefer the one that checks your luggage to the final destination to the one
that does not.
However seemingly appealing, the above-described premiums are not convincing
arguments. If the issue were just in the scope of the frequent flier programs (seamless
travel), the carriers could simply unite their frequent flier programs (sign a trough
luggage-checking agreement), and not effectively unite their networks, putting their
profits at risk.
Yet, there is no need to consider any additional premiums to show that it is
individually rational for each carrier to enter an alliance with an overseas airline to the
hub of which the airline under consideration offers non-stop service, as well as to seek
antitrust immunity for such an alliance. Consider a simple game played between two
airlines on one side of the ocean: airlines 1 and 3. Without loss of generality, we will
work with the same hypothetical example as before. Suppose that airline 1 is considering
an alliance with airline 2 and airline 3 is considering an alliance with airline 4, with both
pairs of carriers seeking antitrust immunity for their partnerships14. The idea of the
analysis that follows is that payoff of a carrier within an alliance depends on whether or
not its competitor on the domestic market entered an alliance with the other overseas
carrier. That is, there is a clear case for setting up a simple game between, for example,
airline 1 and airline 3. Each of the airlines can either enter the alliance (and seek
immunity) or stay away from the alliance. The payoff matrix of the game can be written
as follows:
Enter Alliance
Airline 1
Stay Away
Airline 3
Enter Alliance
Stay Away
1
3
1
Π Alliance
Π Alliance Π Allied
Π 3NonAllied
Π 1NonAllied
14
Π 3Allied
Π1No Alliance
Π 3No Alliance
It can be easily shown that entering into alliance without the antitrust immunity is strictly dominated by
entering into alliance and seeking antitrust immunity. Profit of a member of the ‘immune’ alliance will be
greater than that of a member of the alliance without immunity by the amount the former makes on the
route between hubs of the two alliance members, no matter what the other player does. See (20).
26
j
j
Where Π Alliance
and Π No
Alliance are as calculated before. The terms not defined and which
j
j
will need to be explained are Π Allied
and Π NonAllied
. The former corresponds to the payoff
of the carrier which entered an alliance provided the other player remained non-allied.
The latter is the payoff of the non-allied carrier provided the other player entered the
international alliance with a respective overseas airline. Let us see what those payoffs
are.
j
j
To calculate Π Allied
and Π NonAllied
, we need to determine what will happen when a
single alliance is formed. Suppose that airline 1 enters into an alliance with airline 2.
The first effect of such an alliance is the monopolization of the route between hub 1 and
hub 2. As shown before, on that market the alliance will be able to charge the fare of up
to 3c + 2π dividing the traffic between the two allied carriers. The other routes to
consider are overseas spoke-to-spoke routes. Here the alliance is able to set a single fare,
which will allow it to effectively attract all of the traffic on those routes15. As shown
above, without an alliance, the fares on the overseas spoke-to-spoke routes are equal to
5c + 2π , with each of the airlines making a premium of π + c on half of the traffic,
making a single carrier’s profit from all of such routes equal to 2(π + c)q~SD SO . The
alliance partners can thus easily set the fare equal to 5c + π 16, attract the entire traffic on
the market, and allow each carrier to extract the average profit of 0.5π + c from each
passenger. The total alliance member’s expected profit across the four markets is
~
2(π + 2c)q~S D SO > 2(π + c)q~S D SO , with the traffic increasing due to the lower fare. Note that
~
q~ is different from (to be more exact – larger than) q~ . Obviously, the non-allied carrier
loses its profits from the overseas spoke-to-spoke markets. Then, we can write the
j
j
following expressions for Π Allied
and Π NonAllied
:
~
j
j
Π Allied
= 2(π + c)[q~S D H D + q~S D H O + 0.5q~H D H O ] + 2(π + 2c)q~S D SO > Π No
Alliance
15
(22)
In fact, there was an indication that the Northwest – KLM alliance did end up attracting increasingly
more traffic on the transatlantic market, directing it through their major hubs. This fact did play some role
in granting antitrust immunity to further alliances on the market (US Department of Transportation, 2000).
16
Of course, nothing precludes the alliance to set the fares at the level of 5c + 2π − ε , but the actual level
of fares is not crucial for our analysis here.
27
j
j
Π NonAllied
= 2(π + c)[q~SD H D + q~S D H O ] < Π No
Alliance
(23)
Furthermore:
j
j
j
Π NonAllied
< Π Alliance
< Π Allied
(24)
Once we have these relationships set up, we can easily see that ‘Enter Alliance’ strategy
strictly dominates the ‘Stay Away’ strategy. Note that here ‘Enter Alliance’ strategy
involves alliance with immunity, and a member of alliance with immunity obtains higher
profit than does a carrier within the alliance without immunity, no matter what the other
player does. Moreover, the larger the carriers involved, the larger their payoffs from
entering the alliances, conditional on other airlines remaining non-allied. Therefore, it is
individually rational for each of the airlines to form alliances with the respective overseas
j
j
,
airline, and to seek antitrust immunity for their partnership. When Π Alliance
< Π NoAlliance
this game is structurally equivalent to the prisoners’ dilemma.
2
Implications for Future Research and Antitrust Policy
This subsection considers implications of our model for future research and antitrust
policy. In fact, a lot of work remains to be done before artificial barriers, still governing
most international airline markets are relaxed to allow market forces to govern behavior
of firms. As deregulation of international aviation continues, importance of the relevant
research will increase. The model presented in this paper is one of the first steps towards
analyzing one of the phenomena that resulted from relaxing some of the barriers. Our
model is simple, and a number of extensions can be suggested. One line of research
could consider the possible extensions of the analysis presented in this paper, which will
involve relaxing the basic assumptions of the model. The first obvious ramification
would be to consider capacity constraints and other entry barriers. Yet, relaxing this
assumption will immediately lead to the Bertrand – Edgeworth type of competition and is
very likely to render the model intractable. Another way to consider the entry barriers is
28
to take a closer look at airport congestion. Some work has already been done in this area
(Brueckner, 2001 b, 2002, Borenstein, 1989). In fact, the number of take-offs and
landings that a runway can service within a given time period is limited, which is a
substantial entry barrier, especially in congested airports during peak hours.
Another possible direction of theoretical and empirical research would be
identification and incorporation of other parameters, by which the airline services can be
differentiated. One could try to identify what other possible premiums consumers are
willing to pay for better service; also, one can determine what characteristics of the
airline service do not play any important role, thus defining services on which some
airlines possibly only waste money, and for which consumers are not really willing to pay
more, or those, which would be more likely to deter an average consumer from using
services of an airline (e.g., allowing smoking on board17). Some premiums could be
associated with the frequent flier programs, but the question of importance of those
premiums in strengthening the possible market power of alliances is open.
Other implication of our model for the future research concerns the treatment of
competition. Different competitors may have different impact on fares, depending on the
number of stops they offer relative to the number of stops offered by a given carrier. Of
course, for a time-sensitive customer duration of the journey is more important than the
number of connecting flights, but more connecting flights usually implies longer trip.
Finally, we briefly examine implications of our results for competition policy.
The most important issue here is whether international alliances should be given (or in
some cases, whether they should have been given) antitrust immunity. Our analysis (as
well as previous research) shows that antitrust immunity can be welfare-decreasing on the
hub-to-hub routes, but increases welfare (by lowering fares and increasing traffic) on the
interline spoke-to-spoke routes. Generally, this model will predict that alliances without
antitrust immunity produce higher overall welfare gains than do those, which enjoy such
immunity, if the latter produce overall welfare gains at all. Thus, one would suggest that
giving antitrust immunity to airlines is not going to produce any benefits to interline
passengers beyond those obtained when airlines connect their network through code-
17
When Aeroflot Russian International Airlines prohibited smoking on its transatlantic flights in 2002, this
move increased the number of airline’s passengers on those routes by about one third.
29
sharing. Yet, our analysis also shows that airlines might not be willing to enter into
alliances without antitrust immunity, since such are more likely to decrease their profits.
Hence, even though antitrust immunity is not the first-best policy here, it may
nevertheless have been (and remain) necessary, as otherwise carriers could have been
discouraged from forming partnerships they did. Yet, if antitrust immunity should be
granted in the future, it should be done for those partnerships between carriers, which
involve thin hub-to-hub markets. Also, as indicated above, antitrust immunity can be
justified where it prompts alliance members to create non-stop services between their
hubs.
It is possible, for example, that the recently granted immunity to American
Airlines and Finnair would create non-stop flights between Helsinki and one of American
Airlines’ hub airports18, if the carriers are successful in channeling their traffic through
these hubs.
Other issues to consider when deciding on antitrust immunity are presence of
other competitors on the same route, possibility of one-stop competition (or in the more
general sense, competition with more connections), and market share of the proposed
alliance partners. Take the case of the proposed alliance between British Airways and
American Airlines.
This prospective partnership raised concerns over the possible
dominant position of the carriers on London – New York route. On one hand, one-stop
competition on this route is not very likely, since it will involve significant increases in
flight duration, and the current share of British Airways and American Airlines on that
market is rather high. On the other hand, there are other non-stop competitors on that
market.
The general conclusion from the above paragraphs is that proposed alliances must
be considered on a case by case basis, taking into account the specific network structure
of the partner airlines, as well as the actual and potential competition on the routes
involved. With this respect it may be interesting to theoretically examine the effects of
the possible alliances between the US carriers (note that this model allows us to extend
the logic of our analysis to networks with different structures, as noted above). Another
issue that warrants further investigation is the one of differences in effects between the
18
In fact, Finnair opened non-stop service between Helsinki and Miami, after this paragraph was originally
written.
30
code-sharing agreements with and without the antitrust immunity. At this stage we can
say that there are considerable possible welfare gains from consolidation of airlines, but
welfare losses can follow if we do not consider each proposed case carefully, taking into
account specifics of the networks involved.
V.
Concluding Comments
This paper develops a new model of competition between the international airline
alliances, expanding the network structure first proposed by Brueckner and departing
from Cournot to a differentiated Bertrand setting.
In the model there are two
international alliances, each comprised of two airlines with hub-and-spoke networks,
engaged in price competition with the product being vertically differentiated by one
parameter. Other things equal, all consumers prefer flights with less stops to flights with
more stops. Three different scenarios are considered: competition between alliances with
antitrust immunity, competition between alliances without antitrust immunity, as well as
the case with no alliances. Results of the analysis show that establishment of and
competition between two alliances without antitrust immunity leads to lower fares for
interline passengers, due to removal of double marginalization, which existed prior to
establishment of alliances, since networks of the individual carriers were not connected
and carriers were assumed unable to distinguish between passengers traveling within
their networks, and the interline passengers. Granting the antitrust immunity to both
alliances increases fares for non-stop trips between the hub airports of alliance partners,
not producing any additional benefits to interline passengers, beyond those already
offered by alliances without immunity.
The last result is different from what was
previously suggested by Cournot – type models: those models claim that to completely
remove double marginalization on interline trips, antitrust immunity was necessary.
We were also able to offer a convincing explanation for formation of alliances
even in cases this leads to decreased profits for individual alliance members. In fact,
given the network and assumptions of the model, each airline’s dominant strategy is to
enter into alliance and to seek antitrust immunity for the partnership.
31
The main implication of our model for antitrust policy is that each proposed
alliance (especially the issue of granting the antitrust immunity to the partner carriers)
must be considered on the case by case basis, taking into account the current network
structure of the prospective alliance partners. Alliances with antitrust immunity produce
benefits for the interline passengers, and not granting immunity may discourage airlines
from consolidation. That is, losses to passengers traveling between hub airports of the
alliance members can be considered the price of possibly wider gains to interline
passengers. It is in the interest of regulatory authorities to seek solutions that minimize
such price. Possibly an ideal variant would be the partnership, which by itself creates the
non-stop service between the hub airports of the partner airlines (such as the KLM –
Northwest alliance), in which case possible losses due to higher fares on the route (in
case antitrust immunity is granted) are to some extent offset by gains, accruing to
passengers, who now benefit from shorter duration of the trip.
32
Works Cited
Bamberger, Gustavo E, D. W. Carlton and L. R. Neumann, 2001, An Empirical
Investigation of the Competitive Effects of Domestic Airline Alliances, NBER
Working Paper 8197
Borenstein, Severin, 1989, Hubs and High Fares: Dominance and Market Power in the
U.S. Airline Industry, RAND Journal of Economics, Vol. 20, No. 3, Autumn 1989
Brander, James A. and Anming Zhang, 1990, Market Conduct in the Airline Industry: an
Empirical Investigation, RAND Journal of Economic, Vol. 21, No. 4, Winter
1990
Brueckner, Jan K., 2001 a, The Economics of International Codesharing: An Analysis of
Airline Alliances, International Journal of Industrial Organization, Vol. 19,
December 2001
______________, 2001 b, Internalization of Airport Congestion, Working Paper, The
University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign
______________, 2002, Airport Congestion When Carriers Have Market Power,
American Economic Review, Vol. 92, No. 5, December 2002
______________, 2003, International Airfares in the Age of Alliances: The Effects of
Codesharing and Antitrust Immunity, Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol.
85, 105-118
Brueckner, Jan K and Thomas Whalen, 2000, The Price Effects of International Airline
Alliances, Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. XLIII, October 2000
Busse, Meghan, 2002, Firm Financial Condition and Airline Price Wars, RAND Journal
of Economics, Vol. 33, No. 2, 298-318
Doganis, Rigas, 1991, Flying Off Course: The Economics of International Airlines, 2nd
ed. (Harper Collins Academic)
____________, 2001, The Airline Business in the 21st Century, Routledge
Economist, The, 2001, A Survey of Air Travel, March 10-16, 2001
Hendricks, Ken, M. Piccione and G. Tan, 1999, Equilibria in Networks, Econometrica,
Vol. 67, No. 6, November 1999
Neven, Damien J, Roeller, Lars-Hendrik and Zhentang Zhang, 1998, Union Power and
Product Market Competition: Evidence from the Airline Industry, Centre for
Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper No. 1912, June 1998
33
Pels, Eric, Peter Nijkamp and Piet Rietveld, 2000, A Note on the Optimality of Airline
Networks, Economics Letters 69, p.p. 429-434
Porter, M., 1990, The Competitive Advantage of Nations, Free Press: New York
Tirole, Jean, 1988, The Theory of Industrial Organization (MIT Press, London)
Transportation Research Board, 1999, Entry and Competition in the U.S. Airline
Industry: Issues and Opportunities (Special Report 225) (National Academy
Press, Washington D.C.)
US Department of Transportation, 2000, Transatlantic Deregulation: Alliance Network
Effects, Report
Winston, Clifford, 1985, Conceptual Developments in the Economics of Transportation:
An Interpretive Survey, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 23, No. 1. (Mar.,
1985), 57-94
34
Appendix Proofs of Propositions
Proof of Proposition 1: Suppose nijJ < nijK and let cijJ and cijK denote average cost of
alliance J and K, respectively. The proof is trivial where cijJ ≤ cijK (which includes the
model’s cost symmetry assumption as a special case19). Here travel with alliance J is
both preferred by customers and less expensive. So, alliance J in this case can take away
the entire market by setting the price at a level, which is slightly below the one where the
pijK ( pijJ ) = cijK . This can be rearranged as pijJ = cijK + π ij ( pijJ ) ,
following equality holds: ~
where π ij ( pijJ ) is as defined above20. This will also imply that pijJ > cijK ≥ cijJ , which
suggests that alliance J will have positive mark-ups on those routes which it can serve
with fewer connections, when cijJ ≤ cijK .
Proof of Proposition 2: Proof in this case is trivial, once one recognizes that the above
cost symmetry assumptions make the cost of travel on the routes concerned equal for
both alliances, and given that travel will involve the same number of flight segments
irrespective of the alliance chosen. Also note that (8) in this case collapses to the
textbook Bertrand case, so the classical Bertrand equilibrium applies, given cost
symmetry.
Proof of Proposition 3: Parts (a) and (b) follow directly from Proposition 2. On each of
those markets we have two competitors offering service with the same number of stops.
Cost symmetries do not allow for successful competition by carriers offering services
with more connecting flights. An important result that follows from (a) is that fares on
non-stop overseas hub-to-hub routes will be lower under no alliance competition than
when alliances are present.
Part (c) follows from Propositions 1 and 2. Fares on those markets will be equal to
D
+ π ( p Si H i ) , which implies that the operating carrier will make economic
p Si H i = C SH
D
D
D
D
profit. Also note that this is the same fare as would be observed in case alliances are
present.
To see that what we state in Part (d) is true it is important to consider options the travelers
face on such markets when there are no alliances. Consider a passenger wishing to travel
from spoke 1 to hub 2. He can either choose airline 1 for the entire journey or use airline
Note that this proposition can be generalized to the case of asymmetric costs. This result will be true in
case of asymmetric costs as long as ~
pijK (cijJ ) < cijJ is
pijK (cijJ ) < cijK . In case the inequality cijK ≤ ~
19
satisfied, it can be shown that alliance K has cost advantage over alliance J, sufficient to capture the market,
even though alliance K offers travel with more stops.
20
Strictly speaking, the price charged by alliance J will be pij − ε but this does affect our results much,
J
be pij = min{cij + π ij ( pij ), pij } , where pm is the monopoly price. However, there is no reason to
yet reduces the notational burden. Another presumably more correct way of writing the above result would
J
K
J
m
believe that premiums for travel with less stops are high enough for the monopoly price to be charged in a
naturally occurring situation
35
1 to travel to hub 1 and then fly with airline 2 to the final destination21. The fare if the
first option is taken will be p1S1H 2 . If the second option is selected, then the fare will be
D
+ π ( p1S1H1 ) . Further, part (a) of this Proposition
equal to: p H2 1H 2 + p1S1H1 = p H2 1H 2 + C SH
O
D
+ C SH
+ π ( p 1S1H1 ) , which is strictly greater than the cost
suggests that p H2 1H 2 + p1S1H1 = C HH
of providing the service for airline 1, given cost symmetry. That is, airline 1 can capture
O
D
O
D
+ C SH
+ C SH
+ π ( p1S1H1 )) , which
, C HH
all the traffic on this market by setting p 1S1H 2 ∈ (C HH
means that the fare charged by airline 1 will be slightly less than the upper bound of this
interval. In fact, there is no qualitative difference between this result and the one for the
same market under the alliance equilibrium. This logic applies to all similar markets.
Proving result in part (e) of the proposition will be similar to proving the previous result.
Let us take a passenger traveling from spoke 1 to spoke 3. Assume away airlines 3 and 4
for a moment22. The passenger will buy two tickets, and he can select one of the
following: either use airline 1 to hub 2 and airline 2 thereafter; or, use airline 1 to hub 1
and airline 2 thereafter. Obviously, in the equilibrium the total price has to be the same,
no matter which option is selected. Yet, in either case he will pay more than in the
alliance competition equilibrium, since he will have to buy one ticket for domestic spoke
to domestic hub segment, and one ticket for domestic spoke to overseas hub route; both
tickets will be priced above cost, according to parts (c) and (d). To be more specific, the
fares on such spoke-to-spoke routes will be equal to:
D
O
p S D SO = p S D H O + p H O SO = p S D H D + p H D SO = 2C SH
+ C HH
+ 2π ( p S D H D )
(A.1)
which is higher than would have been observed under the alliance equilibrium by twice
the amount of the premium (note also that half of this premium will go to each of the
operating airlines). We can state that passengers on the routes under consideration will
be equally divided by all four airlines in a sense that each airline will obtain the premium
from each of the passengers flying on this route, but serve only one half of the traffic.
That is, each passenger will be a source of positive profits for two airlines.
As for Part (f) of the Proposition, Part (a) clearly suggests that fares offered on the onestop hub-to-hub markets will be equal to the respective marginal costs. As for unclear
distribution of traffic, consider market for travel between hub 1 and hub 4. Here any
passenger faces four options, two involving change of carrier and two not involving such
a change, but in each case the passenger will face equal fares. Yet, what is important for
our analysis is that there will be no positive profits earned by either carrier on these
markets.
21
Ruling out other options, involving more stops.
If we consider other two airlines we will see that they are able to offer rather similar alternatives to the
passenger wishing to travel on the route under consideration. So, in the end traffic will be divided not by two,
but by four airlines, but analysis is logically more tractable if we only consider two options available to the
passenger.
22
36