STRATEGIC EFFECTS OF AIRLINE ALLIANCES*
Ricardo Flores-Fillol and Rafael Moner-Colonques**
WP-AD 2006-06
Correspondence to: Ricardo Flores-Fillol. Departament d'Economia i d'Història Econòmica, Edifici B,
Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona, 08193 Bellaterra (Barcelona), Spain. Tel.: +34935811811; fax:
+34935812012. E-mail: rflores@idea.uab.es.
Editor: Instituto Valenciano de Investigaciones Económicas, S.A.
Primera Edición Junio, 2006
Depósito Legal: V-2388-2006
IVIE working papers offer in advance the results of economic research under way in order to
encourage a discussion process before sending them to scientific journals for their final
publication.
* We are grateful to Inés Macho-Stadler, José Sempere-Monerris and Ramón Faulí-Oller for their
comments and suggestions. We are also grateful for the comments received during the congress "XXI
Jornadas de Economía Industrial" held in Bilbao in September 2005. Flores-Fillol acknowledges financial
support from the Spanish Ministry of Education and Science, fellowship SEC2002-02506, and the
research grant BEC2003-01132.
** Ricardo Flores-Fillol: Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona and Rafael Moner-Colonques: Universitat
de València.
STRATEGIC EFFECTS OF AIRLINE ALLIANCES
Ricardo Flores-Fillol and Rafael Moner-Colonques
ABSTRACT
This paper looks at the endogenous formation of airline alliances by
means of a two-stage game where first airlines decide whether to form an
alliance and then fares are determined. We analyze the profitability and the
strategic effects of airline alliances when two complementary alliances,
following different paths, may be formed to serve a certain city-pair market.
The formation of a complementary alliance is shown to hurt outsiders and that
fares decrease in the interline market. Contrary to what might be expected, we
find that complementary alliances are not always profitable, even in the
presence of economies of traffic density. The interplay between market size, the
degree of product differentiation and the intensity of economies of traffic
density determines whether the market equilibrium entails no alliances, a single
alliance or a double alliance.
JEL classification: L13, L2, L93.
Keywords: complementary airline alliances, economies of traffic density, product
differentiation.
2
1
Introduction
The air transportation sector has witnessed a number of changes since the deregulation processes of the US industry (in the 1980s) and of the European industry (in
the 1990s). These changes include the substantial decline in the number of major
carriers, the intensified reorganization of routes into hub-and-spoke networks and,
still taking place, the formation of strategic alliances among international carriers.1
In particular, a formal explanation to the rise of international airline alliances seems
to be lacking. The present paper identifies conditions under which airline alliances
are strategically advantageous, examines the effects on carriers outside the alliance
and studies how travel volumes and fares are affected.
Airline alliances are designed to offer passengers a seamless service in order to
minimize some of the inconveniences of interline multi-carrier trips. They allow the
carriers to rely on a partner to provide flight to destinations where they lack route
authority. Cooperation adopts several forms - which in many instances come close
to effective merger - and includes codesharing agreements, the coordination of flight
schedules and the joint use of frequent flyer programs. Collaboration between airlines
can be traced as far back as the 1940s when, for instance, Air France was involved
in setting up the operations of many African airlines, such as Air Afrique, Royal Air
Maroc and Tunisair. The first major multi-partner alliance was that between Delta
Air Lines, Singapore Airlines and Swissair in the early 1990s. At present, almost
every major airline belongs to a big international alliance: Oneworld, Star Alliance,
and The Sky Team.2 The structure of the industry is constantly changing as with the
recent merger (September 2004) between Air France and KLM, and the announced
agreement to merge between America West Airlines and US Airways (May 2005).
Since the major alliances enjoy antitrust immunity, another advantage of an alliance is related with cooperative pricing in interline trips. It seems that IATA’s
1
2
See Morrison and Winston (1995) for an overview of developments in the industry.
The Oneworld Alliance includes British Airways, American Airlines, Iberia, Lan Chile, Aer
Lingus, Qantas, Cathay Pacific and Finnair among others. The most important airlines in the
Star Alliance are Lufthansa, United Airlines, US Airways, Air Canada, All Nippon Airways,
Thai Airways, Singapore Airlines, Air New Zealand, Varig Brasil, SAS, the Austrian Group and
British Midland. Finally, The Sky Team is mainly composed of Air France, Delta Air Lines, KLM,
Northwest, Continental Airlines, Alitalia, Korean Air, CSA and Malaysian Air System.
3
(International Air Transport Association) influence over negotiations on interline
fares has declined and there is evidence that, after the deregulation processes both
in the US and in Europe, airline cooperation has pushed fares down whereas travel
volumes have increased.3 In a sense, this is what theory would predict since joint
pricing of complementary flights through a hub airport internalizes the negative effect of separate pricing. An airline alliance is an agreement within a network which
involves multiproduct competition and, since the airline industry shows evidence of
increasing returns to traffic density, this means that competition transmits across
routes through costs, a feature that becomes particularly relevant in an environment with strategic interaction. It therefore suggests that antitrust treatment on
this issue should be carefully looked at. Although alliances can be beneficial to firms
and/or consumers (for instance by enhancing efficiency and service quality), they
can as well significantly reduce or eliminate competition on routes where the allied
companies were former competitors. In Europe, competition rules (i.e. Articles 81
and 82 of the EU Treaty) are fully applicable to air transport. Indeed the parties,
in their seeking for authorization, try and offer arguments so that the Commission
gives an individual exemption based on Article 81(3).4 The Commission clears or
prohibits airline mergers on the basis of Merger Regulation 4064/89, amended by
Regulation 1310/97. In the United States, the Department of Transportation (DOT)
had the authority over airline mergers until 1989. Since then, the Antitrust Division
of the Department of Justice reviews airline mergers and acquisitions, although the
DOT retains authority over some matters. Thus, the Antitrust Division has challenged agreements in violation of section 2 of the Sherman Act and/or section 7 of
the Clayton Act. Overall, there are no clear guidelines but many airline alliances
receive antitrust immunity subject to conditions, which range from the surrender
of take-off and landing slots and the guarantee that partners do not increase frequencies to obstruct entry, to the limitation or the extension in the use of frequent
3
Brueckner (2003), using data from the U.S. Department of Transportation’s Passenger Origin-
Destination Survey, concludes that airline alliances lead to lower interline fares. His analysis shows
that, when combined codesharing and antitrust immunity, airline cooperation leads to a reduction
in interline fares between 17% and 30%.
4
Article 81(1) prohibits agreements between firms that encompass fixing prices, sharing markets
and so on. However, paragraph 3 allows for an exemption on the application of paragraph 1 if the
proposed agreements satisfy certain requirements such as the promotion of technical progress to
the consumers benefit.
4
flyer programs. One way or the other, the partners receive a lenient treatment by
antitrust authorities since they can determine fares for interline trips in a way that
would not otherwise be possible.5 By now, close cooperation between European
and US authorities has been intensified regarding transatlantic alliance cases; with
regard to "open skies" agreements, the EU and the US are relaunching negotiations
to create a common air space.
To illustrate our analysis let us consider the following simple network structure.
Suppose that a passenger wishes to travel from Madrid to Washington. She can fly
via Chicago O’Hare International or via Amsterdam Schiphol. In the former case,
Madrid - Chicago is provided by Iberia (e.g. IB6275) and Chicago - Washington R.
Reagan National is operated by American Airlines (e.g. AA1730). In the latter, the
passenger can fly with KLM/AF from Madrid to Amsterdam (e.g. KL1708) and
then make the trip between Amsterdam and Washington Dulles International with
Northwest (e.g. NW8651). As it turns out, Iberia and American Airlines belong to
the Oneworld alliance. On the other hand, KLM/AF and Northwest are partners in
The Sky Team. Alternatively, a passenger travelling from Frankfurt to Minneapolis
may fly either with Lufthansa (e.g. LH4670) and Northwest (e.g. NW0041) via
Amsterdam Schiphol; or with Delta Airlines (e.g. DL0027) and Airtran Airways
(e.g. FL857) via Atlanta Hartsfield-Jackson.6 As it turns out, these four firms are
independent carriers. We will provide a theoretical explanation to this type of observed phenomena as a result of strategic behavior.
Travellers perceive a composite trip using two or more airlines as a differentiated
product from other substitute composite trips. That differentiation can be explained
by a number of reasons such as brand loyalty, frequent flyer programs, frequency of
services, quality considerations and so on. In addition, there is empirical evidence
5
The reader might like to look at "Airline Alliances and Mergers - The Emerging Commis-
sion Policy" (2001) by J. Stragier; the statement by R. Hewitt Pate from the Antitrust Division
concerning "International Aviation Alliances: Market Turmoil and the Future of Airline Competition" (2001); and the report "Entry and Competition in the US Airline Industry: Issues and
Opportunities" (1999), by the Transportation Research Board.
6
The reader can access www.airwise.com and find plenty of examples where a passenger must
change planes on their way to final destination where carriers belong to the same alliance or not;
trips can be made through different hubs.
5
that the airline industry, after deregulation, exhibits increasing returns to traffic
density (see Brueckner and Spiller, 1994, and Creel and Farell, 2001). The model
that we propose will consider a network structure to capture competition between
routes through different hubs. It is our purpose to evaluate the role played by market
size, the degree of product differentiation and the intensity of economies of traffic
density as factors that cause strategic airline alliances to show up. We will look at
the endogenous formation of airline alliances by means of a two-stage game where
first airlines simultaneous and independently decide whether to form an alliance
and then, given the inherited outcome of the first stage, fares are simultaneous and
independently determined. Specifically, the aim of our paper is to analyze the profitability and the strategic effects of two complementary alliances, following different
paths, that may be formed to serve a certain city-pair market. We wish to answer
the following questions: when are alliances profitable for the potential partners?,
what are their effects on outsiders?, what is the outsiders’ optimal response? and
how are fares and travel volumes affected?
Our main findings can be summarized as follows. Firstly, the formation of a
complementary alliance is shown to hurt outsiders and that fares will decrease in
the interline market. Secondly, in contrast to what might be expected, the formation of two alliances (double alliance) is not always the equilibrium outcome.
This is a particularly remarkable result because integration of complementary goods
together with the presence of economies of traffic density are elements that favor
the profitability of alliance agreements. Thus, a sufficiently high degree of product differentiation is enough to ensure the double alliance equilibrium, regardless of
market size and the size of the economies of traffic density, since the intensity of
competition is weak. At the other extreme, if product differentiation is low enough
then no alliance will occur in equilibrium. This may also occur for small economies
of traffic density when a low enough degree of product differentiation is combined
with high enough market size. Interestingly enough, asymmetric equilibrium with a
single alliance may arise as the degree of product differentiation increases. Broadly
speaking, the single alliance equilibrium shows up for intermediate values of market
size together with economies of traffic density that are not too significant. This
result provides an explanation about why some carriers decide to remain non-allied
6
(e.g. Japan Airlines) and in several routes only one alliance offers interline tickets.7
Furthermore, the market equilibrium can be a double alliance and yet the carriers
be better off in a no alliance situation for a sufficiently low degree of product differentiation.
The existing literature on airline alliances is sparse. A number of papers have
focused on providing reasons and conditions under which hub-and-spoke networks
are equilibrium structures.8 There only exist a few theoretical contributions on
airline alliances, first initiated by Brueckner and Spiller (1991) who developed a
hub-and-spoke model where an airline is considered as a multiproduct firm with
cost complementarities. These theoretical analyses include Park (1997), Brueckner
(2001), Brueckner and Whalen (2000), Hassin and Shy (2004) and Bilotkach (2005).
The latter three references assume product differentiation although only Brueckner
and Whalen (2000) considers economies of traffic density. It is Park (1997) who
examined the consequences of parallel and complementary alliances on output levels, profits and welfare. Complementary alliances are analyzed by Brueckner and
Whalen (2000) and Brueckner (2001) under different network structures. We will
also address this type of alliances where emphasis is put on the strategic rationale for alliance formation. Brueckner (2001) considers two airlines to study the
effect of alliances on traffic levels and fares both in the inter-hub and the domestic markets. Hassin and Shy (2004) also examine codesharing agreements among
airlines competing on international routes and show that codesharing including all
carriers is welfare improving. Brueckner and Whalen (2000) contemplate that an
international passenger may normally opt between several carrier pairs when making an interline trip. They develop a particular example where aggregate demand
does not vary either with the degree of substitutability or the number of products.
This is a satisfactory property when dealing with more than two firms but there
may be some routes that are better accounted for when total travel volumes are
not fixed. Brueckner and Whalen (2000) consider the no alliance, the symmetric
and the asymmetric alliance situations where domestic markets are operated by two
competing carriers; their focus is on the theoretical and empirical price effects of
7
For instance, most of the one-stop routes between Italy and France are only served by The Sky
Team (e.g. the route Rome Fiumicino - Nantes Atlantique).
8
See Oum et al. (1995), Berechman et al. (1998), Hendricks et al. (1999), Barla and Constantatos (2000) and Brueckner (2004).
7
international airline alliances.9 Our paper is also related with Bilotkach (2005), who
develops a model of price competition among four carriers where two alliances are
possible to examine their effects on fares and travel volumes with assuming constant
returns to scale; unlike Brueckner and Whalen (2000), this author includes routes
between hub airports. Our analysis complements these earlier contributions and
takes a game theoretical approach to examine strategic alliance formation. A complete characterization of the different equilibria is provided in terms of market size,
the degree of product differentiation and the intensity of economies of traffic density.
The paper is structured as follows. Section 2 introduces the model presenting
the pre-alliance equilibrium and the equilibria arising from the situations with a
single and a double alliance, respectively. The effects on fares and travel volumes
are analyzed in Section 3. A simultaneous two-stage game of airline alliances is then
presented in Section 4. A brief concluding section closes the paper.
2
The model
Basic Assumptions
The model’s network structure is shown in Figure 1.
Figure 1: The Network
Airline 1 operates route AH, airline 2 serves route HB, airline 3 provides the
flight AK and airline 4 operates route KB and all of them enjoy monopoly power
9
The effect of airline alliances has also been empirically investigated by Oum et al. (1996), Park
and Zhang (1998) and Brueckner (2003), among many others. These studies provide evidence that
international alliances lead to lower fares, increases in the number of passengers on the relevant
routes and that airline cooperation generates important benefits for interline passengers.
8
in their respective routes. They face standard linear demand functions qi = α − pi ,
where qi represents the travel volume, pi denotes the fare charged by airline i for
i = 1, 2, 3, 4 and α is a positive parameter that measures market size.10 In addition,
there are travellers wishing to fly from city A to city B (interline market) either
through airport H or through airport K. We assume there are no travellers willing
to fly between H and K.11 In this case, travellers must fly by either combining
airlines 1 and 2 or by combining airlines 3 and 4 so that routes AH and HB are
regarded as complementary products (just as routes AK and KB together). However, the trips through airport H and airport K are viewed by travellers as substitute
trips. There is no direct flight connecting cities A and B so that passengers have to
interline at the hubs H and K. The proposed network structure is the simplest possible configuration including rivalry between two composite one-stop trips. It aims
at capturing the particular aspect of alliances that enjoy antitrust immunity, where
two different carriers may cooperate to offer interline trips in which passengers need
to travel with both of them. We consider that cooperation is full, which implies that
the alliance will behave as a single carrier in the market for which it is formed at
the eyes of the passengers.
We will assume that demand functions for air travel between cities A and B are
linear as follows,
Q12 = α − (p1 + p2 ) + d(p3 + p4 )
(1)
Q34 = α − (p3 + p4 ) + d(p1 + p2 ),
where Q12 and Q34 represent the travel volumes on the two interline flights in the
market and d, that ranges between 0 and 1, captures the degree of product differentiation taking value 0 when products are independent and 1 when they are perfectly
homogeneous. This demand system for differentiated products follows from solving
10
Note that, for low and medium density routes, the proportion of monopolist city-pair markets
is very important. For the case of the low density routes, this proportion in Europe and the US
accounts for 90% and 77% on short routes and for 79% and 94% on medium-haul routes, respectively. For the case of the medium density routes, this proportion in Europe and the US accounts
for 87% and 86% on short routes and for 35% and 71% on medium-haul routes, respectively. See
the IATA report "Air Transport Markets in Europe and the US, a comparison" (2001).
11
In considering an inter-hub demand each carrier would operate in three markets. Then, the
effects of alliances would be more complex because a complementary alliance in an interline market
would have effects in all the three markets for each carrier.
9
the optimization problem of a representative passenger with a quasi-linear utility
function a la Dixit (1979)12 and it reflects that composite products are substitutes
for one another up to some extent.13
Brueckner and Whalen (2000) provide an interesting interpretation of this kind
of demand functions in terms of brand loyalty, since an increase in price of one
composite product permits the competitor to "steal" a certain amount of traffic
volume (total travel volume is constant) but both competitors remain in the market.
A and B are assumed equidistant to H and K and a common cost function
C(qi + Qxy ) applies to each of the four links in the network where qi + Qxy accounts
for the total traffic volume using a particular link with xy = 12 for i = 1, 2 and
xy = 34 for i = 3, 4. As in Brueckner and Spiller (1991), we assume linear marginal
cost functions of the form:
C 0 (qi + Qxy ) = 1 − θ(qi + Qxy ),
(2)
that reflect increasing returns to traffic density,14 which is a required assumption in
airline markets.15 The intensity of the economics of traffic density is measured by
12
α
)(Q12 + Q34 ) −
A representative passenger maximizes U (Q12 , Q34 ) = ( 1−d
Q212 +2dQ12 Q34 +Q234
.
2(1−d2 )
This type of utility function has been used by Singh and Vives (1984) and by Economides and Salop
(1992). We are therefore assuming an equal size of the market (α) both for the interline and for the
short markets. A natural extension of the model would be to introduce asymmetric market sizes
by supposing larger short markets. This extension complicates the presentation without offering
any additional insights. Results are qualitatively similar as long as the difference between the two
market sizes remains sufficiently small.
13
As in other papers in the literature, we assume that the interline fare is the sum of the fares
for markets AH and BH (or AK and BK). Such an assumption implies that a carrier gives
equal treatment to all passengers on its flight. In contrast, it seems closer to reality to consider
that a carrier sets a fare for passengers stopping at the hub and a "subfare" for those doing the
interline trip, as done by Brueckner and Whalen (2000) and Brueckner (2001). This practice,
which would lead to different constraints on the parameters, entails some degree of coordination
between carriers even under the pre-alliance situation. We keep the former pricing behavior for
analytical reasons and to better capture the move from a purely non-cooperative setting to others
involving cooperation.
14
For instance, the cost function corresponding to link AH is: C(q1 + Q12 ) = (q1 + Q12 )(1 −
θ(q1 +Q12 )
).
2
15
Brueckner et al. (1992) and Park (1997) also use this marginal cost function, suggested by
Brueckner and Spiller (1991), to model economics of traffic density that can be considered as a
stylized fact of the airline industry as showed in the empirical literature on airlines. See for instance
Brueckner and Spiller (1994) or Creel and Farell (2001).
10
θ ≥ 0 where constant returns correspond to θ = 0.
The pre-alliance equilibrium
We begin by characterizing the pre-alliance solution. Airlines choose non-cooperatively
their respective profit-maximizing fares. In this situation the fare to travel from A to
B (either through H or through K) is just the sum of the fares of the two short markets (either p1 +p2 or p3 +p4 ). The profit functions are πi = pi (qi +Qxy )−C(qi +Qxy )
again with xy = 12 for i = 1, 2 and xy = 34 for i = 3, 4. The system of first order
conditions is given by ∂π 1 /∂p1 = 0, ∂π 2 /∂p2 = 0, ∂π 3 /∂p3 = 0 and ∂π 4 /∂p4 = 0.
Fulfillment of the second order conditions require that θ < 1. The equilibrium price,
which is symmetric across markets (hence we omit subscripts i and xy), is given by,
pna =
2(α(1 − 2θ) + 1)
,
5 − 2d − 6θ + 4dθ
where superscript na denotes the no-alliances scenario. Equilibrium travel volumes
and profits are the following:
q na =
α(3 − 2d − 2θ) − 2
,
5 − 2d − 6θ + 4dθ
Qna =
α(1 + 2d − 4θd + 2θ) − 4(1 − d)
,
5 − 2d − 6θ + 4dθ
θ(qna +Qna ) na
)(q + Qna ).
(3)
2
The equilibrium profits consist of the margin (price minus average cost) times
π na = (pna − 1 +
the travel volume in both the short and the interline markets. Clearly, there exist
some conditions regarding market size, α, the degree of product differentiation, d,
and the size of economies of traffic density, θ, for which positive prices, positive
travel volumes, positive margins and positive marginal costs are obtained.
The single alliance equilibrium
With a single alliance, either airlines 1 and 2 set the fare for flight from A
to B through hub H cooperatively while competition with flight through hub K
remains, or it is airlines 3 and 4 that set cooperatively the fare through hub K
while competition with flight through hub H remains. Denote by Pp the fare of the
interline flight established jointly by the partners in the alliance. The alternative
interline flight is priced separately, po1 + po2 , where subscripts o1 and o2 stand for
11
the two outsiders. Both alliance partners are symmetric and both outsiders too.
The demand functions for the short markets do not change but, in market AB
they now take the form: Qp = α − Pp + d(po1 + po2 ) for the alliance partners and
Qo = α − (po1 + po2 ) + dPp for outsiders. Thus, alliance partners choose two fares
since they price separately the short and the interline market in which they operate.
The joint profit function for the partners, p1 and p2, becomes π p = pp1 qp1 + pp2 qp2 +
Pp Qp −C(qp1 +Qp )−C(qp2 +Qp ) and for the outsiders are the same as before. Solving
the system formed by ∂π p /∂pp1 = 0, ∂π p /∂pp2 = 0, ∂π o1 /∂po1 = 0, ∂π o2 /∂po2 = 0
and ∂πp /∂Pp = 0 yields, given symmetry, the following equilibrium prices,
4dθ(1 + α − 2αθ) + 2d2 (2θ − 1)(α(3θ − 1) − 1) − (6θ − 5)(α(5θ − 2) − 2)
,
54θ − 20 − 36θ2 + 2d2 (2 + θ(10θ − 9))
pap =
4(2 − 3θ)(α(2θ − 1) − 1) + d(1 − 2θ)(α(7θ − 2) − 4)
,
54θ − 20 − 36θ2 + 2d2 (2 + θ(10θ − 9))
4d(2 − 5θ)(α(2θ − 1) − 1) + (5 − 6θ)(α(7θ − 2) − 4)
Ppa =
,
54θ − 20 − 36θ2 + 2d2 (2 + θ(10θ − 9))
pao =
where superscript a identifies the single alliance scenario.16 The second order conditions for a maximum now require that θ < 32 . This condition follows from the
negativity of the Hessian matrix corresponding to the optimization problem of the
allied carriers. Equilibrium travel volumes are,
Qap =
Qao =
4d2 (1 − 2θ)(αθ − 2) + (5 − 6θ)(4 − α(2 + θ)) − 4d(2 − θ)(1 − α(2θ − 1))
,
54θ − 20 − 36θ2 + 2d2 (2 + θ(10θ − 9))
2(3θ − 2)(α + 2αθ − 4) − 2d2 (5θ − 2)(α(2θ − 1) − 2) − d(2θ − 3)(α(7θ − 2) − 4)
,
54θ − 20 − 36θ2 + 2d2 (2 + θ(10θ − 9))
qpa =
4dθ(α(2θ − 1) − 1) − (2 + α(θ − 2))(6θ − 5) + 2d2 (2θ − 1)(1 + α(2θ − 1))
,
54θ − 20 − 36θ2 + 2d2 (2 + θ(10θ − 9))
d(2θ − 1)(α(7θ − 2) − 4) − 2(3θ − 2)(2 + α(2θ − 3)) + 2d2 α(2 + θ(10θ − 9))
.
54θ − 20 − 36θ2 + 2d2 (2 + θ(10θ − 9))
The equilibrium profits for each of the two outsiders are given by:
qoa =
π ao = (pao − 1 +
16
θ(qoa +Qao ) a
)(qo + Qao ).
2
(4)
It is important to know that, when the long market is priced jointly, the stability of the
network requires non-arbitrage conditions to apply. These conditions are of two types. The first
type prevents passengers willing to do a short market trip (AH or BH) from buying an interline
ticket (AB ticket) and then get off at the hub airport (H airport). The second type of conditions
ensure that nobody would buy an interline ticket if breaking down the trip into two parts were
cheaper.
12
However, the joint equilibrium profits for the allied carriers are now:
θ(qpa +Qap ) a
(5)
)2qp + (Ppa − 2 + θ(qpa +Qap ))Qap .
2
The alliance "partially unbundles" the interline from the short markets since the
π ap = (pap − 1 +
interline market is priced separately. Nevertheless, partners are not able to extract
monopoly profits because markets remain connected through the link-dependent
cost function. One can observe that (3) and (4) have the same structure whereas
(5) is different. In (5) there are two margins: one corresponding to the short market (price minus the average cost) and another one corresponding to the interline
market (price minus twice the average cost) since the interline market needs to use
two links of the network while the short market just needs to use one link.
The double alliance equilibrium
We now characterize the situation when two interline alliances are formed, that
is, when airlines 1 and 2 behave cooperatively in setting fares and so do airlines
3 and 4. Denote by P12 and P34 the fare of the interline flight through hub H
and hub K, respectively. The interline market demands are now given by Q12 =
α − P12 + dP34 and Q34 = α − P34 + dP12 . Joint profit maximization results in the
following symmetric equilibrium prices (hence we omit subscripts):
P aa =
4 + 2α − 7αθ
,
4 − 2d − 6θ + 5dθ
paa =
(3d − 5)αθ + (1 + α)(2 − d)
4 − 2d − 6θ + 5dθ
and we employ superscripts aa for the case where both alliances occur. As in the
single alliance equilibrium, the second order conditions for a maximum impose that
θ < 32 . The corresponding travel volumes and profits are given by,
Qaa =
(2 + θ)α − 4 + d(4 − 2αθ)
,
4 − 2d − 6θ + 5dθ
qaa =
(2d − 1)αθ − (α − 1)(d − 2)
4 − 2d − 6θ + 5dθ
and the equilibrium profits can be written as follows:
π aa = (paa − 1 +
θ(q aa +Qaa ) aa
)2q + (P aa − 2 + θ(q aa +Qaa ))Qaa .
2
(6)
Before characterizing the effects of alliances and the Nash equilibrium in alliance
formation, there are a number of restrictions that must be borne in mind. This
amounts to comparing a number of bounds on market size α.
13
Assumption 1 A market in our model is defined by a triple {d, θ, α}. We restrict attention to markets {d, θ, α} ∈ R where R is the relevant region in our
analysis, i.e., the region ensuring positive prices, quantities, marginal costs,
margins and the compliance with non-arbitrage conditions are guaranteed in
the three scenarios under consideration (pre-alliance, single alliance and double
alliance). See Appendix 1 for the details.
3
Effects on Fares and Travel Volumes
We will begin by comparing the changes in firms’ fares and travel volumes in a
move from the pre-alliance situation to the single alliance situation. Then, we will
establish the corresponding variations when two alliances are formed rather than a
single one.
Proposition 1 For any market {d, θ, α} ∈ R, the formation of a complementary
alliance has the following effects:
i) For the partners, the fare Ppa is lower than the pre-alliance fare pna + pna and
travel volume increases, i.e. Qap > Qna (direct effect).
ii) Outsiders’ fares and travel volumes are lower, i.e. pao < pna and Qao < Qna
(outsider effect).
iii) As for the short markets, since pao < pna , we observe that qoa > qna . For the
allied carriers, the effects on pp and qp are unclear.
Proof. See Appendix 2.
The above results partially confirm Cournot’s (1838) model of complementary
duopoly. Cournot considered the merger of two monopolists that produce complementary goods (zinc and copper) into a single (fused) monopolist that produces the
combination of them (brass). The price of the composite good is lower than under independent ownership (direct effect). The alliance between airlines that offer
complementary services internalizes the externality that arises when they set fares
independently thus ignoring the effects on their individual markups. This result,
part i) above, has already been suggested by earlier theoretical work by Brueckner
(2001) and Brueckner and Whalen (2000) although under somewhat different modeling and network structures. Indeed empirical evidence in Brueckner and Whalen
14
(2000) and Brueckner (2003) find that alliance partners charge interline fares that
are below those charged when they were non-allied.
To see the intuition, note that the first order conditions in the single alliance situation implicitly define the corresponding reaction functions in prices.17 Whenever
θ < 12 , which is almost always the case, the effects implied by the reaction functions
are Pp = f (pp , po ), pp = f(Pp , po ) and po = f(Pp ). Therefore, the decrease in the
+
+
+
−
+
interline fare induced by the alliance leads to a reduction in the fares set by outsiders
since Pp and po are strategic complements. Rather obviously a lower interline fare
permits partners to capture a higher travel volume and this occurs at the expense
of a lower interline traffic by the rivals. On the other hand, since the outsiders’
fares are lower than under the pre-alliance situation it follows that there is a gain
in travel volumes for short trips.
Besides, the decrease in the interline fare induces a reduction in the fare pp but
this fare increases due to the indirect effect via the decrease in the fare of outsiders.
The final effect on partners’ fare and travel volumes for their short trips depend on
market size, the degree of product differentiation and the intensity of economies of
traffic density. Although allied carriers are monopolists in their short markets, they
cannot extract monopoly profits because the equilibrium prices and quantities are
linked through the cost function because costs are link-dependent and not market
dependent. Therefore, there is an output reallocation effect affecting the partners in
their short market equilibrium values causing a non-monotonic relationship of prices
and quantities when an alliance to serve the interline market is formed.
An interesting by-product of the previous analysis is that, for outsiders, the
revenue in the interline market decreases since both the fare and the travel volume
are lower in a move to a single alliance setting (outsider effect). Further, revenue in
the short market is unclear because the variation in fare goes in the opposite direction
to the one in travel volume. Finally, as total travel volume by the outsiders decreases
this means that average costs are larger; the output reallocation makes carriers to
take less profit from the presence of economies of traffic density. Consequently,
outsiders will very likely be harmed by the formation of an alliance. Boyer (1992)
17
These are the three reaction functions for the single alliance case:
Pp =
2+α(1−4θ)+2(1−2θ)dpo +2θpp
,
2(1−θ)
pp =
1+α(1−2θ)+θPp −2θdpo
2−θ
and po =
2+2α(1−2θ)+(1−2θ)dPp
.
5−6θ
These
functions are not always upward or downward sloping since they depend on whether θ is higher or
lower than 12 .
15
suggests that non-participating firms in a merger may be harmed by a merger. He
argues that this is more likely to occur if there are inter-market connections. This is
the case in the current setting where markets are linked through the cost function.
The next proposition summarizes the comparison of firms’ fares and travel volumes involved in the single and double alliance equilibria. Notice that the term
outsiders will now allude to the airlines that had previously formed an alliance.
Proposition 2 For any market {d, θ, α} ∈ R, the formation of two complementary
alliances as opposed to a single alliance has the following effects:
i) For the new partners, the fare P aa is lower than their single alliance fare 2pao and
travel volume increases, i.e. Qaa > Qao (direct effect).
ii) Outsiders’ fares and travel volumes are lower, i.e. P aa < Ppa and Qaa < Qap
(outsider effect).
iii) We observe that paa > pap (and qaa < qpa ), which is the opposite to the move from
the no alliance to the single alliance situation, in the outsiders’s short markets. For
the new allied carriers, the effects on po and qo are unclear.
Proof. See Appendix 2.
Again, the alliance of the new partners results in lower fares for their interline
market. Given that prices set by the new partners and by outsiders in the interline
market are strategic complements (upward sloping reaction functions), it follows that
the interline fare of the already allied carriers (now outsiders) goes down. Thus, the
direct and the outsider effects work in the same way as in Proposition 1. However,
the effect on the outsiders’ short markets is now different. In the case of Proposition
1(iii) above, the decrease in the price in the short market was a consequence of the
outsider effect since the price on the interline market was the sum of the price of
two short markets. Now this is not the case anymore and the outsiders react to the
alliance by increasing their short market fares.
As in the move from no alliance to single alliance, there is an output reallocation effect affecting the new allied carriers in their short market equilibrium values
causing a non-monotonic relationship of prices and quantities when moving from a
single to a double alliance scenario.
To sum up, concerning outsiders’ interline market, alliance formation is disadvantageous in terms of revenue no matter they set fares cooperatively (Proposition
2) or non-cooperatively (Proposition 1) in the interline market. Hence, a setting
16
with interline alliances leads to lower fares, which is consistent with some observed
facts in the airline industry, as found by Brueckner (2003).
4
A simultaneous game of airline alliances
The foregoing analysis suggests that airline alliances are profitable only under some
circumstances. The formation of airline alliances is endogenously obtained as a
result of the following two-stage game. In the first stage airlines 1 and 2 and airlines
3 and 4 decide simultaneously and independently whether to form an alliance. In
stage two, given the inherited outcome from the first stage, airlines set fares.
Given the symmetry in the model it suffices to study the best-response of the
potential partners (either airlines 1 and 2, or alternatively 3 and 4) i) when the
rivals decide not to form a complementary alliance, and ii) when the rivals decide
to form a complementary alliance. Let us define
Ψa (d, θ, α) =
πap
− π na .
2
(7)
Therefore Ψa (d, θ, α) > 0 defines when airlines 1 and 2 (alternatively 3 and 4)
will form an alliance given that the rivals do not.18 The following lemma results from
the analysis of this unilateral incentive to form an alliance. Sufficient conditions are
given in parenthesis.
Lemma 1 For any market {d, θ, α} ∈ R, whenever the rivals decide not to form an
alliance, two potential partners:
i) will form an alliance either for a sufficient degree of product differentiation (d ≤
da ≡ 0.802) or for a sufficiently high intensity of economies of traffic density (θ >
a
θ ≡ 0.08);
ii) will not form an alliance whenever the two routes are close enough substitutes
a
(d > d ≡ 0.856);
a
iii) will either form or not form an alliance for values of d ∈ (da , d ]. In this case,
an alliance will not be formed for high values of α combined with low values of θ.
Proof. See Appendix 2.
18
It is assumed that profits are equally shared by partners once they decide to ally and set up a
complementary alliance.
17
This lemma states that a sufficiently high degree of product differentiation guarantees at least one alliance in equilibrium. On the other hand, when products are
close substitutes, which supposes that competition intensity is strong, it is preferable
to remain non-allied given that the rivals do not form an alliance. In this case, it is
strategically profitable for carriers not to cooperate. For values between the specified thresholds, either strategy might be the best-response (BR) depending on the
specific value of the parameters. Figure 2 below constitutes a representative example
a
for d ∈ (da , d ],19 where α(θ) is obtained from solving Ψa (d = 0.835, θ, α) = 0.
Figure 2: BR when rivals do not form an alliance
Values below (above) the function α(θ) identify those cases where, as long as
both the lower and the upper bounds on α are respected, the best-response is (not)
to form an alliance. One can observe that larger values of θ create incentives for
alliance formation since they foster efficiency gains. In fact, as stated in the lemma,
a sufficiently high θ ensures a single alliance for any market {d, θ, α} ∈ R. On the
other hand, it seems that carriers operating in large markets (α) are less willing to
form alliances when the rivals do not do it. Furthermore, as the degree of product
differentiation decreases (higher values of d), the function α(θ) shifts downwards,
thereby enlarging the region for no alliance to be the best-response.
19
As stated in Assumption 1, markets {d, θ, α} ∈ R require to respect some bounds on θ and α.
Following the notation in Appendix 1, θ(d) = L2, α(d, θ) = B2 and α(d, θ) = B3 when d = 0.835.
18
To see the intuition note that the change in a carrier’s profits when moving to
a single alliance setting can be decomposed in three terms. The first one is related
with the variation in revenue from the interline market (∆RI ); the second one comes
from the difference in revenue in the short market (∆RS ); and the third one has to
do with the change in costs due to the reallocation in travel volumes. Only the latter
variation has got an unambiguous sign. It happens that total travel volume by the
allied carriers increases (Qap + qpa > Qna + qna ). Since we have already argued that
the joint cost function exhibits increasing returns to traffic density in the supply of
interline and short trips, higher travel volumes imply a better exploitation of these
economies of traffic density. Concerning the first term, it has been shown above
that the interline fare goes down while travel volume goes up (direct effect). It can
be proven that ∆RI = f(d, θ , α), i.e. the fare effect is more likely to dominate the
− − +
travel volume effect, other things equal, the higher the market size; the higher the
degree of product differentiation; or the smaller the intensity of economies of traffic
density. As for the second term, the variation associated with the revenue from the
short market cannot be neatly established since it involves non-monotonic effects,
but numerical examples indicate that ∆RS is more likely to increase when d does
not take intermediate values.
To sum up, there is a positive effect coming from the efficiency gains due to cost
savings, that may be offset by possible revenue losses (either in the short or in the
interline market). Lemma 1 states that typically, but not always, the positive effects
outweigh negative ones, this meaning that there is a unilateral incentive to form a
complementary alliance given that the rivals do not form an alliance.
The interesting conclusion from our analysis is that, contrary to what one might
expect for an alliance with complementary trips in presence of economies of traffic
density, it is not necessarily optimal for carriers to create an alliance when the other
potential partners remain non-allied. If there were no competition from a substitute
flight, then the alliance would always turn out profitable - as in Cournot’s example.
However, the presence of other airlines serving the interline market unveils that the
alliance will be profitable only under certain circumstances. Therefore, when the
two possible one-stop interline trips are "sufficiently substitutes" at the eyes of the
traveller, the best-response for two potential partners is not to form an alliance when
the other carriers remain non-allied (e.g. Japan Airlines).
Next we study the best-response of the potential partners when the rivals form a
19
complementary alliance. Thus, let us define
Ψaa (d, θ, α) =
π aa
− π ao .
2
(8)
Hence, Ψaa (d, θ, α) > 0 defines when airlines 1 and 2 (alternatively 3 and 4) will
form an alliance given that the rivals do. The analysis of Ψaa (d, θ, α) leads to the
following result.
Lemma 2 For any market {d, θ, α} ∈ R, whenever the rivals decide to form an
alliance, two potential partners:
i) will also form an alliance either for a sufficient degree of product differentiation
(d ≤ daa ≡ 0.707) or for a sufficiently high intensity of economies of traffic density
(θ > θ
aa
≡ 0.195);
ii) will not form an alliance whenever the two routes are rather close substitutes
aa
(d > d
≡ 0.828);
aa
iii) will either form or not form an alliance for values of d ∈ (daa , d ]. In this case,
an alliance will not be formed for intermediate values of α combined with low values
of θ.
Proof. See Appendix 2.
Again, a sufficiently high degree of product differentiation makes alliances strategically profitable. On the other hand, when products are loose substitutes, double
alliance is not an equilibrium. For values between the specified bounds, either strategy might be the best-response. Figure 3 below displays a representative example
aa
for d ∈ (daa , d ],20
20
As stated in Assumption 1, markets {d, θ, α} ∈ R require to respect some bounds on θ and α.
Following the notation in Appendix 1, θ(d) = L2, α(d, θ) = B2 and α(d, θ) = B3 when d = 0.750.
20
Figure 3: BR when rivals form an alliance
where we observe, as in Lemma 1, that larger values of θ create incentives for
alliance formation. In this case, a larger market size seems to foster alliance formation. The functions α1 (θ) and α2 (θ) are the ones that solve Ψaa (d = 0.750, θ, α) = 0.
Thus, values between these two functions indicate that a single alliance is the bestresponse. As the degree of product differentiation decreases (higher values of d), the
functions α1 (θ) and α2 (θ) move far apart thereby enlarging the region where single
alliance is the best-response.
Although the interpretation of Lemma 2 is as before, it is important to notice
that the sufficient conditions to ensure a double alliance are now more stringent,
i.e. either a higher degree of product differentiation (daa < da ) or a higher intensity
of economies of traffic density (θ
aa
a
> θ ) is required. Therefore, we can anticipate
that there will be cases in which the best-response can be to form an alliance if
the rivals do not; but not to form an alliance if the rivals decide to do so, i.e.
Ψa (d, θ, α) > 0 and Ψaa (d, θ, α) < 0. The fact that a setting with two alliances may
not always be privately profitable, certainly opens the door to asymmetric equilibria
which is sometimes a real issue in the airline industry; in fact, there is an important
number of routes where only one international alliance provides interline services
(e.g. most of the one-stop routes between Italy and France are only served by The
Sky Team). Nevertheless, it must be noted that Ψa (d, θ, α) < 0 is not compatible
with Ψaa (d, θ, α) > 0 so that multiple equilibria cannot arise.
21
In the double alliance setting, total travel volume for the new partners increases,
that is, Qaa + q aa > Qao + qoa . This means that the alliance produces an output
reallocation effect which allows the new partners to take advantage of the economies
of traffic density. Besides, a similar analysis to the previous lemma unveils that
revenues in the interline market are higher for a sufficient degree of product differentiation or for small enough economies of traffic density, other things being equal.
On the other hand, the variation in revenues from the short market is negative for
intermediate values of product differentiation or for large enough economies of traffic
density, other things equal. Thus, the above result states that the gains stemming
from travel volume restructuring and interline earnings more than compensate the
losses originated from lower revenues in the short market as long as competition
intensity be sufficiently weak, no matter the size of the economies of traffic density.
Nevertheless, the losses may be more important than the gains as either competition
intensity becomes stronger, or if economies of traffic density are not too significant
or market size is large enough.
In the light of the best-responses studied above, we can easily identify the subgame perfect equilibrium of the game. The next proposition combines the results
stated in the previous two lemmas and singles out sufficient conditions under which
the three possible scenarios are an equilibrium of the game in alliance formation.
In particular, it addresses the corresponding equilibrium for the whole range of the
values of the degree of product differentiation. It should nonetheless be kept in mind
a
that θ > θ ensures at least one alliance and that θ > θ
aa
Since we have daa , da , d
aa
ensures two alliances.21
a
and d , there are five regions to be considered.
Proposition 3 For any market {d, θ, α} ∈ R, the equilibrium in alliance formation
is:
a
i) no alliance for d > d ;
aa
a
ii) either no alliance or single alliance for d ∈ (d , d ]. No alliance will be the
equilibrium for high values of α combined with low values of θ;
iii) no alliance, single alliance or double alliance may be the equilibrium for d ∈
aa
(da , d ] depending on the joint effect of α and θ;
iv) either single alliance or double alliance for d ∈ (daa , da ]. Single alliance will be
for intermediate values of α combined with low values of θ;
21
This means that the no alliance equilibrium in the next proposition, can only arise for markets
a
{d, θ, α} ∈ R with θ < θ .
22
v) double alliance for d ≤ daa .
The proof is straightforward. We conclude that a setting with complementary
alliances arises when the two possible interline trips are strongly differentiated,
whereas alliances will not take place in equilibrium when trips are viewed by travellers as close substitutes. It is worth mentioning that, for intermediate values of
the degree of product differentiation, an asymmetric equilibrium in which only one
alliance occurs is possible in the current setting. Moreover, the transition from the
region where the equilibrium is no alliance to the one where the equilibrium is double alliance is parsimonious since in part ii) above the single alliance equilibrium is
a possibility, in part iii) anything may happen, and in part iv) no alliance is not a
possibility anymore.
The following contention may be useful to illustrate the above proposition. Let
us fix values for market size and economies of traffic density and let the degree of
product differentiation open. Now a pair of carriers have to decide whether to form
an alliance. As argued before, total travel volume by the potential partners increases
when they form an alliance, allowing for a better exploitation of economies of traffic
density. However the effects coming from the interline and short market revenues are
not straightforward. Suppose that d is close to one so that competition intensity is
strong. In this case, the internalization of competition that occurs under cooperation
when setting fares results in greater revenues in the short market since the increase
in short trip traffic is larger than the decrease in fares; the opposite happens to
revenues from the interline market. In this framework, the latter negative effect
outweighs the other two positive effects and the carriers are better off not forming
an alliance.
However, as the degree of product differentiation increases and competition intensity softens, carriers also obtain gains in the interline market thus making the
alliance privately profitable.22 Concerning the rivals, their equilibrium travel volumes go down and the corresponding cost inefficiency incurred suffices to offset any
likely revenue gains so that alliance formation hurts outsiders. This occurs both in
a move to the single alliance equilibrium and from this one to the double alliance
equilibrium. Finally, a sufficiently large degree of product differentiation ensures an
22
Although there might be losses in the short market for intermediate values of d, these are offset
by the efficiency gains due to traffic reallocation and the revenue gains from the interline market.
23
equilibrium with airline alliances.23
A deeper analysis of carriers’ profits in the no alliance and the double alliance
settings reveals that the agents may well get engaged in a prisoner’s dilemma situation. Specifically, let us define
Ψpd (d, θ, α) = π na −
πaa
,
2
(9)
where superscript pd stands for prisoner’s dilemma. Hence, Ψpd (d, θ, α) < 0 concludes that the double alliance is profitable per se; and Ψpd (d, θ, α) > 0 means that
the double alliance leads to a prisoner’s dilemma situation as long as forming an
alliance is a dominant strategy. The fact that outsiders end up worse off when the
rivals form an alliance is behind this possibility. Therefore, the double alliance can
be the equilibrium outcome and yet the four airlines might indeed find themselves
earning lower profits had neither alliance occurred. This can in some sense be considered as an outcome stemming from a "war of alliances".24 The next corollary
summarizes this discussion.
Corollary 1 For any market {d, θ, α} ∈ R , whenever double alliance is the equi-
librium in alliance formation, airlines get engaged in a prisoner’s dilemma situation
for a sufficiently low degree of product differentiation (d > dpd ≡ 0.355).
Proof. See Appendix 2.
We will finish this section with presenting the case of constant returns to traffic
density, i.e. when θ = 0. The previous analysis discloses the difficulties in the characterization of the equilibrium due to the interplay between market size, economies
of traffic density and the degree of product differentiation. The particular solution
for θ = 0 allows us to illustrate the results when the travel volume reallocation effect
is not present.
23
A similar reasoning can be made by letting θ or α vary while keeping the other two variables
fixed.
24
A recent reference by Fridolfsson and Stennek (2005) distinguishes mergers that are profitable
per se from those which these authors call "defensive" mergers. The latter would correspond with
a prisoner’s dilemma situation in the current setting.
24
When θ = 0, a market is characterized by {d, θ = 0, α} and region R is defined
accordingly. There is no upper bound on market size α but there remains a lower
bound α(d).25 Figure 4 below depicts region R.
Figure 4: Region R when θ = 0
The next proposition illustrates the complete characterization of the equilibrium
in the formation of airline alliances as a function of the degree of product differentiation and market size. The functional forms of the expressions α1 (d), α2 (d), α3 (d)
and α4 (d) are conveniently specified in Appendix 2. Subscript 0 identifies values
corresponding to the case of constant returns to traffic density.
Proposition 4 Suppose θ = 0. Then, for any market {d, θ = 0, α} ∈ R , the equilibrium in alliance formation is:
a
i) no alliance for d > d0 ;
a
ii) either no alliance or single alliance for d ∈ (da0 , d0 ]. No alliance will be the equilibrium for α ≥ α1 (d);
aa
iii) single alliance for d ∈ (d0 , da0 ];
aa
iv) either single alliance or double alliance for d ∈ (daa
0 , d0 ]. Single alliance for
α ∈ (max{α(d), α2 (d)}, α3 (d));
v) double alliance for d < daa
0 .
a
aa
Note that d0 ≡ 0.829, da0 ≡ 0.817, d0 ≡ 0.725, daa
0 ≡ 0.707.
25
This is because the upper bound for α comes from positivity of marginal costs. Since now
marginal costs are constant and positive, such a condition is not required. Following the notation
in Appendix 1, α(d) corresponds to B1 for d <
discontinuity and B1 = B3 = 1.
25
1
2
and to B3 for d >
1
2.
At d =
1
2
there is a
Proof. See Appendix 2.
As we did when there exist economies of traffic density, a detailed analysis of the
double alliance case allows us to classify them in the following corollary.
Corollary 2 Suppose θ = 0. Then, for any market {d, θ = 0, α} ∈ R , whenever
double alliance is the equilibrium in alliance formation, these alliances can be classified as follows:
i) double alliance involving a prisoner’s dilemma for d > 0.5;
ii) either double alliance involving a prisoner’s dilemma or double alliance profitable
per se for d ∈ (dpd
0 , 0.5]. In particular, double alliance involving a prisoner’s dilemma
will be the equilibrium for α ≥ α4 (d);
iii) double alliance profitable per se for d < dpd
0 ;
Note that dpd
0 ≡ 0.355.
Proof. See Appendix 2.
Figure 5 summarizes the above proposition and corollary representing the relevant regions for different values of the degree of product differentiation.
Figure 5: Equilibrium when θ = 0
In this particular case, one can observe that asymmetric equilibria (with just
one alliance) arise. Notice too the previously mentioned parsimonious nature of the
26
transition from the region where the equilibrium is no alliance to the one where
it is the double alliance.26 This result highlights the positive relationship between
product differentiation and strategic complementary integration in our setting. The
simplification θ = 0 results in a fairly easy comparison when analyzing Ψa (d, θ =
0, α) and Ψaa (d, θ = 0, α). It amounts to checking the gains or losses in the interline
market vis-à-vis those in the short market. As competition intensity gets stronger
it is more likely to find an equilibrium with just one alliance. Eventually, if the
degree of product differentiation is rather low and market size is rather large one
can find the no alliance equilibrium. Furthermore, and as happened in the presence
of economies of traffic density, carriers may get involved in a prisoner’s dilemma
situation unless the degree of product differentiation be sufficiently large.
5
Concluding Remarks
We have developed a formal model to illustrate how factors such as market size,
the degree of product differentiation and the intensity of economies of traffic density, may explain that (complementary) airline alliances do not always emerge in a
strategic environment. Specifically, alliances allow carriers to benefit from product
complementarities, which together with the presence of increasing returns to traffic
density would make one expect them to be privately profitable. Our findings indicate
that this is not necessarily so and it seems consistent with some of the observed facts
in the industry. This paper raises an interesting empirical question as it suggests
to study the significance of the above mentioned factors in assessing the incentives
of carriers to form strategic alliances. On the other hand, total travel volumes are
higher when either a single or a double alliance arises as long as there is a minimum
degree of economies of traffic density, regardless of market size and the degree of
product differentiation. In the current framework, such an increase in travel volumes would account for a greater consumer surplus. Competition authorities should
therefore favor complementary alliances since consumers would otherwise be worse
off. Furthermore, our model has identified parameter conditions under which al26
For positive values of θ, the relevant region R has a similar shape but it is bounded from above
because positivity of marginal costs requires lower values of α when θ increases. In addition, the
regions on the right side in Figure 5 reduce as θ takes higher values since increases in the intensity
of economies of traffic density favor alliance formation.
27
liances are privately profitable and, consequently, they would lead to higher welfare
levels.
In addition to the proliferation of airline alliances, there are many other features
that help to characterize the current and future status of the air transportation
landscape such as the surge of low cost carriers, the closing of old hubs and the
development of new ones, the expected evolution of regional operators to join networks and so on. Nevertheless, our results are realistic suggesting that the model
captures some important aspects of the airline industry. An interesting question
to be addressed is to endogenize network formation where the structure herein is a
possibility. Further work should explore whether the presence of a low cost carrier
in the network facilitates or hinders the profitability of strategic alliances.
References
[1] Barla, P. and C. Constantatos (2000), ”Airline Network Structure under
Demand Uncertainty”, Transportation Research Part E, 36, 173-180.
[2] Berechman, J., S. Poddar and O. Shy (1998), ”Network Structure and
Entry in the Deregulated Airline Industry”, Keio Economic Studies, 35, 71-82.
[3] Bilotkach, V. (2005), "Price Competition between International Airline Alliances", Journal of Transport Economics and Policy, 39, 167-190.
[4] Boyer, K.D. (1992), ”Mergers that Harm Competitors”, Review of Industrial
Organization, 7, 191-202.
[5] Brueckner, J.K. (2001), ”The Economics of International Codesharing: An
Analysis of Airline Alliances”, International Journal of Industrial Organization,
19, 1475-1498.
[6] Brueckner, J.K. (2003), ”International Airfares in the Age of Alliances: The
Effects of Codesharing and Antitrust Immunity”, The Review of Economics and
Statistics, 85, 105-118.
[7] Brueckner, J.K. (2004), "Network Structure and Airline Scheduling", Journal of Industrial Economics, 52(2), 291-312.
28
[8] Brueckner, J.K. and P.T. Spiller (1994), ”Economies of Traffic Density in
the Deregulated Airline Industry”, Journal of Law and Economics, 37, 379-415.
[9] Brueckner, J.K., N.J. Dyer and P.T. Spiller (1992), ”Fare Determination
in Airline Hub-and Spoke Networks”, RAND Journal of Economics, 23, 309333.
[10] Brueckner, J.K. and P.T. Spiller (1991), ”Competition and Mergers in
Airline Networks”, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 9, 323-342.
[11] Brueckner, J.K. and W.T. Whalen (2000), ”The Price Effects of International Airline Alliances”, Journal of Law and Economics, 53, 503-545.
[12] Cournot, A. (1927), ”Researches into the Mathematical Principles of the
Theory of Wealth”, original published in French (1838), translated by Nathaniel
Bacon, New York: Macmillan.
[13] Creel, M. and M. Farell (2001), ”Economies of Scale in the US Airline
Industry after Deregulation: a Fourier Series Approximation”, Transportation
Research Part E, 37, 321-336.
[14] Dixit, A. (1979), ”A Model of Duopoly Suggesting a Theory of Entry Barriers”, Bell Journal of Economics, 10, 22-32.
[15] Economides, N. and S. Salop (1992), ”Competition and Integration among
Complements, and Network Market Structure”, Journal of Industrial Economics, XL, 105-123.
[16] Fridolfsson, S-O. and J. Stennek (2005), ”Why Mergers Reduce Profits
and Raise Share Prices - A Theory of Preemptive Mergers”, Journal of the
European Economic Association, 3(5), 1083-1104.
[17] Hassin, O. and O. Shy (2004), ”Code-sharing Agreements and Interconnections in Markets for International Flights”, Review of International Economics,
12, 337-352.
[18] Hendricks, K., M. Piccione and G. Tan (1999), ”Equilibria in Networks”,
Econometrica 67 (6), 1407-1434.
[19] IATA (2001), ”Air transport markets in Europe and the US, a comparison”.
29
[20] Morrison, S.A. and C. Winston (1995), ”The Evolution of the Airline
Industry”, Brookings Institution, Washington, DC.
[21] Oum, T.H., A. Zhang and Y. Zhang (1995), ”Airline Network Rivalry”,
Canadian Journal of Economics, 28, 836-85.
[22] Oum, C., J.H. Park and A. Zhang (1996), The Effects of Airline Codesharing Agreements on Firm Conduct and International Air Fare”, Journal of
Transport Economics and Policy, 30, 187-202.
[23] Park, J.H. (1997), ”The Effects of Airline Alliances on Markets and Economic
Welfare”, Transportation Research Part E, 33, 181-195.
[24] Park, J.H. and A. Zhang (1998), ”Airline Alliances and Partner Firms’
Outputs”, Transportation Research Part E, 34, 245-255.
[25] Singh, N. and X. Vives (1984), ”Price and Quantity Competition in a
Differentiated Duopoly”, RAND Journal of Economics, 15, 546-554
30
Appendix 1:
Definition of the relevant region R.
A number of restrictions on the parameters d, θ and α have to be observed to
ensure positive prices, quantities, marginal costs, margins and the compliance with
non-arbitrage conditions are guaranteed in the three scenarios under consideration.
Markets defined by a triple {d, θ, α} ∈ R guarantee comparable results.
• Bounds on α. Positivity and non-arbitrage conditions in the three considered
scenarios lead to several bounds in α. After comparing all these bounds and selecting the most stringent ones, we obtain α ∈ (α(d, θ), α(d, θ)) with α(d, θ) =
4(4−6θ+d(2θ−3+d(5θ−2)))
,
d(2θ−3)(7θ−2)+2(2+θ−6θ2 )+2d2 (2+θ(10θ−9))
4d(3θ−2+d(2θ−1))
.27
4d(2+d)−10+27θ−4d(7+5d)θ+6θ2 (4d(1+d)−3)
min(B1, B2) and α(d, θ) = max(B1, B3, 1) where B1 ≡
B2 ≡
4θ((d−1)d−3)−2(d2 −5)
θ(10−12θ+(d−4)d(2θ−1))
and B3 ≡
Specifically, B1 comes from ensuring positive equilibrium travel volume in the
interline trip for outsiders in the single alliance situation; B2 from positive
marginal cost for partners in the single alliance situation; B3 from the fulfillment of a non-arbitrage condition for partners in the single alliance situation.
Notice that B1 can be either a lower or an upper bound.
• An illustrative representation can be displayed in space (θ, d) - see Figure 6.
To this end, we can compute the bounds on θ that come from the difference
between α(d, θ) and α(d, θ), i.e., the bounds ensuring the existence of a positive
α such that we can find markets {d, θ, α} ∈ R. We obtain θ ∈ (0, θ(d)) with
1
L1 for d < 2
θ(d) =
L3 for d ∈ ( 12 , 0.618]
L2 for d > 0.618
where L1 ≡
2+3d+2d2
,
2(2+3d+d2 )
L2 ≡
2d(2+d)−5
2(d−3+2d2 )
and L3 ≡
4+d
.
6+4d
The case d =
1
2
is a par-
ticular case: there is a discontinuity and α is bounded below by B1 = B3 = 1
27
There are 20 bounds on α to take into account. Let us denote them by B(·), putting in the
argument the equilibrium condition that gives rise to the bound. The precise expressions can be
derived from the equilibrium values provided in the main text. Pre-alliance: B(q na > 0), B(Qna >
0) B(1 − θ(q na +Qna ) > 0), and B(pna − 1 + θ(q
na
+Qna )
2
> 0); Single alliance: B(qpa > 0), B(qoa > 0),
θ(qoa +Qa
o)
2
B(Ppa −pap
B(Qap > 0), B(Qao > 0), B(1 − θ(qoa +Qao ) > 0), B(1 − θ(qpa +Qap ) > 0), B(pao − 1 +
B(Ppa −2+θ(qpa +Qap ) >
aa
Double alliance: B(q
observe that
B(pap
0),
B(pap
> 0),
B(pao > 0),
aa
aa
B(Ppa
> 0),
B(2pap −Ppa
aa
> 0) B(1 − θ(q +Q ) > 0), and B(P
−1+
θ(qpa +Qa
p)
2
aa
> 0) and B(p
−1+
> 0) and
aa
aa
> 0),
> 0);
− 2 + θ(q +Q ) > 0). One can
θ(q aa +Qaa )
2
> 0) simply reduce to α > 1.
After comparing all these bounds and selecting the most stringent ones, we are left with B1, B2
and B3 where B1 ≡B(Qao > 0), B2 ≡B(1 − θ(qpa +Qap ) > 0) and finally B3 ≡B(2pap − Ppa > 0).
31
and above by B2 =
38−52θ
47θ−62θ2
> 1.
Figure 6 below represents L1, L2 and L3. We claim that, for any pair {d, θ} in
the region delimited by L1, L2 and L3, there exist values of α ∈ (α(d, θ), α(d, θ))
such that we can find markets {d, θ, α} ∈ R.
Figure 6: Bounds for d and θ in region R
More precisely,
• For d <
1
2
and θ < L1, there exist values of α ∈ (B1, B2) such that we can
find markets {d, θ, α} ∈ R.
• For d ∈ ( 12 , 0.618] and θ ∈ [L1, L3), there exist values of α ∈ (B3, B1) such
that we can find markets {d, θ, α} ∈ R.
• For d >
1
2
and θ < min(L1, L2), there exist values of α ∈ (B3, B2) such that
we can find markets {d, θ, α} ∈ R.
In addition, we know that θ <
2
3
from the second order conditions. This means
that economies of traffic density cannot be too high. This makes sense because
otherwise marginal costs would become negative.
32
Appendix 2:
Proofs.
Proof of Proposition 1.
The difference Ppa − 2pna yields an expression whose denominator is negative for
4(dθ−1)
.
4d+9θ+12dθ2 −6−14dθ−6θ2
1
in R. Thus, for d < 2 ,
∗
{d, θ, α} ∈ R. The numerator is positive for α > α∗ ≡
∗
now compare α with the corresponding lower bounds
We
the
difference B1− α∗ is positive and, for d > 12 , the difference B3− α is positive too.
Therefore, α > α∗ is always verified in R. It is straightforward to check that α > α∗
also implies Qap > Qna , pao < pna , Qao < Qna and qoa > qna .
As for the fares and travel volumes for the partners’ short markets, the difference
qpa
− qna yields an expression whose denominator is negative for {d, θ, α} ∈ R. The
sign of the numerator depends on whether market size α is greater or smaller than
φ1 (d,θ)
.
φ2 (d,θ)
−
The function φ1 (d, θ) is positive for θ ∈ (θ− (d), θ+ (d)), where θ+ (d) >
2
3
of θ above θ̃(d), which is a decreasing function in d, it is discontinuous at d =
1
2
θ (d) =
√
3−11d−d2 +4d3 + 9−6d−5d2 −6d3 +17d4
.
4d(2d2 −3)
it lies above
2
3
and
The function φ2 (d, θ) is positive for values
and
for d > 12 . When θ < θ̃(d) the numerator in qpa − qna is positive; when
θ > θ̃(d) the numerator in qpa − q na is positive for α <
φ1 (d,θ)
.
φ2 (d,θ)
We have the following
cases.
• Case d < 21 . For every {d, θ, α} ∈ R,
i) for θ < θ̃(d) the numerator in qpa − q na is positive and therefore qpa − q na < 0.
ii) for θ > θ̃(d),
numerator in qpa − q
qpa − q na > 0.
φ1 (d,θ)
φ2 (d,θ)
na
φ1 (d,θ)
the
φ2 (d,θ)
φ1 (d,θ)
, then
φ2 (d,θ)
is positive and greater than B1. If α <
is positive and hence qpa − q na < 0; if α >
• Case d = 21 . For every {d, θ, α} ∈ R, the lower bounds on α are B1 = B3 = 1
and the upper bound is B2 =
negative for every α <
38−52θ
47θ−62θ2
38−52θ
,
47θ−62θ2
> 1. Since the numerator in qpa − qna is
which is always the case, qpa − qna is positive.
• Case d > 21 . For every {d, θ, α} ∈ R,
i) for θ < θ− (d) the numerator in qpa −q na is negative and therefore qpa −q na > 0.
φ1 (d,θ)
φ2 (d,θ)
numerator in qpa
ii) for θ ∈ (θ− (d), θ+ (d)),
α>
φ1 (d,θ)
,
φ2 (d,θ)
the
is positive but smaller than 1. Therefore, for
− qna is negative and qpa − q na > 0.
33
The difference pap − pna follows exactly the opposite pattern.
Proof of Proposition 2.
The difference P aa − 2pao yields an expression whose denominator is negative for
{d, θ, α} ∈ R. The numerator is positive for α > α∗ , as previously defined, and it
follows straightforward that Qaa > Qao , P aa < Ppa , Qaa < Qap , paa > pap and qaa < qpa .
As for the fares and travel volumes for the partners’ short markets, the difference
q aa − qoa yields an expression whose denominator is negative for {d, θ, α} ∈ R. The
sign of the numerator depends on whether market size α is greater or smaller than
φ1 (d,θ)
.
φ2 (d,θ)
−
The function φ1 (d, θ) is positive for θ ∈ (θ− (d), θ+ (d)), where θ+ (d) >
and θ (d) =
√
6−23d+9d3 + 36−84d+49d2 −52d3 +82d4 +d6
.
4d(5d2 −6)
2
3
The function φ2 (d, θ) is positive for
values of θ above θ̃(d), which is a decreasing function in d, it is discontinuous at
d=
1
2
and it lies above
2
3
for d > 12 . When θ < θ̃(d) the numerator in q aa − qoa is
φ1 (d,θ)
.
φ2 (d,θ)
positive; when θ > θ̃(d) the numerator in q aa − qoa is positive for α <
We
have the following cases.
• Case d < 12 . For every {d, θ, α} ∈ R,
i) for θ < θ̃(d) the numerator in qaa − qoa is positive and therefore q aa − qoa < 0.
ii) for θ > θ̃(d),
φ1 (d,θ)
φ2 (d,θ)
φ1 (d,θ)
the
φ2 (d,θ)
aa
a
q −qo > 0.
is positive and greater than B1. If α <
numerator in qaa −qoa is positive and hence q aa −qoa < 0; if α >
φ1 (d,θ)
φ2 (d,θ)
then
• Case d = 12 . For every {d, θ, α} ∈ R, the lower bounds on α are B1 = B3 = 1
38−52θ
>
47θ−62θ2
38−52θ
, which
47θ−62θ2
and the upper bound is B2 =
is negative for every α <
positive.
1. Since the numerator in q aa − qoa
is always the case, then qaa − qoa is
• Case d > 21 . For every {d, θ, α} ∈ R,
i) for θ < θ− (d) the numerator in q aa −qoa is negative and therefore qaa −qoa > 0.
ii) for θ ∈ (θ− (d), θ+ (d)),
α>
φ1 (d,θ)
,
φ2 (d,θ)
φ1 (d,θ)
is
φ2 (d,θ)
aa
the numerator in q
positive but smaller than 1. Therefore, for
− qoa is negative and q aa − qoa > 0.
The difference paa − pao follows exactly the opposite pattern.
34
Proof of Lemma 1.
The denominator in Ψa (d, θ, α) =
πa
p
2
− πna is positive for any {d, θ, α} ∈ R. The
numerator can be written as α2 K1 (d, θ)+αK2 (d, θ)+K3 (d, θ) where K1 (d, θ) may be
either positive or negative. Solving K1 (d, θ) = 0 for θ yields several solutions, from
which only one is relevant in R. Denote this root by e
θ(d) which is increasing in d. For
any {d, θ, α} ∈ R, if θ > e
θ(d), the function K1 (d, θ) is positive and the numerator in
Ψa (d, θ, α) is a convex function in α. On the other hand, if θ < e
θ(d), the function
K1 (d, θ) is negative and the numerator in Ψa (d, θ, α) is a concave function in α.
Solving the numerator in Ψa (d, θ, α) for α results in α− (d, θ) and α+ (d, θ). Thus,
there are two constraints on α to be met to have a positive numerator in Ψa (d, θ, α):
α∈
/ (α− (d, θ), α+ (d, θ)) if K1 (d, θ) is positive; and α ∈ (α− (d, θ), α+ (d, θ)) if K1 (d, θ)
is negative.
• If K1 (d, θ) is positive (θ > e
θ(d)), the functions α− (d, θ) and α+ (d, θ) are either
non real or yield an interval outside region R. Hence if α ∈
/ (α− (d, θ), α+ (d, θ))
then the numerator in Ψa (d, θ, α) is positive and hence Ψa (d, θ, α) > 0.
One can check that d = 0.802 when e
θ(d) = 0. Consequently, since e
θ(d) is
increasing in d, d < 0.802 is sufficient to ensure Ψa (d, θ, α) > 0.
θ(d)), it is unclear whether α belongs to (α− (d, θ), α+ (d, θ)).
• If K1 (d, θ) is negative (θ < e
Nevertheless, one can check that Ψa (d, θ, α) is decreasing in α for d > 0.849.
Therefore, we study Ψa (d, θ, α = α = B3) for d > 0.849. Solving Ψa (d, θ, α) =
0, we obtain a function b
θ(d, α) that is increasing in d as can be seen in Figure
7 below (since there is an upper bound for θ in region R , θ(d) ≡ L2 following
the notation in Appendix 1, we include it in the figure):
35
Figure 7 Proof of Lemma 1
For θ > b
θ(d, α), Ψa (d, θ, α) > 0 and then Ψa (d, θ, α) > 0 for any α in R. Since
solving b
θ(d, α) = θ(d) yields θ = 0.08, it is sufficient to require θ > 0.08 to guarantee
Ψa (d, θ, α) > 0 for any {d, θ, α} ∈ R.
The value d = 0.856 is obtained by a numerical method when Ψa (d, θ, α = α =
B2) since for d > 0.849 the function Ψa (d, θ, α) is decreasing in α. Hence, for
d > 0.856, Ψa (d, θ, α = α) < 0 and then Ψa (d, θ, α) < 0 for any {d, θ, α} ∈ R.
Proof of Lemma 2.
The first part of the proof is similar to Lemma 1. As for the sufficient conditions,
for any {d, θ, α} ∈ R, one can check that Ψaa (d, θ, α) =
π aa
2
− π ao is increasing in
α for low values of d in the interval d ∈ (0.707, 0.870] and decreasing in α for high
values of d in this interval. Solving Ψaa (d, θ, α = α) = 0 and Ψaa (d, θ, α = α) = 0
θ(d, α) that are increasing in d as can be seen in
yields two functions, b
θ(d, α) and b
Figure 8 below.
36
Figure 8̇: Proof of Lemma 2
Therefore for low values of d in the interval, θ > b
θ(d, α) implies Ψaa (d, θ, α =
α) > 0 and hence Ψaa (d, θ, α) > 0 for any α in R. Solving b
θ(d, α) = 0 we obtain the
value d = 0.707. Hence, for d < 0.707, θ > b
θ(d, α), we have that Ψaa (d, θ, α = α) > 0
and then Ψaa (d, θ, α) > 0.
θ(d, α) = θ(d) at d = 0.828 and θ = 0.195
In happens to be case that b
θ(d, α) = b
and Ψaa (d, θ, α) = 0 for any α in R. Therefore, for θ > 0.195, both b
θ(d, α)
θ(d, α) and b
are positive, then both Ψaa (d, θ, α = α) and Ψaa (d, θ, α = α) are also positive, and
hence Ψaa (d, θ, α) > 0. Similarly, for d > 0.828 both b
θ(d, α) and b
θ(d, α) are negative,
then both Ψaa (d, θ, α) and Ψaa (d, θ, α) are also negative, and hence Ψaa (d, θ, α) < 0.
Proof of Corollary 1.
One can check that Ψpd (d, θ, α) is decreasing in α for any {d, θ, α} ∈ R. Therefore
θ(d, α)
we study Ψpd (d, θ, α = α). Solving Ψpd (d, θ, α) = 0, we obtain a function e
that is decreasing in d as can be seen in the figure below.
37
Figure 9: Proof of Corollary 1
For θ < e
θ(d, α), Ψpd (d, θ, α) < 0 and then Ψpd (d, θ, α) < 0 for any α in R. Since
solving e
θ(d, α) = 0 yields d = 0.355, it is sufficient to require d < 0.355 to guarantee
Ψpd (d, θ, α) < 0 for any {d, θ, α} ∈ R.
Proof of Proposition 4 and Corollary 2.
For any market {d, θ = 0, α} ∈ R, α > α(d) and d ∈ (0, 1), where α(d) = B1 for
d<
1
2
and α(d) = B3 for d > 21 .
1. We first analyze Ψa (d, θ = 0, α) =
πa
p
2
− π na and observe that:
(a) For d ∈ (0, 0.8017], Ψa (d, θ = 0, α) > 0.
(b) For d ∈ (0.8017, 0.829], the sign of Ψa (d, θ = 0, α) depends on the value
of α in the following way: Ψa (d, θ = 0, α) > 0 for α < α1 (d), and
Ψa (d, θ = 0, α) < 0 for α > α1 (d),
√ √
100− 10 ((1−2d)2 (5−2d)2 (d2 −5)2 (8d2 −5))+2d(2d−5)(40d−10−5d3 +2d4 )
where α1 (d) =
.
275+2d(d(20+d(120+d(−15+4(−5+d)d)))−250)
1. (a) For d ∈ (0.829, 870], Ψa (d, θ = 0, α) < 0.
2. The analysis of Ψaa (d, θ = 0, α) =
π aa
2
− π ao yields that,
(a) For d ∈ (0, 0.707], Ψaa (d, θ = 0, α) > 0.
(b) For d ∈ (0.707, 0.7105], the sign of Ψaa (d, θ = 0, α) depends on the value
of α in the following way: Ψaa (d, θ = 0, α) > 0 for α ∈
/ (α2 (d), α3 (d)),
and Ψaa (d, θ = 0, α) < 0 for α ∈ (α2 (d), α3 (d)), where
38
√ √
8+8d−39d2 +20d3 +2d4 −4d5 +d6 − 2 (500d−100−585d2 −700d3 +1796d4 −780d5 −445d6 +380d7 −18d8 −40d9 +8d10 )
α2 (d) =
22−36d−11d2 +32d3 −6d4 −4d5 +d6
√ √
8+8d−39d2 +20d3 +2d4 −4d5 +d6 + 2 (500d−100−585d2 −700d3 +1796d4 −780d5 −445d6 +380d7 −18d8 −40d9 +8d1
and α3 (d) =
22−36d−11d2 +32d3 −6d4 −4d5 +d6
1. (a) For d ∈ (0.7105, 0.7249], the sign of Ψaa (d, θ = 0, α) depends on the
value of α in the following way: Ψaa (d, θ = 0, α) > 0 for α > α3 (d), and
Ψaa (d, θ = 0, α) < 0 for α < α3 (d). For these values of d, we do not need
to consider α2 (d) since α(d) > α2 (d) and α is always higher than α(d) in
R.
(b) For d ∈ (0.7249, 0.870], Ψaa (d, θ = 0, α) < 0.
2. Next we study the sign of Ψpd (d, θ = 0, α) = π na −
πaa
.
2
(a) For d ∈ (0, 0.355], Ψpd (d, θ = 0, α) < 0.
(b) For d ∈ (0.355, 0.5], the sign of Ψpd (d, θ = 0, α) depends on the value
of α in the following way: Ψpd (d, θ = 0, α) > 0 for α > α4 (d), and
Ψpd (d, θ = 0, α) < 0 for α < α4 (d),
where α4 (d) =
√ √
8−40d+41d2 −20d3 +4d4 + 2 980d−100−3561d2 +6204d3 −5592d4 +2688d5 −656d6 +64d7
.
22−92d+97d2 −36d3 +4d2
1. (a) For d ∈ (0.5, 0.725], Ψpd (d, θ = 0, α) > 0.
The combination of the above analysis characterizes the Nash equilibrium (NE)
in alliance formation:
1. (a) For d ∈ (0.829, 0.870], the NE is no alliance because Ψa (d, θ, α) < 0.
(b) For d ∈ (0.817, 0.829], with α < α1 (d), the NE is single alliance because
Ψa (d, θ = 0, α) > 0 and Ψaa (d, θ = 0, α) < 0; and with α > α1 (d), the
NE is no alliance because Ψa (d, θ = 0, α) < 0.
(c) For d ∈ (0.7249, 0.817], the NE is single alliance because Ψa (d, θ =
0, α) > 0 and Ψaa (d, θ = 0, α) < 0.
(d) For d ∈ (0.7105, 0.7249], with α > α3 (d), the NE is double alliance because Ψa (d, θ = 0, α) > 0 and Ψaa (d, θ = 0, α) > 0; and with α < α3 (d),
the NE is single alliance because Ψa (d, θ = 0, α) > 0 and Ψaa (d, θ =
0, α) < 0.
39
(e) For d ∈ (0.707, 0.7105], with α ∈
/ (α2 (d), α3 (d)), the NE is double alliance
involving a prisoner’s dilemma because Ψa (d, θ = 0, α) > 0, Ψaa (d, θ =
0, α) > 0 and Ψpd (d, θ = 0, α) > 0; and with α ∈ (α2 (d), α3 (d)), the NE
is single alliance because Ψa (d, θ = 0, α) > 0 and Ψaa (d, θ = 0, α) < 0.
(f) For d ∈ (0.5, 0.707], the NE is double alliance involving a prisoner’s
dilemma because Ψa (d, θ = 0, α) > 0, Ψaa (d, θ = 0, α) > 0 and Ψpd (d, θ =
0, α) > 0.
(g) For d ∈ (0.355, 0.5], with α < α4 (d) the NE is double alliance profitable
per se because Ψa (d, θ = 0, α) > 0, Ψaa (d, θ = 0, α) > 0 and Ψpd (d, θ =
0, α) < 0; and with α > α4 (d) the NE is double alliance involving a
prisoner’s dilemma because Ψa (d, θ = 0, α) > 0, Ψaa (d, θ = 0, α) > 0 and
Ψpd (d, θ = 0, α) > 0.
(h) For d ∈ (0, 0.355] the NE is double alliance profitable per se because
Ψa (d, θ = 0, α) > 0, Ψaa (d, θ = 0, α) > 0 and Ψpd (d, θ = 0, α) < 0.
40