styczeń–luty–marzec
Nr 42
(1/2018)
Contents
Articles
Andrzej Marian Świątkowski Distinctive concept of empirical research
orientations and methods in labour law | 9
Andrzej Szymański When lawlessness became law. A few examples of
the discrimination of the people believing in the Polish People’s Republic | 39
Zbigniew Klimiuk Methods and forms of promoting Polish exports in
the interwar period. Direct actions aimed at expanding the country’s exports
(part II) | 61
Edyta Sokalska Polycentrism as the structural basis for American federalism in the reception of Vincent Ostrom | 85
Tomasz Rakoczy Legal and organization structures of Evangelical Churches in the area of means of social communication | 100
Grzegorz Wolak About the Notion of Entitled Party within Article 6
of the Act of 18 October 2006 on Liquidation of Unclaimed Deposits | 116
Anna Wolska-Bagińska
bankruptcy | 145
Economic and legal aspects of personal
Bartosz Bacia, Patryk Toporowski
tax law | 159
MLI: the new era in international
Małgorzata Chrostowska The risk of the loss of the stability of the
public finance system - health care system in correlation with the aging
society | 182
Michał Grudecki A few words about the rational offender in the light
of selected amendments of the Polish Penal Code from 2015-2017 | 198
Agata Baran Development of the legislation on labour migration in
Poland during the interwar period | 213
Tomasz Guzik The Evaluation of Extradiction from the perspective of
Economic Analysis of Law | 240
Katarzyna Siczek Strasbourg’s fair trial standards regarding proceedings
with examination of aggrieved minor by the example of applications against
Poland | 256
Adrian Romkowski Criminal infringements of the ustawa o ochronie
danych osobowych 1997 in the perspective of personal data protection standards of the General Data Protection Regulation 2016 | 268
Marlena Stradomska, Tomasz Słapczyński Forced treatment of
people who suffer from mental disorders and addicted person in legal-psychological perspective | 307
Bartłomiej Biga The Economic Analysis of Patent in Three Dimensions | 323
Gloss
Sławomir Zwolak Gloss to the judgment of the Supreme Administrative
Court of 6 July 2017 file ref. II OSK 2766/15 | 340
Artykuł ekonomiczny | 323
Bartłomiej Biga
The Economic Analysis of Patent
in Three Dimensions
Ekonomiczna analiza patentu w trzech wymiarach
Introduction
In the context of conducting an economic and social analysis of a patent as
a leading instrument of an invention protection, one should think about deliberations concerning constructive features of this legal institution as they have
got a fundamental meaning. The effectiveness of a patent is mostly determined
by its width, length and height. Each of these dimensions is a subject of analysis
in this paper. However, it will not be a separated analysis, because these features
are strongly intermingled and we can observe a strong trade-off between them.
Deliberations of this text are a part of the research, which purpose is to
answer the question: how strong should the legal protection of inventions be in
order to get the biggest net benefits for a society? To put it simply, it is allowed
to assume that – as a rule – social costs grow with the power of monopoly, which
is created by granting a patent. At the same time, it has to be remembered that
if potential innovators do not have a high enough level of economic incentives
guaranteed, which is to a large extent dependent on the strength of a patent,
then the supply of inventions will be smaller than it is expected by a society
and as a result a social deadweight loss would appear. Therefore, the aspect how
strong the legal protection of inventions should be is one of the key questions,
which arise in the context of the economic analysis of intellectual property law.
According to the assumptions of law and economics, it is desired to seek such
an invention protection system, which would be able to guarantee an appropriate speed of research. It would be achieved with the lowest possible level of
incentives for creators. Looking at his issue from another perspective, it could
324 | Przegląd Prawno-Ekonomiczny 42 (1/2018)
be observed that there is a need for choosing such a level of creators’ protection,
where marginal social costs and marginal social benefits are equalized1.
If the initial marginal cost is lower than the marginal benefit, then the
level of protection should be increased by a single unit, because this action generates more benefits than costs. This increase should be abandoned at the point,
where the cost of increasing the level of protection is higher than benefits caused
by such a change. The reverse mechanism should be used in the situation where
the initial marginal cost is higher. W. Załuski proposed a graphical illustration
of this deliberation for just one of the variables, which constitute the level of
protection – for the duration time. However, for other variables, like the scope
of protection, this graphic would be analogical2.
Figure 1. Illustration of marginal costs and benefits of intellectual property law
Source: Załuski, Schemat…,p. 110.
Moreover, the reason to establish and keep monopoly-based invention protection system can be noticed only in dynamic approach. Thus, in static research,
limiting the spread of innovation warrants strongly negative assessment from
1 W. Załuski, Schemat ekonomicznego ujęcia prawa własności intelektualnej, (in:) J. Stelmach (ed.), M. Soniewicka (ed.), Ekonomiczna analiza w zastosowaniach prawniczych, Warszawa
2008, p. 110; W. M Landes, R. Posner, 1989, An Economic Analysis of Copyright Law, “Journal of
Legal Studies” 1989, vol. 18, no. 2, pp. 341-343.
2 W. Załuski, Schemat…, pp. 110 and following.
Artykuł ekonomiczny | 325
a social point of view. However, the promise of exclusivity (monopoly) generated
by intellectual property is made to increase the level of incentives to innovation
activity. The societies accept this limitation, because they want to keep relatively
high level of invention supply in long term. Without such promise, as the result
of prisoner’s dilemma, potential inventions would prefer the “copy” over “create”
strategy. One of the methods clarifying the discussion about patents is a glance
at this issues from a reward / contribution perspective3.
Without deeper understanding of the structural features of a patent, it is
impossible to give an accurate answer to the question of how strong patent
protection of inventions should be. The resultant of three patent constructional
features will be the so called “strength of a patent”. It seems that to illustrate
this issue one should imagine the patent as a cuboid (figure 2). Then each of the
patent’s structural features would be seen as one of three cuboid’s dimensions –
width, length and height of a patent.
However, the strength of the patent is also determined by other – external –
factors. In this paper, this factors are only mentioned. They are not described in
detail, because the aim of this text is to explore relations between patent structural features, which which influence the strength of the patent much more. If we
demonstrate patent as a cuboid, we can assume as hypothesis, that a given patent
strength can be achieved as a result of many different combinations of those
three structural features. The key question in this paper is which combination
of patent structural features is the most effective to create the given (present)
strength of a patent. Thus, it is worth to manipulate the relation between structural features because in some cases, the rule that strength of a patent corresponds
directly to the amount of social costs does not work. Therefore, it is possible to
reduce social inconveniences while maintaining the same amount of economic
incentives for inventors.
3 C. Saphio, Patent Reform: Aligning Reward and Contribution, “Innovation Policy and the
Economy” 2007, Vol. 8, pp. 141-142.
326 | Przegląd Prawno-Ekonomiczny 42 (1/2018)
Figure 2., Patent structural features in three-dimension-model
Source: Author’s graph.
Such actions, which are one of the fundamental goals of law and economics,
lead us to increase the efficiency of the described tool. These actions are the
subject of research interest in this paper. Deliberations on how high the total
strength of a patent should be or a problem in an access for databases and their
quantification4 will be treated as a background of the research issue, which
was drawn above. The essence of this scientific description will be to answer
the question – which combination of width, height and length of a patent will
allow to maximize the efficiency of this institution as a tool for the protection
of inventions.
Width of a patent
Width, which means the scope of the patent, defines a level of similarity of
other inventions to the patented one whose violation means infringement of the
patent. Therefore, it is the size of an invention range beyond which the activity
4 B. Allered, W. G. Park, Patent Rights and Innovative Activity: Evidence from National and
Firm-Level Data, “Journal of Intellectual Business Studies”, Vol. 38, no. 6 (November 2007), pp.
878-900.
Artykuł ekonomiczny | 327
of competitors is legally allowed. In the literature The Rubic’s Cube is given as an
example. It has got six walls, each divided for criss-cross of 9 squares. According
to the decision of the US court this invention does not violate earlier Moleculon’s patent for a similar game where a cubic had walls divided into 4 squares5.
It is a relatively rare statement for a very narrow scope of a patent. Analysing
the case law one can rather finds arguments, which talk about a much broader
scope of interest.
Assuming even a moderately wide scope of the patent, a monopoly obtained
by a Moleculon would also include a variant with a wall spliced in a 3x3 way.
Therefore, this corporation would get the exclusive right for profits gained from
both variations of this game. Undoubtedly, wide patents are incentives for conducting fast research, because of far-reaching consequences of “the winner takes
it all” rule. On the other hand, this situation reflects on the economic efficiency
in a negative way, because it inevitably leads to the duplication of research. The
expenditure incurred by all participants in the race for a patent, except from
the winner, constitute a loss from the perspective of the inventor. In a social
perspective, it seems to be better to describe it as a cost. With a narrow scope
of a patent, creators are encouraged to conduct complementary research, which
in turn are proceeded significantly slower.
Klemperer6 mentioned that the width of a patent affects two categories of
social costs - those of consumers not purchasing any member of the product class
and those of consumers inefficiently substituting a less-preferred member of the
class. A wider patent reduces the distortion of consumers’ choices between the
patented brand of the product and unpatented, lower-priced varieties of the product sold by competitors. However, a wider patent also permits higher prices and
so increases (relative to profits) the deadweight losses from consumers switching
consumption out of the product class. Thus, if demand is relatively more elastic
in reservation price than in substitution cost, society should generally be more
concerned with non-consumption and hence should narrow the patent scope
to ensure low prices, while if the converse is true, society should generally be
more concerned with substitution within the product class and hence should
broaden patents’ scope. More generally, a narrow patent is desirable when it
causes relatively few consumers to substitute, that is, when demand is relatively
inelastic in substitution cost. When demand is relatively inelastic in reservation
5 Moleculon Research Corp. vs CBS Inc., 872 F2d 407, 409 (Fed. Cir. 1989).
6 P. Klemperer, How Broad Should the Scope of Patent Protection Be, “The Rand Journal of
Economics” 1990, vol. 1, no. 1, pp. 126-127.
328 | Przegląd Prawno-Ekonomiczny 42 (1/2018)
price, on the other hand, controlling price is relatively less important, and so
broader patents are optimal7.
The aspect of width of a patent is often analysed in a context of a horizontal
spread of a product. In this approach technological innovations are seen as
processes, which generate additional opportunities for consuming goods. As
a result of different tastes of consumers – each variant of consumption has got
its own demand and does not absorb the whole market. A wide patent covers
a large part of the horizontal spread of a product, but it would be difficult to
imagine that it could get it all8.
Mazzoleni and Nelson9 warn against a common wisdom, which is widespread
among economists, lawyers and officials that strong and wide patents lead to economic growth. They mentioned that keeping a wide patent by a single company
causes other companies to try to act beside this monopoly. These are imitations,
which do not enhance economic efficiency – the more, the wider patent is. Then
a further shift away from the optimal shape of the invention is required.
Length of a patent
On this basis of this, it is possible to put the next variable into deliberations
– time. In this approach, a shorter duration reduces the amount of inventor’s
revenue, but it also increases social welfare, because it is limited by monopoly
powers for a shorter time. The above-discussed width of a patent has got direct
gear on a price, which could be demanded by a patent’s owner. In this approach,
the sum of benefits obtained from the invention is a ratio of time and price.
This model differs significantly from the proposal of Klemperer, which was
described before, because it notices the possibility of wider regulation of prices,
as a substitute of a model, where making a wider patent means that consumers’
tendency to buy the product is automatically reduced and it increases a social
deadweight loss10 .
7 T. Van Dijk, The Limit of Patent Protection, “Essays on the Economics of Intellectual
Property Rights”, Maastricht 1994, p. 34.
8 B. Verspagen, Intellectual Property Rights in the World Economy, essay from WIPO Arab
Regional Sumposium on the Economic Importance of Intellectual Property Rights, Muscat, Oman
1999, pp. 8-9.
9 R. Mazzoleni, R. Nelson, The Benefits and Costs of Strong Patent Protection: a Contribution
to the Current Debate, “Research Policy” 1998, no. 27, pp. 273, 275.
10 P. Klemperer, How broad…., pp. 126-127.
Artykuł ekonomiczny | 329
Length as a constructional feature of a patent is the time for which it is
granted. In this moment it is necessary to emphasise that the method of economic analysis, which refers to comparison the balance states in the context of
a constant technology – a static balance analysis – is not suitable for the intellectual property law. The immanent aspect of this branch of law is innovation
and changing of technology11.
The longer the duration of patents is, the more benefits related to acceleration
in innovation activities society gets but the growth rate of these benefits probably decreases. Therefore, the marginal benefit from the increase of innovation
decreases with the extension of the duration time of a patent. When the duration
of a patent is exceeded, society bears higher costs due to a reduced distribution.
In response to long-term patents society seeks substitutes of patented goods.
And the longer it seeks, the more it finds. Therefore, as in the case of benefits,
the growth rate of social costs of a patent, probably decreases with the extension
of a patent length12.
Due to the enormous diversity in inventions which could be patented, it
is worth to consider the possibility of diversification of protection length in
relation to specific industries. However, final conclusions in this area could be
made only after a detailed analysis of at least two significantly different markets,
such as the pharmaceutical and the IT market. The choice of these two areas
is justified by the fact that the evaluation of patent in these two industries is
extremely different. This issue will be explained below. It gives a chance to show
how difficult it is to make a general assessment of a patent. Additionally, it is an
opportunity to reveal the strongest points and the most serious weaknesses of
the described institution.
People who are interested in keeping the patent protection system often
cite the pharmaceutical industry. Ethical dilemmas are clearly visible in this
area. Additionally, it is particularly vulnerable to easy unauthorized copying
of inventions, which in combination with the extremely high cost of manufacturing justifies the introduction of a special protective regime. On the contrary,
the possibility of granting software patents is highly controversial. Software is
protected in copyrights way. And it seems that this kind of protection – modelled on literacy protection, is more appropriate and sufficient. It provides an
automatic protection of a code, which is a result of intellectual programmer
activity. Granting a software patent gives a much wider protection, because in
11 R. Cooter, T. Ulen, Ekonomiczna analiza prawa, Warszawa 2009, p. 150.
12 R. Cooter, T. Ulen, Ekonomiczna…, p. 155-156.
330 | Przegląd Prawno-Ekonomiczny 42 (1/2018)
this case a creation of a new implementation does not violate copyrights but it
can be a violation of law.
In other words, software patents create patent thickets, which make entering
a very difficult. Software patents are the source of large danger especially for
independent innovators who do not have enough resources to do research in
patent databases. If they gain a certain effect with a different code then it is not
a plagiarism but it could be treated as a violation of patent. Therefore this phenomenon significantly reduces the overall level of innovation13. It is particularly
dangerous because it happens in the industry, which gives a unique possibility
for the independent creators – talented developers – to appear even without
a financial backing.
Coming back to the considerations of constructional features, it is worth
mentioning that one of first researches on economic efficiency of duration of
patent protection was conducted by Nordhaus14. However, this research proved to
be seriously flawed. His model was based on an assumption of a lack of pressure
from other innovators. Yet it is hard to undermine that even if the extension
of patent duration initially stimulates innovations in the next stage, when the
innovation is patented, the welfare decreases as a result of a too long monopoly.
The social deadweight loss of lack of competition increases with time. However,
the competitiveness could lower the optimal length of patent significantly. Dore15
took it into account, and noted that according to W. Nordhaus assumptions it
is hard to find a reason to justify economic utility of a patent for more than two
or three years.
Research from the 1980s showed that the critical limit for the optimal patent
life is 8 years, with 50% efficiency of a patent in thirteenth year of protection.
Moreover, 70% of patented inventions where imitated in the first year, and 60%
in next four years. The result of this data is that, even if the legislator provides
a very long time of patent protection, it could still play its role properly only in
the first few years. Inventors also recognize the declining efficiency of a patent
and therefore many of them resign from the payment of patent fees during the
next years. It is illustrated in the following chart. The pace of decline is different
in each patent office, but everywhere it is clearly visible. Hence, the maximum
13 J. Bessen, A Generation of Software Patents, Boston University of Law Working Paper no
11-31 (21 July 2011), p. 9.
14 W. Nordhaus, Invention, Growth and Welfare : A Theoretical Treatment of Technological
Change, MIT Press. 1969.
15 M. H. I.Dore, J. Kushner, L. Masse, The Optimal Length of a Patent with Variable Output
Elasticity and Returns to Scale in R&D, “Atlantic Economic Journal” 1993, vol. 21, no 1.
Artykuł ekonomiczny | 331
legal period of patent duration is significantly longer than its real lifetime. This
discrepancy is beneficial mostly for patent trolls, because real inventors resign
from patent protection earlier. This circumstance creates the possibility to make
patent shorter
Figure 3. Percentage of patents maintaned in following years of patental protection
Source: IP5 Statistics Report (2011).
In this context, the proposal of Klemperer16 seems to be very controversial.
He suggested, that in many cases a narrow timeless patent would be the most
effective. Additionally, he hints that this model could be used in situations when
narrow patent causes that only a small part of consumers would choose the substitutes. It corresponds with the results obtained by Nordhaus17 , who mentioned
that optimal patent length depends on flexibility of a demand and flexibility in
the range of a technical advancement in relations with expenditures on R+D.
Therefore, with higher flexibility of demand for a new product, the optimal patent
length is shorter, because of the fact that a high level of monopoly implicates
significant deadweight loss. Additionally, in the situation when research is cheap,
the optimal duration of patent protection is shorter too, because then it is not
necessary to provide especially big incentives to maintain research.
16 P. Klemperer, How broad…., p. 127.
17 B. Verspagen, Intellectual…, p. 8.
332 | Przegląd Prawno-Ekonomiczny 42 (1/2018)
The main argument of the followers of narrow but timeless patents is the
assumption that generally extending the patent generates additional costs by
the means of extending deadweight loss related to the power of a patent holder
in a certain market. In their opinion, in the case of extending the duration of
protection the growth of inventor’s benefits is higher than the growth of social
costs. Therefore, they suggest that granting timeless patents with the minimal
width is economically more effective because they could provide sufficient level
of market power to guarantee the prize for an inventor on the demanded scale18.
Additionally, the concept of timeless patent is supported in such philosophical
ideas, which accent the fact that the right for innovation is an immanent right
with its roots in a natural law. This aspect will not be described in this paper
because it does not belong to Law and Economics.
A serious threat in making a patent a timeless institution is noticed even by
the supporters of this concept19. It is related to the unpredictability of the economic reality even in a mid-term. Therefore, making petrification of a certain
branch for a longer perspective is too risky. In this place it is impossible to avoid
the question, how communication market would look today if the first inventors had been given an infinite monopoly. The growing dynamic of changes in
the social and economic reality inclines to opt for a short patent. It is worth to
consider situation when a longer patent protection would be possible but with
a dynamic increase of patent fees for each year after 20-year period. However, it
seems not to be a good solution for the most significant inventions. What needs
to be emphasised is that most inventors abandon patent protection much earlier
(Figure 3). But the owners of the most valuable patents would be still interested
in keeping their patents even if the fee is being doubled each year. Therefore,
some certain markets could be monopolized for a very long period time.
A bit different understanding of a relation between patent length and width
was proposed by Gallini20 . She defined it as a determinant of entrance to market protected by a patent. The scope of a patent is a cost, which must be taken
by potential competitors to let them make imitation without violation of law.
The income of inventors does not increase through the whole patent duration,
because when the patent length exceeds the threshold of imitation, then some
imitators would appear. Consequently they could change the monopoly pricelist
18 R. Gilbert, Shapiro, Optimal Patent Length and Breadth, “Rand Journal of Economics”
2012, vol. 21, p. 107.
19 R. Gilbert, Shapiro, Optimal…, p. 108.
20 N. Gallini, Patent Policy and Costly Imitation, “Rand Journal of Economics” 1992, Vol.
23, No. 1, p. 60.
Artykuł ekonomiczny | 333
into the oligopoly pricelist. Thus a too long patent protection encourages to
spendthrift imitations instead of creating real innovations expected by a society. Therefore, according to Gallini’s model, a patent should be long enough to
generate the expected income for a patent owner and wide enough to prevent
a harmful imitation.
The alternative of creating a patent policy based purely on a combination of
width and time was revealed by Maurer and Scotchmer21. They proposed a wide
implementation of licensing. It could dismiss the threat of such an imitator’s
activity, which would decrease the price resulting from monopoly. To make it
happen, two conditions must be fulfilled – the cost of R+D of potentially entering
entities must be at the same level as R+D cost of the first innovator and the license
must keep such a high level of market price that it would be high enough to cover
the costs of a patent owner. Then the width of a patent would give a possibility
to regulate the price of a certain product, and licenses would prevent imitations.
Patent height
Beside a problem of patent infringement through its imitation, which was described while analysing a patent width, there is the second type of infringement,
which is about improving a patented invention – especially in the context of low
expenditures in relation to utility increase. The scope of legality of such actions
is described as height of a patent. The higher it is, the further the improvements
are located in granted patent for a primary invention.
Patent height is positively correlated with an incentive for conducting basic
research. Thus, it could be used as a tool of intervention in a situation, when from
the social perspective the number and the scope of basic research is not sufficient
in relation to the number and the scope of work connected with improvements22.
If social value of investments in basic research is higher than social value of
investments in application development, then a patent should be higher. On
the other hand, if social value of investments in application developing is higher
than a social value of investments in basic research, then a patent height should
be lower23.
21 S.M. Maurer, S. Scotchmer, The independent invention defence in intellectual property,
“Economica” 2002, 69(276), p. 535-547.
22 T. Van Dijk, The Limit…, p. 67.
23 R. Cooter, T. Ulen, Ekonomiczna…, p. 153.
334 | Przegląd Prawno-Ekonomiczny 42 (1/2018)
Granting a high patent brings the risk that an inventor, who also gets
a monopoly for further improvements, applications and next level inventions,
would act inefficiently, because if the market mechanisms work properly, they
prevent from waste. Additionally, the social cost of such solution is higher,
because it blocks a possibility to work for many other innovators, who would
improve and develop a certain base more efficiency. Moreover, the bargaining
position of other inventors in relation to a person who has a strong patent, is
too weak To negotiate a fair contract24.
Without doubt the technical progress is continuous, in which artificially
highlighting of phases could be hard to explain. It happens, when a patent is
granted for a solution, which is in fact just a part of this process - often with
arbitrarily drawn boundaries. This assumption puts the lower boundary in search
of the optimal patent height on the relatively high level. In consequence of fuzzy
patent boundaries it is rational to extract as few phases as possible, because the
fewer boundaries have to be drawn, the smaller is the area of unpredictability.
On the other, hand if the number of phases is too small, a certain branch is
monopolized for too long.
A width of a patent could be described as a model of horizontal distinction.
A height of a patent is in this context a model of vertical distinction. It is shaped
mostly through the novelty requirement, which is executed when a patent is
granted. Van Dijk25 noticed that a social goal of setting an incentive for innovation
is best realized with the restrictive understanding of this requirement. However,
if early disclosure is a goal, then novelty requirement should be weaker.
This play a significant role in for the attempt to describe an optimal shape of
a patent, because it could greatly play a role of limiting the number of granting
patents. It seems to be very useful to improve the global economy efficiency of
legal invention protection. It is a phenomenal criterion, which could be objectively used. Furthermore, its restriction is not contradictory to the immanent
patent features. Thus a patent should be granted only if the invention is a real,
remarkable step in development of a certain science or a technical branch.
Thinking about the usage of a novelty criterion in setting a patent’s constructional features. It must be mentioned that in many legal systems there is
a requirement that an invention has to be non-obvious and posses an adequate
innovation level. These criteria are not sharp, and therefore their utility is relatively low. In fact, a subjective scope of a patent is set according to the doctrine
24 R. Mazzoleni, R. Nelson, The Benefits…, p. 280.
25 T. Van Dijk, The Limit…, p. 40.
Artykuł ekonomiczny | 335
of equivalents. It refers to many court sentences, which explain, how close the
equivalent between two inventions must be in order to conclude that a patent
infringement has appeared. However, this doctrine is vague and unpredictable.
What can be noticed is that courts have sometimes indicated that improvement
of enormous commercial value should not be treated as violating a pioneer
invention of low individually value26. Yet consumers assign a real value for
improvement not for a basic invention. The consequences of using this interpretation could lead us to a shortage of basic research, and therefore it would
be negatively assessed in law and economics27.
The solution of this dilemma could provide a wider protection for the firstlevel inventions in the circumstances, when they have got low individual value,
and as a result they could not generate sufficient income for their creator in the
first stage of spreading. In the case of inventions of higher autonomous value,
it is possible to think about narrower protection, because additional income
for initial inventor does not have to be so high28. This approach is typical for
law and economics, which sets the requirement of economy efficiency. It could
be achieved only in the balance proximity between numbers of first- and second-level research.
It is interesting that solving this problem in an economic way is closer – in
the context of justice – to the righteousness category than the above-mentioned
doctrine of equivalents. It does not include the need to compensate expenditures
for basic invention. It is a clear example that law and economics used without
ignoring an ethical context do not lead to a moral monstrosity. Moreover, it could
be a basis to argue for more justice solutions.
What is of crucial importance while comparing the difference between the
width and the height of a patent is the cost benefits analysis. Thinking about the
protection against improvements means taking the height into consideration. On
the other hand, the width determines the level of protection against imitations.
In fact only improvement generates new information - a new value instead of
focusing on only copying created solution in a non-infringement way29.
The fundamental difference is seen when customers’ behaviour will be analysed. In the case of imitation, only a part of potential buyers would resign from
buying a patented product. The number depends on both price flexibility of
demand in a certain group and on substitution cost. In a situation of choosing
26
27
28
29
Westingohouse vs Boyden Power Brake Co., 170 US 537, 572 (1898).
R. Cooter, T. Ulen, Ekonomiczna…, p. 153.
R. Cooter, T. Ulen, Ekonomiczna…, p. 154.
T. Van Dijk, The Limit…, p. 50.
336 | Przegląd Prawno-Ekonomiczny 42 (1/2018)
between an invention and its improved version, the only factor, which could
dissuade a consumer from buying a better version, is a much higher price, that
vividly conveys the potential buyer. This distinction clearly shows what kind of
economic consequences happen for a patent owner in the context of imitation
and improvement made by another player on a market. Undoubtedly, improvements bear the higher threats for gaining profits from a patent. They can evoke
a stronger price pressure.
Conclusion and recommendations
The main target of the presented conclusions and recommendations is to indicate the direction of changes, which would minimalize social welfare. It has to
be analysed taking into account a complicated political context – both national
and international. It makes building deep reforms very difficult. As a result,
the recommended changes are as close to status quo, as it possible or they rely
on such mechanisms, which are close to the existing ones. It is not a goal at
this text to present a revolutionary patent protection system, which would be
deprived of opportunities of even a partial realization. Additionally, the social
reality changes so fast that implementing deeper reforms – which require much
time – is very difficult because of a big delay between the decision stage, and
the factual implementation.
Referring these deliberations to the current social and economics context,
it is possible to express that it would be socially beneficial to form a patent as
a short-duration and relatively wide institution. A fewer number of years for
which a patent is granted, could reflect a permanent acceleration of technical
development, which makes effective patent life shorter and shorter. Therefore,
it would not be a significant change from the inventors’ perspective. It would
rather be an adoption to reality, and it would let us avoid disputes about alleged
violations of over ten years in fact dead patents.
Furthermore, it could make easier to make extension of a vertical range of
this institution and it would be even more effective to discourage for imitation.
If a width of protection is big enough, then the phenomenon of action around
the patent by a competitor would be economically feasible, which would reduce
a social loss as well. In a link with shorter time of bearing costs for society, it
would significantly reduce a sum of costs. However, a patent would be wider to
provide similar incentives for innovators activity. It generates increased social
costs – in the former the first years of patent, which in this proposal would be
Artykuł ekonomiczny | 337
the only years of patent protection – do not consume a whole generated and
above described savings.
Moreover, if a patent is short, the problem of a patent height would disappear
to a large extend. Because, if time for making improvements from the monopolist
position is short, then blocking competitors in this area brings much lower social
costs. Therefore, with a care of balance of an incentive system for the creators,
with far-reaching shortening of the patent, it would be possible to design it as
a very high institution.
Naturally, it is hard to indicate how many years a patent should be shortened.
In this context it would be a very desirable would be to carry out the analysis
about a diversification of a period for which a patent is granted in certain branches. Selecting criteria, which written into normative language would extend
this institution making it higher and wider, would cause many problems. Additionally, the new approach to sentencing such court cases is required. However,
the direction of reforms seems to be inevitable.
In conclusion, it is impossible not to share the concerns of Mazzoleni and
Nelson30 who claimed that change in intellectual property law in the direction
of making patent institution stronger, could bring many troubles in the future.
The world economy will not gain benefits from making patent stronger. Except
from some branches – such as chemistry ones – a stronger patent would be
characterized by a worse relation of generating benefits in relation to social costs.
The emphasis is also required due to the fact that social reality related to
inventions changes very dynamically. It is an additional impediment for seeking
the optimal solutions. Since, even if we have got very accurate diagnosis, as
a result of a delay in its implementation into public policies, it could finally be
classified as pointless. Additionally, there is a problem in an access for databases
and their quantification. Moreover, we have to take into account some differences,
which appear in global, regional, and local contexts.
References
Allered B., Park W. G., Patent Rights and Innovative Activity: Evidence from National
and Firm-Level Data, “Journal of Intellectual Business Studies”, Vol. 38, no. 6
(November 2007).
Bessen J., A Generation of Software Patents, Boston University of Law Working Paper
no 11-31 (21 July 2011).
Cooter R., Ulen T., Ekonomiczna analiza prawa, Warszawa 2009.
30 R. Mazzoleni, R. Nelson, The Benefits…, p. 281.
338 | Przegląd Prawno-Ekonomiczny 42 (1/2018)
Dore M. H. I., Kushner J., Masse L., The Optimal Length of a Patent with Variable Output
Elasticity and Returns to Scale in R&D, “Atlantic Economic Journal” 1993, vol. 21, no 1.
Gallini N., Patent Policy and Costly Imitation, “Rand Journal of Economics” 1992, Vol.
23, No. 1.
Gilbert R., Shapiro, Optimal Patent Length and Breadth, “Rand Journal of Economics”
2012, vol. 21.
IP5 Statistics Report. edition, 2012.
Klemperer P., How Broad Should the Scope of Patent Protection Be, “The Rand Journal
of Economics” 1990, vol. 1, no. 1.
Landes W. M., Posner R., An Economic Analysis of Copyright Law, “Journal of Legal
Studies” 1989, vol. 18, no. 2.
Maurer S. M., Scotchmer, S., The independent invention defence in intellectual property,
“Economica” 2002, 69(276).
Mazzoleni R., Nelson R., The Benefits and Costs of Strong Patent Protection: a Contribution
to the Current Debate, “Research Policy” 1998, no. 27.
Nordhaus W., Invention, Growth and Welfare: A Theoretical Treatment of Technological
Change, MIT Press. 1969.
Saphio C., Patent Reform: Aligning Reward and Contribution, “Innovation Policy and
the Economy” 2007, Vol. 8.
Van Dijk T., The Limit of Patent Protection, “Essays on the Economics of Intellectual
Property Rights”, Maastricht 1994.
Verspagen B., Intellectual Property Rights in the World Economy, essay from WIPO Arab
Regional Sumposium on the Economic Importance of Intellectual Property
Rights, Muscat, Oman 1999.
Załuski W., Schemat ekonomicznego ujęcia prawa własności intelektualnej, (in:) J.
Stelmach (ed.), M. Soniewicka (ed.), Ekonomiczna analiza w zastosowaniach
prawniczych, Warszawa 2008.
Summary
The effectiveness of patent is mostly determined by its width, length and height. Each of
these dimensions is a subject of analysis in this paper. These three dimensions, together
determine “the strength of a patent”. Such perspective allows us to form a fundamental
assumption that a given strength of a patent could be achieved as a result of many different combinations of those three factors, differing in terms of efficiency from the social
perspective. This is the main hypothesis of this text. On this ground a key question is
formulated – i.e. which combination of patent structural features is the most efficient
to create the given (present) strength of a patent.
Keywords: patent, intellectual property, structural features
Artykuł ekonomiczny | 339
Streszczenie
Efektywność patentu jest zdeterminowana głównie przez jego szerokość, długość i wysokość. Każdy z tych trzech wymiarów jest przedmiotem analizy w niniejszym tekście.
Łącznie te trzy wymiary determinują całkowitą „siłę patentu”. W tej perspektywie
określona siła patentu może być osiągnięta w rezultacie różnych kombinacji wspomnianych wyżej trzech zmiennych i charakteryzować się różnym poziomem efektywności
ze społecznego punktu widzenia. Jest to główna hipoteza niniejszego tekstu. Na jej
bazie formułowane jest pytanie o to, jakie kombinacje cech konstrukcyjnych patentu
pozwalają najbardziej efektywnie uzyskać założoną siłę patentu.
Słowa kluczowe: patent, własność intelektualna, cechy strukturalne
Nota o autorze
Bartłomiej Biga, Ph.D., Department of Public Administration, Cracow University of Economics.