Whither Clientelism?: Good Governance and Brazil's Bolsa Família Program
Whither Clientelism?: Good Governance and Brazil's Bolsa Família Program
Whither Clientelism?: Good Governance and Brazil's Bolsa Família Program
Examples of clientelism include offers of cash, material goods (bricks, food, small
appliances), and services such as health care, or public sector employment in exchange
for political support. Vote buying, which occupies the far end of the continuum
between programmatic and clientelist strategies of electoral mobilization, entails
the offering of particularistic material rewards to prospective voters near election time.
Compared to patronage, which often has an ambiguous legal status, vote buying is
almost always illegal.13
Many studies stress several background conditions that render people vulnerable
to clientelism, namely, poverty, inequality, and rural settings.14 Patronage and vote
buying are often viewed as especially prevalent where there is severe poverty, given
the high value placed on benets that patrons can deliver.15 With the low levels of
education that typically accompany extensive deprivation, indigent individuals are less
likely to organize for broad collective solutions. Recent studies also suggest inequality
45
Citya
Camaragibe
Jaboato dos Guararapes
Controls
Bolsa Famlia
Participation
Age
Education
Male
Constant
N
Log Likelihood
Prob > Chi2
Pseudo R2
Std. Err.
Model 2
In the last election, did
anyone try to buy
your vote?
Coef.
Std. Err.
Model 3
Is Bolsa Famlia used
for vote buying?
Coef.
Std. Err.
.6541
.0141
.1777
.1870
.5223
.9661
.2016
.2013
.1618
.3572
.2398
.2416
.4441
.1430
.0166
.1430
.9250
.1678
.0254
.0581
.0104
.0057
.0208
.2605
.0212
.0081
.1757
.0062
.0209
.2630
.0154
.0544
.9382
.0074
.0251
.2715
1.919
.3411
.7524
.3493
1.1142
.4147
1100
680.6047
0.000
0.0537
1100
647.9518
0.0000
0.0356
1100
474.9464
0.0000
0.0657
How do the city-level variables affect the predicted probability that a poor resident reports having received a vote-buying offer? For the average respondent, residence in Jaboato and Camaragibe results in an offer about one-quarter of the time;
in Pau Brasil, such reports are less likely. Indeed, city context matters for the predicted
probability of reported quid pro quo offers.
Finally, the results in model 3 offer a sharp contrast to the previous logistic
models. Unlike those models, which identied varied local experiences with vote
buying, in model 3 respondents across all cities report that the Bolsa Famlia is not used
for vote buying. In other words, whereas city of residence explains variation within
models 1 and 2, in model 3 city variables are not signicant. Respondents views on vote
buying and the Bolsa Famlia are consistent across all three municipalities. Instead, the
control variables yield the leverage in explaining reported differences in the use of
the Bolsa Famlia for vote buying. The most analytically relevant nding in this regard
is that recipients of the program were the least likely to view it as grist for vote buying.
This question reveals a dramatically different scenario regarding the likelihood
that poor families view the Bolsa Famlia in exchange for votes. Drawing once again
on the log odds ratio to generate predicted probabilities, city of residence has no
52
Model 1
Jaboato dos Guararapes
Camaragibe
Pau Brasil
Model 2
Jaboato dos Guararapes
Camaragibe
Pau Brasil
Model 3
Jaboato dos Guararapes
Camaragibe
Pau Brasil
Predicted Probability
Pr(y51|x): 0.6949
Pr(y50|x): 0.3051
Pr(y51|x): 0.5386
Pr(y50|x): 0.4614
Pr(y51|x): 0.6919
Pr(y50|x): 0.3081
Predicted Probability
Pr(y51|x): 0.3584
Pr(y50|x): 0.6416
Pr(y51|x): 0.2638
Pr(y50|x): 0.7362
Pr(y51|x): 0.1753
Pr(y50|x): 0.8247
Predicted Probability
Pr(y51|x): 0.1216
Pr(y50|x): 0.8784
Pr(y51|x): 0.1023
Pr(y50|x): 0.8977
Pr(y51|x): 0.0883
Pr(y50|x): 0.9117
Calculations for average respondent: Bolsa Famlia participant, 38.9 years old, 5.58 years of education,
and female.
meaningful effect on the probability of vote buying with the Bolsa. For the average
respondent, the probability is only 12 percent for Jaboato, 10 percent for Camaragibe,
and 9 percent for Pau Brasil. As reported in Table 1, demographic factors drive the
variation. Holding all else constant, simply participating in the Bolsa Famlia alters the
probability that respondents view the program for vote buying (from a high of 23 percent to a low of 12 percent). Given this result, familiarity with the programs operation
matters. Whereas those with direct knowledge of how the Bolsa functions are more
likely to view it in bureaucratic terms, those without personal experience are more
likely to presume that it is prone to political manipulation.
The side-by-side comparisons of these models allow us to contextualize views on
vote buying with the Bolsa Famlia. Most important, whereas models 1 and 2 suggest
that perceptions and experiences of vote buying vary according to local conditions, the
model about the Bolsa Famlia program generates a standard response. Had there been
political interference with this social policy, we would have found some degree of
local variation. Instead, we found the opposite. That the experiences of poor families
53
Discussion of Findings
Our focus groups and eld research corroborated the statistical results of the three
models. Focus group testimonies revealed not only the general prevalence of clientelism
but also the exception represented by the Bolsa Famlia in these communities. Given
clientelisms widespread operation, it is noteworthy that people saw the Bolsa Famlia
as different. Focus group participants told us that vote buying was frequent and
typically took the form of exchanges for goods or favors. For example, some related
that council members sought to buy votes for amounts between 5 to 50 Reais (approximately $2.50 to $25 US dollars).50 Other respondents indicated that they had received
basic goods, such as a cesta bsica (food basket), bricks, and cement, in exchange for
votes.51 One participants brother was even promised a job in exchange for his entire
familys vote.52 The readiness with which participants acknowledged vote buying suggests that clientelism remains a reality of local elections.
At the same time, participants insisted that Bolsa Famlia grants were not being
traded for votes. When asked whether politicians were either promising Bolsa
resources or threatening to withdraw them our respondents resoundingly answered
no. One person stressed,
I think that politicians would be wrong to try to use Bolsa Famlia for [vote buying].
It would be wrong because the benet is federal. It comes from a federal agency.53
As she went on to explain, the poor would not believe local ofcials promises to
provide or threats to withdraw Bolsa Famlia grants because they understand that the
program falls outside their inuence. This sentiment was echoed across the three communities.54 Braslia decides was commonly repeated to emphasize that local political
efforts to inuence the program would violate its very terms and not even be possible
in practice. Importantly, the focus groups also revealed that local politicians do not play
a regular brokerage role. No one testied to this kind of political assistance, despite
expressions of difculty understanding some aspects of the programs operation, like
the amount of time it took to enroll and changes in grant amounts. Clearly, people
seemed to know the limits of what local authorities could readily deliver or withdraw.
Exploring Causes: Perspectives from Below Suggest How Program Design Matters
What accounts for the nding that the Bolsa Famlia does not appear to grease
clientelistic networks in a most likely case? Testimony from beneciaries suggests
54
Appendix
Table 1A
Variable
Independent Variables
Jaboato dos Guararapes
Pau Brasil
Camaragibe
Bolsa Famlia Participant
Age
Education
Male
404
258
461
726
76
0
0
0
0
16
0
0
1
1
1
1
82
16
1
Mean
Standard
Deviation
.3596
.2293
.4108
.6471
38.8396
5.7494
.0681
.4801
.4207
.4922
.4781
12.5251
3.6796
.2520
59
NOTES
Thanks go to David A. Armstrong, Javier Auyero, Daniel Brinks, Zach Elkins, Cristiano Ferraz, Ken
Greene, Evelyne Huber, Herbert Kitschelt, Ral Madrid, Cssio Muniz, Timothy J. Power, Maria Cristina
Raposo, Cibele Rodrigues, and Kurt Weyland. The authors would also like to thank the anonymous
reviewers for their valuable comments.
1. Robert R. Kaufman and Joan M. Nelson, eds., Crucial Needs, Weak Incentives (Washington, D.C.:
Woodrow Wilson Center Press, 2004); Joan M. Nelson, Reforming Health and Education (Washington/
Baltimore: Overseas Development Council/Johns Hopkins University Press, 1999).
2. Govindan Parayil, ed., Kerala: The Development Experience (London: ZED Books, 2000); V.K.
Ramachandran, Human Development Achievements in an Indian State, in Dharam Ghai, ed., Social
Development and Public Policy (New York: St. Martins Press, 2000); Judith Tendler, Good Government in
the Tropics (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1997).
3. Alberto Daz-Cayeros and Beatriz Magaloni, Aiding Latin Americas Poor, Journal of Democracy,
20 (October 2009), 3649, 40; James W. McGuire, Social Policies in Latin America, in Peter R.
Kingstone and Deborah J. Yashar, eds., Routledge Handbook of Latin American Politics (New York:
Routledge, 2012).
4. For an overview, see Anthony Hall, Brazils Bolsa Famlia, Development and Change, 39 (September 2008), 799882; Kathy Lindert et al., The Nuts and Bolts of Brazils Bolsa Famlia Program,
Social Protection Discussion Paper No. 0709 (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 2007).
5. For example, Kathleen Bruhn, Social Spending and Political Support, Comparative Politics,
28 (January 1996), 15577; Matthew L. Layton and Amy Erica Smith, Social Assistance Policies and the
Presidential Vote in Latin America, in AmericasBarometer Insights (Nashville: Vanderbilt University, 2011).
6. Brian J. Fried, Distributive Politics and Conditional Cash Transfers, World Development,
40 (May 2012), 104253; Wendy Hunter and Timothy J. Power, Rewarding Lula, Latin American
Politics and Society, 49 (Spring 2007), 130; Elaine Cristina Licio, Lucio R. Renn, and Henrique
Carlos de O. de Castro, Bolsa Famlia e voto na eleio presidencial de 2006, Opinio Pblica, 15,
1 (2009); Cesar Zucco, The Presidents New Constituency: Lula and the Pragmatic Vote in Brazils 2006
Presidential Election, Journal of Latin American Studies, 40 (2008), 2949.
7. Alfred P. Montero, No Country for Leftists? Clientelist Continuity and the 2006 Vote in the Brazilian
Northeast, Journal of Politics in Latin America, 2 (January 2010), 11353; Tracy Beck Fenwick, Avoiding
Governors: The Success of the Bolsa Familia, Latin American Research Review, 44, 1 (2009), 10231.
8. Ariel Fiszbein and Norbert Schady, Conditional Cash Transfers: A World Bank Policy Research
Report (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 2009); Lindert et al.
9. Javier Auyero, From the Clients Point(s) of View, Theory and Society, 28 (April 1999), 297334,
297; Susan C. Stokes, Is Vote Buying Undemocratic? in Frederic Charles Schaer, ed., Elections for Sale
(Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner, 2007).
10. Scott Desposato, How Does Vote Buying Shape the Legislative Arena? in Schaer, 101.
11. Javier Auyero, The Logic of Clientelism in Argentina, Latin American Research Review, 35,
3 (2000), 5581; Ernesto Calvo and Victoria Murillo, Who Delivers? American Journal of Political
Science, 48 (October 2004), 74257; Philip Keefer and Razvan Vlaicu, Democracy, Credibility, and
Clientelism, in Policy Research Working Paper (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 2005); Herbert Kitschelt
and Steven I. Wilkinson, eds., Patrons, Clients, and Policies (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2007);
Simeon Nichter, Vote Buying or Turnout Buying? American Political Science Review, 102 (February 2008),
1931.
12. Luis Roniger, Political Clientelism, Democracy, and Market Economy, Comparative Politics,
36 (April 2004), 35375, 35354. Vote buying should be distinguished from constituency services
provided by members of Congress. We do not consider as clientelism antipoverty policies that gain the
programmatic vote of the poor.
13. Frederic Charles Schaer, Why Study Vote Buying, in Schaer, 56.
14. Steen W. Schmidt et al., Friends, Followers, and Factions (Berkeley: University of California
Press, 1977); Kitschelt and Wilkinson; Luis Fernando Medina and Susan C. Stokes, Monopoly and
Monitoring, in Kitschelt and Wilkinson; Stokes, Is Vote Buying Undemocratic?; Susan C. Stokes, Political
Clientelism, in Carles Boix and Susan C. Stokes, eds., The Oxford Handbook of Comparative Politics (New
York: Oxford University Press, 2007).
60
61
62