Stacked Networks Approach
Stacked Networks Approach
Stacked Networks Approach
ABSTRACT
Actor-Network Theory proves particularly inspiring in reconsidering the tenets of quantitative research
and computational methods in the social sciences. However, translating insights from this perspective into
operational models is problematic. The paper examines, in the form of a dialogue, critical problems of the
computational modelling of network topologies considered from the point of view of Actor-Network Theory.
In particular, the paper discusses the impetus of simulation and the inappropriateness of the distinction
between agents and links.
Keywords:
INTRODUCTION
What a network is, what a model is or what a
quantity is are all questions worthwhile being
asked from a methodological viewpoint. At the
same time, all these things (networks, models,
quantities) are all particularly relevant in the
characterisation of contemporary cultures and
deserve also to be studied as such. Work in
Actor-Network Theory has certainly already
provided good occasions to engage into discussions on network topology, on modelling and
on quantification as both vehicles for scientific
investigation and as constitutive features of the
social world (e.g., Callon, 2006; Latour, 2010).
This paper elaborates on the discussion held at
a workshop hosted at the CSI (Centre de Soci-
DOI: 10.4018/jantti.2012010102
Copyright 2012, IGI Global. Copying or distributing in print or electronic forms without written permission of IGI Global is prohibited.
14 International Journal of Actor-Network Theory and Technological Innovation, 4(1), 13-23, January-March 2012
OBJECTING TO SIMULATION
A: You dont seem very happy with the whole
idea of using mathematical models and
computer simulations to understand the
dynamics of networks. Cant you grant
them some empirical value? What do you
think a simulation is, anyway?
B: I can think of two major directions for
understanding the value of a simulation.
One would be a rather sociological one, a
direction in which you start with a dataset,
or a database. You dont care about things
such as whether or not you are confronting
a stable state what you primarily need
is to describe the dataset itself. You can
then imagine a computational model that
is useful or interesting in order to describe
the dataset, to find an analytical vocabulary
that allows making sense of the assemblage
of data. The other way of understanding
simulation would start with getting rid
of data and just playing the game of the
computational device. You might hook the
device onto a dummy database, a database
without data a kind of artificial situation
that does not correspond (does not need
to correspond and could actually hardly
correspond) to any empirical situation.
The second option is the fashionable tendency in computation models, in financial
computational modelling particularly. Just
build an artificial world and play the game
within describing, at best, the behaviour
of a world that you have provoked yourself.
A: Come on. That is a bit of an exaggeration. Model-based prediction of empirical
behaviour is a real possibility. What about
predictions based on the simulation of
real empirical data, such as predictions of
energy consumption which are based on
established trends and which allow for a
pretty accurate prospective modelling of
future behaviour?
B: Of course, prediction of behaviour. But we
are talking here rather about different cul-
Copyright 2012, IGI Global. Copying or distributing in print or electronic forms without written permission of IGI Global is prohibited.
International Journal of Actor-Network Theory and Technological Innovation, 4(1), 13-23, January-March 2012 15
STAKED NETWORKS
B: Staked networks?
A: These are several layers of networks of
different kinds that intermingle together
through small ego-networks that cut across
them all.
B: Ok, I see. That is your idea of heterogeneous
networks as stacked networks. In the case
of, say, a transitional economy, you have
several kinds of networks, such as a network
of corporate interlocking directorates, and
then a network of capitalistic ownership,
and then a network of geographical proximity, and so forth, and then you have nodes
that allow you to make sense of how all
these networks are stacked together. All
right. But then you want to model that
(Figure 1).
A: One big challenge here is to model socalled nonhuman agents: technologies,
artefacts, money, and so forth. The question
is how to model their role, their place, their
behaviour, how to consider them as actors
described within the network. If one knows
how technology behaves and put some efforts to collect the relevant data imagine
for instance a study on competing telecom
protocols (X25, TCP/IP, OSI, etc.) that
would care for how each protocol functions
these nonhuman agents could perfectly be
modelled by a corresponding automata and
added to the compound of diverse human,
individual or corporate agents. Should we
use the same stochastic automaton, slightly
modified, that we used in order to model
human agents? Should we use a separate
automaton? It all depends on the identity
of the nonhuman agent.
B: But what do you mean by the identity of
a nonhuman agent?
A: Im not sure its about the singular identity
of one actor. I mean rather the different
identities of one and the same nonhuman
actor in each of the stacked networks. This
is a big challenge different faces of a
nonhuman agency that acts simultaneously
in different networks? Take money, for
MODEL AS DEMONSTRATION
B: Yes, well, I see the empirical point. But we
need to clarify the purpose of modelling.
A: The most important thing is related to
demonstration. Take Claude Rosentals research on demonstrations used by software
developers (Rosental, 2005, 2008). We are
in a similar situation. If we manage to make
a piece of software sophisticated enough to
model the studied field, and then to model
other fields, you need at least two things.
First, you need data, which are specific for
the given field, allowing an outline of the
stable states, the distribution of variables,
interdependencies, and so forth. Then,
we need to introduce the corresponding
scripts in the model, to change the inputs
and modify the internal properties of the
automata. Then you could get the universality of the tool, not of the model but of
the tool. This is an ambitious goal that is
worth setting If we eventually manage
to build a compound of stacked networks
interconnected via ego-networks, and then
we build the model for this particular field,
and then we model another field, all major
questions about the configuring of stochastic automata will be solved. We will just
need to change the software a little bit. But
its skeleton, its basic properties would be
already available as result of the modelling of the initial field. We get new data, we
change some parameters in the construction
and we are ready to emulate the new field.
Inspiring, isnt it? Its about achieving the
universality of the tool. This is feasible and,
I believe, not very complicated: layered,
stacked networks, taken simultaneously
Copyright 2012, IGI Global. Copying or distributing in print or electronic forms without written permission of IGI Global is prohibited.
16 International Journal of Actor-Network Theory and Technological Innovation, 4(1), 13-23, January-March 2012
Copyright 2012, IGI Global. Copying or distributing in print or electronic forms without written permission of IGI Global is prohibited.
International Journal of Actor-Network Theory and Technological Innovation, 4(1), 13-23, January-March 2012 17
HEURISTIC AUTOMATION
A: Well, we had to come up with these sorts
of concepts. But our key ambition is to
accomplish the automaton, really. We
want to spot its internal simplicities and its
abilities for generating interesting network
behaviour. An accomplished automaton
could be used to build many kinds of
research. Interesting research directions
would include applying the automaton to
simpler datasets. You do not need to have
fifteen variables Each sub-network could
be defined by a single variable, describing the basic (critical) relationship in the
network. It is difficult, of course, to decide
what this basic relationship is, but I think it
is worth thinking in that direction if not
one, we could combine two variables into a
single one, while the other variables could
be built-in as properties of the automaton
itself. So when such and such a script arrives
at the input, the automaton has to react in
a specific manner. The crucial point is to
clarify what you want, to clarify the initial
design that precedes building the automata
itself.
B: But you have first to define properties that
characterise your dataset. Not to try to
model your dataset, because your dataset
is too complex!
A: There is little sense in building purely
abstract models; we need to have datasets
in mind.
B: To build a machine that mimics the real
world, this is a hard task. But you can
have machines that are simple, and then
you say: well, it does not mimic a real
Copyright 2012, IGI Global. Copying or distributing in print or electronic forms without written permission of IGI Global is prohibited.
18 International Journal of Actor-Network Theory and Technological Innovation, 4(1), 13-23, January-March 2012
AGENCY IN NETWORKS
A: Yes, the agency of nonhuman agents?
B: Well, I am not sure that the point of ActorNetwork Theory is to say that there are
some human agents, which have agency,
and that there are also some nonhuman
agents, which also have agency. Im not sure
that the problem is to develop some kind
of network analysis where every kind of
actor could be granted with agency. Is that
the most relevant point of Actor-Network
Theory? I would rather say that the point
is that no one and nothing have agency at
all either human agents or otherwise
unless those agents are networks. So in
some sense the challenge of Actor-Network
Theory is not to discuss the notion of agent,
but rather to reassess the notion of network.
A: Well, its true that the whole point is to
replace both the notion of actor and of
network with the notion of actor-network.
Copyright 2012, IGI Global. Copying or distributing in print or electronic forms without written permission of IGI Global is prohibited.
International Journal of Actor-Network Theory and Technological Innovation, 4(1), 13-23, January-March 2012 19
DATABASES
A: Yes, right. Here we do not consider autonomous fields. But we consider, in a sense,
autonomous sets defined by the propagation
of specific mediators (or intermediaries, or
both). I mean datasets which correspond to
a heteronomous empirical reality but that
look autonomous because they correspond
to one kind of data source. The fields are
thus autonomous only as datasets because
if you are collecting information, there are
business databases, legal databases, scientific databases and so forth. I would like to
come back to the problem of a mediator
transforming itself into an actor: from the
point of view of ongoing interactions in the
topological space, databases are just mediators that stabilise and make predictable
these interactions. But all of a sudden they
become actors speaking or portraying
this space in a specific manner.
B: But that is actually the only reason why
you have such a thing as different subnetworks: because you construct them on
the basis of sources, which are instituted
as different, in a sense. A field is just the
performative result of the institutional
practice of a data provider.
A: Well, the idea that we shouldnt trust the
boundaries between fields is particularly
helpful in the study of transitional economies. The notion of recombination is
particularly illuminating here (Stark, 1996).
The existence of different sub-networks
should not derive from sociological assumptions but primarily from the properties of data sources. Consider the reality
of corporate mergers and acquisitions: it
is a profusion of political, kinship, social,
Copyright 2012, IGI Global. Copying or distributing in print or electronic forms without written permission of IGI Global is prohibited.
20 International Journal of Actor-Network Theory and Technological Innovation, 4(1), 13-23, January-March 2012
automata implied by most existing simulations, in the very way a modelled system
arrives at stability. I think the real challenge is to envision a sort of stochastic
automata in which you do not make many
assumptions about the rules of behaviour
of the agents, and let them fold into the
agency of the networks. Well, for the sake
of computation you incidentally need to
start with the design of the properties of
the agents of the specific sub-network. One
automaton can simulate the behaviour of all
other agents. In fact there is one automaton
that changes its state after each iteration.
To model another sub-network you could
use the same automaton just changing
some of its properties according to the
corresponding dataset and so on, depending on the number of layers you have in
mind. Then you begin thinking about the
ego-network, and about how the very fact
of being together modifies the functioning of automata, which now become some
kind of modules of the larger automata
which is the ego-network. Yes, indeed its
the network that has agency, not the separate automata! But we have to care for the
stability of the sub-networks, which should
not start to fall apart. And this means that
we have to build into the initial automata
some additional properties, stemming not
from the functioning of the sub-networks,
but from the necessity of their mutual coexistence. And this obviously will cause
changes in the properties of the initially
designed automata, in each of the initial
sub-networks. This is a really complex
task.
FLAT NETWORKS
B: It is surely easier to study flat, heterogeneous networks than to model these stacked
networks. I see you want to try But do
not try to use data in the first place, then!
I think the first step is to demonstrate, to
show that this is a good idea to use the
A:
B:
A:
B:
Copyright 2012, IGI Global. Copying or distributing in print or electronic forms without written permission of IGI Global is prohibited.
International Journal of Actor-Network Theory and Technological Innovation, 4(1), 13-23, January-March 2012 21
Copyright 2012, IGI Global. Copying or distributing in print or electronic forms without written permission of IGI Global is prohibited.
22 International Journal of Actor-Network Theory and Technological Innovation, 4(1), 13-23, January-March 2012
CONCLUSION
A: Maybe we should refrain from assessing
stability and instability and limit ourselves
to descriptions of the state of networks, at
best of kaleidoscopically changing states.
And to attempting to trace and visualise the
continuity in their evolution as networks.
From a mathematical topological point of
view, the continuity between a circle and
a square is not a big deal.
B: In a sense, maybe Actor-Network Theory is
more topological than we thought: I mean
in the sense of mathematical topology, not
of network topology. It is precisely a point
of view for which there are no dimensions,
no coordinated space. Everything is selfcontained in the networks, including their
metrics.
REFERENCES
Callon, M. (2006). Can methods for analysing large
numbers organize a productive dialogue with the
actors they study? European Management Review,
3(1), 716. doi:10.1057/palgrave.emr.1500051
Kapriev, G., & Tchalakov, I. (2009). Actor-Network
Theory and Byzantine interpretation of Aristotles
theory of action: three points of possible dialogue.
In Bamm, A., Getzinger, G., & Weiser, B. (Eds.),
Yearbook 2008 of the Institute for Advanced Studies
on Science, Technologies and Society (pp. 207238).
Munich, Germany: Profil.
Latour, B. (2010). Tardes idea of quantification. In
Candea, M. (Ed.), The social after Gabriel Tarde:
Debates and assessments (pp. 145162). London,
UK: Routledge.
Mandelbrot, B., & Hudson, R. L. (2004). The (mis)
behavior of markets: a fractal view of risk, ruin, and
reward. New York, NY: Basic Books.
Rosental, C. (2005). Making science and technology
results public: a sociology of demos. In Latour, B.,
& Weibel, P. (Eds.), Making things public: atmospheres of democracy (pp. 346349). Cambridge,
MA: MIT Press.
Rosental, C. (2008). Weaving self-evidence: a sociology of logic. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Press.
Stark, D. (1996). Recombinant property in East European capitalism. American Journal of Sociology,
101(4), 9931027. doi:10.1086/230786
Tchalakov, I., & Burton, P. (Eds.). (2001). Project
TACTICS. Sofia, Bulgaria: LIK.
Tchalakov, I., & Kapriev, G. (2005). The limits of
causal action: Actor-Network Theory notion of translation and Aristotles notion of action. In Bamm, A.,
Getzinger, G., & Weiser, B. (Eds.), Yearbook 2005
of the Institute for Advanced Studies on Science,
Technologies and Society (pp. 389433). Munich,
Germany: Profil.
Zelizer, V. A. (2001). The social meanings of money:
pin money, paychecks, poor relief, and other currencies. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Copyright 2012, IGI Global. Copying or distributing in print or electronic forms without written permission of IGI Global is prohibited.
International Journal of Actor-Network Theory and Technological Innovation, 4(1), 13-23, January-March 2012 23
ENDNOTES
1
Copyright 2012, IGI Global. Copying or distributing in print or electronic forms without written permission of IGI Global is prohibited.