Determinants of Firms' Liquidation and Acquisition in The Indian Electronics Industry
Determinants of Firms' Liquidation and Acquisition in The Indian Electronics Industry
Determinants of Firms' Liquidation and Acquisition in The Indian Electronics Industry
1. INTRODUCTION
The era of the Indian electronics industry commenced a decade after Indias
independence. The Indian government played a vital role in developing a
domestic electronics industry. For example, in the initial stages of the industrys
development, that is, the 1960s and 1970s, government policies were geared
The author is Senior Research Fellow, Department of Humanities and Social Sciences,
Indian Institute of Technology Kanpur, Kanpur, India-208016, Tel: +919935829507, email:
irfan@iitk.ac.in
An earlier draft of this article was presented at the Second Doctoral Theses Conference
organised by the IBS, Hyderabad, 78 March 2008. The author would like to thank the
conference participants and anonymous referees of this journal for their constructive comments and suggestions.
76
Authors own calculations based on data provided by the Industry Analysis Service of the Center
for Monitoring Indian Economy (CMIE).
and provides some policy-related information to electronics industry organisations and the government to maintain a balanced flow of firms, that is, to
maintain entry and exit and a competitive electronics industry in India.
The decline of firms is termed as exit in industrial organisation literature.
Schary (1991) argues that a firm exits in one of the three modes: voluntary
liquidation, involuntary liquidation or acquisition, and these modes are different economic phenomena. Liquidation is the sale of a firms assets and the
proceeds obtained are used to clear outstanding dues of the claimants (Hudson,
1986). In liquidation, productive capacity is often removed from the industry
and claimants receive partial payment. When the liquidation is initiated by the
creditors it is known as involuntary liquidation, otherwise it is termed voluntary
liquidation. On the other hand, acquisition is the transfer of ownership by the
sale or purchase of a firms equity. In acquisition, much of the productive capacity remains in the industry and the claimants receive full payment. Acquisitions
are considered a more civilised alternative to liquidations (Dewey, 1961). In
addition, the causes of liquidation and acquisition are significantly different
from each other. For example, firms performance (Altman, 1968), leverage
(Zingales, 1998) and size (Harhoff et al., 1998) are identified in the literature
as factors that influence modes of exit in different ways. Previous studies on
firm exit are restricted to developed countries (Audretsch, 1991; Disney et al.,
2003; Evans, 1987; Mahmood, 2000; Shapiro and Khemani, 1987). Therefore,
the empirical observations of previous studies cannot be extended to Indian
electronics industry.
We argue that the determinants of liquidation and acquisition modes of
exit are different in the Indian electronics industry. To the best of our knowledge, no previous study on Indian firms has considered the modes of exit in
their analysis. For example, Das and Srinivasan (1997) studied the survival of
firms in the Indian computer hardware industry. However, in their study, the
distinction among the modes of exit was not considered. Therefore, it is now
necessary to examine the determinants of firm exit in a unified framework to
avoid any sample selection problem which could lead to a biased estimation of
results. The present study examines the determinants of firms exit in the Indian
electronics industry taking into account the two modes of exit: liquidation and
acquisition. The sample consists of 540 firms which were active during the
period 19802006. Multinomial logistic (MNL) regression analysis is applied
to examine the firm-specific determinants of liquidation and acquisition in
the Indian electronics industry. The rest of the article is organised as follows:
Section 2 discusses the literature relevant to this study. Details of the sample
MarginThe Journal of Applied Economic Research 6 : 1 (2012): 7590
78
2.1 Age
Age is considered a key determinant of liquidation and acquisition. The general consensus of the empirical studies which examine the impact of age on
exit modes is that the likelihood of liquidation decreases with age whereas the
likelihood of acquisition increases with age (Audretsch, 1991; Disney et al.,
2003; Evans, 1987; Mahmood, 2000; Mata and Portugal, 1994). According to
Jovanovic (1982), older firms learn from their past experience and hence are
more likely to survive in adverse situations. The literature suggests that older
firms develop a brand name and reputation in the industry which makes them
attractive targets for acquisitions (Esteve-Prez et al., 2010).
2.2 Size
There is a general agreement that the likelihood of exit declines with firm size.
Large firms are equipped with large amounts of physical, financial, human and
other resources which improve their possibility of exploiting scale economies.
As a result, such firms protect themselves from liquidation by earning higher
profits (Audretsch, 1991; Hall, 1987; Mahmood, 2000). Similarly, acquisition of
large firms requires large investments and thus increases the cost of acquisition.
Shleifer and Vishny (1992) argue that the market for corporate control is less
liquid as firm size increases. So it is expected that an increase in the firm size
reduces the likelihood of liquidation and acquisition.
higher for innovative firms. In contrast, Mahmood (2000) finds that the effect
of innovative competence varies across industries. Innovative firms are good
acquisition targets because the acquisition of innovative firms supports the
acquirers expansion policy and it is an economical way to expand (Heeley
et al., 2006). Therefore, it is expected that innovative firms are less likely to be
liquidated and more likely to be acquired.
2.4 Leverage
Leverage is the firms reliance on debts to finance its assets, and higher the
reliance on debt the greater the risk of liquidation. On the one hand, excessive
debt leads to a large debt burden on firms and firms with high leverage are
more likely to be liquidated (Pastena and Ruland, 1986). On the other hand,
high leverage firms are less attractive targets for acquisitions, because acquiring a high-leverage firm transfers the risk of the debt burden to the acquirer
(Fotopoulos and Louri, 2000; Kornai, 1998; Pastena and Ruland, 1986). Hence,
we expect that leverage increases the likelihood of liquidation and reduces the
likelihood of acquisition.
2.5 Profitability
A firms profitability is also likely to be an important factor in the exit of firms. If
a firm fails to attain a desired level of profits, its likelihood of survival diminishes
(Bojnec and Xavier, 2007). Altman (1968) observes that low performance firms
are more likely to fail. Dean (1997) argues that firms with poor performance
are more likely to become takeover targets. Besides, acquisitions act as a corporate control measure to improve firms performance (Jensen, 1986; Shleifer
and Vishny, 1992). Hence, it is expected that the least-profitable firms are more
likely to be liquidated and acquired.
80
(1)
where subscript i denotes the firm and subscript j denotes the mode of exit. Xi
is a vector of firm-specific characteristics and j represents mode-specific
constant terms. If the errors ij are i.i.d. according to a type I extreme-value
distribution, then the differences in are distributed logistically, and the probability that firm i exits in mode j is as follows.
Pij =
e
J
j + Xi j
j + Xi j
; j = 1, 2,..., J
(2)
j =1
82
response data. The MNL model uses one alternative as a reference category,
and any parameter estimate represents the effect of the explanatory variable in
relative to this reference category (Long and Freese, 2001). In the present study,
we use non-exited as a reference category. More specifically, we restrict 3 = 0
and 3 = 0 for reasons of identification of parameters so that the interpretation
of parameters is relative to the non-exited category. Estimation of the MNL
model is best carried out by the maximum likelihood method (Wooldridge,
2003). Accordingly, for firm i the likelihood function can be represented as
J
li ( ) = Pij (X , )Yij
j =1
(3)
where Yij is the indicator function and Yij = 1 if firm i exits in mode j otherwise
Yij = 0, and the log likelihood function for all the firms is as follows:
LL =
log P Y
ij
i =1 j =1
ij
(4)
Exit Mode
AGE
Liquidation
Acquisition
Non-exited
Liquidation
Acquisition
Non-exited
Liquidation
Acquisition
Non-exited
Liquidation
Acquisition
Non-exited
Liquidation
Acquisition
Non-exited
Liquidation
Acquisition
Non-exited
SIZE
RD
DEBT
PROF
ASUT
Mean
Std. Dev.
Min.
Max.
103
142
295
103
142
295
103
142
295
103
142
295
103
142
295
103
142
295
14.22
11.64
22.03
4.819
3.257
4.424
0.017
0.016
0.021
0.574
0.151
0.201
0.095
0.133
0.133
0.027
0.014
0.020
8.829
7.365
11.37
1.496
1.291
1.847
0.059
0.031
0.032
3.316
0.136
0.137
0.203
0.101
0.115
0.064
0.039
0.051
1
1
2
0.94
0.30
0.41
0
0
0
0
0
0
1.51
0.30
0.59
0
0
0
39
35
42
8.03
6.57
9.16
0.49
0.18
0.17
33.8
0.74
0.82
0.31
0.42
0.43
0.45
0.24
0.60
Mean Diff.
2.575
1.562
0.001
0.422
0.037
0.012
Std. Error
1.037
0.178
0.005
0.278
0.019
0.006
2.48
8.74
0.20
1.51
1.90
1.92
Notes: The test statistics are heteroskedastic t-tests of equal means (liquidated versus
acquired firms) with 243 degrees of freedom; indicates significance at the 1 per
cent level; indicates significance at the 5 per cent level; indicates significance at
the 10 per cent level.
The mean value of variable RD is 0.017 for the liquidated firms and 0.016 for
the acquired firms and the mean difference is statistically insignificant.
The mean values of variable DEBT are 0.574 and 0.151 for the liquidated
and acquired firms, respectively. Liquidated firms therefore seem to be highleveraged firms than acquired firms. However, the mean difference (0.422) is
statistically insignificant. In terms of profitability, liquidated firms perform
worse than acquired firms. The mean values of variable PROF are 0.095 and
MarginThe Journal of Applied Economic Research 6 : 1 (2012): 7590
84
0.133 for the liquidated and acquired firms, respectively and the mean difference
(0.037) is statistically significant at the 10 per cent level. The asset utilisation
of acquired firms is lower than liquidated firms. The mean value of ASUT is
0.014 for the acquired firms and 0.027 for the liquidated firms, and the mean
difference (0.012) is statistically significant at the 10 per cent level.
The parameters of the MNL models are estimated using mlogit command in STATA 10.
Model 1
Liquidation
0.364
0.074
(0.013)
0.188
(0.076)
9.428
(3.778)
Acquisition
3.698
0.113
(0.014)
0.523
(0.086)
8.072
(3.750)
1.671
2.652
(0.843)
(0.902)
4.093
0.332
(1.113)
(1.097)
1.054
2.141
(2.099)
(2.501)
427.578
222.21
0.0000
0.2063
Model 2
Liquidation
Acquisition
0.365
3.672
0.072
0.114
(0.012)
(0.014)
0.195
0.518
(0.076)
(0.085)
2.398
16.712
(10.29)
(10.01)
17.912
10.866
(14.341)
(4.355)
1.487
2.618
(0.859)
(0.906)
3.851
0.325
(1.123)
(1.117)
0.952
2.085
(2.099)
(2.498)
425.901
225.57
0.0000
0.2094
Notes: Sample consists of N = 540 firms, including 103 liquidated, 142 acquired and
295 non-exited firms; reference category is non-exited; standard errors in brackets;
significant at 1 per cent level; significant at 5 per cent level; significant at 10 per
cent level. Degrees of freedom for the likelihood ratio test in Model 1 and Model 2 are
12 and 14, respectively.
large firms requires large funds and thus such firms are less likely to be acquired
(Shleifer and Vishny, 1992).
Innovative competence (RD) is negatively related with the likelihood of
liquidation as well as acquisition. The logit coefficients for liquidation and
acquisition modes of exit are 9.428 and 8.072, respectively. The coefficient
for liquidation is statistically significant at the 1 per cent level but the coefficient
for acquisition is statistically significant at the 5 per cent level. The effect of
innovative competence in the Indian electronics industry is inconsistent with
the findings of Ericson and Pakes (1995) and Heeley et al. (2006). This is because
the investments in R&D activities are intangible or sunk costs (Rosenbaum
and Lamort, 1992) and therefore cannot be fully recovered in the liquidation
process or transferred in acquisition. In addition, R&D plays an important
role in increasing profits by increasing sales or reducing costs and thus reduces
MarginThe Journal of Applied Economic Research 6 : 1 (2012): 7590
86
the likelihood of liquidation. Hence, more innovative firms are less likely to
be liquidated and acquired. To examine the lagged effect of innovative competence, we estimated another MNL model (that is, Model 2) with a one-year
lag specification for the variable innovative competence (RDt1). Since R&D
impacts with a lag, it is necessary to examine such effects.3 The results of this
model are presented in the last two columns of Table 4. We find that the effect
of variable RDt1 is statistically insignificant for the modes of exit.
The effect of leverage (DEBT) is found positively associated with the likelihood of liquidation and negatively associated with the likelihood of acquisition.
The logit coefficients are 1.671 and 2.652 for the liquidation and acquisition
modes of exit, respectively. These coefficients are statistically significant at the
5 per cent level (for liquidation) and 1 per cent level (for acquisition). The results
are consistent with past findings and imply that an increase in debt increases
the likelihood of liquidation but decreases the likelihood of acquisition. Highleveraged firms have to pay large interests on their debt, which in turn reduces
their profits and increases their chances of liquidation (Pastena and Ruland,
1986). The increase in debt also increases the risks, namely, liquidity, high cost
of financing and a decrease in the acquirers financial performance involved in
acquiring a leveraged firm (Pastena and Ruland, 1986). Importantly, a greater
part of the acquirers revenue will be exhausted in repaying the debt (Fotopoulos
and Louri, 2000; Kornai, 1998). Hence, an increase in leverage reduces the possibility of a firm to be acquired.
Though profitability is an important determinant of exit in the literature, we
find that in the Indian electronics industry it affects the liquidation mode of exit
only. The logit coefficient for the variable PROF is 4.093 and it is statistically
significant at the 1 per cent level. For the acquisition mode of exit it is insignificant. This suggests that an increase in profitability reduces the likelihood of
liquidation. This finding supports the argument that large profit earnings allow
a firm to develop the distinct capabilities, that is, enhances its ability to adapt
to a changing competitive environment and removes the liquidity constraint,
and hence improves the firms survival prospects (Altman, 1968). The impact
of asset utilisation on the likelihood of liquidation and acquisition is found
insignificant in the Indian electronics industry. This suggests that the survival
prospects in Indian electronics are presumably not governed by the firms ability
to cover their fixed costs over variable costs.
The author is thankful to an anonymous referee for suggesting the lag effect of R&D activities
on exit modes.
(5)
88
Chi2
1
2
3
11.2
2.961
5.456
d.o.f.
P > Chi2
Evidence
7
7
7
0.130
0.886
0.604
for Ho
for Ho
for Ho
Notes: Ho: Odds (Outcome-J versus Outcome-K) are independent of other alternatives;
d.o.f.: degrees of freedom.
the exit modes are independent. Hence, the Hausman test for IIA assumption
strongly recommends MNL model to estimate the parameters.
6. CONCLUSION
Previous research studies argue that low demand and low prices are the driving forces behind the exit of firms. In contrast, the present study has identified
additional factors that affect the exit of firms in the Indian electronics industry.
We have considered two modes of exit, liquidation and acquisition, and utilised
cross-sectional data of 540 firms including 245 non-exited, 103 liquidated
and 142 acquired firms to identify such factors. An MNL regression model is
employed to examine the firm-specific determinants of liquidation and acquisition in the Indian electronics industry during the period 19902006.
We find significant differences in the determinants across exit modes in the
industry. For example, firm size and leverage affect these two modes of exit
differently. An increase in the firm size increases the chances of liquidation
but decreases the chances of acquisition. Similarly, an increase in the leverage
reduces the chances of being acquired but increases the chances of liquidation.
Moreover, profitability affects the likelihood of the liquidation only. The effects
of firm age and innovative competence are found similar for the two modes
of exit. Our findings suggest that the empirical regularities of previous studies related to developed countries cannot hold true for the Indian electronics
industry. Therefore, the study of factors beyond product price provides powerful
policy-making information to both the government and electronics industry
organisations. This information can be used to focus on balanced flow of firms,
that is, maintained entry and exit and a competitive electronics industry.
References
Agarwal, R., & Gort, M. (2002). Firm and product life cycles and firm survival. American
Economic Review, 92(2), 18490.
90
Majumdar, S.K. (1997). The impact of size and age on firm-level performance: Some evidence from India. Review of Industrial Organization, 12(2), 23141.
Mata, J., & Portugal, P. (1994). Life duration of new firms. The Journal of Industrial Economics,
42(3), 22745.
Mahmood, T. (2000). Survival of newly founded businesses: A log-logistic model approach.
Small Business Economics, 14(3), 22337.
Pastena, V., & Ruland, W. (1986). The merger/bankruptcy alternative. The Accounting
Review, 61(2), 288301.
Rosenbaum, D.I., & Lamort, F. (1992). Entry, barriers, exit, and sunk costs: An analysis.
Applied Economics, 24(3), 297304.
Schary, M.A. (1991). The probability of exit. RAND Journal of Economics, 22(3), 33953.
Shapiro, D., & Khemani, R.S. (1987). The determinants of entry and exit reconsidered.
International Journal of Industrial Organization, 5(1), 1526.
Shleifer, A.W., & Vishny, R.W. (1992). Liquidation values and debt capacity: A market
equilibrium approach. Journal of Finance, 47(4), 134346.
Train, K. (2009). Discrete choice methods with simulation. New York: Cambridge University
Press.
Wooldridge, J.M. (2003). Introductory econometrics. Delhi: Cengage Learning.
Zingales, L. (1998). Survival of the fittest or the fattest? Exit and financing in the trucking
industry. Journal of Finance, 53(3), 90538.