Transaction Costs, Trading Volume and Momentum Strategies
Transaction Costs, Trading Volume and Momentum Strategies
Transaction Costs, Trading Volume and Momentum Strategies
Xiafei Li
Nottingham University Business School
Chris Brooks
ICMA Centre, University of Reading
Joelle Miffre
EDHEC, Nice, France
May 2009
Abstract
This study considers the relationship between trading volumes, transactions costs, and
the profitability of momentum strategies using data from the UK. We demonstrate that
round-trip transactions costs for selling loser firms are around double those of buying
winners, and in particular, the costs of selling low volume losers is more than twice as
high as the cost of selling low volume winners. By contrast, there are only modest
differences between the costs of buying winners and losers, irrespective of their
volume levels. Yet we observe that, even in net terms, momentum strategies based on
low volume stocks are more profitable than those using high volume stocks. We also
note important differences between transactions costs measured using quoted versus
effective spreads. Altogether, our findings should sound a word of caution for any
study attempting to evaluate the impact of transactions costs on momentum
profitability that such costs are very heterogeneous across firms and trade types,
implying that they require careful calculation.
_____________________________
* Xiafei Li, Nottingham University Business School (U.K.),
Xiafei.Li@nottingham.ac.uk, Tel: +44 (0) 115 9518603,
** Chris Brooks, ICMA Centre, University of Reading, Whiteknights, PO Box
242, Reading, RG6 6BA, UK, e-mail: c.brooks@icmacentre.rdg.ac.uk, Tel: +44
(0)118 378 8239,
*** Joëlle Miffre, EDHEC Business School, 393 Promenade des Anglais, 06202,
Nice, France, e-mail: Joelle.Miffre@edhec.edu, Tel: +33 (0)4 93 18 32 55.
The authors thank Keith Anderson for providing the mnemonics for the firm list.
1. Introduction
A number of studies document that momentum strategies can be used to predict stock
returns. For example, Jegadeesh and Titman (1993, 2001) report that past winners
tend to outperform past losers over the following 3 to 12 months. Chan, Jegadeesh
and Lakonishok (1996) show that not only price momentum, but also earnings
momentum can help to predict future stock returns. Moskowitz and Grinblatt (1999)
suggest that price momentum can be explained by industry momentum. Grundy and
Martin (2001) find that momentum profits are dominated by stock-specific returns.
Rouwenhorst (1998) and Griffin, Ji and Martin (2003) provide evidence of price
continuation in international stock markets. Most of these studies assume that
transaction costs are symmetric between past winners and past losers and that they are
small enough to allow investors to earn significant momentum profits.
However, the availability of opportunities for exploiting momentum profits has been
questioned by Lesmond, Schill and Zhou (hereafter LSZ, 2004). They argue that the
measurement of transaction costs in early momentum studies is based on the trading
of large and liquid stocks. But momentum profits are mainly generated by short-
selling losers and yet trading in such losers typically has higher transaction costs due
to their small market value, low price and low liquidity. They conclude that positive
net momentum profits cannot be earned after considering transaction costs. By
contrast, Hanna and Ready (2005) show that both equally-weighted and value-
weighted momentum strategies can earn significant excess returns after transaction
costs. Korajczyk and Sadka (2004) also study the impact of transaction costs on
momentum profits. Unlike LSZ (2004), they conclude that the abnormal performances
of equally- and value-weighted momentum portfolios exceed proportional transaction
costs (such as effective or quoted spreads). Yet these abnormal returns quickly decline
with the price impact of trading. In effect, the profits of equally- and value-weighted
momentum strategies do persist but only for relatively small scale investment (of less
than $200 million and $2 billion, respectively).1
1
The alphas are less likely to be wiped out by price impact costs when stocks in the long-short
portfolios are weighted according to the price impact itself. $5 billion then needs to be invested in the
liquidity-weighted momentum strategy for the profits to disappear.
1
The conclusion of LSZ (2004) that momentum portfolios create an illusion of
profitable trading opportunities is drawn solely from the “6-6” strategy, involving
portfolio formation and holding periods each of 6 months’ duration. Hence it may not
be representative of the profitability of all momentum rules since transaction costs
may differ widely for strategies with different holding periods. For example, strategies
with a 6-month holding period require the purchase of winners and the sale of losers
at the end of the ranking period and the closure of the long and short positions at the
end of the holding period twice a year. But strategies with a 12-month holding period
only require the purchase of winners, the sale of losers and the closure of long and
short positions once a year. As a result, the annual transaction costs of strategies with
6-month holding periods are likely to be almost twice as high as those of strategies
with 12-month holding periods.2 Although LSZ’s conclusion is valid for strategies
with 6-month holding periods, it might be invalid for strategies with holding periods
over 6 months. We extend their analysis of transaction costs for momentum strategies
to the UK and examine net momentum returns for 9 momentum strategies with all
combinations of 3-, 6-, and 12-month ranking and holding periods. 3
The second objective of this paper is to investigate the relation between trading
volume and transaction cost. Trading volume has been identified as providing
valuable information for traders (see for example, Karpoff, 1986, 1987; Blume,
Easley and O’Hara, 1994; Campbell, Grossman and Wang, 1993). A better
understanding of the relationship between trading volume and transaction cost is
important for investors to develop their trading strategies. Surprisingly, empirical
findings show an ambiguous relationship between them. Chordia, Roll and
Subrahmanyam (2000, 2001) document that transaction cost and trading volume are
highly correlated since transaction cost can be considered a proxy for commonality in
liquidity and trading volume is a proxy of liquidity in individual stocks. Foster and
2
Although transactions costs will not be twice as high in practice since a reasonable proportion of
stocks in the momentum portfolios are likely to remain there for the following 6-month period and thus
no further costs would be incurred.
3
Li et al. (2009) also provide comparative evidence on the profitability of momentum strategies in the
UK when returns are measured net of transactions costs. They propose an approach to portfolio
construction that explicitly allows for transactions costs. By contrast, the present study instead focuses
on the relationship between the profitability of relative strength portfolios and trading volumes.
2
Viswanathan (1993), Huang and Stoll (1997) and Chordia, Roll and Subrahmanyam
(2001) find a strong positive relationship between trading volume and quoted or
effective spreads. Contrary to their findings, Karpoff (1986), Glosten and Harris
(1988), Admati and Pfleiderer (1988), Foster and Viswanathan (1990), and Brennan
and Subrahmanyam (1995) report a negative relationship between volume and
spreads. Recent studies by Lee and Swaminathan (2000) and Johnson (2008) suggest
that trading volume is weakly correlated with or unrelated to bid-ask spreads.
This study splits each round-trip transaction into buyer- or seller-initiated trades and
separately examines the relationship between trading volume and transaction costs
between purchases and sales. The rationale for this distinction stems from a conjecture
that market responses to a buy order might be different from that to a sell order.
Though numerous studies have examined the relationship between trading volume
and transaction costs, to our knowledge, no one has adopted this method to identify
the patterns of trading volume to the costs of buyer- and seller-initiated transactions
for winners and losers. The purpose of this paper is to fill this gap in the literature and
to shed some light on the currently ambiguous relationship in empirical findings.
In line with the study of LSZ (2004), we show that the loser portfolios mainly consist
of stocks with low market value, low price and low trading volume. Transaction costs
for losers are much higher than those of winners. The average round-trip total
transaction cost (including commissions, stamp duties and short selling costs) based
3
on the effective spread is 6.67% for losers and 3.46% for winners. However, after
taking account of total transaction costs based on full turnover (assuming that
momentum traders close out their entire long-short portfolios at the end of each
holding period), positive and significant momentum returns still exist for strategies
with 12-month holding periods, but disappear for strategies with up to 6-month
holding periods. When we estimate transaction costs based on actual turnover
(assuming that momentum traders only close out the positions if stocks no longer
remain in the same portfolio in the following period), 6 out of 9 momentum strategies
generate significant net momentum profits at the 5% level. This paper therefore
questions the conclusion of LSZ (2004), which may only valid for strategies with a
holding period of up to 6 months in the US market.
We also add evidence to the literature on the link between trading volume and
momentum. Consistent with the high volume return premium reported by Gervais,
Kaniel and Mingelgrin (2001),4 we find that both winner and loser portfolios with
high trading volume generate higher returns than those with low trading volume. But
overall, momentum strategies with low trading volume yield the highest momentum
profits. We also provide evidence that the high momentum profits for low volume
momentum strategies are mainly driven by higher returns on short selling low volume
losers.
The results on the relationship between trading volume and transaction costs are
intriguing. We find a positive relationship between trading volume and the costs of
buying winners and losers and a negative relationship between trading volume and the
costs of selling winners and losers. These results help to clarify the currently
ambiguous relationship between trading volume and transaction costs in previous
studies. Additionally, we find that the costs of buying losers are only slightly higher
than the costs of buying winners, but the costs of selling losers are much higher than
the costs of selling winners, particular for low volume stocks. On average, the costs of
selling losers with low trading volume are almost 3 times as much as the costs of
4
Gervais, Kaniel and Mingelgrin (2001) report a high volume return premium for NYSE stocks,
whereby stocks with unusually large (small) trading volume tend to generate large (small) returns over
the following month.
4
selling winners with low trading volume. Our results therefore suggest that the
relatively expensive transaction costs of losers are mainly driven by the higher costs
involved in selling illiquid stocks.
The rest of the study is organised as follows. Section 2 describes the data and the
methodology. Section 3 presents our results on an extension of the LSZ (2004) to the
UK. Section 4 examines the relationship between trading volume, momentum returns,
and transaction costs. Section 5 analyses the results and finally, section 6 presents
some concluding remarks.
5
These death types represent: liquidation, quotation cancelled for reason unknown, receiver
appointed/liquidation, in administration/administrative receivership, and cancelled and assumed
valueless.
5
2.2. Estimation of Transaction Costs
We measure total transaction costs as the bid-ask spread estimated based on quoted
spreads and on effective spreads plus commissions, stamp duty and short-selling costs
for losers. The quoted bid-ask spread is defined as the difference between the quoted
ask price and the quoted bid price. Following Chordia, Roll and Subrahmanyam
(2000), the proportional quoted spread is calculated as:
where Ait is the ask price, Bit is the bid price and Mit is the bid-ask midpoint for asset i
on the last trading day of month t. The quoted spread measures the cost of a round-trip
transaction. In order to mitigate the problem that estimates of transaction costs may be
severely affected by a few winner or loser stocks with extremely high or low spreads
(e.g., due to data errors), we filter out and remove stocks with negative quoted spreads
and those with quoted spreads larger than 100%.
Lee and Ready (1991) argue that quoted spreads may provide misleading estimates of
actual transaction costs because trades are often executed within the bid and ask
quotes. Alternatively, investors may also face trading prices that are outside the
spread for orders larger than normal market size. Therefore, several studies use the
effective bid-ask spread to measure the “true” transaction costs (see for example, Roll,
1984; George, Kaul and Nimalendran, 1991 and Bessembinder, 1999). The effective
spread is the difference between the transaction price and the bid-ask midpoint. The
proportional half effective spread is calculated as
where Pit is the transaction price for asset i on the last trading day of month t. The half
effective spread measures the cost of a one-way transaction. Following Lee and Ready
(1991), we classify a transaction as seller-initiated when the transaction price is less
than the bid-ask midpoint and as buyer-initiated when the transaction price is larger
than the bid-ask midpoint. A round-trip effective spread is calculated as the absolute
half effective spread for a buyer-initiated transaction plus the absolute half effective
spread for a seller-initiated transaction.
6
Commission charged by brokers is another major component of total transaction
costs. It is calculated as a percentage of the total value of the trade. Commission
normally increases but at a declining rate as the total value of the trade increases. We
compute commission for each stock based on the following commission charges
schedule, which was obtained from Barclays Stockbrokers 6 for company dealing
accounts: transaction value £0-£10,000, commission is 1.75% of trade value;
£10,001-£20,000: 1.125%; £20,001-£40,000: 0.5%; £40,001-£100,000: 0.4%;
£100,001+: 0.3%; (minimum £100). Stamp duty (payable on all UK equity purchases
at the rate of 0.5%) and short-selling costs are also included in the estimates of total
transaction costs. These are particularly important for momentum strategies since
many studies suggest that the momentum profits are mainly produced by the short
position.7 In accordance with the cost levied by Barclays Stockbrokers, we assume a
short-selling cost of 1.5% per year.
6
http://www.stockbrokers.barclays.co.uk/?category=whatweoffer&usecase=landing48
7
See for example Moskowitz and Grinblatt (1999), Hong, Lim and Stein (2000) and LSZ (2004).
7
sample to produce non-overlapped return series for the winner, loser and momentum
portfolios. The resulting momentum strategy taking a long position in the winner
portfolio and a short position in the loser portfolio is called the J-K strategy.
Table 1 presents monthly mean returns for the winner, loser and momentum
portfolios. The rows represent the ranking periods (J = 3, 6 and 12 months) and the
columns represent the holding periods (K = 3, 6 and 12 months). Without exception,
the winners significantly outperform the losers at the 1% level. Across strategies, the
momentum portfolios earn an average return of 1.9% per month, ranging from a low
of 1.62% for the 3-3 strategy to a high of 2.22% for the 12-3 strategy. Consistent with
Moskowitz and Grinblatt (1999), Hong, Lim and Stein (2000) and LSZ (2004), we
find that the momentum profits are mainly produced by the short positions. On
average, the losers generate a return of -1.58% per month and the winners yield a
return of 0.32% per month. The results also strongly reject the criticism that the
momentum effect is only produced by extremely small and illiquid stocks: these
stocks were excluded from our sample and yet the momentum strategies are still able
to generate sizable positive average returns.
In line with LSZ (2004), Table 1 also extends to the UK the evidence that the loser
portfolios are made of stocks with relatively smaller price, smaller size and lower
trading volume than the winner portfolios. Across the 9 strategies, the losers have an
average median share price of £1.20 and the winners have a median price of £2.13;
the losers have an average median market capitalisation of £59.17 million, while that
of the winners is £248.05 million; the losers have an average median trading volume
of 11.32 million and the winners of 20.13 million. Table 1 therefore suggests that
assuming symmetry of transaction costs between losers and winners would be
inaccurate because several US studies (Chan and Lakonishok, 1995, 1997;
Bessembinder and Kaufman, 1997; Keim and Madhavan, 1997) report market
capitalisation as one of the most important factors that affect transaction costs; other
things being equal, stocks with small capitalisation have high transaction costs.
8
3.2. Transaction Costs for Momentum Strategies
Implementing a momentum strategy requires fairly frequent trading as investors have
to buy winner stocks and short sell loser stocks at the end of the ranking period and
close out their long-short positions at the end of the holding period. Transaction costs
therefore become an important factor in assessing the profitability of momentum
strategies. Table 2 reports estimates of round-trip costs for the winner, loser and
momentum portfolios based on full turnover, which assumes that investors close out
the long-short portfolios entirely at the end of each holding period. A round-trip total
transaction costs estimate includes a round-trip quoted or effective spread,
commission, a 0.5% stamp duty for stock purchases and an annual 1.5% cost on short
selling. Table 2 shows that the average round-trip effective spread is 1.90% for the
winners and 3.72% for the losers. The average round-trip commission is 1.06% for the
winners and 1.58% for the losers. Once commissions, stamp duties and short selling
costs are added to the effective spreads, the average round-trip total transaction costs
rise to 3.46% for the winners and 6.67% for the losers.
A comparison of the costs between the winners and the losers in Table 2 suggests that
the estimates of the quoted spread, effective spread and commission associated with
the losers are systematically higher than those of the winners. Across the 9 strategies,
the average round-trip quoted spread and effective spread for the losers are 3.76% and
3.72% respectively, which are 71% and 96% higher than those of the winners (2.21%
and 1.90% respectively). When the stamp duty on purchases and the costs of short-
selling the losers are added, the average round-trip total trading costs based on quoted
spread across the 9 strategies is 6.71% for the losers versus 3.77% for the winners.
Based on effective spread, the losers (with an average round-trip total cost of 6.67%)
are on average 93% more expensive to trade than the winners (which cost 3.46% on
average per round-trip). In conclusion, the transaction costs of winners and losers are
asymmetric and total transaction costs for momentum strategies are much higher than
previously thought.8
8
Early studies on momentum strategies, such as Jegadeesh and Titman (1993), Rouwenhorst (1998),
Moskowitz and Grinblatt (1999) and Liu, Strong and Xu (1999), assume a round-trip cost of up to 2%
for both winners and losers.
9
In fact, some stocks with extreme performance are likely to stay in the same portfolios
from one holding period to the next. Accordingly, momentum traders do not need to
close out their entire positions at the end of each holding period. If stocks remain in
the winner or loser portfolios in the following period, transaction costs are not
actually incurred. Table 3 reports the proportions of winner (loser) stocks that have
remained in the winner (loser) portfolio in the following holding period. We find that
the 12-3 strategy has the highest proportion of positions retained, while the 6-12
strategy has the lowest proportion of positions retained. On average, 22.8% of the
winners and 28.2% of the losers remain in the same portfolio in the following period
across the 9 strategies, suggesting that momentum traders only need to close an
average 77.2% of their long positions and 71.1% of their short positions at the end of
each holding period.
Table 3 also reports estimates of the round-trip total trading costs based on actual
turnover, which assumes that momentum traders only close out their positions if
stocks no longer remain in the same portfolio in the following period. Relative to
Table 2, naturally, total transaction costs are considerably reduced when actual
turnover is taken into account. The decrease in transaction costs is particularly strong
for the strategies with high proportions of winner and loser stocks that are retained in
the same portfolio in the following holding period. For example, the round-trip total
trading costs of the 12-3 strategy based on quoted spread estimates drop from 9.6%
for full turnover in Table 2 to 4.14% for actual turnover in Table 3; similarly, the
average total trading costs based on effective spread estimates drop from 9.32% to
4.01%.
Table 4 reports monthly net momentum profits after controlling for total transaction
costs based on full and actual turnovers. We find that once total transaction costs are
taken into account, based on full turnover, momentum strategies with a 3-month
holding period even produce significantly negative average net returns at the 5%
level. The strategies with a 6-month holding period yield positive but insignificant
average net returns. Interestingly, the strategies with a 12-month holding period still
can generate positive and significant net profits at the 5% level. The average net
momentum return is 0.75% per month when total transaction costs are estimated by
10
quoted spread and is 0.78% per month when total transaction costs are measured by
effective spreads. These results are consistent with the finding of Agyei-Ampomah
(2007) that momentum profits net of transaction costs do exist for strategies with a
12-month holding period but disappear for strategies with 3- and 6-month holding
periods in the UK. The conclusion of LSZ (2004) ignores the fact that transaction
costs are lower for those strategies with longer horizons and high for those strategies
with shorter horizons and is consequently not supported for strategies with a 12-
month holding period in the UK. When we adopt a more practical measure of
transaction costs based on actual turnover, 6 out of 9 momentum strategies (the
exceptions are the 3-3, 3-6 and 6-3 strategies) yield positive and significant net returns
at the 5% level.
In this section, we attempt to add evidence to the literature on trading volume and
momentum strategies, and we examine the returns of the winner, loser and momentum
11
portfolios at different levels of trading volume. Following Lee and Swaminathan’s
(2000) approach, we first rank all stocks into decile portfolios based on their past
returns. We then further rank winner (the best past performance) and loser (the worst
past performance) stocks based on their trading volume at the end of the ranking
period, using 30-70 break points to classify winner and loser stocks into three sub-
portfolios with low, middle and high levels of trading volume.9
Table 5 presents monthly returns for the winner, loser and momentum portfolios at the
three levels of trading volume. The results show that, with only a few exceptions for
the winners (the 6-12, the 12-6 and the 12-12 winners), the high volume winners and
losers uniformly outperform the low volume winners and losers. On average, high
volume winners yield monthly returns of 0.36% and low volume winners earn
monthly returns of 0.2%; while the high and low volume losers generate monthly
returns of -1.46% and -2.26%, respectively. These appear to support the finding of
Gervais, Kaniel and Mingelgrin (2001) regarding the high volume return premium.
We also find that momentum strategies with low trading volume always earn higher
gross returns than strategies with high trading volume, with an average of 2.46% per
month for low volume strategies and 1.82% per month for high volume strategies.
These results indicate that momentum profits are mainly produced by short losers and
high momentum profits for low volume strategies are driven by high returns on short
selling low volume losers.
9
In common with Gervais et al. (2001), we define volume as the total number of shares traded during
the day.
12
transactions and we investigate the costs of purchases and sales for the winner, loser
and momentum portfolios at the three levels of trading volume.
A comparison of the costs between purchases and sales in Tables 6 and 7 shows that
the costs of seller-initiated transactions are much higher than those of buyer-initiated
transactions, particularly for losers, with an average cost of 2.68% for seller-initiated
transactions and 1.05% for buyer-initiated transactions across the three levels of
trading volume. For winners, it costs an average of 1.00% for seller-initiated
transactions and 0.81% for buyer-initiated transactions. Additionally, Tables 6 and 7
suggest that selling low volume loser stocks is the most expensive trading activity,
13
which costs 4.4 times as much as buying low volume loser stocks (0.75% for buying
low volume losers and 3.31% for selling low volume losers). Comparing the costs
between winners and losers, Tables 6 and 7 also show that the costs of buyer-initiated
transactions for losers are slightly higher than those for winners, with an average of
1.05% for losers and 0.81% for winners. But the costs of seller-initiated transactions
are very different between losers and winners, particularly for low volume stocks. On
average, selling low volume loser stocks costs almost 3 times as much as selling low
volume winners (1.12% for selling low volume winners and 3.31% for selling low
volume losers).
Net monthly returns for each of the winner, loser and momentum portfolios by trading
volume class are presented in Table 8. The returns are calculated based on an
assumption of full turnover, and are based on effective rather than quoted spreads.10
Evidently, transactions costs have reduced returns by around 1.2% per month
typically compared with the corresponding gross return figures in Table 5. It is also
clear, as was seen above, that transactions costs are of the order 0.3-0.4% per month
higher for the low volume portfolios than those in the highest volume tricile.
However, interestingly the reduction in costs as we move towards firms with more
liquidity is insufficient to offset the reduction in momentum profitability. As a result,
in net terms, low volume momentum portfolios are considerably more profitable for
any momentum strategies with holding periods of 6 months or longer. For example,
for formation and holding periods of 12 months, the highest and lowest volume tricile
net momentum returns are 0.19% and 1.77% respectively, with the majority of this
difference arising from the additional profits of the short position in the loser stocks.
10
When two-way sorts are performed by momentum and volume, the constituents of the extreme decile
portfolios are considerably less stable, so that the difference in costs between full and actual turnover is
minimal. Nonetheless our results concerning the net profitability of the strategies in Table 8 can be
considered conservative.
14
to the costs of selling winners and losers. Additionally, selling costs are much higher
than buying costs for both winners and losers. As a result, losers with low trading
volume are expensive to sell. Our results indicate that the relatively expensive
transaction costs of losers are mainly due to higher selling costs for illiquid stocks.
Yet short positions in low volume loser stocks generate such large profits that relative
strength portfolios constructed on the basis of low volume stocks are more profitable
than those based on high volume stocks, even after allowing for the higher trading
costs of the former.
5. Analysis of Results
It has been widely recognised that trading volume is mainly determined by liquidity
needs and information flows. Glosten and Harris (1988) have decomposed the bid/ask
spread into a transitory component (such as monopoly profit, clearing costs, inventory
carrying costs, etc.) and an adverse-selection component (due to private information).
They show that trading volume depends mainly on the spread due to the adverse-
selection component. Holthausen, Leftwich and Mayers (1987), Chan and Lakonishok
(1993) and Keim and Madhavan (1996) compare the price impact of large block
transactions between purchases and sales, and they find that the main impact on
trading volume is from the transitory component (a temporary price effect) for large
seller-initiated transactions, while for large buyer-initiated transactions, the main
impact on trading volume is from the adverse-selection component (a permanent price
effect). Their results therefore suggest that trading activities are elicited by different
motivations: large buyer-initiated transactions are more informationally-motivated
and large seller-initiated transactions are more liquidity-motivated.
The relationships between trading volume, transaction costs and information have also
been widely documented in the finance literature. Demsetz (1968), Karpoff (1986),
Glosten and Harris (1988), Admati and Pfleiderer (1988), Foster and Viswanathan
(1990), and Brennan and Subrahmanyam (1995) find a negative relationship between
trading volume and transaction costs, suggesting that high trading volume stocks are
cheaper to trade. Karpoff (1987), Holthausen and Verrecchia (1990), Kim and
Verrecchia (1991) and Bessembinder, Chan and Seguin (1996) report that trading
volume is positively related to a proxy for information flow, indicating that high
15
trading volume is a result of increasing information flows. However, George, Kaul
and Nimalendran (1994) argue that early studies modelling relationship between
trading volume and information flow ignore transaction-cost elasticity. They show
that including transaction costs, trading volume can be either positively or negatively
related to information flows.
Our results are in accordance with several explanations offered by previous studies.
The positive correlation between volume and the cost of buyer-initiated transactions
could be due to information flows. Since a large block purchase of a particular stock
conveys a message of good news, this drives up trading volume and widens spreads.
On the other hand, the negative correlation between volume and the cost of seller-
initiated transactions could be due to liquidity needs because a high level of trading
volume will provide some of this required liquidity and will therefore decrease
liquidity costs. Demsetz (1968) also documents that increased trading volume can
reduce waiting costs in liquid markets and leads to lower spreads. For example,
specialists can offer a narrower bid-ask spread to attract more orders for immediate
fulfillment; on the other hand, they can also decrease trading volume to reduce losses
by setting a wide spread. Alternatively, two behavioural explanations have been put
forward in the literature. Chan and Lakonishok (1993), and Keim and Madhavan
(1995) interpret the positive (negative) relationship between price impact and large
buyer-(seller-) transactions to possibly be a result that institutions following positive
(negative) feedback strategies, in which they buy stocks with rising prices and sell
stocks with falling prices. Chan and Lakonishok (1995) add another conjecture that
the price appreciation could be due to “herding” that arises when institutional
investors respond in common to good news.
6. Conclusions
This article examines the impact of transaction costs and trading volume on
momentum strategies in the UK. We find that losers have much higher transaction
costs than winners. On average, round-trip total transaction costs based on effective
spreads (including commissions, short selling costs and stamp duty) for losers are 1.9
times as much as that of winners (3.46% for winners and 6.67% for losers). Once total
transaction costs are taken into account, we find that based on full turnover,
16
momentum strategies with 12-month holding periods can still generate positive and
significant net profits at the 5% level, but strategies with 3- and 6-month holding
period cannot create significant profit opportunities. Based on actual turnover, 6 out
of 9 momentum strategies produce positive and significant net momentum profits at
the 5% level. This paper therefore questions the conclusion of LSZ (2004) and argues
that it may be specific to their data and the length of their portfolio formation and
holding periods.
We also investigate the relationship between trading volume, stock returns and
transaction costs. Our results show that high volume winners and losers produce
higher returns than low volume winners and losers. But a short position in low volume
losers generates much higher profits than a comparable position in high volume
losers, even in net terms. This leads to the interesting result that low volume
momentum strategies yield higher profits than high volume strategies. Furthermore,
we find the clear pattern that trading volume is positively related to the costs of buyer-
initiated transactions and is negatively related to the costs of seller-initiated
transactions, indicating that high volume stocks are expensive to buy and low volume
stocks are expensive to sell. These results are important for both the academic
literature and investors as they shed light on the ambiguous relationship between
trading volume and transaction costs in previous studies and provide valuable
information for investors to make their investment decisions. Momentum fund
managers who systematically exclude stocks with low trading volumes on the grounds
that they will be more expensive to trade may be losing out on potentially larger
profits, even after transactions costs. We also find that the costs of seller-initiated
transactions are much higher than the costs of buyer-initiated transactions for both
winners and losers, suggesting that the asymmetric costs between winners and losers
are dominated by selling costs.
17
References
Admati, A. R., and P. Pfleiderer, 1988, "A Theory of Intraday Patterns: Volume and
Price Variability," Review of Financial Studies 1, 3-40.
Agyei-Ampomah, S., 2007, "The Post-Cost Profitability of Momentum Trading
Strategies: Further Evidence from the UK," European Financial Management
13, 776-802.
Bessembinder, H., 1999, "Trade Execution Costs on NASDAQ and the NYSE: A
Post-Reform Comparison," Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 34,
387-407.
Bessembinder, H., K. Chan, and P. J. Seguin, 1996, "An Empirical Examination of
Information, Differences of Opinion, and Trading Activity," Journal of
Financial Economics 40, 105-134.
Bessembinder, H., and H. M. Kaufman, 1997, "A Comparison of Trade Execution
Costs for NYSE and NASDAQ-Listed Stocks," Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis 32, 287-310.
Blume, L., D. Easley, and M. O'Hara, 1994, "Market Statistics and Technical
Analysis: The Role of Volume," Journal of Finance 49, 153-181.
Brennan, M. J., T. Chordia, and A. Subrahmanyam, 1998, "Alternative Factor
Specifications, Security Characteristics, and the Cross-Section of Expected
Stock Returns," Journal of Financial Economics 49, 345-373.
Brennan, M. J., and A. Subrahmanyam, 1995, "Investment Analysis and Price
Formation in Securities Markets," Journal of Financial Economics 38, 361-
381.
Campbell, J. Y., S. J. Grossman, and J. Wang, 1993, "Trading Volume and Serial
Correlation in Stock Returns," Quarterly Journal of Economics 108, 905-939.
Chan, K., A. Hameed, and W. Tong, 2000, "Profitability of Momentum Strategies in
the International Equity Markets," Journal of Financial and Quantitative
Analysis 35, 153-172.
Chan, L. K. C., N. Jegadeesh, and J. Lakonishok, 1996, "Momentum Strategies,"
Journal of Finance 51, 1681-1713.
Chan, L. K. C., and J. Lakonishok, 1993, "Institutional Trades and Intraday Stock
Price Behavior," Journal of Financial Economics 33, 173-199.
—, 1995, "The Behavior of Stock Prices around Institutional Trades," Journal of
Finance 50, 1147-1174.
—, 1997, "Institutional Equity Trading Costs: NYSE versus Nasdaq," Journal of
Finance 52, 713-735.
Chordia, T., R. Roll, and A. Subrahmanyam, 2000, "Commonality in Liquidity,"
Journal of Financial Economics 56, 3-28.
—, 2001, "Market Liquidity and Trading Activity," Journal of Finance 56, 501-530.
Conrad, J. S., A. Hameed, and C. Niden, 1994, "Volume and Autocovariances in
Short-Horizon Individual Security Returns," Journal of Finance 49, 1305-
1329.
Datar, V. T., N. Y. Naik, and R. Radcliffe, 1998, "Liquidity and Stock Returns: An
Alternative Test," Journal of Financial Markets 1, 203-219.
Demsetz, H., 1968, "The Cost of Transacting," Quarterly Journal of Economics 82,
33-53.
18
Foster, D., and S. Viswanathan, 1990, "A Theory of the Interday Variations in
Volume, Variance, and Trading Costs in Securities Markets," Review of
Financial Studies 3, 593-624.
—, 1993, "Variations in Trading Volume, Return Volatility, and Trading Costs:
Evidence on Recent Price Formation Models," Journal of Finance 48, 187-
211.
George, T. J., G. Kaul, and M. Nimalendran, 1991, "Estimation of the Bid-Ask
Spread and its Components: A New Approach," Review of Financial Studies
4, 623-656.
—, 1994, "Trading Volume and Transaction Costs in Specialist Markets," Journal of
Finance 49, 1489-1505.
Gervais, S., R. Kaniel, and D. H. Mingelgrin, 2001, "The High-Volume Return
Premium," Journal of Finance 56, 877-919.
Glosten, L. R., and L. E. Harris, 1988, "Estimating the Components of the Bid/ask
Spread," Journal of Financial Economics 21, 123-142.
Griffin, J. M., X. Ji, and J. S. Martin, 2003, "Momentum Investing and Business
Cycle Risk: Evidence from Pole to Pole," Journal of Finance 58, 2515-2547.
Grundy, B. D., and J. S. Martin, 2001, "Understanding the Nature of the Risks and the
Source of the Rewards to Momentum Investing," Review of Financial Studies
14, 29-78.
Hanna, J. D., and M. J. Ready, 2005, "Profitable Predictability in the Cross Section of
Stock Returns," Journal of Financial Economics 78, 463-505.
Holthausen, R. W., R. W. Leftwich, and D. Mayers, 1987, "The Effect of Large Block
Transactions on Security Prices," Journal of Financial Economics 19, 237-
267.
Holthausen, R. W., and R. E. Verrecchia, 1990, "The Effect of Informedness and
Consensus on Price and Volume Behavior," The Accounting Review 65, 191-
208.
Hong, H., T. Lim, and J. C. Stein, 2000, "Bad News Travels Slowly: Size, Analyst
Coverage, and the Profitability of Momentum Strategies," Journal of Finance
55, 265-295.
Huang, R., and H. R. Stoll, 1997, "The Components of the Bid-Ask Spread: A
General Approach," Review of Financial Studies 10, 995-1034.
Jegadeesh, N., and S. Titman, 1993, "Returns to Buying Winners and Selling Losers:
Implications for Stock Market Efficiency," Journal of Finance 48, 65-91.
—, 2001, "Profitability of Momentum Strategies: An Evaluation of Alternative
Explanations," Journal of Finance 56, 699-720.
Johnson, T. C., 2008, "Volume, Liquidity, and Liquidity Risk," Journal of Financial
Economics 87, 388-417.
Karpoff, J. M., 1986, "A Theory of Trading Volume," Journal of Finance 41, 1069-
1087.
—, 1987, "The Relation between Price Changes and Trading Volume," Journal of
Financial and Quantitative Analysis 22, 109-126.
Keim, D. B., and A. Madhavan, 1995, "Anatomy of the Trading Process Empirical
Evidence on the Behavior of Institutional Traders," Journal of Financial
Economics 37, 371-398.
—, 1996, "The Upstairs Market for Large-Block Transactions: Analysis and
Measurement of Price Effect," Review of Financial Studies 9, 1-36.
19
—, 1997, "Transaction Costs and Investment Style: An Inter-exchange Analysis of
Institutional Equity Trades," Journal of Financial Economics 46, 265-292.
Kim, O., and R. E. Verrecchia, 1991, "Trading Volume and Price Reactions to Public
Announcements," Journal of Accounting Research 29, 302-321.
Korajczyk, R. A., and R. Sadka, 2004, "Are Momentum Profits Robust to Trading
Costs?" Journal of Finance 59, 1039-1082.
Kraus, A., and H. Stoll, 1972, "Prices Impacts of Block Trading on the New York
Stock Exchange," Journal of Finance 27, 569-588.
Lee, C. M. C., and M. J. Ready, 1991, "Inferring Trade Direction from Intraday
Data," Journal of Finance 46, 733-746.
Lee, C. M. C., and B. Swaminathan, 2000, "Price Momentum and Trading Volume,"
Journal of Finance 55, 2017-2069.
Lesmond, D. A., M. J. Schill, and C. Zhou, 2004, "The Illusory Nature of Momentum
Profits," Journal of Financial Economics 71, 349-380.
Li, X., C. Brooks, and J. Miffre (2009) "Low-Cost Momentum Strategies" Journal of
Asset Management 9(6), 366-379
Li, X., J. Miffre, C. Brooks, and N. O. Sullivan, 2008, "Momentum Profits and Time-
Varying Unsystematic Risk," Journal of Banking and Finance 32, 541-558.
Liu, W., N. Strong, and X. Xu, 1999, "The Profitability of Momentum Investing,"
Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 26, 1043-1091.
Moskowitz, T. J., and M. Grinblatt, 1999, "Do Industries Explain Momentum?"
Journal of Finance 54, 1249-1290.
Roll, R., 1984, "A Simple Implicit Measure of the Effective Bid-Ask Spread in an
Efficient Market," Journal of Finance 39, 1127-1139.
Rouwenhorst, K. G., 1998, "International Momentum Strategies," Journal of Finance
53, 267-284.
20
Table 1 – Monthly Momentum Returns and Characteristics of Winner and Loser Portfolios
Winner and loser are equally-weighted non-overlapping portfolios containing the 10% of stocks that performed the best and worst over a given
ranking period respectively. Momentum is a portfolio that buys winners and short sells losers. Mean return is the monthly average return of the
portfolio expressed in %. Price (£) is the average share price of the constituents of the portfolio estimated at the end of the ranking period. MV (£
millions) is the average market capitalisation (share price multiplied by number of ordinary shares) at the end of the ranking period. Volume
(millions) is the average trading volume (number of shares traded) at the end of the ranking period. t-statistics are in parentheses.
Holding period of 3 months Holding period of 6 months Holding period of 12 months
21
Table 2 – Estimates of Transactions Costs Based on Full Turnover
The table reports estimates of round-trip transaction costs (%) for winner and loser portfolios based on full turnover. Transaction costs are
measured at the end of ranking period. The estimates of total transaction costs based on quoted spread (%) equal a round-trip quoted spread plus
a round-trip commission, stamp duty on purchases (0.5% per purchase) and short selling costs for losers (1.5% per year). The estimates of total
transaction costs based on effective spread (%) equal a round-trip effective spread plus a round-trip commission, stamp duty on purchases and
short selling costs for losers.
Holding period of 3 months Holding period of 6 months Holding period of 12 months
22
Table 3 – Estimates of Transactions Costs Based on Actual Turnover
The table reports estimates of round-trip total transaction costs (%) for winner and loser portfolios based on actual turnover. Transaction costs
are measured at the end of ranking period. “Portfolio position retained” is the mean ratio of winners and losers that remain in the respective
portfolios in the following period. The estimates of total transaction costs based on quoted spread (%) equal a round-trip quoted spread plus a
round-trip commission, stamp duty on purchases (0.5% per purchase) and short selling costs for losers (1.5% per year). The estimates of total
transaction costs based on effective spread (%) equal a round-trip effective spread plus a round-trip commission, stamp duty on purchases and
short selling costs for losers.
Holding period of 3 months Holding period of 6 months Holding period of 12 months
Winner Loser Momentum Winner Loser Momentum Winner Loser Momentum
23
Table 4 – Monthly Net Returns on Momentum Strategies
The table reports monthly net returns (%) on momentum strategies based on full and
actual turnovers. The estimates of total transactions costs based on quoted spread (%)
equal a round-trip quoted spread plus a round-trip commission, stamp duty on
purchases (0.5% per purchase) and short selling costs for losers (1.5% per year). The
estimates of total transaction costs based on effective spread (%) equal a round-trip
effective spread plus commission, stamp duty on purchases and short selling costs for
losers. The monthly net momentum returns are calculated as monthly momentum row
returns minus monthly total transaction costs. t-statistics are in parentheses.
24
Table 5 – Gross Monthly Returns for Winner, Loser and Momentum Portfolios Based on Trading Volume Classes
The table reports monthly returns for winner, loser and momentum portfolios at three levels of trading volume. Winner and loser portfolios are
first constructed to contain the 10% of all stocks that performed the best and worst over a given ranking period. Momentum is a portfolio that
buys the winner portfolio and short sells the loser portfolio. Then, winner and loser stocks are further classified into three sub-portfolios based
on their trading volume at the end of ranking period. Low represents portfolios comprising winner and loser stocks in the bottom 30% by trading
volume; Middle represents portfolios comprising winner and loser stocks in the middle 40% by trading volume; High represents portfolios
comprising winner and loser stocks in the top 30% by trading volume. t-statistics are in parentheses.
25
Table 6 – One-Way Effective Spreads for Buyer-Initiated Transactions Based on Trading Volume Classes
The table reports estimates of the half effective spread (%) for buying winners and losers based on trading volume classes. Trades are defined as
buyer-initiated when the transaction price is larger than the bid-ask midpoint. Winner and loser portfolios are first constructed to contain the
10% of all stocks that performed the best and worst respectively over a given ranking period. Momentum is a portfolio that buys the winner
portfolio and short sells the loser portfolio. Then, winner and loser stocks are further classified into three sub-portfolios based on their trading
volume. Low represents portfolios comprising winner and loser stocks in the bottom 30% by trading volume; Middle represents portfolios
comprising winner and loser stocks in the middle 40% by trading volume; High represents portfolios comprising winner and loser stocks in the
top 30% by trading volume.
26
Table 7 – One-Way Effective Spread for Seller-Initiated Transactions Based on Trading Volume Classes
The table reports estimates of the half effective spread (%) of selling winners and losers based on trading volume classes. Trades are defined as
seller-initiated when the transaction price is smaller than the bid-ask midpoint. Winner and loser portfolios are first constructed to contain the
10% of all stocks that performed the best and worst respectively over a given ranking period. Momentum is a portfolio that buys the winner
portfolio and short sells the loser portfolio. Then, winner and loser stocks are further classified into three sub-portfolios based on their trading
volume. Low represents portfolios comprising winner and loser stocks in the bottom 30% by trading volume; Middle represents portfolios
comprising winner and loser stocks in the middle 40% by trading volume; High represents portfolios comprising winner and loser stocks in the
top 30% by trading volume.
27
Table 8 – Net Monthly Returns for Winner, Loser and Momentum Portfolios Based on Trading Volume Classes
The table reports the net monthly returns after total trading costs based on effective spreads and full turnover for winner, loser and momentum
portfolios at three levels of trading volume. Winner and loser portfolios are first constructed to contain the 10% of all stocks that performed the
best and worst over a given ranking period. Momentum is a portfolio that buys the winner portfolio and short sells the loser portfolio. Then,
winner and loser stocks are further classified into three sub-portfolios based on their trading volume at the end of ranking period. Low represents
portfolios comprising winner and loser stocks in the bottom 30% by trading volume; Middle represents portfolios comprising winner and loser
stocks in the middle 40% by trading volume; High represents portfolios comprising winner and loser stocks in the top 30% by trading volume. t-
statistics are in parentheses.
H o ld in g p e rio d o f 3 m o n th s H o ld in g p e rio d o f 6 m o n th s H o ld in g p e rio d o f 1 2 m o n th s
W in n e r Loser M o m e n tu m W in n e r Loser M o m e n tu m W in n e r Loser M o m e n tu m
P a n e l A : R a n k in g p e r io d o f 3 m o n th s
Low -1 .5 7 - 4 .7 3 -2 .0 2 -0 .8 1 - 3 .6 0 0 .0 4 -1 .1 2 - 3 .1 2 0 .5 0
(-4 .1 2 ) (- 1 0 .9 5 ) (-5 .6 4 ) (-1 .8 0 ) (-7 .0 8 ) (0 .0 9 ) (-1 .8 8 ) (- 4 .9 7 ) (0 .8 6 )
M id d le -0 .8 6 - 3 .6 1 -1 .4 2 0 .0 9 - 2 .5 3 0 .3 7 0 .2 0 - 2 .3 1 1 .2 1
(-2 .3 0 ) (- 7 .3 4 ) (-3 .5 8 ) ( 0 .2 2 ) (-4 .6 5 ) (0 .8 5 ) ( 0 .3 5 ) (- 3 .7 0 ) (2 .2 5 )
H ig h -0 .7 6 - 3 .1 0 -1 .2 5 -0 .0 1 - 2 .3 6 0 .4 7 -0 .2 5 - 1 .9 7 0 .6 9
(-2 .1 5 ) (- 6 .0 2 ) (-2 .8 8 ) (-0 .0 3 ) (-4 .0 1 ) (0 .9 4 ) (-0 .4 2 ) (- 2 .9 4 ) (1 .0 9 )
P a n e l B : R a n k in g p e rio d o f 6 m o n th s
Low -0 .9 6 - 5 .0 3 -1 .4 1 -0 .3 9 - 3 .5 7 0 .1 5 -0 .3 9 - 3 .2 7 1 .2 4
(-2 .7 3 ) (- 1 1 .4 8 ) (-3 .5 5 ) (-0 .9 7 ) (-6 .9 0 ) (0 .3 3 ) (-0 .7 2 ) (- 5 .5 6 ) (2 .2 8 )
M id d le -0 .3 4 - 3 .6 2 -0 .9 1 0 .2 3 - 2 .6 7 0 .6 0 -0 .0 9 - 2 .0 0 0 .6 4
(-0 .9 2 ) (- 7 .3 9 ) (-2 .2 4 ) ( 0 .5 7 ) (-4 .8 1 ) (1 .3 3 ) (-0 .1 7 ) (- 3 .1 1 ) (1 .2 1 )
H ig h -0 .2 2 - 3 .5 7 -0 .3 1 0 .2 6 - 2 .7 4 0 .9 9 -0 .4 6 - 1 .7 6 0 .1 7
(-0 .6 2 ) (- 6 .8 5 ) (-0 .6 9 ) ( 0 .6 1 ) (-4 .6 6 ) (1 .9 1 ) (-0 .8 2 ) (- 2 .6 1 ) (0 .2 7 )
P a n e l C : R a n k in g p e rio d o f 1 2 m o n th s
Low -0 .7 6 - 4 .8 8 -1 .2 6 -0 .1 0 - 3 .6 5 0 .6 8 0 .1 4 - 3 .2 2 1 .7 7
(-2 .2 8 ) (- 1 0 .9 8 ) (-3 .3 9 ) (-0 .2 5 ) (-7 .3 9 ) (1 .6 3 ) ( 0 .2 8 ) (- 5 .0 2 ) (3 .1 6 )
M id d le 0 .1 3 - 3 .6 4 -0 .4 4 0 .3 8 - 2 .6 7 0 .7 5 0 .1 0 - 2 .1 5 1 .0 0
( 0 .3 8 ) (- 7 .9 2 ) (-1 .3 0 ) ( 0 .9 3 ) (-5 .2 7 ) (2 .0 5 ) ( 0 .2 0 ) (- 3 .3 5 ) (2 .0 7 )
H ig h -0 .2 0 - 3 .2 5 -0 .5 8 -0 .0 5 - 2 .5 2 0 .4 9 -0 .5 3 - 1 .9 5 0 .1 9
(-0 .5 5 ) (- 6 .3 8 ) (-1 .3 2 ) (-0 .1 3 ) (-4 .2 6 ) (1 .0 0 ) (-1 .2 5 ) (- 2 .9 2 ) (0 .3 2 )
28