European Contract Law
European Contract Law
European Contract Law
Series Editor
Elspeth Reid (University of Edinburgh)
Editorial Board
David L Carey Miller (University of Aberdeen)
George Gretton (University of Edinburgh)
Sir Neil MacCormick (University of Edinburgh)
Hector L MacQueen (University of Edinburgh)
Kenneth G C Reid (University of Edinburgh)
Reinhard Zimmermann (Max-Planck-Institute of Comparative Private Law
and Private International Law, Hamburg)
A CIP record for this book is available from the British Library
Preface vii
List of Contributors xii
List of Abbreviations xiii
This volume set out initially to test the claim that, as combinations of Civil
and Common Law influences, the mixed systems of contract law in Scotland
and South Africa have in some sense anticipated the content of the Principles
of European Contract Law (PECL) concluded and published in 2003 by the
unofficial Commission on European Contract Law presided over by Professor
Ole Lando (Copenhagen). In a way, therefore, the volume was supposed to
build on the foundations laid by a trilogy of historical and comparative studies
on Scots and South African law, culminating in a volume affectionately
dubbed Double Cross, but in reality entitled Mixed Legal Systems in Com-
parative Perspective: Property and Obligations in Scotland and South Africa
(2004). At the Edinburgh conference where the papers were first presented
in December 2004, however, it became clear that the studies could and
should go much further. For example, how far might the Scots and South
African contract laws benefit from reform along the lines proposed by
PECL? And given that PECL appeared likely to become the basis for some
sort of European contract law (see further below), what criticisms might be
made of it in the light of experiences made in Scotland and South Africa? Nor
is PECL the only possible model for a European – or indeed global – contract
law. Account has also to be taken of such projects as the (also unofficial) Code
of Contract Law prepared by the Academy of European Law under the
leadership of Professor Giuseppe Gandolfi (Pavia) and of the Principles of
International Commercial Contracts (PICC) first published by UNIDROIT
in 1994 and issued in a second edition in 2004.
The development and nature of PECL and the other instruments just
mentioned are set out in Reinhard Zimmermann’s opening paper, and
therefore need not be further explained here. But it may also be helpful to
readers to know something of the current official moves towards a European
contract law within the European Union, which lend the critiques of PECL
viii preface
contract law. The CFR was seen as a toolbox towards improvement of the
quality and coherence of the acquis and future legislation, as well as its
simplification. “The CFR will provide clear definitions of legal terms,
fundamental principles and coherent model rules of contract law, drawing on
the EC acquis and on best solutions found in Member States’ legal orders”
(para 2.1.1). It would, however, be a non-binding instrument, although the
Commission reserved the right to consult again on this question when elabor-
ating the CFR. The promotion of EU-wide standard terms and conditions is
to be taken forward via a website which would be a platform for the exchange
of information on such terms and conditions. Further, and in parallel with the
development of the CFR, the Commission would continue to investigate the
opportuneness of a non-sectoral-specific optional instrument on European
contract law. The Commission said:
Although it is premature to speculate about the possible outcome of the reflection,
it is important to explain that it is neither the Commission’s intention to propose a
“European civil code” which would harmonise contract laws of Member States,
nor should the reflections be seen as in any way calling into question the current
approaches to promoting free circulation on the basis of flexible and efficient
solutions (para 2.3).
The Commission has now (June 2005) contracted with a number of groups
under the Sixth Framework programme to carry out the research needed for
the preparation and elaboration of the CFR by 2007. The groups involved, to be
known collectively as the CoPECL-Network of Excellence, are the following:
2 See http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/ld200405/ldselect/ldeucom/95/9502.htm#evidence.
3 Accessible at http://www.cliffordchance.com/expertise/publications/details.aspx?FilterName=
@URL&contentitemid=8354).
4 See, e.g., H Muir Watt, “European integration, legal diversity and the conflict of laws” (2005) 9
Edinburgh LR 6; J Smits (ed), The Need for a European Contract Law: Empirical and Legal
Perspectives (2005).
preface xi
Part I: Books
Bankton, Institute
Andrew McDouall, Lord Bankton, An Institute of the Laws of Scotland in
Civil Rights (1751–53), reprinted by the Stair Society, vols 41–43 (1993–95)
Bell, Commentaries
George Joseph Bell, Commentaries on the Law of Scotland and the Principles
of Mercantile Jurisprudence, 7th edn by J McLaren (1870; reprinted 1990)
Bell, Principles
George Joseph Bell, Principles of the Law of Scotland, 10th edn by W
Guthrie (1899, reprinted 1989)
Brownsword et al, Good Faith
R Brownsword, N J Hird and G Howells (eds), Good Faith in Contract:
Concept and Context (1999)
Busch et al, PECL and Dutch Law
D Busch, E Hondius, H van Kooten, H Schelhaas and W Schrama (eds),
Principles of European Contract Law and Dutch Law – A Commentary
(2002)
Christie, Contract
R H Christie, The Law of Contract in South Africa, 4th edn (2001)
De Wet & Van Wyk, Kontraktereg
J C de Wet and A H van Wyk, Kontraktereg en Handelsreg, 5th edn by A H
van Wyk and G F Lubbe, 1992)
Erskine
John Erskine of Carnock, An Institute of the Law of Scotland, 8th edn by J B
Nicholson (1871, reprinted 1989)
xiv list of abbreviations
Walker, Contract
D M Walker, The Law of Contracts and Related Obligations in Scotland, 3rd
edn (1995)
Zimmermann, Comparative Foundations
Reinhard Zimmermann, Comparative Foundations of Set-off and
Prescription (2002)
Zimmermann, Obligations
Reinhard Zimmermann, The Law of Obligations: Roman Foundations of the
Civilian Tradition (1990; paperback edition, 1996)
Zimmermann, Roman Law
Reinhard Zimmermann, Roman Law, Contemporary Law, European Law:
The Civilian Tradition Today (2001)
Zimmermann & Visser, Southern Cross
Reinhard Zimmermann and Daniel Visser (eds), Southern Cross: Civil Law
and Common Law in South Africa (1996)
Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems
Reinhard Zimmermann, Daniel Visser and Kenneth Reid (eds), Mixed Legal
Systems in Comparative Perspective: Property and Obligations in Scotland
and South Africa (2004)
Zimmermann & Whittaker, Good Faith
Reinhard Zimmermann and Simon Whittaker (eds), Good Faith in European
Contract Law (2000)
Zweigert & Kötz, Comparative Law
K. Zweigert and H. Kötz, Introduction to Comparative Law, 3rd edn, transl T
Weir (1998)
LJ Lord Justice
LJC Lord Justice Clerk
LJCP Law Journal Reports, New Series, Common Pleas
LJEx Law Journal Reports, Exchequer
Lloyd’s Rep Lloyd’s Law Reports
LMCLQ Lloyd’s Maritime and Commercial Law Quarterly
LQR Law Quarterly Review
LR CP Law Reports, Common Pleas
LR QB Law Reports, Queen’s Bench
LT Law Times Reports
M Macpherson’s Session Cases
Macq Macqueen’s House of Lords Reports
McGill LJ McGill Law Journal
Memo Memorandum
Menz Menzies Reports, Cape Supreme Court
Mer Merivale’s Reports, Chancery
Michigan LR Michigan Law Review
Mo Missouri Supreme Court Reports
Mo App Missouri Appeal Reports
Modern LR Modern Law Review
Mor Morison’s Dictionary of Decisions, Court of Session
MR Master of the Rolls
N Natal Provincial Division
NC Northern Cape Division
NJ Nederlandse Jurisprudentie
NLR Natal Law Reports
NO nomine officii
NPD South African Law Reports, Natal Provincial Division
NY New York Reports
NZLR New Zealand Law Reports
O Orange Free State Provincial Division
OH Outer House
OJ Official Journal of the European Communities
Ont HCJ High Court of Justice, Ontario
OPD South African Law Reports, Orange Free State Provincial
Division
OR Obligationenrecht (Switzerland)
OR (2d) Ontario Reports, Second Series (Canada) 1974–1991
Oxford JLS Oxford Journal of Legal Studies
list of abbreviations xxi
A. INTRODUCTION
B. THE PRINCIPLES OF EUROPEAN CONTRACT LAW
(1) Scope and origin
(2) Essential characteristics
(3) Style and structure of publication
(4) Rules or principles?
(5) The Unidroit Principles
C. THE OLD IUS COMMUNE
(1) A European legal tradition
(2) Ius commune and codification
D. THE PRINCIPLES AS A CONTEMPORARY MANIFESTATION OF
THE EUROPEAN LEGAL TRADITION
(1) Common core
(a) Elements of contract law
(b) Variations of a theme
(c) Regulae iuris
(d) Good faith
(2) Convergence and tradition
(a) Stipulatio alteri
(b) Direct representation
* This is the text on which my opening lecture of the conference “Principles of European Contract
Law: Another Mixed Legal System” on 2 Dec 2004 in Edinburgh was based. The manuscript, in
turn, is based on an essay on the Principles of European Contract Law which is to be published,
in late 2005, as part of a volume in honour of Hein Kötz. A German version has appeared in Dirk
Heirbaut, Georges Martyn (eds), Napoleons nalatenschap: Tweehonderd jaar Burgerlijk Wetboek
in Belgie (2005), pp. 377 ff.
1
2 european contract law
A. INTRODUCTION
This paper will focus on a key document within the process of the Euro-
peanisation of private law legal scholarship, the Principles of European
Contract Law. I would like to demonstrate that these Principles can be seen
as a contemporary manifestation of a genuinely European tradition – a
tradition which used to be labelled ius commune. And I would like to argue
that they can serve as a catalyst for a Europeanisation of private law “from
within” and “from below” (as opposed to European legal unification by
means of legislation, i.e. unification “from outside” and “from above”). In a
way, therefore, the Principles mark the contours of a new European ius com-
mune and can fulfil a function resembling that of its historical predecessor.
Before these arguments can be developed a few words have to be said about
the Principles of European Contract Law and about the old ius commune. It
IUS COMMUNE and pecl 3
should also be noted, at the outset, that this paper does not deal with private
law in general but merely with one of its constituent elements: the law of
contract. One reason for this is immediately obvious: the Principles of
European Contract Law constitute the most advanced and internationally
most widely noted academic project aiming at the Europeanisation of private
law.1 Similar sets of Principles for other areas of the law are only just
2
beginning to be published. This is hardly accidental. For, on the one hand,
the law relating to commercial contracts has often tended to be the pace-
3
maker for legal harmonisation. On the other hand, most of the basic concepts
and evaluations informing the law of contract have not been deeply affected
by legal developments under the auspices of the age of legal nationalism. The
differences between the national legal systems are largely on the level of
4 5
technical detail. In other areas of private law, the situation is more complex.
6 O Lando & H Beale (eds), Principles of European Contract Law, Parts I and II (2000); O Lando,
E Clive, A Prüm & R Zimmermann (eds), Principles of European Contract Law, Part III (2003)
(PECL).
7 See the list in PECL, Part III, xiii–xiv.
8 This way of proceeding has left its traces in the Principles. Thus, for instance, they contain three
different regimes concerning the restitution of benefits after failure of contracts; see
R Zimmermann, “Restitutio in integrum: Die Rückabwicklung fehlgeschlagener Verträge nach
den Principles of European Contract Law, den Unidroit Principles und dem Avant-projet eines
Code Européen des Contrats”, in Festschrift für Ernst A Kramer (2004), 735 ff.
9 PECL, Part I (1995).
10 Lando & Beale (note 6).
11 Lando et al (note 6).
IUS COMMUNE and pecl 5
12 Code Européen des Contrats, edited on behalf on the Accademia dei Giusprivatisti by G Gandolfi
(2000); on which see H J Sonnenberger, “Der Entwurf eines Europäischen Vertragsgesetzbuchs
der Akademie Europäischer Privatrechtswissenschaftler – ein Meilenstein” (2001) Recht der
internationalen Wirtschaft 409; F Sturm, “Der Entwurf eines Europäischen Vertragsgesetz-
buchs” (2001) Juristenzeitung 1097; R Zimmermann, “Der ‘Codice Gandolfi’ als Modell eines
einheitlichen Vertragsrechts für Europa?”, in Festschrift für Erik Jayme (2004), 1401 ff.
13 See, e.g., for the law relating to breach of contract, C Resch, Das italienische Privatrecht im
Spannungsfeld von Code Civil und BGB (2001).
14 H McGregor, Contract Code drawn up on behalf of the English Law Commission (1993)
(published by Giuffré, Milano).
6 european contract law
base their work on any individual national legal system. Their approach was
more comparative in nature. They have attempted, as far as possible, to
identify the common core of the contract law of all the EU member states
and to create a workable system on that basis. Thus, in a way, they aimed at a
restatement of European contract law.15 At the same time, however, they
realised that they were confronted with a more creative task than the
draftsmen of the American Restatements. Divergences had to be resolved on
the basis of a comparative evaluation of the experiences gathered in the
national legal systems, by assessing and analysing European and international
trends of legal development, or by employing other rational criteria.
16 Rules, in the terminology widely used in methodological writing, set out legal consequences that
follow when their conditions have been met. Principles are general standards that are to be
observed because it is just, or fair, to do so. A principle does not necessitate a particular decision,
a rule does. Principles have a relative weight which has to be taken into account when they
intersect; one rule, on the other hand, cannot supersede another by virtue of its greater relative
weight; see, R Dworkin, Taking Rights Seriously (1977), 22.
17 Lando & Beale (note 6), xxiii.
18 Unidroit Principles of International Contracts (1994); on which see M J Bonell, An International
Restatement of Contract Law, 2nd edn (1997); E A Kramer, “Die Gültigkeit der Verträge nach
den Principles of International Commercial Contracts” (1999) 7 ZEuP 209; J Basedow, “Die
Unidroit-Prinzipien der internationalen Handelsverträge und das deutsche Recht”, in
Gedächtnisschrift für Alexander Lüderitz (2000), 1.
19 On the aims pursued by the Principles of European Contract Law, see Lando & Beale (note 6), xxi.
8 european contract law
proposed by both sets of Principles do not very much differ from each other;
in a number of areas they are virtually identical.20 The dominance of
European legal thinking even outside Europe may provide an explanation, as
far as the first of the points mentioned above is concerned. As for (ii) it may
perhaps be said that what is regarded as fair and reasonable for commercial
contracts can very largely also be regarded as fair and reasonable for consumer
contracts and vice versa. This confirms an observation on the development of
modern sales law: the provisions in the Consumer Sales Directive 1999/44/
21
EC, particularly those concerning the concept of conformity and the reme-
dies in case of non-conformity, very largely mirror the rules contained in the
UN Convention on the International Sale of Goods, even though the latter
22
instrument specifically excludes consumer sales from its range of application.
The correspondence between these two international instruments will
significantly contribute to the emergence of a common framework of
23
reference for the discussion and development of the law of sale in Europe.
The same can be said, on the basis of a comparison between the Unidroit- and
the Lando-Principles, for many central areas of the general law of contract.
20 See, for the topics dealt with in Part I of the PECL, R Zimmermann, “Konturen eines Euro-
päischen Vertragsrechts” (1995) Juristenzeitung 477; generally, see A Hartkamp, “Principles of
Contract Law”, in A Hartkamp & M Hesselink et al (eds), Towards a European Civil Code,
3rd edn (2004) (henceforth Hartkamp & Hesselink, Towards a European Civil Code), 125 ff.
21 Easily accessible now in O Radley-Gardner, H Beale, R Zimmermann & R Schulze (eds), Funda-
mental Texts on European Private Law (2003) (henceforth Radley-Gardner et al, Fundamental
Texts), 107.
22 Article 2 a) CISG. See S Grundmann, in M C Bianca & S Grundmann (eds), EU Sales Directive:
Commentary (2002) (henceforth Bianca & Grundmann, EU Sales Directive), Introduction, nn 6,
22 ff.
23 See, most recently, the Principles of European Sales Law, the first contours of which are pre-
sented by V Heutger, “Konturen des Kaufrechtskonzeptes der Study Group on a European Civil
Code – Ein Werkstattbericht” (2003) 11 ERPL 155.
24 On which see H J Berman, Law and Revolution: The Formation of the Western Legal Tradition
(1983); E Cortese, Il Rinascimento giuridico mediavale (1992); generally on the ius commune see
H Coing, Die ursprüngliche Einheit der europäischen Rechtswissenschaft (1968) (henceforth
Coing, Einheit); H Coing, Europäische Grundlagen des modernen Privatrechts (1986); M Bellomo,
The Common Legal Past of Europe 1000–1800 (1995), 55; R C van Caenegem, European Law in
the Past and the Future (2002), 13 ff, 24 ff.
IUS COMMUNE and pecl 9
25 The standard account is by F Wieacker, Privatrechtsgeschichte der Neuzeit, 2nd edn (1967), 45 ff,
97 ff (trans by T Weir, A History of Private Law in Europe (1995)). For the significance of Roman
law for European legal culture, see P Koschaker, Europa und das römische Recht, 4th edn (1966);
R Zimmermann, “Europa und das römische Recht” (2002) 202 Archiv für die civilistische Praxis
243 ff. For an analysis of early modern German court practice, see P Oestmann, Rechtsvielfalt vor
Gericht (2002).
26 This is the point of departure for H Coing’s opus magnum, Europäisches Privatrecht, vol I (1985).
27 See, specifically for Roman-Dutch law, R Zimmermann, “Roman-Dutch Jurisprudence and its
Contribution to European Private Law” (1992) 66 Tulane LR 1715; generally, see Coing, Einheit
(note 24), 160 ff.
10 european contract law
28 R Zimmermann, Roman Law, Contemporary Law, European Law: The Civilian Tradition Today
(2001) (henceforth Zimmermann, Roman Law), 158 ff.
29 See F C von Savigny, System des heutigen Römischen Rechts, eight vols (1840–1849); S Stryk,
Specimen usus moderni pandectarum (first published between 1690 and 1712).
30 The theme is developed more fully in R Zimmermann, “The Civil Law in European Codes”, in
D L Carey Miller & R Zimmermann (eds), The Civilian Tradition and Scots Law: Aberdeen
Quincentenary Essays (1997), 259 ff; and see, most recently, van Caenegem (note 24), passim
(the subtitle of his book is, characteristically, Unity and Diversity over Two Millennia).
31 See, e.g., R Knütel, “Römisches Recht und deutsches Bürgerliches Recht”, in W Ludwig (ed),
Die Antike in der europäischen Gegenwart (1993), 43; D Johnston, “The Renewal of the Old”
(1997) 56 Cambridge LJ 80; A Flessner, “Die Rechtsvergleichung als Kundin der Rechts-
geschichte” (1999) 7 ZEuP 513; E Bucher, “Rechtsüberlieferung und heutiges Recht” (2000) 8
ZEuP 394; E Picker, “Rechtsdogmatik und Rechtsgeschichte” (2001) 201 Archiv für die
civilistische Praxis 763; J Gordley, “Why Look Backward” (2002) 50 American Journal of
Comparative Law 657; A Bürge, “Das römische Recht als Grundlage für das Zivilrecht im
künftigen Europa”, in F Ranieri (ed), Die Europäisierung der Rechtswissenschaft (2002), 19;
R Zimmermann, “Civil Code and Civil Law” (1994/5) 1 Columbia Journal of European Law 89;
R Zimmermann, “Roman Law and the Harmonisation of Private Law in Europe”, in Hartkamp &
Hesselink, Towards a European Civil Code, 21 ff.
IUS COMMUNE and pecl 11
view after the German Civil Code had entered into force.32 Lawyers in
France or Austria, Prussia and the Netherlands had found similar words a
century before, when the great codes of the age of Enlightenment had
formally replaced the ius commune. A codification of private law, so it was
assumed, contained a comprehensive and closed system of legal rules; it
constituted an autonomous interpretational space. Thus, it contributed to a
vertical as well as horizontal isolation of legal scholarship. The sense of
continuity of the development of private law got lost. In reality, however, a
code like the BGB has not been a radical turning point in German legal
33
history. For those who drafted the BGB did not, on a doctrinal level, intend
their code to constitute a fresh start, a break with the past. On the contrary;
they largely aimed at setting out, incorporating and consolidating “the legal
34
achievements of centuries”, as they had been processed and refined by
pandectist legal learning. Horst Heinrich Jakobs has, therefore, pointedly
referred to the BGB as a codification “which does not contain the source of
law in itself but has its source in the legal scholarship from which it was
created”.35 And Bernhard Windscheid, the leading intellectual force behind
the code, observed that the code “will be no more than a moment in the
development, more tangible, certainly, than the ripple in a stream but, none
the less, merely a ripple in the stream”.36 The BGB was designed to provide
a framework for an “organically progressive legal science”37 which was in
itself an organic product of the Civilian tradition. It was in this spirit that the
38
Imperial Court (Reichsgericht) started to interpret the BGB, and it is in this
spirit that we have learnt, once again, to question the radical separation
between legal history and modern legal doctrine39 and to rediscover that
modern law cannot be understood in isolation; for the present is tied,
indissolubly, to the past from which it has emerged.40
This is as true of the BGB as it is of the Code Civil and the other national
codifications prevailing in modern Europe.41 But it is equally true of the
Principles of European Contract Law. They can be seen as the most recent
fruit of a genuinely European legal experience.
45 This concept goes back to the pointed statements by O W Holmes, The Common Law (1881),
297 ff.
46 Sir G Treitel, The Law of Contract, 10th edn (1999) (henceforth Treitel, Contract), 1. For a com-
parative analysis see, most recently, C Coen, Vertragsscheitern und Rückabwicklung (2003),
19 ff.
47 Gordley (note 42), 79 ff; and see D J Ibbetson, “Natural Law and Common Law” (2001) 5
Edinburgh LR 15.
48 Zimmermann, Obligations, 1 ff, 716 ff.
49 Zimmermann, Obligations, 700 ff.
50 Zimmermann, Obligations, 706 ff.
14 european contract law
content”, § 134 BGB deals with a legal act “which violates a statutory
prohibition” and Article 3:40(2) BW with the violation of a “mandatory rule
of the law”. The French and Italian codes relate the respective legal rule to
their famous doctrines of cause or causa, though not in a completely identical
manner (“The cause is illegal if it is prohibited by the law”: Article 1133 Code
Civil; “The causa is illegal if it is contrary to mandatory rules of law”:
Article 1343 Codice Civile). In Austria and Switzerland contracts infringing a
51
statutory prohibition are void, whereas § 134 BGB limits this sanction to
cases where another legal consequence “does not follow from the statute”.
The Dutch code has a similar proviso though one referring to the intention of
52
the statute. Moreover, it renders a contract voidable rather than void where
the mandatory rule of law which has been infringed merely aims at the pro-
tection of one of the parties to the contract. Infringement of the boni mores is
53
dealt with in all the codes mentioned so far, and it invariably leads to invali-
dity. In France, Italy and the Netherlands, however, l’ordre public, l’ordine
54
pubblico and openbare orde are placed side by side with the boni mores.
English law distinguishes between statutory illegality and common law
illegality; illegality at common law is said to exist, where a contract is against
public policy.55
The Principles, too, retain the traditional bifurcation. On the one hand
they declare a contract to be of no effect “to the extent that it is contrary to
principles recognised as fundamental in the laws of the member states of the
56
European Union”. This formulation is intended to avoid concepts such as
the boni mores or public policy which carry a long history of different inter-
pretations. On the other hand, the Principles deal with contracts infringing a
57
“mandatory rule of law”. What is surprising, at first glance, is the great
flexibility in determining the effect of statutory illegality. In the first place,
regard must be had to the effect expressly prescribed in the mandatory rule
of law itself. Where that rule does not expressly prescribe the effects of an
infringement upon a contract, the contract may be declared to have full
effect, to have some effect, to have no effect, or to be subject to modification.
The decision has to be an appropriate and proportional response to the
76 S Whittaker & R Zimmermann, “Good Faith in European Contract Law: surveying the land-
scape”, in R Zimmermann & S Whittaker (eds), Good Faith in European Contract Law (2000)
(henceforth Zimmermann & Whittaker, Good Faith), 16 ff; and see, for a detailed account,
M J Schermaier, “Bona fides in Roman contract law”, in the same volume, 63 ff.
77 J Gordley, “Good faith in contract law in the medieval ius commune”, in Zimmermann &
Whittaker, Good Faith, 93 ff; F Ranieri, “Bonne foi et exercice du droit dans la tradition du civil
law”, 1998 Revue internationale de droit comparé 1055 ff.
78 See the case studies in Zimmermann & Whittaker, Good Faith, 143 ff.
79 See S Whittaker & R Zimmermann, “Coming to terms with good faith”, in Zimmermann &
Whittaker, Good Faith, 653 ff.
80 Article 1:202 PECL.
81 Article 2:301(2) PECL.
82 Article 2:302 PECL.
83 Article 4:109 PECL.
84 Article 6:102 PECL.
18 european contract law
seventeenth century the struggle had essentially been won, and so the Code
Civil does indeed recognise the possibility of direct representation.
However, the draftsmen of the Code did not conceive of it as an independent
legal institution in its own right but, following Pothier, as something
associated with the contract of agency.101 It was only in the course of the
nineteenth century that Jhering and Laband introduced the conceptual
distinction between the grant of authority and the legal relationship on the
102
basis of which the agent is entitled to act for the principal. The separation
between what can be termed the external and the internal relationship
characterises the regulation contained in the BGB, and the Greek, Italian
103
and Dutch codes have followed suit. In France, too, there has been a
considerable modification of the traditional perspective; nearly every
textbook on the law of obligations today contains an independent chapter on
104
représentation. The Principles, entirely in tune with the more modern
105
codes, confine themselves to a regulation of the external relationship; this
is also, incidentally, in accordance with the Geneva Convention on Agency in
the International Sale of Goods.106
clausula doctrine made its way neither into the Code Civil nor (in spite of
Bernhard Windscheid’s support for a modified version of it)108 into the BGB.
This very rigid point of view, until very recently, continued to prevail in
France; for the théorie de l’imprévision was adopted only in administrative
law and used to be rejected for dispute resolution in private law.109 Only in the
last few years has a certain relaxation occurred insofar as, in cases of a change
of circumstances entailing a significant imbalance in the contractual allocation
of rights and duties, the disadvantaged party is granted a right to ask for a
110
renegotiation of the contract. German courts, on the other hand, had started,
soon after the BGB had entered into effect, to turn the decision of its drafts-
111
men not to recognise the clausula rebus sic stantibus on its head; in response
to the problems posed by the consequences of the First World War on the
performance of long-term contracts the doctrine of Wegfall der Geschäfts-
112
grundlage was established by the Imperial Court on these foundations. In
113
the course of the “modernisation” of the German law of obligations it was
received into the Code. The Principles contain a rule which is very similar as
far as both its structure and the evaluations supporting it are concerned.114
108 For Windscheid’s presupposition doctrine (Voraussetzungslehre), see U Falk, Ein Gelehrter
wie Windscheid (1989), 193 ff.
109 Zweigert & Kötz, Comparative Law, 524 ff.
110 B Fages, “Einige neuere Entwicklungen des französischen allgemeinen Vertragsrechts im
Lichte der Grundregeln der Lando-Kommission” (2003) 11 ZEuP 519 f.
111 K Luig, “Die Kontinuität allgemeiner Rechtsgrundsätze: Das Beispiel der clausula rebus sic
stantibus”, in R Zimmermann, R Knütel & J P Meincke (eds), Rechtsgeschichte und Privat-
rechtsdogmatik (2000), 171 ff.
112 J Emmert, Auf der Suche nach den Grenzen vertraglicher Leistungspflichten (2001), 247 ff;
C Reiter, Vertrag und Geschäftsgrundlage im deutschen und italienischen Recht (2002), 36 ff.
113 On which see R Zimmermann, “Modernizing the German Law of Obligations?”, in Peter Birks
& Arianna Pretto (eds), Themes in Comparative Law in Honour of Bernard Rudden (2002),
265 ff.
114 Article 6:111 PECL.
22 european contract law
which, apart from German law, has also moulded the respective provisions in
the Greek, Italian and Dutch codes125 and which now also finds its expression
in Article 9:509 PECL. Even the French Code was revised in 1975 so as to
allow a judicial reduction of excessive conventional penalties.126
(f) Set-off
Set-off, according to Article 1290 Code Civil operates ipso iure: as soon as
two obligations capable of being set off against each other confront each
other, both of them are extinguished “de plein droit par la seule force de la
loi, même à l’insu des débiteurs”. This pronouncement is based on two
127
sources from the Corpus Juris Civilis. The BGB, on the contrary, requires
set-off to be asserted by an extra-judicial, informal and unilateral declaration
128
to the other party. The draftsmen of the German code, in this respect,
focused their attention on a Constitution by Justinian which appeared to indi-
cate that set-off specifically had to be raised, or pleaded, by the defendant in
129
the course of legal proceedings. Above all, however, they based their
decision on the case law of the Supreme Courts in Germany during the second
half of the nineteenth century, where it had come to be recognised that even
an extra-judicial declaration of the intention to set off two claims against each
other had the effect of extinguishing these claims.130 The German model of
set-off subsequently gained acceptance in many European countries; it has
been followed in Austrian law (in spite of the fact that § 1438 ABGB appears
to endorse the ipso iure effect of set-off),131 in Greece and in the Dutch Civil
Code.132 It also enjoys widespread support in Italian law.133 French courts and
legal writers have also found it impractical literally to implement the regime
125 Article 409 Astikos Kodikas; Article 1384 Codice Civile; Article 6:94 BW. For a comparative
survey, see G H Treitel, Remedies for Breach of Contract: A Comparative Account (1988)
(henceforth Treitel, Remedies), 223 ff; and see H Schelhaas, “The judicial power to reduce a
penalty” (2004) 12 ZEuP 386 ff.
126 Article 1152 II Code Civil.
127 Inst IV, 6, 30; C 4, 31, 14 pr.; on the Justinianic law, see P Pichonnaz, La compensation: Analyse
historique et comparative des modes de compenser non conventionnels (2001) (henceforth
Pichonnaz, La compensation), 260 ff; on the development in France, see Pichonnaz, 386 ff.
128 § 388 BGB.
129 C 4, 31, 14, 1 (“Ita tamen compensationes obici iubemus”; “opponi compensationem”).
130 On the development in Germany, see R Zimmermann, in R. Zimmermann, J Rückert & M
Schmoeckel (eds), Historisch-kritischer Kommentar zum BGB, vol II (in preparation),
(henceforth Zimmermann et al, Historisch-kritischer Kommentar) §§ 387–396, notes 12 ff.
131 See P Rummel, in P Rummel (ed), Kommentar zum Allgemeinen bürgerlichen Gesetzbuch, vol
II, 2nd edn (1992), § 1438, nn 11 f; S Dullinger, Handbuch der Aufrechnung (1995), 96 ff.
132 Article 441 Astikos Kodikas; Articles 6:127 (1), 6:129 BW.
133 In spite of Article 1242 Codice Civile; see G Cian, “Hundert Jahre BGB aus italienischer Sicht”
(1998) 6 ZEuP 220 f.
24 european contract law
periods of prescription, the idea has been gaining ground that prescription
should not run unless the creditor knew (or ought reasonably to have known)
about his claim. A fourth characteristic of a modern prescription regime,
incidentally, follows from the latter point: a maximum period after which no
claim may be brought, regardless of the creditor’s knowledge, appears to be
necessary as a counterbalance to the discoverability principle. The model
sketched in these few lines provides the basis for the regulation contained in
Chapter 14 of the Principles: more consistently so than in the BGB after the
148
modernisation of the law of obligations where we still find, for instance, a
special regime for damages claims based on the seller’s liability for latent
149
defects.
148 For a comparative evaluation, see R Zimmermann, “Das neue deutsche Verjährungsrecht – ein
Vorbild für Europa?”, in I Koller, H Roth & R Zimmermann, Schuldrechtsmodernisierungs-
gesetz 2002 (2002), 9 ff.
149 For criticism, see D Leenen, “Die Neuregelung der Verjährung” (2001) Juristenzeitung 552 ff;
R Zimmermann, D Leenen, H-P Mansel & W Ernst, “Finis Litium? Zum Verjährungsrecht
nach dem Regierungsentwurf eines Schuldrechtsmodernisierungsgesetzes” (2001) Juristen-
zeitung 688 ff. The matter has been solved more satisfactorily in the new Austrian law: §§ 932 ff
ABGB; see R Welser, B Jud, Die neue Gewährleistung, Kurzkommentar (2001).
150 See the table of ratification in Radley-Gardner et al, Fundamental Texts, 239 f.
151 See S Grundmann, in Bianca & Grundmann, EU Sales Directive, Introduction, nn 1 ff; U Magnus,
“The CISG’s Impact on European Legislation”, in F Ferrari (ed), The 1980 Uniform Sales Law:
Old Issues Revisited in the Light of Recent Experiences (2003), 129 ff. The correspondence
between these two international instruments will significantly contribute to the emergence of a
common framework of reference for the development of sales law in Europe; see Heutger
(2003) 11 ERPL 155 ff.
152 For Germany, see Bundesminister der Justiz (ed), Abschlussbericht der Kommission zur
Überarbeitung des Schuldrechts (1992), 19 f; P Schlechtriem, “Rechtsvereinheitlichung in
Europa und Schuldrechtsreform in Deutschland” (1993) 1 ZEuP 217 ff; P Schlechtriem, “10
Jahre CISG – Der Einfluss des UN-Kaufrechts auf die Entwicklung des deutschen und des
internationalen Schuldrechts” (2001) 1 Internationales Handelsrecht 12 ff; generally, see the
references in Schlechtriem, Kommentar, sub III. 4.
IUS COMMUNE and pecl 27
153 R Zimmermann, “‘In der Schule von Ludwig Mitteis’: Ernst Rabels rechtshistorische
Ursprünge” (2001) 65 RabelsZ 1 ff.
154 G Kegel, in G Kleinheyer & J Schröder (eds), Deutsche und Europäische Juristen aus neun
Jahrhunderten, 4th edn (1996), 504.
155 See the table in H M Flechtner, “The CISG’s Impact on International Unification Efforts: The
Unidroit Principles of International Commercial Contracts and the Principles of European
Contract Law”, in Ferrari (note 151), 169 ff (181 ff).
156 Articles 9:301 ff PECL.
157 Articles 9:501 ff PECL.
158 Article 8:103 PECL.
159 Article 8:108 PECL.
160 Article 9:304 PECL.
161 See Article 28 CISG; on which, see U Huber, in Schlechtriem, Kommentar, Article 28, nn 1 ff.
162 Article 9:102 PECL.
28 european contract law
163 But see now C Kern, “Ein einheitliches Zurückbehaltungsrecht im UN-Kaufrecht?” (2000) 8
ZEuP 837 ff.
164 Article 9:201 PECL. On the exceptio non adimpleti contractus, see W Ernst, Die Einrede des
nichterfüllten Vertrages (2000).
165 Articles 81 ff CISG; for criticism, see U Magnus, in Staudinger, Kommentar zum Bürgerlichen
Gesetzbuch, Wiener UN-Kaufrecht (Neubearbeitung 1999), Article 82, n 4; M Krebs, Die
Rückabwicklung im UN-Kaufrecht (2000), 91 ff; H G Leser & R Hornung, in Schlechtriem,
Einheitlichen, Article 82, nn 16 ff and Article 84, n 27a.
166 For criticism see Zimmermann (note 8).
167 Article 9:401 PECL. The Principles, insofar, reflect an international tendency; see A Sandrock,
Vertragswidrigkeit der Sachleistung (2003), 209 ff.
168 For details, see E Luig, Der internationale Vertragsschluss (2002), 33 ff.
169 Schlechtriem, in Schlechtriem, Kommentar, Article 16, n 10; E Luig (note 168), 121 ff.
IUS COMMUNE and pecl 29
170 This is true, particularly, for the United Nations Convention on the Assignment of Receivables
in International Trade (reproduced in (2002) 10 ZEuP 860 ff; and see S V Bazinas, “Der Beitrag
von Uncitral zur Vereinheitlichung der Rechtsvorschriften über Forderungsabtretungen: Das
Übereinkommen der Vereinten Nationen über Abtretungen von Forderungen im
internationalen Handel” (2002) 10 ZEuP 782 ff); for a comparative analysis, see H Eiden-
müller, “Die Dogmatik der Zession vor dem Hintergrund der internationalen Entwicklung”
(2004) 204 Archiv für die civilistische Praxis 457 ff. The United Nations Convention on the
Limitation Period in the International Sale of Goods (printed in Radley-Gardner et al, Funda-
mental Texts, 269 ff) has only been relied upon in some respects; since it only deals with one
specific type of claim, it does not provide a suitable model for a general prescription regime.
171 Lando & Beale (note 6), xxiv; see above, the text to note 99.
172 See the text to notes 127 ff above; on the development of the retrospectivity doctrine, see
Zimmermann, in Zimmermann et al, Historisch-kritischer Kommentar, §§ 387–396, notes 14 ff,
23 ff.
30 european contract law
favouring set-off ipso iure, the other requiring an assertion of set-off.173 In the
course of time, the notion of retrospectivity has become firmly entrenched,
in prevailing legal ideology, as an essential characteristic of a declaration of
set-off.174 Yet this notion is based on a centuries-old misunderstanding.175 The
phrase ipso iure appears to be of classical origin. It had been used, by the
Roman jurists, in the special context of the banker’s agere cum compensa-
176
tione. But the phrase had merely been intended to indicate that this type of
set-off was not one effected by the judge. The banker himself was forced, by
virtue of the formula granted to him by the praetor, to reduce his claim by the
amount of the other party’s counterclaim. The plaintiff was thus made ipso
iure, i.e. by the law itself, to effect set-off. It is probable that Justinian also still
177
attributed ex nunc effect to set-off. The decisive turn came with the
Glossators who reinterpreted set-off ipso iure as a form of set-off which
occurred automatically, sine facto hominis. This misunderstanding still today
casts its shadow on (as it would have been put in the nineteenth century) the
“construction” of set-off in France and all the countries influenced by French
law, but also in Germany178 and the countries following German law.179 From
the sources compiled and edited by Jakobs and Schubert we now know that
in the course of the deliberations leading up to the BGB Bernhard
Windscheid had recommended the attribution of merely prospective effect
to set-off;180 and he had done so in spite of the fact that, as a pandectist
scholar, he had previously made the intellectually most ambitious attempt to
explain the tension between set-off ipso iure and the requirement that set-off
181
had to be asserted.
183 H Grotius, De jure belli ac pacis libri tres, Amsterdami (1631), Lib. II, Cap. XI, § 14. Grotius’
doctrine was based on L Lessius, De iustitia et iure (see Gordley (note 42), 80 f); via Pothier, it
established itself in France and England: for France, see M Ferid & H J Sonnenberger, Das
Französische Zivilrecht, 2nd edn (1994), vol I/1, 1 F 63; for England, see Simpson (1975) 91
LQR 259.
184 § 657 BGB. For the origin of this provision, see F P von Kübel, “Das einseitige Versprechen als
Grund der Verpflichtung zur Erfüllung”, in W Schubert (ed), Die Vorlagen der Redaktoren für
die erste Kommission zur Ausarbeitung des Entwurfs eines Bürgerlichen Gesetzbuches, Recht
der Schuldverhältnisse, Teil 3 (1980), 1171 ff; F P von Kübel, “Einseitiges Versprechen”, in
Schubert, 475 ff. For a comparative overview, see R Zimmermann & P Hellwege, “Belohnungs-
versprechen: ‘pollicitatio’, ‘promise’ oder ‘offer’?: Schottisches Recht vor dem Hintergrund der
europäischen Entwicklungen” (1998) 39 ZfRV 137; J Gordley, The Enforceability of Promises in
European Contract Law (2001), 300 ff.
185 H Dernburg, Pandekten, 6th edn (1900), vol II, § 9; J Baron, Pandekten, 4th edn (1882), § 211.
186 Zimmermann, Obligations, 496 (n 15), 574 f.
187 Stair, Institutions of the Law of Scotland, 6th edn edited by D M Walker (1981), Book I, Title
10, §§ 3 f.
188 W D H Sellar, “Promise”, in K Reid & R Zimmermann (eds), A History of Private Law in
Scotland (2000) (henceforth Reid & Zimmermann, History), vol II, 252 ff.
189 Zimmermann & Hellwege (1998) 39 ZfRV 133 ff; Sellar (note 188), 267 ff, 277 ff; M Hogg,
Obligations (2003), 36 ff.
190 For a detailed analysis, see now J Kleinschmidt, Der Verzicht im Schuldrecht: Vertragsprinzip
und einseitiges Rechtsgeschäft im deutschen und US-amerikanischen Recht (2004).
32 european contract law
invalid.196 Via Pothier these ideas were received in England. The doctrine of
undue influence, in turn, developed in England by the Court of Chancery,
was subsequently reimported by Scots and South African courts into a
Civilian legal environment.197
196 M de Afflictis, Decisionum sacri regni neapolitani consilii, Francofurti (1600), Decisio LXIX; cf
also I Menochius, De praesumptionibus, coniecturis, signis et indiciis commentaria, Lugduni
(1608), Liber IV, Praesumptio XII, nn 8 f.
197 See J Story, Commentaries on Equity Jurisprudence, 3rd edn (by A E Randall), 1920, §§ 234 ff;
G Lubbe, “Voidable Contracts”, in R Zimmermann & D Visser (eds), Southern Cross: Civil
Law and Common Law in South Africa (1996) (henceforth Zimmermann & Visser, Southern
Cross), 296 ff; Du Plessis & Zimmermann (2003) 10 Maastricht Journal of European and
Comparative Law 345 ff.
198 Savigny; see the text to note 37 above.
199 Berman (note 24), 9; and see above, the text to notes 28 ff.
34 european contract law
old ius commune began to turn into a disadvantage. The language of the ius
commune was Latin. It was the language that was understood by every
learned lawyer who had received an academic legal training at any university
in Europe. With the rise of the vernacular as an academic language the use of
Latin was bound to be regarded as quaint and artificial. Dissemination of the
Principles, of course, is not facilitated by a common language. English appears
to be about to emerge as a kind of background language for international
communication. Nonetheless, in countries like France or Germany legal
literature written in English is not as readily received as it is in smaller nations
such as the Netherlands. In order to become a foundational work of a truly
European character the Principles therefore have to be translated into as
many of the official European languages as possible. This process is under
200
way at the moment.
There are also, however, characteristic aspects which the Principles share
with the old ius commune and which thus engender the hope that they can
serve as a nucleus for the emergence of a renewed European legal scholar-
ship. One which has been discussed above is their substantive content.
Another is their source of legitimacy. The old ius commune was widely
thought to apply ratione imperii.201 But this was only true of certain parts of
Europe. Moreover, in the middle of the seventeenth century it was clearly
demonstrated that Roman law had not been made applicable by formal
imperial enactment.202 If it continued to apply, it did so because of its intrinsic
qualities, i.e. imperio rationis. Particularly instructive is the situation prevail-
ing in nineteenth-century Germany. A number of German territories still
administered justice according to the contemporary, pandectist version of
203
the Roman common law. But even in the countries of codified law, the ius
204
commune continued to contribute its underlying legal theory: the codifi-
cations were always compared with, assessed and evaluated from the point of
view of the ius commune. Pandectist legal scholarship very largely achieved a
German unification on a scholarly level. Thus, it remained perfectly possible
200 G Rouhette, I de Lamberterie, D Tallon & C Witz, Principes du droit Européen du contrat
(2003); C Castronovo, Principi di diritto europeo dei contratti, Parte I e II (2001); C von Bar &
R Zimmermann, Grundregeln des Europäischen Vertragsrechts, Teile I und II (2003); P Barres
Benlloch, J M Embid Irujo & F Martinez Sanz, Principios de derecho contractual europeo,
Partes I y II (2003).
201 See Wieacker, Privatrechtsgeschichte, 97 ff.
202 See Wieacker, Privatrechtsgeschichte, 160 ff.
203 In 1890, about 14,416,000 (of a total of 50,000,000) inhabitants of the German Empire lived in
areas where mainly the ius commune was applicable. See the map edited by D Klippel,
Deutsche Rechts- und Gerichtskarte (1996), with an introduction by the editor.
204 Koschaker, Europa und das römische Recht, 292.
IUS COMMUNE and pecl 35
205 For the “pandectification” of the Prussian and Austrian codes, see the references in
Zimmermann, Roman Law, 4ff. For the influence of pandectist scholarship outside Germany,
see the references in R Zimmermann, “Savignys Vermächtnis” (1998) Juristische Blätter 276
(note 18).
206 For the implications, see C-W Canaris, “Die Stellung der ‘Unidroit Principles’ und der
‘Principles of European Contract Law’ im System der Rechtsquellen”, in Basedow (note 1),
5 ff; R Michaels, “Privatautonomie und Privatkodifikation” (1998) 62 RabelsZ 580 ff.
207 Text following note 6 above.
208 Text following note 14 above
209 Text following note 12 above
210 R C van Caenegem, Judges, Legislators and Professors (1987); R C van Caenegem, An Historical
Introduction to Private Law (1988), 170 ff.
36 european contract law
(2) Legislation
The disintegration of the old ius commune has led to the rise of the new
discipline of comparative law. Originally, however, attention was confined
nearly exclusively to foreign legislation. It was studied in order to improve the
quality of one’s own legislation. In its origins, therefore, the new discipline
was one of comparative legislation (législation comparée): “La comparaison
des lois étrangères est une étude de législation bien plus encore que de
jurisconsulte.”211 Draftsmen of new legislation, in the course of the nineteenth
century, usually looked at the way in which the problem at hand had been
dealt with by the legislatures of other countries. This applied, at first, to the
newly emerging areas of the law but subsequently also to codifications
concerning the classical core areas of private law. The draftsmen of the BGB,
for instance, very carefully took account of the French and Austrian codifica-
tions as well as of various other codes and draft codes in Germany and
Switzerland. This tradition has continued throughout the twentieth century.
The preparation of the new Dutch Civil Code provides another excellent
212
example. In recent years, uniform sales law has gained great significance as
a pacemaker for national law reform. The various steps on the road towards
modernising breach of contract and sale in German law have largely been
inspired first by ULIS and then by CISG.213 The Principles of European
Contract Law constitute a model law which has the potential to attain a
similar significance. It was one of the criticisms levelled against the so-called
“Discussion Draft” of a statute for the modernisation of the German law of
obligations, published in September 2000, that it failed to take account of
more than ten years of legal development in Europe, as evidenced in the Dutch
Civil Code, the Principles of European Contract Law and the Principles of
214
International Commercial Contracts. Thus, it was only in the final stages of
215
the German reform process that the Principles were taken into consideration.
211 See H Coing, “Rechtsvergleichung als Grundlage von Gesetzgebung im 19. Jahrhundert”
(1978) 7 Ius Commune 160 ff; H Coing, Europäisches Privatrecht, vol II (1989), 56 ff; Zweigert
& Kötz, Comparative Law, 48 ff; the quotation is from E-R Laboulaye, founder of the Société
de législation comparée, the first association for comparative law in Europe; see Coing,
Europäisches Privatrecht II, 61 and Coing, “Laboulaye” (1993) 1 ZEuP 519 ff.
212 U Drobnig, “Das neue niederländische bürgerliche Gesetzbuch aus vergleichender und
deutscher Sicht” (1993) 1 ERPL 174.
213 Text to note 152 above.
214 B Dauner-Lieb, “Die geplante Schuldrechtsmodernisierung – Durchbruch oder Schnellschuss?”
(2001) Juristenzeitung 15; U Huber, “Das geplante Recht der Leistungsstörungen”, in Ernst &
Zimmermann (note 1), 108 f; Zimmermann (note 113), 284 f.
215 Huber (note 214), 31 ff; C-W Canaris, “Die Reform des Rechts der Leistungsstörungen”
(2001) Juristenzeitung 499 ff.
IUS COMMUNE and pecl 37
However, prescription was the only area of the law where they were able to
exercise a significant influence; the German government specifically
acknowledged to have adopted, in large parts, the model proposed in the
Principles of European Contract Law.216
216 “Bericht des Rechtsausschusses, BT-Drucksache 14/7052”, easily accessible in C-W Canaris
(ed), Schuldrechtsmodernisierung 2002 (2002), 1051 ff (1066); cf also “Begründung der
Bundesregierung zum Entwurf eines Gesetzes zur Modernisierung des Schuldrechts, BT-
Drucksache 6857”, in Canaris 569 ff, 600, 612 f. For a comparative analysis, see Zimmermann
(note 148), 9 ff.
217 See, e.g., K Zweigert, “Rechtsvergleichung als universale Interpretationsmethode” (1949/50)
15 RabelsZ 5 ff; Zweigert & Kötz, Comparative Law, 18 ff.
218 W Odersky, “Harmonisierende Auslegung und europäische Rechtskultur” (1994) 2 ZEuP 1 ff.
219 Odersky (1994) 2 ZEuP 4.
220 Kötz, European Contract Law; H Beale, A Hartkamp, H Kötz & D Tallon, Cases, Materials
and Text on Contract Law (2002).
38 european contract law
221 S Vogenauer, Die Auslegung von Gesetzen in England und auf dem Kontinent: Eine
rechtsvergleichende Untersuchung der Rechtsprechung und ihrer historischen Grundlagen, vol
I (2001), 43 with further references. For a comparative overview, see U Drobnig & S van Erp
(eds), The Use of Comparative Law by Courts (1999); for Scotland, see H L MacQueen,
“Mixing it? Comparative Law in the Scottish Courts” (2003) 11 ERPL 735 ff.
222 Director-General of Fair Trading v First National Bank [2002] 1 AC 481 (HL) at 500 per Lord
Steyn and 502 per Lord Hope. On this decision, see S Whittaker, “Assessing the fairness of
contract terms: the parties’ ‘essential bargain’, its regulatory context and the significance of the
requirement of good faith” (2004) 12 ZEuP 75 ff.
223 The minority in a decision of the Swedish Supreme Court has referred to Article 2:205(1)
PECL: 2000 Nytt Juridiskt Arkiv 747. I am grateful to Mr Justice Torgny Håstad for the
reference.
224 Articles 4:115, 9:305 ff, 15:104 PECL.
225 For criticism, see Zimmermann (note 8); generally, see P Hellwege, Die Rückabwicklung
gegenseitiger Verträge als einheitliches Problem: Deutsches, englisches und schottisches Recht
in historisch-vergleichender Perspektive (2004).
IUS COMMUNE and pecl 39
refined and specified.226 In many other cases, however, the comparison will
reveal quirks and idiosyncracies of the national legal systems and will lead to
a reappraisal of the latter. For Germany the process of comparative assess-
ment was initiated at a symposium on “Unification of European Contract
Law and German Law” which was held in the Hamburg Max Planck Institute
in 1999;227 it was designed to re-establish the intellectual contact between
private law legal doctrine and comparative law under the auspices of the
Principles of European Contract Law and the Principles of International
Commercial Contracts. At the most recent biannual meeting of the associa-
tion of German-speaking professors of private law the Principles of European
Contract Law featured prominently in two of the four lectures, the one dealing
228 229
with breach of contract, the other with the law of assignment of claims.
In the latter paper the technical quality and internal consistency of Chapter 11
of the Principles were emphasised and, on that basis, a number of changes to
the German law of cession were recommended. Unfortunately, however, the
Principles have not yet worked their way into the general textbooks and com-
mentaries on German private law. Dutch writers, on the other hand, refer to
the Principles almost as a matter of routine even if they merely deal with a
question of Dutch law. And a recent collection of texts, cases and materials on
English contract law invokes the Principles on a number of occasions even
though it specifically does not describe itself as a book on comparative law.230
Another very interesting initiative has been taken in the Netherlands. Five
authors have systematically examined their own legal system from the point
of view of the Principles and have thus, by using a supranational frame of
231
reference, made Dutch law more easily accessible to foreign lawyers.
226 For criticism concerning Article 6:110 PECL (Stipulation in Favour of a Third Party), see
Zimmermann (note 98), 478.
227 Basedow (note 1). For France, see now P Rémy-Corlay & D Fenouillet (eds), Les concepts
contractuels francais à l’heure des Principes de droit européen des contrats (2003).
228 H-P Mansel, “Die Kaufrechtsreform in Europa und die Dogmatik des Leistungsstörungs-
rechts” (2004) 204 Archiv für die civilistische Praxis 396 ff. Cf. also R Zimmermann, “Remedies
for Non-Performance: The revised German Law of Obligations, viewed against the Background
of the Principles of European Contract Law” (2002) 6 Edinburgh LR 271 ff.
229 Eidenmüller (2004) 204 Archiv für die civilistische Praxis 457 ff.
230 E McKendrick, Contract Law: Text, Cases and Materials (2003), 55 f, 102, 133, 276 f, 552, 615
f and more frequently; cf. in particular 417 f. For Scotland, see the remarks by MacQueen
(2003) 11 ERPL 751 on two recent texts on contract law that have drawn significantly on the
Principles: H L MacQueen & J Thomson, Contract Law in Scotland (2000) (a student book)
and W W McBryde, The Law of Contract in Scotland, 2nd edn (2001) (a practitioner work).
231 D Busch, E Hondius, H van Kooten, H Schelhaas & W Schrama, The Principles of European
Contract Law and Dutch Law: A Commentary (2002). Cf also D Busch and E Hondius, “Ein
neues Vertragsrecht für Europa: Die Principles of European Contract Law aus niederländ-
ischer Sicht” (2001) 9 ZEuP 223 ff.
40 european contract law
F. CONCLUSION
All in all, it is obvious today that the discussions concerning a European
236
contract law have considerably intensified over the last few years. The main
actors on the stage of the institutionalised Europe, i.e. Council, Commission
and Parliament of the European Union, have even envisaged the possibility
of a codification of European contract law. Whether, eventually, such a step
will be taken or not, the academic community would neglect its duty if it did
not set out to prepare, refine and critically examine the intellectual
foundations for a European contract law. The Principles are an attempt to
establish such foundations. They should be taken into consideration not only
by comparative lawyers but, particularly, by all those engaged in shaping and
elucidating national legal doctrine. The Principles may sharpen an awareness
235 E Friedberg, Die künftige Gestaltung des deutschen Rechtsstudiums nach den Beschlüssen der
Eisenacher Konferenz (1996), 7 f.
236 See Jansen, Binnenmarkt: Privatrecht und europäische Identität, 2 ff (with references); most
recently, see D Staudenmayer, “Ein optionelles Instrument im Europäischen Vertragsrecht”
(2003) 11 ZEuP 828 ff; C von Bar & S Swann, “Response to the Action Plan on European
Contract Law: A More Coherent European Contract Law (COM (2003) 63)” (2003) 11 ERPL
595 ff.
42 european contract law
for the peculiarities of the national legal systems and provide inspiration for
their interpretation and development. Thus, they can serve as a catalyst for a
“soft” harmonisation of the European legal systems. Soft harmonisation
would appear, in the short and medium term, to be the preferable alternative
to central regulation, and the one in tune with the tradition of the old ius
commune.237 At the same time, it may pave the way towards a codification
which is as widely accepted in Europe as the Code Civil in France or the
BGB in Germany.
237 Zimmermann (1998) Juristische Blätter 273 ff; Zimmermann, “Roman Law and the Harmon-
isation of Private Law in Europe” (note 31), 21 ff; for a different view, see O Lando, “Why
Codify the European Law of Contract” (1997) 5 ERPL 525 ff; O Lando, “The Principles of
European Contract Law after Year 2000”, in F Werro (ed), New Perspectives on European
Private Law (1998), 59 ff; W Tilmann, “Eine Privatrechtskodifikation für die Europäische
Gemeinschaft”, in P-C Müller-Graff (ed), Gemeinsames Privatrecht in der Europäischen
Gemeinschaft, 2nd edn (1999), 579 ff; J Basedow, “Das BGB im künftigen europäischen
Privatrecht: Der hybride Kodex” (2000) 200 Archiv für die civilistische Praxis 445 ff;
J Basedow, “Codification of Private Law in the European Union: The Making of a Hybrid”
(2001) 9 ERPL 35 ff. For a balanced assessment of the debate, see W van Gerven, “A Common
Law for Europe: The Future Meeting the Past?” (2001) 9 ERPL 485 ff.
2 Good Faith
Hector L MacQueen
43
44 european contract law
“Good faith” means honesty and fairness in mind, which are subjective concepts.
1
… “Fair dealing” means observance of fairness in fact which is an objective test …
There are links to other concepts in PECL. Comment A says that Article 1:201
PECL is a companion to the Article on usages, which makes binding between
the parties agreed, established or generally applicable and reasonable usages
and practices (Article 1:105 PECL). In this way are ideas about “community
standards”, as well as the standards the parties set themselves, articulated in
the actual text. Article 1:202 PECL, which immediately follows the article
stating the good faith obligation of the parties, further imposes on them a
duty to co-operate to give full effect to the contract (although unlike good faith
and fair dealing this duty is not expressly made unexcludable or unlimitable).
Article 1:302 PECL says that “reasonableness [another frequently used
concept in the Principles] is to be judged by what persons acting in good faith
and in the same situation as the parties would consider to be reasonable”.
The application of good faith and fair dealing is fleshed out in several more
specific provisions, although Comment B to Article 1:201 PECL points out
that the concept is “broader than any of these specific applications”. Thus,
while parties negotiating a contract are not liable for failure to reach an
agreement, negotiating or breaking off negotiations contrary to good faith
and fair dealing leads to liability for the losses caused to the other party.
There is such liability if a party enters into or continues negotiations with no
real intention of reaching an agreement with the other party (Article 2:301
PECL).2 Good faith and fair dealing may also require a negotiating party to
disclose information to the other party, otherwise any resultant contract may
be avoided (Article 4:107 PECL). The requirement will typically arise for a
party who has special expertise on the matter in issue, and account will also
be taken of the cost of acquiring the information, whether the other party
could reasonably acquire the information for itself, and the apparent
importance of the information to the other party (Article 4:107(3) PECL).
Good faith and fair dealing are also among the “relevant circumstances” to
which regard is to be had in interpreting the contract (Article 5:102 PECL),
although it is difficult to see either as a “circumstance” comparable with some
3
of the other matters listed in the Article. Terms stemming from good faith
1 “Good faith” sometimes appears on its own in PECL: see e.g. Articles 1:302, 3:201(3).
2 See also Article 6:111(3) PECL (damages may be awarded for loss suffered through a party refusing
to negotiate or breaking off negotiations contrary to good faith and fair dealing where contract has
become excessively onerous as a result of change of circumstances since the contract was concluded).
3 In his contribution to this volume (at 202) Professor Clive points out that good faith and fair
dealing are “considerations” rather than “circumstances”.
good faith 45
and fair dealing may be implied (Article 6:102 PECL). Since this power is not
limited to consistency with the express terms, freedom of contract may here
be subject to good faith and fair dealing requirements. The Comments do not
refer to this, however, seeing the main function of the implied term as filling
gaps in the contract. If, contrary to duties of good faith and fair dealing or co-
operation, a party prevents or brings about the fulfilment of a condition, to
the respective disadvantage or advantage of the other party, the condition is
to be deemed either fulfilled or unfulfilled, as the case may be (Article 16:102
PECL).
A court may also regulate the provisions of the contract to be in
accordance with the demands of good faith and fair dealing. Here again we
see freedom of contract being hemmed in by good faith and fair dealing. In
cases where one party had taken advantage of another’s relative weakness or
susceptibility to influence in a way that was grossly unfair or took excessive
benefit, courts are empowered to adapt a contract to bring it into accordance
with what might have been agreed had the requirements of good faith and
fair dealing been followed (Article 4:109 PECL). Terms not individually
negotiated (i.e. in standard form contracts) may be avoided if, “contrary to
good faith and fair dealing”, they cause a “significant imbalance in the parties’
rights and obligations under the contract” (Article 4:110 PECL). But the
remedies of avoidance and damages for mistake and incorrect information
(misrepresentation) may be excluded unless to do so is contrary to good faith
4
and fair dealing (Article 4:118 PECL). Likewise remedies for non-performance
may be excluded or restricted unless it would be contrary to good faith and
fair dealing to invoke the exclusion or restriction (Article 8:109 PECL).
All this seems to stand in clear contrast to the classical Common Law view
against general duties of good faith in contracts, succinctly expressed by
Bingham LJ in a well-known dictum: “English law has characteristically com-
mitted itself to no such overriding principle but has developed piecemeal
5
solutions in response to demonstrated problems of unfairness.” Equally well
known is Lord Ackner’s remark in Walford v Miles – “the concept of a duty to
carry on negotiations in good faith is inherently repugnant to the adversarial
position of the parties when involved in negotiations” 6 – almost diametrically
opposite to the position expressed in Articles 1:201 and 1:202 as well as in
4 Note that the remedies for fraud, threats and excessive benefit or unfair advantage-taking may
never be excluded or restricted: Article 4:118(1) PECL.
5 Interfoto Picture Library Ltd v Stiletto Visual Programmes Ltd [1989] QB 433 at 439.
6 Walford v Miles [1992] 2 AC 128 at 138. For further argument against a general principle of good
faith in contract negotiation, see S A Smith, Contract Theory (2004), 197–207.
46 european contract law
Article 2:301 PECL. Commentators such as Michael Bridge argue that the
imposition of a general standard of good faith would undermine commercial
certainty to an unacceptable degree, and that “it is better to confront
particular problems than to adopt a general ethical imperative. … The pur-
pose of legislation should not be to make a moral demonstration.”7 He
questions the machinery by which community values should be introduced
into private litigation (the judiciary at all, but especially lower levels), and
wonders how the relevant community is to be defined. Common Law doubts
about good faith led to the well-known compromise of Article 7.1 CISG: “In
the interpretation of this Convention, regard is to be had to … the obser-
vance of good faith in international trade.” But nevertheless, outside England
good faith has been gaining increasing acceptance and prominence in the
Common Law world, most notably in the Uniform Commercial Code’s duty
of good faith in performance (§ 2–103 UCC), and also in Australian, New
8
Zealand and Canadian court decisions.
Observing the UCC obligation of good faith in performance highlights one
further point about PECL: the almost complete lack of reference to good
faith and fair dealing in the chapters on performance, non-performance and
remedies for non-performance. As we have already seen, however, this lack
cannot be read as meaning that good faith and fair dealing are excluded from,
or irrelevant to, these chapters. So the Comments link to good faith principles
the limits on the remedy of specific performance in Article 9:102 PECL, and
the aggrieved party’s duty to mitigate loss flowing from the other’s non-
9
performance (Article 9:505 PECL). Again, Comment B to Article 1:201
PECL notes that the Article
may take precedence over other provisions of these Principles when a strict
adherence to them would lead to a manifestly unjust result. Thus, even if the non-
performance of an obligation is fundamental because strict compliance with the
obligation is of the essence of the contract under Article 8:103, a party would not
be permitted to terminate because of a trivial breach of the obligation.
7 M Bridge, “Good faith in commercial contracts”, in R Brownsword, N J Hird & G Howells (eds),
Good Faith in Contract: Concept and Context (1999) (henceforth Brownsword et al, Good Faith),
143.
8 See A F Mason, “Contract, good faith and equitable standards in fair dealing” (2000) 116 LQR 66.
Cf J W Carter & E Peden, “Good faith in Australian contract law” (2003) 19 Journal of Contract
Law 155. For judicious analyses of the current state of development in English law, see J
Stapleton, “Good faith in private law” (1999) 49 CLP 1; R Brownsword, Contract Law: Themes
for the Twenty-First Century (2000), ch 5, and E McKendrick, Contract Law, 6th edn (2005),
264–269.
9 See Comments A and D to Article 1:201 PECL.
good faith 47
On the other hand, Comment H to the same Article notes that good faith
is dependent “to some extent” upon what the parties have agreed. So parties
may agree “that even a technical breach may entitle the aggrieved party to
refuse performance, when, for instance, its agents can ascertain a technical
breach but not whether it is a trifle or not”. There is some tension between
Comments B and H, and it is perhaps a pity that there is nothing in the texts
of the relevant Articles to make the position clearer.
Hugh Beale has argued that the concept of good faith and fair dealing is
used in a variety of inconsistent ways in PECL. While the concept is not of
itself a source for development of the Principles, something more than “not
bad faith” is meant. But under Article 1:106 PECL regard is to be had, not
only to good faith and fair dealing, but also, as we have seen above, to
certainty in contractual relationships and uniformity of application. Article
1:102 PECL may appear to create an over-arching principle and role for good
faith; but, suggests Beale, the many other Articles providing for more specific
controls based on good faith would be unnecessary if Article 1:102 PECL did
have this effect. In general, good faith and fair dealing in PECL appear to
exclude the unreasonable rather than to impose a duty to be reasonable.
They are at their most positive in relation to implied terms (Article 6:102
PECL), with regard to the duty to co-operate (Article 1:202 PECL), and with
regard to invalidity (see e.g. Article 4:107 PECL). When good faith and
reasonableness are juxtaposed, as in Article 1:302 PECL, they seem not to be
very different from each other. There is an overall lack of consistency, and
Beale proposes a tidying-up exercise to clarify what is intended by the
concepts of good faith and dealing in PECL before they become part of the
Common Frame of Reference now proposed by the European Commission.
It should be made explicit that good faith is not an over-arching standard or
principle for the whole of PECL, but is rather a standard used within
particular rules. Good faith should be visibly an excluder principle only (i.e.
merely excluding the unreasonable rather than imposing positive standards
of conduct). Finally, a suitably defined standard of “reasonableness” should
10
be used for the imposition of positive duties.
10 H Beale, “General clauses and specific rules in the Principles of European Contract Law: the
‘good faith’ clause”, in S Grundmann & D Mazeaud (eds), General Clauses and Standards in
European Contract Law – Comparative Law, EC Law and Codification (forthcoming), ch 12. I
am grateful to Professor Beale for letting me see his paper in advance of publication and
discussing it with me. Note that Stapleton (1999) 49 CLP 1 at 8, 10–12, argues that reasonableness
is a more demanding standard than good faith.
48 european contract law
11 Director-General of Fair Trading v First National Bank [2002] 1 AC 481 at 500, 502. Lord Hope
of Craighead also refers to PECL in his speech in R v Immigration Officer at Prague Airport, ex
parte European Roma Rights Centre [2004] UKHL 55, [2005] 2 WLR 1, para 59.
12 See also Zimmermann & Whittaker, Good Faith, 653–701.
13 Note too that the Law Commissions’ Report on Unfair Terms in Contract (Law Com No 292; Scot
Law Com No 199 (2005)) recommends that the Directive control of good faith should be
transposed into new legislation in the UK as a test of fairness and reasonableness, without any
reference to good faith.
14 Eric Clive, “The Scottish Civil Code project” in H L MacQueen et al, Regional Private Laws and
Codification in Europe (2003) at 93, 95.
15 See e.g. R Zimmermann, Roman Law, Contemporary Law, European Law: The Civilian
Tradition Today (2001) (henceforth Zimmermann, Roman Law), especially at 126–177; H L
MacQueen, Scots Law and the Road to the New Ius Commune (Ius Commune Lectures on
European Private Law, 1, 2000) (also available in the Electronic Journal of Comparative Law, vol
4.4 (Dec 2000), http://www.ejcl.org/ejcl/44/art44–1.html.
good faith 49
either. In neither Scots nor South African contract law is there an active
general principle of good faith. The most recent commentators on the
subject, Fritz Brand and Douglas Brodie, observe that
in both systems the role of good faith is to inform and explain the rules of the law
of contract and, when necessary, to provide the basis for amending these rules. In
neither of the two systems, however, is good faith recognized as an independent or
16
free-floating basis for the setting aside or amendment of a contract.
The same view has been taken even more recently in an obiter dictum of
Lord Hope of Craighead in the House of Lords:
[G]ood faith in Scottish contract law, as in South African law, is generally an
underlying principle of an explanatory and legitimating rather than an active or
creative nature.17
I want to ask what, if any, significance these observations about Scots and
South African law may have for principles of good faith and their possible
European development and application. Do they support general scepticism
about a wide-ranging principle of good faith in any future European contract
law, or indicate a gap in the laws of these mixed systems?
Although this paper will focus most on the uncodified mixed legal systems
(i.e. Scotland and South Africa), good faith in the codified mixed systems
(Louisiana, Quebec and Israel) can also be taken into account. Their codes all
now state an explicit general principle of good faith. But in each case an
interesting history lies behind the present law.
But this Article was only introduced into the Louisiana Code in 1984.
16 F Brand & D Brodie, “Good faith in contract law”, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal
Systems, 116.
17 R v Immigration Officer at Prague Airport, ex parte European Roma Rights Centre [2004] UKHL
55, [2005] 2 WLR 1, para 60. See also Lord Hope of Craighead, “The place of a mixed system in
the Common Law world” (2001) 35 Israel LR 1–23 at 16.
50 european contract law
Previously there had been only Article 1901 of the 1870 Code, which had
appeared in virtually the same words in the 1808 Digest of the Civil Laws
(Article 34) and the 1825 Code (Article 1895). Under the heading, “Law for
the parties; performance in good faith”, Article 1901 ran as follows:
Agreements legally entered into have the effect of laws on those who have formed
them. They can not be revoked, unless by mutual consent of the parties, or for
causes acknowledged by law. They must be performed with good faith.
Article 1901 and its predecessors were ultimately derived from the French
Code Civil of 1804, which provided – and provides – in its Article 1134 that,
in addition to being the private law of the parties, contracts must be
performed in good faith.
As well as introducing the general good faith clause in Article 1759, the
1984 revisions of the Louisiana Code transformed the wording but not the
substance of the former Article 1901 into what is now Article 1983:
Law for the parties; performance in good faith
Contracts have the effect of law for the parties and may be dissolved only through
the consent of the parties or on grounds provided by law. Contracts must be
performed in good faith.
18 S Litvinoff, Louisiana Civil Law Treatise Volume 5: The Law of Obligations, 2nd edn (2001), § 1.8
(second emphasis HLM). Note also § 1.14, and cf A A Levasseur, Louisiana Law of Obligations in
General: A Précis (1988), 28–29 (“an inductive reasoning led to the inclusion of LSA-CC Art
1759. From a series of extant Code articles, a general principle was extracted and placed in such
a manner as to govern all obligations. … All in all, the novelty and the merit of [Art 1759] reside[s]
only in the formal existence [it] vest[s] on the article [itself] whereas [its] substance has long been
of the essence of the law of obligations”).
good faith 51
Litvinoff has more recently expounded the potential significance of the over-
riding obligation of good faith in an article in the Tulane Law Review which,
however, draws more heavily on comparative law from Europe and else-
where in the USA, than on actual Louisiana case law.19 He shows that good
faith gives rise to duties not expressly contemplated by parties in their agree-
ments, and is not limited to performance. The article suggests that the juris-
prudence of good faith is not very well developed in Louisiana, save where its
good faith in performance requirement can be elaborated upon from the
extensive case law on the equivalent provision in the Uniform Commercial
Code, §1–203. Litvinoff argues that good faith as well as an express codal
20
provision recognising detrimental reliance as a source of obligation allows
21
the court to remedy culpa in contrahendo; and that it may enable the courts
to deal with impracticability as well as impossibility, and to extend the scope
of lesion. Good faith cannot be confined to the opposite of bad faith, or be
presumed in the absence of bad faith; and it could regulate the exercise of
contractual discretions. Litvinoff concludes, still looking to the future: “[A]
wider judicial freedom to revise contracts may be the ultimate product of the
twentieth-century expansion of the requirement of good faith.”22
The gate is therefore open to a much wider use of an overriding principle
of good faith, but the Louisiana courts have not yet passed through. The
concept is frequently referred to in the jurisprudence but has seldom been
the sole or pre-eminent basis for a judicial decision. There is no sign yet of a
decision developing a doctrine akin to culpa in contrahendo. Typically it is
Article 1983 (contract to be performed in good faith) which is used or cited in
23
the cases, while references to the more general, new, Article 1759 seem
24
often to be in conjunction with citations of Article 1983. In Badalamenti v
25 26
Jefferson Guaranty Bank and Nicholas v Allstate Insurance Co it was held
that application of Article 1759 could not affect the meaning of a clear and
unambiguous contract. But in another case where the contract was either
silent or open-ended, it fell to be interpreted in accordance with good faith.27
Perhaps more remarkably, in Bieber-Guillory v Aswell28 the Court of Appeal,
Third Circuit, remanded for trial a reconventional claim that what were
alleged to be excessive charges for services rendered, were contrary to good
faith under Article 1759.
(2) Quebec
Like its Louisiana forebear, the Civil Code of Lower Canada 1866 drew upon
the French Code of 1804 but, “enacted at a time when economic liberalism
29
prevailed”, contained no provision on good faith. Instead it confined itself
to allowing the addition to a contract, beyond what was express in it, “what is
incident to it according to its nature and in conformity with usage, equity or
law” (Article 1024). It is in the new Quebec Civil Code 1992 (implemented in
1994) that we find the following articles:
Article 6
Every person is bound to exercise his civil rights in good faith.
Article 1375
The parties [to a contract] shall conduct themselves in good faith both at the time
the obligation is created and at the time it is performed or extinguished.
Article 7 also prohibits the exercise of rights “in an excessive and unreason-
able manner contrary to the requirements of good faith”. But under Article
2805, restating Article 2202 of the old code, good faith is always presumed,
unless the law expressly requires that it be proved.
The leading Quebec jurist, Paul Crépeau, called the new provisions on
good faith “a spectacular evolution of the civil law”, resulting from “the fact
that Quebec has joined an international trend that is striving to bring a new
30
sense of morality to contract law”. He says that good faith was first revived
in Quebec by “a strong line of cases, originating mostly from the Supreme
Court of Canada, [giving] new life to the long-forgotten term ‘equity’ in article
1024 of the Civil Code of Lower Canada … in allowing good faith to play, as
the source of implied obligations, a fundamental role in the performance of
27 Kite v Gus Kaplan Inc 747 So 2d 503 (1999) (landlord’s right to change premises leased to tenant
limited to providing space reasonably comparable with previous premises).
28 723 So 2d 1145 (1998).
29 Paul-A Crépeau, The UNIDROIT Principles and the Civil Code of Québec: Shared Values (1998)
(henceforth Crépeau, The UNIDROIT Principles and the Civil Code of Québec), 49.
30 Crépeau, The UNIDROIT Principles and the Civil Code of Québec, 53.
good faith 53
31 Crépeau, The UNIDROIT Principles and the Civil Code of Québec, 52. The cases cited are:
National Bank of Canada v Soucisse [1981] 2 SCR 339 (bank’s duty of full disclosure to sureties);
Bank of Montreal v Kuet Leong Ng [1989] 2 SCR 429 (employee’s duty of good faith to employer);
Houle v National Bank of Canada [1990] 3 SCR 122 (bank’s duty of good faith to customer); Bank
of Montreal v Bail Ltd [1992] 2 SCR 554 (obligation of information between contracting parties).
To the list might now be added CIBC Mortgage Corp v Vasquez [2002] 3 SCR 168 and Banque
national de Paris (Canada) v 165836 Canada Inc [2004] 2 SCR 45 (both Quebec cases, kindly
brought to my attention by Professor Madeleine Cantin-Cumyn).
32 Crépeau, The UNIDROIT Principles and the Civil Code of Québec, 57. For the lack of a culpa in
contrahendo doctrine before the 1992 Code, see P Legrand, “Quebec”, in E H Hondius (ed), Pre-
Contractual Liability: Reports to the XIIIth Congress of the International Academy of
Comparative Law (1991), 273–296, and B Lefebvre, “La bonne foi dans la formation du contrat”
(1992) 37 McGill LJ 1053 at 1056–1058.
33 The website is http://www.canlii.org/.
34 See J-L Baudouin & P-G Jobin, Les Obligations, 5th edn (1998), paras 86–123 (a 6th edn is
imminent); (1996) 26(2) Revue de droit de l’Université de Sherbrooke (special issue on the subject
of good faith); B Lefebvre, La bonne foi dans la formation des contrats (1998); J-L Baudouin,
“Justice et équilibre: la nouvelle moralité contractuelle du droit civil québécois”, in Etudes
offertes á Jacques Ghestin: le contrat au début du XXIe siècle (2001), 29–44; D Lluelles, “La
bonne foi dans l’exécution des contrats et la problématique des sanctions” (2004) 83 Canadian
Bar Review 181. I owe several of these references to the kindness of Professor Madeleine Cantin-
Cumyn and Judge Jean-Louis Baudouin.
54 european contract law
hardship (or imprévision).35 Although commentators are clear that the duty
of good faith entails potential liability (including damages liability) for bad
faith in pre-contractual negotiations,36 there has yet to be a judicial decision
to this effect in Quebec.37 In a case coming from Ontario, and therefore reflec-
ting the Canadian Common Law tradition, the Supreme Court of Canada has
denied the existence of a tortious duty of care in contract negotiations.38 But
there seems no reason to suppose that this decision will have any impact on
developments in Quebec.
(3) Israel
The Israeli Contracts (General Part) Law 1973 provides that “An obligation
or right arising out of a contract shall be fulfilled or exercised in customary
39
manner and in good faith.” There is also a specific provision for culpa in
contrahendo: “In negotiating a contract, a person shall act in customary
40
manner and in good faith.” The elevation of the duty to act in good faith to
the rank of an overriding principle in the formation and performance of
contracts nicely illustrates the character of Israel’s mixity – that of a Common
Law system being Civilianised by a group of jurists who, in the first genera-
tion after the Second World War, “were predominantly Jewish jurists who
had been trained in continental Europe (particularly Germany, Austria and
Italy) and who had fled from Nazi tyranny to Mandatory Palestine in the 1930s.
Despite their experiences in Fascist-dominated Europe, these jurists retained
a strong affinity for continental private law.”41 In the thirty years of the good
35 For discussion of the Article 2805 presumption see contributions by Lefebvre (at 329–335) and
Karim (429–454) in (1996) 26(2) Revue de droit de l’Université de Sherbrooke.
36 See, in addition to other works cited in note 34, Lefebvre, La bonne foi dans la formation des
contrats, 111–163; V Karim, “La règle de la bonne foi prévue dans l’article 1375 du Code civil du
Québec: sa portée et les sanctions qui en découlent” (2000) 41 Les Cahiers de Droit 435, and M
A Grégoire, “Les sanctions de l’obligation de bonne foi lors de la formation et de l’elaboration du
contrat” (2002) 104 Revue du Notariat 173.
37 There have been cases where the courts have recognised the possibility of liability for abuse of the
right to withdraw from negotiations but found it not to apply on the particular facts. See e.g.
Jolicoeur v Rainville, JE 2000–201, and Compagnie France Film Inc v Imax Corporation, JE
2002–5, both CAQ. I am grateful to Professor Daniel Jutras for drawing my attention to these cases.
38 Martel Building Ltd v Canada (2000) 12 SCR 860, discussed in P Giliker, “A role for tort in pre-
contractual negotiations? An examination of English, French and Canadian law” (2003) 52 ICLQ
969. Note that the court (at para 73) expressly declined to comment on the existence of a duty of
good faith in pre-contractual negotiations.
39 Section 39.
40 Section 12(a).
41 S Goldstein in V V Palmer, Mixed Jurisdictions Worldwide: The Third Legal Family (2001), 450
(see also for more detail S Goldstein, “Israel: creating a new legal system from different sources
by jurists of different backgrounds”, in E OÚru…cu…, E Attwooll & S Coyle (eds), Studies in Legal
Systems: Mixed and Mixing (1996), 147).
good faith 55
faith provisions in Israel, it is clear that the courts have taken a vigorous
approach to the introduction of equity in contract law by way of good faith,
and that in particular the provision on pre-contractual liability has been much
used.42 Nili Cohen however observes:
The operation of the duty of good faith in Israeli case law is actually translated to
categories of bad faith. The duty of good faith serves as an ‘excluder’ mechanism:
it does not provide for guidelines for positive conduct of good faith, rather it
categorises negative conduct which is incompatible with the standard of good
43
faith.
42 See S Renner, “Israeli contract law – recent trends and evolution” (1995) 29 Israel LR 360; G
Shalev, “Israel”, in E H Hondius, Pre-Contractual Liability: Reports to the XIIIth Congress of the
International Academy of Comparative Law (1991), 179–194; A M Rabello, “Culpa in contra-
hendo and good faith in the formation of contract: precontractual liability in Israeli law”, in Rabello
(ed), Essays on European Law and Israel (1996); N Cohen, “The effect of the duty of good faith
on a previously common law system: the experience of Israeli law”, in Brownsword et al, Good Faith,
189–212. See also Cohen’s “Pre-contractual duties: two freedoms and the contract to negotiate”,
in J Beatson & D Friedmann (eds), Good Faith and Fault in Contract Law (1995), 25–56.
43 Cohen, in Brownsword et al, Good Faith at 209.
44 See for a collection of such dicta J M Thomson, “Good faith in contracting: a sceptical view”, in
Forte, Good Faith, 64–65, 68–69, 70–71. See also Thomson, “Judicial control of unfair contract
terms”, in Reid & Zimmermann, History, vol 2, 157–174.
56 european contract law
attack any underhand dealing. In effect the law of contract might have come full
circle to the time before the development of the doctrines of facility and circum-
45
vention, undue influence and fraudulent or unfair preferences in bankruptcy.
46
But in Smith v Bank of Scotland, decided by the House of Lords in 1997,
the leading speech of Lord Clyde referred to “the broad principle in the field
of contract law of fair dealing in good faith”.47 He then used this principle to
avoid a personal guarantee, applying in Scots law the protection of a
guarantor against unfair pressure (undue influence or misrepresentation)
resulting from close personal relationship (marriage) with the person whose
debts were being guaranteed; a protection created earlier in English law by
the House of Lords in Barclays Bank plc v O’Brien.48 As a result, the creditor
in a guarantee is bound to take steps to ensure that the guarantor is not
improperly affected by conduct of the person whose debts are to be
49
guaranteed. Good faith was used to this end in Smith because the equity of
constructive notice and the doctrine of presumed undue influence deployed
50
in O’Brien is said to be unknown to Scots law. In subsequent decisions, the
Scottish courts have preferred to continue to use the broad principle of good
faith rather than adopt the detailed guidance for creditors developed in
51
English law by the House of Lords in Royal Bank of Scotland v Etridge. The
preference for a broad principled approach over “matters of ritual, the blind
52
performance of which will secure the avoidance of doom”, is probably to be
explained by a reluctance to find the bank’s omission of one of the many steps
set out in Etridge enough of itself to avoid the guarantee.53
45 McBryde, Contract, para 1-33. Compare the rather different analysis in H L MacQueen, “Good
faith in the Scots law of contract: an undisclosed principle?”, in Forte, Good Faith at 13–17. See
also T M Taylor, “Bona et mala fides”, in Encyclopaedia of the Laws of Scotland, vol 2 (1927); and
two works of T B Smith: British Justice: The Scottish Contribution (1961), 177–179, and Short
Commentary on the Laws of Scotland (1962), 297–298, 835–837.
46 1997 SC (HL) 111.
47 Per Lord Clyde at 121B–C. A similar dictum is found in the earlier case of Trade Development
Bank v David W Haig (Bellshill) Ltd 1983 SLT 510 at 517 per Lord President Emslie.
48 [1994] 1 AC 180.
49 Note that the same result is reached in Article 4:111 PECL; see further the contribution to this
volume of Professor du Plessis (171–174).
50 See G J Junor, “The dust settling: Smith v Bank of Scotland” 1999 JR 67; S M Eden, “Cautionary
tales – the continued development of Smith v Bank of Scotland” (2003) 7 Edinburgh LR 107;
Eden, “More cautionary tales” (2004) 8 Edinburgh LR 276.
51 [2002] 2 AC 773.
52 Etridge at 817, per Lord Clyde (para 95).
53 Clydesdale Bank v Black 2002 SC 555 (where the guarantor argued that the bank had fallen foul
of the Etridge requirements by not holding a meeting with her outwith her husband’s presence at
which they warned her about the consequences of signing the document and advised her to
obtain independent legal advice; but she had in fact taken such advice, the content of which she
did not disclose in her pleadings).
good faith 57
Lord Clyde based his assertion about good faith in contract, not upon any
historical or comparative analysis of Scots law, but upon the authority of com-
paratively modern property law cases dealing with the problem of “double
sales”.54 The aptness of this for contract law is doubtful, since good faith in
property is a much more subjective matter than in contract.55 But there is in
fact some good old authority for general contractual obligations of good faith
in Scots law. The Civilian heritage meant that certain contracts (sale being
the prime example) were always bona fide, but this was increasingly general-
ised to all contracts in the eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries, by
56
authoritative writers such as Bankton, Kames and Bell. Bona fides was
57
actively deployed in judicial decisions of the period as well. In Whitson v
58
Neilson & Co, for example, N ordered 200 tons of flax, to be obtained from
Riga and imported in two ships by the seller W, for delivery in the following
July and August. The first ship arrived back on 23 August, but N declined to
take delivery until the full quantity was available. The second ship arrived on
29 August, but the state of the tides prevented it entering harbour before 2
September. W told N that he would begin unloading the second ship by way
of lighters, starting on 30 August; but N continued to refuse to take delivery,
unless the whole quantity could be delivered before the end of August. In the
end, the flax was delivered on 1 September but N stated that since the
original contract was now terminated they would pay only the current market
price, which was £700 less than the contract one. W, who was insolvent,
raised an action for the balance, to which the Court of Session held he was
entitled. The contract was to be construed bona fide, and the seller had
offered sufficient bona fide implement. “If we were compelled to go to the
utmost strictness in bona fide contracts,” said Lord Alloway, in an interesting
inversion of modern arguments against good faith in contract, “I do not know
59
where there would be an end of it.” Lord Glenlee, who was worried about
taking “more liberties with the terms of mercantile contracts than it [is] safe
54 Rodger (Builders) Ltd v Fawdry 1950 SC 483; Trade Development Bank v David W Haig
(Bellshill) Ltd 1983 SLT 510.
55 This observation also holds good for Professor McBryde’s observation (quoted in text accompany-
ing note 45 above) that certain rights cannot be acquired under a contract by a party in bad faith.
56 See A D M Forte, “Good faith and utmost good faith”, in Forte, Good Faith at 77–79, 96–97; see
also at 13 n 32 (MacQueen).
57 See, in addition to the case cited in the next note, Smith v Bank of Scotland (1829) 7 S 244.
58 (1828) 6 S 579. The case was brought to my attention by the Aberdeen PhD thesis of Mohammed
Al Othman, of which I was external examiner in January 2005. For the declining authority of the
case later in the nineteenth century, see McBryde, Contract, 1st edn (1987), 331 n 74 (not in the
2nd edition); see also Gloag, Contract, 283 n 2.
59 (1828) 6 S 579 at 584.
58 european contract law
to do”,60 nonetheless thought the contract did not stipulate for delivery to be
complete before the end of August. Bona fides meant that ambiguous con-
tracts were given common sense constructions. Lord Pitmilly looked for the
“fair meaning”61 of the bargain; and the Lord Justice-Clerk could “see no
authority for holding, that if there was a hundredweight to deliver at twelve
o’clock at night of the 31st, the purchasers could get quit of the bargain.”62
The contract in this case was one of sale, and so one of bona fides in the
Civilian tradition; but nonetheless the case shows the concept of good faith
being deployed in an active way in a commercial context – termination of
contract for literal non-performance – which today some at least might see as
63
controversial.
It was probably later nineteenth-century will and laissez faire theories that
sterilised any potential good faith might have had to become an active
64
doctrine in Scots law. But cases and writers did develop concepts of terms to
be applied generally in all types of contract unless there was express contrary
provision or specific implication in certain kinds of contract. For example, an
1881 House of Lords authority is still cited for a duty on contracting parties to
do all that is necessary to be done on their part to ensure that the contract is
carried out.65 And writers have accepted such implications as requirements
that contracts be carried out within a reasonable time; that one party does not
do anything to prevent completion of performance by the other or otherwise
derogate from the contract; and that discretionary powers under a contract
66
are exercised reasonably. The doctrine of undue influence, which was first
67
borrowed (with some discrimination) from English law in 1879, also looks
like a product of good faith under another name.
60 At 584.
61 At 585.
62 At 586. The Lord Justice-Clerk, lapsing into anti-semitism, adds (at 586): “To hold this would be
a judaical construction which should not be introduced into bona fide contracts.”
63 Compare the Privy Council’s decision in Union Eagle Ltd v Golden Achievement Ltd [1997] AC
514, where the contract was held terminable when a purchaser tendered payment 10 minutes
after the contractually stipulated time. A deposit was also forfeited. See further E McKendrick,
“Good faith: a matter of principle?”, in Forte, Good Faith, 56–58, and Bridge, in Brownsword et
al, Good Faith, 150–162 (discussing termination in commodities contracts under English law).
See also Zimmermann & Whittaker, Good Faith, discussions of case nos 6, 7, 8, and 24.
64 See Thomson, in Forte, Good Faith at 64–69, 70–71; S C Styles, “Good faith: a principled matter”,
also in Forte, Good Faith at 165–166.
65 Mackay v Dick and Stevenson (1881) 8 R (HL) 37 at 40 per Lord Blackburn. Gloag, Contract, 280;
McBryde, Contract, 483; SME, vol 15, paras 6, 714 (where this is summarised as a duty to co-operate).
66 See MacQueen, in Forte, Good Faith at 16, and MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, para 3.34, for
the authorities. For further comment on discretionary powers, mainly in the employment
context, see Brand & Brodie, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 109–112.
67 Gray v Binny (1879) 7 R 332.
good faith 59
68 Unfair Terms in Consumer Contracts Regulations 1999 (SI 1999/2083), implementing Directive
of 1993.
69 1999 SC 628.
70 Contrary to Professor McBryde’s comment about its irrelevance, quoted above, text accompany-
ing note 45.
71 J M Thomson, “An unsuitable case for suspension?” (1999) 3 Edinburgh LR 394.
72 [1992] 2 AC 128.
73 1998 SLT 1403.
74 Although it might well have been: see the sequel to the case after a proof had been held, McCall’s
Entertainments v South Ayrshire Council (No 2) 1998 SLT 1423.
75 2004 GWD 31–638.
60 european contract law
whether or not the parties have reached finality in their agreement. The
question is whether or not the parties have passed beyond negotiation and
have a concluded agreement.”76 After proof Lord Clarke affirmed that there
was indeed no contract, albeit that Drambuie had been guilty of “stringing
along” Karoulias while intending to contract with a third party.77 Neither
counsel nor the judge argued that there was liability in Scots law comparable
to that which Article 2:301(2) PECL would have imposed on such facts.
For the time being, at least, good faith remains at best an underlying
principle of Scots contract law, which “enables the identification and solution
of problems which the existing rules do not, or seem unable to reach. … The
principle also provides a basis upon which existing rules inconsistent with it
78
can be criticised and reformed, whether judicially or by legislation.” I have
suggested in particular that good faith would help us to make sense of an
inchoate culpa in contrahendo doctrine to be found in a series of cases
79
stretching back to Walker v Milne (the “Melville Monument” case) in 1823,
and also perhaps enable the courts to develop the precedents a little way
beyond the very narrow scope they currently receive in the courts.80 But I
have also argued that while good faith underlies or explains much of our
contract law, it has not been necessary to use it actively to fill gaps in the law;
and given the extent of existing statutory protection for weaker contracting
parties, I should be hesitant about its use to add yet further equity into that
particular branch of contract law.
In December 2004 news broke of an action raised against the Scottish
Parliamentary Corporate Body by one of the unsuccessful tenderers for the
81
building of the Scottish Parliament. The gist of the claim is that the tenderer
was wrongfully excluded from the tender competition in its final stages before
the award of the contract. Part of the background is also that the ultimately
76 At para 33. Note also Robertson Group (Construction) Ltd v Amey-Miller (Edinburgh) Joint
Venture [2005] CSOH 60, in which a pre-contractual letter of intent was held to be “a contract of
an essentially temporary nature”, accepted by commencement of work in accordance with the
letter’s instructions (para 1).
77 2005 SLT 813.
78 MacQueen, in Forte, Good Faith at 18, 19.
79 (1823) 2 S 379. See also the comment of J Blackie, “Good faith and the doctrine of personal bar”
(in Forte, Good Faith) on Walker and the line of nineteenth-century cases descending therefrom:
“These cases (and others later) are so full of references to good faith and bad faith that it is clear
beyond a peradventure that this is what they are about” (at 155).
80 MacQueen, in Forte, Good Faith at 22–33. For the current position see Dawson International plc
v Coats Paton plc 1988 SLT 854. For comparative source material from Europe see H Beale, A
Hartkamp, H Kötz & D Tallon, Cases, Materials and Text on Contract Law (2002), ch 2.2.
81 See BBC News Online 22 Dec 2004 (http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/scotland/4118801.stm) and 2 Feb
2005 (http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/scotland/4229151.stm).
good faith 61
successful tenderer had been first excluded, and then, having adjusted its tender,
readmitted to the competition at the behest of the civil servant running the
project at that stage.82 The claim seems to be based upon possible breaches of
European Union public procurement rules rather than upon any common
law notions of good faith or culpa in contrahendo.83 The advantage the public
procurement rules may offer over any common law liability is the recovery of
damages based upon loss of the contract profit, as distinct from the reimburse-
ment of wasted or reliance expenditure which is as far as the previous
Scottish cases go by way of remedy. It thus does not seem very likely that the
Scottish Parliament case will provide an opportunity for belated recognition
of good faith duties in pre-contractual negotiations. Indeed, it looks as
though the first issue to be addressed is that of prescription, since the alleged
breaches of duty took place more than five years before the action was raised
84
in December 2004. On the other hand, the public procurement rules demon-
strate a recognition of the validity of pre-contractual obligations in at least
some cases; and while public body contracts may be particularly strong cases
for insisting on the existence of such obligations,85 it does not follow that the
private, and in particular the commercial, sector should be wholly free of them.
82 For the factual background so far as publicly known at the time the action was raised, see the Final
Report of the Holyrood Inquiry as conducted by Lord Fraser of Carmyllie QC (Sept 2004,
accessible at http://www.holyroodinquiry.org/FINAL_report/report.htm), ch 7. Note in particular
Lord Fraser’s comment in his conclusions that “[i]t does however appear to me, on elementary
considerations of fairness as between competing tenderers, that if one tenderer was effectively
permitted to change a very material aspect of the financial basis upon which its tender was
submitted that is an opportunity which should have been afforded to the others.”
83 For the procurement rules, see SME, vol 3, para 17 (note also Cumulative Service and Service
Update); Chitty on Contracts, 29th edn (2004), vol I, ch 10(7). Note too that on 16 March 2005
the European Commission announced an investigation of possible breaches of the procurement
rules: see its press release at http://europa.eu.int/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=IP/05/
314&format=HTML&aged=0&language=EN&guiLanguage=en.
84 There is also an issue about whether the SPCB is the correct, or the only, possible defender, given
that the contract was awarded by the Scottish Office before the SPCB came into existence. But
see Scotland Act 1998, s 23.
85 See the comments of Finn J in Hughes Aircraft Systems Ltd v Airservices Australia (1997) 146
ALR 1 at 37–42. I cannot here resist also quoting a splendid letter to the Scotsman newspaper by
Mr Ian Arnott, published on 2 Dec 2004 under the heading, “Building on Good Faith”, in which
he commented critically on the findings of the Civil Service Commissioner that the civil servants
involved in the Scottish Parliament building project were blameless since all their decisions were
taken in good faith. Mr Arnott said: “There may be no universal definition of what constitutes
good faith, but there is a general understanding of what it means, and the commissioner’s concept
seems to be elastic to an unusual degree and certainly questionable.” Amongst other subsequent
scathing remarks, Mr Arnott added, with particular pertinence to the present discussion: “Was it
good faith that bent the rules of tendering to allow the reintroduction and appointment of a
previously rejected firm of contract managers?” Perhaps in due course the progress of the Court
of Session action will give Mr Arnott a greater sense of justice being seen to be done.
62 european contract law
In South Africa, however, the existence and scope of open-ended norms such
as good faith in contract law seems to be more hotly disputed than in Scot-
88
land. As Hutchison noted, there were one or two judges prepared to go
further than his conclusion. In Eerste Nasionale Bank van Suidelike Afrika
89
Bpk v Saayman NO, the facts of which were comparable in some respects to
the O’Brien, Smith and Etridge cases described earlier, a sick old woman
stood as surety to a bank for the debts of her son. The woman’s daughter was
subsequently appointed her curatrix and obtained an order from the court
that the suretyship was unenforceable. The majority decided the case on the
basis of the woman’s lack of capacity, but Olivier JA founded his concurring
decision squarely on a doctrine of good faith. In Mort NO v Henry Shields-
86 See R Zimmermann, “Good faith and equity”, in Zimmermann & Visser, Southern Cross, esp at
239–255.
87 D Hutchison, “Good faith in the South African law of contract”, in Brownsword et al, Good Faith,
213–242 at 229–231.
88 See e.g. Zimmermann, in Zimmermann & Visser, Southern Cross; A Cockrell, “Second-guessing
the exercise of contractual power on rationality grounds” [1997] Acta Juridica 26; J Lewis,
“Fairness in South African contract law” (2003) 120 SALJ 330; G Lubbe, “Taking fundamental
rights seriously: the Bill of Rights and its implications for the development of contract law” (2004)
121 SALJ 395.
89 1997 (4) SA 302 (SCA).
good faith 63
since the well-known case of Sasfin v Beukes in 1989,102 and it was put into play
in Afrox, failing because only one basis for doing so was put forward, viz certain
provisions of the Constitution which did not point clearly to the conclusion
sought. Alfred Cockrell and I have argued that public policy falls to be distin-
guished from good faith. The latter is essentially concerned with the relation-
ship of the contracting parties, albeit applying external community standards to
them, while public policy deals with more general issues such as the prevention
of crime and wrongs, the protection of marriage and family life, the right to
work, and the proper administration of justice. South African law has a much
more dynamic concept of public policy than Scotland, where there has been
what Cockrell and I call a “hardening of the categories”; it offers some
103
interesting lessons for PECL, a point to which I will briefly return below.
The Supreme Court of Appeal has reaffirmed, but also developed, its basic
stance on good faith in its most recent discussion of the subject, in South
104
African Forestry Co Ltd v York Timbers Ltd. The case involved contracts
for the supply of logs from SAFCOL plantations to the defendants’ sawmills.
The contracts, which were to continue for an unspecified period, contained
mechanisms for the revision of prices from time to time, and for termination
should the parties be unable to agree new prices. But the contract was later
amended so that in the event of disagreement over price revision the matter
was to be referred to a Government Minister who was empowered to refer
the dispute on to arbitration if he were of the opinion that no agreement
could be reached. There was also provision for the Minister to settle disputes
about other terms subject to revision, but if his decision was unacceptable to
the sawmill company, the contract would continue on the old terms, but sub-
ject to termination after five years. The sawmill company also had the right to
terminate the contract at any time on one year’s written notice, while should
the Minister at any stage be of the opinion that it would be in the interest of
the wood industry or of the country as a whole to terminate the contract, then
SAFCOL would be entitled to cancel the contract on giving the sawmill
company written notice of at least five years. The policy behind this remark-
ably unbalanced contract was to encourage private sector investment in the
sector, with long-term agreements giving investors in a capital-intensive
industry time to recoup their investment, as well as some security of tenure.105
For many years SAFCOL sought price revision under their contract with
York; but they were frustrated, or strung along, by an adroit series of
manouevres by York, which enabled the latter to continue to sell its timber in
the market at prices up to 60 per cent lower than those of competitors who
had agreed price revisions with SAFCOL under other contracts. SAFCOL
had great difficulty in persuading the relevant Minister to become involved,
and finally went to court to seek an order that the York contracts had been
terminated. Their claim was based upon breach by York of an implied term in
the contracts, to the effect that York would act in accordance with the dictates
of reasonableness, fairness and good faith when SAFCOL sought price
revisions under the contract.
Giving the judgment of the court, Brand JA rejected SAFCOL’s conten-
tions. He reaffirmed the approach to good faith in the Brisley and Afrox cases
as an underlying value; to allow good faith a more active role would
undermine certainty to an unacceptable degree. A term could be implied on
the basis of good faith, but not to override what the parties had intended as
that could be derived from interpretation of the contract’s express terms.
But Brand JA then went on to say that “in the interpretation process, the
notions of fairness and good faith … have a role to play”, and continued (para
32):
While a court is not entitled to superimpose on the clearly expressed intention of
the parties its notion of fairness, the position is different when a contract is
ambiguous. In such a case the principle that all contracts are governed by good
faith is applied and the intention of the parties is determined on the basis that they
negotiated with one another in good faith. [33] Having regard to the provisions of
clause 3.2 it is clear that it confers the right upon a party (in this instance, Safcol)
who found it impossible to come to an agreement on revision of price, firstly, to
approach the Minister as a preliminary step to arbitration and, secondly, to refer
the matter to arbitration if the Minister should express the opinion that no
agreement could be reached. Although the clause does not expressly impose any
duty or obligation on the other party (York) the corollary of the rights conferred
upon Safcol is an obligation or duty on the part of York not to frustrate Safcol in the
exercise of these rights. This follows logically from the structure of the rights and
duties the parties themselves created. [34] However, had there been any
interpretative ambiguity as to the existence of such a duty or obligation on the part
of York, it is removed by considerations of reasonableness, fairness and good faith.
In other words, even where the logical consequences of the rights and duties may
not necessitate such an inference, the underlying principle of good faith requires
its importation.
Brand JA then went on to say that York had indeed frustrated and delayed
SAFCOL in the exercise of its rights:
good faith 67
106 1999 SLT 721. See also E & J Glasgow Ltd v UGC Estates Ltd [2005] CSOH 63.
107 Compare, however, Thomson v Thomas Muir (Waste Management) Ltd 1995 SLT 403 (described
in MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, para 3.37).
108 2001 (1) SA 853 (SCA).
68 european contract law
E. LESSONS
What lessons are to be drawn from all this mixed system material? One is
obvious: in all the systems there is current, active debate about good faith in
contract, along with relevant activity in legislation, the courts and legal
practice. This is a significant subject, and it is right that there should also be
discussion about it at a European level. Further, if European legal develop-
ment moves forward by way of instruments, whether legislative or “soft law”
in character, specific reference in them to good faith is highly likely. Indeed,
such reference is already frequently made: see the Unfair Terms, Commer-
cial Agents and Distance Selling Directives, for example. The UNIDROIT
PICC 2004 also use the concept of good faith and fair dealing similarly to
PECL (although the differences between the two instruments deserve more
111
exploration than is possible here). The European Code of Contract
prepared by the Pavia Academy of European Private Lawyers gives good
faith a significant role in pre-contractual liability (Article 6), implying terms
(Article 32), interpretation (Article 39(1)), determining the effects of the
contract (Article 44), performance (Article 75), and suspension of performance
112 I have used the translation published in September 2004 as a special issue of the Edinburgh
Law Review, under the title European Code of Contract.
113 H McGregor, Contract Code drawn up on behalf of the English Law Commission (1993),
section 201. See further McGregor, “The codification of contracts in England and Scotland”, in
A M Rabello (ed), Aequitas and Equity: Equity in Civil Law and Mixed Jurisdictions (1997).
114 See the decision to set aside an extortionate credit bargain reported on BBC News Online 28
Oct 2004: http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/england/merseyside/3962963.stm. A UK Government Bill
to amend the law on extortionate credit bargains is currently before the Westminster Parlia-
ment (see further Professor du Plessis’ contribution to this volume, at 165 n 74).
70 european contract law
be another such area, although the creation of such a liability would meet
opposition from many at least in British legal as well as business circles.
By and large, good faith appears to be primarily an “excluder” in all the
mixed systems, working to prevent bad faith (or perhaps more accurately,
unreasonableness) more than to impose positive requirements of behaviour
on contracting parties. The main exception noted in this paper is the
sequence of cases in Scotland beginning with Smith v Bank of Scotland,
under which the courts have required banks to achieve certain standards of
conduct in their dealings with prospective guarantors where they have a close
personal relationship with the debtor whose debts are to be guaranteed. In
doing this, the courts have taken into account the banks’ own Code of
Practice on the matter – in the language of PECL, they have referred to
generally applicable and reasonable usages and practices. But even here the
courts have looked at all the circumstances, so that, for example, it was not
fatal to the guarantee’s enforceability for the bank to have failed to advise the
prospective guarantor away from her matrimonial home that she needed to
take independent legal advice, when she had anyway taken such advice and
moreover had not disclosed its substance to the court where she was seeking
to reduce the guarantee.115
Against this background, what should be done in European contract law?
There is a debate already about this on the Continent, and I want here to pick
out some recent contributions to that discussion. The Dutch scholar Martijn
Hesselink argues that there is no need for a general principle of good faith in
a European contract code, so long as the rules already developed on the basis
116
of good faith are clearly articulated and formulated as rules in the system.
If a general principle is left in, its function should mainly be to remind judges
of the need to develop the law by way of interpretation, correction and
supplementation of contracts; in Zimmermann’s words, “an invitation, or
reminder, for courts to do what they do anyway: to develop the law in
117
accordance with the perceived needs of their times”. Hein Ko…tz has a
similar, but more positive, view of the role to be played by good faith in Euro-
pean contract law. In an article in which he sets out to allay English lawyers’
fear of good faith, he argues that it is a mechanism by which judicial decisions
develop the law incrementally and case by case (the Fallgruppen approach of
German law). Ko…tz concludes: “An open texture calling for judicial amplification
seems preferable because the whole project [of a European Civil Code/
Contract Law] might fail unless European judges were left with an area of
play larger perhaps than that acceptable in any national legal system.”118
Finally, Matthias Storme argues that while judicial activism should be
contained by the formulation of as many precise rules as possible, an open-
ended rule of good faith which is more than just the absence of bad faith, is
needed in European contract law, because good faith cannot be exhausted as
a source of more specific norms, and may also act as a corrective against the
119
way rules originally based on good faith subsequently develop. Thus, I
think, he would allow Articles 1:102 and 1:106 PECL to co-exist with more
precise rules (such as Article 4:110 PECL) also invoking good faith in their
text. Further, the specific instances of good faith in the code give guidance as
to the scope of the general norm. Perhaps too this refutes Hugh Beale’s
argument that Article 1:102 PECL cannot be meant as an over-arching clause
120
because there are more specific controls elsewhere in PECL. Storme
suggests that the real issue is judicial activism: how to encourage it, without
having too much of it. He thinks the answer may lie in the approach of the
Swiss Civil Code, requiring the judge exercising discretion to do so by way of
a formulation of a rule:
If no relevant provision can be found in a statute, the judge must decide in
accordance with the customary law and, in its absence, in accordance with the rule
which he would, were he the legislator, adopt. In so doing he must pay attention to
121
accepted doctrine and tradition.
From all this, I draw the message that a general good faith principle (or
equivalent) should and probably will be included in a European contract
code or restatement or Common Frame of Reference, as a way of enabling
judges to meet the probability that cases will arise which will be at best
incompletely provided for by whatever more specific rules there may be. It
will have to be a European principle, not one based upon any notion of the
concept found in any given legal system within the European Union; and its
118 H Ko…tz, “Towards a European Civil Code: the duty of good faith”, in P Cane & J Stapleton (eds),
The Law of Obligations: Essays in Celebration of John Fleming (1998) at 258.
119 “Good faith and contents of contracts in European private law”, in S Espiau & A Vaquer Aloy,
Bases of a European Contract Law (2003), 17–30.
120 See above, text accompanying note 10.
121 Article 1 paras 2 and 3 Swiss Civil Code. Cf the approach to equity often found in Louisiana
courts: V V Palmer, The Louisiana Civilian Experience (2005), 249–250, esp at n 98. See also
Stapleton (1999) 49 CLP 1 at 28–35, arguing that recognition of good faith also entails the
deployment of “incidence” rules, identifying relevant factors in determining when the require-
ment bites and when it does not.
72 european contract law
role will be determined in the first place by the other specific rules in the
European system. Good faith should be seen, not so much as an over-arching
as an underlying principle, much as it is at present in Scots and South African
law. As an underlying principle, its role will be mainly to exclude bad faith,
possibly attached to a presumption of good faith akin to that found in Article
2805 of the Quebec Civil Code.122 But the principle can in some circum-
stances be the basis for new rules (e.g. like that in the Smith case in Scots law)
or re-rationalisations of existing authority or rules to develop them further (as
with my suggestions for culpa in contrahendo in Scots law); or simply a
guideline in the application of existing rules.
Whether this is quite what PECL gives us is perhaps a moot point. My
general impression, despite Hugh Beale’s arguments to the contrary, is that
Article 1:201 PECL is intended to be an over-arching principle, capable of
over-powering rather than just tempering freedom of contract; and that the
appearance of good faith in other, more specific, articles must be seen, as
suggested by Matthias Storme, as simply showing places where the drafters
found it especially helpful to reinforce the strong role good faith is intended
to play throughout the Principles. Having said that, it is unfortunate that in
some areas where it would be very important to know whether or not good
faith had a part to play, such as termination for non-performance, there is
nothing specific in the black-letter text, and the ambiguous comments on the
matter are placed at a considerable distance from the actual Articles on
termination. Beale’s point about the need to revise PECL to make the general
approach more explicit, whether it be an over-arching or an underlying one,
is therefore well made in general, and needs, like good faith itself, to be taken
seriously. Indeed, I find myself in agreement with what I take from his paper
to be his preferred position on the question of good faith, seeing it as
primarily an important underlying principle, albeit certainly not a wholly
inactive or inert one.
A final observation concerns the interaction between the good faith
principle, whatever its content and role, and the “public policy” clause in
PECL:
Article 15:101: Contracts Contrary To Fundamental Principles
A contract is of no effect to the extent that it is contrary to principles recognised as
fundamental in the laws of the Member States of the European Union.
122 See above, text accompanying notes 29–30. Stapleton (1999) 49 CLP 1 at 17–20, argues in
favour of a presumption of good faith. See also Article 1:201 PECL Comment F.
good faith 73
A. INTRODUCTION
B. THE OFFER AND ACCEPTANCE MODEL
C. CONTRACT FORMATION INTER ABSENTES
(1) Development in Scotland
(2) Development in South Africa
(3) Justification and problems
(4) The PECL approach
(5) Comparison
D. CONCLUSION
A. INTRODUCTION
It was the Natural lawyers of the seventeenth century, especially in France,
who developed the concept of consensus as the basis of modern contract law.1
Roman-Dutch authorities embraced this notion and further accepted that
consensus can be analysed in terms of two declarations of will, i.e. offer and
2
acceptance. These Civilian concepts also had a profound influence on the
development of contract law in the Common Law. In England, especially,
Pothier’s writings on the subject became influential and resulted in the
3
adoption of the offer and acceptance analysis. English jurists in turn further
developed and refined offer and acceptance to a model of contract
4
formation.
The offer and acceptance model is a standard feature of modern contract
5
law in South Africa and Scotland. Typically of both these mixed legal
74
offer, acceptance and the moment of contract formation 75
systems, the model was received from Civilian sources, but has been signifi-
cantly influenced by the Common Law.6 As such, the offer and acceptance
model presents an interesting subject matter for a comparative analysis of the
newly formulated PECL7 viewed against the mixed legal systems of South
Africa and Scotland. The focus in this paper is specifically on that aspect of
the Scots and South African model that represents the most evident
Common Law influence, namely the rules pertaining to inter absentes
8
contracting and specifically the so-called postal rule. The goal of the analysis
is on the one hand to determine to what extent PECL can be likened to mixed
legal systems such as South Africa and Scotland. On the other hand, and
perhaps more importantly, it is to see whether any reciprocal lessons can be
learned. Part B starts off the discussion with a comparison of the general offer
and acceptance models found in the three systems. Part C then focuses
specifically on the approach to inter absentes contracting, and it begins with
the situation in Scots and South African law (1) and (2). That is followed by a
more general discussion of the justification traditionally advanced for the
adoption of the postal rule of contract formation and the problems emerging
from the application of this rule: C(3). Part C(4) sets out the specific
approach to inter absentes contracting adopted by PECL. Subsequently, the
rules developed in Scots and South African law are compared to those
adopted by PECL. Finally, some conclusions will be drawn.
6 Hutchison, in Zimmermann & Visser, Southern Cross, 173–174; J E du Plessis, “Common Law
influences on the law of contract and unjustified enrichment in some mixed legal systems” (2003)
78 Tulane LR 219 at 230; McBryde, Contract, 7–11; G F Lubbe, “Formation of contract” in Reid
& Zimmermann, History, vol 2, 44.
7 PECL, Chapter 2 Section 2.
8 This is also sometimes referred to as the mailbox rule or dispatch rule.
9 Stair, Institutions, 1.10.3 (“So then an offer accepted is a contract, because it is the deed of two,
the offerer and accepter”); De Wet & van Wyk, Kontraktereg, vol 1, 32; Van der Merwe et al,
Kontraktereg, 52; McBryde, Contract, 123; MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, 39.
10 De Wet & Van Wyk, Kontraktereg, 32–33; McBryde, Contract, 124–125; Gloag, Contract, 44; Van
der Merwe et al, Kontraktereg, 52–53; MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, 39, 54–55.
76 european contract law
21 Article 2:201(1)(a) PECL; Van der Merwe et al, Kontraktereg, 54; McBryde, Contract,128; SME,
vol 15, paras 615, 616, 620; Gloag, Contract, 16–17, 24–25; Walker, Contract, para 7.6;
MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, 40.
22 Article 2:201(1)(b) PECL; Van der Merwe et al, Kontraktereg, 55; McBryde, Contract, 128;
SME, vol 15, para 620; Walker, Contract, para 7.6; MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, 40.
23 Article 2:201(2) PECL; Van der Merwe et al, Kontraktereg, 59; McBryde, Contract,134–135;
SME, vol 15, paras 628–630; Gloag, Contract, 16–17; Walker, Contract, paras 7.7, 7.45, 7.46;
MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, 44.
24 Article 2:201(2) PECL; Van der Merwe et al, Kontraktereg, 54; McBryde, Contract,132–133;
SME, vol 15, para 627; Gloag, Contract, 22; Walker, Contract, para 7.19; MacQueen & Thomson,
Contract, 44–45.
25 In Scots law this is often referred to as an invitation to treat: SME, vol 15, para 620.
26 Van der Merwe et al, Kontraktereg, 55–56; McBryde, Contract, 128–131; SME, vol 15, paras
620–626; Gloag, Contract, 21–24; Walker, Contract, paras 7.7–7.13; MacQueen & Thomson,
Contract, 40–44.
27 Crawley v Rex 1909 TS 1105; Campbell v Ker 24 Feb 1810 FC referred to in SME, vol 15, para
621; McBryde, Contract, 129; Walker, Contract, para 7.9; MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, 42.
28 Article 2:201(1) and (2) PECL.
29 Article 2:201(3) PECL.
78 european contract law
these circumstances will have to show that the advertisement or display did
not amount to an offer.30 Like South African and Scots law, PECL allows for
offers to be revoked prior to acceptance.31
Under all three systems any unequivocal indication of assent to the offer
will amount to an acceptance.32 Such indication may be either by words or
conduct, but must come from the offeree.33 Generally, the acceptance must
34
simply indicate assent to all the terms and conditions of the offer. In each
system this general statement presents a somewhat simplified view of the
model, and exceptions to the general position are recognised, allowing for
35
some variance between offer and acceptance. In keeping with the general
position, and subject to the exceptions just noted, anything more or less than
simple consent to the terms of the offer will amount to a rejection of the offer,
36
and will constitute a counter-offer under all three systems.
From the above discussion, it seems that there is a fair amount of similarity
between PECL on the one hand and Scots and South African law on the
other, as far as the general characteristics of the offer and acceptance model
are concerned. This is not surprising in the light of the shared use of the
model in Civil and Common Law systems noted above. More interesting
though, for present purposes, is PECL’s approach to inter absentes con-
tracting. As also noted above, it is in this aspect of the principally Civilian offer
and acceptance model that our mixed legal systems show significant Common
Law influence. In analysing the “mixed character” of PECL, it is to this
aspect of the model that we therefore have to turn our attention.
30 An alternative defence would be that the condition under which the presumed offer was made
was not fulfilled, i.e. that the stock of goods or capacity to supply the services was exhausted prior
to the other party’s purported acceptance of that offer.
31 Article 2:202 PECL. Van der Merwe et al, Kontraktereg, 57; McBryde, Contract, 140; SME, vol
15, para 647; Gloag, Contract, 37; Walker, Contract, para 7.32; MacQueen & Thomson, Contract,
45.
32 Article 2:204 PECL; McBryde, Contract, 145; SME, vol 15, para 631; Gloag, Contract, 26–30;
Walker, Contract, paras 7.38–7.39; Van der Merwe et al, Kontraktereg, 58–60; MacQueen &
Thomson, Contract, 46.
33 Article 2:204(1) PECL; McBryde, Contract, 145–147, 156; SME, vol 15, paras 631, 632, 638;
Gloag, Contract, 26–30; Walker, Contract, paras 7.38, 7.45, 7.48, 7.66; Van der Merwe et al,
Kontraktereg, 63–64; MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, 46, 47–48.
34 Articles 2:204 and 2:208 PECL; McBryde, Contract, 150; SME, vol 15, para 635; Gloag,
Contract, 39–42; Walker, Contract, para 7.49; Van der Merwe et al, Kontraktereg, 59–60;
MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, 46.
35 In the light of Professor Forte’s chapter on the battle of the forms, this aspect of offer and
acceptance will not be discussed here.
36 Article 2:208(1) PECL; McBryde, Contract, 152; SME, vol 15, para 635; Gloag, Contract, 39;
Walker, Contract, para 7.49; Van der Merwe et al, Kontraktereg 59–60; MacQueen & Thomson,
Contract, 46.
offer, acceptance and the moment of contract formation 79
notably Stair, did not express an opinion on the point.44 In both South Africa
and Scotland it was thus left to the courts to develop an appropriate approach
to contract formation inter absentes, without much guidance from the
traditional sources.
44 Thomson v James (1855) 18 D 1 at 12–13; see Lubbe, in Reid & Zimmermann, History, vol 2, 38;
du Plessis (2003) 78 Tulane LR 219 at 231. Although there is reference to Bell’s Commentaries in
the early Scottish case of Dunlop v Higgins [1848] 1 HLC 381 as authority for the proposition that
the expedition theory applies in Scotland, Bell’s statements have been interpreted as referring to
English rather than Scots law (Huntley, Contract, 137).
45 Thomson v James at 1; McBryde, Contract, 157; SME, vol 15, para 641; Gloag, Contract, 28;
Walker, Contract, para 7.55; Hogg, Obligations, 44; Huntley, Contract, 129; MacQueen &
Thomson, Contract, 48.
46 Hogg, Obligations, 45. This uncertainty is augmented by the position pertaining to the revocation
of offers in an inter absentes context. Although the clear rule seems to be that such revocation will
only be effective if it is communicated to the offeree before acceptance, it is less clear what is
meant with “communication” in this respect. In Burnley v Alford (1919) 2 SLT 123 it was said that
as a general rule a revocation of an offer must be “brought to the knowledge or mind of the party
holding the offer” to be effective, i.e. applying the information theory, but that such rule is not of
rigid application and that mere delivery to the address of the offeree may suffice in certain
circumstances, i.e. applying the reception theory.
47 Entores Ltd v Miles Far East Corporation [1955] 2 QB 327 at 332 per Denning LJ; Brinkibon Ltd
v Stahag Stahl und Stahlwarenhandelsgesselschaft mbH [1982] 1 All ER 293, HL.
48 SME, vol 15, para 643; Walker, Contract, paras 7.55, 7.63; Huntley, Contract, 129–131; see also
Hogg, Obligations, 45; MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, 49, 52; Gloag, Contract, 28, 38.
49 A notable dissent from the above view is the argument presented by Professor McBryde
(Contract at 157–158) that knowledge on the part of the offeror is not a requirement for the
existence of a contract. He argues that the offeree need have only an intention to accept and have
moved beyond the deliberative stage. The focus should thus be on the actions of the offeree and
particularly whether she has indicated an irrevocable intention to be bound. McBryde further
states that indications to the contrary in the case law, requiring actual knowledge on the part of the
offeror, are remnants of the (now outdated) adherence to a subjective basis of contractual liability.
See also Hogg, Obligations, 45 (“Putting the written acceptance through the offeror’s letterbox
would be sufficient to constitute acceptance”).
offer, acceptance and the moment of contract formation 81
50 SME, vol 15, para 637; McBryde, Contract, 145–147; Hogg, Obligations, 45; Gloag, Contract,
34–35; Walker, Contract, para 7.56; MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, 48–49. This is not to
suggest that the offeror has an unlimited capacity to prescribe any mode of acceptance. The
offeror cannot prescribe all types of action as constituting acceptance, especially where
acceptance is to be in the form of conduct rather than express communication. Also, apart from
exceptional circumstances, silence cannot be prescribed as constituting acceptance. In this regard
see McBryde, Contract, 146–150; SME, vol 15, paras 637–640; Gloag, Contract, 28–29;
MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, 48–49.
51 See note 50 above.
52 Postal contracts, in this context, are contracts concluded completely by means of the post, that is
where both offer and acceptance are made by means of letters sent by post.
53 Huntley, Contract, 136–137; SME, vol 15, para 644; Lubbe, in Reid & Zimmermann, History, vol
2, 35.
54 (1818) 1 B & Ald 681. See further S Gardner, “Trashing with Trollope: a deconstruction of the
postal rules in contract” (1992) 12 Oxford JLS 170; Lubbe, in Reid & Zimmermann, History, vol
2, 35 n 378.
55 (1841) 7 Mee and Wels 515.
56 At 400.
57 At 400.
58 As the application of the expedition theory in cases concerning postal contracts became known.
59 (1855) 18 D1.
60 See Report on Formation of Contract: Scottish Law and the United Nations Convention on
Contracts for the International Sale of Goods (Scot Law Com No 144, 1993), para 4.4.
82 european contract law
never reaches the offeror,61 serious doubts exist about this for Scots law.62
Logically, the adoption of the expedition theory in postal contracts should
rule out the possibility of retraction of an acceptance already posted. How-
ever, some commentators have read the case of Countess of Dunmore v
Alexander63 as holding that an acceptance, once posted, may indeed be
retracted should the retraction reach the offeror either before or at least at
64
the same time as the acceptance. Others have doubted whether this is the
65
correct reading of the case. Since Countess of Dunmore preceded the adop-
tion of the postal rule in Scots law it has also been argued that it has been
66
overruled by the decisions accepting the postal rule. It is also not altogether
clear whether the postal rule also applies to other forms of inter absentes
contracting in Scots law. In English law the rule has been applied to
67 68
acceptance by telegram, but not by telephone and telex. It remains to be
69
seen whether this will be followed in Scots law.
Most recently, the Scottish Law Commission has published a report on
contract formation in Scots law containing a recommendation that the postal
rule be abolished in Scots law.70 The report noted the many anomalies
created by the rule and the large measure of uncertainty associated with the
rule in Scots law.71 It furthermore pointed out that all consultees in the
commission’s deliberations leading up to the report supported a change of
the postal rule and that none of them put forward any argument in favour of
61 Household Fire and Carriage Accident Insurance Co v Grant (1879) 4 Ex D 216, CA.
62 Higgins & Sons v Dunlop, Wilson & Co (1847) 9 D 1407 at 1414 per Lord Fullerton; Thomson v
James (note 45) at 12 per Lord President McNeill; Mason v Benhar Coal Co (1882) 9 R 883 per
Lord Shand; Gloag, Contract, 34; Walker, Contract, para 7.60; SME, vol 15, para 644; MacQueen
& Thomson, Contract, 50.
63 (1830) 9 S 190.
64 See SME, vol 15, para 644; Gloag, Contract, 38; MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, 51.
65 SME, vol 15, para 644; Walker, Contract, para 7.69; Huntley, Contract, 149.
66 Walker, Contract, para 7.69 with specific reference to the remarks in Thomson v James (note 45)
at 13 per Lord President McNeill and 25 per Lord Deas, doubting Countess of Dunmore;
MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, 51. Similar uncertainty exists regarding the retraction of an
offer made through the post when such retraction objectively reaches the offeree prior to
dispatch of the acceptance, but only comes to the attention of the offeree after such dispatch. See
note 46 above for a discussion of Burnley v Alford.
67 Stevenson v McLean (1880) 5 QBD 346; Bruner v Moore [1904] 1 Ch 305.
68 See the Entores and Brinkibon cases, both note 47.
69 As noted above, note 47 and accompanying text, Scottish commentators have found these English
cases particularly persuasive regarding the adoption of the information theory in Scots law.
McBryde, Contract at 160 also notes that the reasoning for the adoption of the postal rule in
Thomson v James is not restricted to posting and may therefore lead Scottish courts to extend the
rule to other forms of inter absentes communication. See also Hogg, Obligations, 46.
70 Report on Formation of Contract (Scot Law Com No 144, 1993), paras 4.4–4.7.
71 At para 4.4.
offer, acceptance and the moment of contract formation 83
72 At para 4.6.
73 Formation of Contract (Scot Law Com Memorandum No 36, 1977).
74 See Report on Formation of Contract (Scot Law Com No 144, 1993), para 4.6.
75 Scot Law Com No 144 (1993), para 1.2.
76 At para 1.7.
77 At para 4.7.
78 At paras 2.11, 4.2–4.4.
79 Bloom v American Swiss Watch Co 1915 AD 100 at 102.
80 Bloom at 102. See also Dietrichsen v Dietrichsen 1911 TPD 486, predating that case, where
Wessels J came to similar conclusions.
81 Laws v Rutherford 1924 AD 261; Driftwood Properties (Pty) Ltd v McLean 1971 (3) SA 591 (A);
S v Henckert 1981 (3) SA 445 (A); Westinghouse Brake & Equipment (Pty) Ltd v Bilger
Engineering (Pty) Ltd 1986 (2) SA 555 (A); Amcoal Collieries Ltd v Truter 1990 (1) SA 1 (A); Seef
Commercial & Industrial Properties (Pty) Ltd v Silberman 2001 (3) SA 952 (SCA); Smeiman v
Volkersz 1954 (4) SA 170 (C); Tel Peda Investigation Bureau (Pty) Ltd v Van Zyl 1965 (4) SA 475
(E); Millman v Klein 1986 (1) SA 465 (C); Lines v Liberty Life Association of Africa Ltd 1990 (3)
SA 268 (T); De Jager v Burger 1994 (1) SA 402 (C); Ideal Fastener Corporation CC v Book Vision
(Pty) Ltd (t/a Colour Graphic) 2001 (3) SA 1028 (D); Van der Merwe et al, Kontraktereg, 53 ff;
Kerr, Contract, 111; Christie, Contract, 76; Hutchison, in Zimmermann & Visser, Southern
Cross, 177, 180; De Wet & Van Wyk, Kontraktereg, 37; Lubbe & Murray, Contract, 40.
84 european contract law
The single exception to the information theory’s sway in South Africa is the
application of the expedition theory to postal contracts. This exception is one
of the best examples of the direct influence of English law on the South African
law of contract. In the light of the uncertainty amongst Roman-Dutch
authorities regarding the appropriate theory concerning inter absentes
contract formation, the unanimity reached in English law in the early nine-
82
teenth century of applying the expedition theory to postal contracts has
been too tempting for South African judges to resist. Early cases, such as the
83 84 85
Fern Gold Mining case, Bal v Van Staden and Naude v Malcolm, all
pointed towards increasing English law influence on the issue. The leading
case of Cape Explosive Works Ltd v South African Oil & Fat Industries Ltd
86
was decided in 1921. The contracts at issue had both been concluded through
the mail, the offerors mailing their offers from the Transvaal and Natal Pro-
vinces respectively and the offeree mailing its acceptance in both instances
from the Cape Province. The defendants argued that, since the acceptances
were only communicated to them outside the Cape Province, the contracts
were also concluded outside that province, in line with the information
theory. Kotzé JP discussed the opinions of the Roman-Dutch authorities in
some detail and came to the conclusion that no single approach can be
discerned in Roman-Dutch law.87 His analysis of the more recent discussion
of the issue confirmed that the difference in opinion continued in most
foreign jurisdictions such as Dutch, French and German law.88 In contrast,
the judge noted that English law unequivocally adopted the expedition
89
theory in the case of postal contracts such as the one before the court. His
analysis of the early South African cases on point indicated a leaning towards
the English rule, but confirmed that the issue had not been decided in South
90
Africa. Accordingly, he laid down the principle that postal contracts will
come into existence in South Africa upon the dispatch of the acceptance.
91
Thus, in other words, he adopted the expedition theory. Kotzé JP made
clear in his judgment that he accepted the expedition theory as a result of its
92 At 266.
93 At 265.
94 At 264–265.
95 1939 AD 487 (henceforth Kergeulen). There is some dispute as to whether Kergeulen can be
read as binding confirmation of the expedition theory in cases concerning postal contracts.
Some commentators have argued that the confirmation of Cape Explosive in Kergeulen was
obiter since the latter case did not involve a true postal contract as contemplated in Cape
Explosive: see Flemming J’s opinion in Hawkins v Contract, Design Centre (Cape Town) 1983
(4) SA 296 (T) at 300–301; J P Vorster, “Waar kom ‘n kontrak inter absentes gesluit tot stand?”
1984 TSAR 196; Van der Merwe et al, Kontraktereg, 67 (noting that the confirmation may have
been obiter); contra Kerr, Contract, 118–119.
96 A to Z Bazaars (Pty) Ltd v Minister of Agriculture 1975 (3) SA 468 (AD) at 476; see also Kerr,
Contract, 120.
97 Cape Explosive Works (note 87) at 266 (“we should now lay down that, where in the ordinary
course the Post Office is used as the channel of communication, and a written offer is made, the
offer becomes a contract on the posting of the letter of acceptance”).
98 Yates v Dalton 1938 EDL 177; Christie, Contract, 85–87; Kahn (1955) 72 SALJ 246 at 263–266.
99 Ex parte Jamieson: In Re Jamieson v Sabingo 2001(2) SA 775 (W). Note, however, the comment
in Van der Merwe et al, Kontraktereg, 71 that Willis J’s application of the expedition theory to
telefax cases is “neither convincing nor authoritative” and the references in note 129 to English
cases which treated telefax communication as instantaneous and thus subject to the “normal”
information theory. T Pistorius, “Formation of Internet contracts: an analysis of the contractual
and security issues” (1999) 11 SA Merc LJ 282 at 288 argues, however, that modern technology
has indeed brought telefax communication closer to postal contracts than instantaneous
communication such as telephone and that the relevant English cases should therefore be read
as being “obsolete”. It follows that, in her view, the expedition theory was correctly applied to
telefax cases in the Jamieson case.
100 Wolmer v Rees 1935 TPD 319; C Turpin, “Acceptance of offer: instantaneous communication”
(1956) 73 SALJ 77; Kahn (1955) 72 SALJ 246 at 267.
101 Tel Peda Investigation Bureau (Pty) Ltd v Van Zyl 1965 (4) SA 475 (E) confirmed as the correct
approach in S v Henckert 1981 (3) SA 445 (A); M C J Olmesdahl, “Unheralded demise of
Wolmer versus Rees” (1984) 101 SALJ 545; A J Kerr, “Contracts by telex and by telephone:
86 european contract law
of Appeal has (indirectly) cast doubt on the use of the expedition theory in
postal contracts. In Kaap Suiwelkoöperasie Bpk v Louw102 the court simply
applied the information theory103 in a postal contract context, without any
reference to the expedition theory. In that case the respondent’s membership
in the appellant’s co-operative at a particular date depended on whether
agreement had been reached between the parties as to the date of resigna-
104
tion of the respondent. The respondent had sent several letters to the
appellant in which he conveyed his wish to resign at the earliest possible
105
date. The appellant accepted this request (characterised by the court as an
106
offer of early resignation ) at its annual general meeting on 11 and 12
107
August 1992. Such acceptance was communicated to the respondent in a
108 109
letter dated 31 August 1992. Despite the clear postal nature of the case,
the court came to the conclusion that an agreement had come into existence
regarding termination of the respondent’s membership after receipt by the
110
respondent of the appellant’s letter of 31 August 1992. The statement that
111
the contract only came into existence after receipt of the letter and not
upon receipt seems to suggest that the court had the information theory in
mind rather than the reception theory.112 However, irrespective of whether
the court applied the information theory or the reception theory, the
important point to note is that the court did not apply the expedition theory.
when and where entered into” (1982) 99 SALJ 642; E Kahn, “Contracts by telephone” (1966) 83
SALJ 5; P M Nienaber, “Vonnisbespreking: Tel Peda Investigation Bureau (Pty) Ltd v Van Zyl,
Easten Cape Division, 6 November 1964” (1965) 28 THRHR 67.
102 2001 (2) SA 80 (SCA).
103 It is not completely clear from the judgment whether the court applied the information theory
or the reception theory. Van der Merwe et al, Kontraktereg, 67 n 101 seem to suggest that the
reception theory was applied. However, for the reasons set out below, I think that the inform-
ation theory was applied.
104 At para 20.
105 At para 24.
106 At para 24.
107 At para 17.
108 At para 17.
109 From the judgment it seems that “the Post Office [was] used as the [exclusive] channel of
communication” (in the words of Cape Explosive Works (note 86) at 266), Kaap
Suiwelkoöperasie (note 102) at paras 1, 11–17.
110 At paras 24 - 26.
111 At para 25.
112 This conclusion seems to me to be strengthened by the court’s emphasis on the respondent’s
knowledge of the acceptance in para 25.
offer, acceptance and the moment of contract formation 87
113 Thomson v James at 11; Gardner (1992) 12 Oxford JLS 170 at 173; Kahn (1955) 72 SALJ 246 at
256; Huntley, Contract, 136; Walker, Contract, para 7.63.
114 Cape Explosive Works (note 86) at 262. See also the criticism of this rationale in Scots law in
McBryde, Contract, 159–160; Huntley, Contract, 136; Walker, Contract, para 7.63.
115 Lubbe & Murray, Contract, 68; Gloag, Contract, 34.
116 Lubbe & Murray, Contract, 68; Gloag, Contract, 34.
117 Lubbe & Murray, Contract, 68; Gloag, Contract, 34; Van der Merwe et al, Kontraktereg, 67; De
Wet & Van Wyk, Kontraktereg, 39–40; Kahn (1955) 72 SALJ 246 at 256–257; Anonymous,
“Smeiman revisited” (1955) 72 SALJ 308 at 309; SME, vol 15, para 644; Gloag, Contract, 34;
Huntley, Contract, 136.
118 Van der Merwe et al, Kontraktereg, 67; De Wet & Van Wyk, Kontraktereg, 39–40; Anonymous
(1955) 72 SALJ 308 at 309; Huntley, Contract, 136.
119 Cape Explosive at 265–266; Kergeulen at 504–505; Gardner (1992) 12 Oxford JLS 170 at 173–
176; Huntley, Contract, 136; Gloag, Contract, 34; Walker, Contract, para 7.63.
120 A to Z Bazaars (note 96) at 476; Van der Merwe et al, Kontraktereg, 67; De Wet & Van Wyk,
Kontraktereg, 41; Gardner (1992) 12 Oxford JLS 170 at 173–174, 177; Kahn (1955) 72 SALJ 246
at 256; Report on Formation of Contract (Scot Law Com No 144, 1993), para 4.5. Peter
Goodrich has argued that the postal rule had its origin in early marriage contracts in English law.
The protection it affords specifically to the offeree thus represents the “law’s protection of
women up until the point of entry into the effective completion of the marriage contract”. Such
protection may now seem arbitrary “only because of the erasure of the face of the offeree; it has
been forgotten that it was a woman who put a letter of acceptance in the post” (P Goodrich,
“Habermas and the postal rule” (1996) 17 Cardozo LR 1457 at 1470, 1472).
88 european contract law
convenient for her that when she mails her acceptance she may be certain
that a contract has come into existence. In this sense, the adoption of the
expedition theory also has a risk-allocation function. The risk of loss of the
letter of acceptance in the mail is placed on the offeror.121 This may be seen to
be justified in view of the fact that it was the offeror who initiated
negotiations through the mail.122 The rule also protects the offeree against a
revocation of the offer by the offeror prior to the acceptance reaching the
123
offeror, but subsequent to the declaration of such acceptance. Since
revocation of an offer is always possible in English law as a result of the
requirement of consideration, there is a perceived need to protect the
offeree in such instances. The expedition theory affords this protection. In
South African and Scots law this need is less pronounced. Since neither of
these systems require consideration as an element of contract formation it is
124
much easier to create irrevocable offers. Furthermore, the expedition
theory is convenient in that the time and place at which the letter of
acceptance was committed to the postal service can be objectively
determined, and consequently also the time and place of contracting.125 Yet
121 McBryde, Contract, 159; Walker, Contract, para 7.64; Van der Merwe et al, Kontraktereg, 68;
Gardner (1992) 12 Oxford JLS 170 at 74; Anonymous (1955) 72 SALJ 308 at 309.
122 McBryde, Contract, 159; Van der Merwe et al, Kontraktereg, 69; De Wet & Van Wyk,
Kontraktereg, 41; Anonymous (1955) 72 SALJ 308 at 309.
123 MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, 53.
124 In Scotland offers can be made irrevocable by a mere promise to such effect by the offeror. This
is because Scots law recognises a promise as a binding obligation: Littlejohn v Hadwen (1882)
20 SLR 5; A & G Paterson Ltd v Highland Railway Co 1927 SC (HL) 32; Gloag, Contract, 25;
MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, 45. In South Africa the position seems to be that offers
cannot be made irrevocable by a mere declaration to such effect on the part of the offeror.
Agreement, i.e. offer and acceptance, on the issue of irrevocability is still required before the
main offer will be irrevocable. The absence of a requirement of consideration, however, opens
up the possibility that agreement can be reached on the irrevocability of the main offer without
any quid pro quo from the offeree. See, however, the South African case of Building Material
Manufacturers Ltd v Marais 1990 (1) SA 243 (O) which Christie, Contract, 59 reads as authority
for the proposition that offers can be made irrevocable by mere declaration in South African
law. Van der Merwe et al, Kontraktereg, 79 n 179, argue that the offer to keep the main offer
open in that case was accepted by mere receipt of the former in line with the intention of the
parties. De Wet has also noted that this justification for the adoption of the expedition theory
should be treated with circumspection, since the moment the contract comes into existence and
the moment up to when the offeror can revoke his offer should not be equated as this
justification by implication does. According to De Wet these moments differ. While a contract
will generally come into existence when the offeror learns of the acceptance, he can only retract
his offer up to the moment when the offeree starts declaring her acceptance, which even
precedes the dispatch of the acceptance (De Wet & Van Wyk, Kontraktereg, 33, 40).
125 De Wet & Van Wyk, Kontraktereg, 39 n 135; Kahn (1955) 72 SALJ 246 at 256. This also helps to
prevent fraud since the offeror will not be able to avoid the contract by simply stating that he did
not receive the acceptance when in fact he did: Gardner (1992) 12 Oxford JLS 170 at 174.
offer, acceptance and the moment of contract formation 89
other commentators have suggested that the “real” reason for adopting the
expedition theory in these instances is historical in nature.126
One final explanation that deserves mention is that contract formation at
the moment of posting may be based on an objective standard of contractual
liability in the form of reasonable reliance.127 The argument here, especially
in South African law, is that the use of the expedition theory for postal con-
tracts must be seen as a corrective principle basing liability on objective
128
grounds because the will theory of contract yields harsh or unfair results. If
the reliability of the postal service is accepted it may be said that the offeree
has a legitimate expectation that the negotiations are finalised at the moment
when the acceptance is posted. Hence, the expedition theory bases contrac-
129
tual liability on that reliance.
Despite the justifications formulated for the adoption of the expedition
theory in postal contract cases, this theory does not solve all problems
relating to offer and acceptance inter absentes. When a letter of acceptance
130
does not reach the offeror due to error on the part of the offeree, no
131
contract seems to come into existence. This seems to be an exception to the
application of the expedition theory. However, it is difficult to see how such
situations should be treated in light of the expedition theory. Is there a
126 Gardner (1992) 12 Oxford JLS 170 at 176, 178–192 (where it is noted that the development of
the postal acceptance rule in English law can be explained with reference to historical factors
such as the popular perception of posting as being equivalent to delivery following the postal
reforms of the 1840s in England, the questioning of that perception following the introduction
of telephones in the 1870s and the development of the concept of limited liability companies
and associated mass company flotations of the 1860s and 1870s); Van der Merwe et al,
Kontraktereg, 68. Goodrich (1996) 17 Cardozo LR 1457 at 1473, on the other hand, has argued
that the rule had its origin in early marriage contracts in English law and that the protection it
affords to the offeree “recollects an institutional history, an unconscious structure within which
it would be ethically absurd to allow the man to escape his duties and dishonourable in the
extreme to leave a woman in suspense or unprotected”.
127 Lubbe & Murray, Contract, 67–68; Van der Merwe et al, Kontraktereg, 69; Lubbe, in Reid &
Zimmermann, History, vol 2, 36, 38.
128 Also see Goodrich (1996) 17 Cardozo LR 1457 at 1466–1467 (“While the rule of full communi-
cation suggests a linguistically unrealistic ideology of consensus, the postal rule introduces the
objective possibility of the non-arrival of the letter, and faces the consequences of that failure of
delivery or non-communication which constantly threatens to undermine the subjective theory
of contracts”).
129 Lubbe & Murray, Contract, 67–68; Van der Merwe et al, Kontraktereg, 69; Lubbe, in Reid &
Zimmermann, History, vol 2, 36, 38. See, however, the doubt cast on the reasonableness of this
reliance in Report on Contract Formation (Scot Law Com No 144, 1993), para 4.5.
130 For example, if the offeree incorrectly addressed the letter.
131 Kahn (1955) 72 SALJ 246 at 257; Christie, Contract, 84; Kerr, Contract, 120; Levben Products
(Pty) Ltd v Alexander Films (SA) (Pty) Ltd 1959 (3) SA 208 (SR); McBryde, Contract, 159;
Walker, Contract, para 7.64 (noting, however, that there seems to be no Scottish case to confirm
such outcome).
90 european contract law
132 The court in Levben Products at least seems to suggest that such exception only occurs where
the mistake is of a serious nature, causing non-delivery of the acceptance. McBryde argues that
the postal rule should not apply to cases where the offeree made a mistake in dispatching the
acceptance (Contract, 159). See notes 61–62 and accompanying text above on whether the
operation of the postal rule is qualified in Scots law by the requirement that the acceptance
must in fact be received. A similar mistake analysis seems to be employed in Scots law to
determine the effectiveness of a revocation of a postal offer prior to the dispatch of the
acceptance. See note 46 above for a discussion of Burnley v Alford where it was held, in a postal
contract context, that the revocation of an offer was effective despite the dispatch of an
acceptance after receipt of the revocation, but prior to knowledge of that revocation reaching
the offeree. It seems that mistake on the part of the offeree resulting in his lack of knowledge of
the revocation, and the absence of mistake on the part of the offeror in this regard, played a
significant role in the court’s conclusion. See also Thomson v James at 11; MacQueen &
Thomson, Contract, 50–51.
133 For example, if the offeree telephones the offeror after the former has posted her acceptance
but before the latter has received it, and informs the offeror that she withdraws her acceptance.
134 Kerr, Contract, 121; Hutchison, in Zimmermann & Visser, Southern Cross, 179; this was also
the conclusion of the court a quo in A to Z Bazaars (Pty) Ltd v Minister of Agriculture 1974 (4)
SA 392 (C).
135 A to Z Bazaars 1975 (3) SA 468 (D) at 476; see also Christie, Contract, 84; Kahn (1955) 72 SALJ
246 at 261.
136 See notes 63–66 and accompanying text above.
offer, acceptance and the moment of contract formation 91
137 This is in curious conflict with the statement in the “Survey of Chapters 1–9”, published in the
first volume of PECL (at xxxi), that “[t]he contract will become binding once the acceptance …
has become known to the offeror”.
138 “Survey of Chapters 1–9”, xxix.
139 Article 1:102(2) PECL.
140 Article 2:103(2) PECL.
92 european contract law
Although it follows logically from the adoption of the reception theory that
the offeree can neutralise her acceptance by an overtaking communication,
PECL expressly confirms the effectiveness of such withdrawal.141 It further-
more states that, should the acceptance reach the offeror at the same time as
the withdrawal, the acceptance will not be effective.142
(5) Comparison
From the aforesaid it is clear that PECL differs significantly from the posi-
tion in Scotland and South Africa regarding inter absentes contracting. As a
point of departure they do not differentiate between inter absentes and inter
praesentes contracting. For both scenarios they adopt the reception theory
requiring only formal delivery of acceptance to the offeror for contract
formation. No exception is made for postal contracts.
I would suggest that the approach adopted by PECL is superior in a
number of ways to the position in South Africa and Scotland. As a point of
departure it entails a single default rule for all instances, subject only to
variation by the parties themselves. This approach does away with the need
for tenuous classifications of various forms of communication in order to
establish the applicable rule of contract formation. As a number of
commentators have indicated, it may not be particularly easy (or even
possible) to classify more recent forms of communication into the categories
of instantaneous and non-instantaneous.143 The adoption of a universal rule
that does not rely on such distinctions is clearly preferable. Such an approach
has the added advantage of being perfectly clear, hence advancing legal and
commercial certainty.144 In adopting a universal rule, PECL’s approach seems
to accord much better with the “predilection for reasoning on general prin-
ciple” of both South African and Scots law than “a more casuistic approach”,
145
in which a rule seems to “focus on the postal contract as a special case”.
One of the biggest changes brought about by replacing the postal rule and
the information theory with the reception theory is that the risk of the
acceptance not reaching the offeror is largely shifted to the offeree. This new
allocation of risk seems to be much more in line with the reality of modern
trade than the allocation under the postal rule and information theory. It is
now incumbent on the offeree to ensure that her acceptance reaches the
offeror’s address. This seems to be reasonable since the offeree is undoub-
tedly better placed to ensure such receipt, and a number of mechanisms are
available to her to confirm delivery.146 Furthermore, since she knows that she
has dispatched her acceptance she can ask the offeror whether he has
received it. None of these mechanisms is available to the offeror, who does
147
not even necessarily know that an acceptance has been dispatched.
Although the reception theory to some extent shifts the risk to the offeree
compared to the postal rule, it does not do so in an unreasonable manner. For
under the reception theory, the offeree merely has to prove the delivery of
the acceptance to the offeror. She does not have to prove, as she would have
to under the information theory, that the offeror has actually become aware
of the acceptance.
PECL does not, however, allocate all risk in the period between dispatch
and receipt to the offeree. The offeree is protected against any revocation of
the offer during this period. Article 2:202(1) PECL states that revocation of
an offer will only be effective if it reaches the offeree before dispatch of the
acceptance. Once the offeree has formulated and dispatched her acceptance
she has the certainty that the offeror can no longer nullify her actions by
revoking his offer.148 This bar on revocation of course places the offeror at a
certain inconvenience: he may not be aware of the dispatch of the acceptance
but is, at the same time, unable to revoke his offer. Thus, he is left in a period
of uncertainty. However, on the one hand, he may opt out of the reception
149
theory; on the other hand, he is protected by the requirement that the
acceptance must reach the offeror within the time limit fixed by the offer or,
150
in the absence of an express time limit, within a reasonable time. It is
important to note in this regard that PECL requires the acceptance to reach
the offeror within a reasonable time and not simply that it must be dispatched
146 Most modern postal services offer delivery confirmation and tracking services by means of
which the addressor can at any moment establish the location of his or her posted item.
147 See Report on Contract Formation (Scot Law Com No 144, 1993), para 4.5.
148 This splitting of the moment of contract formation and revocation of the offer was also advanced
by De Wet as an appropriate way of addressing some of the problems experienced with inter
absentes contracting. De Wet, however, identified the two relevant moments as expedition (for
the purposes of the moment of contract formation; this is in line with the postal rule), and as the
moment the offeree starts to express her acceptance (from which time revocation is no longer
possible): De Wet & Van Wyk, Kontraktereg, 40.
149 See notes 138–140 and accompanying text above.
150 Article 2:206 PECL.
94 european contract law
D. CONCLUSION
PECL embraces the offer and acceptance model for contract formation
found in most Western legal systems today. In rejecting both consideration
and causa as requirements for contract formation PECL endorses the offer
and acceptance model as the primary and sole vehicle for analysing the parties’
interaction to establish whether, and when, a contract has come into existence.
PECL is closely aligned to both Scots and South African law in this regard.
However, the model developed by PECL is in a number of respects more
refined and distinctively more modern than those found in Scots and South
African law. One specific aspect of PECL’s model that seems significantly
superior to that found in the former two systems is its treatment of inter absentes
contracting, and specifically the absence of the postal rule in that model.
The reception of the postal rule in South African and Scots law has been
described as undesirable and is not viewed in either system as an unqualified
success.160 Certainly the rule is open to much criticism both from practical
and principled perspectives. From the practical side neither the ambit of the
rule nor its relationship to the retraction of offers and acceptances is
altogether clear. From the point of view of principle, the rule does not sit well
with the subjective approach to contract formation followed in South Africa,
and in both systems it seems to represent a departure from reliance on
161
general principles in favour of casuistic rules focusing on special cases. In
England, the rule’s country of origin, these difficulties are counterbalanced
by the need to protect the offeree against an unfair revocation of the offer
and the difficulty in creating irrevocable offers resulting from the doctrine of
consideration. However, neither Scots nor South African law experience
such need or difficulty. Both systems have developed fairly sophisticated
methods to create irrevocable offers.
Despite these misgivings about the reception of the postal rule, it seems to
me that, at least in South Africa, the rule cannot simply be dismissed as a
knee-jerk reaction to commercial developments of a bygone era precipitated
by convenience and certainty in an influential foreign jurisdiction. The
presence of the postal rule points to a different need experienced in South
African law: a corrective to the subjective theory of contract formation.
Under the postal rule, the contract is not based on the true meeting of the
parties’ minds, but rather on the reliance of one of the parties, the offeree.
Scots law in contrast experiences no such need since it accepts an objective
theory of contract formation. It can therefore simply reject the postal rule in
favour of a receipt rule. This is in line with the principle of an objective
determination of consensus as basis of contractual liability linked to the
requirement that acceptance be communicated to be effective. South
African law, in contrast, cannot at present simply reject the postal rule. Its
place would then be taken by the default information theory with resultant
hardship to the offeree. The South African model would have to be replaced
in its entirety by that adopted by PECL. As I have argued above, that model
seems to protect the interests of both parties effectively. It represents a well-
balanced regime for all forms of contracting, treating inter praesentes and
inter absentes contracting alike. More importantly, at least for the South
African context, it seems to protect a more realistic reliance on the part of the
offeree, namely that the offeror will take note of an acceptance once it has
been delivered.
Overall, the offer and acceptance model adopted in PECL shows more
similarity than difference compared to those found in Scots and South
African law. However, from a comparative point of view, the importance lies
in the difference. In this respect I would suggest that the PECL model
represents an evolution of the Scots and South African models, rather than
any radical departure from them. As such it provides Scots and South African
lawyers with the foretaste of a possible and, I would suggest, highly desirable
future.
4 The Battle of Forms
A D M Forte
1 In Scots law a business-to-business contract concluded on the standard terms of one of the
contracting parties does not prevent exclusion of liability for breach of contract so long as fair and
reasonable: Unfair Contract Terms Act 1977, s 17. However, if both parties deal on the basis of
their respective standard forms, and those forms can be read together, it would seem that the Act
98
the battle of forms 99
Not to be outdone the buyer will point to a counteractive term of its own:
The Company recognises that the Vendor may use its own acknowledgment of
order form. Therefore any provisions in the form of acceptance used which
modify, conflict with or contradict any provision of the contract or order shall be
deemed to be waived unless expressly agreed to in writing by the Company and
2
signed by an authorised representative.
Both of these clauses paramount are of course anticipatory. Buyer and seller
have realised that some of their respective standard forms may clash.
Therefore both seek to neutralise such differences by asserting the exclusive
application of their contract terms. The buyer states that its terms will prevail
no matter what the seller’s terms are. The seller states that the converse will
obtain. Both parties are content to accept that they have a contract and pro-
ceed to performance. The seller delivers the goods to the buyer and the latter
pays for these. Then the dispute arises and only at this stage do the differ-
ences in the two sets of standard forms assume importance.
does not apply. Under recent proposals for reform of the law on unfair contract terms, a
distinction will be observed between business contracts and “small business contracts”. The
former will remain, in effect, subject to the current rules; the latter, however, will be treated in a
more protectionist manner than at present: Report on Unfair Terms in Contracts (Law Com No
292, Scot Law Com No 199, 2005), 57–77. It does not appear to be the case, however, that the
proposed legislation addresses the situation where both parties use standard forms.
2 These examples are based on the terms used by buyer and seller in Uniroyal Ltd v Miller & Co
Ltd 1985 SLT 101.
100 european contract law
the terms in the offer, the second form cannot be regarded as an acceptance
of the first. Instead, the seller’s form represents its rejection of the buyer’s
offer and may be treated by the latter as a counter-offer. For brevity’s sake,
this is often referred to as a “qualified acceptance”.3 At this stage, therefore,
after incongruent forms have been exchanged, the “acceptance” does not
mirror image the offer and so there is no contract concluded between the
parties.
3 Wolf and Wolf v Forfar Potato Co 1984 SLT 100. For a detailed criticism of the construct of the
qualified acceptance, see A D M Forte, “The qualified acceptance: a revisionist view of the
fundamentals of commercial contract formation in Scots law” (1995) 1 Contemporary Issues in Law
43. For a challenging analysis of the mirror-image theory of contract formation, see M M Siems,
“Unevenly formed contracts: ignoring the mirror of offer and acceptance” (2004) 12 ERPL 771.
4 M Hogg and G Lubbe, “Formation of contract”, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal
Systems, 34–65 at 58, n 159.
5 1985 SLT 101.
6 For a more detailed examination of this case as a decision on both battle of forms and letters of
intent see A D M Forte & H L MacQueen, “Contract procedure, contract formation and the
battle of forms” (1986) 31 JLSS 224. Note also, in connection with battle of forms, McBryde,
Contract, 153–156.
7 [1979 1 All ER 965. Note also OTM Ltd v Hydranautics [1981] 2 Lloyd’s Rep 211.
the battle of forms 101
regard to the delivery quoted and uncertainty as to the cost of labour, materials,
etc during the period of manufacture, we regret that we have no alternative but to
make it a condition of acceptance of order that goods will be charged at prices
ruling upon date of delivery.
On 27 May 1969 the buyer placed a written order for the machine employing
its own standard form. This stated that its terms and conditions were to apply.
There were several terms which differed from those in the seller’s quotation;
and at the bottom of the buyer’s order form was a tear-off slip which read:
Acknowledgment: Please sign and return to Ex-Cell-O. We accept your order on
the terms and conditions stated thereon – and undertake to deliver by – Date –
signed.
The seller responded to the buyer’s order form on 5 June 1969, affirming that
delivery of the machine would be as per its quotation of 23 May, and
returning, dated and signed, the buyer’s acknowledgment of order form. By
the delivery date, however, the seller maintained that costs had risen and so it
claimed more than the price originally quoted under reference to the price
variation provision in the quotation of 23 May. The buyer refused to pay the
revised figure and the seller raised an action for payment.
On an analysis of these facts, the majority in the Court of Appeal found
that the seller’s quotation of 23 May was an offer; but that as the buyer’s order
of 27 May contained terms which varied those in the offer, it was not an
acceptance thereof but a counter-offer which the seller accepted by
returning the acknowledgment of order form duly signed. That being so, a
contract was concluded on the buyer’s terms and conditions. However, the
judges were most certainly not ad idem as to why the buyer’s terms
triumphed. Lord Denning MR, thinking outside the box, favoured an holistic
approach to the forms passing between parties. One should abandon the
orthodox contract formation analysis of such documents; establish if there is
8
agreement on the material points; and, if there is, determine which of the
remaining terms are congruent and which conflict. Conflicting terms would
be knocked out, and any remaining gaps filled by implying appropriate terms.
8 Lord Denning expressed much the same view earlier in Port Sudan Cotton Co v Govindaswamy
Chettiar & Sons [1977] 2 Lloyd’s Rep 5 at 10: “I do not much like the analysis in the text-books of
inquiring whether there was an offer and acceptance, or a counter-offer, and so forth. I prefer to
examine the whole of the documents … and decide from them whether the parties did reach an
agreement upon all material terms in such circumstances that the proper inference is that they
agreed to be bound by those terms from that time onwards”. He repeated this in Gibson v
Manchester City Council [1978] 1 WLR 520 at 523. On appeal, however, the House of Lords took
the opportunity to disapprove of this approach generally, though conceding that there could be
“exceptional” circumstances where it might be appropriate: [1979] 1 WLR 297.
102 european contract law
be supplied “in accordance with” its quotation of 23 May. From the seller’s
perspective, therefore, this letter was intended to reinstate the standard
terms in its quotation of 23 May. If, however, the Court of Appeal agreed with
this submission, it meant that on receipt of that letter plus the enclosed
acknowledgment of order form, the buyer now had two documents before it
which were mutually contradictory. The first, the seller’s letter, was a counter-
offer; the second, the buyer’s form, was its own earlier counter-offer to
purchase the goods – albeit duly signed by the seller. On an objective
12
analysis of this highly ambivalent situation, where the offeree holds what
may be construed as a counter-offer, or, possibly an acceptance, together with
what clearly is a counter-offer, both of which arrived at the same time, it is
13
hard to disagree with Bridge LJ that “the parties never were ad idem”. To
avoid such a result the wording of the letter of 5 June was construed
restrictively as referring only to the price and identity of the machine to be
supplied and not to the standard terms and conditions on the reverse of the
quotation of 23 May. The somewhat procrustean moulding of the facts to
produce a finding that there was a contract in this case suggests that orthodox
contract formation analysis affords a rather crude model for solving the battle
of forms;14 and that of Lord Denning appears the more attractive. It may be
objected that in Butler Machine Tool Co Ltd v Ex-Cell-O Corpn (England)
Ltd Lord Denning did not actually adhere to his own model since the parties
did not agree on a “material point”, namely price.15 This is not a persuasive
stance. The seller quoted a price and the buyer accepted that figure. What
the latter objected to was the price variation clause. Consequently, the
dispute was only concerned with whether or not a term permitting variation
of the agreed price should apply.
Butler Machine Tool Co Ltd v Ex-Cell-O Corpn (England) Ltd was refer-
red to in argument in two Scottish cases which may be thought of as involving
in some respects a battle of forms; though in both the judges did not regard
them as such. The first of these is a decision of the Sheriff Principal of North
16
Strathclyde: Roofcare Ltd v Gillies. There the pursuers, Roofcare Ltd,
quoted for roofing repairs to the house of the defender, Gillies. The quota-
tion contained this condition:
This quotation is made subject to the undernoted terms and conditions and no
alterations, exclusions, additions, or qualifications to the quotation and specifica-
tion will be made unless confirmed in writing by Roofcare.
Roofcare Ltd’s terms and conditions did not oblige it to make the premises
wind and watertight. But Gillies’ written acceptance of the quotation stipu-
lated that the repairs had to do so. This elicited no response from Roofcare
Ltd. Gillies then ordered Roofcare Ltd to do the job. After the repairs were
effected, however, Gillies refused to pay, alleging that leaking still occurred.
It was argued for Gillies that (1) there was no contract since there was no
consensus ad idem; and (2) that if there was a contract, then the condition in
his acceptance stipulating that the roofs be made wind and watertight was a
term of that contract. Neither argument found favour with the Sheriff Principal.
Roofcare Ltd had offered to do the work on its terms alone, unless it con-
sented, in writing, to a proposed variation by the offeree. Although just such a
variation was proposed, the offeror did not consent to it. At this stage, there-
fore, there was no contract; but when Gillies instructed Roofcare Ltd to proceed
“it was on the basis that the unaccepted qualification or condition did not
17
apply”. Butler Machine Tool Co Ltd v Ex-Cell-O Corpn (England) Ltd was
rightly distinguished on its facts: this case is not a battle of forms one. None-
theless it is significant to the debate about the battle of forms, since the term
under discussion was a clause paramount whereby the offeror intended to
trump any terms to the contrary in the offeree’s acceptance: which it success-
fully did. Moreover, although the contract here was for the supply of services, it
echoes the judgment of Leggatt LJ in another case concerning the sale of goods:
If express terms are to govern a contract of sale, a buyer would expect to buy goods
18
upon the seller’s terms, unless supplanted by the buyer’s own.
This, it has been argued, indicates that where a seller (or supplier) will not
budge from reliance on its own terms, and does not react to proposals for
change by the other party, any resulting contract is concluded on its terms.19
Roofcare Ltd v Gillies, therefore, provides a measure of support for the view
that “in some cases the battle is won by the man who gets the blow in first”.20
The next case to be examined, however, does not; and it is this case which, as
already noted, has been described as the “classic Scots authority” on the
battle of forms.21
Butler Machine Tool Co Ltd v Ex-Cell-O Corpn (England) Ltd featured in
the arguments for both sides in Uniroyal Ltd v Miller & Co Ltd.22 The
sequence of relevant events was as follows. On 8 February 1974 the
defenders, Miller & Co Ltd, quoted for the sale of steel rolls to the pursuers,
Uniroyal Ltd. The reverse side of this form set out the seller’s terms and
conditions. On 23 May 1974 the buyer sent its purchase order which
contained its standard terms. One of these was a clause paramount:
The [Company] recognises that the Vendor may use its own form of acknow-
ledgement. Therefore, any provisions of the form of acceptance used which
modify, conflict with, or contradict any provision of the contract or order shall be
deemed to be waived unless expressly agreed to in writing by [the Company] and
signed by an authorised representative.
On 7 June 1974 the seller “accepted” this form, but its own acknowledge-
ment of order form stated:
We shall not be liable in respect of defects and we shall not be liable for loss of
profits, detention or other consequential damage or expenses.
One of the substantive terms in this last document excluded liability for loss
of profits or other consequential loss. The seller then delivered the goods and
the buyer took delivery of and paid for these. A dispute subsequently arose
about the quality of the goods and both parties stood upon their respective
standard terms and conditions.
Although the Lord Ordinary thought that it made no difference whether
he followed Lord Denning’s approach in Butler Machine Tool Co Ltd v Ex-
Cell-O Corpn (England) Ltd or that of Lawton and Bridge LJJ, he reached
his decision on the basis of orthodox formation principles. The purchase
order was an offer, and the acknowledgment of order, because it contained a
revised price and specified a delivery date, was a counter-offer. At this stage
therefore the parties were not ad idem on the matter of price and price was
an essential (or material) term in contracts for the sale of goods. A contract
was only concluded when the buyer took delivery and paid for the goods. This
meant that the buyer’s conduct indicated its acceptance of the seller’s counter-
offer and, consequently, that the seller’s terms prevailed over those of the
21 Hogg & Lubbe, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 58 n 159.
22 1985 SLT 101.
106 european contract law
23 Avintair Ltd v Ryder Airline Services Ltd 1994 SC 270. Note also G D L Cameron, “Consensus
in dissensus” 1995 SLT (News) 132.
24 1985 SLT 101 at 106.
25 Bunge Corpn v Tradax Export SA [1981] 1WLR 711. Note also The Honam Jade [1991] 1 Lloyd’s
Rep 38. See also R M Goode, Commercial Law, 3rd edn (2004) at 270.
26 Comment 3, Illustration 1. See further below, text accompanying notes 68–74.
27 At 106.
the battle of forms 107
presently unclear in Scots law which party’s form, first or last, will win that
battle.
It is interesting in this context to note a degree of parallelism with South
Africa. The South African law of contract seems to have tended to ignore the
battle of forms debate. One writer expresses the opinion that if a contract
exists at all it may be hard to determine its content.28 The most recent edition
29
of Christie does not refer to Butler Machine Tool Co v Ex-Cell-O Corpn
(England) Ltd, and makes no mention of the “battle of forms” either as a term
or as a discrete problem. However, the brief yet complex analysis of the case
law by Hogg and Lubbe suggests that while a South African battle of forms
case might be analysed in terms of orthodox contract formation theory
30
(which would produce a victory for the firer of the last shot), overall the law
“reflects an approach which places the emphasis less on the concurrence of
declarations and manifested consent than on disagreement and induced
31
reliance”. For example, in Bok Clothing Manufacturers (Pty) Ltd v Lady
32
Land (Pty) Ltd, the issue was whether or not the seller could rely on a
retention of title clause. Although the parties had done business since 1977, it
was only in 1980 that this clause appeared in the terms and conditions found
on the reverse of the seller’s order forms. Reference to this term was also,
however, in the seller’s invoices and in “the legend at the bottom of the order
form[s]”. As Hogg and Lubbe point out, “the court eschewed an analysis in
terms of the rules of offer and acceptance and the “last shot rule”,33 prefer-
ring an approach based on the rules relating to the incorporation of contract
34 35
terms. In Guncrete (Pty) Ltd v Scharrighuisen Construction (Pty) Ltd,
the issue was whether or not terms found in the main contract between the
defendants and the building owner, and empowering the site engineer to vary
or cancel work, applied to a subcontract between the defendants and the
plaintiffs. In response to the latter’s tender the defendants counter-offered,
accepting the tender subject to the above term of the main contract being
one of the subcontract. The plaintiffs subsequently conducted themselves in
a manner which implied that they accepted the counter-offer and, indeed,
judgment was given in their favour on that basis. According to Hogg and
Lubbe this decision did not turn on whether there was a contract between
contractor and subcontractor, but “on an objective principle of reasonable
36
reliance”. With respect, neither of these two decisions commends itself as a
model for the resolution of the battle of forms. Indeed neither case involved
a battle of forms.
The first, it is true, is correct in inferring that incorporation is an issue of
content and not formation. But the rules regarding incorporation of terms
are essentially designed to promote fair dealing – particularly in the context
of consumer contracts. The basis on which a term is not to be included in a
contract where an incorporation approach is adopted is premised upon its
unfairness: consequently, seller’s term X is not a term of the contract because
it is unfair and the law, for policy reasons, does not permit the inclusion of
unfair terms. However, in a classic battle of forms case between business
parties of proportionate bargaining power substantive fairness of contract
terms should not be an issue which the law encourages either of the parties to
plead easily.37 Furthermore, one cannot assume that the battle of forms is
confined to cases involving terms which are considered to be objectionable
on the ground of unfairness. Is there anything inherently unfair in retention
of title or price-variation clauses? The battle of forms centres on terms that
are different and mutually incompatible: seller’s term X is negated by buyer’s
term Y. The question here is – what is to be done with such terms?
There is, however, one useful point which incorporation analysis can high-
light; and that is the element of (unfair) surprise caused by the manner in
which the term is incorporated. And this is something to which I will return
when discussing the treatment of clauses paramount.
The second case, with its stress on objectivity, is more problematic. The
contract was made on the main contractor’s terms because the subcontractor
reacted in a manner which would induce a reasonable person to believe that
it “was assenting to the terms proposed by the other party”.38 The difficulty
36 Hogg & Lubbe, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems, 59.
37 This is what the two Law Commissions discovered when they proposed extending the grounds of
challenge available under the Unfair Terms in Consumer Contracts Regulations 1999 (SI 1999/
2083) to business-to-business contracts (Law Com No 292, Scot Law Com No 199) at 61 –
“businesses value certainty above protection and, with the exception of small businesses, neither
need nor want additional protection”.
38 At 686 per Alexander J, quoting Blackburn J in Smith v Hughes (1871) LR 6 QB 597 at 607.
the battle of forms 109
with this approach, however, is its recourse to the objectivity paradigm and
the connected problem of which variant of that paradigm is to be used.39
Added to this is the possibility that whichever variant is resorted to, the
conclusion may be that there is no contract. This presents no difficulty where
performance has not yet taken place; but is scarcely satisfactory where it is
otherwise. A further consequence of this approach, if applied to a true battle
of forms situation, would be to distance South African contract law from the
position adopted by the international commercial harmonising measures
which will be discussed later in this essay.
The notes to the Comment to Article 2:209 PECL observe that the last shot
theory represents the “prevailing view” in Scotland in relation to the winning
40
of the battle of forms. As a statement of the stance taken by some scholars,
41
this is correct: though the justification for taking it, as has been suggested, is
rather slight. Certainly for those who do espouse it, or who see the battle of
forms as being resolved on a “traditional approach”,42 this manner of tackling
the problem in Scots law has the merit of simplicity. The buyer’s purchase
order is its offer to acquire goods from the seller. The seller’s acknowledg-
ment of order form represents its rejection of the seller’s offer and its own
counter-offer: at this point not only is there no contract between buyer and
seller, but the buyer’s offer has also ceased to exist, having been killed off by
43
the seller’s qualified acceptance. However, the seller then does what both
parties want: it delivers the goods. And the buyer then does what the seller
wishes; it takes delivery of the goods and pays for these. The buyer’s conduct
here is treated as acceptance; and as acceptance of the counter-offer made by
the seller in the acknowledgment of order form. Thus the battle of forms has
been resolved upon an orthodox contract formation analysis as in Uniroyal
44
Ltd v Miller & Co Ltd.
Chitton Bros v Eker were those of Outer House judges in the Court of Session and that such
decisions do not have a higher authority than those delivered by a sheriff. Thus the case law goes
either way in Scotland: a point overlooked in the Comment to Article 2:209 PECL.
45 A point recognised by Lord Denning MR in Butler Machine Tool Co Ltd v Ex-Cel-O Corporation
(England) Ltd [1979] 1 All ER 965, CA. The Dutch Civil Code provides that it is the first shot
which wins the battle: Hardstaal Holdings BV v NN (2001) C99/315HR.
46 C Sukurs, “Harmonizing the battle of the forms: a comparison of the United States, Canada, and
the United Nations Convention on Contracts for the International Sale of Goods” (2001) 34
Vanderbilt Journal of Transnational Law 1481 at 1487.
47 G Baron, “Do the UNIDROIT Principles of International Commercial Contracts form a new lex
mercatoria?” http://www.cisg.law.pace.edu/cisg/biblio/baron.html.
48 R & J Dempster v Motherwell Bridge and Engineering Co Ltd 1964 SC 308 at 328 per Lord
President Clyde. To like effect was Lord Guthrie at 332: “The object of our law of contract is to
facilitate the transactions of commercial men, and not to create obstacles in the way of solving
practical problems arising out of the circumstances confronting them, or to expose them to
unnecessary pitfalls”.
the battle of forms 111
49 The terminology is that of J White & R S Summers, Uniform Commercial Code (1988), 23;
however the sentiment was one shared by UNCITRAL in drafting CISG: Yearbook of the United
Nations Commission on International Trade Law, vol 9 (1978), 92.
50 D A Levin & E B Rubert, “Beyond UCC Section 2–207: should Professor Murray’s proposed
revision be adopted?” (1992) 11 Journal of Law and Commerce 175 at 188.
51 For a broad comparative perspective, see E Jacobs, “The battle of the forms: standard term
contracts in comparative perspective” (1985) 34 ICLQ 297; A T von Mehren, “The battle of forms:
a comparative view” (1990) 38 American Journal of Comparative Law 265.
112 european contract law
which makes clear that only a de plano acceptance will be tolerated renders
the offeree’s attempt to incorporate its terms, whether additional or differing,
nugatory. There will be a contract, but its content will be determined by the
offer. Subsection (3) is something of a longstop where documentary
exchanges between parties do not disclose a concluded contract. But if buyer
and seller behave in a manner which indicates their belief, which is consistent
with commercial reality, that they have a contract, then the law respects that
belief. In this case the content of the contract is a mixture of those terms
which the documentary exchanges reveal to have been agreed, supple-
mented if need be by terms implied by the UCC in sales contracts.
§ 2–207 UCC remains predicated upon a core requirement that a contract
must exist either in fact or in belief. Nevertheless, its purpose is to determine
the issue of content when the parties’ terms differ in some respects. Its
suggested replacement rests upon the same requirement and continues to
espouse that objective. There is, however, an important difference between
proposed and extant § 2–207 UCC. I have already noted that extant § 2–207
UCC recognises the effect of a clause paramount in the offer. Proposed § 2–
55
207 UCC does not. By implication it appears to reject the automatic effect
of the clause paramount (the first shot) and also orthodox formation analysis
(the last shot). Consequently, a battle of forms cannot, automatically, be won
by either the party who fires the first shot or the party who fires the last. Where
the response to an offer containing a clause paramount is a counter-offer,
there is no presumption that the offeror agrees to contract on the counter-
offeror’s terms. If the parties move to performance, the contract will comprise
those terms on which the parties have agreed (including terms not found in
the documentary record) and terms “supplied or incorporated” by the UCC.
A final brief comment: proposed § 2–207 UCC is not restricted to battle of
forms situations and is generally applicable to contracts for the sale of goods.
(2) CISG56
Article 19 CISG
(1) A reply to an offer which purports to be an acceptance but contains additions,
limitations or other modifications is a rejection of the offer and constitutes a
counter-offer.
55 2002 revision.
56 See generally, F Vergne, “The ‘battle of the forms’ under the 1980 United Nations Convention on
Contracts for the International Sale of Goods” (1985) 33 American Journal of Comparative Law
233; C Moccia, “The United Nations Convention on Contracts for the International Sale of Goods
and the ‘battle of the forms’” (1989–90) 13 Fordham International Law Journal 649; Forte (1995)
1 Contemporary Issues in Law 43 at 62–65.
114 european contract law
The Scottish Law Commission has proposed that certain provisions of CISG
57
should serve as a model for reform of the law of contract formation. Indeed
Article 7(1) and (2) of the Uniform Law on the Formation of Contracts for
the International Sales of Goods 1964, which are substantially the same in
content as Article 19(1) and (2) CISG, were given effect in the United
Kingdom by the Uniform Laws on International Sales Act 1967, section 2(1)
in respect of international sales of goods. So the Scottish Law Commission’s
proposal was scarcely radical. As far as the problem of the battle of forms is
concerned, this is most unfortunate. If § 2–207 UCC extant can be described
as an “amphibious tank that was originally designed to fight in swamps but
was ultimately sent to fight in the desert”,58 then Article 19 CISG is an
amphibious tank that was designed to sink in those swamps. In modern
parlance it “talks the talk”. But we may enquire does it “walk the walk”? To be
blunt – I think not.
Article 19(1) CISG is fundamentally premised on the orthodox analysis of
59
contract formation: the mirror image rule. As a result, additional or differ-
ing terms in the response to an offer cannot in principle permit that response
60
to be viewed as anything other than a rejection and counter-offer. Such
terms are not to be viewed as proposals for modification of the offer’s terms.
57 Report on Formation of Contract: Scottish Law and the United Nations Convention on Contracts
for the International Sale of Goods (Scot Law Com No 144, 1993) at para 1.10.
58 White & Summers, Uniform Commercial Code at 24.
59 Sukurs (2001) 34 Vanderbilt Journal of Transnational Law 1481 at 1496. UNCITRAL considered
the viewpoint that what ultimately emerged as Article 19(2) CISG should be deleted since it
altered the mirror image approach. This proposal was rejected, though only “after considerable
deliberation” (Yearbook of the United Nations Commission on International Trade Law, vol 9
(1978), 42–43). A working group subsequently recommended the addition of a version of what is
now Article 19(3) CISG; but stated that its “first preference” was the deletion of what is now
Article 19(2) CISG since this “contradicted the basis principle”, set out in what is now Article
19(1) CISG, “that an acceptance must agree with the terms of an offer” (Yearbook of the United
Nations Commission on International Trade Law, vol 9 (1978), 43).
60 As was the case in the CISG’s ill-fated predecessor, the 1964 Hague Uniform Law on the
Formation of Contracts for the Sale of Goods, Article 7(1).
the battle of forms 115
It is of course true that Article 19(2) CISG permits minor variations so long as
the offeror does not object; but any material variation of the offer quite
simply precludes the formation of a contract for the sale of goods. Here there
is an instant and stark contrast with § 2–207 UCC, which regards materiality
as relevant to the content of a contract but not to its formation. The converse
is true of Article 19(1) CISG. And when we turn to consider terms which
would preclude the formation of a contract because they constitute material
alterations, Article 19(3) presents a list which is not only extensive but which
is also questionable in some instances and not exhaustive. Consequently, the
scope for departure from the mirror image rule is too severely restricted: a
61
point which the Scottish Law Commission concedes. That said, particularly
in relation to “additional terms”, the Article is less circumscribed than it may
62
first appear. Thus terms implied by trade usage, and therefore implicit in an
acceptance of an offer which makes no mention thereof, will not prevent
conclusion of a contract and will form part of its contents.
Article 19 CISG is directed at the situation where parties have spotted
additions or variations, have not proceeded to performance, and are
wrangling over whether or not they have a contract. But what if after having
exchanged standard forms of offer and acceptance, and having performed
their respective parts of the bargain, a problem arises which is referable to
diverging terms in the documents exchanged? Since Article 18(3) CISG
permits conclusion of a contract on the basis of performance, and since the
seller’s standard acknowledgment of order form would be treated by Article
19(1) CISG as its counter-offer, the buyer by taking the goods and making
payment of the price has accepted the counter-offer and the contract would
be on its terms. In other words, the seller who fires the last shot automatically
63
wins the battle of forms. This is quite simply not an acceptable solution to
the problem.
Article 19(2) CISG represents a compromise between those legal systems
that require the application of a strict mirror image rule, and those that adopt
a more relaxed position re immaterial or ancillary variations of the offer’s
terms.64 Scots law with its rejection of the concept of essential and inessential
terms in offers65 falls into the former category. However, in comparison with
the UCC in both its present and future manifestations, it merely tinkers with
orthodox formation analysis. The Scottish Law Commission regards it as close
to the orthodox model and the features which would seem to commend it to
them all relate to the point that the legislation proposed would require virtually
66
no practical change to current Scots law. This attitude contrasts strongly
with that in the United States where it has been very persuasively argued that
67
CISG should not be used as a paradigm for revision of the UCC. Again in
contrast to the approach of either extant or proposed § 2–207 UCC, Article 19
CISG is inconsistent with the modalities of modern commerce. As a formation-
based approach, it queries commercial understanding of the contracting process
and is therefore unduly paternalistic. Furthermore, as already mentioned, it
is economically inefficient, producing a negative impact on transaction costs.
The American model facilitates commerce; and the proposed revision, by
eliminating first or last strike victories, is conducive to future business relations
between disputants. CISG, on the other hand, by adherence to the contract
formation approach to battle of forms not only produces an almost certain
winner in the party who fires last but, thanks to its restrictive interpretation of
immateriality, is more conducive to a finding of no contract rather than a
determination of contractual content. If Scots law is to be reformed in this area,
I would hope that CISG is no longer considered to represent the ideal model.
(3) PICC
64 A M Garro, “Reconciliation of legal traditions in the UN Convention on Contracts for the Inter-
national Sale of Goods” (1989) 23 International Law 443 at 462–463.
65 Rutterford Ltd v Allied Breweries Ltd 1990 SLT 249.
66 Scot Law Com No 144 (1993) at para 4.19.
67 H D Gabriel, “The inapplicability of the United Nations Convention on the International Sale of
Goods as a model for revision of Article Two of the Uniform Commercial Code” (1998) 72 Tulane
LR 1995.
68 Although the 2004 version of PICC is a revision of the 1994 original, Article 2.1.22 of the 2004
Principles is a verbatim reproduction of Article 2.22 of that original.
the battle of forms 117
69 These are the terms identified in Comment 3, Illustration 1. PECL adds to these terms relating to
description of performance: Comment A.
70 Comment 2.
71 Comment 3.
118 european contract law
If, for example, one applies Article 2.1.22 PICC to the facts of Uniroyal
Ltd v Miller & Co Ltd,72 in which the clauses paramount appeared only in the
parties’ general terms but were not referred to otherwise, then neither would
apply.73 If, on the other hand, the buyer (Uniroyal) had included their clause
paramount along with other variable terms (such as price and time and place
of delivery) on the face of their purchase order, the seller’s acceptance,
regardless of what its standard terms provided, would have concluded a con-
74
tract on the buyer’s terms. So here the first shot would have prevailed. It did
not of course because on the approach taken, the last shot rule was applied.
Article 2.1.22 PICC is quite unlike Article 19 CISG. The latter is mired in
an approach to the battle of forms which is predicated on the orthodox
formation analysis; and by virtue of that connection is condemned to the last
shot principle if indeed there is a finding that a contract has been concluded.
From an international convention concerned with cross-border contracts
one would expect a philosophy designed more to promote enforceability than
to impede it and Article 19 CISG, like Scots law, is at positive odds with the
principle of favor contractus which may be accounted part of the modern lex
mercatoria. Article 2.1.22 PICC is quite a radical shift away from orthodox
theory; which it implicitly recognises as productive of these extreme results.
Indeed its preservation of the clause paramount, but only where there has
been clear satisfaction of a prominent visibility prerequisite, seems to sit well
with the requirement under English (and I would venture Scots) law, that
terms which radically alter the basic expectations of a contracting party must
75
be specifically drawn to the attention of that party.
Perhaps the only major expression of dissatisfaction which might be
levelled at Article 2.1.22 PICC concerns the effect of clauses paramount. The
first point, of course, is that by permitting these adhesive terms one rein-
forces potential inequalities of economic strength between buyers and sellers.
One wonders whether the requirement of fair dealing “in international
76
trade” might not yet be interpreted to encompass abuse of bargaining power.
PICC appears to condone the practice, provided the strike is publicised and
visible. While it is true that a clause paramount may come as a surprise to one
of the parties, the clause is primarily objectionable on policy grounds. True,
the recipient of a document in these terms may “inform the other party that
it does not intend to be bound by such a contract”, but this produces a
dysfunctional solution at least in terms of cross-border trade. In this respect
the policy underpinning proposed § 2–207 UCC is to be preferred.
(4) PECL
There is consensus that Article 2:209 PECL and PICC are basically the
same.77 This is perhaps debatable. There is also a view that Article 2:209
PECL “has adopted the common-law [sic] approach”.78 This is not debatable;
it is simply bizarre. Were Article 2:209 PECL to be applied to the facts of
79
Uniroyal Ltd v Miller & Co Ltd the seller (Miller & Co Ltd) would not have
won by virtue of firing the last shot. But nor would the buyer (Uniroyal Ltd)
have won on the basis of having fired the first shot. Because both parties
asserted the paramountcy of their respective standard terms, thereby
indicating their unwillingness to be bound by the other’s standard terms,
neither set of standard terms would have prevailed. Instead, their contract
would have comprised the essential terms of their contract, upon which their
agreement would be patent, together with those general terms which were
“common in substance”; the standard terms which conflicted with each other
would cancel or knock each other out.
But it “will not always be easy to decide”, the Comment tells us, whether
terms really are “common in substance”.80 The illustration provided by the
Comment deals with an arbitration clause which occurs in both purchase and
acknowledgment of order forms. But whereas one form stipulates that arbi-
tration will take place in London, the other states that it will be in Sweden.81
This is a classic problem which is replicated where parties specify different
courts to hear any potential dispute: for example, the seller specifies the
82
“Commercial Court in London” and the buyer a “Court in London”. The
Under Article 2.1.22 PICC there would be a contract if this clause paramount
was not part of the buyer’s standard conditions. Under Article 2:209(2)
PECL, however, there would not. Under Article 2.1.22 PICC there would
still be a contract if this clause was found in the buyer’s standard conditions
but the clause paramount would be disregarded. The same result would
occur under Article 2:209(2)(a) PECL. PICC, therefore, adheres more
closely to the favor contractus principle than does PECL in this regard. One
wonders why PECL has not here lived up to its belief that a “contract may be
86
formed by the exchange of general conditions”?
Several things are very clear. The first is that as a national legal system Scots
law treats the battle of forms in a fragmented fashion in that the cases do not
suggest a uniform response to the question – does the first or the last shot
prevail? Second, Scots law does not appreciate that the battle of forms is a
matter of contract content, not of contract formation. Third, there has been
no judicial recognition so far that orthodox formation analysis is ill-suited to
the reality of modern commerce, contract procedure, and commercial
expectations.87 A fourth concern is that despite the volume of cross-border
commerce within the European Union, there is no uniform approach to the
battle of forms among the member states. 88 Under Dutch law the first shot
89
rule has been applied; in the United Kingdom the last shot rule has been
90
assumed to prevail; and under Austrian and German law the knock-out rule
91
seems to be preferred. In Spain, however, the position appears to be un-
clear and in Sweden opinion is against the application of any single approach.
But problems are relatively easy to articulate in this context; solutions are
more difficult. How does PECL fit into the reformist debate?
Article 2:209 PECL is not flawless; and some of these flaws have been
mentioned here. However, the provision is based on the fundamentally
86 Comment C1.
87 On the gap between judicial perceptions of commercial expectations and the reality, see S Styles,
“Good faith: a principled matter” in A D M Forte, Good Faith, 157 at 170–171.
88 See E Hondius & C Mahé, “The battle of forms: towards a uniform solution” (1997–98) 10
Journal. of Contract Law 268.
89 Article 6:225(3) BW.
90 Uniroyal Ltd v Miller & Co Ltd 1985 SLT 101; British Road Services v Arthur Crutchley [1968]
1 All ER 811; Butler Machine Tool Co Ltd v Ex-Cell-O Corp (England) Ltd [1979] 1 All ER 965,
CA. As noted in the text earlier, Article 19 CISG also embraces the last shot doctrine.
91 Note also Article 2.1.22 PICC; and proposed § 2–207 UCC.
122 european contract law
sound premise that the battle of forms is a contents question and not a
formation issue. In addition, it is more reflective of commercial reality than
the approach taken by my own legal system. On the other hand, PECL is no
more than a model law which has no force in the member states and may (or
may not) provide a template for a European Union-wide contract code.92
However, it is just as important to remember that PECL, as it stands,
provides a useful point of reference for judges or legislators wishing to
93
develop the law. Moreover, PECL has been considered by the Scottish Law
Commission in connection with the reform of the law on penalty clauses and
94
the payment of interest on debts and damages. This is important because
the Commission’s conception of the Scots law of contract is one which is both
modernist and integrationist in spirit:
Scots law has a tradition of being receptive to the best international legal
developments, given the obvious advantages for Scottish traders, lawyers and
arbiters in having our internal law the same as the law which is now widely applied
95
throughout the world in relation to contracts for the international sale of goods.
At that time, however, the model upon which the Commission pinned its
hopes, at least in relation to the battle of forms, was CISG. For the reasons
argued for above, in my opinion the PECL model is to be preferred; and it is
to be hoped that should the matter arise for adjudication in the future, a
Scottish court will recognise that the battle of forms is not yet a resolved and
settled area of law, and will pay serious consideration to disposing of the issue
on the basis of the approach taken in Article 2:209 PECL.
A. INTRODUCTION
B. APPARENT AUTHORITY
(1) Definition?
(2) South African law
(3) Scots law
(4) PECL
(a) An estoppel or not?
(b) Words or conduct on part of principal
(c) Reasonableness requirement/good faith on part of third party
(d) Reliance by third party
(e) Causation
(f) Loss
(g) Notice requirement
C. UNDISCLOSED PRINCIPAL: THE DIRECT ACTION
(1) Nature of problem
(2) South African law
(3) Scots law
(4) PECL
(a) General
(b) Clarification of types of contract formed
(c) When direct actions may be exercised
D. UNDISCLOSED PRINCIPAL: THE NOTICE REQUIREMENT
(1) General
(2) Interplay with rules on election
(3) Effect of performance to wrong party
(4) Summary of comments on notice requirement
E. UNDISCLOSED PRINCIPAL: AVAILABILITY OF DEFENCES
AND COMPENSATION/SET OFF
(1) Exercise of principal’s direct action
(2) Exercise of third party’s direct action
F. CONCLUSION
123
124 european contract law
A. INTRODUCTION
1 See EC Council Directive 86/653/EC (OJ 1986, L382/17) on the co-ordination of the laws of
member states relating to self-employed commercial agents.
2 R Powell, “Contractual agency in Roman law and English law” (1956) SALR 41 at 49
3 The extent to which such actions are available in other European countries is summarised in the
Notes to Articles 3:302 and 3:303 PECL.
agency 125
explored in more detail below, many argue that the English version fails
adequately to take account of the third party’s interests. This may be because
the principles of English agency law developed largely during the eighteenth
century, at a time when protection of reasonable reliance by third parties was
not a high priority. Suffused as PECL is with overriding concepts of good
faith, it would not be surprising if the versions contained in PECL shift the
balance towards greater third-party protection. The extent to which this is
the case is explored below.
The other concept analysed here, apparent authority, shares the same
English heritage as the concept of the undisclosed principal. Despite the fact
that its rationale appears to be the protection of third parties through the
operation of an estoppel, its requirements are so rigorous that it often
operates in the principal’s favour. The same issue of the lack of third-party
protection therefore arises. Apparent authority differs from the direct actions
in that it is not, at least to the same extent, a “fault line” between the Common
Law and the Civil Law. Many European systems have developed their own
solutions to the problem which the Common Law solves using apparent
authority.4 Again, the version of apparent authority appearing in PECL owes
much to English law. The focus for discussion is therefore the innovations on
English law contained within PECL, and how useful those might be for Scots
and South African lawyers.
B. APPARENT AUTHORITY
(1) Definition?
Where apparent authority is relevant, the agent lacks the authority to do what
he is purporting to do. Lacking such authority, he cannot create a contract
between the principal and the third party. However, it is important to
consider the conduct of the principal. The principal may have misled the
third party as to the extent of the agent’s authority. Using the terminology of
English law, misleading the third party in this way is treated as a
representation. The third party may rely on the representation and suffer loss
as a result. If the third party can successfully prove each of these elements of
representation, reliance and loss, an estoppel is created in his favour. If the
third party sues the principal, the principal is estopped from denying that the
agent was properly authorised. This provides the third party with protection
in cases where the agent is acting beyond the confines of his authority.
Despite what one would imagine the case to be, in practice the rules of
apparent authority tend to operate in favour of the principal. This is due to
the emphasis which estoppel places on the voluntary conduct of the principal
in the form of a representation. It is often difficult to prove that a valid
representation has been made. Any number of factors may have contributed
to form the third party’s impression of the agent’s authority: for example, a
5
representation by the agent himself, or the surrounding circumstances as a
whole, including the appointment of the agent to a specific role. Thus, it is
probably unrealistic to seek to tie the third party’s impression exclusively to
the conduct of the principal. As a result, many commentators are in favour of
a shift in the balance away from the protection of the principal’s interests and
6
towards further third-party protection, perhaps by focusing on the “agent’s
conduct, as seen from the third party’s perspective, rather than the principal’s
7
conduct in creating the appearance of authority”. Basing apparent authority
on estoppel brings with it a high degree of emphasis on the principal’s
representation as the most important factual cause of the loss. It may be that
apparent authority requires to be rationalised in a manner which does not
utilise estoppel in order to rectify the potential bias in favour of the principal.
5 A representation by the agent himself as to the extent of his authority would be an insufficient
basis for a case of apparent authority: see F M B Reynolds, Bowstead & Reynolds on the Law of
Agency, 17th edn (2002) (henceforth Bowstead & Reynolds) at para 8-022, and Armagas Ltd v
Mundogas SA [1986] 1 AC 717.
6 See, e.g., I Brown, “The agent’s apparent authority: paradigm or paradox?” [1995] JBL 360. This
is probably also the motivation behind the wider approach exhibited in the English case of First
Energy (UK) Ltd v Hungarian International Bank Ltd [1993] 2 Lloyd’s Rep 194, particularly by
Lord Steyn. He emphasises the protection of the third party’s reasonable expectations at several
points during his judgment: see at 196, 204. He explores the same theme in judgments in other
cases: see Darlington Borough Council v Wiltshier Northern Ltd [1995] 3 All ER 895 at 903–904;
and in published articles: see “Fulfilling the reasonable expectations of honest men” (1997) 113
LQR 433 and “Written contracts: to what extent may evidence control language?” (1998) 51 CLP
23. Reynolds too prefers this theme as the underlying basis of apparent authority: see F M B
Reynolds, “The ultimate apparent authority” (1994) 110 LQR 21 at 22: “This doctrine, which may
depend on estoppel but is probably better based on the same reasoning which holds contracting
parties to the objective appearances of intention which they create…”
7 Brown [1995] JBL 360 at 372.
agency 127
in some recent cases where the courts, including the Supreme Court of
Appeal, have had the opportunity to identify the separate elements of an
apparent authority case. Quoting from an earlier judgment by Schutz JA,8
Nienaber JA approved the following requirements for a case of apparent
authority in Glofinco v Absa Bank Ltd (t/a United Bank):9
8 NBS Bank Ltd v Cape Produce Co (Pty) Ltd 2002 (1) SA 396 (SCA) at 412C=E.
9 2002 (6) SA 470 (SCA) at 479–480.
10 2002 (6) SA 470 (SCA) at 479.
11 See Slade J in Rama Corporation v Proved Tin and General Investments Ltd [1952] 2 QB 147 at
149–150. Slade J’s judgment is widely cited; however, it could be argued that, as a first instance
judgment, it has had a disproportionate impact on this area of law.
12 [1964] 2 QB 480 at 502.
13 Bowstead & Reynolds, at para 8–014, indicates that Lord Diplock’s judgment is “constantly cited”.
See also B S Markesinis & R J C Munday, An Outline of the Law of Agency, 4th edn (1998) at 37.
14 See, e.g., British Bata Shoe Co Ltd v Double M Shah Ltd 1980 SC 311 at 317 per Lord Jauncey;
Dornier GmbH v Cannon 1991 SC 310 at 317 per Lord Cowie; Bank of Scotland v Brunswick
Developments (1987) Ltd (No 2) 1998 SLT 439 at 443–444 per Lord President Rodger; John
Davidson (Pipes) Ltd v First Engineering Ltd 2001 SCLR 73 at 77 per Lord Macfadyen.
128 european contract law
figure among the origins of the general doctrine of estoppel”,15 others have
suggested that apparent authority cases predate the development of
estoppel.16 By contrast, in South African law, the basis in estoppel is much
clearer than it is in English law. Despite the importance of estoppel in the
South African concept, it would not be correct fully to equate South African
law with English law. It must be remembered that South Africa has its own
version of estoppel.
Closer reference to the South African version of apparent authority also
reveals some differences from English law. The most striking element of the
South African definition is the presence of an extra requirement which is part
17
of neither English nor Scots law. In South African law, a representation
must be in such a form that the principal should reasonably have expected
18
that outsiders would act on the strength of it. At first glance, this may appear
to be a relatively minor difference. However, it is notable that this extra
requirement works in the principal’s favour. The principal is judged by
reference to the conduct of the reasonable person, and only if a reasonable
person would expect the representation to be acted on will it be relevant. The
South African concept therefore appears to be more protective of the
principal than its English equivalent. To this extent South African law appears
to go against the current international trend by adding an extra factor which
favours the principal.
15 Bowstead & Reynolds, at para 8–029, cites as examples Pickering v Busk (1812) 15 East 38;
Pickard v Sears (1837) 6 Ad & El 469 and Freeman v Cooke (1848) 2 Ex 654. Montrose also
tended towards this view: see “The basis of the power of an agent in cases of actual and apparent
authority” (1938) 16 Canadian Bar Review 757 at 787.
16 See W W Cook, “Estoppel as applied to agency” (1903) 15 Harvard LR 324 at 325, which is
favoured by G H L Fridman, The Law of Agency, 7th edn (1996) (henceforth Fridman, Agency)
at 120.
17 Nor is this a requirement of the version of apparent authority which appears in Article 2.2.5
PICC.
18 Monzali v Smith 1929 AD 382; Quinn and Co Ltd v Witwatersrand Military Institute 1953 (1) SA
155 (T) at 159E–F; Connock’s (SA) Motor Co Ltd v Sentraal Westelike Ko-operatiewe Mpy Bpk
1964 (2) SA 47 (T) at 51A; NBS Bank Ltd v Cape Produce Co (Pty) Ltd 2002 (1) SA 396 (SCA) at
412D.
agency 129
(4) PECL
(a) An estoppel or not?
Article 3:201 PECL deals with apparent authority under the heading “Express,
Implied and Apparent Authority”. Apparent authority is covered in sub-
paragraph (3) which states that:
A person is to be treated as having granted authority to an apparent agent if the
person’s statements or conduct induce the third party reasonably and in good faith
to believe that the apparent agent has been granted authority for the act
performed by it.
19 Bank of Scotland v Brunswick Developments (1987) Ltd (No 2) 1998 SLT 439 at 443–444 per
Lord President Rodger. See also the other Scottish cases cited in note 14 above, where Lord
Diplock’s speech from Freeman and Lockyer v Buckhurst Properties (Mangal) Ltd [1964] 2 QB
480 at 502 is used as the main authority.
20 An example is Glofinco v Absa Bank Ltd (t/a United Bank) 2002 (6) SA 470 (SCA) at 479–480.
21 [1964] 2 QB 480 at 502.
22 William Grant & Sons Ltd v Glen Catrine Bonded Warehouse Ltd 2001 SC 901 at 944 per Lord
Clarke (where he approves Lord Keith in Armia Ltd v Daejan Developments Ltd 1979 SC (HL)
56 at 72) and per Lord President Rodger at 915.
23 J Rankine, A Treatise on the Law of Personal Bar in Scotland (1921). This situation will shortly
change with the publication of the Scottish Universities Law Institute text on Personal Bar by
John Blackie and Elspeth Reid. The author is grateful to Professor Blackie and Ms Reid for
advance sight of their chapter on agency.
130 european contract law
is intended. If so, the result is that the principal is barred from denying the
grant of authority to the agent in a question with a third party. The fact that
Article 3:201 PECL contains further conditions redolent of estoppel seems
to support this interpretation: for example, it requires a type of represen-
tation by the principal which induces reasonable reliance by the third party.
There is, however, no reference to the type of loss which the third party must
suffer, which is an issue which would normally be covered were this an
estoppel.
There is an equally persuasive argument that Article 3:201 PECL is not
based on estoppel. The language seems to indicate that, as an established
fact, authority has actually been granted to the agent. One could infer from
the context that, if the criteria are fulfilled, the agent will benefit from full
authority. This inference might arise from the fact that the other types of
authority covered in Article 3:201 PECL, i.e. express and implied authority,
are both types of actual authority. Actual authority is, of course, sufficient to
enable the agent to create contractual relations between the principal and
the third party. Comment D seems to put it beyond doubt that this inter-
pretation is the correct one:
An agent who has apparent authority will have power to bind the principal as
much as if the agent had express authority.
25 A comparison can be made with the concept of rei interventus (the forerunner of s 1(3) and (4) of
the Requirements of Writing (Scotland) Act 1995). This concept prevented a party from relying
on the absence of necessary formalities for a contract where his actings resulted in him being
personally barred from denying the existence of the contract. Thus, although, in theory, the
personal bar operated simply to prevent the party from denying the existence of the contract, the
actual practical effect was to set up a contract.
26 It is interesting to note that Article 2.2.5 PICC retains estoppel as a basis.
27 Dornier GmbH v Cannon 1991 SC 310.
28 A J Kerr, The Law of Agency, 3rd edn (1991) (henceforth Kerr, Agency) at 118–119; Quinn and Co
Ltd v Witwatersrand Military Institute 1953 (1) SA 155 (T) at 160C–E, 161F–G.
29 See Dornier GmbH v Cannon 1991 SC 310 at 314 per Lord President Hope, where he approves
a dictum of Lord Diplock which suggests that the most common form of representation is one by
conduct, “namely by permitting the agent to act in the management or conduct of the principal’s
business” (Freeman and Lockyer v Buckhurst Park Properties (Mangal) Ltd [1964] 2 QB 480 at
503).
30 For South African law see Universal Stores Ltd v OK Bazaars (1929) Ltd 1973 (4) SA 747 (A) at
761C per Rumpff JA. For Scots law see E Reid, “Personal bar: case-law in search of principle”
(2003) 7 Edinburgh LR 340 at 352, 361; Cairncross v Lorimer (1860) 3 Macq 827 at 829 per Lord
Campbell LC; William Grant & Sons Ltd v Glen Catrine Bonded Warehouse Ltd 2001 SC 901 at
925 per Lord President Rodger.
31 For South African law see Kerr, Agency at 118; Quinn and Co Ltd v Witwatersrand Military
Institute 1953 (1) SA 155 (T) at 159F–H; Reed NO v Sager’s Motors (Pty) Ltd 1970 (1) SA 521
(RAD) at 349; Seniors Service (Pty) Ltd v Nyoni 1987 (2) SA 762 (ZSC). For Scots law see
Dornier GmbH v Cannon 1991 SC 310 at 314 per Lord President Hope, where he approves the
dictum of Lord Diplock in Freeman and Lockyer v Buckhurst Park Properties (Mangal) Ltd
[1964] 2 QB 480 at 530.
132 european contract law
factors, one of which may be the agent’s appointment to that job. PECL does
not define relevant conduct on the part of the principal. This would, perhaps,
be to expect too much from PECL in view of its nature as a code rather than
detailed legislation extrapolated from case law.
32 See Gloag, Contract, at 152, citing Paterson Bros v Gladstone (1891) 18 R 403 and Hayman v
American Cotton Co (1907) 45 SLR 207.
33 Quinn and Co Ltd v Witwatersrand Military Institute 1953 (1) SA 155 (T); Monzali v Smith 1929
AD 382 at 389.
34 Glofinco v Absa Bank Ltd (t/a United Bank) 2002 (6) SA 470 (SCA) at 496; British Bata Shoe Co
v Double M Shah Ltd 1980 SC 311 at 318 per Lord Jauncey; Dornier GMBH v Cannon 1991 SC
310 at 315; Kerry v Handel, Garth & Co (1905) 21 Sh Ct Rep 106 at 109 per Sheriff Henderson.
35 See the contribution by H L MacQueen to this volume.
agency 133
(e) Causation
As in estoppel, the causal nexus between the statements or conduct and the
third party’s belief is retained. Again this protects the principal by ensuring
that his actions are the true cause of the loss.
(f) Loss
The type of loss which the third party must suffer in order to raise a successful
action is not specified in Article 3:201 PECL. This is an issue of some
complexity in English, South African and Scots law. In English law, it appears
to be an issue which differentiates apparent authority from estoppel by
representation in general. Whereas estoppel by representation appears to
require an actual loss, change of position in reliance on the representation
36
only is sufficient for apparent authority. This change of position will usually
37
be entering into a contract in reliance on the representation. However, the
English texts focus on a change of position alone, without proceeding further
38
to analyse the extent of loss which is caused by that change of position. The
requirement is therefore a relatively easy one for the third party to fulfil.
The South African requirement appears to be a more difficult one for the
third party to fulfil. David Yuill usefully examines both the type of prejudice
necessary and the time at which it must be suffered.39 According to him, the
third party must prove that he has altered his position to his prejudice.40
Thus, in contrast to English law, real prejudice or loss is a requirement. Other
writers disagree, asserting that, as in English law, a change of position alone is
sufficient.41 Case law does, however, appear to support Yuill’s view that real
prejudice is required, although that term is given a wide interpretation.42
36 Fridman, Agency at 49; Bowstead & Reynolds at para 8-026; S Wilken, Law of Waiver, Variation
and Estoppel 2nd edn (2002) at para 16.12.
37 Bowstead & Reynolds at para 8–026.
38 Fridman, Agency at 49; Bowstead & Reynolds at para 8–026.
39 These arguments are made in an unpublished article by David Yuill, “Unauthorised agency in
South African law”, on file with the author. The author would like to express her thanks to Mr Yuill
for sight of the article.
40 Yuill, “Unauthorised agency” (forthcoming) at 16.
41 D H Bester, “The scope of an agent’s power of representation” (1972) 89 SALJ 49 at 56; Kerr,
Agency at 139.
42 Yuill, “Unauthorised agency” (forthcoming) at 16; citing Jonker v Boland Bank Pks Bpk 2000 (1)
SA 542 (O); Hosken Employee Benefits (Pty) Ltd v Slabe 1992 (4) SA 183 (W) at 191C–D.
134 european contract law
With regard to timing, Yuill suggests that prejudice must be measured, not
when the change of position occurs, but rather by looking forward to the
prejudice which the third party would suffer if the principal successfully
denied that the agent was authorised.43 It is, of course, unnecessary for the
issue of timing to be analysed in English law because of the focus on a change
of position only rather than any real detriment.44
In Scotland there is no real analysis of this issue in an agency context. In
the context of a recent case on personal bar, Lord President Rodger indicated
that the loss is “that which would flow from the change of position if the
45
assumption were deserted that led to it”. The approach is similar to the South
African one: Lord Rodger seems to envisage a change of position which actually
results in some degree of prejudice. His approach also shares the South African
view as to the time at which loss must be measured: the relevant time is the
moment when the principal seeks to withdraw from the so-called contract.
PECL, by omitting to specify the degree of loss or time at which it is
measured, avoids these rather intricate questions. Whether or not this
approach is welcome is debatable. It does seem to leave a court a wide
discretion as to the questions of extent of loss and time at which it must be
suffered. One wonders just how the court would cope with such open
questions. It may be that, because PECL has not opted to take the estoppel
route, any degree of loss on the part of the third party will be treated as
relevant. If so, one can cautiously welcome the PECL solution as likely to act
in a manner which is beneficial to the third party.
43 J E De Villiers & J C Mackintosh , The Law of Agency in South Africa, 3rd edn by J M Silke (1981)
at 449.
44 Fridman, Agency at 49l; Bowstead & Reynolds at para 8–026.
45 William Grant & Sons Ltd v Glen Catrine Bonded Warhouse Ltd 2001 SC 901 at 921 per Lord
President Rodger, citing with approval Dixon J’s definition in Grundt v Great Boulder Pty Gold
Mines Ltd (1937) 59 CLR 641 at 674.
46 Comment B adds that the third party’s belief in the authorisation of the agent must be reasonable
and bona fide.
agency 135
47 Comment C does not help to clarify this point. It simply states that the request for confirmation
and ratification “amount to the same thing”.
136 european contract law
of providing the principal with a direct action against the third party in the
event of the agent’s bankruptcy. To give such a direct action to the principal
where the agent is insolvent may or may not be justifiable. To extend the
doctrine beyond the confines of insolvency takes matters much further. The
modern doctrine gives to the principal an unlimited right to a direct action.
One must query whether this extensive right is justified.
The Appellate Division was also motivated by a desire to avoid the practical
difficulties which would be caused for the right of election were several
undisclosed principals to be given the right to intervene. The third party
would be forced to elect to sue either the agent or a number of principals
whom he would be required to sue separately for his pro rata share. Clearly
this would place the third party in a situation of undesirable complexity.
Thus, in this case the Appellate Division, at the same time as accepting
that the doctrine is an established and workable part of South African law,
sought to constrain rather than expand it. Although the court supported its
view by reference to the rule against cession of a portion of a right of action,
it seems clear from the language used that the main motivation was concern
for the position of the third party.
Another case which exhibits a similar motivation is Karstein v Moribe.54
Here, the Transvaal Provincial Division refused to allow the undisclosed
principal to intervene where to do so would turn a contract, valid at the point
of formation, into an illegal contract. Ackermann J did not limit himself to the
discussion of the area of illegal contracts. Quoting at length from Potgieter
JA’s opinion in Cullinan, Ackermann J identified the ratio for restriction of
the doctrine in that case as the fear of prejudice to the third party. In an
extensive review of academic writings, not only from South Africa but also
55
from, inter alia, England and Scotland, he concluded:
There is much to be said, in my view, for the opinions of the learned writers I have
referred to above that the limitation of the undisclosed principal’s right to
56
intervene is one based on broad considerations of equity.
One may conclude, therefore, that the South African judiciary have applied
the doctrine of the undisclosed principal with great care, mindful of its status
as an exception to established principles of contract law, and careful to
constrain it as much as possible. The doctrine emerges as possessing a clearer
equitable basis than its equivalents in English or Scots law.
either on English cases, or, instead, the works of Bell, who, in turn, relied on
English cases.58 It should at least be mentioned in this context that a wealth of
analysis on agency and mandate exists in the works of the Scottish Institu-
tional Writers. The author has explored elsewhere the possibility that Scots
law did, in fact, develop its own native concept of the undisclosed principal.59
It is true to say, however, that the benefits of the works of the Institutional
Writers in this respect have been almost wholly lost by the application of
English authorities in the leading Scottish cases.
(4) PECL
(a) General
Article 3:102 PECL classifies representation into direct and indirect, with
the latter being dealt with in Section 3. One might question whether the
retention of this classification is justifiable. The term “indirect representa-
tion” evokes what is the traditionally Civilian attitude, refusing to recognise
direct actions between principal and third party. As the main thrust of the
Articles which follow is to create direct actions, the use of the term “indirect
representation” is misconceived.60 Nevertheless, Article 3:301(1) PECL pro-
ceeds to classify indirect representation into two types. Paragraph (b) equates
with the undisclosed principal, whereas paragraph (a) is the equivalent of
what is known in most European countries as “commission agency”. As the
latter is not part of English law, and therefore did not become part of Scots or
61
South African law, it will not be analysed here.
58 See, e.g., Meier v Kuchenmeister (1881) 8 R 642 at 644–645 per Lord Justice-Clerk Moncreiff;
Wester Moffat Colliery Co Ltd v A Jeffrey & Co 1911 SC 346 at 351 per Lord Ardwall; A F Craig
& Co Ltd v Blackater 1923 SC 472 at 482–483 per Lord Justice-Clerk Alness and at 485 per Lord
Ormidale. See also Bell, Commentaries I, 537 (where only one Scottish case, Hood v Cochrane 16
Jan 1818 FC, is cited in addition to English cases).
59 L J Macgregor, “Agency and mandate”, SME Reissue (2002), paras 5–17
60 This term has been dropped from the version which appears in Article 2.2.4 PICC.
61 Whether English law recognises the concept of the commission agent is analysed by D Busch in
“Indirect representation and the Lando Principles: an analysis of some problem areas from the
perspective of English law” (1999) 7 ERPL 319 at 341–346. He identifies some English cases
which could be interpreted as forming a basis for the existence of the commission agent in English
law, but his overall conclusion is that there is no strong evidence suggesting that this is the case.
62 Where indirect agency is at issue, PECL uses the term “intermediary” rather than “agent,” see
Comment A to Article 3:301 PECL.
140 european contract law
name of, a principal. Article 3:301(1) PECL states that “the intermediary and
the third party are bound to each other”. The comment indicates that this
conclusion follows because the intermediary did not act in the name of the
principal. This point is far from clear in English law. Some assert that this is
the case.63 The debate rages on, however, and, very recently, others have
appeared in print arguing that a contract is formed from the outset between
the principal and third party notwithstanding the fact that the principal is
64
completely unknown to the third party at that stage. South African and
Scots law appear to adopt a stance similar to PECL on this point. None-
theless, in both the Scots and South African legal systems it is more common
to see commentators assert that this is the correct approach rather than prove
65
it by reference to case law.
The approach asserting that a contract is formed between intermediary/
agent and third party must be preferred here. It would stretch ideas of
consensus in idem too far to hold that a contract is formed between principal
and third party where the third party is completely unaware of the existence
of the principal. English analyses stress the fact that the agent is fully
authorised to make such a contract, and justify its stance on that point alone.
This emphasis completely fails to consider the issue from the third party’s
perspective. PECL makes a significant contribution by adopting what is the
most logical conclusion and clearing up any doubt on the matter.
The direct actions of the principal and the third party emerge as excep-
tions to the general rule in PECL that the intermediary is bound to the third
66
party. Thus, where the principal is entitled to sue, he exercises against the
67
third party the rights which the intermediary has acquired on his behalf,
63 Welsh Development Agency v Export Finance Co Ltd [1992] BCLC 148. R Powell forcefully
argues to this effect: see in particular his description of this point as “an obvious fact” in The Law
of Agency, 2nd edn (1961) at 151 (see also 158, 267). This is also the argument posed by A L
Goodhart & C J Hamson “Undisclosed principals in contract” (1932) 4 Cambridge LJ 320.
64 See Cheng-Han (2004) 120 LQR 480 at 496. See also Keighley Maxsted & Co v Durant [1901] AC
240 at 261 per Lord Lindley.
65 For South African law see J C de Wet (rev B P Wanda) “Agency and representation” in LAWSA,
vol 1 (second reissue 2003) at para 228. This is also the view of the writer of the previous edition
rev A G du Plessis, first reissue 1993) at paras 154, 155. For Scots law see Meier v Kuchenmeister
(1881) 8 R 642 at 646 per Lord Young; J J Gow, Mercantile and Industrial Law of Scotland (1964)
at 525; Macgregor, “Agency and mandate”, SME Reissue, para 149.
66 It is interesting to note how similar the direct actions are to the formulation which appears in the
Dutch Civil Code. This is acknowledged in note 2 to Article 3:302 PECL and illustrated well by D
Busch, E Hondius, H van Kooten, H Schelhaas & W Schrama (eds), The Principles of European
Contract Law and Dutch Law: A Commentary (2002) (henceforth Busch et al, PECL and Dutch
Law).
67 Article 3:302(b) PECL.
agency 141
and where the third party is entitled to sue, he exercises against the principal
the rights which he had against the intermediary.68
74 [1962] 2 QB 26 at 72.
75 [1962] 2 QB 26.
76 Turnbull v McLean & Co (1874) 1 R 730.
77 Christie, Contract at 598.
78 McBryde, Contract at 511.
agency 143
Although not adopting the same unitary approach to breach as Scots law,
materiality is important in South African law, as Naude has illustrated here
and elsewhere.79 Her analysis of Scots and South African case law leads her to
suggest that the factors which appear in Article 8:103 PECL are used by
Scots and South African courts in order to decide whether the breach is
material or not.80 She therefore welcomes Article 8:103 PECL because it
encourages Scots and South African lawyers to formulate more explicitly the
81
factors that courts consider to establish materiality. Thus, although Article
8:103 PECL, with its resemblance to English law, might at first glance appear
to be some distance away from Scots and South African law, this is not neces-
sarily the case. It is, however, inevitable that any attempt to identify all of the
factors which might render a breach either material or fundamental is likely
to fall short in some way. Article 8:103 PECL could therefore be criticised as
lacking the flexibility possessed by Scots and South African law. One must
also take into account the inevitable difficulty inherent in applying what
appear to be new criteria, even if, at the end of the day, they would also be
part of the assessment of a material breach in our native systems.
Looking at the terms of Article 8:103 PECL as a whole, the important
question must be whether the PECL scheme is, as it would first appear,
narrower than the Scots and South African direct actions. It is difficult to
think of a situation in which the principal or third party would want to sue
which would not be covered by PECL’s current formulation. Both non-
performance and anticipatory non-performance are included. The only
rather unlikely situation which might not be covered under PECL would be
where the principal/third party wanted to use a direct action simply because
the “target” had a better financial reputation than the agent. The difference
between PECL and Scots/South African law therefore boils down to the
difference between material breach and the less flexible and possibly
narrower concept of fundamental non-performance appearing within PECL.
Much would depend upon how this concept was interpreted. The conclusion
must, therefore, be that the PECL formulation is not substantially narrower
than that appearing in Scots or South African law.
79 Naudé, in this volume, particularly at 283; and see also T Naudé & G Lubbe, “Cancellation for
‘material’” or ‘fundamental’ breach: a comparative analysis of South African law, the UN Con-
vention on Contracts for the International Sale of Goods (CISG) and the UNIDROIT Principles
of International Commercial Contracts” (2001) 3 Stellenbosch LR 371.
80 Naudé, in this volume at 284.
81 Naudé, in this volume at 285.
144 european contract law
(1) General
Article 3:304 PECL applies a notice requirement to the exercise of the direct
actions. Before exercising a direct action, the party bringing the action must
inform the “target” of the action that he intends to do so. Thus the principal
intending to exercise a direct action against the third party must serve notice
of his intention to do so on the third party, and vice versa in relation to the
third party exercising his direct action on the principal. There is no require-
ment that the notice be in writing.
Whether serving a notice has a substantive effect rather than simply
alerting the “target” to an impending action is a difficult question. Comment
A to this Article indicates that serving notice crystallises the moment at which
the “transfer or delegation becomes effective”. In other words, where, for
example, the principal is exercising a direct action, the notice marks the point
at which the principal “steps into” the contract originally concluded between
intermediary and third party. The language used by PECL in the comment,
“transfer or delegation”, is very imprecise and this is perhaps not surprising.
Exactly what happens to the contractual structure when the principal
intervenes is a question which has never been resolved in English law.
Clearly, it is not a valid assignation or delegation of rights. The drafters of
PECL have accepted the prevailing view that the transfer of rights cannot be
explained using normal contractual principles. The ability to exercise a direct
action under PECL must be accepted as an anomaly and, as in English law,
82
justified purely on the basis of commercial convenience.
legal systems.84 In one of the leading South African cases it was stated that
“once the cause of action against either of the two is exhausted by reason of a
judgment taken, there can be no room in principle for enforcing that same
claim against the other”.85 It is not clear under PECL whether, once notice
has been served on the “target” that an action is impending, a further action
would be available against the intermediary to recover any sums which
remain uncompensated. Those more familiar with the position under English,
Scots and South African law would tend to the, probably emphatic, view that
a further action could not be available. However, the provisions concerning
the direct actions under PECL are, in general, very similar to those contained
86
in the Dutch Civil Code. In Dutch law, where the third party is exercising
his direct action, the intermediary is not released by an unsuccessful, or
87
partially successful, action against the principal. The principal and the inter-
mediary remain jointly liable. Dutch authors have urged that PECL should
88
be interpreted in the same way. This interpretation is, however, not con-
vincing, given that PECL is entirely silent on the question. Dutch law
contains no similar protection for the principal – only the third party has the
ability to sue first the principal and then the intermediary.
84 For Scots law see Gloag, Contract at 140; David Logan & Sons Ltd v Schuldt (1903) 10 SLT 598;
British Bata Shoe Co v Double M Shah Ltd 1980 SC 311. For South African law see Talacchi v The
Master 1997 (1) SA 702 (T) at 709 per Vorster AJ.
85 Talacchi v The Master 1997 (1) SA 702 (T) at 709 per Vorster AJ.
86 See Note 2 to Article 3:302 PECL and comment by Busch et al, PECL and Dutch Law at 176–
190.
87 Article 7:421 BW.
88 Busch et al, PECL and Dutch Law at 189.
146 european contract law
Turning now to the principal’s direct action and the question of whether
the third party’s payment to the agent absolves him, or whether in Scots and
South African law he may be called upon to pay again, there must be an even
stronger argument that the third party is absolved from liability. This appears
to be the stance of both Scots96 and South African law.97 English cases which
apply estoppel as a solution to this situation, in a manner similar to that
described above in the context of the principal being required to pay again,
98
should be rejected.
Whether a party who has already paid the agent can be called upon to pay
again is clearly a difficult issue in Scots and South African law. By seeking,
through the notice requirement, to avoid such a situation ever arising, PECL
offers an attractive solution.
E. UNDISCLOSED PRINCIPAL:
AVAILABILITY OF DEFENCES AND COMPENSATION/SET OFF
(1) Exercise of principal’s direct action
As stated above, the essence of the principal’s direct action is found in Article
3:302(b) PECL: he is entitled to exercise against the third party the rights
acquired on his behalf by the intermediary. The Article also deals with the
defences which the third party can exercise against the principal if sued by
the principal. Whether the reference to defences includes rights to claim
compensation/set-off is not specified100 but may be assumed.101 As can be
expected, the guiding principle is that the third party should be in no better
or worse position than he would have been in had the principal not emerged.
Article 3:302(b) PECL therefore provides that the principal will be subject to
any defences which the third party may set up against the intermediary.
Whilst this seems to be a sensible approach, it is interesting to note that English
law provides the third party with more protection than PECL in this type of
102
situation. In addition to the ability to exercise against the principal all
defences which he would have had against the agent, the third party is also
entitled to set up against the principal all defences he would have had against
the principal, had the principal himself and not the agent made the contract.103
This additional right of the third party can only be rationalised on the basis
that English law treats the contract as formed between principal and third
party from the outset although, as already discussed, there is little agreement
on this point. PECL specifically rejects this analysis, and therefore it would
not be appropriate to include this additional protection for the third party in
Article 3:302(b) PECL. The approach of PECL in this respect is the same as
104 105
that which currently exists under Scots and South African law. There is
no evidence in either system of the additional right provided by English law.
As such, the attitude of PECL is likely to be acceptable to both jurisdictions.
F. CONCLUSION
The PECL framework for indirect representation and apparent authority is
likely, on the whole, to be acceptable to Scots and South African lawyers. It is
clear that the Common Law has been highly influential in the modelling of
the PECL provisions, and, as a result, they are similar to both Scots and
South African law. The main improvements which PECL has made are
procedural rather than substantive. Examples of such welcome improve-
ments include the rejection of estoppel as a basis for apparent authority, the
clarification of the parties to the contract, and use of the notice requirement
in the exercise of the direct actions in indirect representation. The PECL
scheme is, however, a relatively “traditional” one. PECL offers no significant
gains in third party protection. It may be that to make such gains would
involve too radical a scheme to be acceptable to those drafting PECL. Some
relatively minor criticisms have been made in the course of this chapter: for
example, the lack of any reference to election is regrettable. The PECL
scheme, in general, emerges as practical, workable and sensible, and one
which could be adopted by Scots or South African law with relative ease.
107 Waring v Favenck (1807) 1 Camp 85; Kymer v Suwercropp (1807) 1 Camp 109.
108 Busch et al, PECL and Dutch Law, 333.
109 Kerr, Agency at 271, citing Natal Trading & Milling Co Ltd v Inglis 1925 TPD 724 at 727.
6 Threats and Excessive
Benefits or Unfair Advantage
Jacques du Plessis*
A. INTRODUCTION
B. ARTICLE 4:108 PECL: THREATS
(1) The effect on the victim: the quality of the fear and reasonableness of
the conduct
(a) The overborne will approach
(b) Reasonable fear
(2) Nature of the threats and affected interests
C. ARTICLE 4:109 PECL: EXCESSIVE BENEFIT OR UNFAIR
ADVANTAGE
(1) Introduction
(2) Anticipating Article 4:109 PECL – undue influence in mixed systems
(3) Learning from Article 4:109 PECL: cases of weakness falling outside
undue influence
(a) Article 4:109 PECL from a Civilian perspective: laesio enormis and
usury
(b) Article 4:109 PECL from a Common Law perspective: undue
influence and unconscionability
(c) Article 4:109 PECL and the current position in mixed legal systems
(d) Article 4:109 PECL and the future development of mixed legal
systems
D. ARTICLE 4:111 PECL: THIRD PERSONS
E. CONCLUSIONS
A. INTRODUCTION
Chapter 4 of PECL deals with certain factors that affect the validity of a
1
contract. These include threats (Article 4:108 PECL) and excessive benefit
* This paper was presented at the Oxford University Comparative Law Discussion Group on 3 Dec
2004, as well as at the conference for this volume in Edinburgh. I would like to express my
gratitude to the organisers of these events for their respective invitations and to the participants
for their valuable comments.
1 The other factors are initial impossibility (Article 4:102 PECL), mistake (Articles 4:103–4:106
PECL), fraud (Article 4:107 PECL) and unfair terms not individually negotiated (Article 4:110
PECL). Chapter 4 does not deal with invalidity arising from illegality, immorality or lack of
capacity (Article 4:101 PECL), for which see Chapter 15.
151
152 european contract law
(1) The effect on the victim: the quality of the fear and reasonableness
of the conduct
In line with a number of modern Civilian systems,6 Article 4:108 PECL does
2 Cf J P Dawson, “Economic duress and the fair exchange in French and German law” (1937) 11
Tulane LR 345 at 346.
3 (1937) 11 Tulane LR 345 at 346; (1937) 12 Tulane LR 42.
4 On the historical development of the concepts of force and fear or metus, as well as undue
influence in mixed legal systems, see G F Lubbe, “Voidable contracts”, in Zimmermann & Visser,
Southern Cross, 261; J E du Plessis, “Force and fear”, in Reid & Zimmermann, History, 101–128.
For a comparison of the relevant Scots and South African law see J E du Plessis and W W
McBryde, “Defects of consent” in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems, 117–142.
5 Depending on the emphasis placed on these two dimensions of duress, it is possible to group legal
systems into two categories. It has been said that systems primarily focusing on the effect on the
victim are “result oriented”, while systems focusing on the conduct of the person responsible for
the duress are “means oriented”. See E A Kramer & T Probst, “Defects in the contracting
process”, International Encyclopedia of Comparative Law, vol VII/11 (2001) (henceforth Kramer
& Probst, “Defects in the contracting process”), para 387 n 1640. In this context the distinction
drawn in A Wertheimer, Coercion (1987), between the “choice” and “proposal” prongs of
coercion, is also relevant. The “choice” prong focuses on the effect on the victim, while the
“proposal” prong focuses on the means used.
6 See, e.g., § 123 BGB; Article 3:44 BW; on the limited number of modern codes that do refer to
fear, see Kramer & Probst, “Defects in the contracting process”, para 362.
threats and excessive benefits or unfair advantage 153
not require that the victim acted under fear (metus).7 It is only said that
threats of a certain quality must have “led” the victim to contract. This
indicates that a causal link should exist between the threat and the contract,
without any fear necessarily being present. Unlike earlier Civilian authority,
Article 4:108 PECL therefore does not explicitly link force/threats (vis) with
the effect of fear (metus). The mixed systems, in turn, still remain faithful to
the earlier Civilian approach by regarding fear as a requirement of a claim of
“force and fear” or duress. It is quite clear, though, that it is not sufficient for
victims to allege that they were afraid. The mixed systems require the fear to
be of a certain quality.
7 It seems warranted not to require fear where the threat in any event so inconvenienced or
irritated the victim that he was induced into concluding the contract (but cf Kramer & Probst,
“Defects in the contracting process”, paras 421, 443, who seem to maintain that the emotion of
fear is essential to provide the causal link between the threat and conclusion of the contract). If
the victim’s will had indeed been vitiated in the sense of being rendered totally nugatory, he would
also not be bound, but then other provisions come into play (see Articles 2:101 and 2:102 PECL
on the intention requirement, as well as the Comment accompanying Article 4:108 PECL). The
subjection of a person to actual physical violence, as opposed to threatened violence, but without
vitiating his will (e.g., through imprisonment) is rather problematic – PECL, like some Civil Law
systems, pass it over in silence (see Kramer & Probst, “Defects in the contracting process”, para
393 n 1669).
8 See Hislop v Dickson Motors (Forres) Ltd 1978 SLT (Notes) 73 at 75; Mahmood v Mahmood 1993
SLT 589 at 592B; du Plessis, in Reid & Zimmermann, History, 106–107 especially n 41; du Plessis
and McBryde, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems, 125.
9 See P S Atiyah, “Economic duress and the overborne will” (1982) 98 LQR 197; R Halson,
“Opportunism, economic duress and contractual modifications” (1991) 107 LQR 649 at 665 ff.
On the general decline of the theory, see Kramer & Probst, “Defects in the contracting process”,
para 363.
10 See the speech of Lord Simon of Glaisdale in Lynch v DPP of Northern Ireland [1975] AC 653 at
695.
11 In response to an article by A Thompson, “Economic duress” 1985 SLT (News) 84, Professor
Ewan McKendrick commented that, “[g]iven these criticisms of the overborne will theory, it
154 european contract law
English upon Scots law is rather ironical in this respect. The roots of the Scots
law of force and fear are Civilian. And one of the basic tenets of the Roman
law of (vis et) metus was the statement by Paulus in D 4.2.21.5 that “that
which is willed under compulsion is nonetheless willed” (voluntas coacta
tamen voluntas est), a principle which has gained general acceptance in the
Civilian tradition.12 Even English lawyers have come to prefer this principle
to the overborne will approach. For example, Paulus’s text was expressly
13
referred to in Lynch v Director of Public Prosecutions of Northern Ireland.
The experience of Scots law in being influenced by English law in this
particular context has therefore not been positive. The challenge, as modern
Civilian systems and PECL, as well as a number of Common Law lawyers
have come to accept, is rather to determine what circumstances lead a person
to do something that he does not desire to do, and especially what threats of
harm contribute to this result.
But one qualification has to be added to the criticism above of the
overborne will theory. It is only warranted if the portrayal of the “overborne
will” or “vitiated will” as one characterised by an absence of consent is indeed
accurate. According to the most recent (11th) edition of Professor Treitel’s
Law of Contract,
[t]he view that consent is ‘vitiated’ has been criticised but the criticism appears to
be based on a misrepresentation of it: what it seems to mean is, not that consent is
14
negatived, but that it has been improperly obtained.
15
In the case of The Universe Sentinel, for example, there would only be eco-
nomic duress vitiating the consent to agree to make certain payments if the
threat was illegitimate. Upon such an analysis, the position in English law,
and presumably Scots law, would be closer to that of PECL and modern
Civilian systems than has traditionally been understood.
should cause the Scottish lawyer grave concern that it still appears to form the basis of force and
fear” (“Economic duress – a reply” 1985 SLT (News) 277).
12 See Kramer & Probst, “Defects in the contracting process”, para 363.
13 [1975] AC 653 – Lord Simon tellingly adding that “I do not cite this merely for antiquarian
interest” (694 ff).
14 At 405.
15 Universe Tankships Inc of Monrovia v International Transport Workers’ Federation, The
Universe Sentinel [1983] 1 AC 366.
threats and excessive benefits or unfair advantage 155
demand” (own emphasis). This indicates that the purpose of the no “reasonable
alternative” requirement may be to assist, in a rather roundabout manner,
with determining that a causal link exists between a threat and the decision of
the victim to conclude a contract.23 There are further indications that the
question whether the absence of a reasonable alternative requirement serves
this function is also of central importance in modern English law. 24
These developments are also relevant to mixed systems. They too have to
establish more clearly why it is necessary to disqualify the victim whose fear
is not reasonable or who does not avail himself of reasonable alternatives. And
they especially need to determine whether requirements such as these do not
merely indirectly indicate that an insufficient causal link exists between
25
threat and conduct. In the South African context it can for example be argued
26
that the purpose of the reasonable fear requirement is to determine causality.
However, this does not mean that all duress issues should be reduced to
merely identifying a wrongful threat and then causally linking it to the victim’s
conduct. In this regard lawyers in mixed systems as well as those interested in
PECL would do well to follow debates in English law about the relevance of
the absence of a reasonable alternative when dealing with economic duress. It
may well be that in this context a greater justification exists for requiring that
the victim should display resilience, compared to the traditional cases of threats
of physical harm.27 Such a differentiated approach deserves serious consider-
ation by those who need to apply the reasonable fear requirement of mixed
systems and the absence of reasonable alternative requirement of PECL.
The question now arises whether mixed systems, which are well acquainted
with this abstract approach,30 and which have also demonstrated that at times
they are able to flesh out general principles by resorting to Common Law
authority,31 have anything of value to offer in this context. Here it is of parti-
cular interest that a limited number of cases on economic duress have
generated a wealth of analysis in Common Law jurisdictions.32 Unfortun-
ately, it has not been appreciated in mixed systems that, without blindly
following English law, guidance may be obtained from these analyses of
33
threats of economic harm. This is somewhat ironical given that English
lawyers increasingly appreciate that an unlawful threat is a cornerstone of
34
economic duress. Had mixed systems been more creative in resorting to
Common Law materials in this context, they could have provided valuable
guidance in fleshing out the abstract requirement in Article 4:108 PECL that
35
a threat has to be wrongful in itself or has to have a wrongful purpose.
30 South African law requires a “threat or intimidation” which is “unlawful or contra bonos mores”
(see Broodryk v Smuts NO 1942 TPD 47, BOE Bank v Van Zyl 2002 (5) SA 165(C) paras 36 ff, 49
ff; Shoprite Checkers (Pty) Ltd v Jardim 2004 (1) SA 502 (O), while Scots law recognises that the
method of instilling fear has to be illegal or unwarrantable, or, conversely, that a lawful threat
cannot be actionable; see Du Plessis and McBryde, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal
Systems, 127.
31 A notable example is the South African law of delict.
32 This is not to say that Civilian systems do not recognise that cases of economic duress fall within
the scope of unlawful threats – but, as Kramer & Probst remark, the statutory basis for economic
duress in Civilian systems does not make it any easier to decide whether it renders a contract
voidable (“Defects in the contracting process”, para 419); also see A Hadjiani, “Duress and undue
influence in English and German contract law: a comparative study on vitiating factors in
Common and Civil Law” 2002 Oxford University Comparative Law Forum 1 at http://ouclf.
iuscomp.org, part IV (b) (cc) (accessed on 31 March 2005).
33 In both Hendricks v Barnett 1975 (1) SA 765 (N) and Van den Berg and Kie Rekenkundige
Beamptes v Boomprops 1028 BK 1999 (1) SA 780 (T) the requirement that the threat has to be
contra bonos mores could have been given greater meaning through creative use of comparable
English material without having to accept that South African law has taken over English legal
principles relating to duress, and economic duress in particular, or that such principles should
necessarily determine legal developments in South Africa. South African courts are obliged to
apply the English law of economic duress in admiralty law (see Malilang v MV Houda Pearl 1986
(2) SA 714 (A)). The Namibian Labour Court did not sufficiently appreciate in Vlasiu v President
of the Republic of Namibia 1994 R 332 (LC) that Malilang was an admiralty case, and that English
law consequently had to be applied.
34 Treitel, Contract, 405–406; J Cartwright, Unequal Bargaining (1991) (henceforth Cartwright,
Unequal Bargaining), 163 ff; J Cartwright, “Defects of consent and security of contract: French
and English law compared”, in P Birks and A Pretto (eds), Themes in Comparative Law in
Honour of Bernard Rudden (2002), 153 at 162. It should be noted, though, that the threat must
still have a “coercive effect”: “no particular type of threat is regarded as ipso facto having such
effect or being incapable, as a matter of law, of producing it”.
35 See Note 2 to Article 4:108 PECL (vol 1, 260).
158 european contract law
(1) Introduction
In the previous section it was relatively easy to link a specific provision of
PECL, namely Article 4:108 PECL on threats, with specific areas of Scots
and South African law, namely force and fear and duress, respectively.
Unfortunately, the position is not that simple when dealing with Article 4:109
PECL. The heading “excessive benefit or unfair advantage” is somewhat
misleading. The Article does not only deal with the essentially “substantive”
matters of excessive benefit or unfair advantage. It also contains other
“procedural” requirements. As the definition indicates, the aggrieved party
had to be in some position of weakness which the other party either knew
about or should have known about, and then took advantage of. It is only after
this subtle shift in emphasis that it becomes clearer that Article 4:109 PECL
can be linked to certain grounds for avoiding contracts in mixed legal
systems. These grounds are undue influence in both Scots law and South
African law, and facility and circumvention in Scots law.
(a) Article 4:109 PECL from a Civilian perspective: laesio enormis and usury
Some Continental European legal systems recognise that the substantive
disproportion between the values of performances may influence the validity
of a contract – in other words, they still subscribe to the modern equivalents
of the doctrine of laesio enormis. However, other systems, such as German
law, provide only relief if the conclusion of an excessively one-sided or unfair
contract was accompanied by certain procedural problems – most notably
taking advantage of certain types of weakness or vulnerability. This is also the
approach followed in Article 4:109 PECL. To understand this type of
approach better, it is helpful to examine the German experience more
closely. And to understand this experience the clock should be turned back to
the late nineteenth century,42 when drafting Commissions of the new German
Civil Code were engaged in serious deliberations as to whether a provision on
laesio enormis should be included in the code. They knew that there had been
unfortunate experiences with its application, especially with determining
when it may be renounced. The Commission then decided not to include
such provision – as Dawson has put it, “Germany’s protracted experience
with laesio enormis produced a profound disbelief in this arithmetical
43
standard of fairness”. But, as Dawson also pointed out:
The doctrine of laesio enormis was indeed condemned. What proved harder to
destroy was the central core of ideas which had there achieved inadequate
expression. Before the final publication of the German Civil Code these ideas
were unexpectedly to reappear in a new form but under a very old name. The idea
44
that was to be appropriated for the purpose was the idea of usury.
types of weakness.46 It is from this approach that the Reichstag took its lead.
At the eleventh hour, after the drafting Commission had completed its work,
the centre and left wings of the Reichstag pushed for the introduction of
similar restrictions on usury (or Wucher) in the Civil Code. The new pro-
vision on Wucher was then latched on to the general prohibition in §138(1)
BGB of transactions that offend good morals (i.e. are gegen die gute Sitten).
The location of the new §138(2) BGB in the Code is significant: in essence, it
only deals with a concrete instance of transactions that offend good morals.
Today, after a reform in 1976, it reads as follows:
In particular, voidness attaches to a legal transaction, whereby one person through
exploitation of the distressed situation [Zwangslage], inexperience [Unerfahren-
heit], lack of the ability to form a sound judgment [Mangel an Urteilsvermögen] or
grave weakness of will [erhebliche Willensschwäche] of another, causes economic
advantages to be promised or granted to himself or to a third party in exchange for
a performance, and these advantages exceed the value of the performance to such
an extent that, under the circumstances, there is a striking disproportion between
47
them .
It did not take the German courts long to realise that §138(2) BGB did not
adequately take account of cases where a person was mentally weak without
being insane. The courts therefore expanded the illegality requirement of
§138(1) BGB to cover these cases that were analogous to those falling under
48
§138(2) BGB. In addition, §138(1) BGB could be made to cover situations
where disadvantageous contracts were concluded by economically inferior or
pressurised parties, or by parties who had been subjected to undue solicita-
49
tions. In this way German law could now also provide relief in situations
50
comparable to those covered by the Common Law of undue influence.
Nowadays a number of Continental codes contain provisions comparable
51
to §138(2) and the extensions to §138(1) BGB. For example, the drafters of
46 The inequality between performance and counterperformance had to be achieved through
“exploitation of the necessity [Notlage], thoughtlessness [Leichtsinn] or inexperience [Unerfahren-
heit] of the other party. See Dawson, (1937) 12 Tulane LR 42 at 48 ff; Zimmermann, Obligations,
175 f; Zimmermann, The New German Law of Obligations: Historical and Comparative Perspec-
tive (forthcoming henceforth Zimmermann, The New German Law of Obligations), ch 5, II.7.
47 See Zimmermann, Obligations, 176; Zweigert & Kötz, Comparative Law, 330; Dawson (1976) 89
Harvard LR 1041 at 1052. Before 1976, § 138 II BGB had defined the instances of weakness in
the way set out in note 46.
48 See Dawson (1937) 12 Tulane LR 41 at 64 f; Dawson (1976) 89 Harvard LR 1041 at 1061; on
“wucherähnliche Geschäfte”, see Rolf Sack, in J von Staudinger, Kommentar zum Bürgerlichen
Gesetzbuch (revised edition 2003), § 138 nn 228 ff.
49 See Dawson (1937) 12 Tulane LR 41 at 64–68; Zimmermann, The New German Law of
Obligations, ch 5, VI.1.b) and c).
50 Dawson (1937) 12 Tulane LR at 64; Hadjiani, 2002 Oxford University Comparative Law Forum,
VII, IX.
162 european contract law
the New Dutch Civil Code have been directly inspired by the German § 138,
as well as the English law of undue influence, when they decided to adopt
abuse of circumstances, independently from threats and fraud, as a ground
for attacking the validity of a contract.52
From this short overview it should be apparent that from the perspective
of some Civilian systems, Article 4:109 PECL in terms of both its structure
and approach can be regarded as a modern manifestation of the earlier
prohibitions of usury, rather than laesio enormis.
(b) Article 4:109 PECL from a Common Law perspective: undue influence
and unconscionability
From the Comment and Notes to Article 4:109 PECL it is apparent that the
drafters were not only mindful of Continental positions in the law of lesion
53
and usury, but also of certain parallel developments in the Common Law.
These are undue influence, which we have already touched upon, and
54
unconscionability. To appreciate the relevance of unconscionability in the
present context, a historical perspective is again of value.
It was shown above that in the middle of the nineteenth century, the
relaxation of usury laws in Germany gave rise to abuses that had to be righted
by legislative reform. Significantly, after a long agitation, usury laws were at
that time also relaxed in Britain,55 only to give rise to similar problems.
Unconscionability, which was an established instrument for protecting weak
persons who concluded usurious transactions, then came into greater pro-
minence. Although it is rather difficult for an outsider to grasp its ambit, the
impression is that unconscionability protects persons, sometimes described
51 See PECL, vol 1, 264–265; see Article 3:44(4) BW; Articles 1447, 1448 of the Italian Codice
Civile; Articles 282–283 of the Portuguese Código Civil; Article 118 of the Luxembourg Code
Civil.
52 Article 3:44(4) PECL (“A person who knows or should know that another is being induced to
execute a juridical act as a result of special circumstances – such as state of necessity, dependency,
wantonness, abnormal mental condition or inexperience – and who promotes the creation of that
juridical act, although what he knows or ought to know should prevent him therefrom, commits
an abuse of circumstances”). As to its background, see C J van Zeben and J W du Pon (eds),
Parlementaire Geschiedenis van het Nieuwe Burgerlijk Wetboek (1981), 203, 210; A S Hartkamp,
“Das neue niederländische Bürgerliche Gesetzbuch aus europäischer Sicht” (1993) 57 RabelsZ
664 at 673.
53 PECL, vol 1, 264 f.
54 Cf Treitel, Contract, 420 ff; Cartwright, Unequal Bargaining, 197 ff; J Beatson, Anson’s Law of
Contract, 28th edn (2002) (henceforth Beatson, Anson’s Law of Contract), 296–298.
55 See Alec Lobb (Garages) Ltd v Total Oil (Great Britain) Ltd [1983] 1 WLR 87 (henceforth Lobb v
Total Oil), 94; for the background to the repeal of these laws see P S Atiyah, The Rise and Fall of
Freedom of Contract (1979) (henceforth Atiyah, Rise and Fall of Freedom of Contract), 550–551.
threats and excessive benefits or unfair advantage 163
as the “poor and ignorant”,56 who have been exploited and entered into
oppressive contracts.57 This is done by a presumption of impropriety, which
then has to be rebutted by the party seeking to enforce the contract.58
It should be noted that we again are not dealing with relief purely on the
basis that a contract is unfair in its substance or content.59 As in the case of
undue influence, or the modern German law of usury for that matter, it is a
combination of substantive and procedural requirements that have to be met
before relief can be provided.
(c) Article 4:109 PECL and the current position in mixed systems
From the above overview, it should be apparent that some Civil Law and
Common Law constructs give relief in situations of weakness which do not
fall under undue influence, duress or fraud. The fate of these and compar-
able constructs in the mixed systems will now be examined, starting with
laesio enormis.
Although Roman-Dutch law inherited the doctrine of laesio enormis from
post-classical Roman law, it was rejected in the Cape and Natal in the late
nineteenth century, at roughly the same time as undue influence was on the
rise. Subsequently laesio enormis was abolished by statute in the whole of
South Africa.60 This was done after the Appellate Division had severely criti-
cised the doctrine, branding it as “redolent of the cerebrina aequitas of Con-
stantinople and Berytus” and as “inherently arbitrary and preposterous”.61
Incidentally, to some it appeared rather odd that a system which could reject
laesio enormis could at the same time embrace undue influence.62 For
example, Professor J C de Wet of the Stellenbosch Law Faculty caustically
remarked that:
56 Apparently, these disabilities are nowadays interpreted more liberally (see Cresswell v Potter
[1978] 1 WLR 255; Watkin v Watson-Smith, The Times, 3 July 1986; Cartwright, Unequal
Bargaining, 202; K N Scott, “Evolving equity and the presumption of undue influence” (2002) 18
Journal of Contract Law 236 at 241 n 33; but cf also Beatson, Anson’s Law of Contract, 298.
Treitel refers to unfair advantage being taken “of a person who is poor, ignorant or weak-minded,
or is for some other reason in need of special protection” (Contract, 421, own emphasis).
57 It has been said that the contract has to be so oppressive that it “shocks the conscience of the
court” (Lobb v Total Oil; Scott (2002) 18 Journal of Contract Law 236 at 241).
58 See Treitel, Contract, 420.
59 On the general rejection in English law of providing relief purely on this basis, see S A Smith, “In
defence of substantive fairness” (1996) 112 LQR 138; but cf D Capper, “Undue influence and
unconscionability: a rationalisation” (1998) 114 LQR 479 at 501.
60 Section 25 of the General Law Amendment Act 32 of 1952.
61 Tjollo Ateljees (Eins) Bpk v Small 1949 (1) SA 856 (A) at 862–863.
62 Preller v Jordaan 1956 (1) SA 483 (A), the locus classicus, which placed the final stamp of approval
on undue influence, was decided only four years after the abolition of laesio enormis.
164 european contract law
in the light of the abolition of laesio enormis it is quite puzzling that the Appellate
Division pampers the doctrine of undue influence. The courts took off the
shepherd’s cloak of Justinian, or is it now Diocletian, and put on the cloak of
63
Father Christmas.
But, as we have seen, this comparison is rather unfair, since undue influence,
unlike laesio enormis, contains substantive as well as procedural require-
ments. Nowadays, it is clear in South African law that a contractual term
cannot be avoided merely because it substantively gives a party an “excessive
benefit”. A contractual term may of course be illegal if its content or purpose
is contrary to public policy, but this requirement is interpreted narrowly – in
essence, the impropriety of the transaction and the element of public harm
must be manifest.64 A term generally is not illegal merely because one party
obtains a benefit which is considered excessive. A contractual term would
also be illegal if it is contrary to statute, and in this regard there are a number
of statutory regulations, such as the limitations on usury by the prescription
65 66
of maximum interest rates and on certain terms in credit agreements.
Through applying the illegality test, the courts may protect weak parties, for
example, employees entering into restraint of trade agreements, or borrowers
who were required to provide security to the extent that they were virtually
67
enslaved by their creditors. But such protection is at best indirect, or a by-
product of the regulation of the substance of the contract.
So far as concerns giving more concrete protection to weak parties by
resorting to the notion of good faith, the South African Supreme Court of
Appeal is adopting a careful approach, and is especially wary of a free-floating
principle to which courts might resort whenever they feel that they do not
want to enforce a contract.68 It is not entirely surprising that the South African
Law Commission has suggested some rather bold legislative reforms. This has
taken the form of a potentially far-reaching Bill on the Control of Unreason-
ableness, Unconscionableness [sic] or Oppressiveness in Contracts or Terms.69
This Bill inter alia provides that a court can strike down any contract or
contractual term if the way in which it has come about is “unreasonable,
unconscionable or oppressive”. The guidelines supposed to assist a court in
reaching its decision include lack of relative bargaining power (2(a)), and lack
of intelligibility (2(h)). However, at present the fate of the Bill is uncertain.
As far as Scots law is concerned, the position is not that different. Laesio
70
enormis had already been rejected in the seventeenth century by Stair. At
present, the mere fact that a contractual term is harsh still does not affect its
invalidity. It is only in a number of exceptional cases that, as Professor McBryde
has put it, there is “spasmodic control”; it relates to minors’ contracts, penalty
71
clauses, leonine partnerships, moneylending and irritancies. Nothing has come
of a proposal by the Scottish Law Commission more than twenty-five years
ago that a new ground for annulment of obligations styled “lesion” should be
introduced, which was defined in terms of taking unfair advantage of a person’s
72
weak personal or economic position. The idea was that this ground would
exist alongside error and threats, but replace facility and circumvention,
undue influence and extortion (in the sense of exploiting another’s necessity).
Under Scots law, contractual terms can also be invalid if found to be
contrary to public policy, or contra bonos mores. Statutory control is further
exercised over unfair contract terms,73 and certain credit agreements – more
specifically, section 137 of the Consumer Credit Act 1974 enables a court
which finds a credit bargain extortionate to reopen it so as to do justice
74
between the parties. Of interest in the present context is that in deter-
70 Stair, Institutions, 1.10.14 (“But the question is here, Whether in these contracts there be a moral
necessity to keep an exact equality, that whosoever ex post facto, shall be found to have made an
unequal bargain, the gainer ought to repair the loser. In this the Romans did not notice every
inequality, but that which was enorm, above the half of the just value; which our custom alloweth not”).
71 McBryde, Contract, para 17–22.
72 Defective Consent and Consequential Matters (Scot Law Com Memorandum No 42, 1978), vol
1, paras 1.56 ff, vol 2, paras 3.120 ff.
73 See the Unfair Contract Terms Act 1977 (c 50); Unfair Terms in Consumer Contracts Regulations
(SI 1999/2083), which came into effect on 1 Oct 1999; although these regulations appear to focus
on substantive unfairness, it has been argued that the regulations are not primarily concerned
with substantive fairness but with the prevention of unfair surprises and the absence of real choice
(Beatson, Anson’s Law of Contract, 305). The English and Scottish Law Commissions have
recently published a Report proposing a simpler law of unfair contract terms, by combining the
1977 Act and the 1999 Regulations and widening the control over non-negotiated terms in
business-to-business contracts to protect small businesses: see Report on Unfair Terms in
Contracts, Law Com No 292, Scot Law Com No 199 (2005).
74 Section 137. The provisions are under review. A Government Consumer Credit Bill, under which
the current ss 137–140 would have been repealed, with a new set of ss 140A–D introduced to
govern “unfair relationships” between debtors and creditors, fell in April 2005 when a General
Election was called before the Bill had completed its parliamentary course. The Bill was, how-
ever, reintroduced following the election.
166 european contract law
mining whether a credit bargain is extortionate, section 138 of the 1974 Act
provides that regard shall be had to, inter alia, the prevailing interest rates,
the debtor’s age, experience, business capacity, state of health and extent to
which he was under financial pressure, and his relationship to the creditor.75
It should be apparent that, in the limited context of credit bargains, we are
dealing with a set of circumstances that bear some resemblance to situations
covered by Article 4:109 PECL. But crucially, section 138 only applies to
credit bargains and not to contractual bargains in general.
Finally, Scottish courts, under English influence, have recognised that
good faith can play a prominent role when considering whether parties
should be made to bear the consequences of improperly obtained consent if
they do not take at least some steps to protect their contracting partners. I
will return to this matter when three-party issues are considered in the
context of Article 4:111 PECL below.
(d) Article 4:109 PECL and the future development of mixed legal systems
The overview above shows that mixed systems were progressive by adopting
undue influence, but that they were also somewhat conservative by not
providing relief in other cases of weakness, such as necessity, improvidence,
ignorance or inexperience. Two questions now arise. The first is whether
Scots and South African law should also provide relief in these cases and the
second, on the assumption that the first question is answered positively, is
whether there are suitable instruments with which to promote this end.
1. As far as the first question is concerned, it is simply not clear why taking
advantage of a person’s economic distress, urgent needs, improvidence,
ignorance, inexperience or inability to bargain is qualitatively so different
from the protected case of taking advantage of another’s trust and confidence.
These are all instances of taking advantage of weakness or vulnerability that
may not have been created by the party seeking to enforce the contract, but
are now consciously used to conclude a disadvantageous contract.
It is also not clear why the fact that the exploitation relates to one type of
contract, rather than another, should necessarily influence whether relief is
76
to be granted. For example, why should protection be afforded to weak
parties who conclude extortionate credit bargains due to inexperience and
financial pressure under section 138 of the Consumer Credit Act, but not to
75 Section 138.
76 But cf J Cartwright, ”Taking stock of O’Brien” (1999) 7 RLR 1 at 15, on the need for taking the
special context of suretyship into account when determining whether third parties should bear
the consequences of vitiated consent.
threats and excessive benefits or unfair advantage 167
parties who suffer similar weaknesses and then conclude other transactions
that are equally extortionate? It will be recalled that this type of anomaly was
removed when the reformers of German law more than a century ago
introduced §138 of the new Civil Code. This provision broadened the scope
of “usury” (and incidentally by so doing reverted to its medieval meaning)77 to
include a variety of substantively disadvantageous transactions concluded as
a result of certain types of weakness. This is also the approach of Article 4:109
PECL, which applies to contracts in general, without any specific regimes for
sales, loans, providing services, suretyship contracts, and so forth.
2. Once it is accepted that an argument can be made for broadening the
scope of protection, the second question arises of how this can best be
achieved. One possibility is, of course, to introduce broad legislative provisions,
such as Article 4:109 PECL. However, as indicated above, the legislative
route has thus far not been very promising. This naturally shifts the focus to
judicial development of institutions that might either be transplanted from
other jurisdictions, or already form part of the existing non-statutory law.
Here a number of vehicles for change can be considered.
It is not necessary to deal at length with the vehicle of unconscionability.
There are at least two rather serious obstacles in the way of transplanting it
into mixed jurisdictions. The first is that the climate in mixed systems is at
present not conducive for such a wholesale reception. In the nineteenth and
early twentieth centuries, judges were rather free to incorporate features of
78
the Common Law into the existing law. Nowadays, the judiciaries of the
mixed systems, although certainly not hostile to the comparative method, are
79
more conscious of developing domestic law.
The second obstacle relates to the track record of the doctrine itself. It has
80
not only been applied rarely, but has given rise to a remarkable divergence
in views on its relationship with undue influence – especially on the extent to
which unconscionability and undue influence are “plaintiff”- or “defendant”-
81
based, and whether the one should be subsumed under the other. There is
every reason to believe that if mixed systems were ever to receive the
Common Law doctrine of “unconscionability”, similar demarcation problems
would arise.
The second possible vehicle for change is the law of illegality. It has been
shown that the German codification rejected laesio enormis, but subsumed
“usury” and related cases where a substantively disadvantageous contract was
concluded due to the exploitation of specific forms of weakness under § 138
BGB, which requires that a transaction should not be contrary to public morals.
Given that mixed systems have jettisoned laesio enormis and further have
a very limited, statutory conception of usury, it can be asked whether they
may use the legality requirement to provide relief in these other cases of
weakness. Again, the answer is that the prospects for such a development
seem limited. Apart from the obvious fact that German law achieved this
outcome through some rather bold legislation, illegality in the mixed systems
in any event generally relates to the substance or content of the contract, and
82
not to the manner in which it was concluded. It is of course true that by
finding that the substance or purpose of a contract is contrary to public policy,
protection can be afforded to an exploited weak party. But, as indicated above,
such protection is essentially a by-product of controlling of the substance of
the contract.
This brings us to the third possible vehicle for change, namely the law of
undue influence. Certain features make this a more appealing alternative83
than the previous two. Unlike unconscionability, it nowadays is firmly
former is “plaintiff”-sided, and requires impaired autonomy or consent, rather than improper
exploitation by the defendant (cf P Birks & N-Y Chin, “On the nature of undue influence”, in J
Beatson & D Friedmann (eds), Good Faith and Fault in Contract (1995), 57; also see P Birks,
“Undue influence as wrongful exploitation” (2004) 120 LQR 34, drawing on Hammond v Osborn
[2002] EWCA Civ 885; but see Scott (2002) 18 Journal of Contract Law 236 at 239 on the
negative implications of Etridge for this view). Others have argued that undue influence (see
Capper (1998) 114 LQR 479), or even undue influence and economic duress (A Phang, “Undue
influence methodology, sources and linkages” [1995] Journal of Business Law 552) can be
subsumed under a general doctrine of unconscionability. Apparently, the broader scope given to
unconscionability in Australia has given rise to a decrease in the significance of undue influence.
For demarcation problems see further M Chen-Wishart’s analysis of Credit Lyonnais Bank
Nederland NV v Burch [1997] 1 All ER 144 (“The O’Brien principle and substantive unfairness”
(1997) 56 Cambridge LJ 60).
82 See Barnard v Barnard 2000 (3) SA 741 (C) at 753–754; Van Huyssteen, Onbehoorlike
Beïnvloeding, 133–134. But procedural problems are not irrelevant – see Afrox Healthcare Bpk v
Strydom 2002 (6) SA 21 (A) at para [12] on the possibility that inequality of bargaining power can
be a factor in determining whether an agreement is contrary to the public interest (also see
Christie, Contract, 416).
83 On such a facilitative function of undue influence, see Van Huyssteen, Onbehoorlike
Beïnvloeding, 126–141.
threats and excessive benefits or unfair advantage 169
Determining the extent to which third persons may be made to bear the
consequences of the type of defects of consent under review is a highly
95
complex matter. The focus here will only be on Article 4:111(2)(e) PECL.
This provision relates to a fact pattern which has given rise to some of the
most heated debates in modern contract doctrine – that of one party pro-
viding security for the debts of another closely related party (usually a spouse)
in favour of a third party (usually a financial institution). This fact pattern,
which due to the inventiveness of some Australian feminists has come to be
described as “sexually transmitted debt”,96 has received particular attention in
Scots law. I will therefore only focus on the development in that jurisdiction.97
98 See the judgment of Lord Hope in Mumford v Bank of Scotland; Smith v Bank of Scotland 1996
SLT 392.
99 1997 SC (HL) 111.
100 1997 SC (HL) 111 at 118.
101 1997 SC (HL) 111 at 122.
102 [1994] 1 AC 180.
103 1997 SC (HL) 111 at 121.
104 E McKendrick, “The undue influence of English law?”, in Essays Wilson, 214 ff.
105 [2002] 2 AC 773.
106 Clydesdale Bank plc v Black 2002 SC 555 at para 31.
threats and excessive benefits or unfair advantage 173
E. CONCLUSIONS
As indicated at the outset, one aim of this volume is to determine whether the
solutions found by the draftsmen of PECL have been anticipated in the two
mixed systems. As we have seen, one such instance is the reception of the
Common Law of undue influence to fill a gap between the Civil Law of force
and fear/duress and fraud. In this way mixed systems have reached an
outcome which is now at least partially also achieved by Article 4:109 PECL.
But mixed systems have also at times missed opportunities, which could have
resulted in them anticipating developments in PECL. They do not generally
provide relief in cases of what is called unconscionability under the Common
Law, whereas cases of necessity and ignorance are also brought home under
Article 4:109 PECL. And although there does not seem to be a problem in
either of the mixed systems with recognising that threats of economic harm
can be unlawful,118 these systems have hardly made use of the opportunity to
give greater scope to the notion of unlawfulness by drawing on the Common
Law of economic duress. Such a development could have been an interesting
precursor to the assimilation in Article 4:108 PECL of the Civil Law and
Common Law of threats of physical as well as economic harm under the
broad requirement that the threat has to be wrongful.
A second aim of this volume is to evaluate the respective positions adopted
in the mixed systems compared to PECL. In this regard it was pointed out
that the overborne will theory has had an unfortunate effect on the Scots law
of force and fear, whereas Article 4:109 PECL avoids such problems by
(merely) requiring that a wrongful threat must have led or influenced a party
119
to conclude the contract. But lessons can also be learned from the mixed
systems which may assist in refining PECL. When dealing with three-party
problems under Article 4:111 PECL, the experiences of Scottish courts in
determining whether third parties should bear the consequences of undue
influence and related situations are particularly instructive. However, as we
have seen, it may well be that both the mixed systems and PECL could
benefit from reconsidering their refusal to assist weak parties by making use
of presumptions of impropriety.
118 See McBryde, Contract, para 17–04; Christie, Contract, 353–354; Du Plessis, Compulsion and
Restitution, 68 ff, 102, 131 ff. The statement in the Notes to Article 4:108 that “economic duress
has not yet been recognised in … Scots law” (see PECL, vol 1, 260) is therefore incorrect,
inasmuch as it suggests that Scots law does not recognise that threats of economic harm can give
rise to force and fear.
119 Also see PECL, vol 1, 259–260 (Comment D, Note 1 to Article 4:108 PECL).
7 Interpretation
Eric Clive
A. INTRODUCTION
B. THE PECL RULES: CIVIL LAW, COMMON LAW OR MIXED?
(1) The PECL rules
(2) Civilian influences?
(3) English influences?
(4) The American Restatement
(5) United Nations Convention on the International Sale of Goods
(6) Preliminary conclusion
(7) Further considerations
(a) Is English law really so different?
(b) Are Civilian systems so similar to PECL and each other?
(8) Conclusion on PECL as a mixed system
C. PECL RULES IN RELATION TO SCOTTISH AND SOUTH
AFRICAN LAW
(1) Introduction
(2) General impressions
(3) Must there be ambiguity before extrinsic evidence is admissible?
(4) Negotiations
(5) Subsequent conduct
D. ASSESSMENT OF PECL RULES
(1) Considerations which have to be taken into account
(2) Important policy choices
(a) Scope
(b) Rules of law or rules of evidence?
(c) One-step or two-step process?
(d) One rule for all contracts or different rules for different types?
(e) Subjective or objective starting point?
(3) Main PECL rules assessed
(a) Rule in Article 5:101(1) PECL
(b) Rule in Article 5:101(2) PECL
(c) Rule in Article 5:101(3) PECL
(d) Rules in Article 5:102 PECL
(e) Other rules
(f) Some criticisms
176
interpretation 177
A. INTRODUCTION
Given the statement in the Introduction to PECL to the effect that one of the
benefits offered by them “is to provide a bridge between the civil law and the
1
common law” it is of some interest, particularly for those from so-called
“mixed systems” like Scotland and South Africa, to try to detect major
influences on parts of PECL. Are the PECL rules predominantly Civil Law,
predominantly Common Law, or “mixed”? I will therefore consider the
PECL rules on interpretation from this point of view before turning to what
are for me more interesting questions – namely whether the PECL rules on
interpretation are acceptable rules, and how they compare with the rules in
Scottish and South African law.
contract; usages; and good faith and fair dealing. There are further Articles
containing some rules of preference for cases of doubt.3 These Articles
contain, for example, the contra proferentem rule, a rule giving preference to
individually negotiated terms over standard terms, a rule giving preference to
an interpretation which renders the terms of the contract lawful or effective,
and a rule giving a preference to the linguistic version in which the contract
was originally drawn up.
BGB places particular stress on good faith and usage in the interpretation of
contracts.9 The Italian Civil Code also says that the contract is to be inter-
preted “in accordance with good faith”.10
Most of the later Articles on interpretation can also be seen to have
Civilian origins. Versions of the rule in Article 5:102 PECL on having regard
to the nature and purpose of the contract, the rule in Article 5:103 PECL on
interpretation contra proferentem, the rule in Article 5:105 PECL on
reference to the contract as a whole, and the rule in Article 5:106 PECL on
preferring a construction which renders the terms of a contract lawful or
11
effective can be found in the Digest. From there they made their way into
12 13 14
Pothier, the French Civil Code and several other civil codes.
In short, it is not difficult to find Civilian origins for most of the provisions
in Chapter 5 of PECL.
9 § 157.
10 Article 1366.
11 D 50.17.67; D 12.1.3; D 1.3.24; D 34.5.26 (27); and D 45.1.80.
12 Traité des Obligations, 92, 93, 96, 97.
13 Articles 1157, 1158, 1161, 1162.
14 Articles 1363, 1367, 1369, 1370 of the Italian Civil Code; Articles 1284, 1285, 1286, 1288 of the
Spanish Civil Code.
15 See e.g. Hartog v Colin & Shields [1939] 3 All ER 566 (hare skins offered at so much per pound.
Should have been clear to offeree that offeror meant so much per piece. Offeree nonetheless
accepted. Offeree not allowed to found on contract as written). Reference can also be made to the
House of Lords case of Sutton & Co v Ciceri (1890) 15 AC 144, (1890) 17 R(HL) 40 which,
although a Scottish case, did not proceed on any speciality of Scottish law.
16 29th edn (2004), paras 5-068–5-075.
17 The immediate origin appears to have been CISG but, in essence, the rule is an application of the
principle of good faith in the interpretation of contracts.
180 european contract law
The Notes to the third paragraph of Article 5:101 PECL say that the
paragraph is similar to the basic rule in English law. That is true, but the rule
is not exclusively English and it seems doubtful whether English law was the
main origin of the rule.
In short, there is not much in Chapter 5 of PECL that has an immediately
recognisable English law origin.
There are also some similarities between Article 5:102 PECL and Article 8(3)
of the Convention which provides that:
[Iin determining the intention of a party or the understanding a reasonable person
would have had, due consideration is to be given to all relevant circumstances of
the case including the negotiations, any practices which the parties have estab-
lished between themselves, usages and any subsequent conduct of the parties.
22 Bank of Credit and Commerce International v Ali [2002] 1 AC 251 at 259 (henceforth BCCI v
Ali).
23 Ford v Beech (1848) 11 QB 852 at 866.
24 29th edn (2004), para 12–042.
25 Often, but not always. For example, in what is now the classic and dominant statement of the rules
on the interpretation of contracts in English law, Lord Hoffmann does not mention the common
intention of the parties: see Investors Compensation Scheme v West Bromwich Building Society
[1998] 1 WLR 896 (henceforth Investors Compensation Scheme).
26 See Chitty on Contracts, 29th edn (2004), para 12–000.
182 european contract law
27 See Lord Hoffmann, “The intolerable wrestle with words and meaning” (1997) 114 SALJ 656.
28 The Karen Oltmann [1976] 2 Lloyd’s Rep 708 at 713. Note also Lord Hoffmann’s statements to
the effect that the background which can be taken into account in interpreting a contractual
document can include “proved common assumptions which were in fact quite mistaken”:
Investors Compensation Scheme (note 25) as modified in BCCI v Ali (note 22) at 269.
29 See e.g. Centrovincial Estates plc v Merchant Investors Assurance Ltd [1983] Com LR 158,
Chitty on Contracts, 29th edn (2004), paras 5-063, 5-068–5-075.
30 Mannai Investment Co Ltd v Eagle Star Insurance [1997] AC 749 (henceforth Mannai). This case
concerned a unilateral notice by a tenant which said 12 January when it should have said 13
January. The court held that any reasonable landlord would have realised that 13 January was
meant and interpreted the notice accordingly.
interpretation 183
to the parties in order to ascertain what would objectively have been under-
stood to have been their intention. He went on to say that:
[t]he fact that the words are capable of a literal application is no obstacle to
evidence which demonstrates what a reasonable person with knowledge of the
background would have understood the parties to mean, even if this compels one
to say that they used the wrong words.
effect that if the words appear to be contrary to the evident intention of the
parties the latter prevails,42 but the order of treatment is interesting. Some
Civilian systems keep the legal rules on interpretation deliberately short on
the view that there is no point in stating fairly obvious and often contradictory
rules for the guidance of interpreters. In Germany the BGB says that
contracts are to be interpreted according to the requirements of good faith,
43
giving consideration to common usage. It says little else: it does not contain
the various canons of construction found in a number of other civil codes.
44
The new Dutch Civil Code is also very brief. The rules in these systems do
not look at all like the PECL rules.
(1) Introduction
What has been said in the last paragraph applies also to the Scottish and South
African laws on the interpretation of contracts. They have been exposed to
Roman law and English law influences but, more importantly, have had to
45 See C Lewis, “Interpretation of contracts” in Zimmermann & Visser, Southern Cross, 195–216; E
Clive, “Interpretation” in Reid & Zimmermann, History, vol 2, 47–71.
46 For a comparison of both systems which brings out clearly the shifts and differences of opinion
and the tensions, see L J Macgregor & C Lewis, “Interpretation of contract”, in Zimmermann,
Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems, 66–93. For Scotland, see also MacQueen & Thomson,
Contract, 110–117 (which begins with the traditional objective approach and then proceeds to ask
about a “change in approach”) and the Scottish Law Commission’s Report on Interpretation in
Private Law (Scot Law Com No 160, 1997), which is critical of the extent to which the current law
is dominated by restrictive and complicated rules of evidence. For South Africa, see e.g.
Hutchison et al, Wille’s Principles, 461–462 (which sets out the traditional approach, based on the
exclusion of extrinsic evidence, and then observes that “in more recent times a trend of judicial
thought has emerged in favour of a more liberal approach to interpretation”). See also Lewis, in
Zimmermann & Visser, Southern Cross, 195–216.
47 In addition to the standard texts, see Macgregor & Lewis, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed
Legal Systems, 66–93; Lewis, in Zimmermann & Visser, Southern Cross, 195–216 and Clive, in
Reid & Zimmermann, History, 47–71. For Scottish law, see also Scot Law Com No 160 (1997).
48 Investors Compensation Scheme (note 25); Mannai.
49 See e.g. Bank of Scotland v Dunedin Property Investment Co 1998 SC 657 at 661, 670, 677
(henceforth BoS v Dunedin); Bank of Scotland v Junior 1999 SCLR 284; Lindsay Plant Ltd v
Norwest Group plc 2000 SC 93 at 98; Project Fishing International v CEPO Ltd 2002 SC 534 at
539 (henceforth Project Fishing).
50 See Hunter v Barron’s Trustees (1886) 13 R 883.
51 See Project Fishing (note 49).
interpretation 187
and the other knows this or could reasonably be expected to have known it,
and concludes the contract without saying anything on the point, that
meaning will prevail.52 In the absence of any such special features the
contract will be interpreted objectively. The basic Scottish rules are therefore
perfectly compatible with the PECL rules although, as in English law, the
emphasis often appears to be different. The recommendations of the Scottish
Law Commission on the substantive law on the above matters are also
perfectly compatible with the PECL rules although again the emphasis and
53
order of treatment are slightly different.
54
The current South African law also seems basically similar to English law.
55
English cases and dicta are occasionally cited, although to a lesser extent than
in Scotland. There is much more overt reference to Roman law than there is in
56
Scotland. The Civilian background is worn more openly on the sleeve. None-
theless the basic approach, after some difference of opinion, seems now to be
rather literal and objective. A recent statement is as follows (citations omitted).
According to our … law a policy of insurance must be construed like any other written
contract so as to give effect to the intention of the parties as expressed in the terms
of the policy, considered as a whole. The terms are to be understood in their plain,
ordinary and popular sense unless it is evident from the context that the parties
intended them to have a different meaning, or unless they have by known usage of
trade, or the like, acquired a peculiar sense distinct from their popular meaning. If
the ordinary sense of the words necessarily leads to some absurdity or to some
repugnance or inconsistency with the rest of the contract, then the court may
modify the words just so much as to avoid that absurdity or inconsistency but no
more. It must also be borne in mind that very few words bear a single meaning,
and the “ordinary” meaning of words appearing in a contract will necessarily
depend upon the context in which they are used, their interrelation and the nature
of the transaction as it appears from the entire contract. It is essential to have
regard to the context in which the word or phrase is used with its interrelation to
57
the contract as a whole, including the nature and purpose of the contract.
As in Scottish law, however, it seems that if the parties have attached a special
and unusual meaning to an expression in their contract that meaning will
prevail over the ordinary or dictionary meaning in a question between the
parties.
Even if a word has a plain and ordinary meaning, but the parties at the time the
contract was made both understood it to have a different meaning, the latter
58
meaning is binding on them though not on innocent third parties.
58 Hutchison et al, Wille’s Principles, 464. Similar statements can be found in other books. See
Macgregor & Lewis, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems, 76.
59 For the confused and unsatisfactory state of the authorities on this point, see Macgregor & Lewis,
in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems, 80. One of the most curious features of the
old law was the distinction between latent and patent ambiguities. This came in from English law
but is probably no longer part of that law. See Wickman Tools Ltd v Schuler AG [1974] AC 235 at
268 by Lord Simon of Glaisdale, and K Lewison, The Interpretation of Contracts, 3rd edn (2004),
para 8.02.
60 Scot Law Com No 160 (1997), paras 2.13–2.14. Illogical because meaning often depends on
background. Unnecessary because if there is an arguable dispute about the interpretation of an
expression it will usually be possible to find ambiguity. Troublesome because it merely adds
another stage to the dispute-solving process, a stage where the courts find it difficult to be
consistent.
61 Investors Compensation Scheme (note 25); Mannai (note 30).
62 See the cases cited in note 49 above.
interpretation 189
for the interpretation of a written contract.63 However, this view has been
under challenge for some time. It is now said that a court may always be
informed of the “background circumstances under which the contract was
concluded, such as the relationship in which the parties stood to one another
at the time of contracting.”64 A distinction is drawn between such “back-
ground circumstances” and “surrounding circumstances”, the latter being
65
admissible only in the event of ambiguity or sufficient uncertainty, but the
66
nature of the distinction is not entirely clear and the question has been
asked why evidence of relevant surrounding circumstances should not be
67
admissible in all cases. It remains to be seen whether, and if so how, the
obvious tension in this area of the law will be resolved.
(4) Negotiations
In Scottish law evidence of negotiations or prior communings is still, as a rule,
68
regarded as inadmissible in the interpretation of a written contract. There
seem to be several reasons for this continuing restriction. Each is plausible in
some cases but they do not justify a blanket exclusion for all cases. First, it is
69
said that reference to negotiations will be “unhelpful”. This is often true: it
will not help an interpreter to be told of abandoned negotiating positions
which cast no light on the meaning of expressions in the final agreement.
However, that is not always true: there are cases where reference to parti-
cular parts of the negotiations can elucidate the meaning which both parties
attached, or must have attached, to a particular expression.70 Secondly, it may
be said that in drawing up a formal written contract the parties must have
intended the wording of that contract to supersede anything said in the
negotiations. That will often be true, but not always. Parties may not include
63 See Hutchison et al, Wille’s Principles, 461–462 and, for a more recent statement, Rane
Investments Trust v Commissioner, South African Revenue Service 2003 (6) SA 332 (SCA) at 346.
64 Hutchison et al, Wille’s Principles, 462.
65 See HNR Properties CC v Standard Bank of South Africa Ltd 2004 (4) SA 471 (SCA) at 478 –
court can look at “background circumstances or, in the event of ambiguity, surrounding
circumstances”.
66 Contrast the statements in Delmas Milling Co Ltd v Du Plessis 1955 (3) SA 447 (A) with those in
Coopers & Lybrand (note 57) at 768A-B. And see Macgregor & Lewis, in Zimmermann, Visser &
Reid, Mixed Legal Systems, 82.
67 See Cinema City (Pty) Ltd v Morgenstern Family Estates (Pty) Ltd 1980 (1) SA 796 (AD) at 804
per Jansen JA. See also Hutchison et al, Wille’s Principles, 462 and Lewis, in Zimmermann &
Visser, Southern Cross,195 -216.
68 BoS v Dunedin (note 49) at 661.
69 Prenn v Simmonds (note 32).
70 A point made in S C Smith, “Making sense of contracts” 1999 SLT (News) 307 at 311.
190 european contract law
71 See e.g. Bovis Construction Ltd v Whatlings Construction Ltd 1994 SLT 865.
72 See e.g. Houldsworth v Gordon Cumming 1910 SC (HL) 49.
73 BoS v Dunedin (note 49).
74 See Hunter v Livingston Development Corporation 1986 SC (HL) 31.
interpretation 191
75 This point is also made in D W McLauchlan “Common assumptions and contract interpretation”
(1997) 113 LQR 237 with reference to the Australian case of Codelfa Construction Pty Ltd v State
Rail Authority of New South Wales (1982) 149 CLR 337 where it was held to be permissible to
allow evidence that the “parties had united in rejecting” a particular meaning.
76 See e.g. City Wall Properties (Scotland) Ltd v Pearl Assurance plc 2004 SC 214 at 225.
77 Paras 2.19–2.22, 8.11.
78 Paras 3.19, 8.12.
79 BoS v Dunedin (note 49).
80 As opposed to “background circumstances”. See above, text accompanying note ??.
81 Coopers & Lybrand (note 57) at 768A–B. And see Macgregor & Lewis, in Zimmermann, Visser
& Reid, Mixed Legal Systems, 83–85.
192 european contract law
It is difficult to believe that the result would have been better if evidence of
87
the parties’ subsequent conduct had been held inadmissible.
South African law also appears to be rather less restrictive than English
law in relation to subsequent conduct. The court can have regard to post-
contractual conduct for the purposes of interpretation if there is ambiguity or
82 The Scottish Law Commission listed fourteen cases, from 1830 to 1957, in its Discussion Paper
No 101 on Interpretation in Private Law (1996) at para 7.14 n 233.
83 Whitworth Street Estates (Manchester) Ltd v James Miller & Partners Ltd [1970] AC 583;
Wickman Tools Ltd v Schuler AG [1974] AC 235.
84 See e.g. Cameron (Scotland) Ltd v Melville Dundas Ltd 2001 SCLR 691. The current Scottish
approach has been criticised. See Professor McBryde’s Comment to the case just cited, and
Macgregor & Lewis, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems, 86.
85 It was alleged that this was in accordance with local custom but the court did not decide the case
on the basis of local custom.
86 Hunter v Barron’s Trustees (1886) 13 R 883 at 891.
87 Under the Scottish Law Commission’s recommendations, evidence of subsequent conduct would
have been admissible in this type of case. The Commission did not, however, think that
subsequent conduct would be relevant to a purely objective interpretation of a contract. See Scot
Law Com No 160 (1997), paras 2.24–2.29, 8.13.
interpretation 193
that sense, and then to turn round later and say that the term should
be given some quite different sense. This consideration often finds
expression in notions of good faith or personal bar or estoppel but it
can also come into play directly in interpretation.
4. The need to protect reasonable reliance of the parties and third parties.
Those who have relied in good faith on an apparent meaning should
not be prejudiced by an interpretation based on intentions or circum-
stances of which they did not know and could not reasonably be
expected to know.
5. The need for a measure of certainty and predictability in legal
relationships. This is sometimes said to favour an objective approach
to interpretation but it also suggests that the rules on interpretation
themselves should be clear and consistent. They should not be vague
and full of ill-defined exceptions and sub-exceptions.
6. The desirability of keeping the scope and length and cost of legal
proceedings within reasonable bounds. This consideration is often
reflected in doctrines to the effect that if the words of a written
contract are clear there is no need to go beyond them.
7. The desirability of imposing some discipline on those drafting con-
tracts. Drafters should not be encouraged to be lax: they might be so
encouraged if the courts were to look for actual intention and ignore
the words used in a written contract.
(a) Scope
Should the rules include or exclude rules on the implication of terms? PECL
deals separately with implied terms. Article 6:102 PECL provides that:
In addition to the express terms, a contract may contain implied terms which stem
from
(a) the intention of the parties;
(b) the nature and purpose of the contract; and
(c) good faith and fair dealing.
93
This seems to be the correct approach. The process of interpretation begins
only when the terms of the contract have been determined.
93 It was also the approach taken in Scot Law Com No 160 (1997), para 1.6. See also Bank of
Scotland v Junior 1999 SCLR 284 at 291D–E per Lord Penrose.
interpretation 195
(d) One rule for all contracts or different rules for different types?
The practical question here is whether the same rules of interpretation
should apply to all contracts whether or not the terms are embodied or
recorded in writing. PECL has one set of rules for all contracts. The word
“contract” in Chapter 5 generally means a contractual agreement, not a
97 98
contractual document. A unified approach seems the better approach.
There are millions of contracts which are never recorded in writing. Their
terms may, however, be recorded or provable in other ways and they may
require interpretation. A non-unified approach also gives rise to questions of
classification: what counts as a written contract? One of the implications of a
unified approach is that the law on the rectification of documents cannot be
relied on as a safety valve. Another is that restrictive rules of evidence apply-
ing only to contracts reduced to writing cannot be used to solve all inter-
pretation problems. A unified approach does not mean that the fact that a
contract has been deliberately reduced to formal writing must be regarded as
irrelevant. On the contrary, it would be a highly relevant circumstance to be
taken into account and would lead any interpreter to be most reluctant to
depart from the ordinary meaning of the words which the parties had used to
set out their agreement.
97 There are references, e.g., to a contract being “concluded”. One concludes an agreement, but not
a document. However, in Article 5:107 PECL on linguistic discrepancies the reference to a
“contract drawn up in two or more language versions” seems to use “contract” in the sense of a
contract document.
98 This was the approach recommended by the Scottish Law Commission: see Scot Law Com No
160 (1997), para 1.9.
interpretation 197
That order of treatment could be justified on the ground that the situations
where the parties have a common intention as to the meaning of terms used
198 european contract law
in their contract which differs from the ordinary meaning of those terms are
likely to be rare and exceptional. There is something to be said for beginning
with the ordinary case and then dealing with the exceptional case. However,
there are arguments both ways on this, and the order of treatment does not
greatly matter.
What does matter is that it has to be made clear that where the parties
have formed a common intention as to the meaning of an expression used in
their contract, that meaning should prevail in all questions between them.
The key case which has to be considered is the following. The parties agree
before the contract is concluded that a certain expression is to be used in a
certain sense. They do not, however, state that in the contract itself. Their
prior agreement is admitted by both parties or can be proved by evidence.
Surely any legal system with any regard for fairness would, in a question
between the parties, give effect to the parties’ common intention in this type
of case and would not allow one of the parties to found on a different meaning
objectively arrived at. English law, in spite of its general preference for an
objective approach, would allow the agreed basis to prevail if there is any
ambiguity on the point in the contract,99 and the requirement of ambiguity
now seems dubious in the light of recent developments,100 and in the light of
common sense.101
So the rule in Article 5:101 PECL seems justifiable, even if it need not
necessarily have been the opening rule.
feet’ I mean “linear feet.’” The customer says “Do you want to send a new
offer?” The builder says “No. As long as you realise what is meant that is fine.”
The customer sends a written acceptance of the offer without mentioning
this point. The phone call was recorded. Under PECL the contract would be
read as referring to linear feet. This seems reasonable.
It is perhaps worth noting that if paragraph (2) of Article 5:101 PECL is
accepted as sound policy then paragraph (1) has to be accepted too. The case
where both parties agree on a meaning for an expression is just one type of
case where one party uses an expression in a particular sense and the other
knows of this. Indeed a suitably drafted paragraph (2) would render para-
102
graph (1) unnecessary. That is not to say that it is undesirable to have
paragraph (1) separately expressed as a general rule.
102 This solution is the one adopted by CISG and the one recommended for Scottish law by the
Scottish Law Commission. See Scot Law Com No 160 (1997), para 3.13.
103 See C-W Canaris & H C Grigoleit, “Interpretation of contracts”, in A Hartkamp et al (eds),
Towards a European Civil Code, 445–469 at 456.
200 european contract law
purposes of paragraph (3) of Article 5:101 PECL. It has been explained in the
House of Lords that the general exclusion of reference to negotiations in
English law is not for any technical reasons but just because it is thought that
such evidence will not be helpful.104 That, however, will clearly not always be
true in relation to the principal rules of interpretation in PECL. Of course,
much of the negotiating history will generally be irrelevant to the point in
dispute and it is in nobody’s interests to increase the cost of litigation by
allowing in a great mass of irrelevant evidence – but there are perhaps better
ways of excluding irrelevant evidence than having a blanket rule which also
excludes relevant evidence.
A similar point can be made about subsequent conduct. Often this will be
irrelevant or inconclusive. It may just suggest that the parties have departed
from the contract or chosen to ignore the contract. But sometimes subse-
quent conduct may cast a light backwards on what the knowledge or common
intention of the parties must have been at the time of conclusion of the
contract and then it would be relevant.
means “could reasonably be expected to have known” why not say so? The
reference to “reasonable persons of the same kind as the parties” also comes
from the UN Sales Convention but is also an unhappy one, for several
reasons. The fictitious referees are unnecessary. “Of the same kind” is
curious. Why not just say “the meaning which would reasonably be given to it
in the circumstances”? The beginning of Article 5:102 PECL should perhaps
be permissive rather than directory: it should say “regard may be had” to the
listed circumstances. Nobody would wish to force an interpreter to have
regard to circumstances which were of no relevance to the issue under
consideration. The reference to good faith and fair dealing seems to be
misplaced. Good faith and fair dealing are not relevant circumstances but
relevant considerations. It might be preferable to bring this provision out into
a separate Article.
These criticisms are, however, minor ones. They do not affect the con-
clusion that the PECL rules on interpretation seem preferable to the existing
Scottish and South African rules.
8 Third-Party Contracts
Philip Sutherland
A. BACKGROUND
B. WHY SHOULD THE LAW ALLOW THIRD-PARTY CONTRACTS
TO BE ENFORCED?
C. WHEN AND HOW SHOULD A THIRD PARTY ACQUIRE RIGHT
OR BENEFIT FROM CONTRACT BETWEEN OTHERS?
D. WHAT BENEFITS WILL THIRD PARTIES RECEIVE FROM
THIRD-PARTY CONTRACTS?
E. DIRECT OR INDIRECT BENEFITS FOR THIRD PARTIES
F. WHO WILL ACQUIRE RIGHTS FROM THIRD-PARTY
CONTRACTS?
G. AMENDMENT OR TERMINATION OF THIRD-PARTY
BENEFITS WITHOUT THIRD PARTY’S CONSENT
H. REMEDIES FOR ENFORCEMENT OF THIRD PARTY RIGHTS
I. HOW DO EVENTS THAT NORMALLY AFFECT ENFORCEMENT
OF CONTRACTUAL PROVISIONS IMPACT ON RIGHTS OF
THIRD PARTY?
J. CONCLUSION
A. BACKGROUND
A third-party contract is concluded where one person, the debtor or pro-
misor, agrees with another, the promisee, to perform an obligation to a third
1
party. Third party contracts are now enforced in most jurisdictions. Under
the influence of the Civil Law, they are recognised in the two mixed legal
systems of South Africa and Scotland as well as in Article 6:110 PECL.
In the past the doctrine of privity of contract combined with the doctrine of
consideration stood in the way of recognition of such contracts in England.2
1 France: Article 1121 Code Civil; New Zealand: Contracts (Privity) Act 1982; Netherlands: Article
6:254 BW; Queensland: Property Law Act 1974, s 55; USA: Restatement of Contract (Second) s
302; Western Australia: Property Law Act 1969, s 11(2), (3). See further Privity of Contract:
Contracts for the Benefit of Third Parties (Law Com Consultation Paper 121, 1991) (henceforth
Law Com CP 121) appendix; PECL, vol 1, 322 n 1.
2 Tweddle v Atkinson (1861) 1 B & S 393; Dunlop v Selfridge [1915] AC 847; Drive Yourself Hire
203
204 european contract law
Both mixed legal systems have been contrasted with English law in this
respect.3 If the law in England had continued on this path, it would have been
difficult to find the type of common ground that is necessary for a proper
comparative analysis. However, English law underwent radical change in
1999 and it now recognises a highly sophisticated third-party contract in
terms of a new statute which is the product of a comprehensive comparative
4
investigation of Continental as well as Commonwealth sources. Suddenly
the mixed legal systems are playing catch-up. In this contribution the rules on
third-party contracts in Scotland, South Africa, PECL and England will be
compared from the perspective of a lawyer whose home system is a mixed one.
Co (London) Ltd v Strutt [1954] 1 QB 250 at 272 (criticised (1954) 70 LQR 467); Midland
Silicones Ltd v Scrutton Ltd [1962] AC 446, discussed by M P Furmston, “Return to Dunlop v
Selfridge?” (1960) 23 Modern LR 373; Beswick v Beswick [1968] AC 58; Woodar Investment
Development Ltd v Wimpey Construction (UK) Ltd [1980] 1 WLR 277; R Merkin, Privity of
Contract (2000) (henceforth Merkin, Privity), paras 1.25 ff; Law Com CP 121, paras 2.11–2.16;
Privity of Contract: Contracts for the Benefit of Third Parties (Law Com No 242, 1996) (hence-
forth Law Com No 242), paras 2.1–2.7; R Flannigan, “Privity: the end of an era (error)” (1987) 103
LQR 564 at 564–572; Treitel, Contract, 587, 588–590.
3 Alfred McAlpine Construction Ltd v Panatown Ltd [2001] 1 AC 518 (henceforth Panatown) at
527, 534; Carmichael v Carmichael’s Executrix 1919 SC 636 (henceforth Carmichael (CS)) at
656; Carmichael v Carmichael’s Executrix 1919 SC (HL) 195 (henceforth Carmichael (HL)) at
198; T B Smith, “Jus quaesitum tertio: remedies of the “tertius” in Scottish Law” 1956 JR 3 at 3–
4; H L MacQueen, “Third party rights in contract: jus quaesitum tertio”, in Reid & Zimmermann,
History, vol 2 at 220–221; Tradesmen’s Benefit Society v Du Preez (1887) 5 SC 269 (henceforth
Tradesmen’s Benefit Society) at 276; McCullogh v Fernwood Estate Ltd 1920 AD 204 (henceforth
McCullogh) at 206; D-Jay Corporation CC v Investor Management Services (Pty) Ltd 2000 (2) SA
755 (W) at 762; P Sutherland & D Johnston, “Contracts for the benefit of third parties”, in
Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 208, 211.
4 Contracts (Rights of Third Parties) Act 1999. The Act had a long gestation: see Law Revision
Committee Sixth Interim Report (Cmd 5449, 1937); Law Com CP 121, paras 1.1–1.3; Law Com
No 242, paras 1.3–1.10; Merkin, Privity, paras 5.7–5.13. Treitel, Contract at 580, 651 stresses that
the Act did not reject, but merely created exceptions to, the doctrine of privity of contract.
5 Law Com CP 121, para 1.1.
third-party contracts 205
13 Darlington Borough Council (note 7) at 76; Law Com CP 121, paras 5.36. 6.17; Law Com No 242,
paras 2.1, 2.63, 10.24; Treitel, Contract at 580, 588; F R Malan, “Gedagtes oor die beding ten
behoewe van ‘n derde” (1976) 9 De Iure 85 at 85–86 (although he thinks that a normal offer is not
made here); J C Sonnekus, “Enkele opmerkings om die beding ten behoewe van ’n derde” 1999
TSAR 594 at 598; Sutherland & Johnston, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems
at 209.
14 Crookes NO v Watson 1956 (1) SA 277 (A) (henceforth Crookes) at 292; Sonnekus, 1999 TSAR
594 at 598.
15 See below text accompanying notes 42–49. See also Contracts (Rights of Third Parties) Act 1999,
s 7(1); Law Com CP 121, para 5.39, Law Com No 242 at 12.3; Merkin, Privity, para 5.57. In
England third party rights will not affect any other rights of the third party.
16 See the cases mentioned above in note 2 as well as Panatown (note 3) at 544; Law Com CP 121,
paras 2.5–2.10; Law Com No 242, paras 6.3–6.8; Flannigan (1987) 103 LQR 564 at 568; Merkin,
Privity, paras 1.35–1.36, 5.50–5.53; Sutherland & Johnston, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid,
Mixed Legal Systems at 211.
17 Smith, 1956 JR 3 at 3–5; McBryde, Contract, para 2–02, on gratuitous promise. See Tradesmen’s
Benefit Society (note 3) at 275 where this is recognised.
18 Conradie v Rossouw 1919 AD 279; Christie, Contract, 81.
19 Tradesmen’s Benefit Society (note 3) at 278; Getz, 1962 Acta Juridica 38 at 38. For criticism of this
type of approach in England, see Law Com CP 121, para 2.7; Furmston (1960) 23 Modern LR 373
at 384; Flannigan (1987) 103 LQR 564 at 568. But see Merkin, Privity, paras 1.21 ff.
20 Although only by necessary implication (Merkin, Privity, para 5.52). Thus, gratuitous promises
may not be made unless they form part of third-party contracts (Merkin, Privity, para 5.53).
third-party contracts 207
Next, and in some ways related to the first point, it may be said that the
tripartite relationships established in terms of third-party contracts are
unmanageable and that adequate and clear rules cannot be made in order to
address these difficulties.21 Third-party contracts cannot be recognised
without establishing an intricate set of rules for dealing with them. But this
area of law is no more convoluted than many others. The benefits of allowing
third-party contracts seem to outweigh the disadvantage of creating a
relatively complex set of rules.
Once it is realised that there is a need for third-party contracts, the
previous argument can succeed only if other legal devices can effectively
22
fulfil the same functions as third-party contracts. In the past, several devices
23
have been used to achieve the same ends as such contracts. However, the
evasion of the doctrine of privity of contract for pragmatic reasons often leads
24
to abuse and the skewed development of other legal concepts. Moreover, a
legal system that does not recognise a third-party contract will not adequately
protect parties who are not able to obtain proper legal advice on how to avoid
the principle of privity of contract.25 Experience in England has shown that
other legal phenomena cannot always fill the void left by a strict principle of
privity of contract and that the creation of a range of exceptions to it merely
causes confusion.
The English Contracts (Rights of Third Parties) Act 1999 is a testimony to
the importance of recognising third-party contracts. However, the analysis
below points out the problematic areas that will have to be addressed by
every law on third-party contracts.
Logically, the third party to a true third-party contract should acquire a right
26
directly from the contract between the debtor and promisor, as is the case in
21 See the minority that opposed the proposals in Law Com CP 121, discussed in Law Com No 242,
para 1.7.
22 See again the minority that opposed the proposals in Law Com CP 121, discussed in Law Com No
242, para 1.7.
23 Law Com CP 121, paras 3.1–3.56; Law Com No 242, paras 2.8–2.62; Merkin, Privity, para 1.31,
ch 2; Treitel, Contract at 626–651.
24 Swain v The Law Society [1983] 1 AC 598; Panatown (note 3) at 535; Law Com No 242, para 1.8;
Clark Contracts v Burrel Construction 2003 SLT (Sh Ct) 73 (henceforth Clark Contracts), para
37.
25 Law Com CP 121, para 4.4; Law Com No 242, para 1.8.
26 See the three types of contracts distinguished by De Wet, Ontwikkeling at 140–141.
208 european contract law
England27 and PECL.28 In the PECL comments it is stated that the third
party will acquire a right only if the promisee notifies him of the benefit.29
However, this conclusion is not justified by the text of PECL. Such an approach
would be illogical and cause grave and unnecessary uncertainty for third
parties.
Under the influence of the Roman-Dutch author Hugo Grotius,30 the
South African courts have determined that a third party will acquire a benefit
31
from a contract between others only if he has accepted it. What South
Africans call a stipulatio alteri is really a complex of two contracts, the con-
tract between the promisee and promisor according to which the promisor
agrees with the promisee to keep open an offer to the third party and the
second between the promisor and third party which comes into existence
32
when the third party accepts the offer which the promisor has made to him.
The South African third-party contract that operates in this manner fits in
easily with the ordinary principles of contract law. Many of the general
objections to third-party contracts mentioned above are avoided. But J C de
Wet correctly criticised this construction for not being a third-party contract
at all.33 The objection to the two-contract approach is not just theoretical. In
many situations, acceptance will have to be artificially constructed to allow a
third party a claim. The main problem in South Africa is that most courts and
commentators, especially De Wet, have viewed the two-contract approach
and the true contract for the benefit of a third party as mutually exclusive
alternatives. But why should it not be possible for a legal system to accommodate
both?34 According to a true third-party contract the third party acquires his
right from the valid contract between debtor and promisee. Where the South
African two-contract device is intended, the question is whether there was a
valid offer by the promisee and acceptance by the third party.35 Both rights
and duties, or burdens, for a third party can be established here.36 However,
from a terminological point of view, it seems strange to call this device a
stipulatio alteri or third-party contract. It should rather be labelled a third-
37
party option.
In Scotland a third party automatically acquires rights from the ius
38
quaesitum tertio. The acquisition of the third party’s rights does not depend
39
on his assent. According to Scots law, under the influence of the Institu-
40
tional Writer Stair, even unilateral promises may be enforced. Hence, it has
often been suggested that the foundation of the ius quaesitum tertio in
41
Scotland is unilateral promise or pollicitatio. But this proposal has not
found clear judicial support and is unconvincing. In a system where unilateral
promises are recognised, the need for third-party contracts is reduced, but
where there is a unilateral promise, there is no need to speak of a “third-party
contract”. Again a true third-party contract should be regarded as a unique
device for creating rights for a third party.42
South African and Scots law show that third party contracts are sui generis.
Attempts to equate them with other more familiar legal phenomena only lead
to confusion. Still, Scots law pertinently asks a fundamental question about
34 Sutherland & Johnston, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 215.
35 See Merkin, Privity, para 5.22. If the two-contract device is used, it may be possible in South
Africa to obtain rights on the basis of reasonable reliance, even if the stipulator did not intend to
grant such rights. In the true third-party contract this is inconceivable: see in England Law Com
CP 121, para 5.9. Only the reasonable reliance of the contracting parties is relevant.
36 See below, text accompanying notes 58–61.
37 See Malelane Suikerkorporasie (Edms) Bpk v Streak 1970 (4) SA 478 (T) at 482 where an analogy
with an option was drawn; Kynochs (note 32) at 77 where reference was made to a standing offer;
McKerron (1929) 46 SALJ 387 at 395; M J Oosthuisen, “Die aanspreeklikheid van die maats-
kappypromotor by voorinlywingskontrakte”, 1986 TSAR 360 at 363; Kerr, Contract at 85–86.
38 Although the third party often acquires a limited right initially: see below, text accompanying
notes 101–109.
39 Finnie v Glasgow and South Western Railway Co (1857) 3 Macq 75 (henceforth Finnie) at 90.
40 McBryde, Contract, para 2–02. In Scotland Stair, Institutions, 1.10.4, explicitly rejected the
opposing view of Grotius.
41 Smith, 1956 JR 3 at 16, 21; D I C Ashton Cross, “Bare promise in Scots law” 1957 JR 138 at 145–
146; D N MacCormick, “Jus quaesitum tertio: Stair v Dunedin” 1970 JR 228 at 233–234;
MacQueen, in Reid & Zimmermann, History, vol 2 at 221, 223; SME, vol 15, para 827 (but see
para 828).
42 A Rodger, “Molina, Stair and the jus quaesitum tertio” 1969 JR 34 and 128 (two parts) at 141–144;
McBryde, Contract, para 10–07; Finnie (note 39) at 89–90 per Lord Wensleydale; see Sutherland
& Johnston, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 216–217.
210 european contract law
the law of contract. Very few systems recognise unilateral promise while most
embrace third-party contracts, but why should a legal system not recognise
unilateral promise if it allows two parties to create benefits for third parties?43
Although consent of or acceptance by a third party should not be neces-
sary for the creation of a right created in a contract between other parties,
such a right should of course not be force-fed to a third party, who should be
44
able to renounce it. The third party’s renunciation should cause the right to
45 46
fall away ab initio. This issue is seldom raised in Scotland, but in South
Africa even De Wet, who did not regard acceptance as a necessary require-
ment for establishing rights for third parties, nevertheless stressed that the
47
third party has the power to reject a right created for him by others. This is
48
clearly set out in PECL. The English Act is strangely silent on the matter of
rejection but it is inconceivable that renunciation will not be possible in
49
England.
Moreover, there are some difficult questions that will have to be answered
with regard to how and when renunciation of rights by third parties should be
possible. None of them are answered properly by the legal systems under
discussion. In answering these questions, the objective should be to protect
the third party who has received an unsolicited right. The risk of uncertainty
created by third-party contracts should be on the contracting parties, not the
third party.
In which way should it be possible to renounce a right? According to the
comments to Article 6:110 PECL, notice of rejection has to be given to the
debtor. Formal notice of renunciation of a third-party right provides clear
proof of rejection and it is advisable that third parties reject rights contracted
in their favour in this manner. But it is doubted whether such formalism
should be necessary to enable a third party to rid himself of an unwanted
right and whether this statement is justified by the text of PECL.
Should a third party be required to exercise his power of renunciation
within a particular or reasonable time, or should he have a continuing power
43 Article 2:107 PECL does so. See also Merkin, Privity, para 5.22.
44 See also above, text accompanying note 14.
45 In South Africa the Supreme Court of Appeal has apparently attempted to side-step problems of
repudiation by an insolvent beneficiary in the law of succession: Wessels v De Jager 2000 (4) SA
924 (SCA). But this case has often been criticised.
46 See McBryde, Contract, para 10–32; Smith, 1956 JR 3 at 15; MacQueen, in Reid & Zimmermann,
History, vol 2 at 224.
47 De Wet & Van Wyk, Kontraktereg, at 104, 108–109.
48 Article 6:110(2) PECL; Comment G.
49 See the discussion of rejection in Law Com No 242, paras 11.6–11.11; Merkin, Privity, para 5.62.
third-party contracts 211
to reject the right bargained in his favour? Third parties should lose their
powers of renunciation only if they have either accepted rights or have
created the impression that they have done so.
Renunciation of a right by the third party may have drastic consequences
if there is a quasi-reciprocal relationship between the promisor and promisee
in the sense that the promisee has to perform to the promisor in exchange for
the latter’s performance to the third party. Should rejection be possible in
these situations and, if so, what should its effect be on the relationship
50
between the contracting parties? The existence of an element of reciprocity
should not deprive a third party of his power to reject the third-party right. In
England, although this has not been set out in legislation, the promisee
apparently will then be entitled to claim performance from the promisee but
51
will be liable to the promisor; and this may also be the case in Scotland.
However, this should be merely the default position. The contracting parties
should be allowed to depart from it where performance that was intended for
the third party cannot or should not be made to the promisee. In such circum-
stances the parties will have to agree either that the promisee will no longer
be liable to the promisor or that he has to perform despite the termination of
the promisor’s duty to render performance.
50 See Merkin, Privity, para 5.62 on the distinction that was previously drawn.
51 Law Com No 242, paras 11.7–11.8; Merkin, Privity, para 5.62. See below, text accompanying
notes 101–109, on the right of the promisee.
52 Law Com No 242, para 10.24 (although the Contracts (Rights of Third Parties) Act 1999, s 1(1)(a)
does not make this clear: see Merkin, Privity, para 5.25).
53 SME, vol 15, para 840; McBryde, Contract, para 10–10.
54 Merkin, Privity, para 5.15; Law Com CP 121, paras 5.17–5.18; Law Com No 242, paras 10.24 ff.
See Contracts (Rights of Third Parties) Act 1999, s 1(6) and Merkin, Privity, para 5.46.
212 european contract law
The new English Act mostly refers to the third party’s ability to enforce a
“term” in the contract, but this causes uncertainty.55 It would be more
accurate to refer to benefits and then to define that word as rights and
immunities, or to speak directly of rights and immunities in the legislation.56
PECL refers only to the third party’s rights.57 This term is too narrow and is
not ideal; but it probably can be interpreted to include immunities.
Duties or other burdens may not be imposed upon third parties in terms
58
of a third-party contract, although a right can be granted subject to a con-
dition that the third party will have to render some performance if he wants
59
to enforce it. The third party will be adequately protected in these situa-
tions. The condition cannot be directly enforced, and the third party will be
subjected to it only if he intends to take the benefit. However, it may be
difficult to determine where the line lies between contracts that impose con-
ditional benefits and ones that lay down duties, especially where drafting is
done by laymen.
In South Africa, a third party may become subject to duties in terms of a
stipulatio alteri. This is the primary advantage of the two-contract approach.60
Through it, reciprocal contracts may be concluded with third parties. In true
third-party contracts, promisees often have to perform duties that are
established in exchange for undertakings by debtors to provide third-party
benefits. This has led to many conflicts between third parties and promisees
in Scotland.61 The South African two-contract device can be used effectively
to prevent many of these conflicts.
55 But see Contracts (Rights of Third Parties) Act 1999, s 1(6), which speaks of “benefit”.
56 Many of the problems discussed by Merkin, Privity, paras 5.30–5.32, 5.47 can be addressed more
easily by legislation that is so worded.
57 Article 6:110(1) PECL.
58 This is never stated in the modern legislation because it is too obvious a point: Merkin, Privity,
paras 4.1, 5.14. See the problems that this principle will cause in cases where reciprocity is
required, SME, vol 15, para 830. See above, text accompanying note 14.
59 SME, vol 15, para 830; Contracts (Rights of Third Parties) Act 1999, s 1(4); Law Com CP 121,
paras 5.36 ff; Law Com No 242, para 10.25; Merkin, Privity, paras 5.43–5.45. See also Contracts
(Rights of Third Parties) Act 1999, s 8, on the application of arbitration clauses to the rights
obtained by third parties: also Nisshin Shipping Co Ltd v Cleaves & Co Ltd [2004] 1 Lloyd’s
Rep 38.
60 McKerron (1929) 46 SALJ 387 at 390, 393–394; Sutherland & Johnston, in Zimmermann, Visser
& Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 219; Christie, Contract at 305–307; Crookes (note 14) at 291 with
reference to Jankelow v Binder Gering and Co 1927 TPD 364; Malelane Suikerkorporasie
(Edms) Bpk v Streak 1970 (4) SA 478 (T) at 481–482; Total South Africa (Pty) Ltd v Bekker 1992
(1) SA 617 (A) at 625; Unitrans Freight (Pty) Ltd v Santam Ltd 2004 (6) SA 21 (SCA), para 14;
Pieterse v Shrosbree 2005 (1) SA 309 (SCA), para 9 and Wimbledon Lodge (Pty) Ltd v Gore 2003
(5) SA 315 (SCA), para 54; Brownsword & Hutchison, in Kincaid, Privity at 140; Van der Merwe,
Contract at 244. See also Sage Life Ltd v Van der Merwe 2001 (2) SA 166 (W) at 168.
61 See below, text accompanying notes 101–109.
third-party contracts 213
A third party cannot acquire legal remedies from a contract between other
62
parties merely because that contract benefits him. Where A concludes a
contract of sale with B, and B in turn agrees with C to sell the same merx to C,
63
no direct contractual bond arises between A and C. An agreement between
A and B that A may perform the obligation that he owes B to a third party C,
called an adiectus solutionis causa in South Africa, will cause A to be freed
from his obligation to B if he performs to C; but again C will not acquire any
right against A in these circumstances.64
The third party should obtain legal remedies from a contract between
others only if the contracting parties intend it.65 It may be difficult to deter-
mine when contracting parties have this intention. Both PECL66 and the
English Act67 attempt to address these problems although they are not very
successful in doing so. Both determine that a third party will acquire rights if
the contract expressly so provides. However, it is difficult to understand why
68
this obvious point needs to be made in a statute. It is also not quite clear
when exactly a contract expressly grants a third party a right.
69
Furthermore, the English Act creates a presumption, that a term purpor-
ting to create third-party benefits will be deemed enforceable by the third
party, unless “on the proper construction of the contract it appears that the
70
parties did not intend the term to be enforceable by the third party”. This
62 Law Com CP 121 at para 2.17; Treitel, Contract at 653; Gloag, Contract at 235, 237; Smith, 1956
JR 3 at 8; McBryde, Contract, para 10–11; SME, vol 15, para 835; H L MacQueen, “Third party
rights in contract: English reform and Scottish concerns” (1997) Edinburgh LR 488 at 490–491.
See cases listed above at note 60, esp Sage Life Ltd v Van der Merwe 2001 (2) SA 166 (W) at 168.
63 Merkin, Privity, para 5.33; McBryde, Contract, para 10–11. See Jankelow v Binder Gering and
Co 1927 TPD 364 at 368.
64 Mondorp Eiendomsagentskap (Edms) Bpk v Kemp en De Beer 1979 (4) SA 74 (A) at 88; Barnett
v Abe Swersky & Associates 1986 (4) SA 407 (C) at 411; Mpakathi v Kghotso 2003 (3) SA 429 (W),
para 14; Christie, Contract at 304. See generally on this legal device Lubbe & Murray, Contract at
708–709. See also Comment F to Article 6:110 PECL (at 319), and Comment C (at 318); Gloag,
Contract at 238.
65 Law Com CP 121, paras 2.19, 5.8 ff; Comment F to Article 6:110 PECL (at 319); Gloag, Contract
at 235; Smith, 1956 JR 3 at 7, 10; McBryde, Contract, paras 10–10, 10–12; SME, vol 15, para 835;
and the South African cases mentioned above at note 60.
66 Article 6:110(1) PECL.
67 Contracts (Rights of Third Parties) Act 1999, s 1(1), (2); Law Com CP 121, paras 5.8–5.15; Law
Com No 242, ch 7; Merkin, Privity, paras 5.24 ff.
68 See the explanation of Treitel, Contract at 652.
69 Merkin, Privity, paras 5.27 ff; Law Com No 242, para 7.1.7.
70 Contracts (Rights of Third Parties) Act 1999, s 1(1)(b) read with s 1(2). See Laemthong Inter-
national Lines Co Ltd v Artis [2005] All ER (D) 50; [2005] 1 Lloyd’s Rep 100; Kharegat v Deloitte
& Touche LLP [2004] EWHC 1767 (QB) at para 54; Nisshin Shipping Co Ltd v Cleaves & Co Ltd
[2004] 1 Lloyd’s Rep 38.
214 european contract law
77 Law Com CP 121, para 5.19; Law Com No 242, paras 8.1 ff; Merkin, Privity, paras 5.33–5.36. See
Kharegat v Deloitte & Touche LLP [2004] EWHC 1767 (QB), para 54.
78 Article 6:110(1) PECL and Comment D (at 318–319).
79 Peddie v Brown (1857) 3 Macq 65 at 70–71; McBryde, Contract, paras 10-16–10-19, but see paras
10-18 and 10-19; SME, vol 15, para 833; See also Merkin, Privity, paras 5.33 ff; Law Com CP 121,
para 5.19. A stipulatio alteri in South Africa may be concluded in favour of a class: Van der Merwe,
Contract at 245.
80 Specifically confirmed in England: see Contracts (Rights of Third Parties) Act 1999, s 1(3). See also
Law Com CP 121, paras 5.20, 6.8; Law Com No 242, paras 8.5 ff; Treitel, Contract, 655. See also
MacQueen, in Reid & Zimmermann, History, vol 2 at 249–250; Van der Merwe, Contract at 245.
81 The locus classicus in this area is Kelner v Baxter (1866) LR 2 CP 174, accepted in South Africa in
Nordis Construction Co (Pty) Ltd v Theron Burke & Isaac 1972 (2) SA 535 (D & CLD);
Heathfield v Maqelepo 2004 (2) SA 636 (SCA), para 13; and in Scotland in Tinnevelley Sugar
Refining Co Ltd v Mirrlees, Watson and Yaryan Co Ltd (1894) 21 R 1009.
82 Merkin, Privity, para 5.38; Law Com No 242, paras 8.9 ff Most South African cases on third-party
contracts concern this issue: see e.g. McCullogh (note 3), esp at 208–209; Wimbledon Lodge (Pty)
Ltd v Gore 2003 (5) SA 315 (SCA), para 59. In Scotland in Cumming v Quartzag Ltd 1980 SC 276
at 285 the South African solution was discussed but not correctly understood: see MacQueen (1997)
Edinburgh LR 488 at 491; H L MacQueen, “Promoters’ contracts, agency and the ius quaesitum
tertio” 1982 SLT (News) 257–261; SME, vol 15, para 834 n 8. See also McBryde, Contract, para 10–14.
83 Nine Hundred Umgeni Road (Pty) Ltd v Bali 1986 (1) SA 1 (A); Sutherland & Johnston, in
Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 221.
216 european contract law
are open to criticism. Third parties may think that they are already protected
if they rely on a third-party contract. They may feel that acceptance and
reliance are alternatives and that, accordingly, there will be no need for
acceptance once there is reliance. However, acceptance will strengthen the
third party’s position as the burden of proof will be relaxed.92 The two
mechanisms for fixing third-party rights should not be stated as equal
alternatives as is done in England.
Further, the Act requires that assent be communicated to the promisor;
but is this notice requirement not too narrow? If the only function of
acceptance is to settle the third-party right, it should suffice if it is made to
93
the promisee. Indeed, conflicts in third-party contracts often arise between
the promisee and the third party because the promisee causes third-party
94
rights to be rescinded. It may be as important for the promisee to know
whether the right can be amended or withdrawn as for the promisor. PECL
95
allows notice to either the promisor or promisee.
Again, the difficulties of determining when a third party relies on the rights
created for him by the contracting parties is exacerbated by the wording of
the relevant provisions in the English Act. Section 2(1) determines that vari-
ation or rescission will no longer be possible where the promisor (1) is aware
that the third party has relied on the benefit;96 or (2) should reasonably have
foreseen the reliance and the third party has in fact relied on the benefit.97
This focuses too much on the state of mind of the promisor. Variation in
98
England will require agreement between the contracting parties. The question
whether the third party has acquired a settled right should rather be judged
from the perspective of the third party. The right should be regarded as settled
if the reliance of the third party is reasonable. The question whether the
promisor knew or reasonably should have known that the third party relied on
the benefit should be considered in determining whether reliance is reasonable.
99
At least the English Act is correct in not requiring detrimental reliance.
Where the contract for the benefit of the third party creates immunity against
any liability that may arise from a particular range of activities, there will be
92 Law Com No 242, paras 9.29, 9.32, 9.36; Merkin, Privity, paras 5.75, 5.80, 5.82, 5.85.
93 See De Wet & Van Wyk, Kontraktereg at 95; Getz, 1962 Acta Juridica 38 at 44.
94 See the Scottish cases cited below, text accompanying notes 101–109. See for England below, text
accompanying notes 139–142.
95 Article 6:110(3)(b) PECL.
96 Contracts (Rights of Third Parties) Act 1999, s 2(1)(b).
97 Contracts (Rights of Third Parties) Act 1999, s 2(1)(c).
98 See the reasons for this, Law Com No 242, para 9.27. It may be possible for a promisee to deprive
a third party of a claim by bringing a claim himself: see below text accompanying notes 139–142.
99 Merkin, Privity, paras 5.75, 5.83.
218 european contract law
reliance once the third party, who knows of the immunity, commences
activities within the sphere in which he has immunity. It will not be necessary
for him to perform an act that would otherwise lead to liability.100
In most cases in Scotland the agreement between promisor and promisee
will create initially a mere title to sue in favour of the third party.101 The third
party will obtain the claim himself or a settled claim only once the contract
has become irrevocable. Irrevocability will be “a condition, not a con-
102
sequence, of the expression of the jus in favour of the third party”. It is not
103
quite clear in Scotland what this title to sue means; but it is certain that the
promisee will have a stronger claim to performance than the third party, if the
promisee decides to claim it. In reality the promisee will deprive the third
104
party of his claim by doing so. A promisee has a similar power in England
105
up to the point where the right becomes settled, although Scots law does
not as a general rule allow the promisor and promisee to vary or rescind the
106
right of the third party by agreement as is the case in England. The ius
quaesitum tertio will become irrevocable on delivery of the document in
which the right is set out, or its equivalent.107 This rule developed in the
context of conflicts between promisees and third parties. It has been more or
less successful in resolving such disputes, but only because the delivery
requirement has been widely interpreted.108 Scots law correctly distinguishes
between the requirements for the third party’s right to bring a claim and for
the right becoming fixed. Yet the Scottish irrevocability rule seems to be an
imperfect tool for fixing rights. The right to sue, which the third party
acquires before the ius quaesitum tertio becomes irrevocable, is not the type
100 Merkin, Privity, para 5.83.
101 Carmichael (HL) (note 3) at 197–198; Gloag, Contract at 68, 235; see also MacQueen, in Reid
& Zimmermann, History, vol 2 at 246, 250, and Sutherland & Johnston, in Zimmermann, Visser
& Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 223–224. For cases where claims that were allowed without
reference to the delivery requirement, see Carmichael (HL) (note 3) at 198. See Merkin,
Privity, para 5.26
102 Carmichael (CS) (note 3) at 645–646, 652; Carmichael (HL) (note 3) at 200.
103 McBryde, Contract, para 10–03.
104 This is not revocation in the strict sense: McBryde, Contract, paras 10-27–10-29.
105 See below, text accompanying notes 139–142.
106 See Law Com CP 121, para 5.27 n 50 on the position in Scots law with reference to Blumer v
Scott (1874) 1 R 379 (although it will be possible to provide for such variation by agreement: see
below, text accompanying note 126).
107 See on the delivery requirement Hill v Hill (1755) Mor 11580; Jarvie’s Trustee v Jarvie’s
Trustees (1887) 14 R 411; Cameron’s Trustees v Cameron 1907 SC 407; Carmichael (CS) (note
3) at 643–647, 653; McBryde, Contract, paras 4-07, 4-32–4-44.
108 Carmichael (HL) (note 3) at 203 per Lord Dunedin; and see at 205–207 per Lord Shaw of
Dunfermline; Allan’s Trustees v Lord Advocate 1971 SC (HL) 45; Gloag, Contract at 68–69;
SME, vol 15, paras 829–830; Sutherland & Johnston, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed
Legal Systems at 228–229.
third-party contracts 219
109 The Scottish Law Commission has proposed that the delivery requirement be abandoned:
Constitution and Proof of Voluntary Obligations: Stipulations in Favour of Third Parties (Scot
Law Com Memorandum No 38, 1977), para 36. But something should be put in its place: see
also the criticism of McBryde, Contract, para 4-36; and MacQueen (1997) 1 Edinburgh LR 488
at 490.
110 Article 6:110(3) PECL.
111 Comment H (at 321).
112 Comment H (at 320).
113 Article 6:110(3)(b) PECL.
114 See above, text accompanying notes 87–95.
115 Article 6:110(3) PECL; Comment G (at 320).
116 Comment G (at 321). See also J Kerr Wylie, “Contracts in favour of third parties” (1943) 7
THRHR 94 at 115, criticised by Getz, 1962 Acta Juridica 38 at 48.
117 Article 6:110(3)(a) PECL.
220 european contract law
when to protect himself by giving notice of acceptance himself. But why should
the third party not receive protection from variation even without notice?
Of course contracting parties should be allowed to depart from these
regimes. The English Act makes clear that the rules regarding variation and
rescission are merely default rules.118 The contracting parties may by their
agreement be given a power to rescind or vary rights of the third party even
in situations where the third party’s benefit would otherwise have been settled
in terms of section 2(1). The promisee may be given the power to change the
119
beneficiary of the third-party benefit or to alter its terms. The agreement
may allow variation or rescission only with the consent of the third party in
situations where it would not be required in terms of section 2(1).
The English Act does not expressly provide that unilateral powers of
rescission and variation may be given to the promisor or promisee by the
120
contract, but the drafters thought that the Act implicitly allows for it.
Finally, the English Act grants the court power to allow the variation of third-
121
party rights without that party’s consent, even beyond the cut-off point. It is
doubtful whether there is a need for such a provision, but if there is, then the
wording of the English Act is problematic.
The general rules on revocation in Scotland,122 South Africa123 and PECL124
also merely reflect the default position. In South Africa, for instance, a pro-
misee may be given the power to rescind a third-party right after acceptance
by that party, although acceptance by the third party establishes a separate
125
contract between debtor and third party. In Scotland a provision in the
contract may grant powers of variation that go beyond, or are narrower than,
126
those that will normally exist for the promisee. In the comments to
127
PECL it is stated that the agreement may permit the promisee to rescind
or amend third party rights beyond the cut-off point established by it.
118 Contracts (Rights of Third Parties) Act 1999, s 2(3); Merkin, Privity, paras 5.76–5.77.
119 Treitel, Contract at 659.
120 Merkin, Privity, para 5.77 (although problems may arise with the application of s 2(4), (5)).
121 Contracts (Rights of Third Parties) Act 1999, s 2(4)-2(5); Merkin, Privity, paras 5.87–5.93; Law
Com CP 121, paras 5.32–5.33.
122 See the suggestion in Carmichael (CS) (note 3) at 653 per Lord Gurthrie, at 654–655 per Lord
Skerrington; J T Cameron, “Jus quaesitum tertio: the true meaning of Stair, I.x.5” 1961 JR 103
at 116–117; McBryde, Contract, para 10-03.
123 Sutherland & Johnston, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 227–228, 230–232.
124 Although this issue is not dealt with expressly in PECL.
125 On how the connection between the contracts is made, see below, text accompanying note 161.
126 Love v Amalgamated Society of Lithographic Printers of Great Britain and Ireland 1912 SC
1078 at 1082; Carmichael (CS) (note 3) at 659; McBryde, Contract, paras 10-27–10-29; SME,
vol 15, para 830; MacQueen (1997) Edinburgh LR 488 at 490.
127 Comment H (at 321).
third-party contracts 221
The third party acquires rights from the third-party contract. Where the
promisor does not adequately perform his duties in terms of the third-party
contract, the third party will have the remedies for breach of contract that are
128
ordinarily available to a contracting party. In Scotland it was initially decided
that a third party was not able to claim damages but this view apparently no
129
longer holds true. The English Act, correctly, states that the third party
should not be able to cancel the contract or make use of restitutionary
remedies.130 The same principle should apply in Scotland and in terms of
PECL. The South African two-contract approach calls for somewhat different
rules. There acceptance by the third party brings into being a separate
contract with the debtor. Often this contract will be reciprocal.131 The third
party should be able to cancel the contract for breach by the debtor in the
usual manner.
As an alternative to a contract for the benefit of a third party, the law
simply might allow the promisee to enforce a benefit in favour of a third
party. Nevertheless, the English Law Commission has shown convincingly
that this does not provide adequate protection to a third party. There is a
132
need to grant direct rights to the third party. The more complex question
which then remains is whether the promisee should also be allowed to
enforce third-party benefits.
Unless otherwise agreed, the promisee should indeed have such addi-
133
tional right against the promisor to force him to perform to the third party.
In South Africa the third party acquires no rights against the promisor before
acceptance. The promisee is therefore the custodian of the third party’s
interests before acceptance, and is able to interdict the promisor against
doing anything that would undermine the third party’s benefit.134 There are
conflicting authorities in South Africa on whether the promisee can enforce
a claim on behalf of a third party.135 However, there is no reason why he should
128 Contracts (Rights of Third Parties) Act 1999, s 1(5). Treitel, Contract at 656, calls this a fiction.
129 Especially Scott Lithgow Ltd v GEC Electrical Projects Ltd 1989 SC 412 at 438; MacQueen, in
Reid & Zimmermann, History, vol 2 at 233; SME, vol 15, para 837; Smith, 1956 JR 3 at 16–19;
MacQueen (1997) Edinburgh LR 488 at 492–493.
130 See Merkin, Privity, para 5.49, and Law Com No 242, para 3.33(i), and the Law Commission’s
interpretation of s 1(5).
131 See above, text accompanying notes 30–37, 60–61, on the two-contract approach.
132 Law Com CP 121, para 5.3; Law Com No 242, para 5.12; Merkin, Privity, para 5.8.
133 Article 6:110 PECL, Comment E (at 319).
134 Sutherland & Johnston, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 219–220.
135 African Universal Stores Ltd v Dean 1926 CPD 390 at 395; Gardner v Richardt 1974 (3) SA 768
(C) at 770; Cape Produce Co (PE) (Pty) Ltd v Dal Maso 2001 (2) SA 182 (W) 189; McKerron
222 european contract law
not be allowed to bring such a claim, especially where he has some interest in
the performance. In other legal systems recognising true third-party con-
tracts, the third party acquires rights directly under these contracts but the
promisees will also be able to sue the promisor to perform to the third
party.136
The next, and more controversial, question is whether the promisee should
be allowed to sue the debtor to render the promised performance to him. In
terms of the two-contract approach, this is not possible in South Africa,
unless the parties have agreed differently. The true third-party contract
137
introduced by PECL also does not allow it. In Scotland the promisee will
be able to claim performance before the ius quaesitum tertio becomes irre-
138
vocable. There appear to be good policy reasons for this approach. The
Law Commission in England similarly proposed that the “promisor’s duty to
139
perform is owed both to the third party and the contractual promisee”; but
that performance to the third party should free the promisor from perform-
ance to the promisee. The Commission further stated that the debtor should
be allowed to perform to the promisee, with the promisee being allowed to
claim performance; and that there should be no priority of actions. The
Commission also expressed the view that performance could only be made to
the promisee up to the point when the third party’s rights become settled.140
This broad approach is sophisticated and sensible. However, it will also
cause difficulties. The English promisee, like his Scottish counterpart, will be
able to deprive the third party of the benefit by claiming the right himself
before it becomes settled. However, the English Act does not determine how
(1929) 46 SALJ 387 at 391–392; Christie, Contract at 309 regards an interdict as the appropriate
remedy. De Wet & Van Wyk, Kontraktereg at 98, and D B Hutchison, “Unravelling the
stipulatio alteri” (1974) 3 Responsa Meridiana 1 at 7, accept that the promisee will be able to
force the promisor to perform to the third party, albeit not without the latter’s co-operation.
136 Article 6:110 PECL, Comment E (at 319). It is suggested at 320 that the promisee will have to
enforce the third-party right before he receives notice of it from the promisee but there is no
justification for this interpretation: see above, text accompanying note 29. The Contracts
(Rights of Third Parties) Act 1999 clearly foresees an important role for promisees within third-
party contracts: see Merkin, Privity, para 5.60. See also the comment in Law Com No 242 at
paras 11.1–11.10, 11.20–11.22.
137 Article 6:110 PECL, Comment E (at 319); but see Comment G where it is wrongly suggested
that the promisee will be able to claim performance for himself before notice is given to the
third party. This is not borne out by the PECL text. See the argument in South Africa in Bursey
v Bursey 1997 (4) All SA 580 (E) at 592.
138 Sutherland & Johnston, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 228–229.
139 Law Com CP 121, para 5.34.
140 Law Com CP 121, para 5.34; Law Com No 242, paras 5.18, 11.1–11.4, 11.5–11.6, 11.11–11.15;
Merkin, Privity, paras 5.58–5.60.
third-party contracts 223
141 Law Com No 242, para 11.14; Merkin, Privity, paras 5.73–5.74, although Law Com CP 121,
para 5.34, suggests that the third party should be given preference.
142 Reliance is probably placed on Contracts (Rights of Third Parties) Act 1999, s 4, see below, text
accompanying note 154.
143 Especially Linden Gardens Trust Ltd v Lenesta Sludge Disposal Ltd [1994] 1 AC 85; Panatown
(note 3), where the judges were unanimous on this point but disagreed on the exact rules to be
applied here: Lord Clyde at 529 ff follows a narrow approach but Lords Jauncey, Goff, Millett
and, more reluctantly, Lord Browne-Wilkinson take a wider view of the bases for such claims;
Law Com CP 121, paras 3.39–3.44; Law Com No 242, paras 2.37–2.51, 5.15; Merkin, Privity,
paras 1.34, 2.9–2.15, 5.1, 5.3; Treitel, Contract at 592–603.
144 Panatown (note 3) at 534.
145 Panatown (note 3) at 535. See also the Scottish case of Clark Contracts, at paras 31, 36–38.
146 McLaren Murdoch & Hamilton Ltd v The Abercromby Motor Group Ltd 2003 SCLR 323
(henceforth McLaren Murdoch) at paras 33–42, rejecting Lord Clyde’s suggestion in Panatown
(above text accompanying note 144) but otherwise accepting his approach. Compare the more
conservative approach followed in Clark Contracts (note 24) at paras 23–30.
147 Panatown (note 3) at 529 per Lord Clyde; McLaren Murdoch (note 146) at paras 33, 42.
224 european contract law
third party. If that offer is to the effect that the third-party contract will be
void or will fall away if the underlying contract fails for a particular reason, the
second contract will be subject to a resolutive condition that will make its
existence subject to that of the first contract.
The two-contract approach is important in determining which part of a
third-party contract has to comply with any formalities imposed by the law.
Where the ultimate contract between the third party and promisee has to
comply with formalities, it will be valid if the offer to the third party and
acceptance by him comply with the formalities even if the contract between
162
the promisor and promisee does not.
In a true third-party contract, the relationship between the rights of the
163
third party and the contract from which they derive will be more intricate.
It may be proposed that a third party should be isolated from failures of the
third-party contract. But there are stronger policy reasons for not doing so. In
the English Law Commission’s consultation paper on third-party contracts, it
was contended that the third party should be in the same position as an
assignee,164 but it was convincingly concluded in their final report that this is
a dangerous analogy.165 The third party receives a benefit that derives from a
particular contract. Its existence and enforceability should depend on the
continued validity166 and enforceability of the contract, and should be deter-
mined in the context of that contract.167 Like any normal contracting party,
the third party should be conscious of this. Even the acceptance of the third
party should not be able to change the position, as a separate second contract
will not be created through it.
It is surprising that this topic is not addressed in PECL, but the difficulties
with legislating for these situations are illustrated by the English Act. It
determines that a promisor, confronted by a third party who tries to enforce
168
a term in the contract, will have available to him by way of defence or set-
169
off any matter that (1) applies to the term and arises from the contract; and
162 Kynochs (note 32) at 77; Malan (1976) 9 De Iure 85 at 88. See Trever Investments v Friedhelm
1982 (1) SA 7 (A), although this case was not expressly decided on the basis that the contract
constituted a stipulatio alteri.
163 See Goodwood Racecourse Ltd v Satellite Information Services Ltd 2004 EWHC 2346 (Ch) at
paras 41–42, on rectification of a third-party contract.
164 Law Com CP 121, para 5.24.
165 Law Com No 242, paras 10.8–10.16; Merkin, Privity, para 5.94.
166 Law Com CP 121, para 5.1; Law Com No 242, paras 10.1 (n 1), 10.4; Merkin, Privity, para 5.96.
167 Law Com No 242, paras 10.13–10.15. See for Scotland McBryde, Contract, para 10–09; SME,
vol 15, para 839.
168 See how the defence is defined by Law Com No 242, para 10.2.
169 See on this phrase Law Com No 242, para 10.11; Merkin, Privity, para 5.97.
third-party contracts 227
(2) would have been available against the promisee.170 Moreover, it states that
the promisor will have available by way of defence, set-off or counterclaim
any matter that would have been available against the third party if that third
party had been a party to the contract.171
It is not quite clear from the wording whether a personal defence against
the promisee, such as estoppel, can be maintained against the third party.172
The Act merely states that the defence must relate to the term that provides
the third-party right; but this requirement does not produce a clear answer to
the problem. Although it may be difficult to determine what a personal
remedy is, the issue cannot be avoided. Defences that are personal to the
promisee should not be available against the third party, and legislation on
third-party contracts should make this clear.
The English Act correctly implies that a third party’s right will fall away if
the contract is cancelled by one of the contracting parties for breach by the
173
other. This may be a trap for unwary third parties. A third party may feel
hard done by if the right, though it can no longer be varied by the contracting
parties, is lost because one of the contracting parties has cancelled the
contract due to breach of the other. However, the third party will not be
entirely unprotected in these situations. He should be able to claim damages
in contract from the promisor where the contract is cancelled because of his
breach, and in delict (unless there is a specific contract between the promisee
and third party174) from the promisee where the promisee’s breach caused
the termination of the contract.
Where the promisor has to perform the duty to the third party in exchange
for performance by the promisee, it should be possible for the promisor to
withhold performance to the third party until he has received counter-
performance. This is the implication of the English Act and the law will
probably be no different in terms of PECL. But can the third party force the
promisee to perform to enable him to claim performance from the promisor?
Perhaps the answer should be no, but then the promisor and promisee
J. CONCLUSION
The South African stipulatio alteri is not a third-party contract at all. In South
Africa there is a need for a true third-party contract alongside what is
currently so described. Scots law has a true third-party contract but has been
plagued by the delivery requirement. Legislative reforms along the lines of
the English Act or PECL will be useful in both jurisdictions. Nevertheless,
existing rules in the mixed legal systems should not simply be jettisoned. The
South African two-contract option can be utilised fruitfully in the other legal
systems under discussion. In several respects the Scots law on third-party
contracts is very refined. Both mixed legal systems raise important issues that
175 Sutherland & Johnston, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 218.
176 Contracts (Rights of Third Parties) Act 1999, s 3(3); Law Com No 242, para 10.15; Merkin,
Privity, para 5.102.
177 Contracts (Rights of Third Parties) Act 1999, s 3(5). Law Com No 242, paras 10.13–10.16;
Merkin, Privity, para 5.99.
third-party contracts 229
A. INTRODUCTION
B. FORM AND MANNER OF PAYMENT
(1) South African and Scots law
(2) PECL compared to South African and Scots law
(3) Conclusion
C. PAYMENT BY THIRD PARTY
(1) Introduction
(2) South African law
(3) Scots (and some English) law
(4) PECL compared to South African and Scots law
(5) Conclusion
D. FINAL REMARKS
A. INTRODUCTION
Chapter 7 of PECL deals with the performance of obligations. The focus of
this contribution is on the performance of a particular type of obligation,
1
namely the obligation to pay money, or, in other words, on payment. Two
questions relating to payment dealt with in PECL are considered here in
comparative perspective namely: (1) the form and manner of payment; and
2
(2) payment by a third party.
1 This innocent-looking and apparently simple definition should be approached with care. It
contains terms such as “performance” and “money” both of which are anything but simple. See,
e.g., R M Goode, Commercial Law, 2nd edn (1995), 489 on “money”, and J E du Plessis “Die
regsaard van prestasie” (2002) 65 THRHR 59 on “performance”. See also on the meaning of
“money” and “payment” McBryde, Contract, paras 24-01, 24-07.
2 PECL deals with a number of further topics relevant to payment namely: (1) the place of per-
formance (or payment) (Article 7:101 PECL); (2) the time of performance (Article 7:102 PECL);
(3) early performance (Article 7:103 PECL); (4) currency of payment (Article 7:108 PECL);
(5) appropriation of performance (Article 7:109 PECL); and (6) money not accepted (Article
7:111 PECL). The other provisions of Chapter 7 PECL relate mainly to other types of performance.
230
payment 231
3 On South African law see B & H Engineering v First National Bank of SA Ltd 1995 (2) SA 279 (A)
(henceforth B & H Engineering) at 285G; Van der Merwe et al, Contract, 484, 486; F R Malan &
J T Pretorius (assisted by S F du Toit), Malan on Bills of Exchange, Cheques and Promissory Notes
4th edn (2002) (henceforth Malan & Pretorius, Bills of Exchange), paras 40, 188. On Scots law see
Glasgow Pavilion Ltd v Motherwell (1903) 6 F 116 at 119; Walker, Principles, vol 2, 140;
McBryde, Contract, para 24–08; Gloag, Contract, 709.
4 See s 17(2) of the South African Reserve Bank Act, 90 of 1989. For a summary of the Scottish
legislation in this regard see Walker, Principles of Scottish Private Law, 4th edn (1989)
(henceforth Walker, Principles), vol 2, 140 n 85. See also Walker, Contract, para 31.30.
5 Van der Merwe et al, Contract, 484 n 16. The currency in which the debt must be paid is that of
the locus solutionis. See Joffe v African Life Assurance Society Ltd 1933 TPD 189 at 195. Scots
law appears to be the same; see McBryde, Contract, para 24-03 n 19.
6 Walker, Principles, vol 2, 140 n 85; McBryde, Contract, para 24–08.
7 Leggat Brothers v Gray 1908 SC 67 (henceforth Leggat Brothers) at 74; Walker, Contract, para
31.30.
8 For an overview of the development of methods of payment see C Visser, “The evolution of
electronic payment systems” (1989) 1 SA Merc LJ 189 at 189–191.
9 Christie, Contract, 469 regards it as “almost an anachronism”.
10 1917 TPD 497 at 500.
232 european contract law
18 Walker, Contract, para 31.31; McBryde, Contract, para 24–10, with reference to Bolt & Nut Co
(Tipton) v Rowlands, Nicholls & Co [1964] 2 QB 10; Gloag, Contract, 709.
19 Chitty on Contracts 28th edn (1999) (henceforth Chitty) vol 1, para 22-074.
20 Para 22–077.
21 1908 SC at 67, 73–74. See also McBryde, Contract, para 24–09; Walker, Contract, para 31.31;
Gloag, Contract, 709.
22 Note also the formulation that “payment is complete” on acceptance of the cheque.
234 european contract law
the time of receipt of the cheque, but that the discharge is conditional.23 It is
suggested, however, that too much has been made of the resolutive-condition
construction in the context of this case read as a whole. The Lord President’s
reluctance “to refer the matter to any particular legal category” should be
noted. Moreover, it appears later in the judgment that the question whether
or not “the delivery and acceptance of a cheque really extinguished the debt
during the interval between its acceptance and the payment of the money by
the bank” was argued before the court. The court termed this “an interesting
discussion” but declined to express its views on this question which it
24
regarded as “rather abstract and logical than practical”.
Embarking, as an academic, on the luxury of addressing this abstract question
logically, it seems to me sensible to do so from the perspective of novation.
Stair, in considering the discharge of an obligation by novation, states:
28 In B & H Engineering (note 3) at 285G–H Grosskopf JA states, somewhat vaguely, that the rules
regarding the giving of cheques can be extended to “other instruments”. See also Stassen, 1978
De Jure 134 at 137.
29 R v Lambie [1981] 2 All ER 776 (HL) at 780a–b, by analogy to cheque cards. The bank’s
contractual liability to pay arises against the background of a pre-existing contract between it and
the supplier, in terms of which it undertakes to pay the supplier for goods delivered or services
rendered to the cardholder. See Re Charge Card Services Ltd [1986] 3 All ER 289 (Ch D)
(henceforth Charge Card Services) at 296b–d.
30 D v Cowen & L Gering, Cowen The Law of Negotiable Instruments in South Africa, vol 1, 5th edn
(1985) (henceforth Cowen & Gering, Negotiable Instruments) at 269–270; Stassen, 1978 De Jure
134. Credit cards have only been considered in two South African cases, neither of which sheds
light on this issue: Western Bank Ltd v Registrar of Financial Institutions 1975 (4) SA 37 (T);
Diners Club South Africa (Pty) Ltd v Durban Engineering (Pty) Ltd 1980 (3) SA 53 (A).
31 The creditor will, in any event, most likely be bound contractually as against the card issuer to
honour the card. See Stassen, 1978 De Jure 134 at 140–141; and, Stassen, “Payment by credit
card” (1978) 7 Businessman’s Law 12 at 13.
32 J C Stassen “Payment by credit card – cash or credit?” (1979) 8 Businessman’s Law 183 at 184.
236 european contract law
Scots law appears to be at peace with the Charge Card case.39 The reason-
ing in this case is compelling and it is submitted, despite the earlier academic
opinion to the contrary referred to above, that South African courts are likely
to follow the decision should the matter arise.
As regards payment by letter of credit, this is almost always in pursuance of
an express payment clause in the contract. The legal-tender problem, which
is sometimes present in the case of payment by cheque or credit card, there-
fore does not arise. As regards the effect of the creditor accepting payment by
letter of credit, both the South African and Scots law are almost certainly the
33 Stassen, 1978 De Jure 134 at 136–139; Cowen & Gering, Negotiable Instruments, 270.
34 [1986] 3 All ER 289 (Ch D).
35 At 301f.
36 At 301g.
37 At 301h–303e.
38 At 303h–304b.
39 Walker, Principles, 141.
payment 237
same as that which has developed in the English courts. The leading decision
on the nature of payment by letter of credit is that of the Court of Appeal in
W J Alan & Co Ltd v El Nasr Export and Import Co.40 In his judgment Lord
Denning MR recognised that it was possible in a special case that the creditor
and debtor might have reached an agreement to the effect that the issuing of
the letter of credit would constitute “absolute payment” discharging the debt.41
In the rule, however, it amounted to “conditional payment” which means:
[T]he seller looks in the first instance to the banker for payment: but, if the banker
does not meet his obligations when the time comes for him to do so, the seller can
42
have recourse to the buyer.
So viewed, it must be clear that the underlying debt, as in the case of a cheque,
is not discharged by accepting payment in terms of a letter of credit. There is
no novation. The letter of credit, as in the case of a credit card, gives the
debtor rights against a third party, but, unlike the position in the case of
payment by credit card, if the third party does not perform, the debtor’s
suspended rights in terms of the underlying debt become effective.
1. South African and Scots law both proceed from the basis that, unless
otherwise agreed, a creditor can insist on being paid in legal tender.
However, in both systems, an agreement by the creditor to accept
payment by other common means such as by cheque or credit card is
lightly inferred.
2. Payment by cheque is regarded as conditional, as opposed to absolute,
in both systems. In general terms this means that although the
moment of delivery of the cheque is regarded as the moment of
payment, if the cheque is dishonoured, there has been no payment
and the creditor can sue the debtor either on the cheque or on the
underlying debt.
3. In the more precise analysis of the legal effect of the creditor accep-
ting payment by cheque the two systems may differ, although this is
not entirely clear. Whilst it is clear in South Africa that acceptance of
This implies that the debtor may choose the form of payment. The creditor
cannot unilaterally demand payment in a particular form or manner, not even
in legal tender. If the form and manner of payment are important to him, the
43
particular form or manner must be agreed in the contract. However, the
debtor does not have an unfettered choice: the choice must fall within the
“ordinary course of business”. This is necessary in order to protect the
creditor from having to accept a “surprising, unusual or burdensome manner
44
of payment”. There is much to be said for the way in which PECL addresses
45
this matter. The anachronistic nature of the legal-tender requirement still
present in many legal systems in modern times is recognised. The solution
adopted is a better reflection of the commercial reality in an increasingly
cashless society. It is also more satisfactory than the rule adopted in the USA
in terms of which a creditor, when offered payment in some other manner,
can demand payment in legal tender but subject to a reasonable extension of
time to enable the debtor to procure it.46
The second principle is formulated as follows:
A creditor which, pursuant to the contract or voluntarily, accepts a cheque or other
order to pay or a promise to pay is presumed to do so only on condition that it will
47
be honoured.
The use of the words “may not enforce the original obligation” is significant.
This phrase does not support the idea of the original obligation having been
discharged by acceptance of the substituted performance, and then coming
to life again if the substituted performance leads to nothing – i.e. the idea of
the substituted performance constituting a conditional novation. The drafters,
as is also borne out in the comments,50 have in mind the suspension of the
underlying debt until such time as the substituted performance has been
dishonoured. The understanding of conditional payment under PECL is
therefore the same as that of English and South African law. This approach, it
is suggested, is also in accordance with the probable intention of the parties.
(3) Conclusion
Article 7:107 PECL deserves to be supported. It is clear, and in general
reflects both commercial reality and the probable intentions of the parties. In
doing away with the traditional possibility of requiring payment in legal
tender it is probably prophetic. The solution employed is more advanced
than the law in most countries. Its clear rejection of the idea that the accep-
tance of substituted performance is novatory, by recognising a presumption
to the contrary, is, as a general rule, satisfactory. In the specific instance of
payment by credit card, PECL probably favours an outcome different from
that in the Charge Card Services case. However, it may well be that the
reasoning in that case is compelling enough to rebut the presumption.
(1) Introduction
In dealing with the form and manner of payment above, it was noted that a
creditor very often does not obtain payment from the debtor directly but
from a third party, in the form of the bank on which a cheque has been drawn,
or the bank that has issued a letter of credit or credit card. In these situations
the creditor typically looks towards the bank for payment in accordance with
an agreement with the debtor that he will do so. However, payment of
another’s debt can also arise in various non-consensual situations. A bene-
factor may, for example, simply pay the debt of a friend without his know-
ledge, or a sub-tenant may pay the rental of the tenant to prevent his eviction,
or a bank acting without mandate may pay a cheque. Such third-party
payments are considered below.
51 See B & H Engineering (note 3) at 292F; Froman v Robertson 1971 (1) SA 115 (A) (henceforth
Froman) at 124G; Commissioner for Inland Revenue v Visser 1959 (1) SA 452 (A) at 458A.
payment 241
induces the extinction of the obligation, and the debtor is discharged even against
52
his will.
53
These views have been applied consistently by the South African courts.
Recently, in Info Plus v Scheelke the Supreme Court of Appeal stated “[that]
it is hardly necessary to say that a debt owing by A to B may be extinguished
by a payment made by a stranger to B in discharge of that debt even if A is
unaware of such payment”.54 These views are shared by contemporary
authors.55
Thus, should the payment be subject to the creditor ceding his rights
against the debtor to the third party, the payment was not made with the
56
intention of discharging the debt, and it will accordingly remain intact.
However, payment tendered by a third party on behalf of the debtor with the
57
intention of discharging the debt cannot be refused by the creditor.
Whether the third party will have any claim against the debtor will depend
upon the circumstances. Such a claim may lie in contract (for example where
the third party is a mandatary of the debtor). Claims may also be possible on
58
the basis of negotiorum gestio or enrichment. A problematic question
against this background is whether a bank can recover the amount of a
cheque which it has mistakenly paid to the payee. This question arises, inter
alia, when payment of the cheque was countermanded and the bank
overlooks the countermand.59 The matter has been the subject of a lively
debate in South African law,60 but now seems to have been authoritatively
settled by the judgment of the Supreme Court of Appeal in the B & H
Engineering case. In contrast to the decision of the court a quo, Grosskopf JA
took the view that in this situation one is not dealing with third-party payments
52 R J Pothier, Treatise on the Law of Obligations (1826, transl W D Evans) (henceforth Pothier,
Obligations), para 463. Van der Linden, Institutes, 1.18.1 is virtually identical. See also Voet,
Commentarius, 46.3.1; Van Leeuwen, Censura Forensis, 1.4.32.3.
53 Reliance Agencies (Pty) Ltd v Patel 1946 CPD 463 at 472–473; Froman (note 51) at 124F–H; Info
Plus v Scheelke 1998 (3) SA 184 (SCA) at 192D.
54 1998 (3) SA 184 (SCA) at 192D.
55 Van der Merwe et al, Contract, 492–493; Lubbe & Murray, Contract, 705–706 n 2; Christie,
Contract, 472.
56 Van der Merwe et al, Contract, 492; Shaw v Burger 1994 (1) SA 524 (C); HK Outfitters (Py) Ltd
v Legal & General Assurance Society Ltd 1975 (1) SA 55 (T); cf also Pothier, Obligations, para
464; Christie, Contract, 472.
57 Pothier, Obligations, para 464. The test according to Pothier is whether the payment is in the
interest of the debtor. If it is, it must be accepted. If it is not (as in the case of payment subject to
cession), it need not be accepted.
58 Van der Merwe et al, Contract, 493.
59 It can also arise when the bank pays a forged cheque: see Malan & Pretorius, Bills of Exchange,
para 210.
60 For an excellent historical overview see Malan & Pretorius, Bills of Exchange, para 210.
242 european contract law
The early Scots authorities, however, are not uniform. Some take the view,
which prevails in England, that third-party payment does not discharge a
67
debt unless ratified by the debtor.
There is also little on this topic in the modern Scottish texts. Walker states
that payment by a third party on behalf of the debtor is valid, even if made
without the debtor’s knowledge or consent.68 In the Stair Memorial Encyclo-
paedia a preference is expressed for the view that the unauthorised payment
of a debt by a third party discharges the debt.69 Gloag, with reference to early
case law,70 states that a creditor who is not taking active steps to enforce his
debt, is not bound to accept payment from any person other than the debtor
or someone having his authority. Should he, however, be taking measures to
enforce payment, or to realise securities, “he is bound to accept payment and
to grant an assignation to anyone who can show an interest to intervene, such
as a friend of the debtor, or a postponed bondholder in subjects conveyed in
71
security”. In coupling the obligation to accept payment by an interested
stranger to assignation, it would appear that Gloag does not have a debt-
extinguishing situation in mind. Scottish case law on this topic is sparse. One
case holds that where a third party had paid the debt of another owed to a
bank, the debtor’s obligations to the bank were discharged, and that Scots
72
law, in this regard, was Civilian in character. MacQueen’s conclusions that
the Scots law in this regard is “remarkably unclear”73 or “at best undeveloped”74
appears to be apposite.
It is of interest that the Notes to PECL express the view that, as regards
75 See Note 2(b) to Article 7:107 PECL. Professor MacQueen advises me that this note was drafted
in the mid-1990s before he had fully addressed his mind to the problems involved.
76 S Whittaker, “Performance of another’s obligation: French and English law contrasted”, in
Johnston & Zimmermann, Unjustified Enrichment, 433, 445–446; Treitel, Contract, 755–756;
Chitty, para 22-041.
77 (1851) 11 CB 191 (138 ER 444). For a discussion of the case see P Birks & J Beatson,
“Unrequested payment of another’s debt” (1976) 92 LQR 188 at 189–191.
78 (1852) 22 LJCP 73; 12 CB 791 (138 ER 1115).
79 (1855) 10 Ex 845 at 847 (156 ER 683 at 684). See also Smith v Cox [1940] 2 KB 558 at 560.
80 Whittaker, in Johnston & Zimmermann, Unjustified Enrichment at 447.
81 For detailed expositions and debate regarding this matter, see Birks & Beatson (1976) 92 LQR
188; D Friedman, “Payment of another’s debt” (1983) 99 LQR 534.
82 MacQueen, in Johnston & Zimmermann, Unjustified Enrichment at 471.
payment 245
rest content.” Secondly there is the systematic reason that it would align
Scots law with the other systems in the Civilian tradition. Finally, MacQueen
argues that there is more clear authority for the Civilian rule in Scotland, than
for the English rule. However, he subjects his preference to one reservation:
the Civilian rule appears to be inappropriate to determine the question
whether a bank paying a stopped cheque thereby discharges the underlying
debt. In this regard he prefers the English rule.
The effect of payment by a bank of a stopped cheque in English law was
considered in detail by Goff J in Barclays Bank Ltd v W J Simms Son &
83
Cooke (Southern) Ltd. In this case the bank was successful in recovering
such a payment from the payee on the basis that since the payment was
unauthorised, it did not discharge the debt. The payee was accordingly
enriched and liable to the impoverished bank in restitution. Unlike the stance
taken by Grosskopf JA in the South African B & H Engineering case, it is clear
that Goff J regarded payment of a cheque by a bank as third-party payment.
For this reason, on application of the English law relating to vicarious
payments, it can only discharge the debt if it has been authorised, i.e. if the
bank has paid within its mandate. A bank paying a stopped cheque therefore
does not pay within its mandate and does not discharge the debt. The
recipient of the payment is accordingly enriched and liable to the bank in
restitution, at least in the absence of a change of position defence.84
MacQueen, having reviewed the South African law as well, regards the
85
Barclays Bank case as good law also in Scotland. His preference for the
Barclays Bank approach is based on policy considerations. He argues that the
bank paying on a countermanded cheque is paying without instruction;
therefore it must be very dubious whether in the circumstances the
customer’s debt can be properly treated as discharged by the bank’s payment.
MacQueen points out that the reason for the countermand is often some
claim which the drawer customer wishes to make against the payee of the
cheque in the underlying relationship in which the cheque constitutes
payment. The withholding of payment by this route is a useful and legitimate
pressure tactic towards obtaining proper performance of the payee’s obli-
gation. The drawer’s position would be even more problematic if, in addition
to losing his effective remedy, it was also subject to the bank’s claim in respect
of its impoverishment (as suggested in the B & H Engineering case86).
Against this background it is interesting to note that PECL clearly opts for
a via media. It differentiates between two categories of third parties. The first
87
category consists of any third party who “acts with the assent of the debtor”
as well as a “third person [who] has a legitimate interest” in timeous per-
88
formance of the debt. Any other third party falls into the second category.
As regards performance by third parties falling into the first category, PECL
identifies two consequences: (1) the creditor cannot refuse performance by
such a third party; and (2) such performance discharges the debt. These rules
apply unless the contract requires “personal performance”89 i.e. payment by
the debtor himself – which is unlikely.90 PECL has no provision as to the
consequences of performance tendered by a third party falling within the
second category, which is accepted by the creditor.91
The competence of performance by a third party with the assent of the
debtor, i.e. by an authorised third party, is in accordance with the law of all
(5) Conclusion
The law relating to third-party payments differs substantially in different
countries, and in some, including Scotland, it is rather unclear. To draft prin-
ciples for European contract law on this matter must necessarily be difficult.
The via media adopted here appears to me to be a reasonably practical
solution. It has, however, simply avoided some difficult questions, especially
as to the effect of an unauthorised payment by a disinterested third party that
has been accepted by the creditor. Apart from the fact that PECL clearly
diverges from the strict English rule, it does not appear to have a striking
resemblance to the law of either South Africa or Scotland.
92 See Note 1 to Article 7:106 PECL which states that although “expressed differently” in different
legal systems, all legal systems “seem to agree” on this principle.
93 Comment B to Article 7:106 PECL. Another obvious example would be where the sub-tenant
pays the rental owed by the tenant to prevent the eviction of the tenant.
94 See note 59 above.
95 See the text above at note 68 where the competence to pay arises, inter alia, “where any penal
effect may arise from delay”. It appears to me that this penal effect relates to the debtor. It can,
however, possibly be interpreted as affecting the third party.
248 european contract law
D. FINAL REMARKS
South African and Scots law have a mixed character which, in both cases, they
have developed over a long period of time. This has been well documented in
96
two substantial works that have been published in the past decade. PECL
obviously also have a mixed character. However, the manner and process by
which this mix has come to fruition are very different from what happened in
Scotland and South Africa. In conclusion one might ask the question posed
by Zimmermann, Visser and Reid, the editors of Mixed Legal Systems in
Comparative Perspective: whether, in comparing the Scots and South African
law with PECL, we find either the “comfort of corroboration” in similarity, or
a “cause for reflection” in difference.97
In applying this question specifically to the payment issues considered
above, two difficulties emerge: first, the mixed nature of South African law is
not really evident on these points – its principles are very much Civilian; and,
secondly, although Scots law shows clear signs of English legal influence, this
has not resulted in a blend but has led to uncertainty as to what the law
actually is. A more interesting question, against this background, may be
whether PECL can serve as a fertile source for the future development of
South African and Scots law. I believe that the way in which PECL has dealt
with modern methods of payment constitutes a useful model for legislation
both in Scotland and South Africa. In Scotland, where the effect of
unauthorised third-party payments is still uncertain, PECL may well be
influential in future cases. From a South African perspective, one might in
the light of PECL reflect on whether unqualified acceptance of the rule that
payment by a third party discharges the debt, is sensible.
96 See Zimmermann & Visser, Southern Cross; Reid & Zimmermann, History.
97 Reid & Zimmermann, History, preface.
10 Specific Performance and
Special Damages
Sieg Eiselen
A. INTRODUCTION
B. SPECIFIC PERFORMANCE
(1) Introduction
(2) South African law
(a) Roman and Roman-Dutch law
(b) South African law
(3) Scots law
(4) Articles 9:101 and 9:102 PECL
(5) Comparative conclusion
C. SPECIAL DAMAGES OR REMOTENESS OF DAMAGES
(1) Introduction
(2) South African law
(a) Roman and Roman-Dutch law
(b) South African law
(3) Scots law
(4) Articles 9:502 and 9:503 PECL
(5) Comparative conclusion
D. CONCLUSION
A. INTRODUCTION
The interplay and differences between Common Law and Civil Law in mixed
legal systems are illustrated very clearly in two remedies commonly available
after a breach of contract, namely specific performance, or specific
implement, and the rules relating to special damages. Specific performance
provides an instance where the Civil Law and the Common Law depart from
directly opposing points of view. In Civil Law specific performance is
regarded as the natural remedy after breach, whereas in Common Law it is
regarded as exceptional, with damages being the prime remedy.
The rules on special damages, on the other hand, provide an instance
where there is a large measure of convergence between Common Law and
249
250 european contract law
Civil Law, due to the pervasive influence of Pothier in this field. The
comparison of these two remedies of South African and Scots law provides an
interesting backdrop for a consideration of the relevant provisions of PECL.
B. SPECIFIC PERFORMANCE
(1) Introduction
The issue of specific performance seems to draw a very definite dividing line
between the Common Law and Civil Law traditions.1 During the drafting
process for CISG the question of specific performance presented an obstacle
2
on which no consensus could be reached. It resulted in a compromise which
3
preserved the autonomy of the lex fori to apply its own specific rules.
It is generally said that the point of departure in the Civil Law systems is
that a party is in principle entitled to have its contract enforced as agreed
unless there is some equitable reason for denying it such relief, whereas in
English law the creditor is entitled to damages as the primary remedy for a
breach of contract unless there is some equitable reason for granting it in
4
equity. The validity of these axioms will be discussed below in order to
evaluate the approach followed in Articles 9:101 and 9:102 PECL.
1 Joubert, Contract, 224; De Wet and van Wyk, Kontraktereg, 190; Christie, Contract, 605–606;
PECL, vol 1, 399.
2 See U Huber in P Schlechtriem, Commentary on the UN Convention on the International Sale of
Goods (CISG) 2nd edn (1998) (henceforth Schlechtriem, CISG), Article 28 n 5 at 200.
3 See Article 28 CISG; Huber in Schlechtriem, CISG, Article 28 n 5 at 200 .
4 Joubert, Contract, 224; PECL, vol 1, 395; A Cockrell, “Breach of contract” in Zimmermann &
Visser, Southern Cross, 325; Treitel, Contract, 926; MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, para 6.6; H
L MacQueen & L J Macgregor “Specific implement, interdict and contractual performance”
(1999) 3 Edinburgh LR 239.
5 Zimmermann, Obligations, 770–772; cf Joubert, Contract, 223; De Wet & Van Wyk,
Kontraktereg, 189.
specific performance and special damages 251
accepted that courts had the power to order specific performance.6 This
happened under the influence of Germanic law which granted the non-
defaulting party a choice as to whether it wanted to claim compliance in
forma specifica or whether it would be content with damages.7 This power
was subject to two exceptions, namely instances where the performance had
become impossible and where the estate of the debtor had been sequestrated.8
6 Joubert, Contract, 223–224; De Wet & Van Wyk, Kontraktereg, 189; Cockrell, in Zimmermann &
Visser, Southern Cross.
7 De Wet & Van Wyk, Kontraktereg, 189.
8 Joubert, Contract, 224; De Wet & Van Wyk, Kontraktereg, 189.
9 Cockrell, in Zimmermann & Visser, Southern Cross, 326–327.
10 Atkinson v Vause’s Executors (1892) 13 NLR 85; Pauline Colliery and Developing Syndicate v
Natal Land and Colonisation Co Ltd (1902) 23 NLR 166.
11 Ingle Colonial Broom Co Ltd v Hocking 1914 CPD 495; Barker v Beckett & Co Ltd 1911 TPD
151; Christie, Contract, 615; Cockrell, in Zimmermann & Visser, Southern Cross, 327.
12 Visser v Neethling 1921 CPD 176; Cockrell, in Zimmermann & Visser, Southern Cross, 327.
13 Schierhout v Minister of Justice 1926 AD 99 at 108; Christie, Contract, 613–614.
14 Norden v Rennie (1879) Buch 155; Cohen v Shires, McHattie and King (1882) 1 SAR 41; Van der
Westhuizen v Velenski (1898) 14 SC 237; Fick v Woolcott & Ohlsson’s Cape Breweries 1911 AD
214; Farmer’s Co-operative Society (Reg) v Berry 1912 AD 343; Amoils v Amoils 1924 WLD 88 at
98; Shill v Milner 1937 AD 101; J W Wessels, The Law of Contract in South Africa, 2nd edn by A
A Roberts (1951), § 3122; De Wet & Van Wyk, Kontraktereg, 189; Joubert, Contract, 223;
Christie, Contract, 607–608.
15 See Wells v SA Alumenite Co 1927 AD 69; Brisley v Drotsky 2002 (4) SA 1 (SCA) at 27; and esp
Basson v Chilwan 1993 (3) SA 742 (A) at 777A-B; Santos Professional Football Club (Pty) Ltd v
Igesund 2003 (5) SA 73 (C) at 86–87.
252 european contract law
A claim for the payment of money due under the contract is strictly speak-
ing a claim for specific performance, although this term has become reserved
for those instances where performance of a non-monetary obligation is
claimed.26 Joubert is of the opinion that although some courts have refused to
order specific performance relying on the judicial discretion to refuse such
orders, 27 these cases must be seen as an aberration.28 According to him courts
have no discretion to refuse specific performance for the payment of money.
However, the case law on which he relies does not bear this out.
29 30
In the Anastassiou case to which Joubert refers, the issue of the court’s
31
discretion to refuse specific performance was expressly raised. Davidson J
32
reviewed the leading cases dealing with this issue in order to establish the
33
circumstances under which the court may refuse to exercise its discretion.
There is no indication that the court regarded its discretion as fettered in the
case of the payment of money.
Where a contract contains a negative obligation (i.e. where the debtor
promises not to do something), the creditor is entitled to an order restraining
the debtor from performing that act.34 The usual remedy of the creditor is to
obtain an interdict restraining the debtor from breaching its obligations. The
creditor must prove the usual requirements for an interdict, namely a clear
right, a threat of interference with that right and the absence of similar
protection by any other remedy.35
The enforcement of restraints of trade provides by far the most common
occasion where negative obligations arise. Although the early South African
cases followed English law in regarding restraints of trade as being prima
26 Joubert, Contract, 222; Christie, Contract, 606–607. See also Gibson v Woodhead Plant Ltd 1918
AD 308.
27 Manasewitz v Oosthuizen 1914 CPD 328; Carpet Contracts (Pty) Ltd v Grobler 1975 (2) SA 436
(T).
28 Joubert, Contract, 222; Industrial & Mercantile Corporation v Anastassiou Bros 1973 (2) SA 601
(W).
29 Industrial & Mercantile Corporation v Anastassiou Bros 1973 (2) SA 601 (W).
30 Joubert, Contract, 222.
31 At 606 ff.
32 Shakinovsky v Lawson & Smulowitz 1904 TS 326; Farmers Co-operative Society (Reg) v Berry
1912 AD 343; Haynes v Kingwilliamstown Municipality 1951 (2) SA 371 (AD); R v Milne and
Erleigh (7) 1951 (1) SA 791 (AD).
33 See at 607–609.
34 Wessels, Contract, § 3139 ff; Joubert, Contract, 223. The remarks in Longhorn Group (Pty) Ltd
v The Fedics Group (Pty) Ltd 1995 (3) SA 836 (W) at 843C–D, that this type of relief is not
specific performance, are hard to explain or understand.
35 Setlogelo v Setlogelo 1914 AD 221 at 227; L T C Harms, “Interdict”, in LAWSA, vol 11, First
Reissue (1998) at 288. The requirement of irreparable harm as stated by Joubert, Contract, 223 is
not correct.
254 european contract law
facie void, thus placing the onus to prove reasonableness on the applicant,36
the position was fundamentally changed in the Magna Alloys case.37 The
onus is now on the party under restraint to prove that the restraint is
unreasonable.38 The other party is therefore entitled in principle to a strict
adherence of the contract.39
The focus in the restraint cases has interestingly shifted from the general
enquiries for the granting of an interdict to the issue of legality and reason-
40
ableness. In the Basson case Botha JA remarked:
The effect of it in practical terms is this: the covenantee seeking to enforce the
restraint need do no more than to invoke the provisions of the contract and prove
the breach; the covenantor seeking to avert enforcement is required to prove on a
preponderance of probability that in all the circumstances of the particular case it
will be unreasonable to enforce the restraint; if the Court is unable to make up its
mind on the point, the restraint will be enforced. The covenantor is burdened with
the onus because public policy requires that people should be bound by their
contractual undertakings. The covenantor is not so bound, however, if the
restraint is unreasonable, because public policy discountenances unreasonable
restrictions on people’s freedom of trade.
It would seem that the usual requirements for an interdict have simply
been subsumed in the four requirements set out in the Basson case:41 namely
(1) does the covenantee have an interest deserving of protection; (2) is that
interest being prejudiced; (3) if so, how does that interest weigh up against
the interest of the covenantor not to be economically inactive or unpro-
ductive; and (4) is there any other issue of public policy which requires the
restraint to be enforced or disallowed? If these questions are answered in
favour of the covenantee the restraint will be enforced. There is no reference
to the usual exclusions when considering the enforcement of claims for
specific performance as set out below.
In all other cases of claims for specific performance relating to non-
monetary obligations, it has been accepted that a party is in principle entitled
to an order for specific performance as the point of departure, but that there
36 Katz v Efthimiou 1948 (4) SA 603 (O); Durban Rickshas Ltd v Ball 1933 NPD 479 at 493; Rogaly
v Weingartz 1954 (3) SA 791 (D) at 792G; Cowan v Pomeroy 1952 (3) SA 645 (C) at 649; Arlyn
Butcheries (Pty) Ltd v Bosch 1966 (2) SA 308 (W) at 309H.
37 Magna Alloys and Research (SA) Pty Ltd v Ellis 1984 (4) SA 874 (A). See also Sunshine Records
(Pty) Ltd v Frohling 1990 (4) SA 782 (A); Basson v Chilwan 1993 (3) SA 742 (A) at 767E–I.
38 Magna Alloys and Research (SA) Pty Ltd v Ellis 1984 (4) SA 874 (A) at 893A–B, 898C–D; Basson
v Chilwan 1993 (3) SA 742 (A) at 768D–E; Christie, Contract, 422; Kerr, Contract, 211–212.
39 Basson v Chilwan 1993 (3) SA 742 (A).
40 At 776I–777B.
41 Basson v Chilwan 1993 (3) SA 742 (A) at 767G–H.
specific performance and special damages 255
are some limitations which may restrict that right.42 The principle was clearly
stated in the Berry case by Innes JA:43
Prima facie every party to a binding agreement who is ready to carry out his own
obligation under it has a right to demand from the other party, so far as it is
possible, a performance of his undertaking in terms of the contract. As remarked
by KOTZÉ, C.J., in Thompson v Pullinger, 1 O.R. at p. 301, “the right of a plaintiff
to a specific performance of a contract where the defendant is in a position to do
so is beyond all doubt”. It is true that Courts will exercise a discretion in
determining whether or not decrees of specific performance should be made.
They will not, of course, be issued where it is impossible for the defendant to
comply with them. And there are many cases in which justice between the parties
can be fully and conveniently done by an award of damages. But that is a different
thing from saying that a defendant who has broken his undertaking has the option
to purge his default by the payment of money. For in the words of Storey, Equity
Jurisprudence, sec. 717 (a), “it is against conscience that a party should have a
right of election whether he would perform his contract or only pay damages for
the breach of it”. The election is rather with the injured party, subject to the
discretion of the Court.
Courts will refuse to order specific performance outright in two cases, namely
where performance is impossible and where the estate of the debtor is in
sequestration.44 The rationale for the second instance is that the claim by the
creditor is simply a personal right or obligation and therefore it cannot jump
the queue in a sequestration by obtaining an order for specific performance.
The creditor must make his claim against the insolvent estate along with all
45
other concurrent creditors.
The rationale for the first exception is quite clearly the principle of lex non
cogit ad impossibilia courts will not order something which is impossible to
perform, even if such impossibility is subjective, i.e. if it is impossible for the
46
specific creditor to perform, but not impossible in general. Thus, where a
party has sold the same object to two different parties and delivered it to the
42 Joubert, Contract, 223–224.
43 Farmers Co-operative Society (Reg) v Berry 1912 AD 343 at 350. See also Norden v Rennie
(1879) Buch 155; Cohen v Shires, McHattie and King (1882) 1 SAR 41; Van der Westhuizen v
Velenski (1898) 14 SC 237; Fick v Woolcott & Ohlssons’s Cape Breweries 1911 AD 214; Shill v
Milner 1937 AD 101; Haynes v Kingwilliamstown Municipality 1951 (2) SA 371 (AD) at 378G;
Benson v SA Mutual Life Assurance Society 1986 (1) SA 776 (A) at 782F–783C; Wessels,
Contract, § 3122; De Wet & Van Wyk, Kontraktereg, 189; Joubert, Contract, 223; Christie,
Contract, 607–608.
44 Ward v Barrett NO 1963 (2) SA 546 (A) at 552–553; Rampathy v Krumm 1978 (4) SA 935 (D) at
941; Joubert, Contract, 224.
45 Ward v Barrett NO 1963 (2) SA 546 (A) at 552–553; Rampathy v Krumm 1978 (4) SA 935 (D) at 941.
46 Shakinovsky v Lawson & Smulowitz 1904 TS 326; Wheeldon v Moldenhauer 1910 EDL 97 at 99;
Rissik v Pretoria Municipal Council 1907 TS 1024; Fick v Woolcott & Ohlsson’s Cape Breweries
Ltd 1911 AD 214; Jacobsz v Fall 1981 (2) SA 863 (C) at 873; Pretoria East Builders CC v Basson
2004 (6) SA 15 (SCA).
256 european contract law
second buyer, courts will not order specific performance unless the buyer
knew of the first sale.47 However, where delivery has not yet taken place,
courts will interdict the seller from delivering to the second buyer and will
order specific performance in favour of the first buyer according to the
principle of qui prior est in tempore potior est in iure unless the second buyer
can show a balance of equities in his favour.48 Where a res aliena has been
sold a court will not order specific performance unless the third party had
49
agreed to such sale because it would be a futile order.
It has been recognised from a very early point that although the creditor is
in principle entitled to specific performance, such remedy will not neces-
50
sarily be granted on demand and that it is subject to a judicial discretion.
Although not always explicitly stated in these early cases, it would seem that
the necessity and introduction of such a discretion was heavily influenced by
51
the provisions of English law.
From the outset the Appellate Division made it clear that the discretion to
refuse specific performance was a general judicial discretion and not limited
to a specified numerus clausus of instances. In the Berry case Innes J explained
the discretion as follows:52
It is, however, equally settled law with us that, although the Court will as far as
possible give effect to a plaintiff’s choice to claim specific performance, it has a
discretion in a fitting case to refuse to decree specific performance and leave the
plaintiff to claim and prove his id quod interest. The discretion which a Court
enjoys although it must be exercised judicially is not confined to specific types of
cases, nor is it circumscribed by rigid rules. Each case must be judged in the light
of its own circumstances.
47 Shakinovsky v Lawson & Smulowitz 1904 TS 326; Wheeldon v Moldenhauer 1910 EDL 97 at 99;
Christie, Contract, 609–610.
48 Pienaar v Van Lill 1928 CPD 299; Campbell v First Consolidated Holdings (Pty) Ltd 1977 (3) SA
924 (W) at 928–929; Miller v Spamer 1948 (3) SA 772 (C); Le Roux v Odendaal 1954 (4) SA 432
(N); Barnhoorn v Duvenhage 1964 (2) SA 486 (A) at 494H–495A; Christie, Contract, 610.
49 Pretoria East Builders CC v Basson 2004 (6) SA 15 (SCA) at 21.
50 Even De Wet, who was generally very much opposed to the influences of English law, conceded
this point, without, however, referring to English law – see De Wet & Van Wyk, Kontraktereg, 189.
51 See, e.g., Thompson v Pullinger (1894) 1 OR 298; Manesewitz v Oosthuizen 1914 CPD 328; Re
Coronation Syndicate 1903 TH 254; R v Milne and Erleigh (7) 1951 (1) SA 791 (AD) at 873;
Wessels, Contract, §§ 3113, 3118, 3119, 136, 3137. See also De Wet & Van Wyk, Kontraktereg,
190; Cockrell, in Zimmermann & Visser, Southern Cross, 328–330.
52 Farmers’ Co-Operative Society (Reg) v Berry 1912 AD 343 at 350. This dictum was confirmed in
Haynes v Kingwilliamstown Municipality 1951 (2) SA 371 (AD) at 378G; Benson v SA Mutual
Life Assurance Society 1986 (1) SA 776 (A) at 782F–783C.
53 Tamarillo (Pty) Ltd v BN Aitken (Pty) Ltd 1982 (1) SA 398 (A) at 442B–443F.
specific performance and special damages 257
54 Christie, Contract, 611–615; Kerr, Contract, 680–682; Wessels, Contract, §§ 3117–3121; Joubert,
Contract, 224–227.
55 See Wessels, Contract, § 3136.
56 Farmers’ Co-Operative Society (Reg) v Berry 1912 AD 343 at 351; Haynes v Kingwilliamstown
Municipality 1951 (2) SA 371 (AD) at 378.
57 Benson v SA Mutual Life Assurance Society 1986 (1) SA 776 (A).
58 At 783G–784C.
59 Wessels, Contract, § 3137.
60 Thompson v Pullinger (1894) 1 OR 298 at 301; R v Milne and Erleigh (7) 1951 (1) SA 791 (A) at
873.
61 At 784B–C.
62 Haynes v Kingwilliamstown Municipality 1951 (2) SA 371 (AD) at 378. See also ISEP Structural
Engineering and Plating (Pty) Ltd v Inland Exploration Co (Pty) Ltd 1981 (4) SA 1 (A); Benson v
SA Mutual Life Assurance Society 1986 (1) SA 776 (A).
63 At 378H–379A.
258 european contract law
original club (which he had left in order to coach another club in the same
soccer league). The club could not be denied its ordinary remedy simply
because of the possibility that the coach might no longer perform properly,
which was a factual issue that might, or might not, arise only in the future.71
In terms of section 193 of the Labour Relations Act 66 of 1995 and section
77A(e) of the Basic Conditions of Employment Act, the Labour Court has
the power to make an order of specific performance in relation to contracts of
employment. These provisions further strengthen the direction the courts
have taken since the Stag Packings case.
The third type of case where courts have refused to order specific
performance deals with the enforcement of so-called imprecise obligations.
As Christie points out, there is no sharp dividing line between issues raised by
72
these cases and the enforcement of employment cases. It is on this ground
that specific performance of contracts to form syndicates, partnerships or
companies, to appoint a director, or to repair or insure buildings, has been
73
refused. It would seem that the precedents relied on consist wholly of older
cases heavily influenced by the position and reasoning of English law, and
that the trend in later cases is to enforce contracts rather than rely on the
grounds of imprecision or difficulty in enforcement.74
The decision and reasoning in Ranch International Pipelines (Transvaal)
(Pty) Ltd v LMG Construction (City (Pty) Ltd75 are certainly indicative of
this trend.76 The court pointed out that the granting of the order did not
replace the contract and therefore did not introduce any new difficulties in
deciding whether work had been properly performed. It must be seriously
doubted whether imprecision or difficulty of enforcement will in future be
regarded as sufficient ground for refusing this remedy.
Most recently the Supreme Court of Appeal has confirmed this trend in
77
Southernport Developments (Pty) Ltd v Transnet Ltd. The parties had
concluded a lease agreement which, upon the fulfilment of a particular
71 At 86B–E.
72 Christie, Contract at 615.
73 See Christie, Contract, 615; Wessels, Contract, §§ 3117–3118; De Wet & Van Wyk, Kontraktereg,
190; Kerr, Contract, 680–681.
74 Ranch International Pipelines (Transvaal) (Pty) Ltd v LMG Construction (City (Pty) Ltd 1984 (3)
SA 861 (W) at 880G–881F; Southernport Developments (Pty) Ltd v Transnet Ltd 2005 (2) SA 202
(SCA); Christie, Contract, 615.
75 1984 (3) SA 861 (W) at 880G-881F.
76 See also ISEP Structural Engineering and Plating (Pty) Ltd v Inland Exploration Co (Pty) Ltd
1981 (4) SA 1 (A) at 5B; Santos Professional Football Club (Pty) Ltd v Igesund 2003 (5) SA 73 (C);
Brisley v Drotsky 2002 (4) SA 1 (SCA) at 35.
77 2005 (2) SA 202 (SCA).
260 european contract law
78 Paras [1]–[4].
79 Paras [17], [18].
80 MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, para 6.2; McBryde, Contract, para 23–05.
81 McBryde, Contract, para 23–05.
82 McBryde, Contract, para 23–05.
specific performance and special damages 261
This dictum seems to suggest that the discretion is rather limited, even to the
extent that it has been remarked that considerations of what is equitable or
not are quite irrelevant.93 The rule has been refined and elaborated, however,
to deal with specific situations when the remedy will be refused, without
limiting the generality of the discretion.94 The remedy may be refused:
91 Grahame v Magistrates of Kirkcaldy (1882) 9 R (HL) 91; MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, para
6.6.
92 (1882) 9 R (HL) 91.
93 Salaried Staff London Loan Co Ltd v Swears and Wells Ltd 1985 SC 189.
94 MacQueen & Macgregor (1999) 3 Edinburgh LR 239 at 240.
95 Grahame v Magistrates of Kirkcaldy (1882) 9 R (HL) 91; MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, para
6.6; McBryde, Contract, para 23-18; Walker, Contract, para 33.21.
96 MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, para 6.6; McBryde, Contract, para 23-22; Walker, Contract,
para 33.21.
97 MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, para 6.6; McBryde, Contract, para 23-21; Walker, Contract,
para 33.21.
98 MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, para 6.6; McBryde, Contract, para 23-20; Walker, Contract,
para 33.21. There are also statutory remedies which influence this approach, entitling employees
to be reinstated in certain circumstances. See the Employment Rights Act 1996 in terms of which
an employment tribunal has the power to make an order for reinstatement where an employee
has been unjustifiably dismissed.
specific performance and special damages 263
applied.133 The exception is very specific and does not grant a general remedy
protecting the debtor against undue hardship, although there may be some
overlap.
PECL strictly excludes the possibility of requiring specific performance
for the provision of services or work of a personal nature.134 This is based on
three considerations, namely the severe interference with the personal
liberty of the debtor, the fact that work under compulsion may often be
rendered unsatisfactorily, and the difficulty for a court in controlling proper
135
enforcement of its order. Enforcement of restraints of trade may also fall
foul of this exception if it would result in an indirect enforcement of the
136
personal work or services.
Exception (d) requires the aggrieved party to make a substitute trans-
action where it can reasonably be done. This can place the aggrieved party in
an invidious position because of the legal uncertainty involved in the term
“reasonably”, the application of which will depend very much on the specific
circumstances of the case. The position may be somewhat alleviated if the
suggestion in the Comments is followed that the choice made by the
aggrieved party affords prima facie proof that a substitute transaction would
not be reasonable; this would place the onus on the defaulting party to show
that the aggrieved party could obtain performance from other sources
without any prejudice.137
There is a final limitation under Article 9:102(3) PECL, namely that the
claim for specific performance must be made within a reasonable time after
the creditor ought to have become aware of the non-performance. Once
again the onus is on the non-performing party to show that an unreasonably
long period has elapsed and, possibly in view of the objective of this
exception, that it will suffer prejudice as a result of that.
Where the exception applies, the aggrieved party has to resort to other
138
remedies at its disposal under PECL. Usually this will be a claim for damages.
performance, but that there are certain instances where it will not be
granted. All three systems, it seems, have been influenced to some extent by
English law. It is, however, in these exceptions that we find a clear distinction,
in that the South African and Scots law grant a general judicial discretion to
refuse specific performance whereas the PECL exceptions operate strictly:
this means that on the one hand a court has no discretion to refuse specific
performance where the exceptions are not present, while on the other hand
it has no discretion to grant specific performance where the requirements of
the exceptions have been met. In this sense South African and Scots law
represent a more flexible approach than PECL, although Articles 9:101(2)
and 102(2)(b) and (d) PECL afford some flexibility in the use of the terms
“reasonable”, “unreasonable” and “reasonably”.
In clearly distinguishing between monetary obligations and non-monetary-
obligations, the PECL approach provides a more nuanced and legal solution
which is, at the same time, more conducive to legal certainty, than the South
African position, which is to treat both types of obligations in the same
manner and to subject them to the same general judicial discretion of undue
hardship. This approach comes closer to the Scots approach, where, however,
it appears to be based on different reasons.139 The South African decision in SA
Harness Works,140 in turn, comes close to establishing a position in respect of
the enforcement of payments similar to that under Article 9:101(2)(b) PECL.
So far as non-monetary obligations are concerned, there is a considerable
difference between PECL and the South African approach. PECL provides
for very specific circumstances where the remedy will be refused, whereas
South African law uses a broadly defined judicial discretion which applies in
all cases. Although certain types of exceptions or factual situations have been
identified where the discretion will be applied, these do not form a numerus
clausus. The position is similar in Scots law.
All three systems agree that performance will not be enforced where it is
impossible to do so, whether such impossibility is objective or subjective. The
South African exception with regard to the use of the remedy in cases of
insolvency is not directly dealt with in PECL, although it can possibly be seen
as a performance that would be unlawful if the applicable insolvency
provisions forbid or restrict such performance.
PECL exception (b) is much more limited in its scope than the South
African limitation of undue hardship, although there will probably be quite a
139 In Scots law the distinction is important due to the sanction of imprisonment following non-
compliance with a decree for specific implement.
140 SA Harness Works v SA Publishers (Pty) Ltd 1915 CPD 43.
specific performance and special damages 269
more restricted (especially exception (d)), and in some areas much more
restrictive, (especially (c)), than South African law. The strictness of the
exceptions is more closely akin to the position in Scots law. PECL does,
however, offer a limitation in (d) which is worthy of consideration in South
African law.
That decision has also been influential in South African law,150 Scots law151
152
and the drafting of PECL.
146 Joubert, Contract, 251; Wessels, Contract, § 3239; Christie, Contract, 637; MacQueen &
Thomson, Contract, paras 6.31–6.38; Article 9:503 PECL, Notes 1–3.
147 Zimmermann, Obligations, 826–828.
148 (1854) 9 Ex 341 at 354.
149 At 351.
150 See Holmdene Brickworks (Pty) Ltd v Roberts Construction Co Ltd 1977 (3) SA 670 (A) at 687.
151 MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, para 6.33; McBryde, Contract, para 22-60; Walker, Contract,
para 33.29.
152 See Article 9:503 PECL, Note 1.
specific performance and special damages 271
necessarily reflect the objective value of the object of the performance. The
id quod interest awarded to the plaintiff was based on subjective factors and
constituted a flexible and equitable approach.153
By the time of Justinian this individualised method of assessing loss was
extended to all cases. Justinian was not happy with the intricacies of the case
law and introduced the lex Sancimus in terms of which the claim was limited
154
to double the amount of the value. This crude limitation of the liability of
the defaulting party which baffled generations of jurists, was to remain
155
influential well into the nineteenth century.
The French writer Molinaeus in 1574 seems to have been the first com-
156
mentator who tried to explain the in duplum rule in terms of foreseeability.
Pothier divorced this idea of foreseeability from the original provision in
Codex 7.47.1 and explained it purely on the basis of reason and natural equity.
It was deemed that the debtor would not have subjected himself to risks beyond
157
those that were foreseeable at the time of the conclusion of the contract.
Pothier’s views were enthusiastically received by nineteenth-century
English courts and provided the basis for the formulation of the rule in
Hadley v Baxendale quoted above. It also forms the basis for the approach
initially followed by South African courts.158
For this statement the court relied on passages of Voet, Domat and, above all,
Pothier.160 From Pothier’s exposition it is clear that not only damages in the
actual contemplation of the parties come into play, but also those damages
that were foreseeable at the time of entering into the contract.
In Victoria Falls & Transvaal Power Co Ltd v Consolidated Langlaagte
Mines Ltd161 Innes CJ stated that although the non-defaulting party is
entitled to full compensation for the damages, the reinstatement cannot be
complete for it would be “inequitable and unfair to make the defaulter liable
for special consequences which could not have been in his contemplation
when he entered into the contract”. He then went on to explain that the legal
position in Holland and England is substantially the same, relying on the
162
Emslie case, Voet, Pothier and Hadley v Baxendale. This represented a
simple restatement of the foreseeability test of Pothier, or the contemplation
163
principle, as it has become known subsequently.
The rule in Hadley v Baxendale is usually said to comprise two parts,
namely a provision for liability for damages arising naturally from the breach,
i.e. the “general” or “intrinsic damages”, and a provision for liability for “special”
164
or “extrinsic damages”. According to this division a party is always liable for
general damages, whereas it is only liable for special damages where such
damages may “reasonably be supposed to have been in the contemplation of
both parties”.165
This fairly concise and clear statement of the law, which is in accordance
with the position favoured by Pothier and English law, was thrown into a state
of confusion, still enduring in South African law, by the decision in Lavery &
166
Co Ltd v Jungheinrich. Curlewis JA started off by restating the con-
templation principle, namely that special damages must have been in the
contemplation of the parties and that this can be inferred from either the sub-
ject matter, the contract, or the knowledge of both parties of special circum-
167
stances. He then, however, went on to require that the contract should
have been entered into on the basis of the parties’ knowledge of the special
circumstances. This might have been an ambiguous explanation of the con-
templation principle, but Wessels JA added his own gloss to this explanation
by requiring that the knowledge of the special circumstances must be “so far
168 Shatz Investments v Kalovyrnas 1976 (2) SA 545 (A) at 552F; Holmdene Brickworks (Pty) Ltd
v Roberts Construction Co Ltd 1977 (3) SA 670 (A) at 687; Christie, Contract, 640.
169 1976 (2) SA 545 (A) at 551–552; Holmdene Brickworks (Pty) Ltd v Roberts Construction Co Ltd
1977 (3) SA 670 (A) at 688.
170 Referring to Victoria Laundry (Windsor) Ltd. v Newman Industries Ltd [1949] 2 KB 528 (CA)
and Koufos v C Czarnikow Ltd, The Heron II [1969] 1 AC 350. See also Thoroughbred Breeders’
Association v Price Waterhouse 2001 (4) SA 551 (SCA) para [51] at 582.
171 1977 (3) SA 670 (A) at 687.
172 2001 (4) SA 551 (SCA).
173 Para [52] at 582–583.
274 european contract law
breach”.174 The issue is whether “probable” has the meaning of “more likely
to occur than not”, or whether it has a more limited meaning.
These questions have been dealt with in a number of English cases.175 In
The Heron II case,176 the House of Lords rejected the notion that the test was
reasonable foreseeability if it meant the same low threshold of probability as
that required in tort law.177 Lord Reid ascribed the meaning of “not unlikely
178
to occur” to the word. This meant “a degree of probability considerably less
than an even chance but nevertheless not very unusual and easily foresee-
179 180
able”. Lord Upjohn used the terms “a real danger” and “a serious
181 182
possibility” to describe the probabilities, terms earlier used in the Monarch
183
Steamship Co Ltd case. The result of The Heron II is that a higher degree
of probability is required to satisfy the test of remoteness in contract than in
184
tort law. The difficulty of applying the test is apparent from subsequent
185
cases.
Nienaber JA appears to favour a more moderate approach to this question.
186
Foreseeability or remoteness, according to him, does not mean:
… that the type of event or circumstance causing the loss will in all probability
occur but minimally that its occurrence is not improbable and would tend to
follow upon the breach as a matter of course.
The approach requires a “realistic possibility” that harm may occur, i.e. a test
at the lower end of the scale of probabilities, rather than a “likelihood”, i.e. a
test at the upper end of the scale of probabilities.
174 Relying inter alia on the exposition of Kerr, Contract, 5th edn (1998), 700–701.
175 Victoria Laundry (Windsor) Ltd v Newman Industries Ltd [1949] 2 KB 528 (CA); Koufos v C
Czarnikow Ltd [1969] AC 350; Balfour Beatty Construction (Scotland) Ltd v Scottish Power plc
1994 SC (HL) 20. See generally H McGregor, McGregor on Damages, 17th edn (2003), paras
248–274; M P Furmston, Cheshire, Fifoot and Furmston’s Law of Contract, 13th edn (1996),
614–617; Treitel, Contract, 965–968.
176 Koufos v C Czarnikow Ltd, The Heron II [1969] 1 AC 350.
177 At 385, 411, 425.
178 At 383A.
179 At 397.
180 At 425.
181 At 414–415; The Pagase [1981] 1 Lloyd’s Rep 175 at 182; Malik v BCCI [1998] AC 20 at 37.
182 At 414–415, 425.
183 A/B Karlshamns Oljefabriker v Monarch Steamship Co Ltd [1949] AC 196; 1949 SC (HL) 1.
184 Treitel, Contract, 967.
185 See the discussion of the decision in H Parsons (Livestock) Ltd v Uttley Ingham & Co Ltd
[1978] QB 791 by Treitel, Contract, 967–968.
186 Thoroughbred Breeders’ Association v Price Waterhouse 2001 (4) SA 551 (SCA) at 581F.
specific performance and special damages 275
187 MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, para 6.31; McBryde, Contract, para 22-16 ff; Walker,
Contract, para 33.26.
188 MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, para 6.33; McBryde, Contract, paras 22-01–22-03; Walker,
Contract, para 33.21.
189 (1854) 9 Ex 341.
190 McBryde, Contract, para 22-01.
191 MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, para 6.33; McBryde, Contract, para 22-03; and 22-60.
192 (1854) 9 Ex 341.
193 [1949] 2 KB 528.
194 1949 SC (HL) 1.
195 [1969] 1 AC 350.
196 1994 SC (HL) 20.
197 MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, para 6.34.
198 MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, para 6.34.
199 McBryde, Contract, para 22-64.
276 european contract law
MacQueen and Thomson indicate that there was a definite trend in Scots law
to expand liability by relaxing the standard of contemplation, but that the
trend was somewhat reversed in the Balfour Beatty case by the House of
Lords.201 In that case a contractor was constructing a concrete aqueduct
which necessitated a process of continuous pouring of concrete. There was a
power failure constituting a breach of contract on the part of the power
company which resulted in a substantial part of the aqueduct having to be
demolished and rebuilt. The court held that the damages were too remote,
relying on the first leg of the Hadley v Baxendale test in that the damage did
not arise in the ordinary course of events and was therefore too remote. It
had also not been in the contemplation of the parties and the power company
did not have any special knowledge about the business of the contractor.
202
Cosar Ltd v UPS Ltd provides an interesting illustration of an instance
where a contracting party was held to have had knowledge of special
circumstances. The delivery company failed to deliver tender documentation
in time with the result that the contractor’s tender was not considered during
the tender process. It was held that the information supplied to the courier
was sufficient to provide it with the necessary knowledge that the loss of the
opportunity to tender could lead to a loss of the contract, provided that that
knowledge extended to the likelihood of the tender being successful.203
200 In H Parsons (Livestock)Ltd v Uttley Ingham & Co Ltd [1978] QB 791 at 802.
201 MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, para 6.36; McBryde, Contract, para 22-68.
202 1999 SLT 259.
203 See MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, para 6.38.
204 Zimmermann (2002) 6 Edinburgh LR 271 at 288.
205 PECL, vol 1, 442.
206 Thoroughbred Breeders’ Association v Price Waterhouse 2001 (4) SA 551 (SCA) at 582F.
specific performance and special damages 277
PECL also recognises that the liability for damages cannot be unrestricted.
Article 9:503 PECL therefore formulates a general test of foreseeability
excluding the liability for damages that are too remote. The formulation of
Article 9:502 PECL accords with the general principle recognised in many
legal systems that the aggrieved party is entitled to its fulfilment (or
expectation or performance) interest. Whether a party chooses to enforce the
contract by specific performance, or to terminate it where there has been a
fundamental non-performance in terms of Article 8:103 PECL, the
aggrieved party can claim full damages, including a loss of profit, in order to
be placed, financially, in a position as close as possible to the one if the
contract had been properly performed. This is only limited by the provisions
of foreseeability contained in Article 9:503 PECL.
The first important aspect to note in Article 9:503 PECL is that it focuses
only on what the non-performing party actually foresaw or could have foreseen.
It is therefore not necessary to ask whether the aggrieved party could have
foreseen such loss. That question is irrelevant, and quite rightly so. The test is
an objective one to protect the defaulting party from too wide a liability. It is
therefore reasonable to restrict its liability to what a party in its position could
reasonably have foreseen at the time of the conclusion of the contract.
The limitation on liability apparently does not operate in favour of the
defaulting party where the breach of contract was intentional or grossly
negligent. In these instances the only limitation would be normal factual
causation, i.e. the defaulting party will be liable for all damages caused by its
205
default, even those which would ordinarily be regarded as too remote.
The reference to “as the likely result” of the breach at first blush seems to
require a high degree of probability that such loss would result if regard is
had to the discussion of the English law and The Heron II above. “Likely
result” can either have the meaning of “a reasonable possibility” or “serious
possibility” at the lower end of the scale of probabilities, or “more likely to
occur than not” at the higher end of the scale of probabilities. In the Notes to
Article 9:503 PECL the similarity of this provision with the rule in Hadley v
Baxendale is discussed without reference to the subsequent difficulties in
interpreting the word “probable” in English law.
Finally the foreseeability must be judged as at the time of the conclusion
of the contract and not at the time of the breach. This is in line with the
principle in many legal systems that a party should only be liable for the risks
it actually undertook or should have foreseen at the time of contracting.
278 european contract law
D. CONCLUSION
It is clear that mixed legal systems can often draw upon the collective wisdom
and divergent approaches contained in different legal systems to formulate
their own approaches which may provide solutions that are superior, in the
sense of being more developed and nuanced. However, the hybrid character
or compromise nature of the solution may sometimes also lead to inferior
solutions in the sense that they are too restrictive or limiting; or it may even
lead to outright bad results. The rules relating to specific performance and
special damages in PECL and South African law provide examples for both
possibilities.
The provisions of PECL in respect of specific performance are probably
more limiting than necessary when compared to South African and Scots law.
They do, however, contain some solutions such as that in respect of substitute
transactions which are worthy of consideration in both legal systems.
The acceptance of the convention principle in South African law,
apparently under the influence of earlier English law, is simply bad law.
Fortunately it has been universally recognised that it should be abandoned.
The provisions of PECL may prove helpful in reformulating this area of
South African law.
11 Termination for Breach
of Contract
Tjakie Naudé
A. INTRODUCTION
B. GROUNDS FOR TERMINATION
(1) Fundamental or material breach
(a) Unitary concept of non-performance
(b) More detailed definition of fundamental breach
(2) Ultimatum procedure in the case of delay
(3) Anticipatory breach
(4) Termination for failure to give adequate assurance of performance
C. EFFECT OF TENDER TO CURE ON REMEDY OF
TERMINATION
(1) PECL
(2) Scots law
(3) South African law
(4) Conclusion
D. CONSEQUENCES OF TERMINATION
(1) Mutual restitution not the point of departure under PECL
(2) Article 9:306 PECL
(3) Articles 9:307 and 9:308 PECL
(4) Article 9:309 PECL
(a) Comparison with South African law
(b) Comparison with Scots law
(c) Evaluation
(5) Calls for unified winding-up regime
E. CONCLUSION
280
termination for breach of contract 281
A. INTRODUCTION
1
The remedy of termination for breach of contract was introduced into Scots
2
and South African law under the influence especially of English law. In
neither Roman nor Roman-Dutch law was there a generalised remedy of
termination for breach of contract, as it is known to modern law.3 Scots and
South African law do not, however, mirror English law on all aspects of
termination. In a number of instances, the courts have refused indiscrimin-
ately to take over all of English law on the subject.4
It has been said that the rules on termination upon non-performance of
PECL also follow the Common Law rather closely in a number of respects.5
Similarities between PECL and Scots and South African law on termination
are therefore to be expected.
One characteristic of the remedy of termination for non-performance
under PECL which is not shared with the Common Law, is that the rules on
6
termination apply equally to breach of contract and to excused non-
performance (excused as a result of an impediment beyond the debtor’s
control). In Scotland and South Africa, as in the Common Law, termination
due to excused supervening impossibility of performance is regarded as a
doctrinally distinct issue meriting separate treatment from termination as a
7
remedy for breach of contract. To keep this chapter within manageable
bounds, only termination as a remedy for breach of contract, and only the
following aspects thereof, will be considered:
1 “Rescission” is the preferred term in Scotland, and “cancellation” in South Africa. I prefer the
term “termination” used also by PECL.
2 For South African law, see A Cockrell, “Breach of contract”, in Zimmermann & Visser, Southern
Cross, 303 at 308, 313, 314, 317, 321. The writings of Pothier also played a role in South Africa (J
R Harker, “The nature and scope of rescission as a remedy for breach of contract in American and
South African law” 1980 Acta Juridica 61 at 70). For Scots law, see W W McBryde, “The Scots law
of breach of contract: a mixed system in operation” (2002) 6 Edinburgh LR 5 at 11; D Johnston,
“Breach of contract”, in Reid & Zimmermann, History, vol 2, 175; McBryde, Contract, 509. H L
MacQueen, “Scots and English law: the case of contract” (2001) 54 CLP 205 notes that the
principle of mutuality was also decisive.
3 Stewart Wrightson (Pty) Ltd v Thorpe 1977 (2) SA 943 (A) (henceforth Stewart Wrightson) at
953B; Zimmermann, Obligations, 800 ff; Harker, 1980 Acta Juridica 61 at 69; Cockrell, in
Zimmermann & Visser, Southern Cross at 320.
4 Zimmermann & Visser, Southern Cross at 322. For example, the distinction between conditions
and warranties and the doctrine of total failure of consideration do not form part of South African
and Scots law.
5 H Beale, A Hartkamp, H Kötz & D Tallon, Cases, Materials and Text on Contract Law (2002),
756.
6 In the sense of non-justified failure or refusal to perform in terms of the contract.
7 See, e.g, Walker, Contract; McBryde, Contract; MacQueen & Thomson, Contract; Gloag,
Contract; Christie, Contract; Kerr, Contract; and Van der Merwe et al, Contract, who discuss
these two issues in separate chapters.
282 european contract law
1. grounds for termination (in other words, when the remedy is available);
2. effect, on the availability of the remedy, of a tender to cure the breach;
and
3. consequences of termination.
several categories of breach, each with its own test for when termination is
allowed.13
Closer examination of South African law reveals, however, that the notion
of materiality is important throughout. Thus, positive malperformance
(defective performance) justifies termination when the breach is material.14
Prevention of performance also only allows the debtor to terminate the
15
contract, if it amounts to a material breach. Apart from the case where the
entire contract is repudiated, only the repudiation of a “material aspect” or
16
“material term” allows an election to terminate. It is not specifically stated
that mora or delay justifies termination if it amounts to a material breach.
Instead, a right to terminate exists (apart from the ultimatum procedure)
17
only where “time is of the essence under the contract”. However, this may
just be another way of saying that the delay constitutes a material breach.
It must also be noted that some writers on Scots law have found it useful to
distinguish between different forms of breach, such as delay, defective per-
formance, impossibility of performance and repudiation (conduct demon-
strating an unequivocal intention no longer to be bound), when discussing
the instances when termination will be permitted.18 In addition, the English
law criterion of time being of the essence of the contract is applied to delay
only,19 but that is simply a manner of saying that the delay has to be material.
Textbook writers also generally treat anticipatory breach or repudiation
separately.20
13 The history of this development is sketched by Cockrell, in Zimmermann & Visser, Southern
Cross, 304–319. See also, e.g, Van der Merwe et al, Contract, ch 10; Lubbe & Murray, Contract,
ch 10.
14 De Wet & Van Wyk, Kontraktereg, 179; Van der Merwe et al, Contract, 328; Lubbe & Murray,
Contract, 491–492.
15 Grobbelaar v Bosch 1964 (3) SA 687 (E) at 691; Holgate v Minister of Justice 1995 (1) SA 921 (E)
at 937A–B; Lubbe & Murray, Contract, 483.
16 Culverwell v Brown 1990 (1) SA 7 (A); Tamarillo (Pty) Ltd v BN Aitken (Pty) Ltd 1982 (1) SA 398
(A).
17 See, e.g., Van der Merwe et al, Contract, 319; Joubert, Contract, 237 and cases there cited.
18 MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, 206 ff; Gloag, Contract, 603 ff; Walker, Contract, 523–524; cf
Edinburgh Grain Ltd v Marshall Food Group Ltd 1999 SLT 15.
19 Walker, Contract, 523; Gloag, Contract, 615; McBryde (1996) 1 Edinburgh LR 43 at 65; Ahmed
v Akhtar 1997 SLT 218.
20 McBryde, Contract, 485 ff; MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, 206.
284 european contract law
21 T Naudé & G Lubbe, “Cancellation for ‘material’ or ‘fundamental’ breach: a comparative analysis
of South African law, the UN Convention on Contracts for the International Sale of Goods
(CISG) and the UNIDROIT Principles of International Commercial Contracts” (2001) 12
Stellenbosch LR 357 at 373; Cockrell, in Zimmermann & Visser, Southern Cross, 313; cf Harker,
1980 Acta Juridica 61 at 79.
22 Scottish Law Commission Discussion Paper on Remedies for Breach of Contract (Scot Law Com
DP No 109, 1999) (henceforth Scot Law Com DP No 109 (1999)), 9; Wade v Waldon 1909 SC
571 at 576; Gloag, Contract, 602; Oatarian Properties (Pty) Ltd v Maroun 1973 (3) SA 779 (A) at
784G; Elgin Brown & Hamer (Pty) Ltd v Industrial Machinery Suppliers (Pty) Ltd 1993 (3) SA
424 (A) at 430I–J.
23 Article 8:103 PECL.
24 See note 7 above.
25 For details, see Naudé & Lubbe (2001) 12 Stellenbosch LR 357 at 382–385.
26 See, for example, Macari v Celtic Football and Athletic Co Ltd 1999 SC 628 at 635–636; Ghaznavi
v BP Oil (UK) Ltd 1991 SLT 924 at 928, 931. The Scottish Law Commission has also said that the
modern tendency is to focus on the materiality of the breach rather than simply on the term
breached (Scot Law Com DP No 109 (1999), para 2.9).
27 1949 (3) SA 611 (A).
termination for breach of contract 285
One lesson that Scots and South African law can therefore learn from
PECL is to formulate more explicitly the factors that courts regard as
relevant to establish the materiality of breach. PECL gives the courts some
leeway to take account of the particular circumstances of the case, but it also
provides guidance on the aspects to be considered, enabling parties properly
to prepare for litigation on the materiality of the breach.28 A failure to take
account of all possibly relevant considerations may render a decision on the
29
materiality of a breach less persuasive.
In this regard, the approach adopted in the UNIDROIT PICC is perhaps
closer to South African practice than that of PECL. PICC simply provides
that a material breach justifies termination, but then adds an open-ended list
of factors to be considered in order to establish whether a breach is
30
material. The three tests listed in PECL are part of this list, but another
factor is added, namely whether the non-performing party will suffer
disproportionate loss as a result of preparation or performance if the contract
is terminated. It appears that PICC, albeit not expressly, grants courts an
equitable discretion to decide whether termination is justified. That the
court should have an equitable discretion to decide whether termination is
possible has been accepted in two South African decisions of the Supreme
Court of Appeal on positive malperformance, i.e. Spies v Lombard31 and
Singh v McCarthy Retail Ltd (t/a McIntosh Motors).32 The Singh decision
speaks of a “value judgment” to be exercised and enjoins the court to consider
33
the competing interests of both parties in order to treat them fairly.
Ultimately the test laid down in the Singh case is whether the breach is “so
serious that it is fair to allow the innocent party to cancel the contract and
34
undo all its consequences’.
The difference in approach between PECL, with its numerus clausus of
three alternative instances of material breach, and PICC is not enormous.
The approach of PICC appears preferable as it enjoins the court to have
regard to all relevant circumstances, including the interests of the party
breaking the contract, and the seriousness of the breach, instead of focusing
28 For example, counsel for the aggrieved party in Singh v McCarthy Retail Ltd (t/a McIntosh
Motors) 2000 (4) SA 796 (SCA) only addressed the court on the materiality of the term breached,
whereas the court also considered the consequences of the breach.
29 See Naudé & Lubbe (2001) 12 Stellenbosch LR 357 at 389 for an example from the case law.
30 Article 7.3.1 PICC.
31 1950 (3) SA 469 (A).
32 2000 (4) SA 796 (SCA).
33 At 804F–G.
34 At 804G–H. See also Ankon CC v Tadkor Properties (Pty) Ltd 1991 (3) SA 119 (C) at 123A.
286 european contract law
the court’s attention on only any one of three tests. That termination takes
place extra-judicially is not an obstacle to the view that a discretion is
involved. The decision by the aggrieved party that the breach is serious
enough to warrant termination is explicitly rather than merely implicitly
subjected to a judicial discretion under PICC.35 An objection that the PECL
approach brings more certainty than a judicial discretion36 can be met by the
argument that a certain degree of vagueness is unavoidable in this area. As
Treitel has stated, “the delicate balancing of interests that is required in this
area is pre-eminently a matter for judicial discretion, and not one that can be
37
determined in advance by fixed rules.” What should be avoided is an
unfettered judicial discretion, where the factors which the courts should and
38
do take into account are not formulated clearly.
The acknowledgment by the drafters of PECL that a trivial breach should
39
not warrant termination even where strict compliance is of the essence, means
that the detriment caused to the aggrieved party should in any event be taken
into account in all cases, except, it is submitted, where the contract itself
provides for a right to terminate upon breach. Thus the test in PICC more
correctly reflects the reality that courts should consider the detriment caused
in addition to whether strict compliance is of the essence of the contract.
The recognition of an equitable discretion to allow termination can also be
extended to breach in the form of prevention of performance and mora
(delay).40 Or, at the least, foreseeable substantial detriment caused by the
breach should also justify cancellation for delay, as is the case under PECL.
The causation of foreseeable substantial detriment is probably the best
explanation of the doctrine of “time being of the essence under the contract”.
Certainly such an explanation is superior to the strained argument that a tacit
41
termination clause or lex commissoria is involved. At present, there is a
danger that the “time is of the essence” doctrine will only assist a South
African creditor under a commercial contract subject to price fluctuations
and so on. That there is a need to protect the creditor in a wider ambit of
cases, when late performance will lead to foreseeable substantial detriment,
is demonstrated by the decision of Cowley v Estate Loumeau.42 In this case
the curators of an insolvent estate were allowed to terminate the sale of a
farm on the basis of the buyer’s failure to pay the price by a certain date. The
court took into account the detriment caused by late performance, namely
that the money was required for purposes of the estate, as mortgagees were
demanding interest and other creditors were pressing their claims. A
discretionary approach to termination for delay on the basis of foreseeable
substantial detriment would also lay to rest Alfred Cockrell’s criticism that “it
is anomalous that a debtor who fails to perform a vital term is better placed
43
than one whose timeous performance is materially defective”.
42 1925 AD 392.
43 At 319.
44 McBryde, Contract, 523; MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, 213; Walker, Contract, 557;
McBryde (2002) 6 Edinburgh LR 5 at 18; Rodger (Builders) Ltd v Fawdry 1950 SC 483 at 492;
Johnstone v Harris 1977 SC 365 at 370; Report on Remedies for Breach of Contract (Scot Law
Com No 174, 1999) (henceforth Scot Law Com No 174 (1999)), para 7.38; Van der Merwe et al,
Contract, 319; Christie, Contract, 590; Microcoutsis v Swart 1949 (3) SA 715 (A) at 730. Certainly
in South Africa, this development is owed to English influence (Harker, 1980 Acta Juridica 61 at
74).
45 Article 8:106(3) PECL.
46 Ver Elst v Sabena Belgian World Airlines 1983 (3) SA 637 (A); McBryde (2002) 6 Edinburgh LR
5 at 18.
288 european contract law
not perform at all, the aggrieved party will only be entitled to terminate if
time is of the essence under the contract, since that is presently regarded
under South African law as the only ground when a delay will justify
cancellation in itself.56 However, it appears that even where time is not of the
essence under the contract, a total repudiation of the contract will justify
termination, that is, where the debtor intimates that he will not perform at all.
The test, added the court, is whether a reasonable person would conclude
57
that proper performance will not be forthcoming.
56 Apart from the case where a notice of intention to cancel (an ultimatum) is given or where the
contract expressly provides for cancellation on delay.
57 Datacolor 2001 (2) SA 284 at 294G.
58 Article 8:105 PECL.
59 Van der Merwe et al, Contract, 360.
60 1926 OPD 207.
61 Scot Law Com No 174 (1999), para 7.37.
290 european contract law
right to cure is that the aggrieved party has no obligation to give an invitation to
cure, but the defaulting party has a right to cure, which overrides a purported
termination. Thirdly, a tender of cure may merely lead to a loss of the right to
terminate provided the tender to cure, or alternatively cure itself, occurs
before termination. This is more akin to a possibility of cure than a right to
cure.62 A fourth manner in which a cure might affect the right to terminate is
when a legal system recognises that a tender to cure may prevent the breach
from being fundamental or material, so that no right to terminate arises at all.
The approach to cure diverges in the three systems under consideration.
(1) PECL
Article 8:104 PECL provides that:
[a] party whose tender of performance is not accepted by the other party because
it does not conform to the contract may make a new and conforming tender where
the time for performance has not yet arrived or the delay would not be such as to
constitute a fundamental non-performance.
The right to cure under PECL is limited for a number of reasons. First, it is
limited to instances where the party in breach has indeed made a non-
conforming tender of performance. Delay appears to be curable only if the
party in breach has indeed made a tender to perform late. The right to cure
does not exist if the party in breach has not tendered to perform at all.
Repudiation in the sense of a total refusal to perform is therefore not curable
under this provision (it will be considered later whether it will be retractable
for other reasons).
Secondly, a mere verbal statement of intention to cure will not be suffi-
cient – a new and conforming tender must be made.
Thirdly, either the time for performance must not yet have arrived, or the
resulting delay should not be such as to constitute a fundamental non-
performance. This will depend on whether time is of the essence under the
contract, or has become of the essence by the giving and expiry of an
ultimatum notice under Article 8:104 PECL.63 Of course, the delay can also
constitute a fundamental non-performance if it would cause foreseeable
substantial detriment to the aggrieved party.
It is unclear whether Article 8:104 PECL creates a right to cure which
would override a purported notice of termination. The right to cure is not
expressly limited to instances where notice of termination has not yet been
given.64 By contrast, PICC, for example, specifically provides that the right to
cure is not precluded by a notice of termination.65
Is there any right to retract a repudiation under PECL? The situation is
not dealt with under Article 8:104 PECL. But the Comment to Article 9:304
PECL states that the aggrieved party may terminate on the basis of an
anticipatory breach “at any time while it remains clear that there will be a
66
fundamental non-performance”. This suggests that an anticipatory repudia-
tion may be retracted with the resultant loss of the right to terminate, as it is
then no longer clear that there will be a fundamental non-performance.
Article 9:303(3)(b) PECL also provides for loss of the right to terminate in
the case of delay. It states that, if the aggrieved party knows or has reason to
know that the other party still intends to tender within a reasonable time, and
the aggrieved party unreasonably fails to notify the other party that it will not
accept performance, it loses its right to terminate if the other party in fact
tenders within a reasonable time. Therefore, when it knows that cure of delay
is forthcoming, the aggrieved party must act swiftly if it does not wish to
accept the cure, otherwise the party in breach will have the right to cure the
delay within a reasonable time.
reject cannot be taken away by the later renewed tendering of goods in a proper condition (paras
11, 12). He explained Cumming v Brown on the basis that the seller had not invoked his option to
regard the delay as material (para 11). On the other hand, Lord Hamilton in the same decision
declined to resolve the differences between Ford Sellar Motors and Cumming v Brown, but
nevertheless held that the seller was no longer in breach after it repaired the equipment sold so
that the buyer’s attempted termination came too late (para 48).
68 The contract itself provided that timeous payment was an essential obligation and that there
would be a right to terminate after late payment 1994 SLT (Sh Ct) at 12.
69 Scot Law Com DP No 109 (1999), para 4.26.
70 Clive & Hutchison, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 204 n 157. They do
not refer to Cumming v Brown in this context. McBryde (1996) 1 Edinburgh LR 43 at 62, also
argues that “performance after the specified date was not performance in terms of the contract”.
71 MacQueen & Thomson, Contract at 214. The court stated, however, that personal bar did not
apply in this case (at 213). The issue of personal bar was never raised and the court stated that the
sharp and narrow question to be decided was “where one party … has acquired a right to resile,
does that right remain effective and exercisable notwithstanding a tender of performance by the
other party” (at 213). However, the court quoted Gloag, Contract, 620 who talks of the right to
reject being barred if the aggrieved party is led to the assumption that the contract still exists.
72 McBryde, Contract, 490; Gloag, Contract, 600; McBryde (1996) 1 Edinburgh LR 43 at 57;
MacQueen & Thomson, Contract, 206.
73 MacQueen & Thomson, Contract at206.
74 Lindley Catering Investments Ltd v Hibernian Football Club Ltd 1975 SLT (Notes) 56 at 57;
Strathclyde Regional Council v Border Engineering Contractors Ltd 1998 SLT 175 at 177; cf Clive
& Hutchison, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 201–202; McBryde (2002)
6 Edinburgh LR 5 at 18–19; McBryde, Contract, 521–523. McBryde (1996) 1 Edinburgh LR 43
at 60, states that Lindley Catering may mean that a remediable breach is a non-material breach.
termination for breach of contract 293
Scots law does not recognise such a right.76 One such exception is found in
Part VA of the Sale of Goods Act 1979, in terms of which a consumer must
generally have resort to the remedies of repair or replacement before seeking
rescission.77 Another exception is that of a lessee in breach being granted the
right to an ultimatum before the landlord may terminate for a monetary
breach of the lease.78
There is some authority in Scotland that remediability should be con-
79
sidered in determining whether a breach is material; this is the fourth sense
identified above in which cure can be relevant to the right to terminate. Some
authors explain the aforementioned cases that apparently accept a right to an
80
ultimatum on this basis.
tender of non-conforming goods has induced the aggrieved party to act to its
own detriment (in which case an estoppel may arise).85 The Appellate
Division in BK Tooling (Edms) Bpk v Scope Precision Engineering (Edms)
Bpk86 relied on these cases to state that as long as performance remains
possible and the contract is not cancelled, the other party can still perform,
and that this possibility should be related to our doctrine of purgatio morae.87
88
There are conflicting views on whether a repudiation may be retracted.
Those against retractability point out that this proposition is supported
merely by obiter dicta, and that it derives from the rejected notion of English
law that repudiation is a thing writ in water, without any effect until accepted
by the other party, as opposed to an immediate breach giving rise to an
immediate right to cancel which should not be lost unless by the actions of
89
the aggrieved party itself. It has also been argued that allowing retraction of
repudiation causes the very uncertainty which recognition of this type of
90
breach aims to prevent. Furthermore, it is pointed out that the aggrieved
party may have acted in reliance on the power of termination, even though
notice of termination has not yet been given.91 Nienaber, on the other hand,
provides a theoretical foundation for the doctrine of retraction of repudia-
tion. He argues that, since the test for termination is whether the anticipated
malperformance would justify cancellation, a retraction of repudiation
causes the erstwhile right to cancel to disappear, as the anticipated malper-
formance will no longer occur.92 This presupposes that the time of purported
termination is decisive for establishing whether there is a right to terminate.
There is some authority in South African law that repudiation may also be
93
retracted after the date for performance has passed. A fourth view is that
repudiation can be retracted as long as the position of the aggrieved party has
not been altered in any way.94
Apart from the cursory reference in BK Tooling to the doctrine of purgatio
morae, there appears to be no South African authority holding that the right
to terminate will be lost if the party in “ordinary breach” (as opposed to
repudiation) purports to cure after the date for performance. Instead, some
South African writers deny that the right to terminate should be affected by
95
a tender to cure. There is clear authority that a tender of full performance
96
cannot affect a right to terminate derived from a lex commissoria, inter alia
97
because a party cannot lose the right to terminate except by its own act. It is
98
said that otherwise two competing rights would be set up against each other,
99
which would undermine the object of the lex commissoria. It has been
asked whether the same consideration should not also apply to the common
100
law residual right to terminate for breach.
South African law does not recognise a strong right to cure in the sense of
a right to be given a second chance to perform before the aggrieved party
may cancel. The only common law exception to the rule appears to be the
lessor’s right to be given an opportunity to cure defects arising in the leased
property before the lessee may cancel.101
(4) Conclusion
Scots law recognises that the right to terminate may be lost if the cure takes
place before termination. In addition, cure is a factor affecting materiality.
Repudiation may also be retracted, a notion that has found obiter support in
South African cases. There are some Scottish legislative provisions, which
oblige the aggrieved party to give the other party an opportunity to cure. In
South African law, there is only clear authority for a right to cure other types
of breach before the date for performance, although this has been criticised.
There are cogent policy arguments both in favour of and against allowing
a tender to cure to affect the aggrieved party’s right to terminate. In my view,
these opposing policy arguments can most fairly be balanced by a rule that
94 Langverwacht Farming Co v Sedgwick & Co Ltd (II) 1942 CPD 155 (obiter).
95 Van der Merwe et al, Contract, 386; cf Harker, 1980 Acta Juridica 61 at 82.
96 Schuurman v Davey 1908 TS 664 at 671–672; Pienaar v Fortuin 1977 (4) SA 428 (T); Moodley v
Reddy 1985 (1) SA 76 (D); cf Boland Bank Ltd v Pienaar 1988 (3) SA 618 (A).
97 Boland Bank Ltd v Pienaar 1988 (3) SA 618 (A) at 622 with reference to Voet, Commentarius ad
Pandectas, 22.1.31.
98 The right to cure and the right to cancel.
99 Moodley v Reddy 1985 (1) SA 76 (D) at 81E–F.
100 Lubbe & Murray, Contract, 583.
101 W E Cooper, Landlord and Tenant, 2nd edn (1994), 100.
296 european contract law
the right to terminate will be lost if a tender to cure has been made before
termination has occurred, provided that:
1. the cure will cause no unreasonable inconvenience;
2. the resultant delay will not constitute a fundamental or material breach;
3. the aggrieved party has not yet acted in reliance on the breach;
4. damages and costs are tendered simultaneously; and
5. the cure is effected promptly.
A number of European systems recognise in some form the defaulting
102
party’s right to cure. It is also consistent with the principle of Scots and South
103
African law that the law should encourage performance of a contract, and
that termination is a drastic remedy which should not easily be granted.
104
Allowing cure also reflects the policy of minimising economic waste. The
aggrieved party’s interests are protected by the limitations on the right to
cure set out above. The aggrieved party can make an end to the uncertainty of
whether cure will take place by terminating the contract. Granting the party
in breach a right to cure that overrides a purported termination or a right to
an ultimatum goes too far in protecting the party in breach. A rule that an
ultimatum should always be given does not give due consideration to the
possibility that the aggrieved party may have lost confidence in the party in
breach, and may also tempt unscrupulous parties to perform shoddily in the
knowledge that they will be given a second chance.105
D. CONSEQUENCES OF TERMINATION
The winding-up regime set out in Articles 9:305 to 9:309 PECL has been
criticised on a number of grounds. These provisions are in some respects
overly complex and yet in others too underdeveloped to provide clear
solutions. The aspects that warrant criticism will now be compared with the
position under South African and Scots law.
liberal approach to restitution after termination and thus enable the court or
arbitrator to order full restitution of benefits received. On the other hand, the
value at termination may be intended, so that if the recipient has lost the
performance without having received any benefit therefrom, he need not
restore anything. Comment A to the Article refers to a party being “left with
a benefit which cannot be returned” which seems to support this inter-
123
pretation. To similar effect is Comment B, which refers to the amount by
124
which a party has been enriched. Under the South African and Scots laws
of enrichment, for example, there is a defence of change of position or loss of
enrichment, which would put the risk of accidental destruction of property
on the transferor, and thus on the person who installed the equipment in this
125
instance. Of course, had it been the party in breach who had destroyed or
lost the property, a damages claim would compensate the aggrieved party for
loss of his performance in such a case. But the position where it is the
aggrieved party who has lost the property remains unclear under PECL.
Another aspect on which Article 9:309 PECL is unclear concerns the
situation where the actual value of the performance to the recipient is much
higher than the contract price – that is where the performing party has made
a bad bargain. However, the example in the Comment makes it clear that in
such case the recipient need only restore an appropriate part of the purchase
price.126 An important qualification such as this should rather have been
contained in the Article itself.
the performance must be restored.127 In other instances, there has been some
support in South African law for a principle that the ability to restore
performance is a condition precedent for termination.128 This principle was
then subjected to a number of qualifications based on the idea that
restitution is required only as far as it is equitable.129 However, in the context
of rescission for improperly contained consent, the Supreme Court of Appeal
has made it clear that restitution is not a condition precedent but rather a
130
consequence for the act of rescission, although a tender of restitution, or an
explanation and excuse for its failure is a requirement for a claim for
131 132
restitution. This view should also apply in the breach of contract context.
As Clive and Hutchison point out, there is often no policy reason for denying
termination provided that a suitable adjustment of economic imbalances by
133
way of monetary compensation can be arranged.
Examples of cases where the courts have held it to be inequitable to
require restitution include the situation where the property received has
134
perished as a result of the inherent defect complained of or during the
135
normal intended use of the property. It has also been held to be inequitable
to require restitution where it has become impossible through no fault of the
aggrieved party, provided that that party does not gain an advantage from the
performance.136 Thus a boat owner in circumstances similar to those descri-
bed above was held to be entitled to terminate without having to compensate
the other party for the refrigeration equipment lost at sea.137
There are instances where the recipient must restore the value of a
127 Harker, 1980 Acta Juridica 61 at 100; Spencer v Gostelow 1920 AD 617. The claim has been said
to be based on unjustified enrichment in that context (BK Tooling (note 86) at 424), but the
better view is that it is contractual in nature (S Miller, “Unjustified enrichment and failed
contracts”, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems, 437–468). A full consider-
ation of this controversy is beyond the scope of this chapter.
128 Van der Merwe et al, Contract, 374; Harker, 1980 Acta Juridica 61 at 100; Uni-Erections v
Continental Engineering Co Ltd 1981 (1) SA 241 (W) at 247G, 248A. Cf Walker, Contract, 558
who states that where innocent third parties have acquired rights for consideration in the subject
matter of the contract, e.g. where a buyer has resold goods, rescission is precluded in Scots law.
129 Van der Merwe et al, Contract, 374.
130 Extel Industrial (Pty) Ltd v Crown Mills (Pty) Ltd 1999 (2) SA 719 (SCA) at 731E–G, 732A–D.
131 At 732B.
132 Although Van der Merwe et al, Contract, do not mention the Extel case, they refer to other cases
decided in the context of rescission for improperly obtained consent as if the same principles
should apply in both contexts.
133 Clive & Hutchison, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 205–206.
134 Cf Marks Ltd v Laughton 1920 AD 12.
135 African Organic Fertilizers & Associated Industries Ltd v Sieling 1949 (2) SA 131 (W).
136 Hall-Thermotank (note 120); Van der Merwe et al, Contract, 374; Harker, 1980 Acta Juridica 61
at 100–101; Lubbe & Murray, Contract, 592.
137 Hall-Thermotank (note 120).
302 european contract law
138 Harper v Webster 1956 (2) SA 495 (FC); cf Theron v Africa 10 SC 246.
139 Van der Merwe et al, Contract, 375; Harper v Webster 1956 (2) SA 495 (FC).
140 De Wet & Van Wyk, Kontraktereg, 244 n 236; Lubbe & Murray, Contract, 593 n 5; Van der
Merwe et al, Contract, 383.
141 De Wet & Van Wyk, Kontraktereg, 244 n 236; Lubbe & Murray, Contract, 593 n 5; Van der
Merwe et al, Contract, 383.
142 Clive & Hutchison, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 206; McBryde,
Contract, 480; Hellwege, Rückabwicklung, 346, 348, 354, 357, and P Hellwege, “In integrum
restitutio and the requirement of counter-restitution in Roman Law” 2004 JR 165 at 171, 176,
suggest that it is not a condition precedent, whereas P Hellwege “Unwinding mutual contracts:
restitutio in integrum v the defence of change of position” in Johnston & Zimmermann (eds),
Unjustified Enrichment at 255, states that it is a requirement in the case of defective goods sold.
See also MacQueen, 1994 JR 137 at 148, cf at 138. According to Miller, in Zimmermann, Visser
& Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 449, Scots law prevents termination for breach when the
aggrieved party cannot return a performance received, but there have been calls for restitution
by way of monetary surrogate. However, the authorities Miller lists are concerned with
reduction or rescission of a voidable contract and not with termination for breach.
143 See, e.g., Ramsay v Brand (1895) 25 R 1212.
144 See, e.g., Miller, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems; Hogg, Obligations, 201–
202; J A Dieckmann and R Evans-Jones, “The dark side of Connelly v Simpson” 1995 JR 90 at
100; McBryde, Contract, 524–525; H L MacQueen, “Unjustified enrichment” in C Ashton et al,
Fundamentals of Scots Law (2003), 267 at 306.
145 Scot Law Com No 174 (1999), paras 7.23–7.24. See also Watson v Shankland (1871) 10 M
142 at 152. A number of cases hold that the party in breach cannot sue on the contract but must
termination for breach of contract 303
How would Scots law treat the example of the boat owner who has lost the
performance received? Must he restore the value of the boat upon reclaiming
the price? First, if the boat owner can be said to have had a reasonable oppor-
tunity to examine the equipment to ascertain its conformity, he would lose
the right to reject the goods on the basis that he had accepted them as
provided for in the Sale of Goods Act.146 The buyer could probably have tested
the equipment before going out to sea and on this basis has lost the right to reject.
Suppose, however, that the defect manifested itself before the buyer could
be said to have accepted the goods, that it was serious enough to warrant
rejection, but that the goods had been accidentally destroyed before termin-
ation took place. The majority view is that the risk of accidental destruction
does not pass to the buyer where defective goods are delivered and then
147
rejected by the buyer, and so the buyer would still be allowed to terminate.
Michael Bridge, however, argues that it would be fairer if the risk of interim
loss arising from events unconnected with the non-conforming character of
the goods should remain with the buyer, with the implication that the buyer
may not terminate.148 If one were to follow the former view it has to be asked
whether the seller is entitled to the value of what he performed so that ultim-
ately this is deducted from the purchase price claimed by the buyer. There
seems to be no clear case law on this issue in the breach of contract context.
Robin Evans-Jones contends that a party who is unable to return the
object itself upon termination has to offer its value.149 This is based on the
idea that the parties must be placed into the position in which they were
150
before the transaction was performed (restitutio in integrum). Since the
purpose of the rules on restitution after termination is to prevent unjustified
151 152
enrichment, one answer might lie in the application of enrichment rules.
However, the weight of authority on restitution of corporeal property is to the
base its claim on unjustified enrichment (e.g. Steel v Young 1907 SC 360; Forrest v Scottish
County Investment Co Ltd 1916 SC (HL) 28 at 39).
146 Sale of Goods Act 1979, s 35; see further P S Atiyah, J N Adams, H MacQueen, The Sale of
Goods, 11th edn (2005) (henceforth Atiyah et al, Sale of Goods), 513–515.
147 Atiyah et al, Sale of Goods, 356.
148 M G Bridge, The Sale of Goods (1997), 125.
149 Robin Evans-Jones, Unjustified Enrichment, vol 1 (2003), 316–317; cf Hellwege, Rückab-
wicklung, 600.
150 Hogg also holds that a substitutive claim would lie if the property has been consumed or
transferred to a third party (Obligations, 201–202).
151 MacQueen, 1997 Acta Juridica 176 at 192–193.
152 Clive & Hutchison, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems, at 206, suggest that
contract law could usefully adopt or refer to enrichment rules to provide a solution in this
context.
304 european contract law
effect that the risk of accidental destruction lies with the transferor.153 On this
view, the seller would not have a claim for the value of the goods lost based on
unjustified enrichment. Once again there is a contrary view: Eric Clive
contends that the risk of accidental destruction should lie with the transferee
since, first, ownership has passed to him and the owner, generally, bears the
risk of loss and, secondly, the transferor would have acted reasonably if he
154
cancelled his insurance.
(c) Evaluation
It is commendable that Article 9:309 PECL does not treat restitution in kind
as a condition precedent for termination. Article 9:309 PECL operates fairly
where the performance cannot be returned by reason of its very nature, such
as in the case of services rendered.
The problem of accidental destruction of property in the hands of the
aggrieved party, however, on which Article 9:309 PECL and Scots law are not
155
clear, is not easily resolved. On the one hand it may be argued that breach
justifies a differential treatment of the party in breach and the aggrieved
party, so that the aggrieved party should be excused from paying anything for
the lost property, provided it has exercised the degree of caution which it
would have exercised in its own affairs. On the other hand, breach is not
always accompanied by fault and may not be a suitable reason to subvert the
normal incidence of risk, which should run with physical control of the
property involved.156 This implies that the recipient should carry the risk of
accidental destruction and should therefore compensate the performing
party for the value of its performance if restitution in kind becomes impos-
sible as a result of no fault of either party. Another argument in favour of the
risk of accidental destruction resting on the recipient of the performance is
that the recipient can be expected to insure the property, whereas the
transferor may reasonably have cancelled his insurance.
On balance, the best solution would be for the recipient to carry the risk of
accidental destruction so that he has to pay a monetary substitute if resti-
157
tution in kind is not possible. Accordingly, the recipient should always be
153 Bell, Principles, § 537; Cantiere San Rocco v Clyde Shipbuilding and Engineering Co 1923 SC
(HL) 105 at 111 per Lord Birkenhead.
154 Clive, Draft Rules, Schedule, para 2(2)(a) and (b), comment, example 3.
155 Cf Miller, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 449.
156 Miller, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 449; Zimmermann, in Fest-
schrift Kramer at 753.
157 Zimmermann, in Festschrift Kramer at 753. Hellwege, 2004 JR 165 argues that this was most
likely the position in Roman law.
termination for breach of contract 305
forced to restore the value of what he has received, except where, first, the
impossibility to restore is attributable to the other party, i.e., for example,
where an inherent defect for which that other party is responsible has led to
the destruction, and, secondly, where the damage would have occurred
anyway if the property had been in the hands of the claimant.158 Article 9:309
PECL should be rewritten to provide for these exceptions.
E. CONCLUSION
The PECL provisions on termination for non-performance are similar to
Scots and South African law in a number of important respects, not sur-
prisingly in view of the Common Law influence in all three systems. The right
to terminate is exercised by notice, and recourse to a court is not, therefore,
required. In some respects termination only operates prospectively in all
A. INTRODUCTION
B. ASSIGNMENT UNDER SCOTS AND SOUTH AFRICAN LAW
C. ASSIGNMENT UNDER PECL
(1) PECL’s concept of assignment
(2) The obligationary aspect: effects of an assignment as between assignee
and debtor (Section 3)
(3) Proprietary aspects: Priorities as between assignee and competing
claimants
(4) Immediate effects of assignment as between assignor and assignee
(5) PECL provisions in perspective
D. PRACTICAL UTILITY OF THE ASSIGNMENT REGIME OF
PECL
E. THEORETICAL NATURE OF ASSIGNMENT UNDER PECL
F. CONCLUSION
A. INTRODUCTION
Throughout Europe, assignment is understood as involving a transfer of a
personal right of a creditor to a third party (the assignee), the latter, replacing
the former (the assignor) as creditor in respect of the related obligation.1
Common also is an understanding of assignment as an institution that straddles
2
both the law of property and the law of obligations. As a disposition by a
creditor of an incorporeal asset, assignment is an institution of the law of
property. Because it in addition effects a substitution of creditors, assignment
also reveals affinities with the law of obligations. It is accordingly not
surprising that although national solutions might differ in matters of detail,
comparative treatments are readily able to deal with assignment in the
3
European context by means of a common conceptual vocabulary. The
1 H Kötz & A Flessner, European Contract Law, vol 1 (Formation, Validity and Content of
Contracts and Third Parties) (1997) (henceforth Kötz & Flessner, European Contract Law), 265.
2 P Nienaber & G Gretton, “Assignation/Cession”, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal
Systems, 788.
3 Kötz & Flessner, European Contract Law, 262–284.
307
308 european contract law
Convention). Apart from PECL, restatements of the law of assignment are to be found in the
UNIDROIT PICC 2004 and the draft European Contract Code of Academy of European Private
Lawyers (Gandolfi Draft).
19 Zimmermann, Principles, 39.
20 See the overview of the drafting of the UN Convention on Assignment of Receivables in
International Trade by M E Trager, “Towards a predictable law on international receivables
financing: The UNCITRAL Convention” (1999) 31 International Law and Politics 611.
21 Zimmermann, Principles, 8.
22 Nienaber & Gretton, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 789–790, 791.
assignment 311
suffices to pass the right from the patrimony of the cedent to that of the
cessionary (the proprietary aspect of cession), who thereby also becomes
substituted as creditor in the cedent’s stead (the obligationary aspect).23
In Scots law, on the other hand, the transfer agreement is not enough.
According to Nienaber and Gretton:
Notice to the debtor is a substantive requirement for the transfer of the right and
the substitution of creditors. Absent such notice, the transfer as such is ineffectual
and the claim remains vested in the cedent. It passes only when intimation is made
24
to the debtor.
As in South African law, an assignment has a dual effect, but both the obli-
gationary operation of the assignment, i.e. the substitution of the creditor and
its patrimonial effect, i.e. the transfer of the right, is triggered by intimation
rather than the mere transfer agreement.
Importantly, the notion of a transfer of a right from the assignor to the
assignee is, in both systems, a functional one, explanatory of the operation of
the assignment. Because of the transfer of the right, the assignee becomes
creditor, enjoying the title to sue and having the capacity to effect a discharge
of the debtor by accepting performance, granting a release or concluding a
compromise. This is also the case in respect of the patrimonial consequences
of the assignment. Once a transfer has been effected, by mere agreement in
South Africa or by intimation in Scotland, the assignee is protected against
the attachment of the subject matter at the hands of a creditor of the assignor.
Because there is nothing left in the hands of the assignor to be taken after a
transfer has been effected, the assignee is, subject to the provisions of
insolvency legislation, also insulated against the insolvency administrator of
the assignor where sequestration intervenes after the assignment becomes
effective. The notion of an assignment as a transfer of the right is also of
decisive importance in respect of multiple disposals of the right by the
assignor. In South African law, a full, out and out cession deprives the cedent
of an interest in the subject matter of the cession, so that the same right
cannot, in principle, be ceded twice over to different persons. In Scotland,
the assignor remains creditor until intimation and accordingly still capable of
a further assignment. The rule here is one of priority of intimation. Notice to
the debtor extracts the right from the patrimony of the assignor so that there
23 S Scott, The Law of Cession, 2nd edn (1991) (henceforth Scott, Cession), 101–102, 103.
24 In Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 796; McBryde, Contract, paras 12-100,
12-104, 12-105. Alternatively, in the absence of intimation, the debtor is required to have acknow-
ledged the assignment. See Nienaber & Gretton, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal
Systems at 790, 792; 801–802.
312 european contract law
25 See, generally Nienaber & Gretton, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 796–
801.
26 PECL, vol 2, 85.
27 An assignment involves an “agreement” (Article 11:101(1) and (2) PECL), in respect of contrac-
tual and “other transferable claims” (Article 11:101(2) PECL). That it entails a transfer of a right
is apparent from Article 11:101(3) and (4) PECL and the contrast in Article 11:101(5) PECL
between assignments on the one hand and “grants by agreement” of a right of security over a
claim.
28 PECL, vol 2, 98.
29 Article 11:104 PECL.
30 PECL, vol 2, 98.
assignment 313
46 See e.g. the definition of “competing claimant” in Article 5(m) of the UN Convention on the
Assignment of Receivables in International Trade.
47 Nienaber & Gretton, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 797–798.
48 Nienaber & Gretton, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 797.
49 Article 11:401(3), read with Article 11:202 PECL in relation to future rights.
50 Kötz & Flessner, European Contract Law, 279.
51 Article 11:401(4) PECL. Cf PECL, vol 2, 123.
assignment 317
and this applies also to the determination of the other aspects of the priority
problem. Priority, according to PECL, is accordingly severed from what the
comments style the “validity” of the assignment.56 There is therefore a depar-
ture from the nemo dat rule as a rationale for according priority, and an
express disjunction of the provision regarding the obligationary effect of an
assignment inter partes between assignor and assignee and the issue of
57
priority.
The proviso refers to cases where an assignment, even prior to and indepen-
dently of notice, is said to be ineffective as against the debtor because of a
contractual prohibition on assignment (Article 11:301 PECL) or the highly
personal nature of the right (Article 11:302 PECL). Even in such cases, and
therefore also in all others, an assignment according to the Comments to
Articles 11:301 and 11:302 PECL, “operates to transfer to the assignee the
right to all benefits received by the assignor from the debtor”.61
A transfer presupposes, however, that the subject matter should have been
vested in the transferor. To portray the effect of an assignment as a transfer to
the assignee of a right “to whatever the assignor receives from the debtor” is
artificial in the extreme. This is not a right that the assignor ever had against
the debtor, of course. It comes as no surprise that the text of Article 11:203
PECL does not speak of a transfer at all, but merely states that the assign-
ment “entitles” the assignee to whatever the assignor receives from the
62
debtor. This casts doubt on the portrayal of the effect of the assignment as a
transfer. If as between the assignor and the assignee the only effect of an
assignment is that the assignee has a personal right as against the assignor to
have the proceeds of performance by the debtor paid over, the notion of a
transfer becomes redundant. One might equally well take the view that an
assignment by operation of law creates a claim against the assignor for the
assignee. This is very different from what is envisaged by Article 11:201
PECL, namely a transfer to the assignee of “all the assignor’s rights to
performance in respect of the claim assigned”.
The severance of the effect of an assignment between the parties thereto
and the priority question, coupled with the postponement of obligationary
substitution until notice is given entails that an assignor retains the com-
petence to make multiple assignment in respect of the same claims or other-
63
wise to dispose of the claim in spite of having done so previously. To do so
64
might amount to a breach of contract against an earlier assignee. It will not,
however, preclude a later assignee from acquiring priority by being the first
to notify the debtor.
66 Cf M J Bonell, “UNIDROIT Principles 2004 – The New Edition of the Principles of International
Commercial Contracts adopted by the International Institute for the Unification of Private Law”
(2004) 9 Uniform Law Review 5.
67 Article 2(a) UN Convention; Article 9.1.1 PICC.
68 Bonell (2004) 9 Uniform Law Review 5 with reference to Comment 4 to Article 9.1.1 PICC.
69 Bazinas (2001) 9 Tulane Journal of International and Comparative Law 259 at 285–287.
70 Articles 22–25, 30. On the optional substantive priority regimes held out as models for possible
adoption by member states, see Article 42 and Articles 6–9 of the Annex to the Convention. Cf
Bazinas (2001) 9 Tulane Journal of International and Comparative Law 259 at 285; Eidenmüller
(2004) 204 Archiv für die civilistische Praxis 457 at 474.
71 Article 17(1) UN Convention; cf Article 9.1.10 PICC.
72 UN Convention Article 17(2), cf the provisos in sub-paragraphs 3–8; Article 9.1.10 PICC. By
virtue of Article 9.1.11 PICC in respect of successive assignments of the same right, payment
according to the order in which the notices were received from the various assignees discharges
the debtor. Importantly, this rule has no bearing on the resolution of priority conflicts. See Bonell
(2004) 9 Uniform Law Review 5.
73 Article 17(2).
74 Article 14(1)(a), (b).
assignment 321
under Scots law an assignee does not derive any protection from an uninti-
mated assignation.90 Because “no title vests in assignment until the intimation
has been given to the debtor”,91 the formality of intimation places the assignee
under a confidential factoring arrangement at risk in respect of priority
conflicts.
These difficulties are met by recourse to the institution of the trust.
Although in the absence of intimation, an assignee enjoys no obligationary
standing as against the debtor and no proprietary interest in the subject
matter, it is said to be permissible for the assignor to undertake to hold the
subject matter of the assignment on trust for the assignee. On the basis that
the assignee is thereby constituted the beneficial owner of the claims, it has
been held that the assignee is protected in the event of the insolvency of the
92
assignor provided the constitution of the trust was notified to the assignee.
93
Although the correctness of this approach has been doubted, it is said to be
the normal practice in Scotland to obviate the need for intimation in respect
94
of invoice discounting in this way.
Under PECL, such expedients are unnecessary. The difficulties which the
formality of intimation or notice poses for the recognition of the efficacy of a
global assignment are overcome by the separation of the obligationary con-
sequences of an assignment from the proprietary dimension. Priority dates
from the time of the assignment when the assignee gives value to the assignor
and becomes interested in the claim and not on the obligationary status of the
assignee as against the debtor. The failure to notify cannot therefore detract
from the position of the assignee. The same holds true of the case of a conflict
between successive assignees where, as is often the case, notice cannot be
given because the debtors have as yet not materialised. To the extent that
notification could have been given, it is merely an option to be considered by
the assignee in order to obtain preference over a competing assignee. This
approximates the role of notice in South African law, where notice does not
play a constitutive role. Because the assignee enjoys priority irrespective of
notification, confidentiality can be maintained. The idea underlying practices
such as invoice discounting, namely that the arrangement should not
interfere with the business operations of the assignor and disturb its relations
90 Nienaber & Gretton, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 804.
91 Salinger & Wood, Factoring, 151.
92 Tay Valley Joinery Ltd v CF Financial Services Ltd 1987 SLT 207; Nienaber & Gretton, in
Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 804; Salinger & Wood, Factoring, 152–153.
93 Nienaber & Gretton, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 804; Salinger &
Wood, Factoring, 154.
94 Salinger & Wood, Factoring, 153.
324 european contract law
with its clients, is arguably also better served by a system in which the
assignor remains the creditor until notification. This obviates the need to
resort to expedients, common in South Africa, such as an authorisation to the
assignor to collect on behalf of the assignee as some sort of undisclosed
principal.95 Because the assignor remains creditor until notification, keeping
the assignment quiet will also not present a false front, as is so often the case
96
in systems such as South African law.
The severance of the priority issue from the assignee’s standing as creditor
as a result of the move away from the nemo dat rule has a further important
implication. It permits and facilitates multiple assignments by a creditor of
the same claims, thus optimising the use businesses can make of their trade
claims. In this way, problems experienced in South African law in respect of
97
successive security cessions pertaining to the same rights are overcome.
Provided that the order of priority is clearly determined, such an approach is
value maximising and on the face of it economically efficient.
Overall, the approach of PECL is functional and in harmony with that of
the UN Convention and other international instruments.98 By providing a
basis for the regulation of practices such as invoice discounting, the PECL
regime is responsive to the practical needs of a sophisticated financial
environment such as the European Union.
The priority issue is one of the most complex and intractable facing
attempts to establish a uniform law of international assignment. PECL, as
99
indicated earlier, opts for a regime combining a first-to-give-notice rule and
a rule based on the priority of the assignment. Whether such a mixed system
addresses all aspects of the priority issue adequately cannot be fully dealt
with here. The approach, which is reminiscent of that established for English
100
law in Dearle v Hall, avoids the problems associated with according priority
101
on the basis of the registration of the assignment in a public registry, but
95 For example, Densam (Pty) Ltd v Cywilnat 1991 (1) SA 100 (A).
96 Cf Nienaber & Gretton, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 818.
97 Van der Merwe et al, Contract, 479.
98 See section C(5) above.
99 See section C(5) above.
100 (1828) 3 Russ 1; cf Bazinas (2001) 9 Tulane Journal of International and Comparative Law 259
at 285.
101 See Bazinas (2001) 9 Tulane Journal of International and Comparative Law 259 at 285; Davies
(2004) 24 Legal Studies 295 at 308–311; but see Eidenmüller (2004) 204 Archiv für die
civilistische Praxis 457 at 477–479, 500–501. See generally on the filing system of Article 9 of
the US Uniform Commercial Code: H Kötz, “Rights of Third Parties – Third Party Benefici-
aries and Assignment”, 7 International Encyclopedia of Comparative Law, vol. VII/13 (1992),
para 103 (henceforth Kötz, “Rights of Third Parties”).
assignment 325
brings with it not only the advantages of each of its component elements, but
also their disadvantages. The simplicity of the priority of assignment rule and
the confidentiality which it permits102 must be balanced against the possibi-
lity that the lack of publicity and the risk of harm to would-be assignees might
raise the price at which the latter is prepared to extend credit to a level which
would discourage transactions.103 The supposed advantage of a priority
regime based on the notification of the debtor is that an intending assignee is
able to elicit information about prior assignments by enquiry from the
104
debtor. Apart from the fact that this provides no protection for third parties
105
who supply to assignors on short-term credit, an enquiry of this kind prior
to taking an assignment is not equivalent to a notice of the assignment. The
question in any event is whether a debtor would necessarily be aware of any
prior assignment, and if so, whether he can be regarded as duty bound to
106
inform a would-be assignee thereof. Whatever the position might be in
relation to existing claims of high value, the supposed publicity value of
notice is illusory in respect of the global assignment of future rights and those
comprising both existing and future rights. In such cases the debtors are
either non-existent or unknown. Where the debtors are known, there might
be so many of them that notification is impractical and costly, particularly
where, as will often be the case, the assignment is of claims that taken singly
are of relatively low value.107 In the final analysis the very nature of the assign-
ment might require that an assignee refrain from approaching the debtors of
108
his assignor. Although transaction costs are saved by the fact that in relation
to the issue of priority notice is facultative and not a constitutive require-
109
ment, the mixed system of PECL does not bring the certainty as to the
102 Bazinas (2001) 9 Tulane Journal of International and Comparative Law 259 at 284.
103 Bazinas (2001) 9 Tulane Journal of International and Comparative Law 259 at 284, and see
Eidenmüller (2004) 204 Archiv für die civilistische Praxis 457 at 474–475 on the role of
publicity in reducing transaction costs. Contra Davies (2004) 24 Legal Studies 295 at 309–310.
104 Bazinas (2001) 9 Tulane Journal of International and Comparative Law 259 at 285; cf PECL,
vol 2, 122 (“an intending assignee, before giving value, can ask the debtor whether the debtor
has received any notice of a prior assignment”).
105 Eidenmüller (2004) 204 Archiv für die civilistische Praxis 457 at 476.
106 Eidenmüller (2004) 204 Archiv für die civilistische Praxis 457 at 476; Bazinas (2001) 9 Tulane
Journal of International and Comparative Law 259 at 284–285; McCormack, Secured Credit,
245 (“the debtor is not a publicly commissioned official charged with the task of receiving or
tracking notices”); cf F Oditah “Priorities: equitable versus legal assignments of book debts”
(1989) 9 Oxford JLS 513 at 525–527.
107 Interestingly, Illustration 1 in PECL, vol 2, 122 makes no mention of an assignment of future
rights or of bulk or global assignments.
108 Eidenmüller (2004) 204 Archiv für die civilistische Praxis 457 at 476.
109 Eidenmüller (2004) 204 Archiv für die civilistische Praxis 457 at 475–476.
326 european contract law
110 Eidenmüller (2004) 204 Archiv für die civilistische Praxis 457 at 476; cf McCormack, Secured
Credit, 244–245.
111 Eidenmüller (2004) 204 Archiv für die civilistische Praxis 457 at 480; Kötz, “Rights of third
parties”, para 105.
112 See McCormack, Secured Credit, 221–222, 224–225; M G Bridge, R A McDonald, R L
Simmonds & C Walsh, “Formalism, functionalism and understanding the law of secured
transactions” (1999) 44 McGill LJ 567 at 646–648.
113 Zimmermann, Obligations, 63–75; Ranieri, Obligationenrecht, 434.
114 See note 1 above and the accompanying text.
115 See section B above.
116 See section C(3) above.
117 See section C(4) above.
assignment 327
120 Scott, Cession, 96–105; see also Nienaber & Gretton, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed
Legal Systems at 795 n 43.
121 Van der Merwe et al, Contract, 456.
122 See above section C(4).
123 Scott, Cession, 101–102, 103.
124 Nienaber & Gretton, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 790–791;
Salinger & Wood, Factoring, 150.
125 Nienaber & Gretton, in Zimmermann, Visser & Reid, Mixed Legal Systems at 796.
126 See Article 11:303(4) PECL.
assignment 329
Yet another analysis could proceed from the view that has been advanced
for South African law, that a creditor, as the holder of a personal right, enjoys
not only a beneficial interest in the performance due from the debtor, but
also a legally recognised capacity to enforce and otherwise to dispose of the
right.127 According to some, these components of a creditor’s interest may be
separated from one another by way of a cession, for example by a cession of
the capacity to dispose of the right — or at least the capacity to enforce it —
to a cessionary where a security cession is intended to effect a pledge of the
right. Conversely, the cedent may cede the beneficial interest to the cession-
ary while retaining the capacity to dispose of and control the economic value
128
inherent in the debtor’s performance. The notion of a transfer which
involves a splitting of the claim so as to leave the assignor with the capacity to
deal with the debtor as creditor (at least so long as no notice of the assignment
is given) but to vest the assignee with the beneficial interest in the perform-
ance could conceivably provide a theoretical template for the relative effect
accorded to an unnotified assignment under PECL. The claim of an assignee
to whatever the assignor has received from the debtor under Article 11:203
PECL can be construed as resulting from a transfer to the assignee of the
beneficial ownership in the claims. Interestingly, an analysis along these lines
approximates the results reached in Scots law by the utilisation of the trust in
order to invest the assignee with a proprietary interest in the subject matter
of the assignment even though intimation has not yet been made.129 If the
notion of beneficial ownership in a claim is given legal recognition, an assignee
will be protected on that basis irrespective of his standing as creditor. Article
11:203 PECL echoes the trust construction as far as the assignee, as
beneficial owner of the claims of which the assignor is still formally the
owner, is entitled to whatever has been received by the latter from the debtor.
F. CONCLUSION
127 Van der Merwe et al, Contract, 468, but see P M Nienaber, “Cession” in LAWSA, 2nd edn
(2003), vol 2(2), para 53.
128 Van der Merwe et al, Contract, 468–469.
129 See notes 92–94 above and the accompanying text.
130 Hesselink & De Vries, European Contract Law, 89–90.
330 european contract law
131 Bridge et al (1999) 44 McGill LJ 567 at 572–573; Davies (2004) 24 Legal Studies 295 at 300–
304.
132 Bridge et al (1999) 44 McGill LJ 567 at 573, 614–615, 662; Davies (2004) 24 Legal Studies 295
at 304–305.
133 H L A Hart, The Concept of Law (1961), 126.
13 Capitalisation of Interest
Max Loubser
A. INTRODUCTION
B. NATURE AND FUNCTION OF INTEREST
C. HISTORY OF RULES ON CAPITALISATION
(1) Roman law
(2) Policy on interest and capitalisation
D. MODERN THEORY ON REGULATION OF INTEREST
E. REGULATION OF CAPITALISATION BY CONTRACT AND
TRADE USAGE
(1) Enforceability of agreements on capitalisation
(2) Unconscionability standards
(3) Capitalisation under the Usury Act in South Africa
(4) Small loans in South Africa
F. CAPITALISATION AND THE IN DUPLUM RULE IN SOUTH
AFRICA
(1) General nature, effect and rationale of the in duplum rule
(2) Capitalisation
G. MORA INTEREST
(1) Entitlement to mora interest
(2) Mora interest and capitalisation
(3) Additional finance charges under South African Usury Act 73 of 1968
(4) Mora interest on damages
H. CAPITALISATION AND INTEREST AS DAMAGES
I. CONCLUSIONS
(1) Lack of uniformity
(2) Economic and commercial realities
(3) Capitalisation in respect of both debts and damages
(4) Should consumer debts be excluded?
(5) Contractual provisions
(6) Interest as damages
(7) Calculation – undue complexity?
(8) Intervals for capitalisation
(9) Reform in Scotland and South Africa
331
332 european contract law
A. INTRODUCTION
Distaste for interest has been pervasive in ethics, religion and law in all of
recorded history. The rules against usury are rooted in the idea that interest is
by its nature exploitative. If by this reasoning interest is bad, then the taking
of interest on interest – that is compound interest or anatocism (the archaic
and almost obsolete term for compound interest) – is worse.1 The word
anatocism has a ring about it of something unpleasant.
From an economic and mathematical point of view it does not matter
whether compound interest is seen as the adding of accrued interest to a debt
as interest or as capital, the effect is the same. In legal terminology, almost as
if by verbal sleight of hand, the lawful taking of compound interest becomes
capitalisation – the process whereby accrued interest is merged with the
principal or capital, so as then to generate further interest on the increased
capital amount.
The legal rules on capitalisation indicate circumstances where the taking
of interest on interest is tolerated in terms of a statute, agreement or trade
usage. Research projects in various countries over the last twenty years or so
have indicated that such tolerance has been generally limited and that the law
on capitalisation or compound interest has lagged behind economic and
2
commercial realities. In this chapter the focus is on Article 17:101 PECL,
which provides for the annual capitalisation of interest for certain types of
debt.3 This provision will be compared with the position in Scotland and
South Africa, to assess to what extent it provides a suitable model for reform
of the law.
1 See A S Hartkamp, Asser’s Handleiding tot de Beoefening van het Nederlands Burgerlijk Recht
Verbintenissenrecht Deel I, 11th edn (2000), 463: “Bestond er reeds outijds zekere afkeer tegen
het bedingen van rente, nog groter was de weerzin tegen het berekenen van rente over vervallen,
doch achterstallig gebleven rente.”
2 See generally on various European legal systems the notes to Article 17:101 PECL, vol 2, 241; and
see the Law Reform Commission of Manitoba’s Report on Pre-judgment Compensation on
Money Awards (1982); the Law Reform Commission of British Columbia’s Report on the Court
Order Interest Act LRC 90 (1987); the Law Reform Commission of Ontario’s Report on
Compensation for Pesonal Injuries and Death (1987); the Law Reform Commission of Hong
Kong’s Report entitled Interest on Debt and Damages (1990); the New Zealand Law
Commission’s Report on Aspects of Damages: The Award of Interest on Money Claims, No 28
(1994); the Law Commission of England’s Report on Pre-judgment Interest on Debts and
Damages, Law Com No 287 (2004); and the Scottish Law Commission’s Consultation Paper on
Interest on Debt and Damages, Scot Law Com DP No 127 (2005).
3 Article 17:101 PECL provides as follows:
(1) Interest payable according to Article 9:508(1) is added to the outstanding capital every 12
months.
(2) Paragraph (1) of this Article does not apply if the parties have provided for interest upon
delay in payment.
capitalisation of interest 333
for the use of money, whereas today the term usury is used to indicate an
exorbitant payment for the use of money. Historically the term interest
primarily indicated compensation for non-payment of money due, whereas
today it indicates payment for a number of reasons, including compensation
for unpaid debt; payment for the use of money in terms of a contract or trade
usage; and payment specifically provided for by statute.8
According to Keynes the rate of interest is the “price” which “equilibrates
the desire to hold wealth in the form of cash with the available quantity of
9
cash”. The rate of interest thus represents the price at which there is equili-
10
brium between the demand and supply of loans of money. The rate of interest
can also be said to represent “the percentage excess of a sum of money
contracted for forward delivery, e.g. a year hence, over what we may call the
11
‘spot’ or cash price of the sum thus contracted for forward delivery”. In
functional terms interest is the price a borrower has to pay for the use of money
and, conversely, the return obtained by a lender for parting with liquidity and
12
deferring consumption of money. Interest therefore indicates a time
preference for money and could be described as the price that borrowers are
willing to pay to have money now rather than having it later. The Scottish Law
Commission in its Discussion Paper on Interest on Debt and Damages13
notes that interest can be divided into different elements: an element
accounting for the time value of money, or inflation; an element for reward
for not having the use of money; and an element accounting for the risk of
non-payment.
Simple interest is calculated on the principal sum only, whereas com-
pound interest is calculated on the principal plus any interest due at a date
when by agreement or operation of law interest can be added to the principal
14
(capitalised).
The effective interest rate determines the future value of a payment that
includes interest or, conversely, the present (discounted) value of an
entitlement to receive a future payment that includes interest. For instance,
8 P S Atiyah, The Rise and Fall of Freedom of Contract (1979), 65; English Law Com CP No 167
(2002), para 2.2.
9 J M Keynes, The General Theory of Employment Interest and Money (1949) (henceforth Keynes,
General Theory), 167.
10 Keynes, General Theory, 186 fn 1.
11 Keynes, General Theory, 222.
12 See P Mohr, Economic Indicators University of South Africa (1998) (henceforth Mohr, Economic
Indicators), 179.
13 Scot Law Com DP No 127 (2005), para 7.13.
14 See Mohr, Economic Indicators, 179.
capitalisation of interest 335
the future value of £100, one year from now, at 5 per cent simple interest, is
£105; and the present value of the entitlement to receive £100 now instead of
one year from now, calculated at 5 per cent interest, is £95.23.
The rate of interest is determined by a variety of factors, including the
chance of making profit, the rate of inflation, current and anticipated, and
concomitant fall in the purchasing power of money, the risk of payment-
default, the preference of owning rather than renting an asset and the strength
of borrowers’ time preference for consumption. These factors reflect that in
modern economic theory interest is a fundamental price mechanism.
Legally the function of interest is to provide compensation for being
deprived of the use of money. Liability to pay interest may be pre-determined
as in the case of a loan agreement or contingent upon the failure of a debtor
to pay money on the due date, whatever the cause of the indebtedness. Bell
15
in his Commentaries says: “In the ordinary case the damage due for delay in
payment of money is nothing but interest.” The Scottish Law Commission in
its Discussion Paper on Interest on Debt and Damages comments as follows
on the function of interest:16
3.1 The primary purpose of an award of interest is to acknowledge the fact that by
being deprived of the use of money, a creditor has either lost an opportunity to
benefit from the use of the money or, alternatively, has suffered a further loss as a
consequence of not having it to hand.
…
3.2 Similar considerations apply to a sum claimed by way of damages: so long as
the damages remain unpaid the claimant is deprived of that sum of money. If the
claim is for losses incurred in the past, the claimant is in a position analogous to
that of the creditor of an unpaid contractual debt. The effect of an award of
interest is to compensate the creditor by redressing the balance and, in theory,
leaving both parties in the same position as if the debt had been paid when it fell
due or, in the case of damages, as if reparation had been made as soon as the loss
was sustained. Neither the claimant nor the debtor benefits from delaying
settlement or judicial determination of the dispute.
In the comment on Article 17:101 PECL it is said that the obligation to pay
interest upon delay in payment is functionally equivalent to an obligation to
pay damages: “The interest can be regarded as a form of abstract damages,
17
although it is not ordinary damages.”
The South African Supreme Court of Appeal has held that the economic
function of interest (to provide compensation for being deprived of the use of
money) is the same for both interest ex contractu and interest ex mora. In
Linton v Corser18 Centlivres CJ said in this regard:
The old authorities regarded interest a tempore morae as “poenaal ende odieus”,
vide Utrechtsche Consultatien 3, 63, p 288. Such interest is not in these modern
times regarded in that light. Today interest is the life-blood of finance, and there is
no reason to distinguish between interest ex contractu and interest ex mora. ... The
question that now arises is whether we should apply the old Roman-Dutch law to
modern conditions where finance plays an entirely different rôle. I do not think we
should. I think that we should take a more realistic view then in a matter such as
this than to have recourse to the old authorities.
19
In Bellairs v Hodnett the function of interest is described as follows:
under modern conditions a debtor who is tardy in the due payment of a monetary
obligation will almost invariably deprive the creditor of the productive use of the
money and thereby cause him loss. It is for this loss that the award of mora interest
seeks to compensate the creditor.
overdue interest could be charged only after one year. Cicero, in a letter to
Atticus, refers to both the initial legality of anatocismus anniversarius and its
subsequent prohibition.22 In 51 BC the senate decreed that interest would be
reduced to 1 per cent per month (usura centesima) and that compound
interest (anatocismus) would not be allowed. This limit seems to have
remained in force under Caesar.23 In the early Empire rules on interest
involved three basic principles: (1) Interest rates were fixed and the general
limit was 1 per cent a month (usura centesima). Simple interest was available
24
in a variety of situations, such as in the case of late payment of a debt.
Higher interest rates were allowed in respect of enterprise-lending, as in the
case of foenus nauticum and loans for the training and development of
25
professional sportsmen. (2) Compound interest (usurae usurarum) was not
26
permitted. (3) The total sum of interest paid by the debtor to his creditor
could not exceed the original amount of the loan (usurae supra duplum). The
origins of these three principles, however, and their practical effectiveness
27
are not clear.
The restrictions on interest rates and compound interest in Roman law, as
set out above, were exceptional in the context of a legal system that generally
favoured freedom of contract. Free Roman citizens were supposed to be able
to look after their own interests and the paterfamilias was supposed to
protect the weak and the vulnerable such as women, children and slaves.28
Generally in contracts of sale whatever price was agreed upon could be taken
to represent a fair price in the particular circumstances. Sharp practice was
moderated by remedies such as those based on dolus or latent defects.
Generally, therefore, Roman law recognised the autonomy of contracting
parties to construct their own deals. Prominent exceptions to the general
absence of price-control measures in the Roman law of contract were the
29
restrictions on interest rates and the laesio enormis doctrine. Restrictions
on interest rates applied to the contract of loan (mutuum), where interest, the
30
price element of mutuum, had to be promised by way of a separate stipulatio.
22 Cicero, Ad Atticum, V 21, [11], [12], [13]. The Latin text is available at http://web.tiscali.it/latino/
Cicerone_epistole/ad_atticum_5.1.htm (accessed 30 March 2005); and for a translation see D R
Shackleton Bailey, Cicero Letters to Atticus, vol 2 (1999), 98–103.
23 Verboven (2003) 71 TR at 8.
24 D 22.1.32.2.
25 Zimmermann, Obligations, 181–187.
26 D 22.1.29; C 2.11.20; C. 4.32.28.
27 Verboven (2003) 71 TR at 7, 8.
28 Zimmermann, Obligations, 256.
29 See Zimmermann, Obligations, 166.
30 Zimmermann, Obligations, 258.
338 european contract law
A prominent theme in this debate has been that interest necessarily involves
the exploitation of the poor by rich and powerful creditors and that the taking
of interest is therefore unjust and sinful, flouting the virtues of humility and
charity.34
Another theme has been that money is sterile and that the “breeding” of
money from money is unnatural.35 The visible, calculable and progressive
“growth” of a loan carrying interest appeared to be something unnatural and
31 See Keynes, General Theory, 351: “Provisions against usury are amongst the most ancient
economic practices of which we have record.”
32 PECL, vol 2, 241.
33 Law Com CP No 167 (2002), para 4.12.
34 N N Bowsher, “Usury laws; harmful when effective” Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis Review
(Aug 1974), 16.
35 E L Glaeser & J Scheinkman, “Neither a borrower nor a lender be: an economic analysis of
interest restrictions and usury laws” (1998) 41 Journal of Law and Economics 1.
capitalisation of interest 339
36 See H G Ulrich “Das Zinsnehmen in der Christichen Ethik”, in M Vollkommer (ed), Der Zins in
Recht, Wirtschaft und Ethik (1989), 61.
37 See Ulrich (note 36 above) at 63.
38 See R H Tawney, Religion and the Rise of Capitalism (1938, reprint 1948) (henceforth Tawney,
Religion and Rise of Capitalism), 54–55.
39 Tawney, Religion and the Rise of Capitalism, 58.
40 Glaeser & Scheinkman (1998) Journal of Law and Economics 1 at 21.
41 E Kerridge, Usury, Interest and the Reformation (2002) (henceforth Kerridge, Usury, Interest
and the Reformation), 6–7.
42 Tawney, Religion and the Rise of Capitalism, 50–51.
340 european contract law
the usurers of Cahors in the same area of hell as the denizens of Sodom.51
Shakespeare’s Shylock has become the metaphor for greed and the immor-
ality of moneylending.52
From a political point of view the pervasive restriction on interest over the
centuries is somewhat surprising. It seems to indicate that borrowers often
possessed more political power than lenders, which seems implausible.53
This is exemplified by the special interest rate restriction applicable in the
time of Justinian to the Roman political elite, the senators, many of whom
had thriving moneylending businesses. At work may have been Justinian’s
Christian beliefs, moving him to act as a benevolent dictator and to enforce
exemplary commercial behaviour on the part of the ruling political elite, who
had to accept 4 per cent instead of the usual 6 per cent interest on their
54
moneylending operations.
Theories on the time value of money and inflation were late in developing
and the historical arguments on interest and usury generally fail to explain
why the charging of a price for money is any different from the charging of a
price for other goods. Viewed retrospectively in terms of modern economic
theory usury laws over the centuries may have intended, at least partially, to
narrow the income gap between rich and poor; and consequently interest
rate restrictions were enforced more rigidly when income inequality was high
and growth rates were low.55 Another aim could have been to curb interest
rates which, in a world generally regarded as highly unsafe, would have risen
56
too high to permit borrowing for investment.
Whereas the law on interest and usury was historically based primarily on
moral and religious considerations one would expect modern law on interest
to be consistent with current economic policy and commercial realities. The
prevailing view in modern economic theory is that governments do well to
refrain from controlling prices in most markets, because experience has shown
that in free competitive markets more goods are produced at lower prices
51 See Tawney, Religion and the Rise of Capitalism, 42; Glaeser & Scheinkman (1998) 41 Journal of
Law and Economics 1, nn 40, 41, 42.
52 On the terminology associated with Shylock see Kerridge, Usury, Interest and the Reformation,
Introduction and 8.
53 Glaeser & Scheinkman (1998) 41 Journal of Law and Economics 1 at 2–3.
54 See Zimmermann, Obligations, 168.
55 Glaeser & Scheinkman (1998) 41 Journal of Law and Economics 1 at 26–27.
56 See Keynes, General Theory at 351.
342 european contract law
than in markets subject to price controls. This approach applies also to the
price of credit in the market and underlies the absence of usury legislation in
many countries, as in Europe generally and in Scotland specifically. South
Africa is a mixed system in respect of interest regulation, as will be shown
below.
The economic argument for restrictions on compound interest is that such
restrictions at least assist in staving off the disproportionately oppressive
effect of exponential growth of interest costs on poorer borrowers. Where
compound interest is charged, and the borrower becomes unable even to
service the loan, the effect is destructive. An exponential increase in interest
is more frightening and unpredictable than a linear increase, and liability for
compound interest might be a slippery slope to hopeless debt. This is said to
be the consideration underlying the prohibition of compound interest in the
57
developing world, particularly in some Latin American countries.
The current policy approach in South Africa is to protect consumers against
extortion by setting rate ceilings where these can be enforced relatively
successfully. The system is a mixed one. In the small or “micro-lending” loans
sector, where rate ceilings cannot be enforced effectively and where normal
market-related rate ceilings would in any event be economically unrealistic in
view of high transaction costs, the policy since 1992 has been to exempt defined
small loans from the application of the Usury Act 73 of 1968 (referred to
below as “the Usury Act”). Such loans were made subject to other regulatory
measures, including registration of “micro-lenders” and the prohibition of
58
certain lending and collection practices. In respect of consumer credit
contracts governed by the Credit Agreements Act 75 of 1980 (below referred
to as “the Credit Agreements Act”) and the Usury Act, involving medium-size
consumer debt (loans, credit sales and leases of between R10,000 and R500,
59
000) compound interest is prohibited, except in case of default (mora).
Most medium-sized consumer transactions governed by the Usury Act
involve pre-calculated monthly instalments, providing lenders with a monthly
interest income corresponding to or surpassing that available in the commer-
cial investment market. In this context the commercial need for compound
interest or capitalisation arises mainly in cases of default (mora), where it is
have been abrogated by disuse in the modern law. ... Compound interest will be
admitted provided only that it has been agreed to either expressly or by custom. ...
In South Africa the common-law rule against compound interest was held to
have been abrogated precisely because of evidence that it was the universal
practice of banks in South Africa to charge compound interest.
64 65
There is recognition in Scotland and South Africa that the operation of
current accounts involves an implied agreement on capitalisation of interest.
There is a distinction in banking practice between accrual of interest and
capitalisation.66 Banks customarily calculate interest on overdrawn current
accounts on a daily basis and debit the accumulated total to the account,
usually on a monthly basis. The entries passed to the account and the running
balance which they generate are reflected in a bank statement which is usually
sent to the customer at regular intervals.67 However, the daily debiting of
interest does not constitute capitalisation or compounding. It is only at the
agreed rests or intervals, usually monthly, that the accrued interest is treated
as an accretion to the capital, with the effect that interest is from then on
taken on the total sum.
necessarily make the contract void in its entirety. Arguably a court has the
power to declare a contract partially enforceable to the extent that the
interest is not usurious, so that the creditor may claim his capital and so much
of the interest which is not usurious and can be regarded as reasonable.
75 Interaccess (Pty) Ltd v Van Dorsten [1999] 2 All SA 561 (C) at 574. The court held that s 5 of the
Usury Act does not specifically preclude the charging of compound interest and that compound
interest is claimable provided there is agreement between the parties to that effect (referring to
National Bank of South Africa v Graaf (1904) 2 SC 457 at 462).
76 There is one exception, namely in the case of a moneylending transaction where finance charges
may be recovered on a monthly basis if instalments are paid at intervals of longer than a month. It
would seem that s 2(7) allows the moneylender to recover his finance charges in shorter periods,
but that the rate must still be calculated in accordance with s 2(1)(a). In other words, s 2(7) permits
him to obtain his interest sooner, but at no higher a rate than that allowed by s 2(1)(a).
capitalisation of interest 347
77 See generally Report on Costs and Interest Rates in the Small Loans Sector, published as
Government Notice No 706 of 21 July 2000 at 35.
78 See generally Report on Costs and Interest Rates in the Small Loans Sector at 28, 33.
79 See Examination of Costs and Interest Rates in the Small Loans Sector, 34–35.
80 The term is of Zulu origin and means “those who bring you down”.
348 european contract law
average about 50 per cent per month and mora interest is capitalised.
Stokvels,81 burial societies and rotating savings and credit associations are
informal savings and loan organisations that receive savings from members
and then invest the funds or make loans to members on a rotating basis. The
repaid capital and interest go back into the group fund for redistribution to
the members. Interest on loans is taken as a form of additional forced saving
by the borrower. There are an estimated 800,000 of these institutions with
more than 8 million members. Funds are normally distributed to members
on a rotating basis at group meetings, as a form of dividend. Little is known
about enforcement procedures of these lenders, but there is no reported
judgment involving any of these lenders and no indication that normal legal
82
processes are involved for collection of debts.
81 The term “stokvel” is said to have originated in the Eastern Cape area as a black version of the
periodical “stock fairs” held by white farmers.
82 See generally Report on Costs and Interest Rates in the Small Loans Sector at 35–36.
83 See section C(1) above.
84 See generally M M Loubser & M A Muller “Bank overdrafts: Limitation of interest by the in
duplum rule; and prescription” (1998) 115 SALJ 598–612.
85 LTA Construction Bpk v Administrateur, Transvaal 1992 (1) SA 473 (A) at 482.
86 LTA Construction Bpk v Administrateur, Transvaal at 480.
capitalisation of interest 349
(2) Capitalisation
Because of the fluctuating balance of an open account with a trader or a
current account with a bank, interest is often calculated daily on the
outstanding balance of the account as at close of business on that day. At the
end of each month the individual amounts of daily interest for that month are
added to the outstanding amount.
In Standard Bank of South Africa Ltd v Oneanate Investments (Pty) Ltd
88
(In liquidation) the Supreme Court of Appeal considered the effect of the
banking practice of capitalising interest on a current account on the
operation of the in duplum rule. The court held that the parties cannot by
agreement or conduct waive or alter the effect of the in duplum rule. The
rule is based on public policy and is designed to protect borrowers from
exploitation by lenders. As such it cannot be waived by borrowers and cannot
be altered by banking practice.89
The Supreme Court of Appeal also held that the practice of capitalisation
of interest by bankers does not result in the interest losing its character as
such for the purposes of the in duplum rule. If lenders were entitled to
employ the expedient of a book entry to convert what is interest into capital,
this would afford an easy way to avoid not only the in duplum rule but also
90
prescription and usury legislation.
To apply the in duplum rule, the outstanding capital amount of the debt
must be determined, and this in turn could depend on how credits to the
account have been allocated or appropriated. In the Standard Bank case the
87 At 482F–H.
88 1998 (1) SA 811 (SCA).
89 At 828C–D.
90 At 828I–J.
350 european contract law
court held the rule to be that payments should be allocated first to interest
and then to capital.91
On the application of the rule pendente lite the court in the Standard Bank
case held that the purpose of the rule is to protect borrowers from exploita-
tion where lenders permit interest to accumulate excessively. A creditor who
has instituted action cannot be said to exploit a debtor if the latter, assisted by
the delays inherent in legal proceedings, keeps the creditor out of his money.
The court held that therefore no principle of public policy justifies providing
the debtor with protection pendente lite against interest in excess of the
outstanding capital amount. A creditor can control the institution of litigation
and can, by timeously instituting action, protect himself against loss of
interest by operation of the in duplum rule. However, the creditor has limited
control over delays caused by the litigation process and the rule should
therefore be suspended as soon as the legal process begins, i.e. upon service
of the initiating process. The result is that the outstanding interest, frozen at
the level of the outstanding capital amount, then begins to run again at the
applicable rate of interest, up to the time of judgment. Once a judgment has
been delivered interest begins to run on the judgment debt, which may
already contain a component of accumulated interest equal to the capital
component, or exceeding the capital component as a result of the suspension
of the in duplum rule pendente lite. The judgment reinforces the existing
debt by affording the creditor the right to implement a process of execution
and interest begins to run from the date of the judgment on the judgment
debt as a whole, irrespective of the size of its interest component. The in
duplum rule then applies again to the judgment debt as a whole, the policy
consideration being that after obtaining judgment the creditor is in duty
bound to execute and bring to a close the further accumulation of interest.
The effect is that interest may again accumulate on the judgment debt, but
92
only until the interest equals the amount of the judgment debt.
Arguably the in duplum rule is arbitrary in simply limiting outstanding
interest to double the capital and its reception into modern South African law
has been sparsely and unconvincingly justified. It takes no account of the
effect of fluctuating interest rates on the time that it takes for unpaid interest
to equal the outstanding capital and, insofar as it is supposed to penalise a
tardy creditor it usurps the function of prescription.
91 At 831I–832C.
92 At 834B–H.
capitalisation of interest 351
G. MORA INTEREST
The South African Supreme Court of Appeal has held in Bellairs v Hodnett105
that the function of interest is to provide compensation to a creditor who is
deprived by the debtor’s default of the productive use of the money. Capitali-
sation of interest on unpaid debt is allowed in principle, but not expressly
provided for by the Prescribed Rate of Interest Act 55 of 1975. In Davehill
(Pty) Ltd v Community Development Board106 the South African Appellate
Division considered whether it was permissible, in the absence of agreement,
to award interest on statutory interest payable in terms of legislation on expro-
priation. The court held that the rule against interest on interest in Roman
and Roman-Dutch law has become obsolete in modern South African law.
Commercial agreements involving compound interest are commonplace and
on principle mora interest (a species of damages) could also be claimed on
unpaid interest, statutory interest payable for loss of possession and fruits of
land. The wording of the legislation in question will determine whether it
107
allows for such compound interest.
In Scotland the Late Payment of Commercial Debts (Interest) Act 1998
covers business debts for the supply of goods and services. If the Act applies
to a contract the “qualifying debt” created by the contract carries simple
interest. The Act provides for a particularly high rate of interest, but the rate
is simple rather than compound, a situation clearly not in accordance with
commercial realities.108
In Scotland the general rule, as set out in Nash Dredging (UK) Ltd v
109
Kestrel Marine Ltd, is that interest is not allowed on interest, but there are
occasions where accumulation of principal and interest (capitalisation) is
allowed. A claim for compound interest with annual rests is seldom allowed,
but in some cases it may be legitimate to accumulate outstanding interest
with the principal, and then to claim interest on the whole sum outstanding.
The position in Scotland is complicated by the rule that mere non-payment of
a debt is not sufficient to create a liability for interest. Payment must be
110
“wrongfully withheld”.
111
In Maclean v Campbell the court accumulated the principal and the
105 1978 (1) SA 1109 (A) at 1145G.
106 1988 (1) SA 290 (A).
107 In Boland Bank Ltd v The Master 1991 (3) SA 387 (A), e.g., it was held that s 103(2) read with
s 95(1) of the Insolvency Act 24 of 1936, providing for interest “calculated at the rate of eight per
cent per annum”, payable on a secured claim after date of sequestration, is simple interest, not
compound interest.
108 See McBryde, Contract, paras 22-131–22-135.
109 1987 SLT 67.
110 See on the origins of this rule J Murray, “Interest on debt” 1991 SLT (News) 305 at 306–307.
111 (1856) 18 D 609.
354 european contract law
interest found due as at the date of citation, and allowed interest on the
accumulated sum from that date, but without rests, which were regarded as
being of a penal nature.
In the Nash Dredging case the court found that both the principal and the
outstanding interest had been wrongfully withheld by the debtor. When the
principal sum was paid the interest remained outstanding and the dispute
between the parties concerned the rate of interest to be applied. The
defenders were not entitled to withhold payment of the interest and so to
avoid paying interest on interest. A defender may be regarded as wrongfully
withholding payment even if no decree had been pronounced for payment.
112
Lord Ross concluded as follows:
It appears to me that a distinction requires to be drawn between interest on
arrears of interest on the one hand and compound interest on the other hand. It is
highly unusual for compound interest to be allowed. “A claim for compound
interest, with annual rests, is a demand which can only be maintained, either in the
case of a fixed usage in commercial dealings, or where there has been an abuse in
a party trusted with funds, and violating his trust.” (Douglas v Douglas’s Trustees
(1867) 5 M 827, per Lord Justice-Clerk Patton at p 836). Compound interest
proper does include rests, but interest on arrears without rests may be allowed
when the arrears of interest are treated as the equivalent of the principal sum
(Napier v Gordon; MacClean v Campbell).
The practical effect of both the South African Davehill case and the Scottish
Nash Dredging case is that arrear interest is at one point (and only once)
added to the principal and from then on simple interest runs on the total.
Lord Ross in the Nash Dredging case specifically made the distinction
between the taking of interest on arrear interest on the one hand and com-
pound interest on the other hand. The former indicates a once-off approach,
whereas the latter indicates recurrence of capitalisation at regular intervals or
rests, i.e. annual or monthly. In terms of this distinction Article 17:101 PECL
would qualify as a provision for compound interest with annual rests. The
South African Davehill case professes to support the taking of compound
interest on arrear debt, but applied only a single or once-off capitalisation.
Lord Ross in Nash Dredging stuck firmly to a once-off capitalisation in a case
where it was clear that both principal and interest were at a particular point
being wrongfully withheld.
If interest is to be regarded as a remedy equivalent to damages for the
non-payment of money due, it is difficult to see how a debtor could success-
fully argue on principle that his creditor should not be put into the position
112 At 68.
capitalisation of interest 355
that he would otherwise have been in had he had the use of his money time-
ously.113 The reasonable approach would then be to allow compound interest
with recurrent capitalisation, at least annually, as provided for by Article
17:101 PECL.
The new section was obviously aimed at alleviating the plight of a plaintiff
who has to wait a substantial period of time to establish his claim, through no
121
fault of his own, and is paid in depreciated currency. Section 2A(2)(a) lays
down what is to be the general position, namely that interest runs from date
of demand or summons. If a plaintiff seeks interest from an earlier time then
the court must be urged to exercise its discretion under subsection (5). To
obtain a favourable discretionary decision a plaintiff must discharge the onus
of establishing facts justifying such decision. There is no authority in section
121 Adel Builders (Pty) Ltd v Thompson [2000] 4 All SA 341 (A).
122 See McBryde, Contract, para 22–129.
123 Section 1(2)(a).
124 Section 1(2)(c).
125 PECL, vol 1, 451.
126 PECL, vol 1, 451.
127 2001 (4) SA 551 (SCA).
358 european contract law
overdraft. Thus formulated, the claim was one not for ordinary mora interest
but for additional damages in the form of interest. The court referred with
approval to the following description of such a claim in Bellairs v Hodnett:128
As previously pointed out, mora interest in a case like the present constitutes a
form of damages for breach of contract. The general principle in the assessment of
such damages is that the sufferer by the breach should be placed in the position he
would have occupied had the contract been performed, so far as this can be done
by the payment of money and without undue hardship to the defaulting party.
Accordingly, such damages only are awarded as flow naturally from the breach or
as may reasonably be supposed to have been in the contemplation of the con-
tracting parties as likely to result therefrom (Victoria Falls and Transvaal Power
Co Ltd v Consolidated Langlaagte Mines Ltd 1915 AD 1 at 22). In awarding mora
interest to a creditor who has not received due payment of a monetary debt owed
under contract, the Court seeks to place him in the position he would have
occupied had due payment been made. The Court acts on the assumption that,
had due payment been made, the capital sum would have been productively
employed by the creditor during the period of mora and the interest consequently
represents the damages flowing naturally from the breach of contract.
The court in the Thoroughbred Breeders’ Association case decided that the
claim for interest qua damages, be it general or special, could not succeed,
because it was not proved that the claimant became liable to its banker for the
additional interest claimed. The claimant had failed to prove that, had it not
been for the thefts, its overdraft would have been reduced by the exact
amounts of the thefts and would not, for instance, have been employed for
another purpose.
In Scotland interest may be recovered as a loss for breach of contract in
terms of the principle established by Hadley v Baxendale.129 This means that
liability for interest or loss of interest on money invested must be capable of
being fairly and reasonably considered as arising in the usual course of things
from the breach of contract, or of being reasonably supposed to have been in
the contemplation of both parties at the time they made the contract, as the
130
probable result of the breach of contract. Courts in Scotland have been
reluctant to award interest in terms of these principles in some cases invol-
131
ving cost overruns or late payment in building disputes. This gives rise to
128 1978 (1) SA 1109 (A) at 1146H–1147C.
129 (1854) 9 Ex 341.
130 See Murray, 1991 SLT (News) 305 at 309–311.
131 See Murray, 1991 SLT (News) 305 at 309–311; and see subsequently Margrie Holdings Ltd v
City of Edinburgh District Council 1994 SC 1; Ogilvie Builders Ltd v City of Glasgow District
Council 1995 SLT 15. In the Ogilvie Builders case it was held that in the construction industry
delay in payment to the contractor might naturally result in the ordinary course of things in his
being short of working capital and so having to incur finance charges as those claimed in this
case in the form of “direct loss and / or expense” under the contract.
capitalisation of interest 359
the question whether it is not “in the usual course of things” for a creditor in
such cases either to have to borrow money on which interest would have to be
paid, or to divert funds from other sources on which interest is then lost?
Professor F A Mann has asked rhetorically in this regard: “Who would ven-
ture to suggest that a defaulting debtor could not reasonably foresee interest
as the creditor’s loss flowing from the failure to pay?”132 Professor John
Murray has suggested that the answer to this rhetorical question could be:
133
“The Scottish Judiciary”.
134
An example cited in this regard by the English Law Commission is the
135
case of Hartle v Laceys, where a solicitor knew that his client had borrowed
heavily from the bank at relatively high compound rates of interest and that
he needed to sell property to reduce his borrowing. The solicitor acted
negligently, and so lost his client the opportunity to sell. The court found that
interest could be claimed at compound rates as special damages, because the
issue was in the contemplation of both parties. Where such interest is
claimed it must be specifically pleaded as special damage.
Modern commercial realities indicate that a creditor, who is out of pocket
as a result of breach of contract and has to borrow money on which
compound interest would have to be paid, or to divert funds from invest-
ments on which compound interest is then lost, should be compensated
accordingly.
I. CONCLUSIONS
The following are some conclusions on the need for reform of the law on
capitalisation of interest in Scotland and South Africa, with reference to
Article 17:101 PECL as a possible model for reform.
132 F A Mann, “On interest, compound interest and damages” (1985) 101 LQR 30.
133 Murray, 1991 SLT (News) 305 at 310.
134 Pre-judgment Interest on Debts and Damages Law Com No 287 (2004).
135 [1999] Lloyd’s Rep PN 315, CA; see Law Com No 287, summary, para 2.21.
136 (1884) 12 R 104.
360 european contract law
137 See McBryde, Contract, para 22–118; Murray, 1991 SLT (News) 305.
138 Scot Law Com DP No 127 (2005), paras 3.7 – 3.19.
139 Scot Law Com DP No 127 (2005), para 8.11.
140 Law Com No 287 (2004).
141 Scot Law Com DP No 127 (2005).
142 Law Com No 287, summary, para 4.3.
capitalisation of interest 361
Simple interest does not reflect business practice. When money is borrowed,
interest accrues on outstanding balances which include interest charges already
incurred. For example, where a bank lends money to a customer, there will
normally be regular payments of interest during the term of the loan. If payments
are not made, the outstanding interest is capitalised and interest charged upon it.
Where interest does not compound, it fails to compensate adequately the person
143
to whom money is owed.
144
The Law Reform Commission of British Columbia has found that com-
pounding pre-judgment interest is theoretically desirable in that it would
more accurately reflect both the behaviour of investors in the marketplace
and the cost of delay to successful plaintiffs. The Commission accepts that
the basic rationale for making an award of interest is that the defendant has
kept the plaintiff out of his money and should compensate him accordingly.
This objective cannot be achieved adequately if courts are limited to
awarding simple interest rather than compound interest. At higher interest
rates and in cases where the delay between the due date of payment and the
date of judgment is greater, the degree of under-compensation becomes
more acute. Commentators have decribed the antipathy of courts and
legislatures to compound interest as “a relic from the days when interest was
145
regarded as necessarily usurious”.
143 Aspects of Damages: The Award of Interest on Money Claims, NZ Law Com No 28 (1994), para
24.
144 Report on the Court Order Interest Act, LRC 90 (1987).
145 R Bowles & C J Whelan “The law of interest: dawn of a new era?” (1986) 64 Canadian Bar
Review 142 at 143. See also Bowles & J Whelan, “Compound interest: could multipliers be the
way forward?” (1986) 136 New LJ 876.
146 PECL, vol 1, 451.
362 european contract law
147 Law Com No 287 (2002), summary, para 5.9; and see also Scot Law Com DP No 127 (2005),
para 8.29.
148 Scot Law Com DP No 127 (2005), para 8.38.
149 Law Com No 287 (2002), summary, para 5.16.
150 Law Com No 287 (2002), summary, para 5.31.
capitalisation of interest 363
on their shelves, or for advocates to take to court. It noted that judges would
probably benefit from some training in using the tables.
* This reproduction of the text of the Principles of European Contract Law appears with the kind
permission of the Commission on European Contract Law.
367
368 european contract law
by the first party, and the notice is properly dispatched or given, a delay
or inaccuracy in the transmission of the notice or its failure to arrive does
not prevent it from having effect. The notice shall have effect from the
time at which it would have arrived in normal circumstances.
(5) A notice has no effect if a withdrawal of it reaches the addressee before
or at the same time as the notice.
(6) In this Article, “notice” includes the communication of a promise,
statement, offer, acceptance, demand, request or other declaration.
CHAPTER 2: FORMATION
(2) If the merger clause is not individually negotiated it will only establish a
presumption that the parties intended that their prior statements,
undertakings or agreements were not to form part of the contract. This
rule may not be excluded or restricted.
(3) The parties’ prior statements may be used to interpret the contract. This
rule may not be excluded or restricted except by an individually
negotiated clause.
(4) A party may by its statements or conduct be precluded from asserting a
merger clause to the extent that the other party has reasonably relied on
them.
(2) An offer made to the public can be revoked by the same means as were
used to make the offer.
(3) However, a revocation of an offer is ineffective if:
(a) the offer indicates that it is irrevocable; or
(b) it states a fixed time for its acceptance; or
(c) it was reasonable for the offeree to rely on the offer as being
irrevocable and the offeree has acted in reliance on the offer.
been sent in such circumstances that if its transmission had been normal
it would have reached the offeror in due time, the late acceptance is
effective as an acceptance unless, without delay, the offeror informs the
offeree that it considers its offer as having lapsed.
(a) the agent’s authority has been brought to an end by the principal, the
agent, or both; or
(b) the acts for which the authority had been granted have been com-
pleted, or the time for which it had been granted has expired; or
(c) the agent has become insolvent or, where a natural person, has died
or become incapacitated; or
(d) the principal has become insolvent.
(2) The third party is considered to know that the agent’s authority has been
brought to an end under paragraph(1) (a) above if this has been com-
municated or publicised in the same manner in which the authority was
originally communicated or publicised.
(3) However, the agent remains authorised for a reasonable time to perform
those acts which are necessary to protect the interests of the principal or
its successors.
performance towards the third party, or if prior to the time for performance
it is clear that there will be a fundamental non-performance:
(a) on the third party’s demand, the intermediary shall communicate the
name and address of the principal to the third party; and
(b) the third party may exercise against the principal the rights which the
third party has against the intermediary, subject to any defences which
the intermediary may set up against the third party and those which the
principal may set up against the intermediary.
CHAPTER 4: VALIDITY
Article 4:101: Matters not Covered
This chapter does not deal with invalidity arising from illegality, immorality or
lack of capacity.
CHAPTER 5: INTERPRETATION
Article 5:101: General Rules of Interpretation
(1) A contract is to be interpreted according to the common intention of the
parties even if this differs from the literal meaning of the words.
(2) If it is established that one party intended the contract to have a
particular meaning, and at the time of the conclusion of the contract the
other party could not have been unaware of the first party’s intention, the
contract is to be interpreted in the way intended by the first party.
(3) If an intention cannot be established according to (1) or (2), the contract
is to be interpreted according to the meaning that reasonable persons of
the same kind as the parties would give to it in the same circumstances.
professional supplier unless it did not know and had no reason to know of
the information or undertaking.
and equitable manner the losses and gains resulting from the change
of circumstances.
In either case, the court may award damages for the loss suffered through
a party refusing to negotiate or breaking off negotiations contrary to good
faith and fair dealing.
CHAPTER 7: PERFORMANCE
Article 7:101: Place of Performance
(1) If the place of performance of a contractual obligation is not fixed by or
determinable from the contract it shall be:
(a) in the case of an obligation to pay money, the creditor’s place of
business at the time of the conclusion of the contract;
(b) in the case of an obligation other than to pay money, the debtor’s
place of business at the time of conclusion of the contract.
(2) If a party has more than one place of business, the place of business for
the purpose of the preceding paragraph is that which has the closest
relationship to the contract, having regard to the circumstances known to
or contemplated by the parties at the time of conclusion of the contract.
(3) If a party does not have a place of business its habitual residence is to be
treated as its place of business.
shall terminate automatically. If the period stated is too short, the aggrieved
party may terminate, or, as the case may be, the contract shall terminate
automatically, only after a reasonable period from the time of the notice.
(2) In the case of delay the aggrieved party may also terminate the contract
under Article 8:106 (3).
9:308, does not affect the rights and liabilities that have accrued up to the
time of termination.
(2) Termination does not affect any provision of the contract for the
settlement of disputes or any other provision which is to operate even
after termination.
further loss it has suffered so far as these are recoverable under Section
5 of this Chapter.
may recover the difference between the contract price and the price of the
substitute transaction as well as damages for any further loss so far as these
are recoverable under this Section.
(2) Obligations are separate when each debtor is bound to render only part
of the performance and the creditor may require from each debtor only
that debtor’s part.
(3) An obligation is communal when all the debtors are bound to render the
performance together and the creditor may require it only from all of
them.
any prior right and interest of the creditor, exercise the rights and actions
of the creditor, including accessory securities, to recover the excess from
any of the other debtors to the extent of each debtor’s unperformed
share.
(3) If a solidary debtor who has performed more than that debtor’s share is
unable, despite all reasonable efforts, to recover contribution from
another solidary debtor, the share of the others, including the one who
has performed, is increased proportionally.
(b) the claim and any contract under which it arises will not be modified
without the consent of the assignee unless the modification is provided
for in the assignment agreement or is one which is made in good faith
and is of a nature to which the assignee could not reasonably object; and
(c) the assignor will transfer to the assignee all transferable rights intended
to secure performance which are not accessory rights.
(4) Where the debtor gives performance to the assignor, the debtor is dis-
charged if and only if the performance is given without knowledge of the
assignment.
good faith and fair dealing or co-operation, and if fulfilment would have
operated to that party’s disadvantage, the condition is deemed to be
fulfilled.
(2) If fulfilment of a condition is brought about by a party, contrary to duties
of good faith and fair dealing or co-operation, and if fulfilment operates
to that party’s advantage, the condition is deemed not to be fulfilled.
AXZS Industries v AF Dreyer (Pty) Ltd 2004 (4) SA 186 (W) ............................. 195
A to Z Bazaars (Pty) Ltd v Minister of Agriculture 1974 (4) SA 392 (C) ............... 90
A to Z Bazaars (Pty) Ltd v Minister of Agriculture 1975 (3) SA 468 (AD) ...... 85, 87
Aaron v Landcraft Inc 2005 La App LEXIS 616 ..................................................... 51
Ackermann v Burland and Milunsky 1944 WLD 172 ........................................... 225
Adams v Lindsell (1818) 1 B & Ald 681 ............................................................. 81, 84
Adams v SA Motor Industry Employers Association 1981 (3) SA 1189 (A) ......... 232
Adel Builders (Pty) Ltd v Thompson [2000] 4 All SA 341 (A) .............................. 357
African Organic Fertilizers & Associated Industries Ltd v Sieling
1949 (2) SA 131 (W) .......................................................................................... 301
African Universal Stores Ltd v Dean 1926 CPD 390 .................................... 221, 224
Afrox Healthcare Bpk v Strydom 2002 (6) SA 21 (SCA) ............... 63, 64, 65, 66, 168
Agnew v CIR [2001] 2 AC 710 ............................................................................... 193
Ahmed v Akhtar 1997 SLT 218 .............................................................................. 283
Aktiebolaget Hässle v Triomed (Pty) Ltd 2003 (1) SA 155 (SCA) ........................ 187
Alan (W J) & Co Ltd v El Nasr Export and Import Co [1972] 2 QB 189 (CA) ... 237
Allan’s Trustees v Lord Advocate 1971 SC (HL) 45 .............................................. 218
Amcoal Collieries Ltd v Truter 1990 (1) SA 1 (A) ................................................... 83
Amoils v Amoils 1924 WLD 88 .............................................................................. 251
Anderson v Pringle of Scotland 1998 SLT 754 ...................................................... 263
Ankon CC v Tadkor Properties (Pty) Ltd 1991 (3) SA 119 (C) ............................ 285
Arlyn Butcheries (Pty) Ltd v Bosch 1966 (2) SA 308 (W) .................................... 254
Armagas Ltd v Mundogas SA [1986] 1 AC 717 ..................................................... 126
Armia Ltd v Daejan Developments Ltd 1979 SC (HL) 56 ................................... 129
Armstrong v Magid 1937 AD 260 .......................................................................... 158
Atkinson v Vause’s Executors (1892) 13 NLR 85 .................................................. 251
Atteridgeville Town Council v Livanos 1992 (1) SA 296 (A) ................................ 297
Aucamp v Morton 1949 (3) SA 611 (A) ................................................................. 284
Avintair Ltd v Ryder Airline Services Ltd 1994 SC 270 ........................................ 106
415
416 european contract law
Bagradi v Cavendish Transport Co (Pty) Ltd 1957 (1) SA 663 (D) .............. 224, 227
Bal v Van Staden 1902 TS 128 .................................................................................. 84
Balfour Beatty Construction (Scotland) Ltd v Scottish Power plc
1994 SC (HL) 20 ................................................................................ 274, 275, 276
Bank of Credit and Commerce International v Ali [2002] 1 AC 251 ... 181, 182, 183
Bank of Montreal v Bail Ltd [1992] 2 SCR 554 ...................................................... 53
Bank of Montreal v Kuet Leong Ng [1989] 2 SCR 429 .......................................... 53
Bank of Scotland v Brunswick Developments (1987) Ltd (No 2)
1998 SLT 439 ............................................................................................. 127, 129
Bank of Scotland v Dunedin Property Investment Co 1998
SC 657 ........................................................................................ 186, 189, 190, 191
Bank of Scotland v Junior 1999 SCLR 284 .................................................... 186, 194
Banque national de Paris (Canada) v 165836 Canada Inc [2004] 2 SCR 45 .......... 53
Barclays Bank Ltd v W J Simms Son & Cooke (Southern) Ltd
[1979] 3 All ER 522 (QB) .......................................................................... 242, 245
Barclays Bank plc v O’Brien [1994] 1 AC 180 ................................... 56, 62, 167, 172
Barker v Beckett & Co Ltd 1911 TPD 151 ........................................................... 251
Barnard v Barnard 2000 (3) SA 741 (C) ................................................................ 168
Barnett v Abe Swersky & Associates 1986 (4) SA 407 (C) .................................... 213
Barnhoorn v Duvenhage 1964 (2) SA 486 (A) ....................................................... 256
Basson v Chilwan 1993 (3) SA 742 (A) .......................................................... 251, 254
Beeton v Peninsula Transport Co (Pty) Ltd 1934 CPD 53 ................................... 258
Bellairs v Hodnett 1978 (1) SA 1109 (A) ............................................... 336, 353, 358
Belshaw v Bush (1851) 11 CB 191 (138 ER 444) .................................................. 244
Bennett v Inveresk Paper Co (1891) 18 R 975 .............................................. 146, 149
Benson v SA Mutual Life Assurance Society 1986 (1)
SA 776 (A) .................................................................................. 252, 255, 256, 257
Beswick v Beswick [1968] AC 58 ................................................................... 204, 205
Bieber-Guillory v Aswell 723 So 2d 1145 (1998) ..................................................... 52
Blair’s Trustees v Payne (1884) 12 R 104 ............................................................... 359
Bloom v American Swiss Watch Co 1915 AD 100 .................................................. 83
Blumer v Scott (1874) 1 R 379 ............................................................................... 218
BOE Bank v Van Zyl 2002 (5) SA 165 (C) ....................................................... 64, 157
Bok Clothing Manufacturers (Pty) Ltd v Lady Land (Pty) Ltd
1982 (2) SA 565 (C) ........................................................................................... 107
Boland Bank Ltd v Pienaar 1988 (3) SA 618 (A) ................................................... 295
Boland Bank Ltd v The Master 1991 (3) SA 387 (A) ............................................ 353
Bolt & Nut Co (Tipton) v Rowlands, Nicholls & Co [1964] 2 QB 10 .................. 233
Botha (now Griessel) v Finanscredit (Pty) Ltd 1989 (3) SA 773 (A) .................... 164
Bovis Construction Ltd v Whatlings Construction Ltd 1994 SLT 865 ................. 190
Brinkibon Ltd v Stahag Stahl und Stahlwarenhandelsgesselschaft mbH
[1982] 1 All ER 293 (HL) .............................................................................. 80, 82
Brisley v Drotsky 2002 (4) SA 1 (SCA) .............................. 63, 66, 164, 174, 251, 260
British Bata Shoe Co Ltd v Double M Shah Ltd 1980 SC 311 ............ 127, 132, 145
British Road Services v Arthur Crutchley [1968] 1 All ER 811 .................... 102, 121
list of cases 417
Co-operative Insurance Society Ltd v Argyll Stores (Holdings) Ltd [1998] AC 1261
Co-operative Insurance Society Ltd v Halfords Ltd 1998 SC 212 ....................... 263
Coopers & Lybrand v Bryant 1995 (3) SA 761 (A) ................................ 187, 189, 191
Coronation Syndicate, Re 1903 TH 254 ................................................................ 256
Cosar Ltd v UPS Ltd 1999 SLT 259 ...................................................................... 276
Cowan v Pomeroy 1952 (3) SA 645 (C) ................................................................. 254
Cowley v Estate Loumeau1925 AD 392 ................................................................ 287
Craig (A F) & Co Ltd v Blackater 1923 SC 472 .................................................... 139
Crawley v Rex 1909 TS 1105 .................................................................................... 77
Credit Lyonnais Bank Nederland NV v Burch [1997] 1 All ER 144 .................... 168
Cresswell v Potter [1978] 1 WLR 255 ................................................................... 163
Crookes NO v Watson 1956 (1) SA 277 (A) ........................................... 206, 212, 216
Cullinan v Noordkaaplandse Aartappelkernmoerkwekers Koöperasie
Beperk. 1972 (1) SA 761 (A) ..................................................................... 137, 138
Culverwell v Brown 1990 (1) SA 7 (A) ................................................................... 283
Cumming v Brown 1994 SLT (Sh Ct) 11 ............................................... 291, 292, 306
Cumming v Quartzag Ltd 1980 SC 276 ................................................................. 215
Cunningham’s Trustees v Hutton (1847) 10 D 307 ............................................... 243
Edinburgh Grain Ltd v Marshall Food Group Ltd 1999 SLT 15 ......................... 283
Eerste Nasionale Bank van Suidelike Afrika Bpk v Saayman NO
1997 (4) SA 302 (SCA) .......................................................................... 62, 63, 171
Elgin Brown & Hamer (Pty) Ltd v Industrial Machinery Suppliers
(Pty) Ltd 1993 (3) SA 424 (A) ........................................................................... 284
Emslie v African Merchants Ltd 1908 EDC 82 ............................................ 271, 272
Entores Ltd v Miles Far East Corporation [1955] 2 QB 327 ........................... 80, 82
Eriksen Motors (Welkom) Ltd v Protea Motors, Warrenton
1973 (3) SA 685 (A) ........................................................................................... 232
Esso Petroleum Co Ltd v Harpers Garage (Stourport) Ltd [1968] AC 269 ........ 264
Esterhuyse v Selection Cartage (Pty) Ltd 1965 (1) SA 360 (W) ........................... 232
Extel Industrial (Pty) Ltd v Crown Mills (Pty) Ltd 1999 (2) SA 719 (SCA) ........ 301
GL Group plc v Ash Gupta Advertising Ltd 1987 SCLR 149 .............................. 288
Gardner v Richardt 1974 (3) SA 768 (C) ............................................................... 221
Gayather v Rajkali 1947 (4) SA 706 (D) ................................................................ 208
Ghaznavi v BP Oil (UK) Ltd 1991 SLT 924 .......................................................... 284
Gibson v Manchester City Council [1978] 1 WLR 520, [1979]
1 WLR 297 (HL) ............................................................................................... 101
Gibson v Woodhead Plant Ltd 1918 AD 308 ........................................................ 253
Glasgow (E & J) Ltd v UGC Estates Ltd [2005] CSOH 63 .................................... 67
Glasgow Pavilion Ltd v Motherwell (1903) 6 F 116 .............................................. 231
420 european contract law
Glofinco v Absa Bank Ltd (t/a United Bank) 2002 (6) SA 470 (SCA) ..... 127, 129, 132
Goodwood Racecourse Ltd v Satelite Information Services Ltd
2004 EWHC 2346 (Ch) ..................................................................................... 226
Gordon v Tarnow 1947 (3) SA 525 (A) .................................................................. 232
Govender v Standard Bank of South Africa Ltd 1984 (4) SA 392 (C) .................. 242
Gracie v Hull Blythe and Co (SA) Ltd 1931 CPD 539 ......................................... 258
Grahame v Magistrates of Kirkcaldy (1882) 9 R (HL) 91 ..................................... 262
Grant (William) & Sons Ltd v Glen Catrine Bonded Warehouse Ltd
2001 SC 901 ....................................................................................... 129, 131, 134
Gray v Binny (1879) 7 R 332 .................................................................................... 58
Grobbelaar v Bosch 1964 (3) SA 687 (E) ............................................................... 283
Grosvenor Developments (Scotland) plc v Argyle Stores Ltd 1987 SLT 738 ...... 261
Grundt v Great Boulder Pty Gold Mines Ltd (1937) 59 CLR 641 ...................... 134
Guncrete (Pty) Ltd v Scharrighuisen Construction (Pty) Ltd
1996 (2) SA 682 (N) ........................................................................................... 107
Ideal Fastener Corp CC v Book Vision (Pty) Ltd (t/a Colour Graphic)
2001 (3) SA 1028 (D) ................................................................................... 83, 101
Industrial & Mercantile Corporation v Anastassiou Bros 1973 (2)
SA 601 (W) ................................................................................................. 253, 258
Info Plus v Scheelke 1998 (3) SA 184 (SCA) ......................................................... 241
Ingle Colonial Broom Co Ltd v Hocking 1914 CPD 495 ..................................... 251
Inrybelange (Edms) Bpk v Pretorius 1966 (2) SA 416 (A) .................................... 293
Interaccess (Pty) Ltd v Van Dorsten [1999] 2 All SA 561 (C) .............................. 346
Interfoto Picture Library Ltd v Stiletto Visual Programmes Ltd
[1989] QB 433 ...................................................................................................... 45
Investors Compensation Scheme v West Bromwich Building
Society [1998] 1 WLR 896 ........................................ 181, 182, 186, 187, 188, 198
Irvine & Co v Watson (1874) QBD 414 ................................................................. 146
ISEP Structural Engineering and Plating (Pty) Ltd v Inland
Exploration Co (Pty) Ltd 1981 (4) SA 1 (A) ..................................... 257, 258, 260
LTA Construction Bpk v Administrateur, Transvaal 1992 (1) SA 473 (A) .... 348, 349
Laemthong International Lines Co Ltd v Artis [2005] All ER (D) 50,
[2005] 1 Lloyd’s Rep 100 ................................................................................... 213
Langverwacht Farming Co v Sedgwick & Co Ltd (II) 1942 CPD 155 ................ 295
Lavery & Co Ltd v Jungheinrich 1931 AD 156 ............................................. 272, 273
Laws v Rutherford 1924 AD 261 ............................................................................. 83
Le Roux v Odendaal 1954 (4) SA 432 (N) ............................................................. 256
Leggat Brothers v Gray 1908 SC 67 ........................................................ 231, 233–34
Levben Products (Pty) Ltd v Alexander Films (SA) (Pty) Ltd 1959 (3)
SA 208 (SR) .................................................................................................... 89, 90
Levin v May 887 So 2d 497 (2004) ........................................................................... 51
Leviseur v Scott 1922 OPD 138 ..................................................................... 293, 294
Libertas-Kommerz GmbH v Johnson 1977 SC 191 .............................................. 314
Linden Gardens Trust Ltd v Lenesta Sludge Disposal Ltd [1994] 1 AC 85 ........ 223
Lindley Catering Investments Ltd v Hibernian Football Club Ltd
1975 SLT (Notes) 56 .......................................................................................... 292
Lindsay Plant Ltd v Norwest Group plc 2000 SC 93 ............................................ 186
Lines v Liberty Life Association of Africa Ltd 1990 (3) SA 268 (T) ....................... 83
Linton v Corser 1952 (3) SA 685 (A) ..................................................................... 336
Littlejohn v Hadwen (1882) 20 SLR 5 ..................................................................... 88
Lloyds Bank Ltd v Bundy [1975] QB 326.............................................................. 171
Lobb (Alec) (Garages) Ltd v Total Oil (Great Britain) Ltd [1983]
1 WLR 87 ................................................................................................... 162, 163
Logan (David) & Sons Ltd v Schuldt (1903) 10 SLT 598 ..................................... 145
list of cases 423
Lombard v Pongola Sugar Milling Co Ltd 1963 (4) SA 860 (A) ........................... 169
Longhorn Group (Pty) Ltd v The Fedics Group (Pty) Ltd 1995 (3)
SA 836 (W) ......................................................................................................... 253
Love v Amalgamated Society of Lithographic Printers of Great Britain
and Ireland 1912 SC 1078 ................................................................................. 220
Lynch v DPP of Northern Ireland [1975] AC 653 ........................................ 153, 154
OTM Ltd v Hydranautics [1981] 2 Lloyd’s Rep 211 ..................................... 100, 119
O’Leary v Harbord (1888) 5 HCG 1 ...................................................................... 146
Oatarian Properties (Pty) Ltd v Maroun 1973 (3) SA 779 (A) .............................. 284
Ogilvie Builders Ltd v City of Glasgow District Council 1995 SLT 15 ................ 358
Talacchi v The Master 1997 (1) SA 702 (T) ................................................... 144, 145
Tamarillo (Pty) Ltd v BN Aitken (Pty) Ltd 1982 (1) SA 398 (A) .................. 256, 283
Tay Valley Joinery Ltd v CF Financial Services Ltd 1987 SLT 207 ...................... 323
Taylor v Hoddard (1886) 2 SAR 78 ........................................................................ 167
Tel Peda Investigation Bureau (Pty) Ltd v Van Zyl 1965 (4) SA 475 (E) ......... 83, 85
Theron v Africa 10 SC 246 ..................................................................................... 302
Thompson v Pullinger (1894) 1 OR 298 ........................................................ 256, 257
Thomson v Davenport (1829) 9 B & C 78 ............................................................. 146
Thomson v James (1855) 18 D 1 ...................................................... 80, 81, 82, 87, 90
Thomson v Thomas Muir (Waste Management) Ltd 1995 SLT 403 ...................... 67
Thoroughbred Breeders’ Association v Price Waterhouse
2001 (4) SA 551 (SCA) ...................................................................... 273, 274, 278
Tinnevelley Sugar Refining Co Ltd v Mirrlees, Watson and Yaryan Co Ltd
(1894) 21 R 1009 ........................................................................................ 357, 358
Tjollo Ateljees (Eins) Bpk v Small 1949 (1) SA 856 (A) ........................................ 163
Total South Africa (Pty) Ltd v Bekker 1992 (1) SA 617 (A) .................................. 212
Trade Development Bank v David W Haig (Bellshill) Ltd 1983 SLT 510 ....... 56, 57
Tradesmen’s Benefit Society v Du Preez (1887) 5 SC 269 ........... 204, 205, 206, 208
Transnet Ltd v Goodman Brothers (Pty) Ltd 2001 (1) SA 853 (SCA) ................... 67
Transnet Ltd v Sechaba Photoscan (Pty) Ltd 2005 (1) SA 299 (SCA) .................... 68
Trever Investments v Friedhelm 1982 (1) SA 7 (A) .............................................. 226
428 european contract law
The Index is arranged letter by letter. References are to page numbers. References to
footnotes are in the form of page number followed by ‘n’: 36n refers to a footnote on
page 36. Names are indexed if they are discussed or quoted in the text.
430
index 431
invoice discounting, 322, 323, 324 first shot rule, 104, 109, 110, 111, 112,
knowledge of, 314 113, 117, 118, 120, 121
meaning, 307 holistic approach, 101
multiple or global, 321–6 last shot theory, 102, 109, 110, 113,
nemo dat rule, 318, 324 117, 121
notification, 313, 316, 317, 320–1, 322, material contract terms, 103, 106
323, 324–5 objectivity, 102
obligationary aspect, 313–15 orthodox approach, 102, 109, 110, 113,
payment instruction, 320, 321, 322 117, 121
PECL, 308, 309–10, 313–19, 321, PECL, 119–22
322–30 PICC, 116–19
personal rights, 326–7, 329 qualified acceptance, 100
PICC, 320–1 Scots law, 103–7, 109–11, 121, 122
priorities, 316–18, 320–1, 323, 324–5 South African approach, 107–9
proprietary aspects, 316–18 UCC, 112–13
publicity, 324, 325, 326 Bavaria, 19
public registry, 324 Beale, H, 47–8, 71, 72
Scots law, 310–12, 322–3, 328–9 Bell, G J, 57, 139, 146, 243, 247
South African law, 310–12, 328–9 BGB
substitution, 314 drafting, 11
theoretical nature, 326–9 interest rates, 345
third parties, 315, 316, 319–20 Bingham, Lord, 45, 181, 183
timing, 316–17, 323 Bologna, 8, 9
transfer agreement, 310, 311 bona fides, 17, 57, 58
transfer construction, 326–9 boni mores, 14
transfer of right, 311, 312, 318–19, Botha, J A, 254
326–9 Brand, F, (JA), 49, 66–7
trust, use of, 323, 329 breach of contract
UCC, 330 anticipatory, 283, 287–9, 291, 306
UN Convention on Assignment of fundamental, 282–7, 306
Receivables in International Trade, generally, 27–8
319–21, 324 interest as a form of special damages,
utility of regime, 321–6 357–9, 363–4
Auslobung, 31 material, 282–7, 289, 306
Austria, 11, 19, 25, 121 tender to cure see tender to cure
autonomous harmonisation of contract termination see termination for breach
law, 40 of contract
Avant-projet, 5, 6, 7 see also specific implement; specific
performance
Bankton, Lord, 57, 242 Bridge, L J, 102
Bartolus, 15 Bridge, M, 46, 303
battle of forms British Columbia Law Reform
CISG, 113–16 Commission, 361
classical or orthodox approach, 102, 109 Brodie, D, 49
clause paramount, 104, 109, 110, 111, business contract, 99n
112, 113, 117, 118, 120, 121
counter-offer, 100–3, 105 Canada
English law, 100–3 British Columbia Law Reform
EU, lack of uniform approach, 121 Commission, 361
432 index
prior communings, 189, 190 lex non cogit ad impossibilia, 255, 262
rectification, 195–6 lex Non Dubium, 13
reliance interests of third parties, 201 limitation of actions, 40
rules of evidence, 195 literature
Scots law, 186–8, 189–91, 192 interest and usury in, 340–1
South African law, 187–8, 191, 192–3 legal, 34
starting point, 196–7 Litvinoff, S, 50–1
subjective starting point, 196–7 Louisiana, good faith, 49–52, 69
subsequent conduct, 192–3, 199–200
substantive rules, 195 McBryde, W W, 55–6, 80n, 82n, 165
third parties, reliance interests, 201 McKendrick, E, 172
true intention of parties, 186 MacQueen, H L, 233–4, 242, 243, 244–5,
UN Convention on International Sale 263, 276, 292
of Goods, 180 mashonisas, 347
unified approach, 196–7 Max Planck Institute, Hamburg, 39
unilateral juridical acts, 200–1 metus reverentialis, 32, 173
Ireland, 29 Molinaeus, 271
Islam, views on interest, 340 mora, meaning, 342, 343, 351
Israel, good faith, 54–5, 69 mora interest
Italy, Codice Civile, 5, 14, 20, 184, 178 additional finance charges, 355–6
ius commune capitalisation, 351–5
background to PECL, as, 33–4, 36 entitlement, 351
codification, 10–12 generally, 336
European legal tradition, as, 8–19 New Zealand Law Commission, 352
ius quaesitum tertio, 209, 218, 222, 223 PECL, 351–2, 355
Scots law, 353–4
Jakobs, H H, 11, 30 Scottish Law Commission, 352
Jhering, R von, 18, 20 South African law, 353, 354, 355–6
Joubert, D J, 252, 253, 349 mutuum, 339
Justinian, 9, 23, 271, 341, 351
negative obligation, 252, 253–4
Kames, Lord, 57 negotiations
Kerr, A J, 150 good faith and fair dealing in, 45–6
Kerridge, E, 340 prior to contract formation, 76
Keynes, J M, 334 negotiorum gestio, 241
Kötz, H, 70–1 nemo dat rule, 318, 324, 328
Kotzé, J P, 84–5 Netherlands
abuse of circumstances, 162, 169, 170
Laband, 20 battle of forms, 121
laesio enormis doctrine, 160–2, 163, 164, generally, 11, 14, 36
165, 168 PECL references, 38, 39
Lando Commission, 4, 7, 197 presumptions, 173
language, 6, 34 representation, 20
latent defects, 337 set-off, 23
Lawton, L J, 102 see also Dutch Civil Code
legal scholarship, PECL and, 38–9 New Zealand Law Commission, Aspects
legal training, 40–1 of Damages: Awards of Interest on
legislation, comparative, 36–7 Money Claims, 352, 360–1
letter of credit, 236–7, 239 Nienaber, J A, 273, 274, 294, 311
index 437
non-performance payment
definition, 282n cash, 231, 232n
generally, 27 cheque, 231–2, 239
good faith and fair dealing, 45, 46–7 cheque as conditional payment, 232–3,
termination for, 24, 298, 305 234
unitary concept, 282–3, 306 cheque as novation, 233, 234
see also performance; termination for conditional, 232–3, 234, 236, 237
breach of contract conditionality of acceptance of
Norway, 12 substituted performance, 239, 240
novation, 233, 234, 237 credit cards, 235–6, 239, 240
numerus clausus, 256 form and manner generally, 230
legal tender, 231, 240
obligation letter of credit, 236–7, 239
assignment, 313–15 methods, 231
imprecise, 259 ‘ordinary course of business’, 238
monetary, 263, 265, 268 PECL principles, 238–9
negative, 252, 253–4 principles from South African and
non-monetary, 252, 254–5, 265–7, 268 Scots law, 237–8
Odersky, W, 37 ‘promise to pay’, 239
offer and acceptance promissory note, 231, 239
assent, 78 wrongful withholding, 351
burden of proof, 77–8 see also capitalisation of interest
condition not fulfilled, 78n payment by third party
consideration, 76 assent of debtor, with, 246
counter-offer, 78 bank as instrument, 241–2, 245
dispatch rule, 75 enrichment claim, 241, 242, 247
display of goods, 77 generally, 240
generally, 74–5, 95–7 legitimate interest, 246
intention to be bound, 76 negotiorum gestio, 241
inter absentes contracting, 75; see also PECL comparisons, 246–8
contract formation inter absentes Pothier argument, 240–1, 242, 247
late acceptance, 94 Scots law, 242–5
mailbox rule, 75 South African law, 240–2
model, 75–8 two categories of third parties, 246
PECL, 91–5 unauthorised, 243, 244, 245, 246, 247
postal rule, 75 unauthorised cheque, 241–2, 245
reception theory, 91–5 validity, 240–1
revocation prior to acceptance, 78, 80n PECL see Principles of European
risk allocation, 92–5 Contract Law
overborne will theory, 153–4, 175 penalty provisions, 22–3, 122
peregrinatio academica, 9
pacta sunt servanda, 18, 20, 251, 260, performance
265, 269 anticipatory non-performance, 27
Papinian, 178 counter-performance, 298
partial invalidity, 16 defective, 283
Patton, L J-C, 333 impossible, 255, 262, 266–7, 268, 299–
Paulus, 154 302
Pavia Academy of European Private late, 291–2
Lawyers, 68; see also Gandolfi non-conforming, 293
438 index
South African law, 293–5, 296 ultimatum procedure, 287, 292–3, 306
time is of the essence, 290, 291 unjustified enrichment, 300, 301, 302,
ultimatum, 292–3, 306 303–4
verbal statement of intention, 290 verbal statement of intention, 290
see also termination for breach of winding-up regime, 296, 305
contract terms of the contract
termination for breach of contract ‘clear and precise’, 184
accidental destruction of property, 299, implied, 194
301, 303, 304–5 see also interpretation of contract
anticipatory breach, 283, 287–9, 291, Theodosius, Emperor, 13
306 third party
cancellation, 281n assignment, 315, 316, 319–20
conforming performance, 292 autonomy of individuals, 174
consequences, 296–305 duress, 171–4
counter-performance, 298 duties to warn and advise, 172, 174
defective performance, 283, 284 good faith, 171n, 172
defects arising in leased property, 295 interest of the surety, 172, 172, 174
delay, 283, 284, 285–6, 287, 290, 291 presumptions, 173, 174
extra-judicial way, 40 sexually transmitted debt, 171
fundamental breach, 282–7, 306 undue influence and, 171–4
generally, 40, 281–2, 305–6 third-party contract
grounds, 282–96 acceptance, 216, 217, 219, 220, 225
impossibility, 299–302 acquisition of right, 207–8
late performance, 291–2 adiectus solutionis causa, 213
lex commissoria, 295 amendment without third party
material breach, 282–7, 289, 306 consent, 216–20
mutual restitution, 296–7 automatic acquisition of rights, 205–6,
non-conforming performance, 293 209
non-performance, 282–3, 305, 306 beneficiary, change, 220
PECL, 290–1, 297–300 beneficiary, identification of, 214–15
performance, 282–3, 284, 289, 305, benefits, 207, 213–14
306 burdens, 212
personal bar, 292 cancellation due to breach of one
positive malperformance, 283, 284 party, 227
property value reduced due to non- damages claim, 223–5
performance, 298 defences, limitation of agreements on,
purgatio morae, 294, 295 228
remediability, 293 determination of reliance, 216, 217
rescission, 281n doctrine of valuable consideration and,
repudiation, 283, 284, 288–9 206
repudiation retracted, 292, 294–5 double jeopardy, 225
restitution, 299–305 duties, 212
restoration inability, 299, 300–1 enforcement, 204–7, 221–5
Scots law, 291–3, 295, 296, 302–4 estoppel, 227
South African law, 293–5, 296, 298, generally, 203–4, 228–9
300–2 immunities, 211–12
tender to cure, 289–96, 306 inference, 214
time is of the essence, 283, 284, 285–6, intention, 214
289, 290, 291 irrevocability, 218, 219, 220
index 443