WP 2018-66 0 PDF
WP 2018-66 0 PDF
WP 2018-66 0 PDF
2018-66
Marcio Garcia†
PUC-Rio, CNPq and FAPERJ
Joao Ayres
Inter-American Development Bank
Diogo Guillen
Itau-Unibanco Asset Management
Patrick Kehoe
Stanford University, Federal Reserve Bank of
Minneapolis, and University College London
Abstract
Brazil had a long period of high inflation. It peaked around 100% per year in
1964, and accelerated again in the 1970s, reaching levels above 100% on average
between 1980 and 1994. This last period coincided with severe balance of payments
problems and economic stagnation that followed the external debt crisis in the early
1980s. We show that the high-inflation period (1960-1994) was characterized by a
combination of deficits, passive monetary policy, and constraints to debt financing.
The transition to the low-inflation period (1995-2016) was characterized by
improvements in all those instances, but it did not lead to significant improvements
in economic growth. In addition, we document a strong correlation between
inflation rates and seigniorage revenues, but observing that the underlying inflation
rates are too high for the modest levels of seigniorage revenues. Finally, we discuss
the role of monetary passiveness and indexation in accounting for the unique
features of the inflation dynamics in Brazil in comparison to the other Latin
American countries.
∗
We would also like to thank Marcelo Abreu, Pérsio Arida, Edmar Bacha, Marco Basseto, Tiago Berriel, Afonso
Bevilaqua, Amaury Bier, Claudio Considera, Gustavo Franco, Fabio Giambiagi, Clau- dio Jaloretto, Eduardo Loyo, Timothy
Kehoe, Randy Kroszner, Pedro Malan, Rodolfo Manuelli, Juan Pablo Nicolini, Affonso Pastore, Murilo Portugal, Thomas
Sargent, Rogério Werneck, and participants of the workshops on The Monetary and Fiscal History of Latin America held in
Chicago, Buenos Aires (LACAE-LAMES meetings), and Rio de Janeiro (hosted by PUC-Rio). This project has been
coordinated by Marcio Garcia.
†
The order of authors was selected randomly.
1 Introduction
This Chapter presents the monetary and fiscal history of Brazil between 1960 and
2016, with emphasis on the hyperinflation episodes. It describes the evolution of the
Brazilian monetary and fiscal policy institutions and how they relate to episodes of
macroeconomic instability and growth experience, focusing on the high-inflation period
(pre–1994) and two stabilization plans: the Government Economic Action Plan (PAEG)
and the Real Plan. The PAEG, in 1964, stabilized an inflation of around 100% per year,
whereas the Real Plan, in 1994, stabilized an inflation of around 80% per month after six
failed attempts in over a decade. The analysis follows the conceptual framework in
Chapter 2, by focusing on the government budget constraint.
A summary of the period is illustrated in Figure 1, in which we show the evolution of
real GDP per capita, inflation, and government deficit for the 1960–2016 period. Three
subperiods are identified: (1) 1960–1980, fast economic growth with high inflation; (2)
1981–1994, slow growth with hyperinflation; and (3) 1995–2016, moderate growth with
low inflation. The average deficit is similar across subperiods, being roughly the same in
the earliest two subperiods and lower in the most recent one.1 One must bear in mind that
fiscal statistics for earlier periods before 1997 are very flawed. For example, the deficit
series in Figure 1c does not include investment by state-owned enterprises (SOEs) before
1985, and in the next sections we show that it represented an important source of
government expenses in the earliest subperiods.2 The 1981–1994 subperiod stands out
not only by its poor growth performance and hyperinflation, but also by severe balance of
payments problems, a common feature among highly indebted Latin American countries
affected by the increase in international interest rates and the slowdown in international
economic growth.
When relating the episodes of macroeconomic instability to the government fiscal and
monetary policies, we observe the following: (a) both stabilization plans, PAEG in 1964
and Real Plan in 1994, included measures to improve fiscal balances (although in the
case of the Real Plan they took longer to be consolidated) and were followed by increased
access to debt financing; (b) the government policy to increase public investment in the
wake of the first oil shock in 1973 explains the rapid increase in external debt that
preceded the external debt crisis of 1983; and (c) the high-inflation periods (pre-1994)
were characterized by the combination of fiscal deficits, passive monetary policy, and
constraints to debt financing, while the transition to the low-inflation period (1995-
2016) was associated with improvements in government fiscal balances, higher de facto
independence of the monetary authority (Brazil still lacks a formally independent Central
1
See Chapter 2 for the definition of deficit we use. It is the primary deficit over GDP plus real interest
expenditures on debt discounting for real GDP growth.
2
We refer the reader to the Data Appendix for a detailed description of the data and methodology.
Bank), as well as much larger access to debt financing.
In comparison to other Latin American countries, the following two characteristics
make the Brazilian experience rather unique: a long period of high inflation, with annual
inflation rates, on average, above 100% between 1980 and 1994, and modest levels of
deficits for very high underlying inflation rates. We discuss two features that may explain
these unique characteristics of the Brazilian hyperinflation: first, a poor institutional
framework in which other public entities besides the monetary authority had indirect
control over money issuance (we discuss that in Section 4.1); second, the combination of
a high degree of indexation in the economy to past inflation with a passive monetary
policy.3 Together, both features have created what has been called inflation inertia, which
could explain why the Brazilian hyperinflation was a much more protracted process than
elsewhere, and gave many the illusion that it could be cured without major improvements
in the fiscal stance. We discuss this issue in Section 4.2 and in our final remarks.
This study is organized as follows: in Section 2, we present a summary of the
government budget constraint; in Section 3, we provide a historical description of each
of the subperiods 1960–1980, 1981–1994, and 1995-2016; in Section 4 we discuss the
evolution of the institutional framework involving both fiscal and monetary authorities
and the genesis of inflation inertia; in Section 5, we present our final remarks and
conclusion.
3 Historical description
3.1.1 1960–1964
Before 1964, the separation between monetary and fiscal policy institutions in Brazil
was almost nonexistent, in the sense that the government treasury had total control
over money issuance. That was done through the Bank of Brazil (BB), which had the
monopoly over money issuance and operated in many instances as the bank of the
government, a commercial bank, and a development bank. Technically, the Super-
intendency of Money and Credit (SUMOC) was the monetary authority, but its council
was mainly composed of BB employees. At the time, the main monetary policy
instruments that SUMOC used were control over the monetary base expansion,
subsidized credit to the industrial and agricultural sectors, and interventions in the
foreign exchange market. Some of those interventions aimed to protect the local
industry by imposing restrictions on imports of products that were also produced
locally, that is, they were used to implement import-substitution policies.11 There
8
Data from the Brazilian Institute of Geography and Statistics (IBGE).
9
For thorough analyses of that period, we refer to Orenstein and Sochaczewski (2014), Mesquita
(2014), Resende (2014), Lago (2014), and C arneiro (2014).
10
The other well-known Brazilian SOEs Companhia Siderúrgica Nacional (CSN), Companhia Vale do
Rio Doce, and Petrobras had been created in 1941, 1942, and 1953, respectively.
11
That was done through both quantity (restricted access to foreign currency) and price restrictions.
was no centralized market in which one could trade government debt securities in
Brazil. Debt contracts were very heterogeneous and faced legal limits on the nominal
interest rates that could be charged (12% per year).12 With rising inflation, that led to a
decrease in the stock of domestic debt before 1964 (Figure 2), while seigniorage
revenues became the main source of funds for the government to cover its fiscal deficits,
as Table 1 shows. Access to external debt was restricted in that period. Brazil had a
balance of payments crisis in 1952, and faced balance of payments problems again in
the late 1950s.13
On the fiscal side, Brazil already had a diverse set of tax instruments, such as income,
import, and consumption taxes. They were cumulative instead of value-added taxes, and
amounted to around 15% of GDP (Figure 3). There were no fiscal rules such as limits to
fiscal deficits, and the government could adopt expansionary policies without explicitly
indicating how to finance them.
In 1956–1961, President Juscelino Kubitschek launched the first major national
development plan, the Targets Plan, which had ambitious goals to create the necessary
infrastructure to facilitate the industrialization process in Brazil. The transportation and
energy sectors were the main targets, and the country observed a rapid expansion of its
highway and electric energy systems. That plan also became famous for the creation of
the new capital city, Brasilia. Besides relying on government funds, that plan also counted
with large foreign direct investment, especially in the automotive industry. During its
implementation, Brazil experienced high growth rates in real GDP per capita, but entered
a recession in the following years (1962 and 1963), accompanied by rising fiscal deficits
and inflation. That crisis was followed by a military coup in 1964, and by the
implementation of an economic stabilization program in 1964–1967, PAEG, that aimed
to stop the inflationary process and resume growth through fiscal and financial
reforms.14
PAEG was launched in November 1964. At that time, there was a clear relationship
between inflation and the expansion of the monetary base (Figure 4), so the government
understood that it should find alternative ways to finance its expenditures and investment
projects other than through seigniorage revenues. The government tackled that problem
on two fronts: a fiscal reform to decrease government deficits and a financial reform to
create other financing options. On the fiscal side, the government increased its tax
revenues to around 23% of GDP (Figure 3) and managed to reduce its fiscal deficits, as
illustrated in Table 1 subperiod 1965–1972. That was achieved through the creation of
new taxes, increases in existing tax rates, and modernization of the tax system with the
introduction of a value-added tax. On the financial side, the main changes were the
introduction of monetary correction (indexation) to circumvent the legal limits on
nominal interest rates, the creation of the Central Bank of Brazil (CBB), and the adoption
12
See Silva (2009) and Pedras (2009) for the history of the Brazilian government debt.
13
In the late 1950s, Brazil started negotiations with the International Monetary Fund (IMF), but the
negotiations were suspended as Brazil did not accept its conditions.
14
The military dictatorship would last until 1985.
of a banking system based on a clear-cut separation among commercial banks and
nonbank institutions. These changes would have important implications for the
inflationary process in Brazil.
Regarding CBB, it is important to mention that it was not created as an independent
institution. The SUMOC’s council was restructured to form the National Monetary
Council (CMN), which had regulatory powers over CBB and operates until today. The
relationship between CBB and BB also deserves special attention. Many of the
government policies, such as subsidized credit, were initially conducted by BB and they
remained so after CBB was created. In order to facilitate the interaction between both
institutions, the government created the Conta Movimento, which was a BB account that
would show up in CBB’s balance sheet as an asset and whose balance should average
zero. But in practice, that ended up providing BB with the control over money issuance,
since it could withdraw funds automatically from that account, and that would be
automatically matched by an expansion of the monetary base in CBB’s balance sheet.15
Section 4 discusses these issues in greater detail.
With respect to the monetary correction, the existence of indexed public debt held by
private savers on a voluntary basis defined the bedrock for the development of financial
markets in Brazil in the following years.
3.1.2 1965–1972
Between 1966 and at least 1971, the demand for public debt was growing faster ahead
of the government’s financial needs. The federal government’s overfinancing led to the
institutionalization of mechanisms that increased the spending capacity of local
governments, a phenomenon that would eventually pose great fiscal challenges taking
years to be reverted.
The 1968–1973 period became known as the years of “economic miracle” in Brazil,
with annual GDP growth rates in excess of 10%. That led to the optimistic view that the
Brazilian state had created a wholesome mechanism to capture private savings and
channel them to public investment. The idea of complementarity between public and
private investments reinforced the view that public debt was a key element in channeling
funds for more investment, either public or private. During those years the government
implemented the National Development Plan I (1972–1974), focused on improving the
country’s infrastructure. It included large projects such as the Itaipu Dam, Trans-
Amazonian Highway, and Rio-Niterói Bridge. The country also experienced higher
investment by SOEs and increasing supply of credit by public banks, such as BB and the
National Bank for Economic Development (BNDE).16
15
The original deficit series does not include the operations of BB, but since Conta Movimento was used
to make transfers from CBB to BB, we added its variation to the deficit series. See Data Appendix.
16
BNDE was established in 1952, and later became the National Bank for Economic and Social De-
3.1.3 1973–1980
When the first oil crisis in 1973 challenged the feasibility of the high-growth path, the
Brazilian government kept its long-run strategy in the President General Geisel years
(1974-79) to grow its way out of the first oil crisis, even if it had to rely on further
deepening of public indebtedness supported by the growth of external liquidity. That
explains the rapid increase in external debt in Figure 5 and accounts for the rise in
external debt financing in the 1973–1980 period in Table 1. One of its goals was to reduce
the country’s dependence on oil imports, using the SOEs as its main implementation
vehicle. As part of this strategy, the government implemented the National Development
Plan II in 1975–1979, which focused on the manufacturing, energy, transportation, and
communication sectors (see Table 2). The external debt series does not allow us to
distinguish SOEs from the rest of the public sector before 1981, but in that year external
debt of SOEs represented 72% of the total, which indicates that they accounted for a
large fraction of the increase in external debt after 1973 (Figure 6a). The same holds for
the domestic debt, although in that case the concentration of SOEs was less pronounced.
They accounted for 45% of the total domestic debt in 1981, while 33% was from states
and municipalities, and 22% from the federal government (Figure 6b).
That period was characterized by the poor management of the government budget, so
it is important to take into account the off-budget transactions when analyzing the
dynamics of the government budget constraint during those years.17 The government
operated two budgets, one that was discussed in the Congress, and the monetary budget,
controlled by the CMN (see Section 4). In addition, the government did not have control
over the budget of its SOEs. Given the deterioration of their accounts and trying to
control that process, the government created the Secretary of Coordination and
Governance of State-Owned Enterprises (SEST) in 1979. Figure 7 shows the deficit
series including transfers, and we observe that government deficits increased significantly
during that period. Besides the increasing indebtedness, the country also observed an
increase in subsidies and subsidized credit provided by public banks to state and local
authorities and to the private sector, reflected by the increase in transfers from CBB to
BB through the Conta Movimento (Figure 8).
The strategy to sustain growth through external borrowing was successful in the first
few years, as the accumulation of public debt was compatible with the maintenance of
economic growth at high rates. Continuity of this process of growing indebtedness,
however, relied on other factors: on the growth of private wealth, on the wealth holders’
confidence in the prospects of public sector ability to serve the debt, and on the use that
velopment (BNDES). See Costa Neto (2004) for the history of public banks in Brazil.
17
The main off-budget transactions we identified were the operations of BB and SOEs. The former is
captured by the transfers made from CBB to BB through Conta Movimento, and we added its variation
to the original deficit series. Those are the deficit series used to construct Table 1. The operations of SOEs
are partially captured by the transfers before 1985, since they are included in the external debt series. See
Data Appendix.
was ultimately being made of the savings captured by the government. In the second half
of the decade, GDP growth declined sharply, inflation doubled, and there were increasing
difficulties in controlling the growth of the public sector financial needs. Average
maturity of federal government domestic debt securities reached its peak in 1975 (Figure
9), but the share of nominal bonds kept growing (Figure 10) until the end of the decade,
as interest rates began to rise in 1976 following the abandonment of the interest rate
ceilings, which had prevailed until September 1976.
The first year of President General Figueiredo’s term (1979) started with a reduction
in the real value of public bond debt due to two effects: first, the decline in nominal
interest rates promoted by Planning Minister Delfim Netto, the new economic czar, in an
attempt to stimulate economic activity, which reduced the attractiveness of the debt;18
second, the increase in exchange rate uncertainty related to the second oil crisis. Figure
11 shows how interest rates were kept consistently below inflation rates between 1979
and 1981. Both factors reduced the attractiveness of the public debt in private portfolios.
From 1971 onward, nominal Treasury Bills (LTNs) had been issued side-by-side with the
old Indexed Treasury Bonds (ORTNs) as a result of the success of the reforms. In contrast
with the ORTNs, which were held both by financial and nonfinancial institutions, LTNs
were the typical assets used as reserves by financial institutions. They were auctioned at
a discount only in large denominations, with maturity ranging from 30 to 720 days.
CBB’s daily operations to regulate short-term liquidity via open market operations were
collateralized by LTNs, while ORTNs were thought as adequate to provide steady finance
for the structural fiscal deficit of the federal government. CBB’s portfolio, therefore, was
concentrated by-and-large in LTNs.
The real value of indexed debt reached a plateau and stabilized in the middle of the
decade, so that further finance for the public deficit came from the steady increase in the
stock of LTNs between January 1975 and October 1978. The share of ORTNs held by the
private sector declined by half at the end of the decade as the duration of the debt shrank
in face of higher inflation and unstable interest rates. The average maturity of public debt
fell from 1.42 to 1.16 years between 1977 and 1979 (Figure 9), when the widespread
practice of repurchase agreements by CBB made it harder to ascertain the actual demand
for longer-term debt.
The policies implemented by Delfim Netto, mainly low interest rates and change of
wage indexation rules, from once to twice a year, had the effect of significantly increasing
inflation, from around 50% in 1979 to over 100% in 1980, as argued in Simonsen (1983).
18
Delfim Netto replaced Mario Henrique Simonsen in August 1979 as the de facto manager of the
economy, less than six months into the new government of President General Figueiredo.
3.2 1980–1994: no growth with high macroeconomic instability
If the previous subperiod was characterized by the number of national development
plans that were implemented, the subperiod 1980–1994 is famous for its number of
stabilization plans, some of them indicated in Figure 12, and by severe balance of
payments problems.19 In this section, we discuss Brazil’s balance of payments crisis and
provide a description of its stabilization plans during the 1980s and early 1990s, focusing
on their main points and reasons for their failures, and trying to find out the most
important differences between them and the ultimately successful plan (Real).
Even though inflation was increasing to rates above 100% per year, in the first half
of the 1980s there were larger concerns to reduce external imbalances than to reduce
inflation. In 1981 and 1982, the main objective of Brazil’s macroeconomic policy was to
reduce the need for foreign capital. Figure 13 shows the current account balance, trade
balance, and net interest income, and we can observe the increasing cost of interest
payments on external debt and the trade balance reversal (from deficit to surplus) in
those years. There was a large devaluation of the real exchange rate (Figure 14), and real
GDP per capita contracted sharply.20 In 1982, Brazil would enter a sequence of episodes
in which it accumulated arrears on interest payments of its external debt, illustrated in
Figure 15, that would only end in 1994.21 These facts account for the drop in external
debt financing and rise in interest payments on external debt reported in Table 1,
subperiod 1981–1994. During that period we also observed the nationalization of the
external debt. Foreign debtors would pay CBB in domestic currency and CBB would not
pay the external creditor. After a few years, CBB allowed external creditors to exchange
their funds retained at CBB by domestic assets.22 Figure 16 shows that a large fraction of
the external debt became concentrated in CBB’s balance sheet up to 1994.
While government’s attention was focused on the balance of payments crisis, inflation
kept increasing. It was only in 1986 that the sequence of stabilization plans began. But
before moving to the discussion about each stabilization plan in detail, it is important
to put into perspective the cause of high inflation was at the time. The Cruzado Plan, as
well as the Bresser and Summer plans, considered that inflation inertia due to the highly
indexed economy was the essence of the inflationary process, and it should be the main
focus of the stabilization plan. These plans had a “neutral shock” of freezing prices as
one of their main characteristics. However, the staggering of wages and other prices
under very high inflation was an extra obstacle to a heterodox plan. At the moment that a
shock to stop inflation was introduced, agents with similar average real wages would
have different real wages depending on when the
19
For thorough analyses of that period, we refer to Carneiro and Modiano (2014), Modiano (2014),
and Abreu and Werneck (2014).
20
According to our definition of exchange rate, a real depreciation happens when its value increases.
21
See Cerqueira (2003) for a description of the external debt negotiations during that period.
22
See Cerqueira (2003).
last adjustment was set. Since inflation was supposed to decrease substantially after the
plan, the differences in real wages at the moment of the plan would prompt losers to
claim rights to be compensated, while the winners would not complain. If the losers were
compensated, that would reignite the inflation spiral. To avoid that problem, a conversion
table was always mandated at the beginning of each plan, aiming at keeping, in the new
low inflationary environment, the same average real wage that had prevailed under the
previous high inflationary period.23
As we will see, from the first to the last plan there was a decrease on the emphasis on
the heterodox part of the plan, which comprised price freezes, and more emphasis on the
orthodox part. Fiscal and monetary policies became a major component of the latter
plans, while maintaining a device to synchronize the adjustment of nominal variables to
avoid threatening the new low inflation level.
Cruzado Plan: In February 1986, the government implemented the Cruzado Plan. As
it became standard in some Brazilian stabilization plans, the first rule was to change the
currency, in that case from cruzeiro to cruzado, which meant cutting three zeros. Prices
were frozen.24 Wages were converted into cruzados based on the average purchasing
power of the last six months but could be readjusted every time inflation hit 20% or
during the annual readjustment cycle. Moreover, unemployment benefits were introduced
and the minimum wage was raised by 8% in real terms. The exchange rate regime also
changed, with the domestic currency now pegged to the US dollar. The plan also
extinguished monetary correction, and any indexation clauses for periods shorter than
one year were forbidden.25 Fiscal and monetary policies were put under the discretion of
the policymakers, but there was an important change, the end of the Conta Movimento
between CBB and BB. As previously mentioned, the Conta Movimento worked as free
money that BB would use whenever prompted to further extend financing to sectors
or firms targeted by economic policy. In practice, however, that took place only after
1988, because another account between CBB and BB, Conta de Suprimentos Especiais,
replaced Conta Movimento until its extinction in 1988 (see Section 4). Another important
measure was the creation of the Department of the Treasury, which would take control
over both the administration of the domestic public debt and the government budget.26
23
The change of currency allowed for reductions of those wages that had been recently adjusted, in
order to keep the same average real wage. Without the change of currency, the reduction in nominal
wages would not be possible since nominal wage reductions are not allowed by Brazilian Law.
24
Except for electricity, which had a 20% increase.
25
For fixed-rate contracts, a schedule for interest rate conversion was set. It was assumed that all
nominal interest rates were based on the inflation expectation of 0.45% a day (210% a year), which had
been the average daily inflation in 1985/86. The real rate was, then, the (new) nominal rate in the new
currency (cruzado), since the new expected inflation (at least for the government) was zero. For the
variable interest rate contracts, which prescribed a nominal rate equal to the sum of the monetary
correction and a variable (real) interest rate, the new nominal rates in cruzados were set to be the ones
above the monetary correction before the plan.
26
Before that, CBB managed both the domestic and external public debt.
At first, the Cruzado Plan was very successful in reducing inflation. The average
monthly inflation from March to July 1986 was 0.9% (IGP-DI). Moreover, the claim to
freeze prices had a civic impact since the population felt that they were “auditing prices.”
But that led to overheating. Sales increased 23% in the first six months of 1986 compared
to the first six months of 1985. Real wages increased 14% from March to September of
1986 (Figure 17). One consistent story with such evidence is that even though prices
were not allowed to change, the “equilibrium prices” were increasing, which was
producing overheating since posted prices were too low. It is clear that there was political
pressure to avoid a recession or bring inflation back to high levels. On the other hand,
CBB tried to keep interest rates low to induce low expectations. In the end, the monetary
base was increasing much faster than inflation itself (Figure 4a). Something needed to be
done. Many products became scarce, but nobody wanted to bear the political burden of a
recession.
In July 1986, the government introduced a timid fiscal package (Cruzadinho)
involving compulsory loans on fuel, car purchases, and international airline tickets and
foreign exchange sales for travel expenses. But in reality Cruzadinho had the opposite
result from what policymakers expected. Expecting prices to defreeze, demand increased
and the overheating problem became even more dramatic. Inflation remained low, but it
was not really representative, because products were scarce. Due to the high demand,
imports kept increasing while exports declined (Figure 18), thereby aggravating the trade
deficit. A rumor of a large devaluation in the near future reinforced that pattern. This
expectation lead to a postponement of exports and acceleration of imports, which
augmented the balance of payments problems.27 Facing all these challenges, in November
1986, the government opted for a fiscal plan, Cruzado II, trying to increase revenues
through the readjustment of some public prices and some indirect taxes, which led to a
high inflationary shock. It was again an environment of high inflation (17% per month in
January 1987). The external crisis was just getting worse. In February 1987 the
government suspended the interest payments on the external debt (see Figure 15) for an
indeterminate time). The idea was to stop the losses of international reserves and to start
a new phase on the renegotiation of the debt with the support of the population.
Bresser Plan: In July 1987, the government implemented the Bresser Plan. It was
presented as a hybrid plan, with fiscal and monetary policies as well as aspects to deal
with inflation inertia. Just like the Cruzado Plan, prices were frozen. As usual, the
moment in which the price freeze took place was important, because the relative prices
would remain stuck and possibly off-equilibrium. In an attempt to get a better result than
the Cruzado Plan on this aspect, after the price freeze there was an increase in the prices
of public services and some administered prices to correct for misalignments in relative
27
The government kept the minidevaluations based on an indicator of the ratio exchange rate /wage
(crawling peg). However, this same indicator suggested that the exchange rate was appreciated.
prices. The extinction of the automatic trigger in wage resetting if inflation surpassed a
20% was also perceived as another improvement. The trigger was extinct, but the
economic team created another kind of wage indexation, the URP (price reference unit).
Every quarter, the government would specify the readjustment for the next three months
based on the average inflation of the period. This would keep a monthly readjustment,
but there would be a gap between the readjustment and current inflation. In contrast to
the Cruzado Plan, monetary and fiscal policies were active. Real interest rates remained
positive in the short term. In the fiscal policy arena, the government aimed to reduce the
operational deficit from the expected 6.7% to 3.5% of GDP.28 The plan also kept the
default on the external debt. Another interesting aspect of this plan is that it did not target
zero inflation, it was meant to be just a deflationary shock.
The main purpose of Bresser-Pereira, the finance minister, was to have a fiscal reform
to reduce inflation. However, it was not successful. In 1987, the operational deficit was
5.5%, much higher than the promised 3.5%. Different from the Cruzado Plan, which had
popular support, the Bresser Plan lacked popular support and, in February 1988, there
was some liberalization of prices, reducing the effectiveness of the price freezing. As a
third pitfall of the economic plan, gross fixed capital formation fell.
Feijão-com-Arroz Policy: In January 1988, the government adopted an economic
policy referred to as Feijão-com-Arroz Policy, which can be translated to English as black-
beans-and-rice policy. Its name reflects the meaning of black beans and rice in the
Brazilian culture. It is the dish that Brazilians eat every day. It is not considered to
be very interesting, or very difficult, but it does the job of providing a healthy meal. After
Minister Bresser left, Maı́lson da Nóbrega, the second in command, took his position.
Instead of freezing prices, Nóbrega sought to merely to keep inflation at 15% per month.
The deficit was expected to reach 7%-8% of GDP in 1988, and there was a temporary
freeze of public sector wages to reduce it.
At first, this policy succeeded in avoiding an inflationary explosion and the fiscal
stance improved. The default on external debt was suspended and the government started
negotiations with external creditors. However, inflation started rising again and the target
of 15% per month was not achieved in the second quarter of 1988.
In October 1988, a new Constitution was enacted. The Brazilian Constitution
increased expenditures and increased the transfers from the central government to states
without transferring the corresponding responsibilities. It induced an increase in the
deficit of the central government. Just to put this into perspective, 92% of revenues were
earmarked. Among other measures not usually object of constitutional law, the new
Constitution reduced the standard
28
At the time the government used the public sector borrowing requirement as a measure of the
nominal deficit. However, nominal deficits were very high due to the monetary correction of the value
of the debt. In order to overcome that, the operational deficit was adopted as the main deficit measure,
which included only the nominal value of real interest payments. See Data Appendix.
weekly working time from 48 to 44 hours and increased the cost of overtime. Not only
did the Constitution increase the fiscal expenditures and reduce the flexibility of
expenditure switching between fiscal accounts, it also increased labor costs substantially.
On the external side, it should be mentioned that 1988 was a good year for the trade
balance and the current account.
Summer Plan: The government implemented the Summer Plan in January 1989.
Again, it was a hybrid plan, but the debate on the need for changes in fiscal and
monetary policies was increasing. Like the previous plans, there was a component of
price freezing as well as the adoption of a nominal anchor. In that case, a fixed exchange
rate (1 Cruzado Novo = 1,000 Cruzados = US$1) was implemented for indefinite time.
Moreover, there was an attempt to end inflation indexation. On the fiscal and
monetary side, the plan was to adopt a tight monetary policy and to fight inflation
by controlling the public deficit. It intended to control expenditures and increase
revenues through the privatization of public-owned assets and reduction in the wage bill
of the public sector. Overall, the plan seemed to incorporate everything that lacked in
the previous plans.
Although it kept a heterodox flavor (that is, it had an income policy component),
the plan was mostly an orthodox one aiming to reduce subsidies, close public firms, and
fire excessive public employees, with a deindexation plan that was sort of a small default.
However, the government did not have the political power to carry it through. Without the
Congress, privatizations and other unpopular measures, such as the closing of public
firms, were canceled. In the end, the reforms were not implemented. Moreover, the tight
monetary policy put interest rates at high levels and increased the fiscal deficit of the
government. With low credibility and a reform that did not go through, inflation came
back and the Summer Plan also failed.
The 1980s ended with almost 100% of the federal bond debt being rolled over in the
form of zero-duration bonds.29 This state of affairs reflected not only the extremely high
uncertainty regarding inflation and interest rates, but also the fear of an explicit default of
the debt by the incoming administration of President Fernando Collor de Mello. At the
time, there was a widespread suspicion regarding the credit risk of the public securities,
which were indeed validated by the new administration’s actions. Fernando Collor de
Mello was elected president of Brazil after 29 years of indirect elections or
nondemocratic ones. The very day he took office, he launched the Collor Plan.
Collor Plan I: In March 1990, the government launched the Collor Plan I. It
recognized that a reduction in deficits was necessary to end the hyperinflation, and it
implemented both temporary and permanent fiscal policies. Among the temporary
measures were the establishment of a tax on financial intermediation and the suspension
of tax incentives. But the permanent policies were more important. There was an effort to
29
Zero-duration bonds are bonds that pay ex-post the accrual of daily overnight interest rates.
Therefore, the price of these bonds are insensitive to interest rate changes. It was a way to separate
interest rate risk from maturity risk, thereby lengthening a bit the very short-term public debt.
reduce fiscal evasion (one of his trademarks during the presidential campaign) and to
increase taxes. The other major components comprised privatizations and an
administrative reform. On the monetary side, the plan attempted to reduce the money
supply by confiscating funds in both transactions and savings accounts for a period of
eighteen months. Those funds would be kept at CBB and invested in government bonds,
and represented 80% of bank deposits and financial investments. Finally, prices and
wages were also frozen.
Following its implementation, monetary aggregates reduced sharply, especially the
higher ones (Figure 19). This reduction of liquidity, however, was not sufficient to control
inflation. Regarding the fiscal reform, the threatening behavior of the government toward
the public sector employees turned the reform very unpopular. There was a lot of
resistance and, in the end, it could not reach everything it proposed. Some privatizations
succeeded, but most of the fiscal reforms were short-lived.
Collor Plan II: In January 1991, the same government implemented the Collor Plan
II. Just like the previous one, it planned to reduce government expenditures by firing civil
servants and closing public services. It also proposed the privatization of SOEs. As
usual, the plan had a price freezing aspect. Wages were converted by a twelve-month
average, a new tablita was adopted based on the assumption that the inflation would fall
to zero, and it put an end to indexation.30 Not entirely related to the fight against
inflation, this plan had a motif that Brazil had to improve the quality of its products. In
the words of the president, “Brazil was producing horse-drawn coaches instead of cars.”
To achieve that, the government opened the Brazilian economy to foreign competition and
privatized state-owned firms.
Following its implementation, the country experienced a recession. But it recovered
afterward, and this is usually attributed to enhanced competition in the economy.
Inflation rose again, but this plan left two important permanent changes. First, it opened
up the Brazilian economy. The trade chain increased in 1990, reversing the previous
trend. Second, productivity increased. In the beginning of 1992, when expectations of
accelerated inflation did not materialize, the effects of recovered investors’ confidence
started to appear in public debt markets. Those expectations had been based on the
combination of price liberalization, corrections of public tariffs, and on the devaluation
that followed the floating of the exchange rate in October 1991 in face of the strong
monetization of the hijacked assets during Collor Plan I.31 The return of investors’
30
Tablita was the name for the interest rate conversion table when the currency changed.
31
The recovery of the stock of public debt in the portfolio of the private sector was a clear
demonstration that asset-holders were willing to return to business as usual in spite of the violence of
repeated interventions, which had been made in the rules of indexation and liquidity of public
securities in the previous twelve years. One should bear in mind that the majority of economic analysts
at the time were forecasting that the government would never again be able to place new debt.
confidence is also confirmed by the recovery of foreign exchange reserves after 1992.
Following the high political turbulence that characterized the months preceding the
impeachment of President Collor de Mello (October 2, 1992), the beginning of Itamar
Franco’s presidency was marked by high uncertainty concerning economic policy.
Proposals of another moratorium, and even repudiation of the public debt, were
constantly in the press. It was only after the president nominated his fourth minister of
finance in less than six months that the recovered confidence materialized in higher
external reserves.
Real Plan: In June 1994, the government launched its last stabilization plan, the Real
Plan, that would finally put an end to the hyperinflation. A new currency was created, the
real, valued at 2750 cruzeiros reais. The plan that would eventually conquer Brazilian
inflation did not have the blessing of the International Monetary Fund (IMF), an always
troubled relationship in the previous decades. It had different concepts from the previous
ones, aiming to reduce deficits, to modernize firms, and to reduce the distortions that
arose from previous price freezes. The first stage of the Real Plan was defined by the
fiscal element. Different from the previous plans that originally had the fiscal
component but ended up unsuccessful in its implementation, the Real Plan had the fiscal
component negotiated with the Congress. The Programa de Ação Imediata (Program for
Immediate Action) was designed to focus on fiscal imbalances that would arise when the
seigniorage revenues fell. A significant adjustment came in the beginning of 1994, with
the Fundo Social de Emergência (Emergency Social Fund), a way to suspend part of the
earmarked revenues of states and municipalities. Despite its ambitious reform goals, the
government ended up targeting what was available at that time to generate fiscal
revenues, and it increased taxes of financial intermediaries. On the monetary side, a
clearly stated intention to limit issuances of the new currency led to the adoption of a
high interest rate policy and of high reserve requirement ratios (100% reserve
requirement on new deposits after July 1st).
The Real Plan did not involve price freeze itself, but it was able to solve the problems
of staggered wages and prices. Actually, this was considered the most controversial aspect
of the plan, but probably the most ingenious and ultimately very successful. The creation
of a new unit of account URV–Unidade Real de Valor (Unit of Real Value)–aimed at
establishing a parallel unit of value to the cruzeiro real, the inflated currency. The idea
was to make it temporary. Prices were quoted both in URVs and cruzeiros reais, but
payments had to be made exclusively in cruzeiros reais. The way the URV worked was
like a shadow currency that had its parity to cruzeiro real constantly adjusted, since it was
one-to-one with the dollar. Therefore, a conversion rate of the URV/cruzeiro novo (the
old currency) rate was set every day. With that system, the relative price problem was
diminished. Many conversions were left to free negotiation between economic agents,
with the government having more interference in oligopolized prices. Wages, for instance,
were converted into URVs taking into account their real value in the last four months, as
this was the inherited indexation horizon. The objective was to get relative prices right.
The URV was extinguished July 1, 1994, when it was converted to a new currency, real,
with the parity being 1 dollar = 1 real = 1 URV.
subperiod
subperiod
GDP
percentage of agricultural sector
18 10
6
percentage of manufacturing sector 32 41
28
percentage of services sector 50 49
67
Population
percentage living in urban areas 45 68
81
percentage living in rural areas 55 32
19
(c) Deficit
Source: Brazilian Institute of Geography and Statistics, Central Bank of Brazil, and authors’ calculations.
Note: We use the general price index from Getulio Vargas Foundation, IGP-DI, to compute the inflation rates.
Figure 2: Domestic debt of the public sector: 1960–2016
Source: Brazilian Institute of Geography and Statistics and Central Bank of Brazil.
Note: Before 1981, the domestic debt consists of the federal and state governments debt securities, together with Dívida Publica
Fundada, from Estatísticas do Século XX - IBGE. After 1981, it is the net debt of the public sector computed by the Central
Bank of Brazil plus the balance of the Banco do Brazil accounts at the Central Bank.
Source: Brazilian Institute of Geography and Statistics and Central Bank of Brazil.
Figure 4: Inflation, seigniorage, and money growth: 1960–2016
(a) Money growth and inflation
Source: IPEADATA, Brazilian Institute of Geography and Statistics, Central Bank of Brazil, and authors’ calculations.
Note: For the inflation and money growth series, we plot the transformation log(15 + X), in which X
denotes the percentage annual rate. We sum 15 to avoid taking logs of negative numbers.
Figure 5: External debt: 1960–2016
(a) Percentage of GDP
Source: Brazilian Institute of Geography and Statistics, Central Bank of Brazil, and authors’ calculations.
Figure 6: Sectoral composition of the public debt: 1960–2016
(a) External debt
Source: IPEADATA, Brazilian Institute of Geography and Statistics, Central Bank of Brazil, and authors’ calculations.
Source: IPEADATA.
Source: IPEADATA.
Figure 13: International accounts
Source: IPEADATA.
Source: IPEADATA.
(b) Liabilities
Source: Brazilian Institute of Geography and Statistics and Central Bank of Brazil.
the government to implement its economic policies (see main text), that was considered
to be a significant advantage. Third, there was a lack of confidence in the capability of
the government to report its finances accurately. The National Treasury Secretariat, for
example, was only created in 1986.
Even though the paper uses the primary deficit series from CBB after 1985 as many
Brazilian economists recommend, we use this appendix to discuss a few points. First, the
inclusion or not of SOEs in the primary deficit series does not make a big difference after
1985, especially after the 1990s when most privatizations took place (Figure 24). Second,
CBB did not take into account privatizations when estimating primary deficits. In other
words, if the government sold some of its assets to finance current expenditures, that
would not be captured in the deficit series from CBB. Figure 25a compares both series,
with privatization and not, for the period after 1996, which is the year when the data on
privatizations used by CBB became available.
Third, CBB does not account for defaults. It estimates interest payments on an
accrual basis. So if the government defaulted on its interest payments, CBB would
underestimate the primary deficit. The reason is that CBB assumes that the government
paid all the interest that was due. Therefore, it would conclude that the government had
the resources to pay for them, which must have come from lower primary deficits (or
higher surpluses) according to CBB’s methodology. Remember that primary deficit is
computed as a residual. But if the government defaulted on the interest payments, then it
must be the case that deficits were actually higher than the ones reported by CBB. As the
main text mentions, the country accumulated arrears on interest payments on the external
debt for many years, especially in the 1990–1994 period. We use the information
Figure 25: Adjustments to primary deficit series from CBB
(a) Privatization adjustment
Source: Brazilian Institute of Geography and Statistics and Central Bank of Brazil.
on the fraction of interest on external debt that were actually paid to correct for both the
interest payments and primary deficit series reported by CBB. The difference in the
primary deficit series is illustrated in Figure 25b. Unfortunately, we do not have
information regarding defaults on domestic debt.
Fourth, CBB does not distinguish “bad assets” from the rest of the government’s
assets. In these cases, CBB might conclude that the government is saving, since it is
accumulating more assets, when in reality those assets are worthless (extreme case). One
example is the accounts from Bank of Brazil (BB) in CBB’s balance sheet (see main text),
that were used to transfer funds from CBB to BB. In Figure 26a we show the magnitude
of those transfers given by the variation in their balances. By looking at its own assets,
CBB would conclude that it is saving, but those funds were never repaid and represented
deficits. We did correct the primary deficit series for the transfers between CBB and BB
through those accounts. However, there might be other cases. Imagine, for example, the
(hypothetical) case in which the government bails out a public bank by exchanging its
“bad assets” that they were holding in their balance sheets. CBB would conclude that
there were no surpluses or deficits, since the government is exchanging assets by
liabilities in “equal” amount, when in reality there were transfers to finance
expenditures.43
Fifth, there are also cases in which there are debt recognitions (skeletons) that enter
the debt series. CBB does not include those variations when estimating the primary
deficit, but it shows that there were previous deficits that were not taken into account.
They are shown in Figure 25c.
Finally, note that the IBGE series also misses the transactions between CBB and BB,
so we also need to make that adjustment on the IBGE series for the period in which we
use it (before 1985). See Figure 26b.
C.1.1 Implications
As we could see in Figure 24, the difference between both series is significant,
especially around the Real Plan. However, the main conclusion from our analysis does
not change, even when we include the adjustments mentioned above. The low-inflation
period (after 1994) is characterized by improvements in fiscal balances. Note that both
series show primary surpluses after 1998. The main controversy arises in the period
surrounding the implementation of the Real Plan. It is usually emphasized that the
government switched from large surpluses to large deficits when it was implemented, but
given the pitfalls in CBB’s series, one cannot be 100% sure of it. If we look at IBGE’s
series instead, we observe the opposite: large deficits before the Real Plan and an
improvement right after. But again, this series also has its own pitfalls, so one must be
careful when making conclusions based on those observations.
43
In other words, the value of those assets in the balance sheet do not represent their true value.
Figure 26: Adjustment regarding Bank of Brazil (BB)
(a) CBB + BB
(b) IBGE + BB
Source: Brazilian Institute of Geography and Statistics and Central Bank of Brazil.
Data is from the Brazilian Institute of Geography and Statistics (IBGE). It is annual,
from 1947 to 2014, and can be downloaded at http://seriesestatisticas.ibge.gov.br (series
SCN53). The series show the percentage variation in volume. We normalize real GDP in
1995 to 100 and use the variation to construct the series of real GDP. We use another
data series to extend it until 2016. We use the annual variation in real GDP (reference
year 2010) between 2015 and 2016 available at http://ipeadata.gov.br to update the real
GDP series until 2016.
We also work with monthly data, so it is useful to construct a monthly series of real
GDP. We assume that the annual values correspond to July values, and use linear
interpolation to compute real GDP for the other months.
Price index
We use the General Price Index (IGP) from the Getulio Vargas Foundation. It is com-
posed by: 60% Producer Price Index (IPA), 30% Consumer Price Index (IPC), and 10%
Construction Price Index (INCC). Prices are collected from day one to day thirty of the
reference month. Series begin in January 1944. The series can be downloaded at
http://www.ipeadata.gov.br (IGP-DI - geral - ´ındice (ago. 1994 = 100)). End-of-period
values are computed as the geometric average of IGP-DI in t and t + 1. In order to make
the IGP-DI consistent with the GDP deflator, we normalize the IGP-DI such that its
average in 1995 is equal to the GDP deflator in that year. The GDP deflator in 1995 is
equal to the nominal GDP (IPEADATA: Produto interno bruto (PIB) a preços de
mercado - referência 2000) in 1995 divided by 100 (since we normalized real GDP to 100
in 1995).
The IGP-DI is very sensitive to variations in the exchange rate, so Table 4 reports the
results using the consumer price index from FIPE, instead.
subperiod
Computed by the multiplication of the real GDP series and price index series described
above.
Population
Data is from the Brazilian Institute of Geography and Statistics (IBGE), available at
http://ipeadata.gov.br, for the period 1872 until 2015 at annual frequency. The name of
the series is população residente. We update the series until 2016 using another series
from IBGE available at http://ipeadata.gov.br, “populacão residente - 1◦ de julho
- estimativas”. We assume the same growth rate between 2015 and 2016.
Exchange rate
For the exchange rate, we have both average price and end-of-period prices available.
We focus on buy price. The series is available at http://ipeadata.gov.br, with the annual
series available from 1942 to 2017, and the monthly series from January 1953 to May
2018.
Monetary base
Monthly series from January 1946 to April 2018 from Central Bank (series 1788), and
it can be decomposed between currency issued (series 1786) and banking reserves (series
1787) starting in January 1980. They reflect end-of-period balances and the annual series
is constructed based on December values. The monthly series for average monthly balance
is also available for the period January 1980 to April 2018 (series 1785), and it can be
decomposed between banking reserves (series 1784) and currency issued (1783).
Reserves
Annual series (reservas internacionais) from 1945 to 2017 is available at http://ipeadata.gov.br. The
monthly series from December 1970 to May 2018 is available at the Central Bank (series 3546).
Domestic Debt
Before 1981, we use the sum of three series: D´ıvida Fundada do Governo Federal, debt
securities from federal government, and debt securities from states, available at
IPEADATA. After 1981, we use the Dı́vida Lı́quida do Setor Público (DLSP) from the
Central Bank of Brazil and which is available at IPEADATA.
External Debt
Before 1971, we assume external net debt of the public sector is zero. Between 1971
and 1981, we use data on the public sector external debt related to balance of payments
data. After 1981, we use the Dı́vida Lı́quida do Setor Público (DLSP) from the Central
Bank of Brazil and which is available at IPEADATA.
References
Bacha, E. 2003. “Development Economics and Structuralist Macroeconomics: Essays in Honor of Lance
Taylor.” Chapt. Brazil's Plano Real: a view from the inside. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.
Bevilaqua, A. S., D. D. Carneiro, M. G. P. Garcia, and R. L. F. Werneck. 2001. “The Structure of Public
Sector Debt in Brazil.” RES Working Papers 3121, Inter-American Development Bank, Research
Department.
Carneiro, Dionísio D. 2014. “Crise e esperança: 1974-1980.” In A Ordem do Progreso: Dois Séculos de
Política Econômica no Brasil, 2nd ed. Edited by Marcelo P. Abreu. Elsevier.
Carneiro, D. D., and M. G. P. Garcia. 1993. “Capital Flows and monetary control under a domestic currency
substitution regime: The recent Brazilian experience.”. Textos para discussão 304, Department of Economics
PUC-Rio (Brazil).
Carneiro, Dionisio D., and E. Modiano. 2014. “Ajuste externo e desequilíbrio interno: 1980-1984.” In A
Ordem do Progreso: Dois Séculos de Política Econômica no Brasil, 2nd ed. Edited by Marcelo P. Abreu.
Elsevier.
Carvalho, B. S. M., and M. G. P. Garcia. 2008. “Ineffective Controls on Capital Inows under Sophisticated
Financial Markets: Brazil in the Ninities.” In Financial Markets Volatility and Performance in Emerging
Markets, NBER Chapters. National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc., pp. 29-96.
Cati, R. C., M. G. P. Garcia, and P. Perron. 1999. “Unit Roots in the Presence of Abrupt Governmental
Interventions with an Application to Brazilian Data.” Journal of Applied Econometrics 14 (1): 27-56.
Cerqueira, Ceres A. 2003. Dívida externa brasileira, 2nd ed. Banco Central do Brasil.
Costa Neto, Yttrio C. 2004. Bancos oficiais no Brasil: origem e aspectos de seu desenvolvimento. Banco
Central do Brasil.
Franco, Gustavo H. B. 2017. “O Conselho Monetário Nacional como Autoridade Monetária: das origens aos
dias atuais.” In A Crise Fiscal e Monetária Brasileira. Civilização Brasileira, 2nd ed. Edited by Edmar
Bacha.
Garcia, M. G. P. 1993. “The Fisher effect in a signal extraction framework: The recent Brazilian experience.”
Journal of Development Economics 41 (1): 71-94.
________. 1996. “Avoiding some costs of inflation and crawling toward hyperinflation: The case of Brazilian
domestic currency substitute.” Journal of Development Economics 51 (1): 139-159.
Guardia, E. R. (1992). “Orçamento Público e política fiscal: aspectos institucionais e a experiência recente,
1985-1991.” Universidade de Campinas. Master’s thesis.
Gurkayanak, R. S., B. Sack, and J. H. Wright. 2010. “The TIPS Yield Curve and Ination Compensation.”
American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2 (1): 70-92.
International Monetary Fund. 1995. “Guidelines for Fiscal Adjustment.” No 49 in Pamphlet Series.
Mesquita, Mário M.C. 2014. “Inflação, Estagnação e ruptura, 1961-1964.” In A Ordem do Progreso: Dois
Séculos de Política Econômica no Brasil, 2nd ed. Edited by Marcelo P. Abreu. Elsevier.
Modiano, Eduardo M. 2014). “A ópera dos três cruzados, 1985-1990.” In A Ordem do Progreso: Dois
Séculos de Política Econômica no Brasil, 2nd ed. Edited by Marcelo P. Abreu. Elsevier.
Pastore, A. C. 1995. “Déficit Público, a Sustentabilidade do Crescimento das Dívidas Interna e Externa,
Senhoriagem e Inflação: Uma Análise do Regime Monetário Brasileiro.” Revista de Econometria 14 (2): 177-
234.
________. 1996. “Por que a Política Monetária perde a eficácia?” Revista de Econometria 50 (3): 281-311.
Pedras, Guilherme B. V. 2009. “História da dívida pública no Brasil: de 1964 até os dias atuais.” In Dívida
Pública: a experiência brasileira. Edited by Silva, Anderson C., L. O. de Carvalho, and O. L. de Medeiros.
Tesouro Nacional.
Resende, André L. 2014. “Estabilização e reforma, 1964-1967.” In A Ordem do Progreso: Dois Séculos de
Política Econômica no Brasil, 2nd ed. Edited by Marcelo P. Abreu. Elsevier.
Rezende, M. 2000. “O Crescimento da Dívida Pública no Período 1970 a 1999.” PUC-Rio, Departamento de
Economia. Master’s thesis.
Rocha, R. R., and F. Saldanha. 1995. “Fiscal and quasi-fiscal deficit, nominal and real: measurement and
policy issues.” Revista Brasileira de Economia 49 (3): 431-466.
Silva, Anderson C. 2009. “Origem e história da dívida pública no Brasil até 1963.” In Dívida Pública: a
experiência brasileira. Edited by Silva, Anderson C., L. O. de Carvalho, and O. L. de Medeiros. Tesouro
Nacional.
Simonsen, M. 1983. “Indexation: Current Theory and the Brazilian Experience.” In Inflation, Debt and
Indexation. Edited by Rudiger Dornbusch and Mario H. Simonsen. The MIT Press.