Moot Defendant PDF
Moot Defendant PDF
Moot Defendant PDF
Before
THE HONOURABLE SUPREME COURT OF KRATOS
Under53T of the Kratotian Competition Act, 2002and Article 136 of Constitution of Kratos.
Page | i
2nd TNNLU – CCI National Moot Court Competition, March 2019
TABLE OF CONTENTS
INDEX OF AUTHORITIES………………………………………………………………….ii
STATEMENT OF JURISDICTION…………………………………………………….……xi
STATEMENT OF FACTS……………………………………………………......................xii
STATEMENT OF ISSUES…………………………………………………………………xiii
SUMMARY OF ARGUMENTS……………………………………………………………xiv
ARGUMENTS ADVANCED…………………………………………………………………1
1. THE RESPONDENTS ARE NOT INVOLVED IN CARTELISATION …………………1
1.1. Price parallelism is not per se anti-competitive………………………………………..1
1.1.1. Price parallelism is not conclusive proof of cartelization in an oligopolistic
market…………………………………….………………………….………...1
1.1.2. Legitimate justification for parallel pricing…………………………………....3
1.2. There was no agreement between the respondents……………………………………5
1.2.1. Using of pricing algorithm per se is not anti-competitive…………………......5
1.2.2. There is no evidence of an agreement…………………………………………6
1.2.3. Burden of proof………………………………………………………………..7
1.2.4. No structural links between the five companies……………………………….7
1.3. There was no appreciable adverse effect on competition……………………………..8
1.3.1. No evidence of adverse effect on competition………………………………...8
1.3.2. Pro-competitive effects of the algorithm………………………………………8
1.3.3. Consideration of factors mentioned in section 19(3)…………………………..9
2. THE RIGHTS OF TRADERS HAVE NOT BEEN VIOLATED…………………...……..9
2.1. News report is not admissible evidence……………………………………………….9
2.2. No violation of fundamental rights…………………………………………………...10
2.2.1. Fundamental rights cannot be enforced against private parties………………10
2.2.2. No violation of fundamental rights…………………………………………...11
2.3. Appellants no longer possess the cause of action…………………………………….13
2.4. Alternate remedy is available with the appellants……………………………………15
3. THE RESPONDENTS ARE NOT HOLDING COLLECTIVE DOMINANT POSITION
AND HAVE NOT VIOLATED THE PROVISIONS OF THE ACT………….…………16
3.1. No concept of collective dominance as per Kratos competition law………………...16
3.2. CCK has acted outside the scope of its power……………………………………….17
3.2.1. Judiciary cannot legislate…………………………………………………….17
3.2.2. Non enforcement of a law……………………………………………………18
3.2.3. Strict interpretation…………………………………………………………...19
3.3. No abuse of dominant position………………………………………….……………19
3.3.1. Relevant market………………………………………………………………20
3.3.2. No dominance in relevant market……………………………………………22
3.3.3. No abuse under provisions of the competition act……………………..…….23
3.4. Pro-competitive justification……………………………………………………..…..24
Prayer ……………………………………………………………………..…………………xv
INDEX OF AUTHORITIES
BOOKS
ABIR ROY AND JAYANT KUMAR, COMPETITION LAW IN INDIA (2nd edn, 2014).
S.M. DUGAR, GUIDE TO COMPETITION LAW (6th edn, 2016).
DP Mittal, Competition Law and Practice (3rd edn, 2011) 172.
CASES
Sr No. Case Name & Citation Pg No.
1. A.K. Jain (OP) v The Dwarkadhis Projects (P) Ltd. 2015 CompLR 487 20
(CompAT).
2. Aberdeen Journals v Director General of Fair Trading CAT 4 [2002] 21
Comp AR 167.
3. Accreditation Commission for Conformity Assessment Bodies Private 13
Limited v Quality Council of India/National Accreditation Board For
Certification Bodies and others 2012 Indlaw CCI 62.
4. Ahlstrom Oy v Commission (1993) 4 CMLR 407. 1, 2
5. Airtours Plc v. Commission, Case T-342/99, [2002] ECR II-2585. 20
6. Ajay Hasia v Khalid Mujib (1981) 1SCC 722. 10
7. Alkali & Chemical Corporation of India Ltd. And Bayer India Ltd RTPE 1
21 of 1981.
8. All India Footwear Manufacturers & Retailers Association v Union of 13, 14
India W.P. (C) 7479/2015.
9. All India Online Vendors Association v Flipkart India Private Limited 12
and Anr Case No. 20 of 2018(CCI).
10. All India Tyre Dealers' Federation v Tyre Manufacturers 2013 CompLR 2
92 (CCI).
11. ANI Technologies Pvt. Ltd. v. Fast Track Call Cab Pvt. Ltd. (2015) 131 22
SCL 240 (CCI).
12. Arshiya Rail Infrastructure Limited v Ministry of Railways 2012 Indlaw 21
CCI 25.
13. Ashish Ahuja v Snapdeal and Anr 2014 Indlaw CCI 42. 11
14. Babloo Chauhan @ Dabloo v State Govt. of NCT of Delhi 247 (2018) 11
DLT 31.
STATUTES
Competition Act, 2002.
Indian Evidence Act, 1872.
Clayton’s Act, 1914.
Constitution of India, 1950.
Freedom in Pricing and Competition Act, 1992.
Indian Evidence Act, 1872.
Indian Penal Code, 1860.
Monopolistic and Restrictive Trade practices Act, 1969.
Sherman Act, 1890.
Treaty for the functioning of the European Union, 1957.
DICTIONARIES
ONLINE DATABASE
www.westlawindia.com
www.scconline.com
www.jstor.org
www.manupatra.com
LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS
Co. Company
DG Director General
EU European Union
In Re In Reference
OP Opposite Party
SC Supreme Court
STATEMENT OF JURISDICTION
The Hon’ble Supreme Court of Kratos exercises jurisdiction to hear the appeal under “Order
LV Rule 5” of The Supreme Court Rules1which states that:
“Where there are two or more appeals arising out of the same matter, the Court may at any
time either on its own motion or on the application of any party, order that the appeals be
consolidated.”
APPEAL PROVISION
Appeal 1: Against order of 53T2. The Central Government or any State Government
National Company Law Appellate or the Commission or any statutory authority or any local
Tribunal (NCLAT) in Premier and authority or any enterprise or any person aggrieved by
Others. vs. Ganga and Another any decision or order of the Appellate Tribunal may file
an appeal to the Supreme Court within sixty days from
the date of communication of the decision or order of the
Appellate Tribunal to them.
Appeal 2: Against judgment of Article 1363. Special leave to appeal by the Supreme
High Court of Madrasapatnam in Court
MTU v. Premier and Others. (1) Notwithstanding anything in this Chapter, the
Supreme Court may, in its discretion, grant special leave
to appeal from any judgment, decree, determination,
sentence or order in any cause or matter passed or made
by any court or tribunal in the territory of India
Appeal 3: Against the order of 53T4. The Central Government or any State Government
National Company Law Appellate or the Commission or any statutory authority or any local
Tribunal (NCLAT) in Premier and authority or any enterprise or any person aggrieved by
Others. vs. David and Co. any decision or order of the Appellate Tribunal may file
an appeal to the Supreme Court within sixty days from
the date of communication of the decision or order of the
Appellate Tribunal to them.
1
The Supreme Court Rules, 2013.
2
Competition Act, 2002.
3
Constitution of Kratos, 1950.
4
Competition Act, 2002.
STATEMENT OF FACTS
The Republic of Kratos, a democratic country has laws pari materia with India. Their
Competition Act was enacted in 2002. The Kratotian Competition Act gives due regard to
precedents from India, EU and US. Kratos has 7 major e – commerce namely Premier Pvt.
Ltd., Brahmaputra Pvt. Ltd., Moneykart LLP, Chapo Pvt. Ltd., Mahjong Ltd., Ganga Pvt.
Ltd. and Origamy Pvt. Ltd. A new start-up, named as ‘Pablo’s Alogors’ had developed
algorithm called as ‘Rutta’ to promote easy flow of information and innovative price fixation
techniques in the e – commerce industry. All 7 e- commerce websites used Rutta for fixing
prices of its products. After a year Pablo’s Alogors came up with new version Rutta 2.0
which would consider the price of its competitors while determining the price of a product.
Ganga and Origamy did not switch to Rutta 2.0 while other five companies did. Premier
launched its e- wallet App called FastZapp. Subsequently, MoneyKart and Chapo also
launched their own e – wallet service applications known as ‘PayKing’ and ‘Heisenberg.
Case No. 2 Madrasapatnam Traders Union (MTU filed a case before the High
(Rights of Small Court alleging e – commerce companies’ virtual market is distorting the
Traders) physical market of small traders. The High Court summarily dismissed
the case on the ground that the matter is not justiciable before the High
Court and the alternative remedy lies elsewhere.
Case No. 3 David and Co., a small e – wallet service provider filed a complaint
( Alleged Abuse before the CCK alleging that Premier, MoneyKart, and Chapo are
of Dominance) abusing their dominant position in the market by entering into the
exclusivity agreements with the ISPs and thus creating hindrance for the
new and existing competitor to enter or survive in the market. CCK held
them to be collectively abusing their dominant position. NCLAT
reversed the finding of CCK.
The Supreme Court clubbed the cases together.
ISSUES RAISED
SUMMARY OF ARGUMENTS
The Respondents humbly submit that the rights of the traders have not been violated as there
was no illegal conduct on the part of appellants moreover; present suit is not maintainable as
alternative remedy lies elsewhere. Moreover, the whole prosecution is based upon a news
report which is unreliable. And Press Note dated 26th December 2018 on Foreign Direct
Investment Policy in the e-commerce sector resolved any possible issue that may have been
faced by the appellants thus they no longer possess cause of action.
The Respondents humbly submitthat Premier, Moneykart and Chapo are not holding
collective dominant position, and thus, have not violated the provisions of the Competition
Act as there is no concept of collective dominance in Kratos Competition law, therefore, by
holding them liable CCK has acted outside its scope of power and respondents are not
holding collective dominant position in the relevant market as none of the factors stipulated
under 19(4) has been satisfied. In addition, the agreements between respondents and ISP’s
have pro-competitive justification.
ARGUMENTS ADVANCED
5
Express Industry Council of India v Jet Airways Ltd. 2016 CompLR 102 (CCI).
6
Zuchner v Bayerische Vereinsbank (1981) ECR 2021.
7
In re: Alleged cartelization by steel producers 2012 Indlaw CCI 45.
8
Brooke Group v Williamson Tobacco Corp. 509 US 209 (1993).
9
In re: Domestic Air Lines 2012 CompLR 154 (CCI); Abir Roy and Jayant Kumar, Competition Law in India
(2nd edn, 2014) 111.
10
Alkali & Chemical Corporation of India Ltd. And Bayer India Ltd RTPE 21 of 1981.
11
Theatre Enterprises Inc v Paramount Film Distribution Corporation 346 US 537 (1954); In re, Flat Glass
385 F.3d 360 (2004).
12
Bell Atlantic Corporation v Twombly 550 US 544(2007).
13
Ahlstrom Oy v Commission (1993) 4 CMLR 407.
14
Southway Theatres Inc. v Georgia Theatre Company 672 F.2d485 (5th Cir. 1982).
Parallel prices may furnish proof of concerted practice only if the behaviour cannot be
explained by conditions of competition in the market.15 However, it is legal in case of market
conduct pursued independently16 considering the foreseeable conduct of competitors.17
Parallel pricing occurs if firms change their prices simultaneously, in the same direction, and
proportionally.18 It does not furnish proof of concerted practice if the behaviour can be
explained by conditions of competition in the market.19 It is legal when the adaptation to
market conditions was done independently and not based on information exchanged between
the competitors.20 Competition law only prohibits collusion. It does not deprive economic
operators of their right to adapt intelligently to the anticipated conduct of their competitors.21
15
Ahlstrom Oy v Commission (1993) 4 CMLR 407.
16
Express Industry Council of India v Jet Airways (India) Ltd. 2016 CompLR 102 (CCI).
17
Zuchner v Bayerische Vereinsbank (1981) ECR 2021.
18
Abir Roy and Jayant Kumar, Competition Law in India (2nd edn, 2014) 103.
19
Ahlstrom Oy v Commission (1993) 4 CMLR 407.
20
Express Industry Council of India v Jet Airways (India) Ltd. 2016 CompLR 102 (CCI).
21
Zuchner v Bayerische Vereinsbank (1981) ECR 2021.
22
All India Tyre Dealers' Federation v Tyre Manufacturers 2013 CompLR 92 (CCI).
23
Abir Roy and Jayant Kumar, Competition Law in India (2nd edn, 2014) 67.
24
All India Tyre Dealers' Federation v Tyre Manufacturers 2013 CompLR 92 (CCI).
25
Ibid.
26
Ibid.
27
¶4, Moot Proposition.
28
All India Tyre Dealers' Federation v Tyre Manufacturers 2013 CompLR 92 (CCI).
29
In Re: Manufacturers of Asbestos Cement Products 2014 CompLR 272 (CCI).
The present case, the respondents must be allowed to use the defence of “Objective
justification” that refers to three conceptual categories:30
“Predatory pricing schemes are rarely tried, and even more rarely
successful,37 and the costs of an erroneous finding of liability are high. “The
mechanism by which a firm engages in predatory pricing-lowering prices-is
the same mechanism by which a firm stimulates competition; because 'cutting
prices in order to increase business often is the very essence of competition ...
[;] mistaken inferences ... are especially costly, because they chill the very
conduct the antitrust laws are designed to protect.''38 It would be ironic indeed
if the standards for predatory pricing liability were so low that antitrust suits
themselves became a tool for keeping prices high.”
“Meeting competition” defence is applicable when a lower price was made to meet an equally
low price of the competitor.39 It must comply with the principle of proportionality, i.e. the
30
Hilti AG v Commission of the European Communities (1990) ECR II-163 (UK).
31
Hoffmann La Roche & Co. AG v Commission (1979) ECR 461 (UK).
32
United Brands v Commission (1978) ECR 207 (UK).
33
Benzine en Petroleum Handelsmaatschappij BV v Commission (1978) ECR 1513 (UK).
34
Irish Sugar plc v Commission of the European Communities (1999) ECR II-2969 (UK).
35
Brooke Group Ltd. v Brown & Williamson Tobacoo Corp. 509 US 209 (1993).
36
Jonathan B Baker, ‘Predatory Pricing after Brooke Group: An Economic Perspective’ (1994) 62 Antitrust L.J.
585, 586.
37
Matsushita Electric Industrial Co. v Zenith Radio Corp. 475 US 574 (1986).
38
Cargill, Inc. v Monfort of Colorado, Inc. 479 U. S. 104, 117 (1986).
39
Richard Posner, Antitrust Laws, vol 3 (2nd edn, 2006) 2351.
conduct has to pursue a legitimate aim, be reasonable and proportionate to the threat posed by
its competitors.40
After the period of infancy comes the process of maturity and excuses for "promotional" or
"penetrative" pricing start veering.41 Several agencies stated that the discounts can be
anticompetitive if they effectively foreclose a large share of the relevant market42 and exclude
rivals as a substantial impediment to entry and/or expansion.43
Since, all these 5 companies were using Rutta 2.0, which has certain fixed variables44. These
fixed variables could not be altered manually like in Rutta. Therefore there is a probability of
it leading to determine similar or parallel pricing. Therefore any synchrony in the prices
observed, can be arguably due to the Rutta 2.0 and not due to any collusion between the
parties.
Also, it is a necessity to use pricing algorithms like Rutta 2.0 in the today’s competitive
scenario as these algorithms provide benefits on both demand and supply side.
The rise of algorithms on the supply side can also promotes static efficiencies by reducing the
cost of production, improving quality and resource utilisation, as well as streamlining
business processes.45
On the demand side, they can assist in improving, refining or developing products and
services in a number of ways. Some e-commerce sites use past purchase information and
browsing history to make personalised shopping recommendations for users. 46
Similarly, the advanced version (Rutta 2.0) also had another special feature called as ‘Birds
Eye’ which is a web crawler software. Birds Eye program can analyse the traffic or searches
for a product on the leading world search engine ‘Jugaadu’. This would enable the e –
40
United Brands v Commission (1978) 3 C.M.L.R. 83.
41
MCX Stock Exchange Ltd. v National Stock Exchange of India Ltd. (2012) 2 CompLJ 473.
42
Greek Telecommunications Organization (OTE) v National Commission (2005) E.C.C. 2 (UK).
43
Napp Pharmaceutical Holdings L. v Director General of Fair Trading (2002) E.C.C. 13.
44
¶12, Moot Proposition.
45
‘Algorithms and Collusion: Competition Policy in the Digital Age’ (Oecd.org, 2017)
<www.oecd.org/competition/algorithms-collusion-competition-policy-in-the-digital-age.htm.> accessed 19
January 2019.
46
Ibid.
commerce websites to understand the total market considerations before deciding the price
for a commodity.47
c. Efficiency gains.
Efficiency gains which has two aspects. Firstly, non-implication of some kind of inefficiency
i.e. socially undesirable wastes of economic resources,48 and Secondly, conformance with
public interest.49
In the Raghavan committee report50, it was stated that when the reduction in the prices of the
product is done with the intention of eliminating other firms, it should be prevented.
However, the restrictions should not prevent the firms capturing the larger market share due
to high efficiency and low prices. There should be a demarcating line between wilful
restrictions to eliminate competition and reduction in competition due to high-level efficiency
of the dominant firm.
In the instant case, all three categories are satisfied and the justification for reduced pricing is
to meet the competition.
Although algorithmic pricing is not illegal and is a common practice in many industries, it
was the existence of an agreement to jointly implement the algorithm that makes it
unlawful.53
In Trod Limited and GB Eye Ltd.54 the Competition and Markets Authority (the ‘CMA)
stated:
47
¶11, Moot Proposition.
48
Weizsäcker, Barriers to Entry-A Theoretical Treatment (1st edn, Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 1980).
49
Haridas Exports v All India Float Glass Manufacturers Association (2002) 111 Comp. Cas. 617 (SC) .
50
Report of the High Level Committee on Competition Policy & Law, 2000.
51
Case 40/73 Suiker Unie v Commission [1975] ECR 1663.
52
Case 48/69 Imperial Chemical Industries (1972) ECR 619.
53
‘Algorithms and Collusion: Competition Policy in the Digital Age’ (Oecd.org, 2017)
<www.oecd.org/competition/algorithms-collusion-competition-policy-in-the-digital-age.htm.> accessed 19
January 2019.
“5.47. Further, the CMA notes that repricing software used by the Parties to implement the
Infringing Agreement is normally used by online sellers to compete with other online sellers
by automatically adjusting the prices of their products in response to the live prices of
competitors’ products. However, in the present case the repricing software was configured by
the Parties to restrict price competition between them in order to give effect to the Infringing
Agreement”
In the case of U.S. v. David Topkins55, the US Department of Justice (DOJ) charged a seller
in the Amazon marketplace, David Topkins, of coordinating with other sellers for setting the
prices of posters through price algorithms. Although algorithmic pricing is not illegal and is a
common practice in many industries56, it was the existence of an agreement to jointly
implement the algorithm that made the case for the DOJ.
Therefore, in absence of any agreement between parties mere usage of pricing algorithm
between the parties is not per se anticompetitive.
Even NCLAT came to conclusion that that DG’s report had appropriate conclusions and
“cartel cases cannot be prosecuted in the absence of direct evidence of anti-competitive
agreements between the parties.”58
To invoke the provisions of section 3 of the Act, the existence of an ‘agreement’ is sine qua
non.59It is therefore contended that the CCK has come to a conclusion after considering
merely one factor, namely, the parallelism in prices,60 which as mentioned above is
commonly acknowledged to be insufficient. In the absence of any other evidence in support
54
Trod Limited and GB Eye Ltd. Case 50223
55
US v David Topkins No. 15 Cr. 201 (N.D. Cal.).
56
‘Algorithms and Collusion: Competition Policy in the Digital Age’ (Oecd.org, 2017)
<www.oecd.org/competition/algorithms-collusion-competition-policy-in-the-digital-age.htm.> accessed 19
January 2019.
57
¶23, Moot Proposition.
58
¶26, Moot Proposition.
59
In re: Alleged cartelization by steel producers 2012 Indlaw CCI 45.
60
¶25, Moot Proposition.
of such an allegation, we humbly submit that the findings of the CCK were not in conformity
with legal standards and thereby erroneous.
Two main sources of evidence of concerted practice are: i. direct evidence of coordination64
ii. Indirect evidence of coordination which cannot be explained otherwise than by collision.65
Thus, an examination must always be made of whether the parallel conduct can be explained
by normal market conditions or must have been coordinated.66 It is submitted that the acts of
the respondents can very well be attributed to be a parallel behaviour which is not illegal per
se.67
A yardstick was laid down in the case of Hanuman v. State of Madhya Pradesh68 that;
“Circumstances should be of a nature such as to exclude every hypothesis but the one
proposed to be proved or to show that within all human probability they must have acted in
concert.” As was held in SA & Grundig,69 the probability and not merely possibility70 is
important. A cartel needs to be profitable since it is illegal and poses risks.71 Thus, the wider
the variations in the marginal gains, the less stable the cartel will be72 since the interest
diverges substantially and with the risk of cheating, it is effectively impossible.73
61
Herbert Hovenkamp, Federal Antitrust Policy: The Law Of Competition (4th edn, 2011) 80.
62
Bayer v Commission 2000 ECR II-3383 (UK).
63
European Commission v Volkswagen [2006] ECR I-6585.
64
Polypropylene-Atochem 1991 ECR-II 1991 (UK).
65
In re SACEM III 1989 ECR 2521 (UK).
66
Polypropylene-Petrofina 1991 ECR II-1087 (UK).
67
Theater enterprises Inc. v Paramount Film Distributing Corp. 346 U.S. 537 (1948).
68
Hanuman v State of Madhya Pradesh AIR 1979 SC 798.
69
DP Mittal, Competition Law and Practice (3rd edn, 2011) 176.
70
SA & Grundig – Verkaufs – GmbH v Commission 1966 ECR 299 (UK).
71
Lennart Ritter and W David Braun, European Competition Law: A Practitioner’s Guide (3rd edn, 2005) 245.
72
Margret C. Levenstien, ‘What determines Cartel Success?’ (2006) 54 J. ECON. LIT. 43 86.
73
Herbert Hovenkamp, Federal Antitrust Policy: The Law Of Competition (4th edn, 2011) 80.
74
Joined cases T-68, 77 and 78/89 SocietaItalianaVietro [1992] ECR II-1403; Case T-102/96 Gencor v
Commission [1999] ECR II-753.
be against the interests of the economy and of the public. Economic links must be shown in
order to prove the joint nature of the companies implicated.75
It is submitted that there are no economic links between the companies which can help them
to enter into anti-competitive agreements. Trade associations do not ipso facto engage in an
unlawful restraint of commerce.76
75
Builders' Association of India v Cement Manufacturers' Association & Ors. 2016CompLR 983 (CCI).
76
Maple Flooring Manufacturers association et al v United States 268 US 563 (1925).
77
DP Mittal, Competition Law and Practice (3rd edn, 2011) 171.
78
Mahindra & Mahindra Ltd. v Union of India (1979) 2 SCC 529.
79
DP Mittal, Competition Law and Practice (3rd edn, 2011) 178.
80
SM Duggar, Guide to Competition Law and Policy (5th edn, 2010) 68.
81
‘Algorithms and Collusion: Competition Policy in the Digital Age’ (Oecd.org, 2017)
<www.oecd.org/competition/algorithms-collusion-competition-policy-in-the-digital-age.htm.> accessed 19
January 2019.
82
¶6, Moot Proposition.
aggressive levels in Kratos.83 The above facts clearly leads to the conclusion that Rutta and
Rutta 2.0 helped in strengthening the competition between e-commerce websites in Kratos.
83
¶14, Moot Proposition.
84
Competition Act, 2002.
85
Competition Act, s 19(3)(d).
86
Annexure 8, Moot Proposition.
87
Competition Act, s19(3)(e).
88
Competition Act, s 19(3)(f).
89
Competition Act, s 19(3)(b).
90
¶4, Moot Proposition.
91
Competition Act, s 19(3)(a).
92
¶5, Moot Proposition.
The Competition Appellate Tribunal (COMPAT) has denied the admissibility of news report
in Lupin Limited case96, where it observed that “the so called information available in the
public domain could not have been used by the Commission because no one had appeared in
the witness box to prove the same.”
A news report that has no further proof of what actually transpired has zero evidentiary
value.97 Judicial notice of news items can be taken by the court if they are proved by evidence
aliunde.98 The details provided in the report need to be proved by the news channel with help
of sufficient evidence on record.99
No substantial material was provided to strengthen the validity of the news report and hence
the same is not admissible in the court of law.
To come with the definition of ‘State’, the entity in question must be declared as an
instrumentality of State.103 Instrumentality of state is an entity that discharges an essential
93
¶28, Moot Proposition.
94
R. P. Luthra v CBI 2014 Indlaw DEL 2951.
95
Indian Evidence Act, 1872.
96
Lupin Limited others v Competition Commission of India and others 2016 Indlaw COMPAT 34; Board of
Control for Cricket in India v Competition Commission of India and another 2015 Indlaw COMPAT 8.
97
Samant N. Balakrishna v George Fernandez (1969) 3 SCC 238; Oommen Chandy v State of Kerala and others
2016 Indlaw KER 599.
98
Laxmi Raj Shetty & Anr v State of Tamil Nadu 1988 Indlaw SC 69.
99
Khilumal Topandas v Arjundas Tulsidas 1959 Indlaw RAJ 26.
100
Constitution of India, art 12.
101
Ajay Hasia v Khalid Mujib (1981) 1SCC 722.
102
Zee Telefilms Ltd. v Union of India (2005) 4 SCC 649.
public function.104It is a settled principle that company does not come under the definition of
company.105
In the present suit, the respondents are private entities that do not discharge any public
function nor do they hold any statutory power106 therefore Fundamental rights cannot be
enforced against them. Any violation of fundamental rights by private entities needs to be
dealt by the general laws.107
2.2.2. NO VIOLATION
The Respondents humbly submit that there exists no violation of fundamental right of
appellants in the instant suit and any injury suffered by them is one which is suffered due to
fair competition and not due to any illegal conduct on part of respondents.
To constitute violation of Fundamental rights in the present case it is necessary to prove some
illegal act or else it will amount to wrongful prosecution.108 Mere injury, no matter how
severe, suffered when the other party was acting in accordance with the relevant law, cannot
amount to violation of fundamental rights.109
In defining offline retail and online retail markets it has been observed that buyers weigh the
options available in both markets before making a purchase. Thus both markets are,
essentially, different distribution channels of the same product; hence, part of a single
market.110
It has been established that e-commerce enterprises form a small part of entire retail market111
thus any such player cannot create any adverse effect on the market structure prevalent in
Kratos.112 In the present case none of the respondent companies have sufficient market
103
The Executive Engineer (State Of Karnataka) v K. Somasetty & Ors. 1997 Indlaw SC 996, (1997) 5 SCC
434.
104
M.C. Mehta v Union of India (1987) 1 SCC 395; Unni Krishnan, J.P. & Ors. v State of Andhra Pradesh &
Ors. 1993 AIR 217, 1993 SCR (1) 594.
105
S.K. Mukherjee v Chemical Allied Products AIR 1962 Cal 10, 65 CWN 1172, 1961 (3) FLR 404.
106
Kochuni K.K. v State of Madras 1960 AIR SC 1080.
107
P.D. Shamdasani v Central Bank Of India 1952 AIR 59, 1952 SCR 391.
108
Babloo Chauhan @ Dabloo v State Govt. of NCT of Delhi 247 (2018) DLT 31.
109
State of Punjab v Rafiq Masih (2015) 4 SCC 334; Chameli Singh v State of Uttar Pradesh AIR 1996 SC
1051, (1996) 2 SCC 549.
110
Ashish Ahuja v Snapdeal and Anr 2014 Indlaw CCI 42.
111
'E-Commerce Share Of Total Retail Sales By Country 2017' (Statista, 2018)
<https://www.statista.com/statistics/255083/online-sales-as-share-of-total-retail-sales-in-selected-countries/>
accessed 23 February 2019.
112
In Re: Mr. Mohit Manglani v M/s Flipkart India Private Limited & Ors. Case No. 80 of 2014(CCI).
share.113The current market structure does not allow a particular market player to emerge as a
dominant enterprise due to high substitutability between products and countervailing buying
power of consumers.114 In absence of the ability to direct market in their favor, the
respondents cannot be abstained from providing discounts to their consumers.115
In present case even though the respondent companies were able to increase their respective
share but they compete amongst themselves and continue to do so till date. Any pricing
strategy to meet the competition in the market cannot be treated as illegal116 unless intention
to drive out competitors is proved.117 It has to be noted, if market share increases
substantially but profits increase by a small margin due to discounting policy of the party and
economies of scale, then such conduct cannot be held violative of fundamental rights simply
because goods are sold at a price lower than that of its competitors118, unless done in a
manner that directly affects the public at large.119
The law does not allow imposition of cap on discounts offered120 if adopted to meet the
competition.121 On the other hand, any agreement which imposes minimum price for products
not only hinders the ability of dealers to compete on price of product122 but also harms the
consumers resulting in adverse effect on competition.123 Imposition of minimum resale price
is per se illegal.124
Exclusivity agreements between the respondents and producers do not amount to any
appreciable adverse effect on competition (“AAEC”) in Kratos as most of the products sold
via such arrangement face stiff competitive constraints and substitutes for the same are
readily available.125 Various features offered by respondents allow the buyers to compare
various products and thus improve the competition.126 The basic structure of competition act
113
¶ 4, Moot Proposition; MCX Stock Exchange Ltd v National Stock Exchange of India Ltd. 2011 SCC OnLine
CCI 52, 2011 Comp LR 0129 (CCI).
114
All India Online Vendors Association v Flipkart India Private Limited and Anr. Case No. 20 of 2018(CCI).
115
All India Online Vendors Association v Flipkart India Private Limited and Anr. Case No. 20 of 2018(CCI);
Fast Track Call Cab Private Limited and another v ANI Technologies Private Limited 2017 Indlaw CCI 48.
116
United Brands v Commission (1978) 3 C.M.L.R. 83 (UK).
117
In Re: Johnson And Johnson Ltd. (1988) 64 Comp Case 394 NULL.
118
Notice under sub-section (2) of Section 6 of the Competition Act, 2002 filed by Wal-Mart International
Holdings, Inc. Combination Registration No. C-2018/05/571
119
US v Aluminum Co of America (Alcoa) 148 F.2d 416 (2d Cir. 1945).
120
Fx Enterprise Solutions India Pvt. Ltd. & Anr.v Hyundai Motor India Limited 2017 Indlaw CCI 39.
121
Competition act, 2002, s 4(2) (a) (ii).
122
Jasper Infotech v Kaff Appliances 2019 Indlaw CCI 1.
123
Brooke Group Ltd v Brown and Williamson Tobacco Corporation 509 US 209 (1993).
124
Competition act, 2002, s 3(4) (e).
125
¶6, Moot Proposition.
126
In Re: Mr. Mohit Manglani v M/s Flipkart India Private Limited & Ors. Case No. 80 of 2014(CCI).
allows for survival of the most competent player in the market.127 If a competitor is able to
best his counterparts because of better strategies then it is not for the court to assume that his
actions have been illegal.128
Any infringement or illegal act needs to be proved with the help of clear and cogent
evidence.129 Benefit of doubt should be given to the respondents to the extent the doubt can
stand130 and no adverse inference should be drawn by the courts towards the pricing strategies
of the Respondent companies.
Article 21 provides for protection of livelihood and does not impose any positive obligation
on state to provide livelihood to such people who have lost the same as a result of lawful
conduct of some other party.131
The conduct of the respondents in the present case was lawful and in response to the market
forces prevalent in the market. Therefore no adverse inference with regards to violation of
fundamental rights should be drawn.132
In All India Footwear Manufacturers & Retailers Association v. Union of India petition134 a
petition was presented before Delhi High Court where brick-and-mortar retailers have alleged
that e-commerce sites are offering heavy discounts which amounts to violation of
Fundamental Rights of such “brick and mortar” retailers. Before the matter could be decided
127
Brooke Group Ltd v Brown and Williamson Tobacco Corporation 509 US 209 (1993).
128
Accreditation Commission for Conformity Assessment Bodies Private Limited v Quality Council of
India/National Accreditation Board For Certification Bodies and others 2012 Indlaw CCI 62.
129
Neeraj Malhotra v North Delhi Power Ltd. (2011) 3 SCC 436; Naap Pharmaceuticals Holdings v Office of
Communications (2002) CAT 1; In re JFE Engineering (2004) ECR II-2501 (UK).
130
Dinesh Bulakhi Harijan v The State 2009 CriLJ 114.
131
Delhi Development Horticulutre Employees’ Union v Delhi Administration AIR 1992 SC 789; Benilal v State
of Maharashtra 1995 Supp (1) SCC 235; Indian Drugs & Pharmaceuticals Ltd. v Workmen, Indian Drugs &
Pharmaceuticals Ltd. (2007) 1 SCC 408.
132
Dish TV v Prasar Bharti Case No. 44 of 2010(CCI).
133
RC Cooper v Union of India 1970 AIR SC 564; Peerless General Finance and Investment Company v Union
of India (1992)2 SCC 343; Bhavesh D Parish v Union of India (2000) 5 SCC 471; Ekta Shakti Foundation v
Govt. of NCT Delhi (2006) 10 SCC 337; Manohar Lal Sharma v Union of India (2013) 6 SCC 616.
134
All India Footwear Manufacturers & Retailers Association v Union of India W.P. (C) 7479/2015; Retailers
Association of India v Union of India W.P. (C) 5034/2015.
the petitioners, due to clarification issued by the Government of India vide Press Note
3(2016)135, choose to withdraw from the petition.136
In the instant suit appellants have made similar allegations with regards to the pricing policy
of respondents.137 The Press Note dated 26th December 2018 dealing with Foreign Direct
Investment (FDI) policy is the same clarification that has been mentioned in the above
case.138
The FDI policy has amended paragraph 5.2.15.2 (e-commerce activities) of the current
'Consolidated FDI Policy' of the DIPP to incorporate the following:
1. Entities using Marketplace platform are not to exercise control over the inventory of
other enterprise or make more than 25% of the sales on the platform from such
enterprise or its ‘group companies’.139 Marketplace entities are further barred from
equity participation in any of the sellers on its platform.140 Marketplace entities used
to create/ invest in companies which in turn acted as wholesalers. They had huge
buying power therefore got better discounts from producers which reflected in the
prices offered by marketplace entities. New FDI policy prohibits this conduct. This
enables the brick and mortar retailers to attain equal footing in terms of disposable
resources.
2. Marketplace entities are barred from using unfair and discriminatory pricing. This
includes, but not limited to, restrictions on discounts and cashbacks offered on certain
products. Any discount offered on product of one seller also needs to be incorporated
in the products of other sellers as well.141
3. No marketplace entity is allowed to enter into exclusive agreements with any
enterprise for sale of products on marketplace platform.142 This enables the sellers to
list their product on more than one marketplace thereby allowing such products more
market exposure. This increases the sales of such vendors due to economies of scale.
135
Press Note 2 (2018) by DIPP.
136
All India Footwear Manufacturers & Retailers Association v Union of India W.P. (C) 7479/2015; Retailers
Association of India v Union of India W.P. (C) 5034/2015.
137
¶30, Moot Proposition.
138
All India Footwear Manufacturers & Retailers Association v Union of India W.P. (C) 7479/2015; Retailers
Association of India v Union of India W.P. (C) 5034/2015.
139
¶5.2.15.2.4 (iv), Press Note 2 (2018) by DIPP.
140
¶5.2.15.2.4 (v), Press Note 2 (2018) by DIPP.
141
¶5.2.15.2.4 (ix), Press Note 2 (2018) by DIPP.
142
¶5.2.15.2.4 (xi), Press Note 2 (2018) by DIPP.
There exist no violation of fundamental rights in the existing case and any discrepancy
arising out of lack of legislative mandate has already been remedied by the Press Note No. 2
(2018). Due to the aforementioned reasons appellants have no cause of action left to contest
the present suit.
In presence of a statutory redressal forum, High Court is not to entertain any petition
presented before it by-passing such statutory remedy.146 If a right or liability is created by a
statute, then it is essential to resort to the statutory remedy provided therein for the
enforcement of the right or the liability before invoking the extraordinary and prerogative
writ jurisdiction of the High Court.147
The Apex Court in Thansingh Nathumal v Supdt of Taxes148 held that “a High Court shall not
entertain a writ petition, where the petitioner has an alternative remedy, which without being
unduly onerous provides an equally efficacious remedy.”
It is the duty of High Court not to entertain the petition and relegate the petition to
appropriate form.149 Supreme Court has issued strict instructions to High Court to exercise
the extraordinary jurisdiction, vested in them by virtue of Article 226, with great caution.150
143
Union of India v T.R.Varma AIR 1957 SC 882; Municipal Council Customs v Shanti Lal AIR 1966 SC 197;
Vali Pero v Fernando Lopez (1989) 4 SCC 671.
144
PN Kumar v Municipal Corp of Delhi 1988 SCR (1) 732.
145
Kanubhai Brahmbhatt v State of Gujarat AIR 1987 SC 1159.
146
Commissioner of Income Tax v Chhabil Dass Agrawal (2014) 1 SCC 603; Nivedita Sharma v Cellular
Operators Association of India 2011 14(SCC) 337; Bela Rani Bhattcharyya v Union of India 2014 Indlaw DEL
3601; 2014 (213) DLT 1.
147
Commissioner of Income Tax and Ors. v Chhabil Dass Agarwal (2014) 1 SCC 603.
148
Thansingh Nathumal v Supdt of Taxes AIR 1964 SC 1419.
149
Mina Perween v The State Of West Bengal & Ors MAT 515 of 2018; U.P. State Bridge Corporation Ltd And
Others v U.P. RajyaSetu Nigam S. KaramchariSangh (2004) 4 SCC 268.
150
United Bank of India v Satyawati Tondon (2010) 8 SCC 110; State of Goa v A.H. Jaffar and Sons Asstt. AIR
1995 SC 333; Collector, C.E., Chandan Nagar v Dunlop India Limited AIR 1985 SC 330; Uttaranchal Forest
Development Corporation v Jabar Singh (2007) 2 SCC 112; U.P v U.P Rajya Khanij Vikas Nigam S.S 2008 (9)
Scale 1
Even During the final hearing, it is open to the Court to dismiss the Writ Petition on the
ground of alternative remedy, notwithstanding the issuing of Rule Nisi.151
In the present suit, the allegations put forth by the appellants do not invoke the extraordinary
jurisdiction vested within the High Courts.152 The present suit arises out of alleged anti-
competitive activities of respondents.153 The regulation of fair trade in the state of Kratos lies
with Competition Commission of Kratos154 which is also the competent tribunal in the
present case.
The respondents humbly submit before the honorable court that there exists no violation of
fundamental rights in the present suit. High Court or Supreme Court is not the appropriate
tribunal to deal with the issues at hand in presence of statutory remedy available with the
appellants.
151
Nivedita Sharma v Cellular Operators Association of India 2011 14(SCC) 337.
152
P.V. Surender Babu v Prohibition & Excise Supdt. Chittoor 1998 (5) ALD 549.
153
¶28, Moot Proposition.
154
¶21, Moot Proposition.
155
Jyoti Swaroop Arora v. Tulip Infratech Ltd. 2015 CompLR 109 (CCI); Sanjeev Rao v Andhra Pradesh Hire
Purchase Association Case No. 49 of 2012(CCI); Shri Sonam Sharma v Apple, Vodafone, Airtel & Ors. 2013
CompLR 346 (CCI).
Same was observed by the commission in Royal Energy Ltd v. IOCL156where it was held that
the concept of collective dominance is not envisaged under Section 4 of the Competition Act.
In In Re: Dish TV India Limited case157, the commission found out that appraisal of Section 4
and 5 makes is abundantly clear that Competition Act, 2002 covers dominance of one
enterprise or a group of enterprises. The word “group” as referred in section 4 of the Act does
not include or refer to a group of independent entities or enterprises.
The Commission in the case of Consumer Online Foundation Informant v. Tata Sky
Limited158 covered the aspect of ‘collective dominance’ and observed:
“It further observed that Indian law does not recognize collective abuse of
dominance as there is no concept of “collective dominance‟ which has
evolved in jurisdictions such as Europe.”
The Commission has on more than one instances found that the concept of collective
dominant position is not applicable to Indian cases.159
Therefore, DG has rightly concluded that collective dominance is neither present nor possible
according to Indian law.160
156
Royal Energy Ltd v IOCL and others 2012 CompLR 563 (CCI).
157
Dish TV India Ltd v Hathway Cable & Datacom Ltd 2014 Indlaw CCI 20.
158
Consumer Online Foundation v Tata Sky Limited & Ors. 2011 Indlaw CCI 12.
159
Indian Sugar Mills Association v Indian Jute Mills Association 2014 CompLR 225 (CCI); M/s Royal Energy
Ltd. v M/s Indian Oil Corporation Ltd. & Ors. 2012 CompLR 563 (CCI); Manappuram Jewellers Pvt. Ltd. v
Kerala Gold & Silver Dealers Association 2012 CompLR 548 (CCI).
160
¶36, Moot Proposition.
161
Competition Act, 2002, s 4.
is the task of the legislature, not the judiciary.162 The latter’s job is only to interpret the law
made by the legislature, and direct its enforcement.163In England, this principle was strictly
enforced because there was no written constitution, and parliament was supreme. Hence law
making by judges would violate the principle of parliamentary supremacy.164
In the case of Divisional Manager Aravali Golf Course v. Chander Haas165, a bench of
Justice A.K. Mathur and Justice Markandey Katju wrote a detailed judgment saying that there
is separation of powers in the constitution between the three organs of the state, and one
organ should not ordinarily encroach into the domain of another, otherwise there will be
chaos. If there is no law judges cannot enforce it.166
162
Jeremy Waldron, ‘Separation of Powers in Thought and Practice’ (2013) 54 B.C.L. Rev. 433
<http://lawdigitalcommons.bc.edu/bclr/vol54/iss2/2> accessed 12 January 2019.
163
Markandey Katju, 'Can Judges Legislate? The Supreme Court Sets The Record Straight.' (The Wire, 2018)
<https://thewire.in/law/can-judges-legislate-the-supreme-court-sets-the-record-straight> accessed 12 January
2019.
164
Magor and St Mellons RDC v Newport Corporation [1951] 2 All ER 839.
165
Divisional Manager Aravali Golf Course v Chander Haas 2008 (3) JT 221.
166
Indian Drugs & Pharmaceuticals Ltd. v The Workman of Indian Drugs & Pharmaceuticals Ltd. (2007) 1
SCC 408; S.C. Chandra and Ors. v State of Jharkhand and Ors. JT 2007 (10) 4 SC 272.
167
Harla v The State Of Rajasthan 1951 AIR 467, 1952 SCR 110.
168
Cantonment Board, Dinapore v Taramani AIR 1995 SC 61, 1992 Supp (2) SCC 501.
169
Mahabir Coke Industry v PCB AIR 1998 Gau 10.
In S. Khushboo v. Kanniammal170 Supreme court has held that a person cannot be tried for an
alleged offence unless the legislature has made it punishable by law and it falls within
definition of offence. Similarly, When Act171 does not provide for abuse of collective
dominance as an offence, Respondents should not be held liable.
Moreover, The Competition (Amendment) Bill, 2012172 was introduced to include the
concept of collective dominance by amending section 4(1)173 to include words "jointly or
singly". The bill has not been passed in the either of the house of parliament, therefore it
cannot be enforced.
170
S. Khushboo v Kanniammal AIR 2010 SC 3196.
171
Competition Act, 2002.
172
The Competition (Amendment) Bill, 2012.
173
Competition Act, 2002.
174
R. Klayani v Janak C Mehta 2008 (14) SCALE 85.
175
State of West Bengal v Swapan Kumar Guha AIR 1982 SC 949.
The respondents humbly submit that they are included in the relevant market of ‘market for
e-wallets, credit card/debit card payment options, net banking and cash on delivery in
Kratos.’
Market place is the place of operation between the parties in trade with each other.177 The
relevant market is the area of effective competition.178 In Kali & Salz179 it was held that to
access whether the alleged market player has a dominant position or not the primary
requirement is to define the relevant market. Section 19(5)180 provides that to define relevant
market, its two facets need to be established- Relevant Product Market and Relevant
Geographical Market. In A.K. Jain (OP) v. The Dwarkadhis Projects (P) Ltd.181 The plaintiff
was alleged with abusing its dominant position but the commission was of the view that the
plaintiff was not holding dominant position182 in the established relevant market and hence
was not liable.183
a) Substitutability
While defining the relevant product market under Section 2(t)184 of the Act, all those products
or services which are regarded as interchangeable or substitutable by the consumer, by reason
of characteristics of the products or services185, their prices186 and intended use187, need to be
included in the realm of relevant product market. The products, to be a part of the same
176
¶35, Moot Proposition.
177
Kailash Suneja v Appropriate Authority (1998) 231 ITR 318 (Del).
178
Standard Oil Co. of California and Standard Station Inc. v US 337 US 293.
179
Joined Cases C-68/94 and C-30/95 Kali & Salz [1998] ECR I-1375; Airtours Plc v. Commission, Case T-
342/99, [2002] ECR II-2585, ¶19; NVV v. Commission Case T-151/5, [2009] ECR II-1219; Volkswagen AG v
Commission of the European Communities [2000] ECR II-2707.
180
Competition Act, 2002, s 19(5).
181
A.K. Jain (OP) v The Dwarkadhis Projects (P) Ltd. 2015 CompLR 487 (CompAT).
182
R. Ramkumar v Akshaya Private Limited 2017 Indlaw CCI 71.
183
Rishi Keshwani v Kanti Traders 2017 Indlaw CCI 61.
184
Competition Act, 2002, s 2(t).
185
Competition Act, 2002, s 19(7)(a).
186
Competition Act, 2002, s 19(7)(b).
187
Commission Notice on the definition of the Relevant Market for the purposes of Community Competition
Law OJ 1997 C372.
market, need not be perfect substitutes.188It is also necessary to determine the category of
clients who require such goods/services.189
Further, Telefonica case190held that “from a demand-side perspective, P2P payments services
through a digital wallet are interchangeable with traditional online banking or off-line
transactions. In particular, the market investigation provided indications that in Spain there
are already a number of mobile/online P2P payment applications which are offered to
consumers to carry out transactions with end-users, and which are substitutable with
traditional online payments, such as money transfers, or direct debit.” Therefore E –wallets
is substitutable with traditional online payment system.
E-wallets can be used to buy goods and services online based on value of money that is
stored on each such instrument.191 They need to be loaded with money before
usage.192However, the nature of service remains same as that of mode of payment on e-
commerce market193 and moreover, consumers perceive it as an alternative to other modes of
payment on e-commerce website.194 Moreover, in a market where there is substitutability
between e – wallets, credit card/debit card payment options, net banking and cash on
delivery, each can effectively present a competitive constraint since they have a lot of the
same characteristics as others such as ease of payment and carrying out transaction etc.195
The presence of these characteristics means that credit card/debit card payment options, net
banking and cash on delivery are capable of being substituted with e – wallets.196
188
Arshiya Rail Infrastructure Limited v Ministry of Railways 2012 Indlaw CCI 25; British Airways v
Commission [2003] ECR II-5917; Kish Glass v Commission [2000] ECR-II 1885; Clearstream v Commission
General Court [2009] ECR II-3155.
189
Hugin v Commission [1979] E.C.R. 1869.
190
Case No COMP/M.6956 - TELEFONICA/ CAIXABANK/ BANCO SANTANDER / JV.
191
Master Direction on Issuance and Operation of Prepaid Payment Instruments, Art 2.3.
192
Master Direction on Issuance and Operation of Prepaid Payment Instruments, Art 7.
193
Guidance on the Commission’s Enforcement Priorities in applying (Article 102 TFEU) to Abusive
Exclusionary conduct by Dominant Undertaking. [2009] OJ C45/7; Fast Track Call Cab Private Limited and
another v ANI Technologies Private Limited 2017 Indlaw CCI 48.
194
Aberdeen Journals v Director General of Fair Trading CAT 4 [2002] Comp AR 167.
195
Robert Pitofsky, ‘New Definitions of Relevant Market and the Assault on Antitrust’ (1990) 87 COLOMBIA
LAW REVIEW 1805,1807.
196
B A K, ‘The Role of Supply Substitutability in Defining the Relevant Product Market’ (1979) 65 VIRGINIA
LAW REVIEW 129, 132.
197
Magnus Graphics v Nilpeter India Pvt. Ltd. 2015 CompLR 93 (CCI).
confined to a specific model only, though they used different technologies198 the end-use of
goods was the same. E-wallet services are perceived as substitutes by the common customers
intending to purchase products from e-retailers thereby placing it in the same relevant product
market.199 If two enterprises produce differentiated products but such products are perceived
by the consumers as close substitutes then both of such products will constitute same relevant
product market.200
The relevant geographic market is the area in which the undertakings concerned is involved
in the supply of relevant products or services where the conditions are homogenous.201
Relevant Geographical Market is the specific area in which conditions of competition are the
same. Section 19(6) lays down the factors for determining “relevant geographical market”
such as regulatory trade barriers202, local specification requirements203, language204, consumer
preferences205 etc. The Act provides that “all or any of the following factors” can be taken
into regard while determining the relevant geographical market. In the present suit all the
payment methods are operable across Kratos; hence the relevant geographic market stands as
Kratos.
The respondents humbly submit that the relevant market in the present case is ‘market for e-
wallets, credit card/debit card payment options, net banking and cash on delivery in Kratos.’
198
Quadrant EPP Surlon India Ltd. v INA Bearings India Pvt. Ltd. 2013 CompLR 664 (CCI).
199
Willy Alexander, 'Europemballage Corporation and Continental Can Co. Inc. v. Commission of the European
Communities. Case 6/72. Decision of February 21, 1973' (1973) 10 Common Market Law Review, Issue 3, pp.
311–318
200
Global Tax Free Traders v William Grant & Sons Limited 2015 CompLR 503 (CompAT).
201
ANI Technologies Pvt. Ltd. v. Fast Track Call Cab Pvt. Ltd. (2015) 131 SCL 240 (CCI).
202
Competition Act, 2002, s 19(6)(a).
203
Competition Act, 2002, s 19(6)(b).
204
Competition Act, 2002, s 19(6)(f).
205
Competition Act, 2002, s 19(6)(g).
Since In the instant case, Premier, Moneykart and Chapo were collectively holding 75% of
the market share only in Kratoian e-wallet segment.206 But relevant market would also
include credit card/debit card payment options, net banking and cash on delivery. Thus, their
share as considered in the whole relevant market of e-wallets, credit card/debit card payment
options, net banking and cash on delivery would be much less taking into consideration that
respondents did not/ have any other product in the relevant market except e –wallets.
Moreover, market shares of an entity is ‘only one of the factors that decides whether an
enterprise is dominant or not, but that factor alone cannot be decisive proof of
dominance.207Therefore, that respondent’s insignificant market share in the relevant market
for e-wallets, credit card/debit card payment options, net banking and cash on delivery in
Kratos concludes their weak market strength.
206
¶24, Moot Proposition.
207
Mr. Ramakant Kini v L.H. Hiranandani Hospital 2014 Indlaw CCI 79.
208
Competition Act, 2002, s. 19(4)(b).
209
Belaire Owners’ Association v DLF Limited, HUDA & Ors. [2011] 104 CLA 398 (CCI).
210
M/s HT Media v Super Cassettes Industries Limited 2014 Indlaw CCI 74.
211
SM Duggar, Guide To Competition Law and Policy (5th edn, 2010).
When the agreement did not suggest any clause of exclusive dealing with the appellant nor
did it spell out any loyalty clause, - restricting choice, access to competing suppliers212, It
cannot be treated as an infringement of provisions of 4(2)(c).213 Similarly in the instant case,
when there is no such exclusivity clause mentioned in their respective special agreements. No
allegation of hindering the competitors to enter or survive into market by denial of market
access can be sustained.
Furthermore, COMPAT in the Schott Glass case214 has concluded that merely because the
NGC and NGA were product from common tank and because same were being marketed by
same appellant, did not mean that the appellant was insisting on any tying-in arrangement in
respect of NGC and NGB tubes. Thereby exonerating Schott glass of sec. 4(2)(d) charges.
Similarly no such presumption of tie-in agreements could be adopted in the instant case
solely on the basis that e-commerce website and its e- wallets belong to the Respondents.
3.4.PRO-COMPETITIVE JUSTIFICATION215
Assuming but not conceding that, there was an exclusive agreement between the Respondents
and ISP’s, yet it’s not an abuse as it has Pro-competitive justification.
There are various pro-competitive effects of these agreements.216 Any adverse effects on
competition are outweighed by the substantial procompetitive benefits of
exclusivity.217According to EC law, the dominant firm must prove that likely efficiencies
outweigh the likely negative effect and, that the conduct does not eliminate effective
competition.
Further, in the TELCO218 dispute, the SC had emphasized on efficiency of such agreements
and held:
“The exclusive dealings of the appellant do not impede competition but promote it. Such
dealings lead to specialization and improvement in after-sales service. The exclusive
dealership agreements do not restrict distribution in any area or prevent competition. By
making its dealers exclusive, it cannot be said that there is prevention, distortion or
restriction of competition in the territory in which the dealer operates. Any manufacturer of
212
Schott Glass India Pvt. Ltd. v CCI 2014 CompLR 295 (CompAT).
213
Competition Act, 2002.
214
Schott Glass India Pvt. Ltd. v CCI 2014 CompLR 295 (CompAT).
215
Clorox Co. v Sterling Winthrop, Inc. 117 F.3d 50, 56 (2d Cir.1997).
216
Abir Roy and Jayant Kumar, Competition Law in India (2nd edn, 2014).
217
Gilbarco, 127 F.3d at 1163.
218
TATA Engineering & Locomotive Co. Ltd. v Registrar of Restrictive Trade Practices [1977] 2 SCR 685.
vehicle similar to those of the appellant is also free to appoint dealers of its choice in the
same territory covered by the appellant’s dealers.”
Moreover, when an enterprise enters into any contract to avoid disruptions in supplies219 and
to ensure continuance of its operations. It is not considered an abuse.
Applying the above mentioned precedents in the instant case, Even if Respondents have
entered into special agreements with ISPs . It was for priority bandwidth and uninterrupted
supply of internet. Which is not an abuse. Moreover, these arrangement do not restrict
competition in the market, as there are many other ISPs in the market. Thus, other e-wallets
are free to get into such special agreements.
In addition, it may lead to incentives for exclusive distributors to focus their sale efforts on a
particular brand, thereby leading to increased investments and an enhanced brand image.220
The application of exclusive distribution helps create and maintain a brand image by
imposing a certain measure of uniformity and quality standardization, thereby increasing
attractiveness of the product to the final consumer and increasing its sale
potential.221Exclusive agreements also ensure a steady, reliable outlet of supply for a
manufacturer to enable him to make investments thereby increasing product’s efficiency and
ensure scale economies.222
Similarly, in the instant case, Respondents by good intention had entered into special
agreements for priority bandwidth and uniform internet supply to maintain its brand
reputation. Hence, it is obvious that the special agreement entered with ISPs has pro-
competitive justification leaving no room for any doubt.
Therefore, it can be deduced that the respondents are not involved in cartelisation as neither
any agreement nor appreciable adverse effect on competition is there. Further, the stand of
MTU in the high court is not sustainable as their fundamental rights were not violated and in
that case an alternative remedy is also available. Moreover FDI policy has also resolved any
possible issue. Furthermore, CCK’s decision in holding respondents liable for abuse of
collective dominant position is erroneous as Kratos Competition Act does not provide this
conduct to be an offence In addition, the agreements between respondents and ISP’s have
pro-competitive justification.
219
Explosives Manufacturers Welfare Association v. Coal India Limited, 2012 CompLR 525 (CCI).
220
Guidelines on Vertical Restraints OJ C 130.
221
Guidelines on Vertical Restraints OJ C 130.
222
Ibid.
PRAYER
WHEREFORE, in the lights of, issues raised, arguments advanced and authorities cited, it is
most humbly and respectfully prayed that this Hon'ble court may be pleased to adjudge and
declare that:
The court may also be please to pass any other order, which this Hon'ble Court may deem fit
in the light of justice, equity and good Conscience.
Sd/-