The Persistance Of....
The Persistance Of....
The Persistance Of....
3000 CA Rotterdam
Netherlands
E j.mackenbach@erasmusmc.nl
T +31107038460
Acknowledgement: The author would like to thank Dr Mauricio Avendano, Dr Terje Eikemo
and Dr Frank van Lenthe for their comments on a previous version of this paper. The valuable
comments of the anonymous reviewers have also helped to further improve this paper and
This paper has been published as: Mackenbach JP. The persistence of health inequalities in
modern welfare states: The explanation of a paradox. Social Science and Medicine
2012;75:761-769.
1
ABSTRACT
‘welfare states’ of Western Europe, is one of the great disappointments of public health.
Health inequalities have not only persisted while welfare states were being built up, but on
some measures have even widened, and are not smaller in European countries with more
this paradox, by reviewing nine modern ‘theories’ of the explanation of health inequalities.
The theories reviewed are: mathematical artifact, fundamental causes, life course
conditions by the welfare state: (1) inequalities in access to material and immaterial
resources have not been eliminated by the welfare state, and are still substantial; (2) due to
become more homogeneous with regard to personal characteristics associated with ill-
health; and (3) due to a change in epidemiological regime, in which consumption behavior
became the most important determinant of ill-health, the marginal benefits of the
immaterial resources to which a higher social position gives access have increased.
Further research is necessary to test these hypotheses. If they are correct, the
persistence of health inequalities in modern European welfare states can partly be seen as a
failure of these welfare states to implement more radical redistribution measures, and partly
as a form of ‘bad luck’ related to concurrent developments which have changed the
2
composition of socioeconomic groups and made health inequalities more sensitive to
immaterial factors. It is argued that normative evaluations of health inequalities should take
these explanations into account, and that a direct attack on the personal, psychosocial and
immaterial resources.
stronger selection.
5. Tackling the personal, psychosocial and cultural determinants of health inequalities may
3
INTRODUCTION
of public health. All countries, including those ranking high on indices of economic prosperity
and human development, have systematic inequalities in mortality and morbidity between
occupation, income or wealth. These health inequalities are often substantial, and usually
amount to between 5 and 10 years difference in average life expectancy at birth, and
This also applies to the highly developed ‘welfare states’ of Western Europe. All
socioeconomic inequality and its various consequences. With notable variations all these
‘welfare regimes’ include measures to redistribute income (e.g. by progressive taxation and
social security) and a range of collectively financed provisions (e.g. public housing, education,
health care, access to culture and leisure facilities) (Esping-Andersen, 1990, Ferrara, 1996).
inequalities in income, housing quality, health care access and other social and economic
outcomes (Esping-Andersen, 1990, Kautto et al., 2001), but they have apparently been
spanning the whole of the 20th century are rare, but English data suggest that while
inequalities in mortality have narrowed until 1950 they have since then substantially
widened (figure 1) (Pamuk, 1985, Wilkinson, 1989). If we take 1920-1980 to be the period in
which European welfare states (including the British welfare state) were being built up, any
4
narrowing effect on inequalities in mortality must have occurred in its early stages. The
widening of mortality inequalities has continued into the 21st century, not only in Britain (Fair
Society, Healthy Lives 2010) but also in other countries with available data. During the last
also on an absolute scale, has been reported for many Western European countries
(Mackenbach et al., 2003, Strand et al.,2010, Fawcett et al., 2005, Valkonen et al., 2000). This
widening started well before the welfare reforms (with cutbacks in provisions and
entitlements) of the 1990s (Wilkinson, 1989, Strand et al., 2010, Fawcett et al., 2005,
This paradoxical situation is made even more puzzling by the lack of association
between the extent or intensity of welfare policies in a country on the one hand, and the
magnitude of its health inequalities on the other hand. Comparative studies have found that
socioeconomic inequalities in mortality and morbidity are not smaller in countries with
relatively universal and generous welfare policies (e.g. the Nordic countries) than they are in
other countries (e.g. the United Kingdom with its more liberal welfare regime, or Southern
European countries with their more family-based welfare arrangements). This was first
observed for the 1980s (Mackenbach et al., 1997) and then confirmed for the 1990s
(Mackenbach et al., 2008) and 2000s (Eikemo et al., 2008a, Eikemo et al., 2008b), and applies
both to relative and absolute measures of health inequalities. Recent reviews have
concluded that the association between welfare regimes and health inequalities is
European countries. Within Western Europe, both relative and absolute inequalities in total
mortality tend to be smallest in the South, e.g. in the regions of Turin and Madrid. This is
5
primarily due to small inequalities in mortality from cardiovascular disease (among men and
women) and cancer (among women) (Mackenbach et al., 2008). In the North of Europe,
Sweden tends to have relatively small inequalities in mortality, but Norway’s inequalities in
mortality are considerably larger than those seen in the South or in England/Wales, partly
In this paper I will explore the explanation of this paradox. What explains the
developed welfare states of Western Europe, and the lack of association between
generousness of welfare policies and the magnitude of health inequalities? Although this
question has been discussed before (Dahl et al., 2006, Eikemo & Huijts, 2009, Hurrelmann et
al., 2011, Bambra 2011), clear hypotheses have not emerged. I will review current scientific
theories on health inequalities, and evaluate what elements they could contribute to an
explanation of the paradox. My approach resembles that in Bambra (2011), but while the
latter study’s main conclusion is that “[existing] theories provide little insight into the issue”
and that this “public health puzzle highlights the limitations of existing theories”, I will argue
that some of these theories do suggest plausible hypotheses on the explanation of the
paradox. I will also review a wider range of potentially relevant theories. The conclusions of
the analysis will then be used to discuss some policy implications, starting with the question
what these explanations would imply for the normative evaluation of health inequalities in
modern welfare states. The main purpose of this paper is to generate hypotheses, and to
6
CURRENT THEORIES AND HOW THEY MAY HELP TO EXPLAIN THE PARADOX
Socioeconomic inequalities in health ultimately derive from social inequality, and an analysis
made up of three components, each of which can vary between societies and over time: (1)
mobility mechanisms that “sort” individuals into social strata, (2) allocation rules that
distribute resources to social strata, and (3) social processes that render some resources
This distinction in three components can also be used to identify the general
will then be a function of: (1) social mobility, and the resulting differences between social
strata in personal characteristics of their individual members, (2) resource distribution, and
the resulting differences between social strata in access to material and immaterial
resources, and (3) resource benefits, i.e. the value of the resources for the avoidance of
health problems which are prevalent in that society. Variations over time or between
countries in any of these factors may give rise to variations in the magnitude of health
inequalities.
Over the last two decades, the persistence and widening of health inequalities in
Western Europe, despite advances in material well-being and welfare policies, has given rise
to a rich body of empirically grounded literature. Box 1 gives an overview of nine ‘theories’ of
the explanation of health inequalities which are potentially relevant for the explanation of
the paradox. Not all of these ‘theories’ may fully deserve this label – the notion of
7
‘mathematical artifact’ is a rather narrow account only, and the ‘life course perspective’
could perhaps better be labeled a broad conceptual scheme – but for convenience we will
consistently use the term ‘theory’ to refer to each of them. None of these theories was
developed to explain the paradox that is central to this analysis, but I will assess them for
their usefulness in explaining the paradox, by deriving hypotheses that are compatible with
the observations of persisting and even widening health inequalities, also in highly
developed welfare states. Please note that I do not intend to provide a general assessment of
the validity of these theories. None of these theories is mutually exclusive, and they may
therefore operate simultaneously and reinforce each other. With the exception of three very
general theories (‘mathematical artifact’, ‘fundamental causes’, and ‘life course perspective’)
each relates to one of the three components of health stratification mentioned above.
the paradox, the strength of the proposed mechanism or pathway must have become larger
over time, and/or be larger in countries with more extensive welfare arrangements. As
modern European welfare states have to some extent been successful in reducing
inequalities in access to material resources, one or more of the other components must have
The theory of ‘mathematical artifact’ suggests that increasing relative inequalities in health
outcomes are inevitable when the overall level of the outcome falls (Scanlan, 2001, Scanlan,
2006, Vagerö & Erikson, 1997). In intuitive terms, the idea is that when the background risk
of mortality or morbidity is lower (as it tends to be in more recent time-periods, and in more
advanced welfare states), it is ‘easier’ for determinants to produce a high relative risk (even
8
though the absolute risk difference declines). There is indeed an association between the
average frequency of health problems in a population and the level of the relative risk for
socioeconomic status: relative risks for mortality and morbidity tend to be higher when
average mortality and morbidity are lower (Eikemo et al., 2009). However, it has been shown
that larger inequalities are not a mathematical necessity when over-all health improves
(Houweling et al., 2007), and an association between average frequency and relative risk
does not prove causality. Furthermore, absolute inequalities in mortality have also increased
in several countries (Mackenbach et al., 2003, Strand et al., 2010, Valkonen et al., 2000), and
mortality (Mackenbach et al., 2008), so that it is difficult to see how this theory could explain
the paradox.
The theory of ‘fundamental causes’ stipulates that it is the social forces underlying
social stratification which ultimately cause health inequalities, and not exposure to the
proximal risk factors which are usually studied by social epidemiologists (like smoking,
psychosocial stress, working conditions, …). According to this theory, the persistence of
health inequalities in different time-periods and different national conditions is due to the
fact that a person’s socioeconomic status provides him or her with “flexible resources”. These
include “knowledge, money, power, prestige, and beneficial social connections” which can be
used “to avoid disease risks or to minimize the consequences of disease once it occurs”
and health “is reproduced over time via the replacement of intervening mechanisms”, and as
opportunities for avoiding disease continue to expand so will health inequalities continue to
exist (Link & Phelan, 1995, Phelan et al., 2010, Phelan et al., 2004). This theory is an elegant
reformulation of the problem, and the paradox may actually be seen as an example of the
9
workings of this theory. But it does not provide a specific explanation of the paradox. What
are the new “intervening mechanisms” which replace the mechanisms eliminated or
attenuated by the welfare state? Or are health inequalities perhaps “reproduced” in highly
developed welfare states because people with higher socioeconomic status make better use
of these welfare resources? We thus need other theories to provide more specific
explanations.
The ‘life course perspective’ is another useful and increasingly popular approach to
the explanation of health inequalities, and is based on the observation that health at adult
ages is partly determined by experiences in early life, both biological and social. ‘Biological
diseases like diabetes and cardiovascular disease (Barker et al., 1989), and unfavorable social
and health conditions in childhood may be the starting-points of pathways leading into both
health and social disadvantage in adulthood (Wadsworth, 1997). Some of these processes
have been shown to extend over several generations (Modin & Fritzell, 2009). While this may
explain a long delay between exposure to modern welfare arrangements and a reduction of
health inequalities among adults, it does not explain the fact that even among generations
who were born during the welfare state there is no association between welfare policies and
the magnitude of health inequalities (Bambra et al., 2010). Furthermore, long delays are not
inevitable as both mortality and morbidity often respond quickly and dramatically to
changing social conditions (Vaupel et al., 2003). In any case, as with ‘fundamental causes’
Two theories focusing on social mobility and the composition of social strata
10
The theory of ‘social selection’ suggests that health inequalities result from health-related
selection during social mobility. Health problems may lead to downward social mobility
(thereby creating ‘direct health selection’) (Inequalities in Health, 1982), and upward
mobility is more likely for those with personal characteristics conducive to good health
(thereby creating ‘indirect health selection’) (West, 1991). Direct health selection is
equivalent with reverse causality (health problems leading to low socioeconomic status,
instead of vice versa), while indirect health selection can also be thought of as confounding
(by third factors which influence both health and socioeconomic status). This theory would
help to explain the paradox if social mobility has increased over time, or if social mobility has
Intergenerational social mobility has increased slowly but systematically in all high
income countries since the Second World War, both with regard to educational achievement
and occupational class (Heath, 1981, Ganzeboom, 2007, Ganzeboom et al., 1989, Breen,
have not found consistent differences between countries in rates of intergenerational social
mobility, but countries with well-developed welfare policies such as the Nordic countries
usually also have egalitarian education policies and substantial social mobility (Erikson &
Goldthorpe, 1992). As a result, the scope for both ‘direct’ and ‘indirect health selection’ is
likely to have become larger over time and to be larger in more advanced welfare states.
(dis)advantage in a society, and therefore may ‘dilute’ the health effects of social
stratification, it also increases opportunities for selection into higher social positions on the
11
certain degree modern societies have become ‘meritocracies’, in which educational and
talent and effort (Arrow, 2000). To the extent that these personal characteristics are
important for health, e.g. because they determine health-related behaviour, inequalities in
A number of studies has shown that cognitive ability and the Big Five personality
traits statistically explain part of the gap in health between socioeconomic groups (Batty et
al., 2006, Hart et al., 2004, Judge et al., 1999, Nabi et al., 2008). Socioeconomic inequalities
in these personal characteristics may partly arise from differences in early environment,
because the comparatively harsh living conditions of families of low socioeconomic status
increase family stress and hamper family investments in children, which could harm their
personality and cognitive ability (Mackenbach, 2010), partly from selection during social
mobility. While inequalities in early environment are likely to have become smaller over time,
and to be smaller in countries with more extensive welfare arrangements, opportunities for
social selection on the basis of these personal characteristics may well have become larger as
noted above.
The ‘neo-materialist theory’ emphasizes the fact that despite increases in average prosperity
and some redistribution inequalities in access to material resources are still universal, and
still generate health inequalities (Lynch et al., 2000, Davey Smith et al., 1994). There is indeed
no doubt that inequalities in material advantage are still substantial everywhere, even in
countries with relatively small income inequalities (Luxembourg Income Study, 2011). The
welfare state, and its redistribution of lifetime welfare through taxation, cash transfers and
12
non-cash benefits, does attenuate material inequalities, but what remains is still substantial
(Ter Rele, 2007). Over the past decades, even ‘diseases of affluence’ have become associated
with material disadvantage, because the latter partly determines health-related behaviours,
such as leisure-time physical exercise, diet etc. (Van Oort et al., 2005).
However, while this theory may provide a plausible explanation for the persistence of
health inequalities, it is unlikely to explain their widening. Over the 20 th century income
inequality has declined in Western European countries, partly as a result of welfare policies,
and the same applies to wealth inequalities (Nolan & Lenski, 2004). It is only since the 1980s
or 1990s that income and wealth inequalities have tended to rise again, partly as a result of
globalization, …) (OECD, 2008). Inequalities in mortality started to rise well before that
(Pamuk, 1985, Strand et al., 2010, Valkonen et al., 2000). Also, within Western Europe there
is no clear association between the magnitude of income inequalities and the magnitude of
Similarly, the ‘psychosocial theory’, which emphasizes the role of psychosocial stress,
lack of social support, and sense of control (Marmot, 2004, Wilkinson, 2005), cannot
plausibly explain the widening of health inequalities, although the unequal distribution of
these psychosocial factors may contribute to their persistence. Despite the welfare state,
considerable differences in power and prestige have continued to exist. People with a higher
level of education and income have a much stronger sense of control over their own lives,
and this is linked to healthier behaviour, and lower rates of morbidity and mortality (Bosma
et al., 1999). The perception of material inequality, and in particular of one’s own ‘relative
deprivation’, may have a direct effect on a person’s health via psychosocial stress
mechanisms (Wilkinson & Pickett, 2009). The welfare state may have blurred some of the
13
inequalities in psychosocial stress, but the middle classes have also benefited from the
welfare state, for example because it has reduced the psychosocial stress of job insecurity
However, in order to explain the widening of health inequalities one would have to
assume that inequalities in exposure to psychosocial risk factors have increased over time,
and this is unlikely, if only because material hardship in lower socioeconomic groups must
have been a powerful source of psychosocial stress in the past. It has sometimes been
argued that advanced welfare states may raise unrealistic expectations of a better life among
people with a lower socioeconomic position, and therefore induce higher levels of frustration
and stress (Dahl et al., 2006, Wilkinson & Pickett, 2009), but this is largely speculative.
Studies of the ‘diffusion of innovations’ have observed that people with a higher
socioeconomic position often tend to be early adopters of new behaviors, only later to be
followed by those with a lower social position (Rogers, 1962). This theory provides a
improvements in population health occur that are mediated by behavior change. Many
Western European countries, particularly those in the North and West, have entered a new
disease, some cancers, injuries, …) which dominated the third stage are rapidly being pushed
back (Omran, 1971, Olshansky & Ault, 1986). This is partly the result of health care
interventions, partly the result of behavior change, such as quitting smoking and adopting a
more healthy diet (Goldman & Cook, 1984, Capewell et al., 1999). As predicted by this
theory, these behavior changes tend to follow a trajectory through populations in which
14
those with a higher social position adopt the new behavior first (Lopez et al., 1994, Sobal &
stunkard, 1989). As a result, this dynamic phase is characterized by large and widening
inequalities in health behaviors, which in their turn lead to large and widening inequalities in
mortality (Cavelaars et al., 2000, Roskam et al., 2010). Within Western Europe, countries in
the South happen to be in a later stage of this transition, with inequalities in health
behaviors only recently arising and inequalities in ‘diseases of affluence’ still being small
(Mackenbach et al., 2008, van der Heyden et al., 2009, Avendaño et al., 2006).
The ‘inverse equity’ hypothesis, which postulates that “new interventions will initially
reach those of higher socioeconomic status and only later affect the poor [….] which results
in an early increase in inequity ratios” (Victora et al., 2000) is based on a similar line of
reasoning, but focuses on the emergence of inequalities in the use of preventive or curative
health care during periods of rapid health improvement. These inequalities may be due to
differences in both access and uptake, and may explain part of the socioeconomic
It is as if, during the most dynamic phases of health improvement, the marginal
benefits of a higher social position for health temporarily become larger. Economic resources
may play a role: in the early stages of their implementation new interventions are often
expensive, and being rich may temporarily become very important for preserving health. But
in the case of behavior change cultural resources may also play a role. The theory of ‘cultural
knowledge and competency between socioeconomic groups which are transmitted across
generations. These differences partly arise from the need for ‘social distinction’: people in
higher socioeconomic groups behave differently to show off their social position, but doing
15
this successfully requires a lot of ‘cultural capital’ (Bourdieu, 1984). It is unlikely that, during
the last decades, inequalities in ‘cultural capital’ have increased, but the need for ‘social
distinction’ on the basis of health-related behaviour may have increased due to the decline in
importantly, the relevance of cultural capital for health is likely to have increased with the
16
DISCUSSION
Synthesis
Only some of the reviewed theories can provide a plausible and specific explanation for the
persistence and even widening of health inequalities in the advanced welfare states of
Western Europe. The ‘mathematical artifact’, ‘fundamental causes’ and ‘life course’ theories
reframe the problem in different (and potentially useful) terms but do not provide a specific
explanation for the paradox. ‘Neo-materialist’ and ‘psychosocial’ theories help to understand
why health inequalities persist, i.e. because inequalities in access to material and immaterial
resources persist. If modern welfare states would have abolished the economic and social
structures which produce unequal lives, health inequalities would probably have largely
disappeared. But these theories do not explain their widening, or the fact that health
inequalities do not tend to be smaller in countries with more generous welfare policies.
The other four theories hold more promise, and can be used to derive two general
hypotheses on the explanation of the paradox. The first hypothesis is that the lower social
strata have become more exclusively composed of individuals with personal characteristics
which increase the risks of ill-health. This is the result of decades of upward
intergenerational social mobility, which may have increased opportunities for social selection
and may have made the lower social groups more homogeneous with regard to personal
characteristics like low cognitive ability and less favorable personality profiles. The increase
of intergenerational social mobility is primarily due to changes in the economy which have
led to an expansion of higher education, but to the extent that welfare policies have
contributed to making the education system more merit-based, they may paradoxically have
17
The second hypothesis is that advanced welfare states happen to be further in their
epidemiological development, and have now reached the fourth stage of the epidemiological
transition in which health improvement depends to a large extent on behavior change. This
may have increased the importance of immaterial factors like cultural capital (and personal
characteristics like cognitive ability) for health – factors which may be as strongly (cultural
capital) or even more strongly (personal characteristics) socially differentiated than they
were before, because they have largely been left untouched by the welfare state. To the
extent that welfare policies have contributed to making an ‘affluent lifestyle’ widely
inequalities.
That inequalities in access to material and immaterial resources have not been
eliminated could be seen as a partial failure of the welfare state: had more radical
redistribution measures been taken, then social inequalities might have been reduced more
effectively, and health inequalities might have declined as well. The welfare state, however,
has never had such revolutionary goals. On the contrary, its rise reflected a compromise
between the interests of employers and employees, between the laboring and the middle
classes, and between the political ideologies representing these interests (Hicks 1999). It
therefore should not come as a surprise that its redistributive effects were modest.
It is also not surprising that the welfare state did not have effective solutions for
widening inequalities in ‘diseases of affluence’. The welfare state’s ‘bad luck’ was that, while
it had been invented to remediate poverty and its consequences, it was soon overtaken by
the rise and subsequent fall of ‘diseases of affluence’, against the social patterning of which
the old arsenal was largely ineffective. One poignant illustration is tobacco control: countries
18
which have made stronger tobacco control efforts tend to have larger socioeconomic
As explained in the introduction, the approach followed in this paper was similar to
that in Bambra (2011). The latter paper reviewed six theories: ‘artifact’, ‘health selection’,
sometimes conceptualized differently, these theories roughly correspond with what I have
factors’, ‘psychosocial pathways’ and ‘life course’. Bambra did see some value in the ‘cultural-
behavioural’ approach for explaining the ‘puzzle’ or ‘paradox’, but her over-all conclusion was
that these theories “provide little insight”, mainly because most of them “to a greater or
lesser extent expect health inequalities to be smaller in the Scandinavian countries”. The
analysis reported here reviewed three additional theories (‘fundamental causes’, ‘personal
two hypotheses based on, respectively, a combination of the ‘social selection’ and ‘personal
‘psychosocial’ theories for understanding why health inequalities persist (because the
welfare state has far from eliminated inequalities in access to material and immaterial
resources).
Limitations
As stated in the introduction, this analysis had a hypothesis-generating character, and does
not pretend to provide final answers. Its limitations include the theoretical nature of the
analysis: although most of the nine ‘theories’ have substantial empirical support, empirical
19
analyses that try to explain the persistence and widening of health inequalities in advanced
welfare states from these theories are almost non-existent. I suggest that further research on
the paradoxical relationship between welfare policies and health inequalities should focus on
the specific hypotheses that can be derived from these theories. This will require
considerable efforts in data mining and/or data collection, because internationally and/or
historically comparable data on the composition of social strata or on the social distribution
of immaterial resources are difficult to find. The hypothesis on the changing composition of
personality profiles and cognitive abilities between different birth cohorts. The hypothesis on
the rising importance of immaterial resources can be empirically tested by comparing the
It is likely that further research would also benefit from unpacking welfare regimes
into specific components: some Nordic welfare policies may reduce inequalities in health,
while others are neutral or may even exacerbate them. The same applies to measures of
socioeconomic status. This analysis was limited in the sense that I have used a global concept
of socioeconomic status, ignoring the fact that education, occupational class, income, … have
partly different associations with mortality and morbidity. The various mechanisms which
were reviewed may also have different relevance for each of these indicators of
socioeconomic position: for example, selection effects (reverse causality) are likely to be
more important for income than for education. Further research will benefit from a higher
Policy implications
20
Can health inequalities as they are currently found in Western Europe still be regarded as
‘unfair’, and do widening health inequalities imply that they are becoming more unfair?
These are questions that immediately arise when one considers the hypotheses suggested
Determinants of Health, 2008), that health inequalities are ‘unfair’ is not obvious. Health
inequalities are certainly ‘tragic’ – it is sad that people who have less of everything also tend
to live shorter lives and spend more years in ill-health, and it is disappointing that after all
that has been done to reduce social inequalities and their consequences, health inequalities
have not been eliminated. But because health is not a ‘good’ that lends itself for
redistribution, the unfairness of health inequalities does not automatically follow from their
existence, however tragic this may be. Normative evaluations need to focus on how health
inequalities arise: it is the processes by which, or the circumstances from which they arise
that should be evaluated for their distributive fairness (Whitehead, 1991, Daniels et al., 1999,
Deaton, 2011). The analysis presented in this paper of how health inequalities arise therefore
If the hypotheses presented in this paper are correct, then current health inequalities
arise from partly different mechanisms as compared to those observed before the rise of the
modern European welfare state, some 50 years ago (with variations between countries).
Nowadays, health inequalities arise in a society with considerable social mobility, and
whether one stays poor when one is born poor may have become partly dependent on
personal characteristics like cognitive ability and personality factors. Some of the involuntary
causes of health inequalities have been taken away by extensive welfare arrangements, and
although patterns of oppression and exploitation can still be distinguished these have to
some extent been softened by democratization and equal rights movements. Health
21
inequalities between social strata partly arise from differences in consumption behaviour,
which may partly be determined by cultural factors and personal characteristics, and not only
by material disadvantage. Health inequalities have recently widened, not necessarily because
of widening inequalities in access to material or even immaterial resources, but possibly also
because of changes in the composition of social strata and because the marginal benefits of a
Even those (like the present author) who believe that current inequalities in income,
status and power are too large to be justified by whatever differences there are between
individuals in merit or effort, and must therefore partly result from subtle and less subtle
forms of exploitation, and who believe that social inequalities in consumption behaviour do
not result from the exercise of free choice but from differences in material and immaterial
living conditions, may ask themselves whether if the hypotheses presented here are correct,
current health inequalities are perhaps less unfair than those observed 50 years ago – even
though they are larger. Can health inequalities that result from differences in composition of
social strata be considered unfair, even if they are a by-product of social policies promoting
equal educational opportunities? Can health inequalities that result from to differences in
immaterial resources (such as cultural capital), which do not directly result from forms of
oppression or exploitation, and which do not easily lend themselves for redistribution
between social strata, be considered unfair? Can health inequalities that are a temporary
side-effect of over-all progress, from which everyone in the end will probably benefit, be
considered unfair?
But even if current health inequalities would not unambiguously and completely be
considered unfair, they are still likely to be seen as partly unfair, and unfairness is not the
only legitimate reason for reducing them. One may also find them tragic, and want to reduce
22
them because they reinforce social inequalities by depleting the smaller resources of people
in lower socioeconomic groups, and by preventing them to reinforce their social position.
Other reasons include the huge population health losses due to health inequalities, and the
economic costs of health inequalities (e.g. through lost labour productivity and costs of
It is no wonder, therefore, that there have been many pleas for reducing or even
eliminating health inequalities, and that several European countries have developed and
2003, Independent Inquiry into Inequalities in Health, 1998, Mackenbach & Stronks, 2002,
The 2005 Public Health Policy Report, 2005, National strategy to reduce social inequalities in
health, 2007, National Action Plan to Reduce Health Inequalities 2008-2011). These attempts
have so far, however, been insufficiently effective. The most powerful attempt at tackling
health inequalities so far, the English strategy of successive Labour governments in the
period 1997-2010, has produced a few positive intermediate results but has failed to reduce
health inequalities. This was due to a lack of policies of proven effectiveness and a lack of
Mackenbach, 2011).
If the hypotheses presented in this paper are correct, neither of these two
have been ineffective against health inequalities, partly because of a failure to implement
have changed the composition of socioeconomic groups and made health inequalities more
sensitive to immaterial factors. In that case, a substantial reduction of health inequalities can
only be achieved with more radical redistribution measures, and/or a direct attack on the
23
personal, psychosocial and cultural determinants of health inequalities. As long as there is
insufficient political support for the first, and as long as the second is unfeasible because of a
lack of effective interventions, those who want to reduce health inequalities will have to be
24
Literature
Abel, T. (2008). Cultural capital and social inequality in health. J Epidemiol Comm Health, 62,
e13.
Arrow, K., Bowles, S. & Durlauf, S. (eds.) (2000). Meritocracy and economic inequality.
Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Avendaño, M., Kunst, A.E., Huisman, M., Lenthe , F.J. van, Bopp, M., Regidor, E., Glickman,
M., Costa, G., Spadea, T., Deboosere, P., Borrell, C., Valkonen, T., Gisser, R., Borgan, J.K.,
Gadeyne S. & Mackenbach J.P.(2006). Socioeconomic status and ischaemic heart disease
mortality in 10 western European populations during the 1990’s. Heart, 92: 461-467.
Bambra, C. (2011). Health inequalities and welfare state regimes: theoretical insights on a
public health ‘puzzle’. J Epidemiol Comm Health 65: 740-745.
Bambra C., Netuveli, G. & Eikemo T. (2010). Welfare state regime life courses : the
development of Western European welfare state regimes and age-related patterns of
educational inequalities in self-reported health. Int J Health Serv, 40, 399-420.
Beckfield, J. & Krieger, N. (2009). Epi + demos + cracy: linking political systems and priorities to
the magnitude of health inequities--evidence, gaps, and a research agenda. Epidemiol Rev.
31:152-77.
Barker, D.J.P., Osmond, C., Winter, D.P., Margetts, B. & Simmonds, S.J. (1989). Weight in infancy
and death from ischaemic heart disease. Lancet, 2, 577–580.
Batty, G.D., Der, G., Macintyre, S. & Deary, IJ. (2006). Does IQ explain socioeconomic
inequalities in health? Evidence from a population based cohort study in the west of
Scotland. BMJ, 332, 580-584.
Bosma, H., Schrijvers, C.T.M. & Mackenbach, J.P. (1999). Socioeconomic inequalities in
mortality and importance of perceived control: cohort study. BMJ 1999, 319, 1469-1470.
Breen, R. (ed.) (2004). Social mobility in Europe. Oxford etc.: Oxford University Press.
Capewell, S., Morrison, C.E. & McMurrey, J.J. (1999). Contribution of modern cardiovascular
treatment and risk factor changes to the decline in coronary heart disease mortality in
Scotland between 1974 and 1994. Heart, 81, 380-386.
Cavelaars, A.E.J.M., Kunst, A.E., Geurts, J.J.M., Crialesi, R., Grötvedt, L., Helmert, U., Lahelma,
E., Lundberg, O., Matheson, J., Mielck, A., Rasmussen, N.K.R., Regidor, E., do Rosário Giraldes,
M., Spuhler, Th. & Mackenbach, J.P. (2000). Educational differences in smoking: international
comparison. BMJ, 320, 1102-1107.
25
Commission on Social Determinants of Health (2008). Closing the gap in a generation: Health
equity through action on the social determinants of health. Geneva: World
Health Organization.
Dahl, E., Fritzell, J., Lahelma, E., Martikainen, P., Kunst, A.E. & Mackenbach, J.P. (2006).Welfare
state regimes and health inequalities. In: Siegrist J, Marmot M (eds.), Social inequalities in
health. New evidence and policy implications. Oxford/New York, Oxford University Press. ISBN
0-19-856816-9.
Daniels, N. et al. (1999). Why Justice Is Good for Our Health: The Social Determinants of
Health Inequalities. Daedalus, 128, 215-251.
Davey Smith, G., Bartley, M., & Blane , D. (1994). Explanations for socioeconomic differentials
in mortality: evidence from Britain and elsewhere. Eur J Publ Health, 4, 131-144.
Deaton A.S. (2011). What Does the Empirical Evidence Tell Us About the Injustice of Health
Inequalities? Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1746951
Eikemo, T.A., Bambra, C., Joyce, K. & Dahl, E. (2008). Welfare state regimes and income-related
health inequalities: a comparison of 23 European countries. Eur J Public Health, 18, 593-599.
Eikemo, T.A., Huisman, M., Bambra, C. & Kunst, A.E. (2008). Health inequalities according to
educational level in different welfare regimes: a comparison of 23 European countries. Soc
Health Illness, 30, 565-582.
Eikemo, T.A. & Huijts, T.(2009). Causality, social selectivity or artefacts? Why socioeconomic
inequalities in health are not smallest in the Nordic countries. Eur J Publc Health, 19, 452-453.
Eikemo, T.A., Skalicka, V. & Avendano, M. (2009). Variations in relative health inequalities: are
they a mathematical artefact? Int J Equity Health, 8, 32.
Erikson, R. & Goldthorpe, J.H. (1992). The Constant Flux: A Study of Class Mobility in Industrial
Societies. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Fair Society, Healthy Lives (the Marmot review), 2010. London: Department of Health.
Also available at: http://www.ucl.ac.uk/gheg/marmotreview
Fawcett, J., Blakely, T. & Kunst, A.E. (2005). Are mortality differences and trends by education
any better or worse in New Zealand? A comparison study with Norway, Denmark and Finland,
1980-1990s. Eur J Epidemiol, 20, 683-91.
Ferrera, M. (1996). The southern model of welfare in social Europe. J Eur Soc Pol, 6, 17-37.
26
Ganzeboom, H. & Treiman, D.J. (2007). Ascription and achievement in occupational
attainment in comparative perspective. Paper prepared for presentation at The Sixth Meeting
of the Russell Sage Foundation/Carnegie Corporation University Working Groups on the
Social Dimensions of Inequality UCLA.
Ganzeboom, H.B.G., Luijkx, R. & Treiman, D.J. (1989). Intergenerational Class Mobility in
Comparative Perspective. Research in Social Stratification and Mobility, 8, 3-84.
Goldman, L. & Cook, E.F. (1984). The decline in ischemic heart disease mortality rates. An
analysis of the comparative effect of medical interventions and changes in lifestyle. Ann Int
Med, 101, 825-836.
Grusky, D. (2010). Social stratification. In: Ritzer G, Ryan JM (eds.). The concise encyclopedia of
sociology. Wiley-Blackwell.
Hart, C.L., Taylor, M.D., Davey Smith, G., Whalley, L.J., Hole, D.J., et al (2004). Childhood IQ
and cardiovascular disease in adulthood: prospective observational study linking the Scottish
Mental Survey 1932 and the Midspan studies. Soc Sci Med, 59, 2131-2138.
Heyden J.H. van der, Schaap, M.M., Kunst, A.E., Esnaola, S., Borrell, C., Cox, B., Leinsalu, M.,
Stirbu, I., Kalediene, R., Deboosere, P., Mackenbach, J.P. & Oyen H. van (2009). Socioeconomic
inequalities in lung cancer mortality in 16 European populations. Lung Cancer, 63(3), 322-330.
Hicks, A. (1999). Social democracy and welfare capitalism. A century of income security
politics. New York: Cornell University Press.
Houweling, T.A.J. , Kunst, A.E., Huisman, H. & Mackenbach, J.P. (2007). Using relative and
absolute measures for monitoring health inequalities: experiences from cross-national
analyses on maternal and child health. Int J Equity Health, 6:15.
Hurrelmann, K., Rathmann, K., Richter, M. (2011). Health inequalities and welfare state
regimes. A research note. J Public Health 19: 3-13.
Independent Inquiry into Inequalities in Health (the Acheson report), 1998. London:
Department of Health. Available at: http://www.archive.official-
documents.co.uk/document/doh/ih/ih.htm (accessed September 18th, 2010)
Judge, T.A., Higgins, C.A., Thoreson, C.J. et al (1999). The big five personality traits, general
mental ability, and career success across the lifespan. Person Psychol, 52, 621–652.
27
Kautto, M., Fritzell, J., Hvinden, B., Kvist, J. & Uusitalo, H. (eds.) (2001). Nordic welfare states in
the European context. London/New York: Routledge.
Link, B.G. & Phelan, J.C. (1995). Social conditions as fundamental causes of disease. J Health
Soc Behav, extra issue, 80-94.
Lopez, A.D., Collishaw, N.E. & Piha T. (1994). A descriptive model of the cigarette epidemic in
developed countries. Tob Control, 3, 242-247.
Lynch, J.W., Davey Smith, G., Kaplan, G.A. & House, J.S. (2000). Income inequality and
mortality: importance to health of individual income, psychosocial environment, or material
conditions. BMJ, 320(7243), 1200–1204.
Mackenbach, J.P., Stirbu, I., Roskam, A.J., Roskam, A.J., Schaap, M., Menvielle, G., Leinsalu,
M. & Kunst A.E, (2008). And the EU Working Group on Socioeconomic Inequalities in Health.
Socioeconomic Inequalities in Health in 22 European Countries. N Engl J Med, 23, 2468-2481.
Mackenbach, J.P. (2003). An analysis of the role of health care in reducing socioeconomic
inequalities in health: the case of the Netherlands. Int J Health Serv, 33, 523-541.
Mackenbach, J.P., Bos, V., Andersen, O., Cardano, M., Costa, G., Harding, S., Reid, A.,
Helmström, O., Valkonen, T. & Kunst, A.E. (2003). Widening socioeconomic inequalities in
mortality in six Western European countries. Int J Epidemiol, 32, 830-837.
Mackenbach, J.P., Kunst, A.E., Cavelaars, A.E.J.M., Groenhof, F. & Geurts, J.J.M. (1997). . And
the EU Working Group on Socioeconomic Inequalities in Health. Socioeconomic inequalities
in morbidity and mortality in Western Europe. Lancet, 349, 1655-1659.
Mackenbach, J.P. (2010). New trends in health inequalities research: now it’s personal.
Lancet, 376(9744), 854-855.
Mackenbach, J.P., Meerding, W.J. & Kunst, A.E. (2011). Economic costs of health inequalities
in the European Union. J Epidemiol Comm Health 65(5): 412-419.
Mackenbach, J.P. & Bakker, M.J. (2003). And the European Network on Interventions and
Policies to Reduce Inequalities in Health. Tackling socioeconomic inequalities in health: an
analysis of recent European experiences. Lancet, 362, 1409-1414.
Mackenbach, J.P. & Stronks, K. (2002). A strategy for reducing health inequalities in the
Netherlands. BMJ, 325, 1029-1032.
Mackenbach, J.P. (2010). Has the English strategy to reduce health inequalities failed? Soc Sci
Med, 71(7), 1249-1253.
28
Mackenbach, J.P. (2011). Can we reduce health inequalities? An analysis of the English
strategy (1997-2010). J Epidemiol Comm Health 65: 568-575.
Marmot, M. (2004). Status syndrome. How your social standing directly affects your health
and life expectancy. London: Bloomsbury.
Modin, B. & Fritzell, J. (2009). The long arm of the family: are parental and grandparental
earnings related to young men’s body mass index and cognitive ability? Int J Epidemiol, 38,
733-744.
Muntaner, C., Borrell, C., Ng, E., Chung, H., Espelt, A., Rodriguez-Sanz, M., Benach, J., O’Campo,
P. (2011). Politics, welfare regimes, and population health: controversies and evidence. Sociol
Health Illness, 33: 946-964.
Nabi, H., Kivimaki, M., Marmot, M.G., et al (2008). Does personality explain social inequalities
in mortality? The French GAZEL cohort study. Int J Epidemiol, 37: 591–602.
National strategy to reduce social inequalities in health. Report No. 20 (2006–2007) to the
Storting (2007). Oslo: Norwegian Ministry of Health and Care Services. Available at:
http://www.regjeringen.no/pages/1975150/PDFS/STM200620070020000EN_PDFS.pdf
(accessed September 18th, 2010)
National Action Plan to Reduce Health Inequalities 2008-2011 (2008). Publications of the
Ministry of Social Affairs and Health 2008, 25. Helsinki: Ministry of Social Affairs and Health.
Available at: http://www.stm.fi/en/publications/publication/_julkaisu/1063837#en (accessed
September 18th, 2010)
OECD (2008). Growing Unequal? Income Distribution and Poverty in OECD Countries. Paris:
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. ISBN Number: 9789264044180.
Olshansky, S.J. & Ault, B. (1986). The Fourth Stage of the Epidemiologic Transition: The Age of
Delayed Degenerative Diseases. Milbank Quarterly, 64, 355-391.
Pamuk, E. (1985). Social class inequality in mortality from 1921 to 1972 in England and Wales.
Population Studies, 39, 17-31.
Phelan, J.C., Link, B.G. & Tehranifar, P(2010). Social conditions as fundamental causes of health
inequalities: theory, evidence, and policy implications. J Health Soc Behav, 51, S28-S40.
Phelan, J.C., Link, B.G., Diez-Roux, A, Kawachi, I. & Levin, B. (2004). Fundamental causes of
social inequalities in mortality: a test of the theory. J Health Soc Behav, 45, 265-285.
29
Raad voor Maatschappelijke Ontwikkeling (2011). Nieuwe ronde, nieuwe kansen. Sociale
stijging en daling in perspectief. Den Haag: Raad voor Maatschappelijke Ontwikkeling.
Rogers, E.M. (1962). Diffusion of innovations. New York etc.: Free Press.
Roskam, A.J.R., Kunst, A.E., Oyen, H. Van., Demarest, S., Klumbiene, J., Regidor, E., Helmert,
U. Florence, J. Dzurova, D. & Mackenbach, J.P. (2010). Comparative appraisal of educational
inequalities in overweight and obesity among adults in 19 European countries. Int J
Epidemiol, 39(2), 392-404.
Scanlan, J.P. (2006). Can we actually measure health disparities? Chance, 19(2), 47-51.
Schaap, M., Kunst, A.E., Leinsalu, M., Regidor, E., Ekholm, O., Dzurova, D., Helmert, U.,
Klumbiene, J, Santana, P. & Mackenbach, J.P. (2008). Effect of nation-wide tobacco control
policies on smoking cessation in high and low educated groups in 18 European countries. Tob
Control, 4, 248-255.
Sihvonen, A.P., Kunst, A.E. Lahelma, E., Valkonen, T. & Mackenbach, J.P. (1998).
Socioeconomic inequalities in health expectancy in Finland and Norway in the late 1980s.
Soc Sci Med, 47, 303-315.
Sobal, J. & Stunkard, A.J. (1989). Socioeconomic status and obesity: a review of the literature.
Psychol Bulletin, 105(2), 260-275.
Stirbu, I., Kunst, A.E., Bopp, M., Leinsalu, M., Regidor, E., Esnaola, S., Costa, G., Martikainen,
P., Borrell, C., Kalediene, R., Rychtarikova, J., Artnik, B., Deboosere, P., Mackenbach, J.P.
(2010). Educational inequalities in avoidable mortality in Europe. J Epidemiol Comm. Health
64(10): 913-920.
Strand, B.H., Groholt, E.K., Steingrimmsdottir, O.A., Blakely, T., Graff-Iversen, S. & Naess, O.
(2010). Educational inequalities in mortality over four decades in Norway: prospective study of
middle aged men and women followed for cause specific mortality, 1960-2000. BMJ, 340:c654.
Ter Rele, H. (2007). Measuring the lifetime redistribution achieved by Dutch taxation, cash
transfer and non-cash benefits programs. Rev Income Wealth, 53, 335-362.
The 2005 Public Health Policy Report (2005). Summary. Stockholm: Swedish National
Institute of Public Health. Available at:
http://www.fhi.se/PageFiles/4385/r200544fhprsummary0511.pdf (accessed September
18th, 2010)
30
Vagerö, D. & Erikson, R. (1997) Socioeconomic inequalities in morbidity and mortality in
Western Europe [letter]. Lancet, 349:516.
Valkonen, T. Martikainen, P., Jalovaara, M., Koskinen, S., Martelin, T. & Makela, P. (2000).
Changes in socioeconomic inequalities in mortality during an economic boom and recession
among middle-aged men and women in Finland. Eur J Publ Health, 10, 274-280.
Van Oort, F.V.A., Van Lenthe, F. & Mackenbach, J.P.(2005). Material, psychosocial, and
behavioural factors in the explanation of educational inequalities in mortality in The
Netherlands. J Epidemiol Community Health, 59, 214-220.
Vaupel, J.W., Carey, J.R. & Christensen, K. (2003). It´s never too late. Science, 301, 1679-1681.
Victora, C.G. (2000). Explaining trends in inequities: evidence from Brazilian child health
studies. Lancet, 356, 1093-1098.
Wadsworth, M.E.J. (1997). Health inequalities in the lifecourse perspective. Soc Sci Med, 44,
859-869.
West, P. (1991). Rethinking the selection explanation for health inequalities. Soc Sci Med 32,
373-384.
Whitehead, M. (1991). The concepts and principles of equity in health. Health Prom Int, 6,
217-228.
Wilkinson, R.G. (1989). Class mortality differentials, income distribution and trends in poverty
1921-1981. J Soc Pol, 18, 307-335.
Wilkinson, R.G. (2005). The impact of inequality. How to make sick societies healthier.
London: Routledge.
Wilkinson, R.G. & Pickett, K. (2009). The Spirit Level: Why More Equal Societies Almost
Always Do Better. Bloomsbury Press.
31
Figure 1. Mortality by occupational class among men in England and Wales, ca. 1920 – ca.
1980.
Source: modified data from Pamuk 1985
32
Table 1. Excess deaths among the lowest educated, by cause of death, 1990s (Slope Index
of Inequality, expressed as age-adjusted deaths per 100,000 person-years).
33
Box 1. Theories which may help to explain the persistence of health inequalities in high-
income countries with extensive welfare arrangements
34
course of exposures and trends over time or
experiences which affect health geographical patterns within
Western Europe.
Psychosocial Marmot [m] Socioeconomic position is still Persistence of inequalities in
pathways Wilkinson [n] strongly associated with exposure to psychosocial stress
psychosocial stress, e.g. is well documented, and
through variations in exposure psychosocial stress does affect
to demand-control imbalance health, but cannot explain
or through relative deprivation. trends over time or
geographical patterns within
Western Europe.
Diffusion of Rogers [o] Increasing inequalities in health Supported by a lot of evidence,
innovations Victora [p] outcomes result from a faster but theory does not identify
rate of improvement in higher the specific pathways linking
socioeconomic groups, which is socioeconomic position and
due to earlier adoption of new adoption of new behaviors or
behaviors and earlier uptake of uptake of new interventions.
new interventions.
Cultural capital Bourdieu [q] In modern societies, Empirical support is limited,
Abel [r] socioeconomic position is still but may provide specific
strongly associated with pathway for ‘diffusion of
cultural factors such as innovations’ theory. May
normative beliefs and explain paradox if relative
knowledge on health risks, importance of ‘cultural capital’
which strongly affect health for health has increased over
because the latter is largely time.
determined by lifestyle.
35
q. Bourdieu P. Distinction. A social critique of the judgement of taste. Cambridge (Mass.): Harvard University
Press, 1984.
r. Abel T. Cultural capital and social inequality in health. J Epidemiol Comm Health 2008;62:e13.
36