Startup Valuation by Venture Capitalists: An Empirical Study
Startup Valuation by Venture Capitalists: An Empirical Study
Startup Valuation by Venture Capitalists: An Empirical Study
net/publication/241733865
CITATIONS READS
88 11,484
3 authors:
Mathieu Cabrol
Université Savoie Mont Blanc
16 PUBLICATIONS 232 CITATIONS
SEE PROFILE
Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:
All content following this page was uploaded by Arild Aspelund on 26 February 2014.
To cite this article: Tarek Miloud , Arild Aspelund & Mathieu Cabrol (2012): Startup valuation by
venture capitalists: an empirical study, Venture Capital: An International Journal of Entrepreneurial
Finance, 14:2-3, 151-174
This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any
substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing,
systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden.
The publisher does not give any warranty express or implied or make any representation
that the contents will be complete or accurate or up to date. The accuracy of any
instructions, formulae, and drug doses should be independently verified with primary
sources. The publisher shall not be liable for any loss, actions, claims, proceedings,
demand, or costs or damages whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or
indirectly in connection with or arising out of the use of this material.
Venture Capital
Vol. 14, Nos. 2–3, April–July 2012, 151–174
Introduction
How should an entrepreneur value his startup company when he seeks equity
financing from a venture capitalist? And on the other side of the table, how do
venture capitalists value a prospective entrepreneurial firm when they make an
investment decision? These are two central questions that entrepreneurs and venture
capitalists have been struggling with for generations. Yet, currently there is no
systematic answer to these two important questions. To identify good solutions are
essential for both the entrepreneur and the investor for many reasons.
For the venture capitalists, the valuation is important because the value of the
company determines the proportion of the shares they receive in return for their
investments, guides the overall profitability of their fund and thus also affects their
relationship with their fund providers. Likewise, the valuation is important for the
entrepreneur as it governs the motivation and sets a value to the efforts and resources
he puts into his new venture. More than that, research has shown that the valuation
is important because it aligns the ambitions of the entrepreneur and investor, helps
structure and assure a fair treatment (Clercq et al. 2006) and reduces the sources of
potential conflict between the entrepreneur and the investor (Zacharakis, Erikson,
and Bradley 2010). The seminal venture capital study by Tyebjee and Bruno (1984)
shows that the venture capital investment follows a somewhat well-defined process –
starting from deal origination and ending at the exit of investment. In this staged
process, the valuation of an entrepreneurial firm is one of the most important and
challenging issues facing both entrepreneurs and venture capitalists. Tyebjee and
Downloaded by [Universitetbiblioteket I Trondheim NTNU] at 01:48 20 December 2012
Bruno (1984) maintain that establishing the price of venture capital is the heart of
any negotiation between the founders of the venture and potential investors.
According to mainstream finance theory, the economic value of any investment is
the present value of its future cash flows (Brealey, Myers, and Allen 2007). Simple as
it is, this axiom definition of economic value presents a challenge to financial
valuation methods when applied to valuating a new venture. The commonly used
valuation techniques in corporate finance (e.g. discounted cash flow method, earning
multiple method and net asset method, etc.) depend on strict assumptions and
require information that new ventures typically cannot provide (such as accounting
information). Hence, their applicability is severely limited in valuating early-stage
new ventures and both venture capitalists and entrepreneurs are frustrated by huge
variance of valuations computed from the extant methods for exactly the same new
venture. Practically, the practice of startup valuation by venture capitalists remains a
‘guess’ and ‘alchemy’.
The need for more rigorous research in venture capital investment, in general, has
also been recognized by many prominent entrepreneurship scholars. For example,
Barry (1994, 3) points out that ‘in spite of the intriguing issues in venture capital
finance, relatively little has been published on this subject in the most influential
finance journals’. Furthermore, some studies (see, e.g. Waldron and Hubbard 1991;
Hall and Hofer 1993; Gompers 1999) review studies of startup valuation in both the
entrepreneurship and corporate finance literature and find that there is a gap in the
extant literature. More recently, several studies in the entrepreneurial finance
literature have investigated the factors that influence the investment process. For
example, Silva (2004) studies venture capitalists’ (VCs) decision-making and finds
that their attention is focused on the entrepreneur, the business idea, its sustainable
advantages and growth potential. According to his study, the financial projections of
the prospect do not seem to play a major role in the selection of early-stage projects.
Levie and Gimmon (2008) explain why there is a suboptimal evaluation by investors
of the human capital of first-time high tech venture founders – they support the idea
that there is a gap between in-use and espouse investment criteria, and extensive use
of gut feeling in decision-making.
These studies show that there is a great need for a better understanding of startup
valuation for both practical and theoretical reasons. Venture capital investment in
general, valuation in particular, is a very important entrepreneurial phenomenon and
we do not know sufficiently about this critical aspect of the entrepreneurial process.
This study aims to contribute by performing a quantitative empirical investigation of
the influence of non-financial, strategic factors on the actual valuation of French
startup firms. We identify the most influential factors for firm performance from three
different but complementary strategic perspectives – industry organization economics,
Venture Capital 153
resource-based view and network theory for our analysis. The result is the first step on
an alternative route to startup valuation based on strategic analysis rather than
manipulation of ‘imaginary’ numbers.
rivalry, entry and exit barriers, and firm characteristics, such as its development stage
and competitiveness, are qualitative rather than quantitative factors which
significantly influence firm value. To gain insight into these factors for valuation
purposes, we need to look to other theories than finance for directions. In particular,
the entrepreneurship and strategic management literatures provide us with
considerable insight on the antecedents of firm performance and how value is
created in an entrepreneurial process.
Over the past half century, several theories have been developed to explain and
predict firm performance and value creation. Three of these are of particular
relevance to our startup valuation context: (i) industry organization economics, (ii)
resource-based view and (iii) network theory. Each of these theories approaches the
central issue (firm performance) from a different perspective. The industry
organization tradition focuses on the structure of the market in which firms
compete and highlights the importance of industrial structure in determining firm
performance. The resource-based view conceptualizes the firm as a bundle of
valuable resources and stresses the importance of internal resources in predicting
firm performance. Bridging the two ends of the spectrum, network theory
underscores how the external relationships of a firm channel resource flow and
shape its strategies, and hence impact its performance. By putting them together, we
seek to develop an integrated framework to estimate the value of a startup.
This theoretical framework suggests that firm resources, external ties and market
opportunities jointly determine firm performance, which is unobservable ex ante, but
is the theoretical base for firm value, upon which venture capitalists and
entrepreneurs negotiate their individual estimates of the valuation. Through
negotiations between the venture capitalists and the entrepreneur over their
estimations of future economic performance of the startup, their estimations
converge and the deal is priced. The logic of this approach is straightforward. The
constructs (and related variables) in the framework have been found important to
firm performance in the strategy literature. If financial methods relying on an
estimated future cash flow can come up with a valuation for a new venture, the
strategic management approach developed here can achieve similar (or better) results
when future cash flow is difficult to estimate but input factors that influence future
cash flow can be objectively measured. Obviously, when it is difficult to value a
subject based on output (future cash flows), pricing it based on inputs (entrepreneur,
industry attractiveness, etc.) may be a better alternative than ‘pure guess’. As the first
exploratory study applying strategy theories to startup valuation, this study may not
completely solve the problem, but based on accumulated knowledge of the strategy
field over the past half century, empirical findings in new venture performance and
venture capital investment literature, and discussions with entrepreneurs and venture
154 T. Miloud et al.
capitalists, there are substantial justifications that the model will perform well.
According to Dittmann, Maug, and Kemper (2004), the use of multiple valuation
methods significantly reduces the failure rate of funding agreements between venture
capitalists and entrepreneurs.
The framework also has high internal consistency. A fundamental similarity
between industry organization economics and the resource-based view is that both
theories assume competition is the ultimate force that drives (or determines) firm
performance and any factors – exogenous or endogenous – that impede the
competitive forces that are positively related to firm performance. Industry
organization theory takes an exogenous perspective by focusing on industry
Downloaded by [Universitetbiblioteket I Trondheim NTNU] at 01:48 20 December 2012
Product differentiation
Caves (1972) argues that product differentiation is one of the most important
structural elements of an industry and is positively related to firm performance.
Comanor and Wilson (1967) examined consumer goods industries (at three-digit SIC
code level) and found that industries with high advertising intensity earn higher rates
of return on equity. Porter (1980) argues that industries characterized by low
product differentiation require new entrants to attend to cost and capacity
considerations, which encourages retaliation against entrants and decreases venture
Venture Capital 155
Industry growth
Hall and Weiss (1967) find that industry growth rate is positively associated with
industry profitability. Porter (1980) argues that because rapid industry growth
Downloaded by [Universitetbiblioteket I Trondheim NTNU] at 01:48 20 December 2012
ensures that incumbents can maintain a strong financial performance, even though a
new entrant takes some market share, an entrant into a rapidly growing industry
may experience less retaliation. Also, Peltzman (1977) notes that rapid market
growth can be beneficial for small firms in lowering costs and enabling such firms to
more rapidly assimilate critical skills and knowledge needed for effectively competing
in the marketplace. According to Porter (1980), in early stages of the industry life
cycle (when industry growth is usually rapid), the costs of entry may be much less
than the costs would be for later entrants because of the minimum scale of entry is
much smaller. There are initially few entry barriers and seldom dominant actors that
can wield monopolistic power. Thus, early entrants may be able to erect entry
barriers and gain monopoly profits after they successfully enter the market.
Specifically, new entrants entering industries in the introductory stage may realize
the benefits of establishing: (i) product standards; (ii) a reputation in the
marketplace; (iii) higher customer awareness; (iv) high switching costs; (v) control
of scarce resources; (vi) control of distribution channels and (vii) barriers to
subsequent entry. Finally, industries in the early stages of development provide an
opportunity for new entrants to capture the new demand in markets that have
relatively little likelihood of retaliation by established incumbents.
Zider (1998) stresses that the lucrative nature of industry growth has long been
chased by practicing venture capitalists, who usually focus on the middle part of the
classic industry S-curve (where growth is most rapid). They avoid both the early
stage, when technologies are uncertain and market needs are unknown, and the later
stages, when competitive shakeouts and consolidations are inevitable and growth
rates slow dramatically. Venture capitalist usually can give new ventures in a rapidly
growing market higher valuation, just because the market conditions may allow the
entrepreneurs to make some mistakes and the investment is less risky compared with
similar projects in a low growing market (in which even a small mistake may be
vital). Lower risk can usually justify higher valuation. Therefore, we advance the
following hypothesis:
H2 – The growth rate of an industry is positively related to the valuation of new ventures in
this industry.
Hofer 1987; Aspelund, Berg-Utby, and Skjevdal 2005) and top management team
(TMT) effects (see, e.g. Eisenhardt and Schoonhoven 1996). The heterogeneity of the
entrepreneurial team in terms of experience, education or function provides a signal
to potential investors and is associated with a higher capital accumulation especially
during an initial public offering (IPO) (Zimmerman 2008).
Assumable, as the most important human resources a new venture can have, the
founder/entrepreneur plays a critical role in initiating and growing the new business.
This fact has been unanimously acknowledged by both academic and venture capital
practitioners, and the positive influence associated with the founder/entrepreneur
can be found in numerous entrepreneurship studies, e.g. Tyebjee and Bruno (1984),
Downloaded by [Universitetbiblioteket I Trondheim NTNU] at 01:48 20 December 2012
MacMillan, Siegel, and Narasimha Subba (1985), Gimeno, Folta, and Cooper (1997)
and Aspelund, Berg-Utby, and Skjevdal (2005). The resource-based perspective
suggests a positive relationship between human resources associated with the startup
and its valuation.
Entrepreneur
From a venture capitalists perspective, Timmons (1992) assesses that entrepreneur’s
‘track record’ of ‘thorough and proven operating knowledge of the business they
intend to launch’ is very important. Numerous studies on venture capitalists
investment process report that experience (a combination of industry, technical,
management, startup experience) is a very important criterion in funding decisions.
Three types of experience are considered important in determining this track record:
(1) Industrial (technical and/or market) expertise: Siegel, Siegel, and MacMillan
(1993) find that the number of years the entrepreneur has worked in a similar
industry significantly and positively related to sales growth. Similar findings
are also reported by Gimeno, Folta, and Cooper (1997) and that growth
firms tend to be led by entrepreneurs who began their venture based on ideas
developed in their previous jobs. Therefore, we propose:
H3 – A new venture is valued higher if its founder has relevant industry
experiences before founding the venture.
(3) Startup or other entrepreneurial experience: Larson and Starr (1993) argue
that prior startup (entrepreneurial) experience is assumed to yield a
customized set of entrepreneurial skills, a rolodex of network contacts and
Venture Capital 157
a business reputation which are strategic resources that can be leveraged into
future ventures. Rather than ‘starting from scratch’, experienced entrepre-
neurs have accumulated the ‘wealth, power and legitimacy’ which can be used
to surmount the traditional obstacles facing new ventures. Muzyka, Birley,
and Leleux (1996) confirm that the venture capitalists believe that hand-on
direct experience in starting up a new business is an important predictor of
new venture success. Lerner (1994) finds that the venture capitalists
representation on boards of directors increased by 44% for firms in which
the CEO had no prior experience in running an entrepreneurial firm.
Increased board presence of venture capitalists indicates increased needs for
Downloaded by [Universitetbiblioteket I Trondheim NTNU] at 01:48 20 December 2012
both assistance and monitoring, which incurs more costs for the investors.
Therefore, we propose:
H5 – A new venture is valued higher if its founder has previous startup experiences.
Solo founder vs. founding team. With the increasing complexity of technologies and
competition in the marketplace, ‘one-man’ shop becomes more and more difficult
to survive – simply because no one can have all the necessary skills and knowledge
to effectively compete. Eisenhardt and Schoonhoven (1990, 510) argue that ‘more
founders means that there are more people available to do the enormous job of
starting a new firm that there is more opportunity for specialization in decision-
making’. The entrepreneurial team plays a key role in the ventures’ valuation by
venture capitalists (Franke et al. 2008). According to Tushman and Anderson
(1986), entrepreneurial teams help attain strategic maneuvers, including attaining
first-mover advantages, forming strategic alliances or developing discontinuous
innovations. We suggest that entrepreneurial teams also allow firms greater agility
to enter markets quickly and maintain responsiveness to changing market
conditions. Members are the repositories of much of the technical and
management knowledge, skills, and ability that make up the intangible assets of
the firm. Likewise, Eisenhardt and Schoonhoven (1990) found that the size of the
founding team is positively related to new venture’s sales growth. Therefore, we
propose:
H6 – New ventures founded by a team of founders are valued higher than those founded by
one founder.
158 T. Miloud et al.
will not only affect the future performance of the new venture, but also directly affect
the valuation of the new venture by potential venture capitalists. For example, a
well-known venture capitalist states, ‘If we must spend much time to recruit other
managers for him (the entrepreneur), we will definitely value him down’. Zider (1998)
interprets his statement that a complete management team not only carries more
credibility and enhances the chance of success, but also saves time for potential
investors, for venture capitalists routinely assist the entrepreneur in hiring. Siegel,
Siegel, and MacMillan (1993) found that functionally balanced entrepreneurial
teams were positively associated with entrepreneurial firm growth. Therefore, we
hypothesize:
H7 – New ventures with a complete management team are valued higher than those without
one.
Network size
Hoang and Antoncic (2002) propose that actors’ differential positioning within a
network structure has an important impact on resource flows and on entrepreneurial
outcomes. According to Gulati (1995), as one of the most important aspects of
network structure, network size has been frequently used to describe the position of a
focal firm in its network.
Analyses of network size measure the extent to which resources can be accessed
at the level of the entrepreneur (Hansen 1995) and the organization (Baum,
Calabrese, and Silverman 2000). Deeds and Hill (1996) have found that the larger the
network size, the more benefits accrue to the focal firm, subject to the constraints of
Downloaded by [Universitetbiblioteket I Trondheim NTNU] at 01:48 20 December 2012
its capability to effectively manage the network relationships. Stuart, Hoang, and
Hybels (1999) find the more strategic alliances a new biotech venture has formed, the
sooner it will go public and the more money it will raise in an IPO (higher market
valuation). The presence of strategic partners, such as venture capitalists, established
pharmaceutical firms and other business firms, all are positively (significant at
various levels) related to the speed to and valuation of IPO. Therefore, we propose:
H8 – The network size of a new venture is positively related to its valuation by venture
capitalists.
Research methodology
As we are seeking to test proposed causal relationships, we have found a quantitative
research approach to be appropriate. In the following, we will describe our research
design.
characteristics diminished somewhat in later stages’. For the purpose of this study,
early stages include seed stage, startup stage and first stage, consistent with Ruhuka
and Young (1987).
The case selection procedures consist of the following steps. The sample firms
must (i) have received their early-stage venture capital funding in the period from 1
January 1998 to 31 December 2007; (ii) be less than 5 years old at the time of
funding; (iii) be French firms and (iv) not be in the financial and insurance sector.
The sample window period covers both ‘hot’ and ‘cold’ market and is right after the
AMF’s (AMF, French Securities Regulator) electronic filling requirement. The
above sampling procedures yield a sample of 102 new ventures in 18 industries
Downloaded by [Universitetbiblioteket I Trondheim NTNU] at 01:48 20 December 2012
Measurements
The purpose of this research is to attempt to establish the initial theoretical linkage
between the strategy variables and new venture valuation, not to maximize the
explaining power of the model. While there are different ways to operationalize the
variables in the model, we decided to follow the tradition in respective research
streams while also acknowledge the constraints imposed by the availability of data.
Dependent variable
The valuation of a startup is measured by the pre-money valuation, which equals the
announced amount of valuation minus the money invested at the financing round – a
standard way in the venture capital financing literature among author Gompers
(1995). To make sure that the dependent variable is normally distributed, we did a
Shapiro–Wilk W test to diagnose a possible deviation from normal distribution. The
result shows that the data are not normally distributed. Following Gompers (1995),
we did a log transformation of the raw data and used the logarithm of the absolute
amount of the pre-money valuation to measure the pre-money valuation of a startup
company. After the transformation, the dependent variable becomes normally
distributed.
Independent variables
Industry structural variables. Product differentiation: This has been commonly
measured as the advertising intensity ratio, i.e. advertising expenditures divided by
sales revenue of an industry. Therefore, following Caves (1972), we measure the
degree of product differentiation of an industry as total industry advertising
expenditure/total industry sales.
On the other hand, according to Lerner (1995), venture capital investments are
known to be biased towards high-tech industries. In high-tech industries, firms
aggressively pursue technology superiority and develop products with advanced
technological features. Thus, R&D investment is also an important way for firms to
differentiate. In other words, product differentiation may consist of two dimensions:
perceptual differentiation and innovative differentiation. Therefore, we also use the
average R&D investment over sales of an industry as a measure of R&D intensity to
capture the innovative differentiation as a complementary measure of product
differentiation together with the advertising intensity ratio. We can view the
Venture Capital 161
is not available for most private firms. Indeed, we could find such detailed experience
information for only 23 of the 305 founders in the sample firms. As a crude proxy, we
decide to use a dummy variable to measure the founder’s industry experience, which
is coded ‘1’ if any of the founders has worked in the same industry before, ‘0’
otherwise.
Top management experience: Similarly, the management experience of the
founder/founding team is measured by a dummy variable, coded ‘1’ if any of the
founder(s) has worked in any executive positions (VP and above position), ‘0’
otherwise.
Startup experience: We use a dummy variable to indicate the startup experience
of the founder and/or founding team, which is coded ‘1’ when any of the founders
has founded a firm before, ‘0’ otherwise.
Top management team. Following the TMT literature, we define the TMT as the
top two tiers of an organization’s management. This might include the CEO,
chairman, chief operating officer, chief financial officer and the next-highest
management tier of a firm, such as President, Senior Vice President and Vice
President. Such a definition, which is expected to capture the dominant coalition of
the ‘upper echelons’ of the sample firms, has been applied in other research
concerned with strategic actions (Carpenter and Fredrickson 2001) and entrepre-
neurial firm performance (Roure and Keeley 1990). Thus, we follow this common
practice in this study.
Solo founder/founding team: We use a dummy variable to indicate whether a
startup in the sample is founded by a single founder or by a team, which is coded ‘1’
if it is founded by more than one founder and ‘0’ otherwise. While Eisenhardt and
Schoonhoven (1990) use the number of founders of measure founding team size, our
interest here is not to ascertain the quantitative effect of the marginal contribution of
each founder, but rather the qualitative difference between team-based founding and
solo-founder founding in terms of valuation. A qualitative variable is better suited
for our research purpose here.
Team completeness: As discussed earlier in this section, depending on the specific
situation, key positions in the TMT of a new venture may include: (i) CEO/
President, (ii) VP of marketing/sales/business development, (iii) VP of engineering/
technology, (iv) VP of finance/controller and (v) VP of operation/production/
manufacturing (for manufacturing ventures). We use a dummy variable to capture
the completeness of the TMT, which is coded ‘1’ if all of the above positions were
filled at the time of the financing, ‘0’ otherwise. To make sure the coding is accurate,
following Gompers (1999), we also check whether any new positions were filled after
the current financing round, as venture capitalists routinely assist in executive
recruitment for their portfolio companies.
162 T. Miloud et al.
formed after the financing round, we expect this potential problem can be
partially mitigated.
Control variables
Valuating a startup company, or any company, is a complicated task and a
myriad of factors may affect the exact valuation. Some of these factors are
beyond the scope of our theoretical framework. We need to control for the effects
of these factors to avoid making spurious conclusions about our theoretical
variables. Thus, we include various control variables in the model, which include
financial market, industrial and firm-specific factors. The measurement of these
items is straightforward and objective and also follows the established practice in
the relevant literature. Further, all measurements (except firm-level control
variables) are taken directly from their respective data sources, which have
already been calculated.
Previous research finds that movements in the public financial market affect
activities in private financial market. For example, Gompers and Lerner (1999) find
that every doubling of capital infusion into the public capital market is associated
with 26% increase of average valuation in the venture capital market. To control for
this effect, we include the SBF 250 index in the model.
For industry level factors, we include market size and industry profitability as
control variables. Market size is measured by the annual revenue of the industry
defined at five-digit NACE level, as it is the standard way the Euronext Paris
reports the data. While there are several ways to measure profitability, we elect to
use the industry return on investment as the measurement. We also control for
several firm level variables, namely, firm age and firm development stage at the
financing round, and whether the firm is a pure e-commerce firm. Labeled ‘Age’
in the model, firm age is measured by subtracting its founding date from its
financing date and its unit is ‘month’. Firm Developmental Stage is coded as a
categorical variable, coded ‘71’ for ‘seed stage’, ‘0’ for ‘startup stage’ and ‘1’ for
‘first stage’. We use a dummy variable to code whether a firm is a pure dot.com
firm, which is coded ‘1’ if the firm’s main business is mainly conducted through
the Internet and ‘0’ otherwise. Table 1 summarizes the measurements of these
variables.
where a is the intercept, b1–b9 are the coefficients of the theoretical variables to be
estimated, b1–k represent the coefficients of the control variables to be estimated,
where k equals to 6. Substantial firms received multiple early-stage financings in the
sample, with a minimum of one and maximum of four. Including repeated
observations on the same firm in the regression model is likely to violate the standard
assumption of independence from observation to observation in regression models.
The interdependence of observations may lead to firm-specific heteroscedasticity and
autocorrelation. If these problems exist, the coefficients estimated by ordinary least
square (OLS) are inefficient. We went through two procedures to diagnose any
potential violations of the classic assumptions. To diagnose potential heteroscedas-
Downloaded by [Universitetbiblioteket I Trondheim NTNU] at 01:48 20 December 2012
ticity problem, we follow Greene (2007) and examine the data by the Modified Wald
test for heteroscedasticity. The results show that the variances of the dependent
variables are not constant (heteroscedastic) across panels. To correct this
heteroscedasticity problem, we estimate the model with random-effect OLS
estimator, assuming heteroscedasticity across panels. By choosing a generalized
least square (GLS) estimator with assumed heteroscedasticity, the variances of the
error terms are allowed to vary from panel to panel and the effects of those
contemporaneous variances are taken into account in the intercept term. To ensure
that we make a correct choice of the random-effect estimator, we also conduct a
Hausman specification test and the result confirms that random-effects model is
appropriate for our data. Finally, we use the Breusch–Godfrey Lagrange multiple
test to detect possible autocorrelation problem. The result indicates that there is no
serious autocorrelation in the error terms, probably because the time waves are quite
limited.
Table 2 reports the means, standard deviations and minimum and maximum of
all variables used in the model. The 102 new ventures received a total of 184 rounds
of early-stage venture capital financing during the sampling period. There is
sufficient variability among all the variables in the model. The average valuation of
the young firms across all financing rounds is around e6.4 million. The average firm
age at the financing round is around 15 months, with a minimum of 3 months and
The Appendix reports the bivariate correlation matrix of the variables used in the
model. The bivariate correlations between the dependent variable and a number of
independent variables are largely consistent with the theoretical predictions. Five of
the nine theoretical variables are significant at 1% and in the predicted direction. The
matrix also indicates that some of the independent variables are significantly
correlated, but significant correlation between individual variables does not
necessarily mean severe multicollinearity for the whole model. Indeed, the average
variance inflating factor (VIF) of the model is only 1.23, which is far below the
conventional threshold level of 20. Thus, in this case, according to Kutner,
Nachtsheim, and Neter (2004), there is no multicollinearity problem in the data.
Table 3 reports the estimates from the random-effects GLS estimation on pre-
money valuation of the new ventures in the sample. The coefficients are obtained
after correcting heteroscedasticity across panels and controlling some confounding
effects.
Model 1 is the baseline model, which contains the control variables only. Model 2
tests the industry structure effects, Model 3 tests the firm resources effects and Model
4 tests the effects of external network. Model 5 is the full model, containing all the
variables. Except a small variability, the estimates are quite consistent across all the
models. Therefore, we report the results mainly from the full model.
Since our primary interest at this stage of the study is to establish a theoretical
linkage (and substantiate it with empirical evidences) between venture capitalists’
valuation of a new venture and the theoretical variables derived from the theoretical
framework, not to estimate the exact quantitative coefficients of these variables, we
focus our discussion on the general relationships, not on individual coefficients.
166
ROI 0.00104 (0.0004)b 0.0014 (0.00037)a 6.4e-7 (0.0004)a 9.57e-4 (2.85e-4)a 0.0034 (0.00003)b
Stock index 0.00044 (0.00003)a 0.0004 (0.00003)a 3.8e-4 (3e-5)a 3.329e-4 (2.56e-5)a 0.00034 (0.00003)a
Firm stage 0.0067 (0.0006)a 0.0065 (0.0005)a 6.7e-3 (6e-4)a 6.04e-3 (5.29e-4)a 0.00549 (0.00057)a
Firm stage 0.153 (0.009)a 156 (0.009)a 0.1228 (8.7e-3)a 0.1246 (7.1e-3)a 0.112514 (0.008)a
Dotcom dummy 0.09 (0.012)a 0.145 (0.0126)a 0.123 (0.0253)a 3.44e-2 (2.14e-2)b 0.09983 (0.02)a
Constant 3.159 (0.03)a 2.993 (0.037)a 2.948 (0.055)a 3.227 (0.026)a 2.8624 (0.037)a
N 184 184 184 184 184
Wald w2 1760.3(6) 5928.9(9) 2932.5(11) 5922.8(7) 5778.1(15)
Log likelihood 751.98457 750.49872 735.8 732.3786 727.28336
Prob4w2 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
Notes: (i) Coefficients are standardized; (ii) standard error in parenthesis; (iii) coefficients with ‘a’, ‘b’ and ‘g’ are, respectively, significant at 1, 5 and 10% level; (iv) Number
in superscript in the Wald w2 statistics is the degree of freedom for the test.
Venture Capital 167
As predicted, results from Model 2 and Model 4 confirm that the industry growth is
indeed positively and significantly related to the pre-money valuation of new
ventures. These results render strong support for the hypothesis that industry
structure partially determines the startup valuation by venture capitalists. They are
also consistent with McDougall, Robinson and DeNisi’s (1992) study which
concluded that the industry structure influences the performance of new businesses
and the Zider’s (1998) finding that venture capitalists give higher valuation to new
ventures in growing industries.
Downloaded by [Universitetbiblioteket I Trondheim NTNU] at 01:48 20 December 2012
Entrepreneurial resources
Subsequently, we hypothesized that venture capitalists consider the characteristics of
the founder(s) and his management team when valuating a new venture. More
specifically, we proposed that the quality of the entrepreneur and the entrepreneurial
team should be positively related to the valuation of his new venture. Consistent with
the theoretical prediction, all the five subhypotheses about the founder/entrepreneur
and his top management receive strong support.
In terms of founder experiences, the results show that venture capitalists value a
new venture significantly higher if its founder(s) has (i) relevant industry experience
(H3), (ii) relevant managerial experiences (H4) and (iii) startup experiences (H5)
before he founded his current new venture than those without such valuable
experiences. Thus, all hypotheses on the three important experiences measuring the
quality of the founder received strong support. The only exception is for ‘industry
experiences’ in Model 3 with a significance level around 10%, but this may also be
due to a change in the covariance structure in the model.
Regarding the hypotheses on entrepreneurial team, new ventures with a
complete management team are valued significantly higher than those without one
(H7), so are new venture founded by a team of entrepreneurs rather than a solo
founder (H3). Hence, these findings give strong overall support for proposed
relationship that the characteristics of the entrepreneurial team influence new firm
valuation. These findings are also consistent with those from the venture capitalist
screening and selection literature that focuses on the ‘GO/NO-GO’ decision
(MacMillan, Siegel, and Narasimha Subba 1985; Zacharakis and Meyer 1998) as
well as Franke et al. (2008) that find experience at the individual level, the
existence of an entrepreneurial team, the qualifications of team members, the
completeness of the team and its cohesion are important criteria for venture
capitalists’ valuation.
External ties
Consistent with previous findings of Stuart, Hoang, and Hybels (1999) on the public
stock market’s valuation of new ventures on the IPO market, the size of the new
venture’s network (as measured by the number of alliance partners) is significantly
and positively related to its valuation by venture capitalists. This finding supports H8
and is consistent with the literature on the benefits of alliances, particularly with the
work of Zheng, Liu, and George (2010) showing that the inter-organizational
network of a startup, in conjunction with its ability to innovate, influence its
performance and its assessment by venture capitalists.
168 T. Miloud et al.
It is worth noting that the above results are obtained after controlling for
potential confounding effects of other factors from financial market, industry and
firm age, stage of development and whether the new venture is a dotcom, all of which
are highly significantly related to the valuation and in the positive direction.
random-effect GLS estimator to estimate the models. While the GLS estimator is
more efficient and has other benefits, one of the drawbacks of the GLS model is that
it only reports the Wald Chi-squared test as an indicator of the model’s overall fit. It
does not report the R-squared coefficient. Thus, we cannot determine the relative
explanatory power of the models by just looking at the magnitude of the overall
model statistics. Fortunately, a little exploration helps solve this challenge. We know
Chi-squared distribution is the sum of n-squared standard normal distributions,
where n is the number of degrees of freedom. Like the standard normal distribution,
the Chi-squared distribution has several nice features, such as additivity and
divisibility. Following Greene (2007), a feature of particular usefulness to our task
here is that the ratio of two independent Chi-squared variables has the F
distribution. Therefore, we can compare the relative explanatory power of two
models by dividing the two Chi-squared statistics, which is an F distribution. Table 4
reports the F statistics.
From the F-statistic value in Table 4, it is clear that there is no significant
difference among the three theoretical perspectives in terms of their explaining power
of new venture valuation. In other words, it seems that venture capitalists weigh
these factors equally in their valuation. However, such a conclusion may be
premature as the models estimated are not fully specified as many other important
variables from each theoretical perspective are not included in the model.
To further explore this issue, we did another F-test between all the industry
variables (including the three theoretical variables – differentiation and growth, and
two control variables – market size and profitability) and all the firm-level variables
(including all the five theoretical variables and three firm level control variables –
age, stage and dotcom dummy). The value of the F test – F(8/5) – is 4.6962, with a p-
value of 0.0526, which indicates that the difference is still only marginally significant.
Therefore, the relative importance of the respective theoretical perspectives is not
conclusive at this stage.
Conclusions
How to value a company is traditionally a finance topic; however, most financial
valuation methods were developed for well-established companies and especially for
companies in the more efficient public capital market. As demonstrated by Waldron
and Hubbard (1991), the traditional financial methods yield valuations with large
variability. Against such a backdrop, this article leverages established theories in
strategic management to develop an integrated framework and use those input
variables important to firm performance to directly predict the valuation of an early-
stage new venture. Presumably, when it is difficult to value a young firm based on
output (e.g. future cash-flows), pricing it based on inputs (e.g. entrepreneur, industry
attractiveness, etc.) may be a better alternative than ‘pure guess’. Though tentative,
the results from the empirical analyses support the central propositions that strategic
management theories are useful in explaining the valuation of early-stage new
ventures. This empirically substantiated linkage between established strategy
theories and new venture valuation practice makes it possible to develop a
systematic approach to identify and measure factors important to new venture
valuation. Such findings hold a lot of promise for both theory building and practice
in entrepreneurial financing.
For Dittmann, Maug, and Kemper (2004), the use of multiple valuation methods
significantly reduces the failure rate of funding agreements between venture
capitalists and entrepreneurs. Venture capital investors that base their investment
strategy on core business values and adopt a long-term vision seem to have an
advantage over those who engage in short-term subjective bargaining strategies. The
use of valuation criteria from the strategic management provides a long-term vision
of both the venture and of the funding provided after the venture valuation.
Gompers and Lerner (1999) argue that the venture capital has been an important
factor behind both entrepreneurship and innovation in US economy for the past 30
years. Despite its critical importance in venture capital financing, how to value a new
venture is seldom touched in the extant literature and only a handful papers are
available. Moreover, even the few existing studies are clinical and descriptive in
nature. This study goes beyond simple descriptive statistics and fills this noted gap in
the research literature. We leverage well-established theories in strategic
Venture Capital 171
founder and TMT, and external relationships of a new venture on its valuation by
venture capitalists. Robust statistical analyses based on a large sample of 184 early-
stage financing rounds on 102 new ventures provide support for almost all of the
hypotheses, which indicate that the strategic management theories are indeed useful
to explain venture capitalists’ valuation of early-stage new ventures. This empirically
supported linkage between strategic management theories and new venture valuation
practice should hold some promise for exploring complementary valuation methods
for new ventures, especially when traditional valuation approaches are not reliable
due to lack of accounting information.
References
Aspelund, A., T. Berg-Utby, and R. Skjevdal. 2005. Initial resources’ influence on new venture
survival: A longitudinal study of new technology-based firms. Technovation 25: 1337–47.
Barry, C. 1994. New directions in research on venture capital finance. Financial Management
23: 3–15.
Baum, J., T. Calabrese, and B. Silverman. 2000. Don’t go it alone: Alliance network
composition and startups’ performance in Canadian biotechnology. Strategic Manage-
ment Journal 21: 267–94.
Brealey, R., S. Myers, and F. Allen. 2007. Principles of corporate finance. New York: McGraw
Hill Higher Education.
Carpenter, M., and J. Fredrickson. 2001. Top management teams, global strategic posture and
the moderating role of uncertainty. Academy of Management Journal 44: 533–45.
Caves, R.E. 1972. American industry: Structure, conduct, and performance. Englewood Cliffs,
NJ: Prentice Hall.
Clercq, D., H. Fried, O. Lehtonen, and H. Sapienza. 2006. An entrepreneur’s guide to the
venture capital galaxy. Academy of Management Perspectives 20: 90–112.
Comanor, W., and T. Wilson. 1967. Advertising, market structure, and performance. Review
of Economies and Statistics 49: 423–40.
Deeds, D., and C. Hill. 1996. Strategic alliances and the rate of new product development: An
empirical study of entrepreneurial biotechnology firms. Journal of Business Venturing 11:
107–32.
Dittmann, I., E. Maug, and J. Kemper. 2004. How fundamental are fundamental values?
Valuation methods and their impact on the performance of German venture capitalists.
European Financial Management 10: 609–38.
Dubini, P., and H. Aldrich. 1991. Personal and extended networks are central to the
entrepreneurial process. Journal of Business Venturing 6: 305–13.
Eisenhardt, K., and C. Schoonhoven. 1990. Organizational growth: Linking founding team,
strategy, environment and growth among us semiconductor ventures, 1978–1988.
Administrative Science Quarterly 35: 504–29.
Eisenhardt, K., and C. Schoonhoven. 1996. Resource-based view of strategic alliance
formation: Strategic and social effects in entrepreneurial firms. Organization Science 7:
136–50.
172 T. Miloud et al.
Franke, N., M. Gruber, D. Harhoff, and J. Henkel. 2008. Venture capitalists’ evaluations of
start-up teams: Trade-offs, knock-out criteria, and the impact of VC experience.
Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 32: 459–83.
Gimeno, J., T. Folta, and A. Cooper. 1997. Survival of the fittest? Entrepreneurial human
capital and the persistence of underperforming firms. Administrative Science Quarterly 42:
750–83.
Gompers, P. 1995. Optimal investment, monitoring, and the staging of venture capital. Journal
of Finance 50: 1461–89.
Gompers, P. 1999. A note on valuation in entrepreneurial ventures. Harvard Business School
Case 9298082: 1–17.
Gompers, P., and J. Lerner. 1999. Conflict of interest in the issuance of public securities:
Evidence from venture capital. Journal of Law & Economics 42: 1–28.
Downloaded by [Universitetbiblioteket I Trondheim NTNU] at 01:48 20 December 2012
Greene, W. 2007. Econometric analysis. 6th ed. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Gulati, R. 1995. Social structure and alliance formation patterns: A longitudinal analysis.
Administrative Science Quarterly 40: 619–52.
Hall, J., and C. Hofer. 1993. Venture capitalists’ decision criteria in new venture evaluation.
Journal of Business Venturing 8: 25–42.
Hall, M., and L. Weiss. 1967. Firm size and profitability. The Review of Economics and
Statistics XLIX: 319–31.
Hansen, E. 1995. Entrepreneurial network and new organization growth. Entrepreneurship:
Theory & practice 19: 395–412.
Hoang, H., and B. Antoncic. 2002. Network-based research in entrepreneurship: A critical
review. Journal of Business Venturing 17: 1–23.
Kutner, M., C. Nachtsheim, and J. Neter. 2004. Applied linear statistical models. 5th ed. New
York: McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Larson, A., and J. Starr. 1993. A network model of organization formation. Entrepreneurship:
Theory & Practice 17: 5–15.
Lee, C., K. Lee, and J. Pennings. 2001. Internal capabilities, external networks, and
performance: A study on technology-based ventures. Strategic Management Journal 22:
615–40.
Lerner, J. 1994. The syndication of venture capital investments. Financial Management 23: 16–
27.
Lerner, J. 1995. Venture capitalists and the oversight of private firms. Journal of Finance L:
301–18.
Levie, J., and E. Gimmon. 2008. Mixed signals: Why investors may misjudge first time high
technology venture founders. Venture Capital 10: 233–56.
MacMillan, I., R. Siegel, and P.N. Narasimha Subba. 1985. Criteria used by venture
capitalists to evaluate new venture proposals. Journal of Business Venturing 1: 119–28.
McDougall, P., R. Robinson, and A. DeNisi. 1992. Modeling new venture performance: An
analysis of new venture strategy, industry structure, and venture origin. Journal of Business
Venturing 7: 267–89.
Muzyka, D., S. Birley, and B. Leleux. 1996. Trade-offs in the investment decisions of
European venture capitalists. Journal of Business Venturing 1: 273–87.
Peltzman, S. 1977. The gains and losses from industrial concentration. Journal of Law and
Economics 20: 229–63.
Porter, M. 1980. Competitive strategy: Techniques for analyzing industries and competitors.
New York: Free Press.
Roure, J., and R. Keeley. 1990. Predictors of success in new technology based ventures.
Journal of Business Venturing 5: 201–20.
Ruhuka, J., and J. Young. 1987. A venture capital model of the development process for new
ventures. Journal of Business Venturing 2: 167–84.
Sandberg, W., and C. Hofer. 1987. Improving new venture performance: The role of strategy,
industry structure, and the entrepreneur. Journal of Business Venturing 12: 11–25.
Siegel, R., E. Siegel, and I. MacMillan. 1993. Characteristics distinguishing high growth
ventures. Journal of Business Venturing 8: 169–80.
Silva, J. 2004. Venture capitalists’ decision-making in small equity markets: A case study using
participant observation. Venture Capital 6: 125–45.
Venture Capital 173
Stuart, T., H. Hoang, and R. Hybels. 1999. Interorganizational endorsements and the
performance of entrepreneurial ventures. Administrative Science Quarterly 44: 315–49.
Timmons, J. 1992. New venture creation: Entrepreneurship in the 1990s. 4th ed. New York:
McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Tushman, M., and R. Anderson. 1986. Technological discontinuities and organizational
environments. Administrative Science Quarterly 31: 439–65.
Tyebjee, T., and A. Bruno. 1984. A model of venture capitalist investment activity.
Management Science 30: 1051–66.
Uzzi, B. 1996. The sources and consequences of embeddedness for the economic performance
of organizations: The network effect. American Sociology Review 61: 674–98.
Waldron, D., and C. Hubbard. 1991. Valuation methods and estimates in relationship to
investing versus consulting. Entrepreneurship: Theory & practice 16: 43–52.
Downloaded by [Universitetbiblioteket I Trondheim NTNU] at 01:48 20 December 2012
Zacharakis, A., and G. Meyer. 1998. A lack of insight: Do venture capitalists really
understand their own decision process? Journal of Business Venturing 13: 57–76.
Zacharakis, A., T. Erikson, and G. Bradley. 2010. Conflict between the VC and entrepreneur:
The entrepreneurs’ perspective. Venture Capital 12: 109–26.
Zheng, Y., J. Liu, and G. George. 2010. The dynamic impact of innovative capability and
inter-firm network on firm valuation: A longitudinal study of biotechnology start-ups.
Journal of Business Venturing 25: 593–609.
Zider, B. 1998. How venture capital works. Harvard Business Review 76: 131–9.
Zimmerman, A. 2008. The influence of top management team heterogeneity on the capital
raised through an initial public offering. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 32:
391–414.
Downloaded by [Universitetbiblioteket I Trondheim NTNU] at 01:48 20 December 2012
174
(9) Team 0.3124a 70.1276 0.0567 0.0249 0.0203 0.1328 0.0852 0.0667 1.000
completeness
(10) Network size 0.3570a 70.0157 70.0349 0.1093 0.0421 0.0455 0.0680 0.0868 0.2925a 1.000
(11) Market size 0.1539a 70.1230 70.2765a 0.2346a 70.0926 0.1409a 0.0781 70.0240 0.0547 0.0893 1.000
a
(12) ROI 70.0520 0.0439 70.0883 70.1690 0.0150 70.0511 0.0348 0.0278 70.0703 70.0450 0.0014a 1.000
a
(13) SBF 250 0.2945a 70.3503a 0.0422 0.0145 0.0726 0.0861 0.0287 0.0371 0.2131 0.2077a 0.2099 70.2046a 1.000
index
a a a a
(14) Firm age 0.2923a 0.0582 0.1436 0.1595 0.0134 70.0650 70.0724 70.0229 0.2557 0.2647 0.0487 70.1157 0.1082 1.000
(15) Firm stage 0.3436a 0.0004 70.0245 70.0450 0.0762 70.0006 0.0605 0.0658 0.1894a 0.2233a 0.0459 70.0941 0.1983a 0.2698a 1.000
a
(16) Dotcom 0.1126 0.000 70.2929 70.0517 70.0759 70.0745 0.1186 0.0242 0.0242 0.1546a 0.0651 0.1219 70.0382 70.0040 0.0629 1.000
dummy